The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
FOREWORD On October 24 and 25, 1980, the Center for the Study of American Business at Washington University and the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis cosponsored their fifth annual conference, "The Supply-Side Effects of Economic Policy." This volume contains the papers and comments delivered at that conference. Proponents of "supply-side economics" have challenged the policy recommendations that emerge from "Keynesian" macroeconometric models. These models focus on the effects of economic policy on the demand for output. Supply-side economics, in contrast, emphasizes the response of output to changes in the supply of inputs. Decisions affecting the capital stock and employment-in particular, saving and investment decisions and labor force participation and hours decisions-are the focus of the supply-siders' attention. The 1980 conference examined most of the major themes associated with supply-side economics. The papers in Part I of this volume develop the theory underlying various supply-side propositions and present empirical evidence in support of some of these propositions. In Part II, the effect of taxes on capital formation and the effect of increased capital formation on output growth and inflation are examined. The effect of tax and transfer programs on labor supply, employment and unemployment are examined in Part III. The final section contains the special luncheon and dinner presentations. Leading proponents of supply-side economics develop the underlying theory and evidence in support of their propositions in Part I. In "Tax Rates, Factor Employment, and Market Production," Victor Canto, Douglas Joines, and Arthur Laffer (CJL) develop a simple, static, one-good, two-factor general equilibrium model in which taxes on factor incomes drive a wedge between gross factor payments and net factor incomes. The authors then derive the response of factor supplies, output, and tax revenue to changes in tax rates. They demonstrate that the framework is consistent with the existence of the so-called "Laffer Curve," according to which increases in tax rates initially increase government revenue up to some revenue maximizing tax rate but decrease tax revenue beyond this point. CJL note that the theoretical analysis only suggests the possibility that tax rate reductions may raise tax revenue. Empirical evidence is required to demonstrate whether or not tax rates are in the vii VIII / FOREWORD viii/ FOREWORD prohibitive range of the Laffer curve. In the second half of their paper, CJL therefore employ a time series analysis of tax revenues 1962 and 1964 to estimate the effects of the the Kennedy tax cuts in 1962 1964 on tax revenues. They conclude that the cumulative cumulative revenue change induced by the tax tax cuts is approximately zero, with an equal chance that the tax cuts increased revenue as that that they reduced it. “An Econometric In "An Econometric Model Incorporating the Supply-Side Policy,” Michael Evans discusses the Effects of Economic Policy," implications of the supply-side macroeconometric macroeconometric model he recently developed. According to Evans, stimulating investment is a key to supply-side policy because it will will both increase real growth and moderate inflation. Evans finds that investment would would be significantly stimulated by reductions in tax rates, regardless of whether whether the tax cuts apply to corporate income, personal income, or capital gains. He believes that a change in the corporate tax rate has the most powerful effect on investment, and an increase in the investment tax credit has the least impact. Evans also examines in considerable detail the influence of personal tax cuts, cuts cuts in capital gains taxation, and a variety of other plans to stimulate saving. These tax reductions raise the after-tax real rate of return and increase saving; the increased saving saving in turn increases demand for assets, lowering interest rates and stimulating investment. In the labor market equations, Evans finds important effects of of tax rates on both labor supply (participation rates and hours worked) and on wage gains. The effect of taxes on wage gains is particularly particularly important because it permits tax declines to moderate moderate inflation. Curve,” Alan Blinder "Thoughts on the Laffer Curve," Blinder notes that the In “Thoughts proposition that the function relating tax rates to tax revenues rises to a peak and then falls is both an old idea and a noncontroversial noncontroversial one. The important issue raised by the CJL paper, according to Blinder, is whether or not current U.S. tax rates are in the prohibitive range of the the Laffer curve, implying that that a decrease in tax rates would increase tax revenues. Blinder presents a simple model and employs alternative values of the critical labor supply to provide some and demand elasticities to some hints as to whether whether or not it is plausible that we could be in this prohibitive range. He “the revenue maximizing tax rate is very likely to be concludes that "the so high as to be considered ridiculous for any broad based tax.” tax." Steven Braun, who discusses the Evans paper, raises a number of serious questions about the specifications of the key equations in the Evans model: the Phillips curve curve and the labor force FOREWORD/ FOREWORD / ix participation, hours, investment, and consumption (saving) that each of Evans' equations. Braun concludes that Evans’ key policy conclusions conclusions is derived from an equation which is marred by serious misspecification. Albert Ando also discusses the Evans paper and reinforces Braun's concern about misspecifications in the Evans model. He Braun’s on the two equations focuses on Evans' Evans’ productivity equation and on in which the output of the productivity equation plays a role: the manhours manhours equation and the equation explaining maximum production. Ando concludes that the Evans model is dominated by a pattern of major defects, making it of questionable value as a the effects of policy changes. tool for examining the Parts II and III provide evidence on the effects of economic policy on investment and labor supply, respectively. In "Tax “Tax Policy and Corporate Investment," Investment,” Lawrence Summers evaluates various arguments in support of policy measures to stimulate investment response of investment and then presents empirical evidence on the response to an assortment of tax changes. Summers concludes that policies to encourage investment will result in only a small increase in the growth over the next decade, that that tax policies to rate of economic growth to moderate stimulate investment are unlikely to moderate inflation, and that that fears of insufficient capital accumulation as a source of of unemployment are groundless. However, despite his pessimism about increased economic growth or reduced inflation via tax policies designed to stimulate investment, investment, Summers concludes that that tax rate reductions may substantially reduce the deadweight deadweight loss associated with capital income taxation and substantially improve economic welfare. In “Estimates "Estimates of Investment Functions and Some Implications Growth,” Patric Hendershott evaluates the for Productivity Growth," Evans’ macroeconometric model and discusses investment sector of Evans' the implications of the composition of investment for productivity Evans’ treatment of growth. Hendershott concludes that Evans' nonresidential investment and residential investment does not represent an advance relative to conventional treatments. treatments. Hendershott also considers ways in which economic policy can affect economic growth by channelling investment into into more in implicitly mandated productive uses. He notes that the surge in investment in the last decade and the subsidy extended to ownerownerinvestment occupied housing have tended to divert investment from its most productive uses and, therefore, to lower the productivity associated with a given capital stock. with X x /7 FOREWORD EOREWORD Summers’ paper, Norman B. Ture takes issue In his discussion of Summers' with Summers’ Summers' conclusion regarding the effects of tax cuts cuts on investment. Ture questions the adequacy of the framework that Summers used to investigate these issues. While he accepts Summers' associated Summers’ view that there are substantial welfare gains associated with decreasing taxes on on capital income, Ture concludes that that Summers "grossly underestimated" the gains in output and “grossly underestimated” employment which would result from reducing the existing tax bias against capital formation and saving. “Income and Payroll Tax Policy In the first paper in Part III, "Income and Labor Supply,” Supply," Jerry Hausman presents evidence on the supply. Hausman effects of income and payroll taxes on labor supply. emphasizes that while supply-side economics has focused attention attention on the labor supply and revenue effects of changes on tax rates, the the correct measure of the economic cost of taxation is the deadweight loss associated with taxation. Hausman compares the implications the Kemp-Roth of JO"lo 10% and 30% tax cuts, along lines suggested by the tax proposal, with with a move to a linear progressive tax system (i.e., one with progressive average tax rates but constant marginal tax rates). He finds that Kemp-Roth tax cuts cuts decrease deadweight loss, but they do so at the expense of a large decline in tax revenue. A linear income tax which yields the the same revenue as the current tax system, on the other hand, can significantly reduce deadwcight deadweight loss as well as increase labor supply. “Transfers, Taxes and the NAIRU,” NAIRU," Daniel Hamermesh In "Transfers, presents a detailed examination of the effects of individual tax and transfer programs on the unemployment rate (specifically, on the the NonAccelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment, NAIRU), labor supply and employment. employment. He argues that this microeconomic approach, building up from a study of individual programs, is likely to be more reliable than an aggregate or or macroeconomic approach that ignores the programs’ complexities. programs' While Hamermesh concludes that the net effect of tax and transfer programs on the NAIRU NAJRU is approximately zero, he finds they have a significant effect on labor supply, noting that all the the programs he examines are likely to decrease labor supply on net. Hamermesh concludes that we cannot ease ease program eligibility and raise benefits without inducing change in labor supply and employment, which further raise the costs associated with the various transfer programs. age for programs. He suggests raising the eligibility age Old Age and Survivors Insurance benefits back to its previous level its FOREWORD / FOREWORD/ xi and preventing the evolution of Disability Insurance into a retirement program. Hausman’s paper, Jeffrey M. Perloff concludes Commenting on Hausman's that the paper provides the most reliable labor supply estimates to date. Perloff does, however, raise a number of questions about Hausman’s Hausman 's methodology and examines some some of the implications of moving from Hausman's Hausman’s partial equilibrium analysis to more of a general equilibrium framework. Commenting on Hamermesh's Hamermesh’s paper, Fredric Raines questions Hamermesh's conclusions about the overall effects of the various Hamermesh’s transfer programs on on unemployment and labor force participation. Raines agrees that the macro evidence is unreliable, but he questions Hamermesh’s Hamermesh's selectivity in accepting or rejecting evidence from from various studies of the effects of individual tax and transfer programs. He also notes that it may be inappropriate to treat the effects of the various programs as additive, as Hamermesh does in his paper. In his luncheon speech, "The “The Power of Negative Thinking: Performance," Murray L. Government Regulation Regulation and Economic Performance,” Weidenbaum warns that, at a time when when the importance of tax incentives on on economic activity is being debated, economists economists should increasing array of government not overlook the continually increasing regulation that that impairs economic activity. In the current maze of of a change in the after-tax rates government regulation, the impact of of return may, according to Dr. Weidenbaum, have little effect on production. On the other hand, hand, the response of the economy to cuts can be greatly enhanced by simultaneously supply-side tax cuts reducing the burden of regulation on the economy. “The Politics of Supply-Side Economics," Economics,” In his dinner talk, "The concludes that the establishment of a Senator Orrin G. Hatch concludes “budget process" process” in Congress in the mid ‘7Os "budget '70s has not helped arrest arrest spending or the reliance on on deficits. the growth in government spending war between supply-siders who seek substantial tax cuts However, a war and the various constituencies for for federal government spending spending is that supply-side unnecessary, according to the Senator. He believes that tax cuts will sufficiently stimulate economic activity to pay for the current rate of government expenditures. Washington University Laurence H. Meyer Chairman, Chairman, Dept. of of Economics ACKNOWLEDGEMENT A CKNO WLEDGEMENT Many people associated with the Center for the the Study of American Business and the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis have contributed to the planning planning of this conference and to the particularly like production of this proceedings volume. II would particularly to thank Marcia B. Wallace, of the the Center for the Study of American Business, who supervised the arrangements for the conference and helped edit the manuscripts and prepare them for publication, to Chris Varvares, who was my assistant, and provided enormous help at all stages of the conference and with production of the volume, and to Dan Brennan, of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, who helped prepare this volume. L.H.M. Tax Rates, Factor Employment, and Market Production VICTOR A. CANTO DOUGLAS H. JOINES ARTHUR B. LAFFER INTRODUCTION An increasing amount of attention has recently been devoted to the effects of alternative tax structures on the pattern of economic activity, on the level of taxable economic activity, and on the aggregate amount of revenue generated by the tax system. In this paper, a static, one-sector, two-factor model is developed in order to analyze the effects of taxes imposed purely for the purpose of generating revenues. 1 For simplicity, these taxes are assumed to be proportional taxes on the incomes of factors of production. We derive some properties of the tax structure needed to maximize output while raising a given level of government revenue. We then examine empirically a specific instance of tax cuts, the Kennedy cuts of the early 1960s, to determine their effect on revenues. The model we present is a highly simpHfied one. While we call our two factors of production capital and labor, we do not distinguish one as fixed and the other as variable. Since the model is static, we do not attempt to analyze the process of capital formation.' Instead, we assume that at any point there exist fixed stocks of capital and labor and that these stocks must be allocated either to household production or to market sector production.' Victor Canto and Douglas Joines are Assistant Professors of Finance and Busines1 Economics. and Arthur Laffer is Professor of Business Economics at the Graduate School of Business, University of Southern California. 'More accurately, our model only has one market outpuc It is in facl a two-sector model in lhe sense that it has a household production sector which also employs capital and labor in proportions which depend upon their relative cost. 'For dynamic models which treat capital formation as the outcorne of au intertemporal utility maximization process see Canto (1977) and Joines (1979). 'For a discussion of househQld production see, for examp!e, Becker and Ghez (1975). 3 PRODUCTION 44 // TAX RATES RATES AND AND PRODUCTJON THE MODEL MODEL Two factors are combined in the market sector according to a Cobb-Douglas production function to produce produce the market good Q: Q: (I) Q = K°L0~), (I) where a and (l elasticities of capital (Kl (1 - a) are the partial output elasticities (K) and labor (L), respectively, and 0O < < a< a < I. The market good, capital, and labor are inputs into the household production process. Capital and labor thus have identical analytical properties except that they are not not perfect substitutes in either household or market production. We assume that in the market sector are that factors employed in are paid their marginal products and that the rental rate received by capital (R *) and the wage rate received by labor (W*) (W*) differ from the rates (R*) paid because of the taxation of factor income: —~ (2) W* = W(l tL) = ti) (3) R* = R(l t~) = tK) — — where W and R are the gross-of-tax wage and rental rates on labor and capital services, and t~ l1, and t~< tK are the tax rates on income of labor and capital, respectively. These tax rates are expressed as percentages of the rental and wage wage rates paid. The gross-of-tax factor payments are denominated in terms of the market good Q. A change in the ratio of W to R will cause a change in the ratio of capital to labor demanded by by firms for production of any level of market goods. One of the characteristics characteristics of the Cobb-Douglas Cobb-Douglas production function is the constancy of of the shares of the factors of production. Accordingly, the demands for labor and capital and the optimal factor proportions are: (4) Kd = aQ R (5) Ld (6) (l - IK) W* 1 Kd aa w a Wa( tK)V.T* = Ld L’1 (I - a) R (I a) tL) (] - le) (] (l a) (I R* = (] (1 -— a)Q a)Q W w — — — CANTO, AND LAFFER LAFFER/ CANTO, JOINES, JOINES, AND / the ratio of W* to R A change in the R*t will cause a change in the ratio of capital to labor demanded by households for production of any level of the household household commodity. In addition, an increase in *, given the same ratio of W* to the absolute levels of W* W’~and R R*, R*, R •, will cause households to substitute market goods for capital and labor in the production of a given level of of the the nonmarket commodity. In other words, an equiproportional increase in W* and R* causes households to supply more of both capital and labor to the market sector. Specifically, we assume that the supply functions for capital and labor take the following form:'4 following form: R* 5 (7) K K' (8) LL'5 (R*\OK(R*\E = (~:) OK(R*Y C + = \W*/ \ / c::)°L(w•y = (\V*\OL(w*Y = \R*/ ~ / o~>0 C + 01 >0 It is assumed that the the government derives its revenue entirely from proportional taxes on factor income, that its budget is always balanced, and that revenue collections collections are returned to the economy generated.’5 in a neutral fashion so that no income effects are generated. 4 that these factor supply elasticities. Notice that these assumptions yield yield positive positive own-price factor 5,' LR LR W* 8L w* ØL -~L- ~ OW* tKR — (o, .. + 0 (°L ± t) t)>> 0 ~ c)> 0 + The cross-price elasticities, however, could he be either either positive positive or negative. negative. £ tk,.,,.. <~‘ — tLR C LR = w* 8K K aw• R' R — ~ W* 8K — --K aw* L L BL FL ag~ BR' > .2:_o -o —0 K - < > 0 .::,_ OL L< < 5 ‘For For simplicity simplicity it is assumed that: athe form of transfer payments to individuals, a. government expenditure takes the receipt receipt of which is unrelated to factor supply, b. there isis no waste or inefficiency on government, and on the part of the government, costless to collect and distribute, c. taxes and transfers are costless distribute, respectively. Under these conditions government spending will have have no net income effect, effect, only a due to the relative price changes resulting from the taxes. Joines substitution effect effect due (l 979) and Canto Canto (1977) develop a similar analysis of government fiscal policy in (1979) tiscal policy Miles (1980) which the possibility of deficit financing is presented. Canto and Miles consider consider the possibility of income effects resulting from different types of government expenditure, collection col!ection costs, costs, and the government efficiency level. 5 S 66 // TAX RATES RATES AND TAX AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION Combining equations 77 and 8, the the ratio of factors supplied to the Combining market sector is: (9) (9) K L5 (~~\G o, \W*J >0 - where o,, o~,tthe he elasticity of substitution in factor supply, is assumed to be positive and defined as 01< + oL o~ + + e. oK + £. Equation 9 says that that the the ratio of capital to labor supplied to the market sector depends only On the other hand, equation 6 upon the after-tax wage-rental ratio. On says that the proportion proportion of capital to labor demanded by the the market sector depends only upon the gross-of-tax wage-rental ratio. the equilibrium Combining the two equations, one can solve for the level of the gross- and net-of-tax wage-rental ratio as as a function of the tax rates: (10) W* W* R* frI = — a\ (I_—_tL~ l+o, ,/ \l a — taJj 05 (11) W(l_a\[(l_a~(ltL~~0s R \ a a J\l_txJj I Equations 10 IO and 11 show that both the net-of-tax wage-rental ratio ratio upon tax rates, factor and the gross-of-tax wage-rental ratio depend upon supply elasticities, and output elasticities of the two factors. It can be shown that if producers maximize profits, the cost function of the market good will also be of the Cobb-Douglas form: (12) I = (~)~ (w)(l~) where the market good has been defined as the numeraire. numeraire. 12 and substituting for the gross-of-tax Rearranging equation 12 wage-rental ratio (equation 11), one can solve for the gross-of-tax wage rate: a0 5 (13) w (l - a) W=6-a) [(l_a\ a J (1-tL~] \l t~/ - - 1+05 CANTO, JOINES, AND LAFFER/ Similarly, the gross-of-tax rental rate can be expressed as: (14) R = a- Substituting equations 13, 14, 2, and 3 into the factor supply equation, one can determine the equilibrium quantities of each factor and the proportions of capital to labor employed in the market sector: (16) (17) K ""' -l+a5 L The equilibrium level of market output as a function of the tax rates is obtained by substituting equations 15 and 16 into equation 1: aL - a 5 (l + f)ct (18) l + a5 Q EFFECTS OFTAXATION ON MARKET ACTIVITY :* Upon inspection of equations 13, 14, and 11, it is apparent that an increase in the labor wedge {Le., a reduction in (TL = )J will unambiguously increase the equilibrium levels of the gross-of- 1 8 // TAX RATES AND PRODUCTJON PRODUCTION 8 TAX RATES rate (W) and wage-rental ratio (W/R) tax wage rate (W /R) and decrease the rates.' equilibrium levels of the gross-of-tax rental rates.’ The increase in the the gross-of-tax wage-rental ratio will generate a substitution effect away from labor into capital. The equilibrium level of labor employed in the market sector will unambiguously of the tax on the equilibrium level of capital decline.' decline.’ The effect of will employed will be ambiguous.' ambiguous.’ However, the capital-labor ratio will ‘Defining = T = = (I "Defining E as the d log operator, TTL = (1(I —- 5,) t 1) and TK (l — - t~) tK) 1 1< obtains Differentiating logarithmically Equations 11 one Equations 13, 13, 14 14 and ll obtains 13) EW =- 14) ER =- -—~—— I (I ~ 15)E(W/R) * E(T /T,) 1< — a)o. 1-4-n Eli N/Ti) = E(T /T~) 1< ~ - Notice that ET 1< = dt 4- and ET 4TN — —- dt T1 t. = ‘Differentiating "Differentiating logarithmically equation IS 16 EL = £ ET, OL -·- = cw, ~L:1~± !I -~+ o, as £ EO 1< 1~ rK+ (o~= aor /T,) + o~+ I + n (l_a)0 t] 5 (l+n~) ET, - The cocfficicnr coefficient for the the ETK ET K tern, term is clearly ambiguous. This ambiguity is due to two opposing effects. One is the substitution subsritution effect generated generated by by an increase in the tax rate on capital which leads to a higher hig}1er proportion of labor services being used in in the production of of market goods, (reduction in goods, and the other is a scale effect (reduction in output) which leads to a lower amount amount of labor services being demanded. Whether Whether employment of labor on the relative strength of the two labor increases or not nor depends on effects. On the the other hand, since + aL > > 0, 0, °~ 0, and ft > effects, since<-a + a_,>> 0, > 00 by assumption, the the ET positive. In this case, the the scale and coefficient for the ETL term is unambiguously positive, 1 substitution effect reinforce each other. 8 ‘Differentiating IS Differentiating logarithmically equation 15 ElK = a ET,~—EK=tETK = l(J = t(l f(I -— a)o -= a,., —~ S' "K E(TK/TL) E(T /T ) 11 + K L + o, a)o. —o EI~ * - cr)o, ~x -OK lI+o, + o, - a + cr0 + a -=-·-~-r:rw_., + OK I+o, l + o --—-—- ~- ' As in the previous footnote, the coefficient coefficient ET 1< the second term is unambiguously for the that of the first term is clearly tirst positive, while that dearly ambiguous. The ambiguity of the first term term is due to two opposing effects. One is the the substitution effect which which leads to a higher proportion of capital per worker work-er and the other is the scale effect (reduction (reduction in amount of capital output) which leads to a lower amount capita! being demanded. Whether employment of capital increases or not depends on the relative strength of the two. two. CANTO, JOINE5, AND LAFEER / CANTO, JOINES, AND LAFFER/ unambiguously increase, resulting in a net reduction of the level of goods.’ The effects of an increase in the production of the the market goods.' tax on income from capital can be analyzed in a similar manner. Using the simplified model developed in the the previous section, we derive certain certain propositions concerning concerning the effects on output and government revenue of changes in the two tax rates. The specific forms taken by the proofs of these propositions depend upon the structure we have assumed for our model. This structure allows us to obtain a closed form solution for the the variables of interest. Despite its simplifications, we feel the present model is useful as a pedagogic device for demonstrating the propositions. Most of these propositions can be proved using less restrictive models which derive the factor supply decisions as explicit explicit results results of utility maximization, treat capital accumulation in a dynamic framework of intertemporal choice, and allow for the possibility of government debt. Proposition 1. I. There exists a trade-off between taxes on labor necessary to maintain level. and capital necessary maintain output at a given level. The percentage change in output is: EQ = = (19) E ET C ETL L - (°L (0 L — \ o,(l + o~(l+ (I + a,) (l+o,) -— E)a) E(T IT ) e)a\ E(TK/TL) / K L At a given level of output (i.e., on an isoquant), EQ EQ =0. = 0. Thus, the the previous equation implies that: ‘For a Cobb-Douglas production function, E(K/L) "For E(K/L) was shown that that E(w/R) E(TL/TK) = = = E(W/R). E(W /R). In footnote 6, 6, itit <0 — I + Differentiating equation 18 18 logarithmically a,oL —- n/I os(l + a)a £)a EQ == aET EQ EETL— 1 EQ = II++ r~.(I -— a) (I + E)a,(l . Il*a, + a, a’, o, — a NET E(TN/Tj) + aØ + r)n — n — ‘ETN (l+o,) T and T TKK appear to be ambiguous. The signs of the coefficients for TL ambiguous. However, it isis 1 apparent that as long as the own own price elasticities effects dominate the cross-price supply, the elasticities of factor supply, the coefficients will be unambiguously positive. In In the is assumed that own effects dominate cross remainder of this paper, it is cross effects. This assumption is consistent consistent with available empirical evidence on factor supply. An implication of this assumption is that an increase in any of the factor tax rates will unambiguously reduce the level of market output. 9 10 // TAX R0 OD U CCT ON T A X RATE R A T E S AND AN 0 P PR 0U T II 0 N FIGURE I Tx (20) -!~-ii~ I = ETL + a UI1 E(I + a,) o,(l oQ + + E)a e)a — <O ' from which one can derive the marginal rate of factor tax substitution.” This is merely the rate at which the economy can substitution.'" substitute the tax on a given factor of production for a tax tax on another factor, while keeping output constant. The marginal rate of factor tax substitution is the slope of an isoquant in the tL - tK tK 1. space. Such an isoquant is shown in Figure l. The above assumptions ensure that only one isoquant will pass through any point in the tax space. Also, the the higher the level of tax rates, the lower will be the level of output. Thus, the closer an isoquant is to the origin, the higher is the the level of output to which range, isoquants are concave it corresponds. Within the relevant range) say, the isoquants exhibit a diminishing from above; that is to say, homothetic marginal rate of factor tax substitution. They are also homothetic — “The unambiguous given the assumption that own effects ''"The negative sign isls unambiguous dominate cross effects. See n. n. 9. CANTO, JOJNES, AND AND LAFFER/ CANTO, JOINES, LAFFFR / 11 11 in the tax space. Finally, since it is possible to produce some output without one of the factors being taxed, the isoquants will intersect each axis with a finite slope. Proposition 2. There exists a tax structure that maximizes Proposition government revenue. Here we seek to demonstrate that increases in tax rates are not always accompanied by increases in tax revenues, and the reverse the reverse fact be the case. Total government receipts can be may in fact expressed as: as: (21) o G = = + atd atEI Q[(l -— a)tL + = = + a(l -— TK)]. Q[(l —- a)Q a)(] -— T~) Tc) + Differentiating Differentiating logarithmically, we have: (22) EG = = [(l[ + [o+rxI 1 — j FT1 a) 0~ — ~K l+o, 1 + [(l + r)ao, - oL] + [Q+e~os_—_~L a, lI + o_, [ j ETK —- (I a)(TL) —FT l—Rl—a)TL+aTK] F — - — aTK aT~ ETK. 1—[Q— Or)TL l - [(l - a) TL + aTRI a T Kl Equation Equation 22 shows that the percentage change in tax revenue induced by changes in tax rates depends on the output elasticity with respect to tax rates (the first and third terms) and the levels of the tax rates rates on capital and labor. The equation implies that the government tax revenue will increase initially with increases in the tax rates, but at a decreasing rate. Thus, the the marginal tax revenue with increases in tax rates, finally reaching some raised decreases with point where the marginal tax revenue raised is zero. Beyond this point, any tax rate increases will reduce revenue collection. Tax revenue is maximized at the point at which the the marginal tax revenue zero, Figures 22 and 33 illustrate is zero. illustrate government tax revenues as functions of the tax rates on labor and capital, respectively, assuming that the tax rate on the other factor remains constant. In Figures 2 and 3, two distinct stages can be identified. In Stage I, the normal range, !, &tL 0 and BtK 0. FIGURE 2 G Government Revenues n Tax Rate FIGURE 3 G Government Revenues / Tax Rate CANTO. JOINES, AND LAFFER/ 13 CANTO. JOINES, LAFFER / 13 In other words, lowering tax rates lowers government receipts and vice versa. In in Stage ll, II, the prohibitive range, JG <Oand <O, <0 and ilG <0, a1L otK OIL 8t~( and increases in tax rates on on labor and capital decrease government revenues, and vice versa. In in all the stages, the change in government revenues arising from on the elasticities of the factor changes in the tax rates depends on supply curves, the output elasticities of the factors, and the the level of the taxes. The foregoing foregoing analysis shows that there exists a tax structure structure at which government tax receipts are maximized. The first-order conditions imply that G maximized when 0 is maximized (23) —A + (I (24) —9 + (1— O)BTL + (B + 9aT~ = 0 — cr)(A + DTL + OATK = (3 where (25) A (26) B B = (] + ,)(! - a)o, - oK (I+r)Q—a)o,—oK I + 05 1+0 = J!-± (l + ,) aa_, a)ao, = aL 0 L — Il ++ Os a, From equations 23 and 24, one can solve solve for the factor wedge: (27) TL= TL— (28)) TK A A (l—afl,A+B+I) (l - a )(A + B + l) - = ___B_ __ a(A + B —icr(A + I)l) — — — t)(l —- a)a, (l (I + + LXI a)~~-— oK (l+a)(l—a~J+o,) (l + ,)(1 - a)(l + a,) (l + (I + E)ao, e)ao, - o'-.c (1(l + c)a(l + + a,) o,) — illustrate the marginal wedges which maximize quations 27 and 28 illustrate vernment tax revenues. Using these results, one can then solve ,vernment licitly for the tax rates, the maximum amount of revenue that ,licitly output. government can produce, and the corresponding level of output. apparent also that that these results depend on the supply and ‘ut elasticities of the •ut the factors of production. - CANTO, JO JOINES, CANTO, INES, AND LAFFER LAFFER // IS 15 FIGURE 44 B A D C TK If both factor income tax tax rates are in the prohibitive range, an increase in either tax rate, the other rate constant, leads to a reduction in in total revenue collected. Since both tax rates are in the prohibitive range, the the other factor tax rate must be reduced if revenue is to remain unchanged. Hence the iso-revenue curve is also downward downward sloping in this region, which corresponds corresponds to segment BC in Figure 4. In Case 3, one of the factor tax rates is in the prohibitive range while the other is in the normal range. An increase in the the prohibitive tax rate leads to a reduction in revenue. If revenue is to remain unchanged, the tax rate in the normal range must increase, and the iso-revenue curve is therefore upward sloping. Case 33 corresponds to segments AB and CD in figure 4. Higher valued iso-revenue curves lie inside lower valued curves. In the limit, the iso-revenue curve shrinks to a point, the maximum revenue point (Proposition 2). Proposition 3: There exists a tax structure that that maximizes output output at a given level of government expenditures. CANTO, / 1$ CANTO, JOINES, JOJNES, AND AND LAFFER LAFFER/ 15 FIGURE 44 TL B A C If both factor income tax rates are in the prohibitive range, an increase in either tax rate, the other rate constant, leads to a rates are in the reduction in total revenue collected. Since both tax rates prohibitive range, the other factor tax tax rate must be reduced if revenue is to remain unchanged. Hence the iso-revenue curve is also Segment BC downward sloping in this region, which corresponds to segment in Figure 4. In Case 3, one of the factor tax rates is in the prohibitive range while the other is in the normal range. An increase in the prohibitive tax rate leads to a reduction in revenue. If revenue is to remain unchanged, the tax rate in the normal range must increase, and the iso-revenue curve is therefore upward sloping. Case 33 corresponds to segments AB and CD in figure 4. 4, Higher valued iso-revenue curves curves lie inside lower valued curves. In the limit, the iso-revenue curve shrinks to a point, the maximum revenue point (Proposition 2). Proposition 3: There exists a tax structure that maximizes output at a given level of government expenditures. 16 // TAX RATES RATE5 AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION FIGURE 55 tL Isorevenue lsoquant * t. tK tK K The graphical solution to this problem is quite simple." simple.’’ The level Once this is of revenue collection determines determines the iso-revenue curve. Once known, the objective becomes to find the lowest lowest possible isoquant that satisfies the revenue constraint. At this point the two curves curves two loci has the are tangent. The question becomes which of the two largest curvature at the tangency point. It is obvious that the isorevenue curve can never be below the isoquant. If it were, a lower isoquant (higher output level) could be found that that yields the same amount amount of revenue. The graphical solution is presented in Figure 5. The design of an optimal tax system has long been a matter of concern to economists. economists.’122 In order to design an optimal optimal tax system (since value judgments must be made as to the objective function to be maximized), some sort of social welfare function has to be specified. Our discussion of Proposition 3 3 implicitly assumes that ‘‘For a formal derivation of this proposition, see Canto, Laffer, and Odogwu "For (1978). “For an illustration see Harberger (1974), Mirlees "For Mirlees (1971), Stiglitz Stig!itz (1972), (1972), Cooter (1978). CANTO, JOINES, AND LAFFER / 17 17 CANTO, JOINES, LAFFER/ policymakers have somehow arrived at a social welfare function into which both transfer payments and market output enter with the transfers, some cost cost in terms positive signs. In order to finance the of market output is incurred. Thus, a trade-off exists and the optimum will be at a point where the marginal social gain from the government expenditure equals the marginal social loss from the fall in output. EMPIRtCAL EVIDENCE FROM THE KENNEDY TAX CUTS CUTS EMPIRICAL In the previous section, we demonstrated that there is a tax structure which maximizes government revenue (Proposition 2) and that it is possible for tax rates to be so high as to generate less revenue than would be raised from lower tax rates. Whether any real-world governments have ever operated in the prohibitive range, however, is an empirical issue. There are several ways of analyzing this question, the most common of which is what might be called “elasticities” approach. This approach consists of examining the "elasticities" existing estimates of, for example, factor supply elasticities and tax rates. These estimates are applied to some theoretical model in order to simulate the revenue effects of tax rate changes. In general, the higher the elasticities and the tax tax rates, the more likely it is that the tax rates are in the prohibitive range. One recent study conducted along these lines is that of Fullerton (1980). While this approach can undoubtedly provide valuable information on the revenue effects of tax cuts, it has several shortcomings. The first of these is that the effective tax base may be smaller than total economic activity. Some economic activity may escape taxation because it is legally exempt from taxation or because of outright tax evasion. The factor supply elasticities relevant for an analysis of revenue effects are the elasticities elasticities of supply of factors to taxable activities. If there is a reasonable degree of substitutability between taxable and nontaxable activities, then these elasticities elasticities may well be higher than the conventionally measured overall factor supply elasticities. This problem can be quite severe as concerns saving, since there are many uses to which saving can be put which involve involve a partial or complete tax exemption of the resulting income. Notable among these are residential capital of resulting income. and municipal bonds. Recent discussions of the “underground "underground economy” economy" suggest that under-reporting of income may well make 18 // TA TAX PRODUCTION 18 X RATES RATE S AND A N D PRO D U CT I ON the distinction between taxable and nontaxable activity important for labor supply as well.” well." Another difficulty with employing this elasticities approach in a highly aggregated model is that there are in fact many tax rates which apply to different types of economic activity and also many categories of productive factors, each of which potentially has a different elasticity of supply to taxable economic activity. Given this multiplicity of tax rates and of types of factors, it seems quite likely that some tax rates somewhere in the system are in the prohibitive range. This, in fact, is the very essence of certain tariffs on international transactions which are imposed for protectionist protectionist purposes rather than for revenue generation. Certain features of the domestic U.S. tax system may also result in a high tax rate being imposed imposed on an elastically supplied factor. For example, the federal personal income tax imposes a “marriage Hmarriage penalty” penalty" which taxes the income of a secondary worker at the marginal rate of the primary worker in the family. This fact, combined with evidence that that married women have substantially higher labor supply elasticities elasticities than do prime-age males, makes it at least reasonable to conjecture that some features of the current tax system result in prohibitive taxation. Also, recent evidence indicates that that proprietors of small businesses, who have more control over hours worked than do most employees, may have a considerably higher supply elasticity elasticity than do 4 14 general.’ Finally, effective marginal tax rates can be quite males in general. quite for high for those in upper income brackets and can be even higher for “The JJThe factor supply functions (equations 77 and 8) attempt to take these these effects into account. As tax rates alter the relative price of factors of production, they also alter alter the relative price of the nonmarket (i.e., nontaxed) activities. The change in the in the to the market sector thus depend.s factor supply to depends on two effects, a substitution substitution effect household production and a scale effect. The substitution effect ls is captured by in household by the factor supply equations. E term in both factor These to own own and cross factor supply elasticities, as shown in n. 4. 4. These effects give rise lO The The own effects are always positive, and the cross effects are ambiguous. ambiguous. It can be shown sho,vn that if the rhe product of the own-price elasticities is larger than that that ,vtkp > ttRrK\v). of the cross-price elasticities frI (El,wrh ri,R<=kw), the effects of taxes on on output outpur are the cross effects. However, qualitatively similar to those that neglect the Hmvever, the magnitude of the change will be different. Whether the total effect effect is larger or smaller depends or not the cross-price upon whether wherher or cross-price elasticities offset or reinforce the own-price own-price etfects. In In the the latter case, it is easily shown that the market-output price elasticity effects. will he the case in which the the cross-price elasticities are wil! be larger than the arc zero. Thus, the the factor markets) markets) could neglect of these cross elasticities (the interaction interaction between the lead one to underestimate the economy’s economy's responsiveness to tax tax rate changes. See Canto (I 977) and Joines ( 1979). (1977) Joines (1979). “See "Sec Wales (1973). C A N T O , J O l N E S . A N D L A F F E R / 19 the poorest workers and those receiving Social Security, who stand to lose benefit payments as their earnings increase. The relevant question to ask is thus not whether the United States or some other real-world economy is operating in the prohibitive range. It is quite Hkely that somewhere in the system there exists a tax rate on some type of activity which results in less revenue than would a lower tax rate. The relevant issue concerns the revenue effects of a specific set of tax rate changes.' 5 Of particular interest are recent proposals for broad-based cuts in federal personal and corporate income tax rates. While the elasticities approach might be employed to simulate the effects of such a tax cut, another method suggests itself. 10 This method consists of examining past instances of similar tax cuts to determine their effects on revenue, The Kennedy tax cuts of 1962 and 1964 offer a natural experiment. Following their enactment, the economy experienced a greater than normal expansion of real economic activity. A comparison between measures of economic act1vity prevailing before (l 96 l) and after ( 1966) the tax cuts were enacted indicates that unemployment declined from 6.7 percent to 3.8 percent and capacity utilization as measured by the Federal Reserve Board increased from 77 .3 percent to 91.9 percent. During this period, real GNP grew at an average annual rate of 5.9 percent. The average annual growth rate in nominal GNP was 7 .5 percent, while federal government expenditures grew at a rate of 6.2 percent. Consequently, the ratio of government expenditures to GNP fell. It thus seems unlikely that the increase in economic activity can be attributed entirely to the stimulus of increased government spending. Another issue concerns whether the apparent expansion of economic activity was sufficiently large to offset the negative effect on tax revenues of the tax rate reductions themselves. Alternatively stated, the issue concerns whether the economy was in the normal or the prohibitive range of the Laffer curve. Michael K. Evans' "Fullerton recognizes the multiplicity of tax rates and factor supply elasticities to which we refer. He i~ also careful to simulate the effects of a specific tax cut-a broad-base<l cut in tax rates on labor income. "In using the elasticities approach to simulate the effects of proposals such as the Kemp-Roth bill, one must be careful not to treat them as cuts only in labor income tax rates. They also entail reductions in personal tax rates on income from capitaL The elasticity of supply of saving and factor demand ela&ticities, as well as labor supply elasticities, are important in su<:h a model. In addition, there may be important cross elasticities of factor supply, as discussed in n. 13 above. 20 I/ TAX TAX RATES AND PRODUCTlON PRODUCT(ON RATES AND (1978) examination of revenue data for this time period indicates that revenues from individuals with taxable incomes incomes in excess of $100,001) increased from $2.3 billion in 1962 to $2.5 billion in 1963, $100,000 to $3 billion in 1964, and to $3.8 billion in 1965. Total personal income tax revenues, however, declined between 1963 and 1964. Although high-income individuals would appear to have been in the the Laffer curve, the evidence concerning prohibitive range of the overall personal tax revenue suggests that the weighted average of the individual personal income tax rates was in the normal range. the range. That is, a reduction in the overall personal tax rate led to a loss in tax reduction in revenues. This can be attributed to a loss revenues from individuals at low low income levels in excess excess of the gain in tax revenues revenues from from individuals at high income levels. Other Other casual evidence on the revenue effects of the Kennedy tax tax cuts cuts exists, but there is some dispute as to the interpretation of this evidence. Representative Kemp and Senator Roth have asserted that federal tax revenues during the fiscal fiscal years 1963 through 1968 federal the 1962 showed a cumulative increase of $54 billion over the 1962 level of annual annual receipts, whereas the Treasury Department had estimated a cumulative revenue loss of $89 billion over the the same period as a result of the tax cuts." cuts,’ Heller (1978) and others have pointed out that these two numbers are not comparable, comparable, however. The $54 billion refers to the increase in actual revenues between the earlier and later years. The $89 billion figure is the Treasury Department's Department’s estimate of the difference between actual revenues during the later period and what they would the same period if wonld have been during the the tax reduction had not occurred. That there is no no necessary inconsistency inconsistency between these two numbers can be seen by examining set of estimates reported by Pechman (1965). Pechman a similar similar set forecast that actual individual income tax liability on returns filed for 1965 would be $46.4 billion, or $10.7 billion lower than his estimate of 1965 I 965 liability liability with no tax cut, but $$1.6 l.6 billion higher than actual liability on 1962 1962 returns. Furthermore, if the $89 billion figure cited by Kemp and Roth were adjusted to include similar estimates of of the effects of the Tax Adjustment Act of Treasury estimates estimate would be 1966, the Treasury’s Treasury's cumulative revenue loss estimate be only $83 billion. It is quite possible that the Pechman and Treasury estimates overstate the size of the actual revenue loss resulting from the tax of the early 1960s. 1960s. These estimates are derived by comparing cuts of “See Kemp Kemp (1977). "Sec CANTO, JOINE5, AND LAFFER/ LAFEER / CANTO, JOINES, AND 21 the revenues which would result from applying alternative tax structures to a given level of economic activity. Such “static” "static" estimates thus ignore any feedback effects of tax rates on economic activity and revenues. If these feedback effects are quantitatively estimates may considerably important, then the static estimates considerably overstate the true revenue loss. It would be desirable to obtain an alternative set of revenue loss for any any actual feedback of tax rates on estimates which allow for economic activity. Such estimates would not be based on any prescribed level of economic activity. In the next section, we report such a set of estimates derived from univariate time series analysis of various revenue series and reported in Canto, Joines, and Webb (1980). TIME SERIES ESTIMATES ESTIMATES There are several ways of obtaining revenue estimates without first prescribing a level of aggregate economic activity. activity. The the true desirability of these estimates rests on the belief that the structure of the economy is such that tax rate changes affect economic activity. activity. An obvious way of incorporating incorporating any existing existing feedback effects would be to estimate aa structural model which includes such This model could be used to obtain forecasts such effects. This would have been in the absence of tax rate cuts, of what revenues would and these forecasts could in turn be compared with actual revenues. could be used to simulate the the effects of Alternatively, the model could of various tax changes. difficulties with this approach, however. Aside There are several difficulties from the sheer effort required to design and estimate aa complete structural model, the resulting forecasts would be subject to certain sources of error in addition addition to the parameter estimation errors which affect all all attempts at statistical inference. The most important of these sources is misspecification of the structural model, either either through an incorrect choice of variables to be included in the the model or through the imposition of of incorrect incorrect identifying restrictions. In addition, Lucas (1976) points out that policy simulations simulations based on such structural models models are inherently suspect because the parameters of the model will in general be functions of policy variables and will change in response to shifts in those policy variables. Palm (1974) provide an exhaustive taxonomy of the the Zellner and Palm 22 / TAX RATES RATEs AND AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION TAX types of equations associated with dynamic simultaneous various types equation systems and discuss the uses uses and limitations limitations of each. It is of particular interest to note that the univariate time series properties of the system’s system's endogenous variables are implied by the structure of the model and the time series properties of the exogenous variables. It is thus meaningful to fit time series models to each of the endogenous series over periods when both the structure of the complete model and the time series properties of exogenous variables are stable. One of the primary uses of such the exogenous a simple univariate model is in forecasting forecasting the series to which it is fit. In addition, these models make much more modest demands in terms of data requirements and a a priori knowledge of the system's system’s structure than would full-blown structural estimation. Furthermore, as Nelson (1973) points points out, univariate time series models are not subject to errors errors in specifying the structure of the complete model, and hence in theory need not yield less accurate forecasts than would structural estimation. The results reported in Nelson (1972) indicate that this conclusion holds in practice as well as in theory. 1950 to the the early 1960s there existed the most stable federal federal From 1950 tax policy of any period of comparable length length since the end of World War I. There were no important changes in personal or corporate income tax rates from 1951 to 1964. Compared to the fluctuations in tax rates during the Great Depression, World War II, II, and the the Korean War, the stability during the later period is quite striking. It thus seems reasonable to regard this period as one during which the underlying structure of the economy was fairly stable. Furthermore, the period of stability is long enough to provide a minimal number of observations for estimation of univariate time series models. models. Canto, Joines, and Webb used this period to fit univariate models to various revenue series of interest and employed these models to forecast revenues into the mid-l960s under the assumption that there would would be no changes in tax rates or the underlying structure of the economy. The forecast errors from these models models can regarded as revenue these can be be regarded as point point estimates estimates of of the the revenue changes resulting from the tax rate rate cuts of the early 1960s. The two federal revenue series to which univariate models were fit are denoted FPR and FCR. They represent, represent, respectively, quarterly federal personal income tax receipts and quarterly federal corporate income tax receipts, each deflated by the Consumer Price Index. The base period for the price deflation is the fourth quarter of 1963. None of these series has been seasonally adjusted. CANTO, JOINES, AND LAFFER/ 23 The models which fit these two series are:' s vv .FPRl ""' 0.0026 + lt (0, 11) 6£ "" 0.60 t "" 1956:l - 1963:4 and 0.2403 + 0.156. + {0.12) (0.12) [I + O.2OB 4 ] (0.15) 0.326, + 0.4162 (0.l3) (0.12) au "" 0,47 di ""' l, quarter i, i ""1, ... , 4 0, otherwise - 1962:4 of the residuals t 1and 1\ yielded t "" 1952:4 Examination no indication of model inadequacy. The forecast errors which result from applying these models to the immediate post-estimation observations may be regarded as "Standard errors appear in parentheses below parameter estimates. The model for FPR for the longer period 1952:2 to 1963:4 is slightly complicated due to an "intervention" which occurred in the first quarter of 1955. The Internal Revenue Code of 1954 moved the filing deadline for the federal personal income tax from March 15 to April l5 of ead1 year. This change noticeably altered the seasonal pattern of personal income tax receipts, shifting revenues from the first quarter to the second quarter of each calendar year from !955 onward. Such an intervention could be represented by the model in the differenced serie, 'v'v,FPR, ~ µ, + {wo - w,B - w,B'J !, + ,, where l _ ' - 1, t = 1955: t 0, otherwise. One would expect a priori to find w,, w, yielded the equation 1/V .FPR, "" -0.049 + (0.091) o, = < 0 and w, > 0. Estimation of this model I - 2.00 + 5.998 - 2.278'! (0.61) (0.61) I, + £1 (0.61) 0.60 Examination of the residuals t, gave no indication of model inadequacy. Since !he intervention term does not affect forecast, for the posH963 period, Canto, Joines, and Webb chose to base their analysis on the simpler model reported in the text. See Box and Tiao (l 975) for a description of intervention analysis. 24 / TAX RATES AND PRODUCTION TABLE l Estimates of Cumulative Change in Federal Personal Income Tax Receipts (Billions of Dollars) Cumulative Change Through 1964 Time Seriesa,b -2.93 Treasuryb,c,d Pechmanc,~ -2.4 -9,9 -20.6 ( 1.32) 1965 - 9.31 (6.76) -11.l 1966 -14.43 -23A ( 18 .00) aconstant (]%3:4) dollars. Standard errors appear in parentheses below estimates. 0Fisca! year. "Current dollars. <lSource: H.J. Fowler, "Statement Bdore the Committee on Banking and Currency." /',feelings Wirh Department and Agency Officia{s: Hearings Before the Commitlee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1967, p. 12. •Cumulative change in rnx liability on returns filed for relevant tax year. Source: J. Pechman, "The lndividual Income Tax Provisions of the Revenue Act of 1964." Journal of Finance 20 (May 1965), p. 259. point estimates of the revenue changes resulting from the 1962 and 1964 tax reductions. These estimates may then be compared with other published estimates of the revenue changes. Table 1 contains alternative estimates of the cumulative change in federal personal income tax receipts. The time series and Treasury estimates are for the cumulative change from the time the rate reductions became effective until the end of selected federal government fiscal years. Pechman's estimates are for the cumulative change in tax liability on returns filed for selected tax years, and hence do not cover time periods strictly comparable to those of the other estimates. 19 Comparison of the time series estimates with the various static estimates shows very little discrepancy for 1964, Furthermore, while "The lime series estimates which correspond most closely to the periods covered by Pechrnan are --9.07 (wilh standard error of 4.SJ} for 1964 and -14.77 (with standard error of 14.50) for 1965. CANTO, JOlNES, AND LAFFER/ 25 TABLE 2 Estimates of Cumulative Change in Federal Corporate Income Tax Receipts {Billions of Dollars) Cumulative Change Through Fiscal Year aTime Series bTreasury 1963 -0.06 (1.06) -2.4 1964 L70 (4.34) -4.1 1965 4.77 (8.47) -6,9 1966 10,74 (13.43) -9.5 aconstant (1%3:4) dollars. Standard errors appear in parentheses below estimates. "Current dollars. Source: H. J. Fowler, "Statement Before the Committee on Banking and Currency." Meetings With Depar!ment and Agency Officials: Hearing5 Before the CommiUee 011 Banking and Currency, House of Representatives. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, !967, p. 12. the point estimates are indistinguishable from the various static estimates for that year, they are more than two standard errors below zero. This would seem to indicate that the initial feedback effects on the tax base were negligible. Examination of Table I shows that for years after 1964, the time series estimates show smaller revenue losses than do the static estimates, and by l 966 the difference between the time series and Treasury estimates is considerable. It should be noted that the standard error associated with the time series estimate for 1966 is quite large. Nevertheless, these results, if taken at face value, indkate that there is only about a twenty percent probability that the cumulative change through 1966 was positive. They also indicate, however, that there is only about a thirty percent chance that the cumulative loss was as large as the Treasury estimated. Table 2 contains alternative estimates of the cumulative change in federal corporate income tax receipts resulting from the various corporate tax changes legislated in 1962 and 1964. Whereas the 26 TAX RATES RATES AND AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION 26 /I TAX Treasury estimates show a steadily growing growing revenue loss between 1963 and 1966, the time series estimates show a negligible revenue loss in I1963 963 followed by a steadily increasing revenue gain between 1964 and 1966. As was the case with federal personal personal income tax receipts, the standard error associated with the cumulative revenue receipts, change through 1966 is somewhat large. Nevertheless, these results indicate that there isis only a twenty-five percent chance that there ten percent was aa cumulative revenue loss, and less than a ten probability that there was a loss as great as the Treasury estimated. Thus far we have examined only federal government receipts taxes which were actually reduced in the early early 1960s. As from the taxes 1960s. As Bronfenbrenner (1942, p. 701) points out, however, the notion that reduction in tax rates may increase revenues takes two forms. A direct form limits attention to the specific levy under consideration. As As argument applied to the tax on beer states simply applied in it1 direct form, the the argument that an increased rate would would decrease revenues from the tax on beer, and vice vice versa. tax system. applied to versa. An An ittdirect indirect form form applies applies to to the the general general .... , tax system. As As applied to the the beer tax, it states that even though an increased rate may increase receipts receipts even though from beer, it will decrease receipts receipts from other taxes by more than rhan enough to offset the gross increase. If the federal personal and corporate income tax cuts did in fact expand economic activity, if the base for other taxes is positively related to economic activity, and if the rates of of these other taxes remained constant, then one should observe higher than expected revenues from these other taxes during the years immediately following the federal if such federal income tax reductions. Furthermore, if indirect effects do exist, exist, they should be taken explicitly into account in estimating the revenue effects of proposed tax tax changes. In order to determine whether any any indirect revenue revenue increases resulted from the federal income tax cuts, Canto, Joines, and Webb fit a univariate time time series model model to quarterly quarterly state and local local income income tax receipts deflated by the Consumer Price Index, neither of which had been seasonally adjusted. The model appropriate to this variable, SL!, is variable, denoted SLI, 2}e, V SLJ, = = 0.11 + [I [1 + 0.258 v,su, 0.25B + 0.548 0.54B'Je, 4 (0,11) (0.020) (0.11) (0.11) (0,020) 6,, = 0.089 0.089 o, = t = 1948:1 - 1963:4 1948:l — ê~gave no indication Examination of the residuals e, indication of model inadequacy. C A N T O , J O l N E S , A N D L A F F E R / 27 TABLE 3 Estimates of Cumulative Change in State And Local Income Tax Receipts (Billions of Dollars) Cumulative Change Through Fiscal Year 1964 1965 1966 2 3 Time Series Estimate Standard Error 0.49 1.48 0.14 0.45 3.28 0.86 Corn,tant (1963:4) dollars. Table 3 contains estimates of the cumulative change in state and local income tax receipts for selected fiscal years. For each year the point estimate is positive and large relative to its standard error. It is possible that part of this increase could have arisen because state and local tax rates increased faster between I 964 and I 966 than they did during the period used to construct our forecasts. To check this possibility, we computed a weighted average of state personal income tax rates for years before and after the federal rate cuts. This average actually increased more slowly during the three years after the federal rate cuts than during the preceding three years. This evidence therefore strongly suggests that the federal tax cuts did entail the predicted indirect revenue increases. In summary, analysis of these three types of revenues yields a point estimate for the cumulative loss in the three types of revenues combined of $0.41 billion through 1966. Given the uncertainty attaching to this estimate, it is virtually indistinguishable from zero. Furthermore, it contrasts sharply with the Treasury's estimate of the federal revenue loss of $33 billion. 1t thus seems quite likely that the static revenue estimates used by the Treasury greatly overstate the revenue effects of federal tax rate changes. In addition, it seems almost as likely that the federal tax cuts increased revenues as that they reduced them. If the Kennedy tax cuts did result in revenue losses smaller than those implied by simple static calculations, this suggests that tax rate reductions may in fact be effective in stimulating economic activity. One qualification to this line of reasoning is in order, however. lt was noted above that if tax shelters are expensive, a 28 // TAX TAX RATES AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION TABLE 4 Estimates of Cumulative Estimates Cumulative Changes in Real Gross National Product Cumulative Change Thro ugh Fiscal Year Through aTime Series Estimate Standard Standard Error 1964 1965 1966 5.25 29.05 84.34 4.81 4.81 18.03 33.68 33.68 aConstant (1963:4) dollars. dollars. aconstant (1963:4) reduction in tax tax rates might result result in a decrease in tax revenues without necessarily necessarily being accompanied by an increase in economic activity. The expansion of of the tax base might instead occur as people transfer economic activity from nontaxable to to taxable forms. Product Examination of some variable such as real Gross National Product would allow allow a separate separate check on the influence influence of the Kennedy tax tax cuts on economic activity. The following multiplicative seasonal time series model was identified and estimated for quarterly quarterly data on real Gross National Product: 206 + 0.0956,, + 8.3656,, 6 VGNP —= -9.366" 5.206,, VGNP —9.366,, ++ (0.627) S. 2t + (0.624) 0.09563~ + (0.626) S~ Sd4~ T — (0.652) T (0.652) (0.627) (0.624) (0.626) + 11 —- 0.350B'Ja, 0.350B1Ja, + [I (0.140) 6a &, = 2.15 = — it — = l,quarteri,i 0, otherwise otherwise 0, 1, quarter i, i = I 4 l, ... , 4 1951:2 - 1963:4 — The price index was the Consumer Consumer Price Index, and the series was not seasonally adjusted. Diagnostic checks of the residuals did not indicate any significant departures from a white noise process. This time series series model was used to develop forecasts of real output which which were then compared with post-sample realized values. The results are summarized in Table 4. The point estimates reported there provide evidence that an unforecast expansion in economic activity followed the tax rate cuts, with most of the effect occurring C A N T O , J O I N E S , A N D L A FF E R / 29 in fiscal years 1965 and 1966. This is consistent with the evidence from the analysis of tax revenues. The point estimate of the cumulative gain through 1966 is $84 bjl]ion and is about two and a half times its standard error. CONCLUSION Our analysis shows that increases in taxes reduce the returns to the factors as well as factor employment and market output. A firm's decision to employ a factor is based partly on the total cost to the firm of the factor's services. The more it costs to hire factors, the lower the quantity of factor services the firm will demand. The lower the costs to the firm to hire factors, the more factor services the firm will demand. Increases in tax rates increase the cost of hiring factors. Therefore, increases in tax rates will result in fewer factor services demanded. For the owners of factors, the decision to offer factor services to the market is based in part on the earnings the factor receives net of taxes. The more the factor receives net, the larger will be the quantity of services offered to the market, and vice versa. Increases in tax rates reduce the net-of-tax returns to factors. Increases in tax rates reduce the quantity of factor services supplied. Thus, both the firms' desire to employ factors and the factors' willingness to work are diminished by increases in tax rates. The foregoing analysis applies equally to either capital or labor employment and their respective returns. The net effect is that the level of factor employment and output fall as tax rates increase. Our analysis also indicates that increases in tax rates could as well reduce as increase government tax revenues. In fact, there exists a tax rate structure which maximizes government tax receipts. This tax structure depends on the supply and output elasticities of the factors of production. The set of tax rates which creates conditions such that increases in the rates are accompanied by increases in government tax revenues are referred to as the normal range. The tax rates where increases in the rates are accompanied by decreases in tax revenues are said to be in the prohibitive range. Except at a corner solution, whenever tax rates are reduced, total revenue is never reduced in the same proportion as the tax rate reduction. The more elastic factor supplies are, the more likely it is that any given tax rates will fall into the prohibitive range. Also, the higher the level of tax rates, the more likely tax rates are to be in the prohibhive range. 30 / TAX TAX RATES RATES AND AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION Our simple static model shows the government tax policy affects output which can be obtained from a given stock the market-sector output of resources. In particular, increases in tax rates reduce market employment and output. Such a tax rate increase, however, would would also have long-term effects on the size of the resource stock. Both human and nonhuman capital are are reproducible resources which can any be augmented only at some cost. The stocks of such capital at any point point in time depend upon past investment decisions, and the future stocks upon current current investment A change in afterstocks depend depend upon investment decisions. decisions. A change in aftertax factor rewards will affect not not only the intensity of utilization of existing factors, but also the decision to invest in new currently existing resources, and thus the size of the future stock of factors of production. A dynamic model is required to analyze such questions. We merely We merely note in closing that increases in tax rates are likely to cause reductions in future output potential, which reinforce the reductions in current output predicted by our static model. The proposition that increases in tax rates beyond a certain level may actually reduce tax revenues and hence market-sector output is an empirical issue. Data on tax revenues and real per capita output before and after the Kennedy tax cuts of 1962 1962 and 1964 l 964 were examined in order to ascertain whether this proposition has empirical support. The evidence suggests that a significant expansion of of economic activity and no significant loss of revenue occurred as a result of the Kennedy tax cuts. The point estimate of occurred the cumulative unexpected expansion in output through 1966 is $84 billion, which is large relative to its standard error. Our evidence on revenues is The point cumulative is less less conclusive. conclusive. The point estimate estimate of of the the cumulative revenues revenue change is virtually identical to zero, and it is thus almost equally likely that the Kennedy tax cuts increased revenues as it is that they decreased them. CANTO, JO INES, AND l.. AF FER / 31 REFERENCES Atkinson, A. B., and J. E. Stiglitz. "The Structure of Indirect Taxation and Economic Efficiency." Journal of Public Economics I (April 1972): 97-119. Becker, G. S. and G. Ghez. The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Lijecycle. Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1975. Box, G. E. P., and G. C. Tiao. "Intervention Analysis with Applications to Economic and Environmental Problems." Journal of the American Statistical Association, 70 (March 1975): 70- 79. Bronfenbrenner, Martin. "Diminishing Returns in Federal Taxation?" J.P.E., 52 (October 1942): 699-717. Canto, V. A. "Taxation, Welfare and Economic Activity." Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Chicago, 1977. Canto, V. A., D. H. Joines, and R. L Webb. "The Revenue Effects of the Kennedy Tax Cuts." Unpublished Working Paper. Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Southern California, August 1980. Canto, V. and M. Miles. "The Missing Equation: An Alternative Interpretation," Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 3, No. 2, Spring 1981. Canto, V., A. Laffer, and 0. Odogwu. "The Output and Employment Effects of Fiscal Policy in a Classical Model." University of Southern California, Working Paper, I 978. Cooter, R. "Optimal Tax Schedules and Rates: Mirrlees and Ramsey." American Economic Review, 68 (December 1978): 756-68. Evans, M. "Taxes, Inflation, and the Rich." The Wall Street Journal, August 7, 1978, p. 10. Fowler, Henry J. "Statement before the Committee on Banking and Currency." Meetings with Department and Agency Officials: Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1967. 32 / TAX RATEs RATES AND AND PRODUCTION PRODUCTION Fullerton, Don. Don. “On "On the Possibility of of an Inverse Relationship Revenues.” NBER NBER Working Between Tax Rates and Government Revenues." Paper No. 467, April 1980. 1980. Harberger, A.C. Taxation and Welfare. Little Brown and Company, Boston 1974. “The Kemp-Roth-Laffer Free Heller, Walter. "The Free Lunch.” Lunch." The Wall Street Journal, July 12, 12, 1978, p. 20. “Government Fiscal Policy Joines, D. D. H. "Government Policy and Private Capital Formation." Dissertation, University of Chicago, 1979. Formation.” Ph.D. Dissertation, 1979. Kemp, Jack. "The “The Roth-Kemp Tax Reduction Act of 1977 Parallels of 1977 the Kennedy Tax Reductions of the Early Sixties." Sixties.” Congressional Record, July 14, 1977: H7156-58. 87156-58. Lucas, R. “Econometric "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.” Critique." In K. Brunner and and A. Meltzer, eds. Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. North Holland, 1976. 1976. Mirrlees, J. "An “An Exploration Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation.” Review of Economic Studies 38 (April 1971): 197111: Taxation." 175-208. Nelson, Nelson, C. R. Applied Time Series Analysis for Managerial Forecasting. San Francisco: Holden Day, 1973. 1973. “The Predictive Performance ______ . "The Performance of the FRB-MITFRB-MITEconomy.” American PENN Model of the U.S. Economy." American Economic Review 62 (October 1972): 902-17. ____________ Pechman, J. J. "The “The Individual individual Income Tax Provisions Pechman, Income Tax Provisions of of the the Revenue Act of 1964.” Journal of Finance 20 (May 1965): Reve@e Act of 1964." Journal of Finance 20 (May 1965): 247-72. 247-72. Terence J. of aa Labor Curve for for SelfSelf"Estimation of Labor Supply Supply Curve Wales, Terence J. “Estimation Proprietors.” International Economic Review Employed Business Business Proprietors." 14 (February 1973): 69-80. Zellner, “Time Series Analysis and Simultaneous Zellner, A. and F. F. Palm. "Time Models." Journal of Econometrics 22 (1974): 17-59. Equation Models.” An Econometric Model Incorporating The Supply-Side Effects of Economic Policy MICHAEL K. EVANS This paper summarizes the principal findings of the new macroeconomic supply-side model which I have recently completed at Evans Economics. Rather than describe each individual equation or even blocks of equations, I have selected an alternative approach. Since the main thrust of the supply-side model is to examine the ways in which total productive capacity can be increased, I first examine the determinants of productivity, and then show how these determinants are estimated within the confines of the model. The bulk of this paper is devoted to the discussion of the productivity function, the investment functions, and the labor market functions. The concluding section then examines some alternative solutions generated by changes in monetary and fiscal policies. Rather than examine the usual full-scale multiplier tables, I have chosen to concentrate on a specific set of policy alternatives which should be able to increase productive capacity and employment while at the same time reducing inflation. DETERMINANTS OF PRODUCTIVITY As part of the supply-side model, we have estimated an econometric equation to explain changes in productivity on an endogenous basis. Previous attempts to explain productivity reached the conclusion that while some of the decline could be tied to the reduction in the investment ratio and other endogenous factors, part of it could not be explained by economic variables. However, we have found that not to be the case. The function we have estimated relates the annual percentage change in productivity to two sets of variables: short-term cyclical variables and long-term secular factors. The short-term variables are a) percentage change in real GNP, and b) a nonlinear term of capacity utilization which takes the form (95 - CP)'ic. Essentially this term represents the fact that productivity growth slows down as Mirhael Evans is Presiden1 of Evans Economics, Inc., Washing!on, D.C. 33 34 // SUPPLY-SIDE 5UPPLY~5tDE ECONOMETRIC ECONOMETRIC MODEL 34 the economy approaches approaches full employment and full capacity capacity because of shortages and bottlenecks, more overtime and hence more worker errors, and hiring of less skilled and trained workers. The long-term long-term secular factors which we consider, together with with the weights which we have assigned to each of them, are as follows: I. Decline in the investment ratio 1. 2. Costs of government regulation 3. Increase in secondary workers in the the labor force 4. Increase in relative price of of energy energy 5. Reduction in ratio of R&D expenditures to GNP 1% 1% ½o/o ½% #I; (included in #1; not measured separately) in the function While the last factor was not explicitly included in because of the very long lag times involved, it enters the function function indirectly through its eventual effect on investment. This point is discussed in in more detail in next section. discussed more detail in the the next section. The actual equation used in our supply-side model isis as follows: Independent Variable Variable -CSECWKO1 SECWK0I INVXCOI INVXC0I REG ENERGYC GNP72 CAPUTIL Estimated Coefficient Coefficient Standard Error T-Statistic T ~Statistic Contribution Contribution To H’ R2 —7.51592 -7.51592 —0.839850 -0.839850 0.625840 —0.208791 -0.208791 —4.11652 -4.11652 0.524536 1.11549 1.11549 4.57449 0.35581 0.355811I 0.419031 0.419031 0.170205 2.49016 2.49016 0.108446 0.108446 0.440452 0.440452 -1.64301 —1.64301 -2.36038 —2.36038 1.49354 - 1.22671 —1.22671 -—1.65311 1.6531 I 4.83686 2.53261 0.6983770-01 0.698377D-01 0.379613D-Ol 0.379613D-0I 0.188628D-0l 0.188628D-0I 0.3425540-01 0.342554D-0l 0.293259 0,804009D-01 0.804009D-0I = 0.7368 R-Squared = 0. 7368 R-Squared (Corrected) = 0.6616 = 0.2122 Multicollinearity Effect = Durbin-Watson Statistic Statistic = = 1.3901 1,3901 Durbin-Watson Number of Observations = = 28 Number 28 Sum of Squared Residuals == 17.7071 Standard Error of the the Regression Regression = 0.918256 Standard Error of 0.918256 = The dependent variable is: PRDT PRDT = i\PRD = 41±RP PRD, PRO, where PRD = Private Private nonfarm business productivity. productivity. where PRD = non farm business EVANS/35 EVAN5 / 35 The independent variables are: 22 = IJ_ ~:l: SECWORK_; SECWORKS SECWK0I SECWKOI = 22.0 i=0 where SECWORK INVXC0I INVXCO1 I = 2 . 2. 2 :l: X = Secondary workers Total employment INVXC; INVXC~ I where INVXC where INVXC ENERGYC cars and trucks Gross National Product = A11 ( PWIFP ) = PGNP PGNP where PWIFP PGNP PGNP GNP72 GNP72 = Business Fixed Fixed Investment = Business Investment less less investment investment in in = = Producer Price Index, fuel and power Implicit Deflator, Gross National Product = LiGNP = AGNP GNP_, GNR where GNP = Gross National Product, billions of 1972 = l 972 dollars = (95 - CP) 112 where CP = = Index of Capacity Utilization, manufacturing CAPUTJL CAPUTIL = — to GNP has At first glance, the ratio of fixed business investment to remained roughly constant over the postwar period and in fact posted an above-average value for for 1979. However, this ratio is misleading and must be adjusted for several factors. calculated in constant rather than First, the ratio should be calculated current dollars. Just Just because the price of capital goods has increased faster than other prices does not mean that we are devoting more of our resources resources to capital formation. Second, the investment figure should exclude capital spending undertaken to meet federally-mandated standards. The only figures meet federally-mandated available in this category are those for pollution abatement and control, so our estimate obviously understates total capital spending in this area. However, removal of these figures makes a noticeable difference to the investment ratio. 36 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL FIGURE I RATIO OF FIXED INVESTMENT TO GNP 11.0 10.5 10.0 I - \ I I 9.5 6.5 - , \. I -- - 7,0 I' I II 1 R A 9.0 T I 8.5 0 8.0 7.5 I \ ' ~ - ~~ - .,._., ~ - CL'.FiJi.C'lt POl i.AR~ { ON'HANT DOI LAR:, I Jr,.:\.!..STMf-:-..;· !l-:',~ 1-'();J LTJO!\o- "-f:IATl.'-H:",I t-;XPfNDIH:R}!,., ("ON'i-TA~l l){)\ 1 AFCS _ ._______,_,. _ _ l~\"f:';.7Mf:S:1 f 1.:S5 P(ll U. not-, AB.>\ n-.'\ff~T LXPI" Nlnn:RE'.1 A"ifJ ,'WIO ;\:,JD Ll(i.}-1) F~U(K f\:.E'"°;,iD/Tl:lU:$, CON~TM-.1 Dl:)[LAR'; 6.0 1956 !960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 YEAR Third, "investment" in cars and light trucks should be excluded from the total investment figures. Most of these purchases are made for personal or quasi-business reasons, and do not represent investment in the traditional sense. We have adjusted the investment ratio for all of these factors, and the very considerable difference which it makes is shown in Figure 1. Thus although the nominal ratio may not have declined, the real ratio of capital spending to GNP properly adjusted exhibits a striking demise for the past five years. Our productivity equation suggests that a 1OJo increase in the investment ratio, or a switch of about $25 billion (in I 980 dollars) from consumption to investment would raise productivity by about 0.611/o per year and thus lower inflation by about twice that amount. We defer discussion of the ways in which this could be accomplished until the next section, turning now to the other principal determinants of productivity. The second factor causing reduced growth in productivity, namely increased investment to meet federally-mandated standards, is summarized in Table I. This table should also include investment TABLE 1 Fixed Investment and Capital Stock Adjustment for Inflation and Pollution Control Equipment Year Fixed Business Investment {Current$) 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980E 100.5 104. l ll6.8 136.0 150.6 150.2 164.6 190.4 221.1 254.9 264.2 •Pollution Control 2.2 2.9 4.1 5.3 5.8 6.5 6.8 7.5 6.9 7. t 7.7 "Health and Safety Productive Fixed Business Investment (Current $2 l.7* 1.8* 2.5 2.6 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.9 4.3 2.9 3.7 96.6 99.4 110.2 128.1 141.7 141 155.4 180 209.9 244.9 252.8 Productive Fixed Business Investment ~Constant $2 105.8 103.2 110.2 123.4 122.7 106.6 112.2 122.9 143.3 155.3 147.6 •June, 1980 Survey of Current Business. bAnnual Survey of Investment in Employee Safety and Health, McGraw-Hill Publications Company, 1980. cAugust, 1979 Survey of Current Business. *Extrapolated by Evans Economics, Inc. All figures are in billions of dollars. cNet Capital Stock {Constant $} 833.7 859.5 889.8 929.5 965. l 981.2 1000.8 1029.0 1060.2 1089.3* 1110.7* Net Productive Capital Stock (Constant $2 830.0 851.4 875.8 908.5 936.7 944.9 956.1 973.7 993.7 1024.8 1044.3 MODEL 38 // SUPPLY.SIDE SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC ECONOMETRIC: MODEL undertaken by the automobile industry to meet pollution, fuel economy, and safety standards, but but we were unable to find find even approximate estimates for these figures. Even without them, approximate however, we note that adjusted capital stock has grown at an annual rate of only 2.4% since 1970, I 970, compared to 3.0% as calculated from the investment figures figures before adjustment. Because pollution control costs represent share of nonrepresent the lion’s lion's share nonproductive investment, we have presented them in greater detail in Table 2. As shown there, investment in private sector pollution control for stationary source emissions (i.e., excluding motor vehicles) will average about 4% of investment over the 1973-1984 period. Public sector spending for pollution control will average between 15% 20% of total public sector investment, while 150/o and and 200/o pollution control devices will represent about 10% 100/o of the cost of purchasing aa new car. costs associated with pollution control We also repeat repeat the annual costs investment; they are defined to include interest, depreciation, and operation and maintenance costs. According to Council on Environmental Quality (CEQ) estimates, the total annual costs for Environmental the 1975-1984 period will be $486 $486 billion in 1975 dollars, or approximately $750 billion in current dollars. These costs will amount to between 2% ONP during the 20/o and 3% 30/o of total GNP forthcoming decade, representing a very significant significant economic and solid waste. burden for the costs of clean air, water, and additional comments should be appended to these these figures. Two additional First, the cost of regulation appearing in the government budgets is private sector of the only a tiny fraction of the cost imposed on the private economy; Murray Wiedenbaum and others have estimated that it is 50/o. Second, while pollution abatement probably does only about 5%. represent represent the lion’s lion's share of these costs, the burden of occupational safety and health standards, consumer product safety, toxic control act, and and other programs are substantial and substances control should not be assumed to be zero just because no definite figures are available for these categories, categories. We do not think itit is reasonable to expect expect society to turn turn back the clock on the the massive changes in social policy which produced the federally-mandated standards of the 1970s. Yet it certainly certainly should at least be possible to rationalize these regulations so that firms are charged with attaining the ends rather than the means. If, for example, example, one national goal is to reduce air pollution, utilities ought to be able to decide on their their own whether this is to be accomplished through through choice of fuel, use of scrubbers, less TABLE 2 Total Actual and Expected Investment for Pollution Control, 1970-1984 (I) (2) (3) Capital Investment Stationary Source Mobile Source• Private Public 0 Year 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 2.2 2.9 4.1 5.3 5.8 6.5 6.8 7.5 8.9 11.0 11.7 12.2 13.6 15.0 16.5 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.5 3.7 6.6 8.0 6.0 6.7 7.0 7.4 7.8 8.2 8.6 9.1 0.3 0.4 0.4 I.I 1.2 2.3 2.9 3.5 5.6 6.3 6.6 7.2 7.8 8.4 8.9 (4) (5) Annual Costs•• "Stationary Source Private Public I.I 1.7 2.4 3.5 5.4 8.2 11.4 15.3 20.6 25.3 31.0 37.7 45.2 53.3 62.9 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 1.4 3.3 7.4 10.3 14.2 17.2 20.5 25.0 29.3 37.4 42.9 (6) (7) (10) Mobile Source• (8) Pollution Control Investment (Percent) (9) Total Fixed Business Investment Total GNP Pollution Control Resources (Percent) 1.3 2.0 2.8 4.1 5.3 5.7 6.0 6.4 8.2 11.3 100.5 2.2 982 l04.1 116.8 136. () 150.6 150.2 164.6 190.4 221.1 242. l 2.8 3.5 3.9 3.9 4.3 4.1 3.9 4.0 4.5 1063 1171 1307 1413 1529 1700 1887 2104 2281 0.2 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.9 1.1 1.5 1.7 2.0 2.4 12.1 12.2 12. l 11. 7 11.3 262.7 299.7 337.5 376.6 417.8 4.4 4.1 4.0 4.0 4.0 2479 2730 2980 3256 3551 2.6 2.7 2.9 3 .1 3.3 Source: Figures are interpolated from ten-year to,als given in the CEQ Annual Report. All figures are converted from constant to current dollars. Numbers are based on total rather than incremental polJution control expenditures. **lnlcrcsl, Depreciation, Operation. and Maintenance CosL, of Po!lu1.ion control. "Air, water, and solid waste, excludes motor vehicle, *Includes additional fuel costs, motor vehicle\ (8) = (J) / (7) S U p p L Y - 5 I D P FECONOMETRIC C 0 N0 M FT R C M 0 0F 40 / SUPPLY-SIDE MODEL production during "air alerts," building plants in new locations, “air alerts,” and so forth, best guess is forth, rather than by administrative fiat. Our best that the use of common sense in these areas could reduce the loss in ½ ¾per productivity growth due to regulation regulation from 1¾to l "lo to ½ "lo per year, tVo per thus reducing the per year. If the overall rate of inflation by about II "lo $50 billion in addition this reduction from $100 billion to $50 billion per year would would would free resources for increased increased capital spending, spending, the the gains would be even larger. The third factor which has accounted for the the slowdown in productivity growth, although it will be reversed during during the 1980s, is the sharp growth of secondary workers in the labor force. In 460/o of of the the total labor 1964, males aged 25 to 54 accounted for 46¾ force; in 1980 1980 the figure will be 38¾.The 380/o. The major increases have 54 and in teenagers of both sexes. occurred in women aged 25 to 54 The problem has been compounded not only by rapid increases in force participation rates but in the population aged under 25. labor force Many of these secondary workers have less education, vocational training, or on-the-job experience than their primary counterparts when first hired. As aa result, result, they initially less less productive. productive. when first hired. As they were were initially This does not necessarily imply that such individuals will continue to have a lower level of productivity over the lifetime of their jobs, but rather that their productivity was lower when they initially entered the labor market. During the 1980s, however, the size of the population aged 16 16 to 24 will shrink by a full 66 million persons. Thus even if labor force rates continue to rise for teenage workers, the number of potential potential rates 25 employees will decline significantly. Second, many women aged 25 to 54 in the labor force will have had the full complement of education, vocational training, and on-the-job experience as their male counterparts, so they they will be just as productive. productive. As a result, we look for for this factor to improve, hence raising the growth rate of productivity for the 1980s by about ½¾ ½ "lo per per year. The fourth factor retarding productivity, the skyrocketing cost of of energy, is only too well known to anyone associated with with the the utility industry, but the increase as shown in Figure 2 isis striking nonetheless. Furthermore, we find little if any reason to expect this ratio course over 10 years. In the U.S., ratio to to reverse reverse course over the the next next IO years. In the U.S., consumption of petroleum products remains at a high level, although not as much as previously, and production is stagnant. Under these two sets sets of circumstances it is clear that the long-run trend for oil imports continues continu_es in the upward direction, which gives need to continue to raise OPEC all the economic justification they need prices in real terms. terms. In this respect respect itit is is noteworthy noteworthy that OPEC was was prices in real In this that OPEC EVANS EV ANS // 41 41 FIGURE 22 RATIO OF OF PPI: PP!, FUEL TO TOTAL TOTAL PP! PP1 I 220 t=:;:=;:::::::;::::::::;:::::;:::::;:=;:::::::;::::::::;:::::;:::::;:=;:::::::;::::::::;:::::;::::;::::l I I I I I I 210 — 200 — 190 — 180 ISO R 170 — ~I70 A TI6O— Tl60 I 0 150 0150— 140 — 130 130 — 120 — 110 I 10 — — 100100 90 II......- ~......- ~...... liii 1111111 - ~......- ~...... - ~......- ~......- ~...... 1952 1952 1956 1960 1964 1%4 1968 1968 1972 1972 1976 1976 1980 1980 YEAR price increase in June in spite of of able to push through yet another price the fact that the U.S. U.S. is definitely in the midst of a fairly serious the the world economy is also slowing recession and the rest of the significantly. Jong-run effects effects of energy prices on productivity are The long-run undoubtedly understated. understated. Indeed, it has has become increasingly apparent that the long-term effects of changes in energy prices on and productivity are greater greater than had been generally appreciated, and larger than would be determined by empirical techniques which are are by nature restricted to to the period since 1973. The productivity productivity equation which we have model have estimated in our supply-side model indicates that that the increase in energy energy costs has lowered productivity ¾ per year. While that is probably probably the appropriate growth by ½ "lo long-run figure is considerably greater. figure for the short run, the long-run greater. of how higher energy costs reduce The standard explanation of manufacturing sector. With a productivity is usually confined to the manufacturing shift in relative prices, firms use energy and more labor, labor, raw use less energy materials, and capital. This shift is borne out by the increase in SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC ECONOMETRiC MODEL 42 / SUPPLY-SIDE MODEl, employment throughout 1979 during a period of virtually stagnant output, and while some of the excess workers are being disgorged now that we we are in a recession, the demand for labor still still has has shifted to a higher plane, plane. This shift is an important change and one which cannot be treated lightly. lightly, Yet in in the longer run it will will probably probably turn out to be less important than the changes in in productivity productivity which affect the the transportation and and distribution network. Some of these changes changes are are already obvious, such such as the 197475 decline in productivity in the 1974-75 transportation industry industry when higher fuel prices led to lower speeds speeds by airlines (voluntary) and trucking (mandatory). However, these short-run changes are already included in in our measurements of the ½¾ ½ % yearly decline. Here we consider consider the longer term changes brought about by higher energy energy prices as they affect the entire production and and distribution distribution system system of the economy. Let us first consider a world in which transportation and distribution distribution costs are negligible. If that that were the case, the location of manufacturing plants would be largely independent of markets except except for those products that gain weight or bulk during during manufacturing or those processes processes which utilize large quantities of raw materials. materials. Most important, all plants would would be large enough to take full advantage of of economies of of scale. Hence there would be relatively few plants in those industries where economies of scale are significant, particularly metals, machinery, transportation equipment, equipment, and power power generation. Competition would would thrive could not because one firm could not obtain an an advantage merely by accident of be the only part of location. The manufacturing sector would not be part of the economy economy to benefit from this arrangement. Consumers Consumers would also benefit; they could comparison shop at several locations locations since the cost of a reasonable amount of travel to obtain better prices would would be small. While transportation costs have always been substantial portion been a substantial of the the total price for some goods, such as cement, cement, it is not not too farfetched to to say say that that many elements of of the the economy economy described farfetched described 1973. Indeed, itit should be clear in above applied to to the the U.S. U.S. before 1973. general productivity general that cheap transportation and distribution aids productivity and retards inflation. inflation. ItIt encourages encourages greater greater efficiency efficiency through through economies of scale in manufacturing, and it encourages greater greater competition through a wider range of choice in retail markets. markets. After all, if consumers consumers had had no transportation and were virtually virtually After all, if and were forced to shop only at the closest store, the storekeeper would would have to cut costs through higher productivity. far less incentive 10 Thus the higher cost of energy, energy, through reducing the tbe amount of EVANS/ 43 transportation utilized, raises prices by much more than the cost of the more expensive fuel alone. Furthermore, this is not reflected in higher profits; it is the deadweight loss of productivity which does not benefit anyone. Manufacturing plants gradually become less efficient, and retail outlets become less competitive and less productive. Obviously these events change only very slowly over time, which is precisely why we cannot yet measure them very well. Existing plants do not shrink when energy costs rise, alchough they may run at lower rates of capacity utilization. Consumers do not change their driving or living habits overnight, and so on. But over time these gradual changes, almost imperceptible within the time frame of a quarter or even a year, cumulate and eventually represent a potent force affecting productivity. Offsetting this to a certain degree is the fact that if capital spending is stimulated during the 1980s, much of the new investment may be used for energy-saving plant and equipment, thus diminishing our dependence on imported oil. This would eventually cause OPEC to reduce their price in real terms, hence removing one of the major hurdles to higher productivity growth. In other words, higher investment may have benefits far greater than the traditional methods of raising productivity through expanded capital stock; the new mix of capital stock may be more energy-efficient as well, representing savings which would not come about were new investment to proceed at a slower pace. However, the entire relationship between energy prices and investment is a very complicated one, wel! beyond the scope of this modest report. The fifth factor which we believe influences the long-term growth rate of productivity is the proportion of resources devoted to R&D compared to GNP. As is shown in Figure 3, from a peak of 3% reached in the mid-1960s at the height of the space program, this ratio has declined to slightly over 2% in 1976, although it has recently improved as private industry has stepped up its R&D spending. The long lags between R&D spending and productivity growth, which average up to five years, mean that this relationship is not quite as precise as the other factors determining productivity. However, as discussed in the next section, it is thought to have an effect on investment, albeit with this very long lag. To summarize this section, output/manhour in the private sector increased at an annual average rate of 3% for the period from 1948 to 1965, but has declined to almost 0% currently. Table 3 contains the tabulation of the postwar record for increases in output/ manhour in the private non farm sector. We have taken three-year 44 /I SUPPL 5 U P P L Y - 5SIDE I D F ECONOMETRIC F C 0 N 0 M F T R I C MODEL M 0 D E t~ 44 0 FIGURE 3 OF GNP R AND D SPENDING AS A PROPORTION OF I I I I I I I I 3.0 p R 2.5 0 TOTAL p 0 2.0 R R2.0 TT l 0 1,5 N l.5 1.0 1,0 — FEDERALLY FUNDED -. - - -·-·-. - ~. — - — - INDUSTRY FUNDED 0.5 I 1960 1960 I 1964 1964 I I 1968 1972 I I 1976 1976 I 1980 YEAR YEAR averages rather than yearly figures in order order to smooth smooth out the the output. fluctuations in productivity caused by sharp changes in output. While \\Fhile some traces of recessions still remain in these numbers, the overall swings in productivity emerge much more more clearly than is is the case in in the series for annual changes. As shown in Table 3, productivity productivity rose in the the years rose very very rapidly rapidly in years immediately following World War II (no figures are available before 1948) GNP devoted to 1948) because of the large proportion of GNP to equipment. Productivity investment to replace obsolete plant and equipment. increases then declined to to the the 2.0% range for for the period 1956-1961, increases 2.0"7o range 1956-1961, considerably below the long-term average. This was due in in large part to the severity of the 1958 recession. Productivity then rose 1962 to l1968, rapidly from from tlte tl1e period 1962 968, due to the the increase in capital capital spending spurred by by the investment tax credit, liberalized liberalized depreciation allowances, allowances, and and the the reduction reduction in the corporate depreciation in the corporate income income by the substantial tax rate; productivity gains were also also increased by increases in federal spending for research and development. of these driving forces toward Beginning in 1969, l 969, both of toward higher growth were removed. The investment tax cancelled, and tax credit was cancelled, and TABLE 3 Long-Term Trends in Productivity Growth Three-Year Period 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981-1990 Average Annual Growth Rate in Productivity (Private Nonfarm Sector) 4.2 4.0 3.5 2.2 2.0 2.4 1.6 1.6 1.7 2.8 2.3 2.4 2.7 3.5 3.5 3.0 3.1 2.4 2.4 1.3 1.5 2.1 2.3 2.9 0.8 0.2 0.8 2.3 1.9 0.3 -0.6 1.0 S U P P t. V - S I D E FECONOMETRJC C 0 N 0 M F T R I C !\.10DEL M0 DE E 46 // SUPPLY-SIDE recurring recurring financial crises reduced the amount of money money available available for new investment investment spending. The reinstatement of of the investment 1971 did raise investment above the levels which would would tax credit in in 1971 otherwise have been reached, but this was offset by the substantial expenditures required required for environmental and and safety safety standards. As a result, productivity actually declined for the first time in the the postwar period in 1974 and for the three-year period 1973-1975 postwar 1973-1975 showed virtually no improvement. While the 1977-78 1977-78 figures indicate a rebound, that was was due mainly to cyclical factors, as as shown by 1979 and 1980. 1980. by the subsequent slowdown slowdown in in 1979 The 980s clearly depends on The growth rate of productivity in the I1980s what happens to the factors we we enumerated at the beginning of this this section. DETERMINANTS DETERMINANTS OF INVESTMENT INVESTMENT It is generally agreed that an increase in the production of spending will raise productivity, hence resources devoted to capital spending increasing real growth and lowering lowering inflation. However, less agreement exists concerning concerning the determinants of investment. generally divided into two groups: groups: those who Economists are generally believe in the “trickle-down” "trickle-down" theory, and those who claim that the primary variable variable is expected expected rate of of return. The trickle-down theory theory states that a rise in consumption is sufficient to increase investment to the desired desired level. Once the demand for goods increases, businessmen, ever alert and eager for increased opportunities, opportunities, will expand capacity sufficiently to create the productive capacity for these new goods. In somewhat somewhat oversimplified oversimplified terms, terms, demand creates its own supply. return theorists would argue that no such such automatic The rate of return mechanism exists to equilibrate demand and and supply. Capital spending will not increase increase unless the expected rate of return is sufficient to cover cost of investment. To To be be sure, an increase increase in in sufficient to cover the the cost of investment. sure, an demand does raise the rate rate of return, other things being equal-but equal—but it does not not in and of itself guarantee an adequate rate of return. return. Thus the tax mechanism must be used to insure that demand and and Thus has supply are kept in in balance. Obviously the choice of theory has tremendous implications in determining determining the the appropriate appropriate tax tax policies tremendous implications in policies to stimulate growth and productivity. productivity. The investment functions which we have estimated in the the Evans Evans Economics macro model on the cost of capital-rate of model rely heavily on return variable originally introduced introduced by by Jorgenson. However, the than approach which we have used permits much greater flexibility than EV ANS / 47 his original construction. By using a two-step procedure in which we estimate equations for orders and investment separately, we are able to measure the separate contributions for a change in the corporate income tax rate, investment tax credit, and depreciation allowances. Furthermore, since the index of stock prices is included as one of the variables in the rental cost of capital term, we can also examine how changes in the capital gains tax rate wiU affect investment. We can summarize the results here by listing the impact effects of changes in these tax laws. By impact effects we mean simply the marginal coefficients times the change in the tax law in quesHon, These coefficients do not take into account the interactive and dynamic effects, for which we need to solve the entire model, but they do give some idea of both the absolute and relative importance of each type of tax change. Our results in the supply-side model have shown that, for the same revenue-producing change, the corporate income tax rate cut has greater efficacy than a change in depreciation allowances, which in turn has a greater effect than a change in the investment tax credit. Furthermore, a change in the stock prices has a substantially greater effect than a proportional change in interest rates. Since these findings are not universally accepted, a further word of explanation is in order. We have found that the corporate income tax cut has the highest efficacy because it is a "pure" tax cut; it does not contain any of the restrictions that the other types of tax changes contain. For example, an investment tax credit can be used only for equipment, but not for plant; a certain amount of the credit must be carried over into future years and in certain circumstances companies cannot use all the credit, which means they must find other investors who use the credjt as a tax shelter. Jn addition, at least until recently many investors believed that the investment tax credit was a "gimmick" to be suspended or terminated at will by Congress, and hence they were less .viUing to use it as a basis for long-term investment planning, While we do think that these three changes in the tax law will have somewhat differing effects on investment, it should be stressed that all of them will have a significantly positive response. Indeed, the post-war history of capital spending in the U.S. economy is largely tied to changes in the effective tax rate on corporate income. The relationship between changes in capital spending (in constant prices) and the effective corporate income tax rate lagged one year is given in Figure 4. 48 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC FIGURE 44 REAL PRODUCTIVE INVESTMENT V EFFECTIVE TAX RATE 20 II I I II I II I I 15 ‘5 p P E £ R C E £ N T T JO 10 — 55 00 C H A —5 -5 N 0 G E -JO - 15 —IS '',, REAL tNVESTMENT -— REAL!NVESTMENT -, EFFECTIVE TAX RATE • - - . I —20 -20 1956 1960 1964 1968 I I 1972 1972 I 1976 1980 1980 YEAR YEAR To summarize the information given in Figure 4, the U.S. economy has undergone three investment booms in the postwar period: 1955-1956, 1964-1966, and 1972-1973. Each of of these booms has a common characteristic: characteristic: it was preceded in the previous year by a major change in the tax code which was favorable to investment. Hence 1954 marked the end of the the excess profits profits tax from the Korean War and the first liberalization of depreciation 7"1o rate allowances. The investment investment tax credit was was introduced at a 7% 20% reduction in in late I1962 962 and was accompanied by a 20"/o accounting tax lives; when this was followed by a reduction in the 48% in 1964, capital corporate income tax rate from 52% 520/o to 480/o 200/o in constant prices in 1965, the the only time in spending climbed 20% the postwar period that has occurred. Finally, in 1972 the 7% and accounting tax lives investment tax credit was reinstated at 70/o 200/o. were reduced by an additional 20%. We also note that that the sharp increase in tax rates in 1969, caused 10% income tax surtax and the suspension by the imposition of the 100/o of the investment tax credit, was sufficient to cause a decline in in EV ANS / 49 FIGURE 5 PRODUCTIVE INVESTMENT AND COST RATIOS :, R E "r I "VE s r v1 E 'I r I d 'I p 9.8 9.6 9.4 9.2 9.0 8.8 8.6 8.4 8.2 8.0 7.8 7.6 7.4 7.2 7.0 6.8 6.6 6.4 1.4 l.3 R A T 1.2 0 1.1 T l s l.O 0.9 0 C K p R I C E PRODUCTIVE INVESTMENT /REAL GNP - , 0.8 STOCK PRICE/CONSTRUCTION COST----- 0.7 C 0 0.6 T I 0.5 1960 1964 1972 1968 1976 1980 YEAR investment in I 970 even though the economy was still operating at high utilization rates. However, the correlation between changes in investment and changes in the effective corporate income tax rate is not perfect. In particular, the sharp declines in investment in 1958 and 1975 appear to be unrelated to changes in the tax code, and were indeed caused by the severe recessions which occurred in those years. This anomaly disappears when we correlate the investment ratio and the ratio of stock prices to construction costs, lagged one year. As shown in Figure 5, this ratio captures both the cyclical and secular movements in the investment ratio. This fact has received bipartisan support, as it was prominently discussed in both the 1977 and 1978 issues of the Economic Report of the President. The theory behind this ratio is fairly straightforward. When stock prices are high relative to construction costs and equity capital is relatively inexpensive, businesses will expand by building new plants and filling them with new equipment. However, when stock prices are relatively depressed, businesses will expand by buying smaller s SO 50 I/ SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL FIGURE 66 1960 = 100 100 OUTPUT PER MANHOUR FOR MAJOR COUNTRIES 450 Japatl 414 -- 378 378 342 342 Belgium /Netherlands 306 306 - 270 270 ; - _/ ,/" ~t~ice Germany 234 Canada 198 198 162 162 126 ----- - .,, .,,~~:~-~-------~-: - ..----: • , .....- _ .....- __..- Great Britain - • -~nited ------States 90 '--''---'---'--....l.--.....j._ _'---'---'---'------'--'--' 1968 1976 1976 1960 1964 1980 1972 YEAR YEAR capital existing businesses, rather than than by investing more in new capital assets. The course of the stock stock market market is thus of extreme importance in determining the growth in investment, and explains why this term is relatively more important than the interest rate. We can never be absolutely positive that the slowdown in I 966 was due to the reduced rate of growth in productivity after 1966 investment. However, However, additional supporting evidence can be and growth patterns of of the the gathered by by examining the investment and U.S. economy with those of other other leading leading industrialized countries of the world. These comparisons are provided in the next two graphs. In Figure 6 we find almost a perfect correlation between the proportion of GNP spent on fixed investment and the growth in productivity. the extent to which in productivity. Figure Figure 77 documents documents the extent to which increases increases in output/manhour in the U.S. have fallen behind growth in the rest of the world. Even when one one adjusts for lower wage gains in of the world. Even when adjusts these these for lower wage gains in the evidence explaining the weakness of the dollar dollar this country, the seems compelling. compelling. seems It often comes as a shock to realize that in the past 15 15 years the GNP going to proportion of GNP to fixed business investment and the rate 51 EV ANS / FIGURE 7 p E R C lO E N T 9 PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH V. INVESTMENT, BY COUNTRY I - A N G 7 - E 6 I 5 f- 4 f- 3 - D u C T I V I T y * Netherlands - - - ltaly " * France * Germany - * Canada l-t ~ - * - Great Britain · United States - 0 l Belgium~ ¼t 2 I - 8 p R 0 I Japan C H N I l (1965-1979) I I ! I 10 15 20 25 I 30 INVESTMENT AS A PERCENTAGE OF REAL GNP I 35 of increase· in productivity for the United States are below even those of the United Kingdom. It is this below-par performance which has been at the root of the weakness of the dollar since 1970. The oil embargo and subsequent quintupling of OPEC oil prices may result in some relative shift in these relationships during the next decade. As shown in Figure 7, productivity declined in Japan and all major European countries except Germany during 1974, the first time this has occurred in the entire postwar period. Furthermore, wage gains in Europe and Japan have been well above increases in the U.S.; if this continues and is not offset by continuing relative increases in productivity, these areas could lose much of their allure for investors. So far we have been discussing plans to stimulate investment directly through lower taxes. However, investment can also be stimulated indirectly, namely by increasing personal saving. A decline in the tax rate on income generated from saving-such as interest and dividend income-would result in more personal saving, and eventually more investment. 52 / SUPPLY-SIDE MODEL SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC ECONOMETRIC MODEL previous empirical work on on the the consumption The vast majority of previous implies that the interest rate has no significant effect on function implies the proportion of of disposable disposable income which which is consumed or saved. It is true that a simple correlation between between the saving rate and the the interest rate reveals no relationship. However, we have have found aa very strong link between the real after-tax rate of of return and personal personal saving. After substantial testing, we have determined determined that this rate can best be represented by by the long-term bond yield yield multiplied by by average tax rate on personal income) minus the (1 the average rate this rate of of inflation over the past four years. Thus defined, this return isis found to have an important effect on consumption return consumption and saving. Specifically, Specifically, a 1IWo % increase in the rate of return—e.g., return-e.g., from 3% 4%-would raise saving saving by $12 billion. billion. Furthermore, we 3% to 4%—would find that the importance importance of the after-tax rate of of return on savings has been increasing increasing in recent years as interest rates and inflation to higher levels. move to An across-the-board $10 billion personal income tax tax cut from, 30% to 29% would have relatively little say 30% little effect on saving over over although as and above the increase stemming from higher income, although we note later would have on labor market we note later itit would have aa much much larger larger effect effect on labor market behavior. However, the increase increase in saving from this tax cut cut due due to the increased rate of return would be only about $1 billion. billion. On the other hand, cut of of the the same targeted only other hand, aa tax tax cut same size size which which was was targeted only to to increase saving saving through a higher higher rate of return would would result in aa rise in saving of some some $13 billion. Thus the form of the tax cut is allimportant in determining the effect on consumption and saving. We now consider some of the ways in which saving and investment are stimulated in the the high-productivity simulation simulation this calculated for th is report. As mentioned mentioned above, the the simplest and most direct approach isis a reduction in the corporate income tax rate. A decrease from the Sb present level of 46% to 40% would cost cost the Treasury about $11 billion per per year year before before reflows; reflows; these these figures obviously increase increase over over time as the economy expands and time as and profits rise in nominal terms. The impact effect on on investment investment would would be be to raise it $9 billion billion after the lagged effects were fully considered. The multiplier effects are discussed in more detail in the final section. Changes in depreciation lives could take several different forms, Changes and in general the analysis is somewhat more complicated than for for the major plans the simple cut in corporate income income taxes. The two two major plans which have been suggested suggested for changing depreciation depreciation allowances are (a) replacement cost accounting, and (b) shortening tax lives, which — EVANS/53 has recently been popularized as 10-5-3, although clearly other variants of shorter lives are possible. The theoretical justification to adjust depreciation allowances, in addition to the fact that this would stimulate investment, is that these allowances fall far short of replacement needs in a period of inflation. Since that is the avowed objective of all such plans, it seems most reasonable to us to meet the ravages of inflation by an adjustment which compensates for inflation. This would be accomplished very simply as follows. Depreciation allowances would be set equal to the appropriate proportion of investment for each year times the ratio of capital goods prices in the present year to capital goods prices in the year during which the investment was originally undertaken. Symbolically this can be expressed by: where PkT = price of capital goods (implicit deflater, national income accounts, business fixed investment) in year T; DT SL-r = = depreciation allowances in year T; proportion of investment depreciated by the straight line method in year T; t-r = average length of depreciable life of assets depreciated by the straight line method in year T; ACCr = proportion of investment depreciated by accelerated methods in year T; and IT = investment in year T. The drawback to replacement cost accounting, according to the proponents of 10-5-3, is that it is too complicated. However, we feel that such a plan could be implemented very simply by having all depreciation allowances increase by the average rate of inflation of capital goods, as published by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Some distinction could be made for equipment and structures, but as a first order of approximation 900'/o of the inequities caused by inflation would be wiped out by linking to one or two overall indexes. The reduction in the maximum capital gains tax rate from 49 .1 0/o 54 I SUPPLY,SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL to 28% in late 1978 brought forth anguished cries from some critics who claimed that it benefited the speculator rather than the longterm investor. While we believe that all capital gains taxes should eventually be abolished, the remaining tax burden could be restructured to benefit more directly those members of society who contribute most to spending on R&D, venture capital, and investment in new companies. One plan to restructure the capital gains tax laws states that anyone investing venture capital into a new or fledgling company and then holding on to the stock for five years or more would not have to pay any capital gains taxes at all. Furthermore, capital gains would be calculated on an indexed basis, so that investors would not have to pay tax on the phony profits which are due only to inflation. For purposes of calculation, the implicit GNP deflator or some other broad-based price index would be used. In order to relate the relationship between stock market prices and investment to tax policy, we must determine how much a change in capital gains taxes will affect the stock market. Here we have found a significant relationship, namely that a I% change in the maximum tax rate on capital gains (i.e., from 48% to 47%) would raise stock prices by approximately 1 ½ % . Hence one of the most important ways to stimulate investment and productivity is to reduce the capital gains tax rate further. Although no specific figures are available, it is likely that the reduction in capital gains taxes will also contribute to a renaissance of the venture capital industry, which was approximately a $3 billion a year industry in 1968 before higher capital gains taxes and the decline of the stock market combined virtually to wipe out this industry. R&D spending has also been hampered by the lack of venture capital, and while this does not show up immediately in declining productivity, it is thought to have a very substantial effect over a five to IO year period. A number of plans have emerged to reduce the burden on the individual saver, and although these are not0'as far advanced through the Congressional labyrinth, they still merit some discussion and inclusion in our model simulations. The formation of Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) four years ago permitted individuals not covered by pension plans to invest $1,500 each year tax-free, providing the money was not withdrawn before retirement age. Our planned Individual Saving Account (ISAs) would have some elements in common with this general idea, in that they would encourage savings, but the scope EV ANS / 55 would be much more broad-based. Each taxpaying unit could treat up to $1,500 per year in interest income, dividend income, or capital gains rollover as tax-exempt income. Thus, for example, if an individual had a savings account of $10,000 on which he earned an average interest rate of 9% and dividend income of $1,000, $1,500 of that $1,900 income would not be included in his gross taxable income. The plan would have certain strictures; taxpayers would have to keep thefr principal fully invested, although they could switch assets just as is the case for IRAs now. Any capital gains would have to be reinvested (rolled over) into other similar investments in order for that part of the exemption to qualify. However, the basic idea of an ISA would be that income generated from stocks, bonds, savings accounts, money market funds, or similar assets would be tax exempt as long as the principal remained invested in this class of assets. We estimate that this would cost about $6 billion per year in ex ante revenue loss. Clearly the establishment of ISAs would have many advantages. It would reduce the tax burden for savers, particularly smaller savers, and thus would be politically as well as economically popular with the vast majority of voters. It would stimulate savings and investment, and would pull the U.S. closer to being able to compete with other major industrialized nations in terms of gains in investment and productivity. The disadvantages which are likely to be raised are threefold. First, such a move would definitely increase the size of the federal budget deficit; no backward-bending supply curves would operate here. Second, it could be argued that mosr of the tax break would simply go to taxpayers who would save and invest in any case; i.e., it would attract very little new savings. Third, someone is sure to complain that most of the tax breaks will go to the "rich", which to a certain extent cannot be refuted because most of the poor don't save. These objections suggest an alternative plan which would affect marginal savings more directly. Under this alternative, taxpayers would not receive an exemption or credit unless their savings in any given year were greater than the average savings rate for that income bracket. For example, if the average savings rate was 5% for a $30,000 per year income, taxpayers at that level would not receive any exemption unless they saved over $1,500 in that year. It is difficult to estimate the ex ante revenue loss, but it would certainty be under $5 billion per year. A third alternative plan would be to "start the tax table over" 56 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRJC MODEL for nonwage income. For example, if a taxpayer had $50,000 in wages and salaries and $10,000 in interest and dividend income, the nonwage income would be taxed at marginal rates applying to $ I0,000 of income, rather than $60,000. Thus if a wealthy individual had, say, $250,000 of interest and dividend income he would still pay high marginal tax rates-although in this case the top marginal bracket would be limited to 50%, just as it is for wage income, rather than the current top level of 70%. Indeed, we estimate that lowering the top tax bracket from 70% to 50% would actually net the Treasury about $3 billion per year as taxpayers would shift out of tax-sheltered or tax-exempt sources of income. Other alternative plans are available as well. The original concept of the IRA could be expanded to allow much more of a deduction than $ l ,500. The principal and interest on money put aside to buy a home could be declared tax-exempt. In any case, all these schemes would have the net effect of reducing the net tax rate on saving. In the model we have assumed that some combination of these reductions would result in lowering the marginal tax rate on savings from its current level of 40% to 30%, which would result in a net loss of revenue to the Treasury of $8 billion per year before reflows. As a result of these findings, we have also introduced some personal income tax cuts in the high-growth simulations, and some personal tax increases-mainly through bracket creep rather than actual rate hikes-in the low-growth simulation. While the changes in laws affecting investment behavior are the most important movers of the differential rate of growth, we should not ignore the effect of changes in personal income tax rates on labor force participation, the amount of labor offered by those already in the labor force, the level of productivity, and the increase in wage rates. We now examine these relationships in greater detail. RELAT!ONSH!P BETWEEN LABOR AND TAX RATES The theoretical literature of microeconomics has always posited significant relationships between the demand and supply of labor and the cost of that labor, including tax rates. A tax on labor (such as a social security tax) would raise the cost of this labor, thereby reducing its use. Similarly, an increase in taxes would reduce the supply of labor offered, although this effect is sometimes thought to be offset by the so-called backward bending supply curve. However, these linkages have been almost entirely absent from previous macroeconomic models, even though microeconomic studies, including several funded by the federal EV A NS / 57 government, have shown significant elasticities for various classifications of employees, particularly secondary workers in the labor force. In addition to the beneficial aspects of tax cuts on saving and investment in our new macroeconomic model, we have also found significant relationships between changes in personal income taxes and labor market conditions. These can be subdivided into three areas: labor force participation, amount and quality of work offered, and increase in wage rates. Typical macroeconomic labor supply functions have been estimated in the form of labor force participation rates by demographic composition, with the principal independent variable being the lagged value of the unemployment rate. Both theory and microeconomic results suggest that the real wage should be included as an additional determinant of labor force participation. However, on an empirical basis the problem of separating out the income and substitution effects has proved baffling. In general we would expect that an increase in the wage rate would have offsetting effects. The higher wage would induce an increase in labor supply, following the usual upward-sloping supply curve for factors of production. However, an increase in income would result in substitution of leisure for work, following the so-called backward-bending supply curve. Furthermore, an increase in prices generally reduces the real income of the wage earner, so that a higher rate of inflation would draw more people into the labor force in an attempt to make ends meet. The major problem in estimating labor force participation rate equations with the wage rate has always been the difficulty in sorting out the difference between the substitution and income effects, since they should have different signs. Furthermore, most of the theoretical work has been done under assumptions which assume constant prices, whereas in reality fluctuations in the real wage due to inflation are among the major determinants of labor force participation. Let us first turn to the problem of the income and substitution effects. Musgrave has suggested that this problem can be handled by considering the average and the marginal tax rates separately. He argues that work effort will decline if the marginal rate is raised (substitution effect) but will increase if the average rate is raised (income effect). From a theoretical point of view, therefore, the problem is solved by entering both of these tax rates. From an empirical point of view, however, it is perfectly obvious 58 I SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL that these rates mo~e together over time, and that it is not possible to measure the empirical effects separately on a time-series basis. One way around this problem is to introduce an income term together with the marginal tax rate in the labor force participation rate equations. Thus we have included the wage bill deflated by the CPI, thus incorporating elements of both the wage rate and income. While not a perfect solution, this combined variable does enable us to estimate more robust estimates of the effect of tax rates on labor force participation, separate the average and marginal tax rate effects, and include the theoretical desirable income term. Thus the key variable used in the labor force participation rate equation is: where: W = wage and salaries; = consumer price index; and trn = marginal tax rate as calculated by Evans Economics, Inc. (EEi). CPI We now turn to the distinction between primary and secondary workers in the labor force. In general economists have found a modest if not insignificant relationship between labor force participation rates for males aged 25 to 54 and either the real wage or the rate of inflation. On the other hand, we would expect both of these variables to be quite significant for secondary workers in the labor force. We also need to consider the effect of changes in the marginal tax rate on labor supply. Again one can raise the question of whether the substitution or income effect dominates; as tax rates rise, it could be argued, labor supply increases in order to hold real income constant. However, the overwhelming evidence of the microeconomic studies suggest that the substitution effect predominates, and that an increase in tax rates reduces the supply of labor offered. Thus we have combined the tax term with the real wage term in all of these equations. We thus expect the standardized labor force participation rate equation to contain the following terms: the unemployment rate, the wage bill divided by the price level, the marginal tax rate on personal income, and the rate of inflation. It is often claimed that the minimum wage has contributed to an EV ANS / 59 increase in the unemployment rate among teenagers, since they are the potential employees whose marginal product is most likely to be lower than the minimum wage. While this is undoubtedly the case, the relationship has another dimension, which is that the existence of the minimum wage barrier also deters many teenagers from entering the labor force in the first place. Thus we find a significant negative correlation between labor force participation rates for those aged 16 to 24 and the minimum wage in real terms. A l OJo increase in the minimum wage wiU reduce labor force participation by approximately 0.2%. At the other end of the age spectrum, we find a very strong negative correlation between social security benefits in real terms and labor force participation for those 55 and older. Since the benefits are tied to the cost-of-living and in fact are one of the very few types of personal income to outstr1p inflation over the past deeade, it is clear that an increase in the rate of inflation raises real income for recipients, especially when it is considered that social security benefits are tax-free whereas earned income is subject to personal and social security taxes. Hence the situation for retirement-age individuals is unlike the situation for the rest of the work force, for whom an increase in inflation lowers real income and thus leads to greater labor force participation. One might argue that real income remains constant for those on social security, but actually very few people over 55 are buying or financing new homes, and hence the CPI increase clearly overstates the increase in their cost of living. Also, those over 65 receive medical care free of charge; hence those rapidly rising prices are also not indicative of the costs faced by older citizens. The empirical results for labor force participation are best divided into primary and secondary members of the work force. The effects on primary workers, defined here as males aged 25 to 54, are significant but small. A one percentage point (p.p.) reduction in the marginal personal income tax rate would result in only a 0.05% increase in the primary labor force. However, it would result in a 0.37% increase in the secondary labor force. However, total increase in the labor force caused by a l p.p. reduction in the tax rate would be 0.26%, or approximately 270,000 workers at the present size of the labor force. The labor force participation equations also indicate that a I% increase in the real minimum wage {adjusted for inflation) would decrease labor force participation for those aged 16 to 24 by 0.2%. At the other end of the age scale, a l % increase in real per capital 60 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL social security benefits would diminish labor force participation of those 55 and over by 0.4%. The equations relating the amount of utilized labor to output, capital stock, and productivity are usually known as inverted production functions or labor demand functions. However, they are actually a reduced form of labor demand and supply equations, since the amount of labor used depends both on the demand for labor by business and the degree of willingness to offer their labor. These combined effects are very significant. We find that a 1% increase in the average personal income tax rate including social security taxes will reduce the amount of labor utilized by 0.5%. This decline is caused by several factors. First, an increase in the cost of labor through higher social security taxes will reduce the demand. Second, an increase in tax rates will reduce hours worked per week; we find that this effect accounts for slightly over half of the total reduction in labor offered. Third, higher taxes lead to a rise in vacation time, absenteeism, and unwillingness even to work at alI by some members of the labor force. The results we have found on the effect of changes in taxes on work effort are quite striking. Yet they are corroborated by some cross-section studies which we performed for the years 1962 and 1966. These years were chosen because they bracketed the major 1964 tax cut. We used the IRS tapes and stratified the income tax returns by income classification in order to determine what happened to work effort when taxes were reduced. Basically the approach we have taken is the following. We know that tax rates were reduced significantly between 1962 and 1966. For any given level of adjusted gross income (AGI), we examined what happened to the proportion of income accounted for by the sum of wages and salaries and business and professional incomein other words, income earned from current work efforL If this proportion remained unchanged we could conclude that the reduction in tax rates had no significant influence on work effort. If it increased, however, we could conclude that the tax reduction heightened work effort. Note that by holding AGI constant in the regressions we have automatically excluded any increase in work effort which might have accrued from the overall growth in the economy or rise in productivity. Our analysis is strictly a marginal one for any given level of income. We found the following results for a 1% reduction in tax rates. For lower-income workers, such a reduction would raise work effort by about 0. l %. For middle- and upper-middle workers, the EV A NS / 61 increase was about 0.25%. For upper-income workers-those with taxable income of $120,000 or more-we found that elasticities were in excess of 2.0. The upper-income elasticities are probably overstated for the following reason. When the top marginal tax rate dropped from 91 \\1o to 70%, many individuals simply shifted some of their compensation from capital gains and stock options back into earned income. As a result, tax revenues in the top bracket more than doubled from 1964 to 1966 after accounting for growth in the economy even though the top bracket rates dropped drastically. We now consider the wage rate functions in the supply-side model, for they play a critical role in determining the rate of inflation. From the point of view of supply-side economics, the view that we cannot simultaneously have full employment and stable prices is anathema, for it is just this combination which our model shows how to achieve. The problem is that a decline in unemployment is usually triggered by policies which increase aggregate demand but do not raise aggregate supply. When this happens, it is small wonder that inflation eventually rises. However, balanced growth policies, which raise both demand and supply at the same rate, wiH lead to lower unemployment without increasing inflation. Yet if we accept the empirical proposition that a strong negative relationship exists between wages and unemployment, how can we then claim that a decline in unemployment will not result in higher wages, unit labor costs, and prices? Several possibilities can be considered. The main ones are as follows: 1. The decline in unemployment is accompanied by an increase in productivity, thus offsetting higher wage rates. This would occur, for example, if the reduction in unemployment were due to greater capital spending. 2. The decline in unemployment is accompanied by a reduction in personal income tax rates, thereby causing wage earners to accept smaller pre-tax pay increases. 3, The increase in output is accomplished by increasing labor force participation and lengthening the work week, thereby leaving the unemployment rate almost unchanged. This solution is preferable mainly when the economy is near full employment; but as indicated in our previous discussion, that is when the trade-off between wages and unemployment becomes most severe. When slack still exists in the labor markets, the increase in wage rates 62 / S U P P L Y~S I D E E C O N O M E T R IC MO D E L stemming from a decline in unemployment is much smaller. 4. An increase in output could be accompanied by declining prices for other factors, such as an improvement in the value of the dollar and hence lower import prices. To be sure, these changes will not happen automatically. In fact, it is probably the rule rather than the exception that wages, unit labor costs, and prices will rise as unemployment falls. However, to state that this is a general empirical rule because of past experience does not necessarily imply that policies which will offset or mitigate this trade-off cannot be fashioned. In fact, we have just proposed four solutions which would accomplish just that. It should be stressed that the lags on all of these variables are substantial. The unemployment rate is included with an average lag over the past two years. The lag on the CPI is at least one year in all cases and ranges as far back as three years in the construction equation. Similarly, the personal tax rate is averaged over the past two to three years. Thus the effects which we are describing clearly do not happen instantaneously. They do, however, point out that delayed wage demands may be viewed as somewhat of a ''ticking time bomb" in the aftermath of sharp increases in inflation or tax rates. Just because wage demands do not spiral up immediately after inflation and taxes increase does not necessarily mean that they will never catch up, for the lag process can take up to three years to become fully effective. The generalized wage rate function which we estimate is of the form: w w - w p where: w = average wage rate; Un = unemployment rate; p = consumer price index; tr = average tax rate on personal income; 4 x "" ¼ i= I X_,; and g = a generalized nonlinear function, e.g., ~1 ~ Un Both the unemployment and inflation terms are in common use in macroeconomic wage rate equations. However, the last major term which we use in these equations, namely the average tax rate on personal income, definitely is not. Yet its inclusion should not EVANS/63 be considered particularly surprising. An increase in tax rates will cause workers to bargain for wage increases in excess of the rise in inflation in order to keep their real income constant. Similarly, a tax reduction will permit them to accept gains which are less than the rate of inflation because their take-home pay will still be at the same or higher levels. The elasticities for the various sectors of the economy, and for total private nonfarm business, are given in Table 4. We see that a I% increase in the CPI eventually results in a 0.62%, or 5/8%, rise in wage rates. While this figure is high, it is not unity. Even after a lag of up to three years, wage earners do not recoup the full increase in the reported CPI. This fact has been fairly evident ever since I973, when the real wage was some lOIIJo higher than current levels in spite of two tax cuts in the intervening years. TABLE 4 Elasticities for Wage Rate Equations Manufacturing Construction Nonmanu facturing Total private nonfarm 1% Change in CPI • 1% Change in Un blOJo Change in Un qeyo Change in tr 0.58 0.87 0.62 0.25 0.67 0.00 0.82 2.23 1.17 0.50 0.46 0.37 0.62 0.11 1.13 0.41 afrom 8% !O 7% bfrom 5% to 4% CJ p.p. change, Le,, from 30% to 3 I eyo The elasticity with respect to unemployment is nonlinear, as we think it should be. Above 8% unemployment we do not find any effect at all on wage rates from a change in unemployment. The change in each percentage point below 8% then becomes progressively larger. We have selected two points on this unemployment/wage trade-off curve: a change from 8% to 7%, and a change from 5% to 4%. As can be seen, a change in the first case results in a change in wage rates well below I%, whereas a change in the second case results in a change in wage rates somewhat above 1% . We finally turn to the change in wage rates resulting from a change in the average tax rate. It is encouraging to find that the coefficients in all of the three equations are bunched closely 64 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL together. While we might expect differences in the unemployment/ wage rate trade-off in different industries because of varying institutional and union structure, we would expect that workers would respond similarly to changes in tax rates regardless of the particular industry in which they were employed. We find that for the overall economy, a I p.p. change in tax rates (i.e., from 30% to 31 %) would result in a 0.4% change in wage rates. However, this is only an impact multiplier although it does take place over as much as three years; we also need to consider the total effect after including the interaction between wages and prices. In order to understand the dynamics of the wage-price-tax interaction, let us aggregate the equations in the wage sector. We then find that a I p.p. reduction in personal income tax rates will reduce prices by about 0.45% and wage rates by about 0.70%_ Since wage rates rise a full I OJo because of lower taxes, the after-tax increase in the real wage rate stemming from the tax reduction is 0.9%. To summarize the results of this section, we find that: I. A 1 p.p. change in the tax rate will change labor force participation in the opposite direction for primary workers by a minuscule 0.05% but will change the participation rate for secondary workers by 0.37%. 2. A 1 p.p. change in the tax rate will change employment-hours in the opposite direction by 0.5%. Much of this change stems from the change in hours worked. 3. A 1 P-P· change in the tax rate will change the average wage rate in the same direction by 0.4% on impact, and 0.7% when the interaction between prices and wages is considered. Thus a reduction in the personal income tax rate would increase the supply of labor, increase the number of hours worked, and reduce the gain in average wage rate. An increase in the demand and supply of labor would expand the maximum productive capacity of the economy. Thus inflation would be reduced both through a lower wage rate and a higher level of maximum capacity, thus widening the gap between actual and maximum capacity_ MAJOR LINKAGES IN THE SUPPLY-SIDE MODEL One of the reasons that demand-oriented policies have been used almost exclusively in the past 15 years is that all of the current large scale econometric models have indicated that these policies will benefit the economy more than supply-side changes. Embedded in EVANS/65 these models is the implicit assumption that an increase in demand will automatically trickle down to increase aggregate supply, thus insuring balanced, noninflationary growth. However, there is nothing magical about the balance between aggregate demand and supply. If incentives are lacking for investment, capital formation will stagnate. If incentives are lacking for labor, labor force participation will decline, the amount of labor offered by those already in the labor force will be reduced, and productivity will diminish. As a result, total productive capacity of the economy will grow more slowly than total demand, and bottlenecks, shortages and higher inflation will eventually result. According to Keynesian demand economics, this higher inflation must then be fought by causing a recession and reducing aggregate demand. It is true that the gap between aggregate demand and supply must be widened in order to diminish inflationary pressures. However, surely there are two ways to accomplish this aim. One is indeed to diminish demand, thereby causing higher unemployment. The other is to increase aggregate supply, thereby raising the production possibility curve of the economy and increasing jobs and output at the same time that inflation is being lowered. This is the fundamental hypothesis underlying our supply-side modeling. As already noted, most fiscal policy analysis of the past I 5 years has been based on the belief that an increase in government spending will lead to a larger rise in demand and output than an equivalent reduction in taxes. The reasoning which leads to this conclusion is straightforward if inaccurate. If the government increases its spending, the entire dollar is used to raise aggregate demand. If taxes are cut, however, some of each dollar is used for saving. Since existing Keynesian models do not incorporate the links between saving and investment, demand does not rise as much. Furthermore, these models also state that a personal income tax cut has a larger effect than a corporate income tax cut, and for much the same reason. Individuals spend a larger proportion of the extra money they receive from reduced taxes than do corporations, and that left-over saving does not contribute to economic growth or prosperity. The supply-side model which we have built gives exactly the opposite result: an income tax cut has a larger effect on the economy than an increase in government spending. The supply-side mechanisms which support this conclusion can be qualitatively summarized as follows. In particular, a reduction in personal and 66 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL corporate income taxes will set in motion the following chain of events. 1. An increase in the after-tax rate of return on personal saving occasioned by a reduction in personal income tax rates raises the incentives of individuals to save. This increase in saving leads to lower interest rates and higher investment. 2. A reduction in the effective corporate income tax rate, either through lower tax rates, a higher investment tax credit, or more liberal depreciation allowances, improves capital spending directly by increasing the average rate of return. 3. An increase in both personal and corporate saving leads to greater liquidity and less loan demand, thereby lowering interest rates. These effects help both capital spending and residential investment. 4. A rise in the ratio of investment to GNP leads to higher productivity, which means that more goods and services can be produced per unit of input. As a result, unit costs do not rise as fast and inflation grows more slowly. 5. A reduction in personal income tax rates leads to a rise in labor force participation and work effort, thereby increasing the supply of labor necessary to produce more goods and services. 6. Thus labor supply, capital stock, and productivity are all increased by lower tax rates, thereby expanding the maximum productive capacity of the U.S. economy. 7. As a result of higher maximum capacity the inflationary pressures of shortages and bottlenecks diminish, thereby reducing the rate of inflation. 8. An increase in maximum capacity also permits the production of more goods and services for export markets. This improves our net foreign balance and strengthens the dollar, thus leading to lower inflation because imported goods decline rather than advance in price. 9. Lower personal income tax rates lead to smaller wage gains, since wage bargaining is based at least in part on the level of after-tax income. This in turn reduces inflation further. 10. Thus lower tax rates cause a reduction in inflation through several channels. Inflationary pressures decline as the gap between actual and maximum potential GNP rises; productivity increases, thereby lowering unit labor costs; the donar strengthens, causing less imported inflation; and wage rates rise more slowly. I I. Lower inflation leads to higher real disposable income, since EV ANS/ 67 bracket inflation is mitigated. The rise in income leads to an increase in consumption, output, and employment. 12. Lower inflation leads to lower interest rates, stimulating investment in both plant and equipment and in housing. 13. The increased demand for goods and services stemming from lower inflation is matched by the rise in the maximum potential capacity of the economy to produce these goods and services, thereby resulting in balanced, noninflationary growth. One of the most important sets of linkages in the supply-side model is the relationship between saving and investment. For if saving rises and these funds are just used to increase idle cash balances, investment may not expand. However, these links are well documented in our model. A $10 billion increase in personal saving raises time deposits by $3.0 bH!ion and thrift institution deposits by $L6 billion. In addition, it reduces loan demand by $3.6 bilHon. As a result of these changes in the balance sheet of commercial banks, demand for U.S. government securities by the banks increases by $11.5 billion. This results in approximately a l % decline in interest rates and a 3.2% increase in stock market prices. These changes have two related effects on investment. First, lower interest rates and higher stock prices stimulate fixed business investment. Second, easier credit increases housing starts and mobile homes and, to a lesser extent, producers durable equipment. As would be expected, nonresidential construction is more sensitive to changes in interest rates and stock prices than is equipment. Thus we find a $2.5 billion increase in structures, as compared to a $1.3 billion rise in producers durable equipment from a $IO billion increase in personal saving. Residential construction rises $ l .5 billion because of credit easing and $1.2 biHion because of lower interest rates. These are, of course, only first-round effects which do not take into account the increase in investment stemming from higher income and outpuL However, these results do document the strong linkages between saving and investment which exist in the supply-side model. For if these linkages are not strong, the second-round effects will not be observable either. Another important breakthrough i.n our supply-side model is the endogenous explanation of productivity, which we have already d1scussed 1n the first section. A l % increase in productivity will not only expand maximum 68 / SliPPLY-SlDE ECONOMETRlC MODEL potential GNP by that amount; it will initially lower prices by 2/ 3%, since labor costs consist of 2/3 of total factor costs. This is only the first-round effect, since lower prices will lead to lower wages and further declines in unit labor costs and prices. The total effect of a l % increase in productivity is to reduce prices by about 2%. We are also able to introduce other innovations into the supplyside model because of the endogenous treatment of maximum capacity. In particular, the model introduces the concept of the cumulative gap, already discussed in the first section, which we define as the cumulative difference between 99% of maximum GNP and the actual level of GNP when this gap is negative. When it is positive-Le., actual GNP is below maximum potential outputinflationary pressures do not build because of bottlenecks and shortages. However, when it is negative, prices start to rise faster than would be indicated by the cost of factor inputs alone. So far this term does not sound greatly different than an index of capacity utilization, although it is much more inclusive in that it covers all sectors of the economy. However, we have cumulated this gap for all periods when the gap is negative. This term therefore indicates that inflationary pressures build up over many years and do not disappear every time a mild recession occurs. The inefficiencies and distortions which occur when the economy is operating near full capacity are not reversed overnight, and remain as a legacy until the cumulative gap once again returns to zero. This term may also represent the gradual buildup of inflationary expectations. The final area of the model in which supply-side economics has been incorporated is the integration of the international sector with the U.S. economy. Again, this is an area where theoretical economists have long posited strong links, but they have never been empirically documented within the context of a macroeconomic model. Supply-side effects are important in two specific areas, First, an increase in the gap between actual and maximum potential GNP raises exports, since the greater capacity of the U.S. economy permits the production of more goods and services for export markets as well. A I% increase in this gap raises net exports by about $0. 7 billion per year; since the gap is cumulative, this figure continues to increase linearly and is, for example, $2.1 billion after three years. The second major effect is the link between the trade-weighted EV ANS / 69 average of the dollar, which is itself closely tied to the size of the net foreign balance, and the overall rate of inflation. We find that a 10% decline in the value of the dollar relative to a trade-weighted average of the Deutschemark, French franc, Belgian franc, Dutch guilder, and Japanese yen raises the producer price index 1.3% and the consumer price index about half that much after a period of two years. Thus we can document several supply-side relationships that have a significant effect on inflation as well as the rate of growth. All these figures refer to the change in the CPI and are impact estimates only. First, a 1 p.p. decline in the personal income tax rate will lower wage rates and thus prices by about 0.5%. Second, a I% increase in productivity will lower prices by 2/3%. Third, a 10% improvement in the trade-weighted average of the dollar will reduce inflation by about 0.6%. Fourth, after a three-year period, a 1% increase in the gap between actual and maximum GNP will lower prices by 0.4%. It is worth repeating that all of these figures are impact estimates only and do not take into account the interaction between wages, prices, productivity, and other factors of production. Indeed, the final changes in prices are between two and three times the initial impacts, depending on cyclical conditions at the time. Thus we find that the nemesis of demand-side economics, namely that output must be reduced and unemployment increased in order to dampen the rate of inflation, is only one of several alternatives. Inflation can also be reduced by increasing productivity, reducing personal and corporate tax rates, and strengthening the value of the dollar. We would not quarrel with the statement that the size of the gap between actual and maximum potential GNP is one of the factors determining the rate of inflation, but do believe that other factors must be considered as well. The actual reduction in the implicit GNP deflator for the highgrowth, high-deficit case is only 1.3% by 1990, although even this represents a marked change from the usual finding that inflation would be higher. The two principal reasons for this discrepancy are a) the lag structure and b) the large deficit. The changes in productivity do not immediately translate into lower prices, since both changes in wages and prices react to change in economic stimuli with a substantial lag. In addition, the benefits to higher productivity from higher investment are not felt immediately. The second and more important reason is that the huge budget deficit pushes up interest rates, thereby contributing to higher costs 70 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL of doing business and also raising the CPI through higher mortgage interest rates. Because of the fact that the implicit GNP deflator declines in this high growth scenario, we find that the reflows are rather modest. Hence the ex post deficit in 1990 is approximately $500 billion in spite of the higher growth generated. While such a deficit is economically feasible because the dissaving by the government is funnelled into saving by the private sector, we do not think it would be politically feasible, nor do we consider it the optimal solution. For this reason we have calculated another high-growth scenario, one with a balanced budget, which is generated by reducing transfer payments. This alternative high-growth scenario, which we then adopt as our preferred run, also provides additional information about the timing and magnitude of government spending multipliers. GENERATING A HIGH-GROWTH SCENARIO: THE BALANCED BUDGET CASE To generate this simulation, we made only one change from the previous high-growth run: we reduced transfer payments enough to generate a balanced budget. This resulted in transfer payments increasing only 2.2% per year (current dollars) instead of the 11 .4% per year increase which is included in both the baseline and high growth-large deficit scenario. The total reduction in transfer payments by l 990 is approximately $500 billion per year. Before examining the economic ramifications of such a reduction, it certainly is worth asking whether it would be possible to cut transfer payments by this amount while still retaining the present social fabric of the United States. Figures on the projected growth of transfer payments over the next decade under alternative assumptions are given in Table 5. For purpose of this analysis, we can divide transfer payments into three categories: retirement benefits, medical care payments, and other transfers, which are largely veterans benefits and welfare payments. Under the baseline case, retirement benefits are expected to grow at a rate equal to the annual average increase in the CPI plus the average increase in the population over 65. A similar formula would apply for medical care benefits, although there we use the increase in the CPI for medical care. Other transfer payments are expected to grow at a rate of increase equal to the TABLE 5 Projected Growth of Transfer Payments 1980 (billions) Annual Increase Due To: Change in Inflation Pop. Coverage Total Annual Change 1990 (billions) A. Baseline Retirement Benefits Medical Care Other TOTAL Retirement Benefits Medical Care Other TOTAL $157 38 98 293 9.9% I0.1 2.0% 2.0 8.3 LO 0.0% 1.0 0.0 12.1% 13.4 9.4 11.4 B. Adjustment for Lower Inflation Only 0.0% 8.2% 6.1% 2.0% $157 7.8 2.0 ll.O 38 1.0 8.5 7.5 o.o 98 l.O 293 8.7 C. Lower Inflation and Cutbacks in Program Retirement Benefits $157 6.30/o 2.0% -9.0% -0.7% Medical Care 38 7.8 2.0 -5.0 5.0 Other 98 7.5 1.0 -3.7 4.6 TOTAL 293 2.2 aJmplicit Constant Def1ator instead of CPI $490 134 241 865 $344 108 222 674 $147 62 154 363 72 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL average rise in the implicit GNP deflator plus the average gain in total population. These figures are all given in Table 5A. The figures in Table 5B are adjusted for lower inflation, and also incorporate the assumption that retirement benefits would be indexed to the implicit deflator for consumption rather than the CPI, since the tendency of the latter to overstate price increases because of its overdependence on the cost of buying and financing a home is now weil known. Thus switching to the higher-growth lower-inflation scenario, plus this one sensible adjustment in the indexation scheme for social security benefits, reduces transfer payments by almost $200 billion per year by 1990. While this $200 billion is indeed an impressive saving, it is far less than the $500 billion which is needed to balance the budget. Table 5C provides the arithmetic to indicate how these remaining savings are achieved. From an economic point of view, the following changes are instituted: 1. The retirement age is raised from 65 to 70. There is nothing sacrosanct about the number 65 for a retirement age; indeed, if we use the most recent actuarial tables, we find that a retirement age of 65 in the mid-1930s (when social security was originally implemented) now corresponds to an age of almost 70, and that figure will probably rise to 72 by the end of this decade. As might be expected, the savings in postponing the retirement age are substantial. Each additional year of postponcment-e.g., from 65 to 66-saves the government $18 billion at current levels of benefits and population. If we adjust this figure upward for the increase in the implicit consumption deflator and the growth in population over 65, by 1990 this figure amounts to $40 billion for each year the retirement age is postponed. Thus raising the retirement age to 70 would save a whopping $200 billion, in which case retirement benefits would actually be somewhat below present levels. The other cuts are less drastic. The reduction in medical care benefits could be accomplished, we believe, by simply adding a deductible and coinsurance whereby the patient would pay the first $100 per year of medical expenses and 90% of the remainder up to some fixed limit which might be equal to, say, 10% of his annual income. For example, if an individual had an income of $20,000, be would be required to pay no more than $2,000 in medical premiums that year regardless of the extent of his actual bills. This would provide 100% coverage for catastrophic illness while alerting patients to the substantial cost of medical services which is borne EVANS/ 73 by society at large. We estimate that the deductible and coinsurance as outlined above would cut the growth of medical care payments in half. The remaining cuts would occur in the phasing back of existing programs, such as food stamps for college students, a cap on black lung payments, reduction in the Aid to Families with Dependent Children as these parents returned to work, and other similar welfare programs. Of the three major areas, these cuts are proportionately the smallest and the most politically feasible. It should be made quite clear that workers who no longer receive retirement benefits at ages 65 through 69 will remain in the labor force, but the higher growth rates will certainly provide the additional jobs necessary to support these older workers. As we have already mentioned above, the U.S. economy will shift from a labor surplus to a labor shortage economy by 1990, and the jobs which these older workers retain will mitigate the labor shortage problem. Hence the gradual raising of the retirement ageincreasing it, for example, six months every year over the next decade-would fit hand in glove with the need for more workers and the redirection of resources from the public to the private sector. COMPARISON OF THE TWO HIGH-GROWTH SCENARIOS Based on traditional multiplier analysis, one might expect that the $500 billion decrease in transfer payments would result in a far slower rate of growth because of the resulting decline in consumption. However, this is not at all what happens. The reduction in the federal government budget deficit lowers interest rates, thereby stimulating capital formation. Furthermore, the lower rate of inflation which stems from higher productivity growth also reduces interest rates. Finally, since income is redistributed to those who are working away from those who are not, labor force participation rises, which provides the additional labor inputs needed to complement increased capital spending. The comparison for several key variables is given in Table 6. In particular we note that while real growth is about ½ OJo per year higher for the largest deficit case in the early 1980s, the pattern is completely reversed in the second half of the decade, and by I 990 real GNP is increasing almost 1/2 OJo per year faster for the balanced budget case. As can be seen, the rate of inflation is approximately 1% per year lower for the balanced budget case after 1985. 74 / S U P P L Y · S I D E E C O N OM E T R l C M O D E L TABLE 6 Comparison of Two High-Growth Scenarios 198119821983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- Real GNP,% Growth Large deficit No deficit 2.6 2.5 6.2 5.9 4.4 3.8 1.0 0.2 2.1 1.6 3.4 3.2 3.9 4.1 4.4 4.7 4.8 5.2 5.0 5.4 7.6 6.9 6.6 5.7 6.1 5.0 5.6 4.5 5.3 4.2 4.9 3.8 Implicit GNP Deflator, OJo Growth Large deficit No deficit 9.2 9.2 8.7 8.7 8.8 8.6 8.6 8.2 Federal Budget Surplus or Deficit, billions of $ Large deficit No deficit -78 -65 -70 -19 -92 -148 -199 -239 -284 -348 -416 -508 -2 -15 -16 -2 13 15 16 -4 Government Spending/GNP, ratio Large deficit No deficit 37.1 35.5 34.5 34.8 35.1 35.2 35.2 35.2 35.2 35.2 36.6 34.0 32.2 31.9 31.6 31.1 30.4 29.9 29.4 29.0 AA Utility Bond Rate, % Large deficit No deficit 11.5 11.3 11.7 13.0 13.6 14.l 14.6 15.5 16.6 18.0 t t.5 11.0 IO. 9 11.8 11.5 11.3 11.0 11.2 I 1.5 12.2 LOW -OROWTH SCENARIO We have generated a high-growth scenario with a balanced budget by cutting corporate and personal income tax rates dramatically and then balancing the budget through lower transfer payments. The low-growth alternative, however, cannor realistically be generated by raising tax rates the same amount they were cut in the high-growth alternative, for no one expects the statutory tax rates to be raised during the l 980s, although rates may drift up EV ANS / 75 because of bracket creep. Thus we must lower growth directly by reducing growth in the labor force and by lowerfog the rate of growth in productJvity. This can be done by a combination of a) higher tax rates through bracket creep, b) higher costs of government regulation, and c) higher relative energy prices. Thus we have approached the 1ow-growth scenario in a much different manner, and have changed those variables which impact directly on labor force growth and productivity other than income tax rates. The changes which we have introduced to generate this scenario are the following; 1. Energy prices, both imported and domestic, grow at a faster rate. 2. The cost of government regulation doubles over the decade. 3. Labor force participation rates grow more slowly. 4. Transfer payments grow 15.6% per year instead of 11.4%. The average tax rate increases from 24.9% to 38.3% by 1990-but that is entirely due to bracket creep and does not reflect any rise in the statutory rate. In addition to these four changes, we have also cancelled any personal or corporate income tax cuts over the decade which are included in the baseline, held depreciable lives at I 980 levels, and terminated the investment tax credit. However, it should be stressed that these do not account for the bulk of the decline in growth which occurs in this scenario- that is due to the four factors listed above. COMPARISONS OF THE ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS We now compare the performance of the economy, on a decadelong average and for year-by-year changes, for the baseline, high growth with balanced budget, and low-growth scenarios. We have not included the high growth with large deficit run, since that is not a feasible alternative; furthermore, we have already discussed the difference between the two high-growth runs in the previous subsection. The principal assumptions and results are presented in Table 7. While the decade average figures are useful, they really do not convey the full flavor of the differences between the runs; this is best done by examining the differences in the forecast on an annual basis, which is presented in Table 8. Here we note the great divergence which occurs in the saving rate, growth in productivity, and inflation, particularly after 1985. The forecasts are somewhat 76 / S U P P LY - S l D E E C O N O M E T R I C M O D E L TABLE 7 Growth Rates (1980 - 1990) Selected Economic Indicators for Alternative Scenarios Baseline Real GNP Labor Input Labor Productivity Labor Force Participation Real GNP per capita Relative Price of Energy (PPI) Growth of Transfer Payments 2.9 2.0 0.9 0.6 2.0 6.6 ll.4 High Growth Low Growth 3.6 1.6 2.0 0.8 2.7 2.1 1.6 1.3 0.3 0.3 0.7 7.2 15.6 0.168 0.20 10% 5.0 10.0 0.284 0.46 0% 10.5 23.0 6.8 Levels in 1985 Personal Income Tax Rate Corporate Income Tax Rate Investment Tax Credit Depreciation Lives, Equipment Depreciation Lives, Structures 0.227 0.46 10% 8.4 18.4 similar for the first five years but then differ markedly, which emphasizes the fact that mosl of the effects of changes in supplyside fiscal policies occur only after rhe first five years. The results in Table 8 point out that the effect of higher productivity on higher saving and investment on productivity, growth, and inflation is far from instantaneous. In fact, even if an optimal fiscal policy were to be implemented immediately, we would not expect it to have a noticeable effect on slowing inflation for at least two years. In fact. it is often five years or even more before the full effect of higher saving is translated into benefits for the entire economy. In fact, it is imeresting to note that the initial effect of these tax cuts is to raise inflation, just as would be the case in a traditional demand-side model. This occurs because the demand elementshigher consumption and investment-are activated before the supply elements-higher productivity and lower wage rates-work TABLE 8 Annual Comparisons of Alternative Scenarios 198119821983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- Real GNP, % Change Baseline High Growth Low Growth 2.0 2.5 1.7 5.2 5.9 3.8 3.6 0.0 1.5 3.8 0.2 1.6 1.7 -0.9 -0. l 3.0 3.2 I.2 3.6 4.1 2.4 3.6 4.7 2.9 6.3 5.7 8.4 6.2 5.0 8.5 6.3 6.6 6.9 4.5 4.2 3.8 9. 1 10.0 11.6 3.6 3.5 5.2 5.4 3.5 -0.3 Implicit GNP Deflater, % Change Baseline High Growth Low Growth 9.1 9.2 9.8 8.2 8.7 9.2 8.0 8.6 9.2 7.9 8.2 9.2 7 .1 6.9 8.8 Productivity Growth, OJo Change Baseline High Growth Low Growth 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.4 1.7 1.5 1.3 0.3 0.0 0.7 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 1.8 1.1 1.2 2.3 2.9 3.4 3.9 4.2 I. I -0.7 -1.4 -1.5 -1.9 -2.4 -2.7 -3.0 Ratio of Fixed Business Investment to GNP Baseline High Growth Low Growth 9.3 9.8 10.8 11.2 10.8 10.8 11.0 I I.I 11.1 11.0 9.4 10.2 11.6 12.1 12.1 12.3 12.5 12.8 12.9 13.0 9.3 9.7 10.4 10.5 10.3 10.1 IO. I 10.2 10.0 9.9 Ratio of Government Spending to GNP Baseline 36.6 36. l 35.6 36.3 36.8 36.9 36.8 36.6 36.5 36.4 High Growth 36.6 34.0 32.2 31. 9 31.6 3 l. l 30.4 29.9 29.4 29.9 Low Growth 37.2 36.6 36.9 38.I 39.2 39.7 39.7 39.3 38.5 38.9 Personal Saving Rate, 0/o Baseline High Growth Low Growth 4.5 5.0 3.2 5. l 5.1 3.2 6.6 6.1 3.4 6.6 5.7 2.8 6.5 5.5 2.5 7.6 6.5 3.0 8.8 8.0 3.3 9.7 10.3 11.1 9.4 10.7 12.5 3.0 2.2 0.8 78 / SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMETRIC MODEL their way through the system. However, by 1985 the situation is reversed and by 1990 the inflation rate in the higher growth scenario is almost 3% below the baseline solution. It is perhaps not very difficult to convince anyone that a higher rate of growth is preferable to a lower one. However, recently two groups of lower growth advocates have emerged: those who argue that we either cannot or should not produce enough resources necessary to support higher growth, and those who argue that higher growth would be inflationary and hence ultimately destroy that which we set out to accomplish. The resource question is not a trivial one, but can be solved by an appeal to market economics. The decline in domestic oil production and the huge increases in the volume of oil imports during the past decade has been directly related to the decision by U.S. government officials that we would somehow all be better off if oil prices were not allowed to rise as fast as increasing costs. While the problem with energy reserves is the most virulent, similar problems exist with respect to many other basic industrial commodities. It is imperative that the higher growth scenario be accompanied by adequate supply response in terms of profit margins for those who extract or produce basic materials. SIMULATIONS AND MULTJPLIER ESTIMATES One way to approach this subject would be to give the usual multiplier estimates for small changes in government spending, personal income tax cuts, corporate tax cuts, and similar measures. Even these estimates can be quite instructive; we have already used this model to show that the Carter tax packages are much more inflationary than the Reagan tax packages. However, the full flavor of the supply-side model cannot really be savored unless we introduce massive changes in fiscal policy, and it is these changes which we report in this section. Specifically, we have prepared three simulations: a) the baseline case with moderate tax cuts and essentially a balanced budget after 1982, b) a daring experiment in which we cut personal and corporate tax rates in half, and c) the same tax cuts, but combined with enough reductions in transfer payments to balance the budget. GENERATlNG A HIGH-GROWTH SCENARIO: THE LARGE DEFICIT CASE The high-growth run is generated by changing the following tax parameters: EVANS/79 1. Gradual reduction in the corporate tax rate from 0.46 to 0.20 by 1985. The actual yearly values are: 1980 0.46 1981 0.40 1982 0.35 1983 0.30 1984 0.25 1985 and later 0.20 2. Depreciation lives for equipment reduced from 10.5 presently to eight years in 1981 and five years in i 982 and thereafter. 3. Depreciation lives for structures reduced from 23 presently to 18 years in 1981 and lO years in 1982 and thereafter. 4. Gradual reduction in the average marginal federal personal income tax rate from 24% to 12% in equal increments by 1990. The revenue losses from these changes are immense, particularly when calculated in 1990 prices. For example, taxable personal income is estimated to be $3.4 trillion by 1990. Thus a cut from 24% to 12% in the tax rate would result in a static revenue loss of some $410 billion. The changes in the corporate tax rates are not as great, but they are still substantial. Pre-tax corporate profits are expected to be about $400 million by 1990; hence, cutting the tax rate from 46% to 20% would reduce tax receipts by $100 billion. In addition, shortening depredation lives would lower pre-tax corporate income by $140 billion, although since the tax rate is reduced to 20%, this only accounts for an additional $30 billion revenue loss per year. In fact, it should be clear that as the corporate tax rate approaches 0%, the length of depreciation lives is no longer of any importance for tax purposes. These figures indicate a static revenue loss of $540 billion per year. Even when compared with a GNP of almost $7 trillion and a federal budget of $1. 7 trillion, the amounts are quite large. This loss amounts to a deficit of 7. 7% of GNP, which is far larger than the postwar record of 4.6% posted in the recession year of 1975. It is usually argued that such static revenue loss estimates are inappropriate, for they fail to consider the higher revenue base raised by faster growth of the economy, higher employment and income, and greater profits. However, this leads to one of the major findings of the supply-side model. Because lower personal income tax rates generate smaller gains in wage rates and hence smaller increases in unit labor costs and prices, current dollar GNP is only slightly larger in the higher growth scenario than in the baseline case. Real GNP is some 8,6% higher, since we have defined the high growth alternative to show real GNP rising approximately I% per year faster for the nine-year 80 / SUPPLY-SJ DE ECONOMETRIC MODEL period 1981 -1990. However, according to our basic results on the trade-off between productivity and inflation, every l \lJo increase in productivity results in a 2% reduction in inflation. Hence in steady state equilibrium, we would expect current dollar GNP to grow 1% less per year with this higher productivity growth. The hypothesis that higher growth leads to more inflation is effectively defused by the results given in this report. Indeed, the higher growth scenario is accompanied by lower rather than higher rates of inf1ation, due to greater productivity and lower wage rate increases both slowing the rise in unit labor costs. Thus we are able to generate realistic alternative scenarios which not only provide for more jobs and greater output, but reduce the rate of inflation as well by redirecting resources toward saving and investmenL Finally, it is clear that one of the major contributors of higher growth in the preferred scenario has been the increase in the investment ratio, which in turn has been brought about through tax incentives for increased saving and investment. The generalized incentives for investment-lowering the corporate income tax rate and shortening depreciation lives-are well known and have often been suggested for stimulating investment. We have not used an increase in the investment tax credit in this scenario because of our finding that it is not as efficacious. It increases investment only about half as much as an equal reduction in the corporate income tax rate and about ¾ as much as an equal reduction in depreciation allowances. We have also introduced a net reduction in the capital gains tax by increasing the exclusion from 60% to 70% of the total gain, a change which also stimulates investment through raising stock prices and hence lowering the cost of equity capital. However, one should not neglect the fact that capital markets are fungible-that an increase in saving in any major sector of the economy will result in lower interest rates, greater credit availability, and hence greater investment and productivity. We can achieve these gains not only by stimulating investment directly, but by increasing saving in the personal and governmental sectors. In particular, we believe that capital formation can be stimulated by reducing personal as well as corporate income taxes. Hence in addition to reducing the corporate tax rate to 20% and restructuring depreciation lives to adjust for inflation, we also favor broad-based personal income tax cuts accompanied by commensurate reduction in government transfer payments. It is the balanced approach~the use of all three legs of the stool-which we feel is essential for balanced low inflationary growth. Thoughts on the Laffer Curve ALAN S. BLINDER ... the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. -J. M. Keynes The first part of the paper by Canto, Joines, and Laffer, which is the only part I will discuss, sets up a simple general equilibrium model with two factors (both taxed proportionately) and one output, and proceeds to grind out the solutions. The model, while not entirely unobjectionable, is certainly not outlandish in any important respect. The authors make no claims that the model tells us anything about the U.S. economy; nor do they draw any policy conclusions. They use the model to provide intellectual underpinnings for the celebrated "Laffer Curve" -the notion that the function relating tax receipts to tax rates rises to a peak and then falls. Since, as I will point out shortly, the analytical foundations of the Laffer curve were in fact established centuries ago, and require no economic analysis at all, I will devote my comments to the critical empirical issue: is it possible that taxes in the U.S. have passed the points at which tax receipts cease rising? Is the U.S. tax system over the Laffer hill? Let me note at the outset why this is an important question. Certainly not because of the implications for the government deficit. Surely what a tax change does to the budget deficit must be one of the least important questions to ask. It is important to know which taxes, if any, have reached the downside of the Laffer hill because, in an optimal taxation framework, tax rates should be set to raise whatever revenues are required with minimum deadweight loss. 1 Since a tax that is past this point causes deadweight loss and Alan S. Blinder is Professor of Economics, Princeton University, and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. 'The statement assumes that lump sum taxes arc unavailable and ignores distributional objectives. 81 82 / THOUGHTS ON LAFFER CUR VE FIGURE I G(t) t* makes a negative contribution to revenue, it must be irrationally high, as Canto, Joines and Laffer correctly state. 2 ORIGINS OF THE LAFFER CURVE Figure 1 is a Laffer curve relating tax receipts, G, to the tax rate, t. For some types of taxes (example: income taxes), the tax rate has a natural upper bound at 100%, so we may assume that G(l) = 0. For others (example: excise taxes) there is no such natural bound at 100%, so we assume instead that G asymptoticaHy approaches zero as t approaches infinity. The distinction is not terribly important so long as we keep in mind that taxes greater than 1000/o are indeed possible in many cases. 3 The Laffer curve reaches its peak at tax rate t*, which I hereafter call the Laffer point. 'Such a tax might be rational if its avowed purpose was to "distort" behavior (e.g., an emissions tax to reduce pollution). A purely redistributive objective is also a potential rationale; but there must be better ways to redistribute income. 'Taxes on such items as cigarettes, liquor, and gasoline have exceeded !00070 of the producer's price in many times and places. BLINDER/ 83 According to the media, the Laffer curve was born on a napkin in a Washington restaurant in 1974. This, however, l know to be wrong. The Laffer curve should perhaps be called the Dupuit Curve, because Dupuit-a man who was ahead of his times in many respects-wrote in 1844 that:• lf a tax is gradually increased from zero up to the point where it becomes prohibitive, its yield is at first nil, then increases by small stages until it reaches a maximum, after which it gradually declines until it becomes zero again. But Dupuit was just an academic scribbler distilling his frenzy from a politician of a bygone age. In parliament in I 774, Edmund Burke used what was perhaps called the Burke Curve by the journalists of the day to argue against overtaxation of the American colonists: Your scheme yields no revenue; it yields nothing but discontent, disorder, disobedience; and such is the state of America, that af!er wading up to your eyes in blood, you could only end just where you began; that is, to tax where no revenue is to be found ... But, alas, we cannot credit Burke with the idea either, for the concept goes back even further and is far more basic. One of the first things that freshmen learn in their first course in cakulus is RoHe's Theorem. RoUe's Theorem is as follows, Let G(t) be any continuous and differentiable function with G(a) = 0 and G(b) = 0. Then there must be some point t>t- between a and b such that G '(t*) = 0. Let a = 0, b be either 1 or infinity, depending on the type of tax under consideration, add the proviso that G '(0) > 0, and you have a Laffer curve. The existence of a Laffer curve, in other words, is not a result of economics at all, but rather a result of mathematics. We cannot doubt that there is a Laffer hill, i.e., there is a tax rate that maximizes tax receipts, so long as the assumptions of Rolle's Theorem are granted. Are they? I think we do not want to quibble with continuity or differentiability, and it must be true that a tax rate of zero yields no revenue. This leaves only the endpoint condi6on-either G(l) "" 0 or 0( 00 ) "" 0, depending on the type of tax in question. But I, for one, am willing to accept that a 100 6/o income tax rate or an infinite sales tax rate will, to a first approximation, eliminate the taxed activity entirely. The Laffer curve almost certainly exists. 'This quotation appears in Atkinson and Stern (1980). For other interesting precursors, see Canlo, Joines and Webb (1979). 84 / THOUGHTS ON LAFFER CURVE ARE WE OVER THE LAFFER H1u? I now turn to the question at hand. Is it plausible that the tax rates we observe in the real world are greater than t*, so that we are operating on the down side of the Laffer hill? First a preliminary point. We all know that the applicability of the Laffer curve hinges on elasticities being "large" in some sense. (I will be more precise in a moment.) Thus the possibility of taxing beyond the Laffer point is much more real for taxes whose bases are narrowly defined-either in time, or in geographical space, or in commodity space-than it is for taxes that are broadly based. Let me iHustrate. A sales tax on pastrami is much more likely to have a negative marginal revenue yield than a sales tax on all food, simply because of the much greater substitution possibilities on both the demand side and the supply side of the market for pastrami, as compared to the market for all food. Similarly, I rather doubt that an income tax on earnings between noon and 2 p.m. on Wednesdays would bring in much revenue. As a final example, I have heard it claimed that if New York City raised its sales tax, but the surrounding states and counties did not, revenues would actually decline. The possibility of being over the Laffer hill, I submit, is a very real one for very narrowly defined taxes. This, of course, merely strengthens the argument-which economists have been making for eons, it seems-for using broadly-based taxes rather than narrow ones. The important question for current public policy debates, as I understand it, is: Can it be that some of our broadly-based taxeslike the personal and corporate income taxes-have passed the Laffer point? This seems to me highly implausible, and let me explain why. Tax receipts are the product of the tax rate times the tax base. For ad va!orem taxes, the latter is itself the product of a price (the net-of-tax price) and a quantity.' Thus: (1) G = tpQ. Since t affects both p and Q, the derivative dG has three terms. dt The first term: pQ might be called (with some unfairness to the Treasury) the naive 'I assume markets clear so quantity demanded and quantity supplied arc equal. BLINDER/ 85 Treasury term. It would be a good estimate of marginal tax yield if there were no behavioral responses. The second term: tp dQ dt is the effect of the celebrated tax "wedge." Normally, we expect a contraction in the level of any activity whose tax is raised, so this term makes a negative marginal revenue contribution. The third term: tQ~ dt is the effect that arises from the fact that market prices generally change when tax rates change. Laffer et al. suggest that some economists have been led to underestimate the potency of the Laffer effect by ignoring general equilibrium reactions. Exactly the reverse seems to be true for many taxes. Consider, for example, a tax on a factor income where p is the price the firm pays and p(l- t) is the price the factor supplier receives. Standard tax incidence theory suggests that normal market reactions would make p rise and p(l - t) fall when t increases, suggesting that this third term is positive, not negative. Similarly, if there are possibilities for factor substitution, the demand curves for competing factors of production would be expected to shift out; if these factors are taxed, this will also bring in more revenue. 6 The shape of the Laffer curve depends on the balancing of these three forces. It is clear that if t* is to occur at an empirically meaningful level, the "wedge" effect will have to be quite large. To illustrate the conditions that are necessary, let us work out a concrete example of a flat rate tax on labor income. Let W be the wage the firm pays and W(l- t) be the wage the worker receives. Let S(W(l - t)) be the supply function and D(W) be the demand function, and assume S(O} = 0 so that a Laffer curve exists. Tax receipts are: (2) G(t) = tWS(W(l- t)), from which it follows by some simple algebra that marginal tax yield is: (3) dG dt = W · S( · )[ l - ~t_ 17c 1-t ' + _!_ dW (1 W dt + 17c)], ' 'For excise taxes, the argument cuts the other way. If pis the selling firm's price and p(l + t) is the consumer's price, then p probably falls while p(l + t) rises. 86 / THOUGHTS ON LAFFER CURVE where YJ 5 is the elasticity of supply: YJs = W(l - t) S ' (W(l- t)) s > 0. The positive Treasury effect, the negative wedge effect, and the positive price effect mentioned above can be seen clearly here. Working out the elasticity of W with respect to t, and substituting it into (3) gives:' (4) dG WS(' )[ 1 dt + _t_ riJl + rio) l-t rys-Y/D where r, 0 is the elasticity of demand: rJo "" WD '(W) < O. D Notice that (4) cannot possibly be negative in the range where demand is inelastic. The Laffer point, t*, is found by setting (4) equal to zero: (5) t* = ris - Y/o -r,D(l +YJs) Table I shows the values of t* for selected values of the two elasticities. It is clear that, unless the elasticities are quite high, we can be over the Laffer hill only when marglnal tax rates are extremely high. For example, even if each elasticity is as high as 2, receipts continue to rise until the tax rate reaches two-thirds. In other words, it is very unlikely (though not totally impossible) that the peak in the Laffer curve comes at a tax rate that anyone might seriously entertain. By exactly the same procedure, it is possible to work out the formula for the peak of the Laffer hill for the case of an excise tax at rate t on a commodity with producer price p and consumer price p(l + t). The answer is: (6) t* = Y/s - Y/n -risO + !'Jo) and Table 2 provides numerical values for selected elasticities. It is clear once again that t* is a huge number unless the elasticities are incredibly high. For example, with elasticities of 2 for both supply 'This is, of course, not a general equilibrium analysis, since I consider only one market in isolation. l think most economists would be very surprised if a multimarket setting changed things very much. In any case, the next section takes up a general equilibrium example. BLJNDER / 87 and demand, tax revenues are maximized at a tax rate of 200%. Elasticities as high as 5 are necessary to get t* as low as 50%. I conclude, therefore, that the revenue-maximizing tax rate is very likely to be so high as to be considered ridiculous for any broad-based tax. Only very narrowly based taxes, where elasticities in the neighborhood of 5 start to become at least believable, are Hkely to encounter the down side of the Laffer hill. For the important taxes in our economy, the Laffer curve holds no more interest than Rolle's Theorem. THE CANTO, JOINES, AND LAFFER (CJL) MODEL Now the examples just considered were mfoe, not Laffer's. So let me turn next to the empirical relevance of the Laffer curve in the model proposed by the authors. The model has perfectly conventional demands for two factors (called labor and capital, though both are variable) derived from a Cobb-Douglas production function. The factor supply equations are somewhat unconventional, so let me explain them a bit and interpret the parameters. Households hold fixed supplies of capital and labor, which they TABLE 1 Values oft* from Equation (5) Value of '1s 0 Value below 1.0 1.00 of l.O 1.00 -rio 2.0 5.0 1.00 LOO .25 - 1.00 .90 .84 .50 1.0 2.0 more than 1.00 LOO 1.00 LOO .75 .67 .83 .73 .60 .47 5.0 ... 1.00 .58 .33 TABLE 2 Values oft* from Equation (6) Value of Y/s 0 Value of -rJo l or below 2.0 5.0 .25 .... .50 LO 2.0 infinity 00 9.0 00 5.25 5.0 2.75 3.0 1.5 5.0 -+ 2.0 .88 1.4 .50 88 / THOUGHTS ON LAFFER CURVE can either supply to the market-at net-of-tax returns R* and W* respec:tively-or reserve for home production. Laffer et al. view the factor supply decision in a kind of "utility tree" framework. First, the household considers the choice of devoting its resources to the market versus home sectors; this choice depends on the average level of market returns relative to the average level of home returns (the latter is, I suppose, always unity). Second, the household decides on its relative factor supplies to the market by looking at relative market prices. This analysis suggests supply functions (assuming constant elasticity functional forms}: (7) u = [(R*)'>(W*)l-<>]' {_WR**) \ fl (8) f > 0, /3 > 0 .l >a where [(R*)"(W*) 1 -"1 is the (geometric) weighted average of market returns, weighted by the production function weights. The use of the same "i::" parameter in (7) and (8) reflects the assumption of CJL that the ratio of L to K depends only on the ratio W* JR*. A tiny bit of manipulation puts (7) and (8) into the form of equations (7) and (8) in the CJL paper: (7 ') (8 ') L5 = ( W>j< /-·rn(W*)' R* so that the parameters oK and oL that appear in the CJL paper are seen to have the following interpretations: Ea. The authors assume these parameters to be negative, which means they are assuming a fairly sizable value for E -which is the one unconventional parameter in this model. The interpretation of£ is the general price elasticity of supply of factors to the market sector (from the home sector). That is, if borh W* and R * were to increase by 1% , then the supplies of both capital and labor to the market would increase by£%. This is not a parameter for which much empirical evidence is available. The authors take pains to make clear that income effects are ignored in their analysis because marginal tax receipts (positive or BL l ND ER / 89 negative) are redistributed to the populace in a nondistorting way. In theory, this is correct. In practice, three caveats must be entered. First, it seems inconsistent to assume that revenue can be raised only by distortionary taxes, but can be given away in a nondistortionary way. Surely, any real way to give back the revenue (through transfer payments or government gifts of goods and services) will be just as distortionary as taxes. And isn't reducing lump sum transfers the same as levying lump sum taxes? Second, for the argument to hold, it is necessary that the recipients of the (lump sum?) transfers be the same as the payers of the additional taxes. If, for example, we consider cutting capital taxation and making up for the lost revenue by reducing transfers for the poor, there is no reason to think that income effects are of second order. In fact, I would be inclined to think that income effects would be of first order and substitution effects of second order. Third, it should be understood that the thought experiments considered in the paper are balanced-budget alterations in the tax structure, so we cannot really speak of revenue effects and Laffer curves at all. The model assumes that lump sum transfers are available, and what appear to be "Laffer curves" in Figures 2 and 3 represent instead the behavior of aggregate lump sum transfers as tax rates are increased. If we really care about Laffer curves we cannof ignore income effects. Nothing more need be said about the structure of the model. CJL correctly work out the solutions for prices and quantities and then compute the revenue-maximizing tax rates on capital and labor (their equations (27} and (28)). These can be simplified to: (9) (10} (I - a )(1 + £ )(1 + 1 + [3) f3 + a a(l + £ )(1 + 1 + {3) Let me now pose the $64 question. Is it possible that the tax rates implied by these formulas could be anywhere near current tax rates, which I take to be approximately tL = .3 and tK = .4? There are four parameters in these formulas. The one we know fairly well is capital's share, a, which I take to be .25. f3 is approximately the (compensated) wage elasticity of labor supply in the aggregate. There is much empirical evidence on labor supply. My reading of the evidence suggests that the lowest and highest values that can be seriously entertained are O and 0.6 respectively. 90 / THOUGHTS ON LAFFER CURVE Values oft{ and t; TABLE 3 from Equations (9) and (10) i::=0 high elasticities low elasticities t*L t*L = .77 ca, .91 t*K t*K = t*K t*K = NE = NE £=1 high elasticities low elasticities t*L t*L = = .38 .45 .85 .64 i::::c2 high elasticities low elasticities NE t*L t*L = .26 .30 t*K t*K .57 .42 Nonexistent (i.e., no tax rate under 100% solves equation (IO)). A is a trickier parameter; it is the elasticity of capital supply to the market (versus to the home sector) with respect to the rate of return. It is hard to know what to make of this parameter in a static model. Will I really keep my capital home if the return in the market is low? Doing what? In a dynamic model, I guess households supply capital to the market by saving, and the steadystate interest elasticity of capital is the same as the interest elasticity of saving. I think the absolute limits on reasonable estimates of the interest elasticity of saving are probably - .05 < A < + .40, with zero a strong candidate. This leaves the unconventional parameter£. Since I have no idea of how to "guesstimate" £, I will simply try three very different values: 0, 1.0, and 2.0. Table 3 evaluates equations (9) and (10) for a number of different sets of parameter values. The case denoted "high elasticities" is (J = .6, A = .4; the case denoted "low elasticities" is (J = .l, A = 0. The results are unambiguous. If£= 0, revenues keep on rising right up to the point where the tax rate on capital income reaches 100% ,8 and the Laffer point for the tax rate on labor 'It might be argued that, because of inflationary distortions in the tax system, effective rates of taxation of capital under current inflation rates are over 100% because laxes are being levied on negative real income. If this is the case, however, the Laffer curve no longer follows from Rolle's Theorem, and may not turn down at all. fl LINDER / 91 income far exceeds what we actually observe. If£""' 1, Laffer points do exist for both capital and labor. But the revenue-maximizing tax rates still exceed the rates that characterize the U.S. economy (though perhaps not by much in the case of labor). Only when E gets as high as 2 does the peak of the Laffer curve come at tax rates that approximate those actually levied in the U.S.-26-30% for tabor income and 42-57% for capital income. Finally, suppose that the elast1cities of supply of capital and labor are really much greater than I have allowed for here. Suppose, for example, that both .:I. and {J are unity. Equation (9) then implies that will be as low as .30 if E exceeds 1.6; equation (10) implies that t; is 0.4 when E = 3 .2. I conclude that, given the CJL model, the only way the contemporary U.S. economy could find itself on the down side of the Laffer hill is if the parameter t is quite sizable. Unfortunately, this is not a parameter we know much about. Pending evidence to the contrary, I am inclined to think it quite small. But nothing much hinges on this belief; all that matters is that£ not be huge. As Table 3 shows, to be anywhere near the top of the Laffer hill with current tax rates, E wilt have to be about 2. This means that a 100/o increase in both wage rates and the rate of return on capital must induce a 20% increase in the quantity of each factor supplied to the market sector. I find this scenario quite fantastic. tt SUMMING Up To establish the existence of a Laffer curve in theory, we do not need to know anything about either economics or the tax system. Rolle's Theorem will do. But it is a long way from proving the existence of a Laffer curve to arguing that existing taxes are on its downhill side. While the down side of the Laffer hill may perhaps be relevant to very narrowly-based taxes, back-of-the-envelope calculations such as those presented here make it seem highly unlikely that broad-based taxes could fall in this range. The specific model presented in the paper by Canto, Joines, and Laffer does nothing to dispel this belief unless the tax system (at the margin} chases huge amounts of capital and labor out of the market system and into the home production sector (or the underground economy). 92 / THOUGHTS ON Li\FFER CURVE REFERENCES Atkinson, A.B. and N.H. Stern. "Taxation and Incentives in the U.K.: A Comment." Lloyds Bank Review, April 1980. Canto, V.A., D.H. Joines, and R.I. Webb. "Empirical Evidence of the Effects of Tax Rates on Economic Activity." mimeo, University of Southern California, September 1979. Discussion of the Evans Paper STEVEN BRAUN Aggregate supply is an old idea. Although discussed by Keynes and the early Keynsians, most recent econometric models can justly be criticized for not adequately developing the supply side. It is therefore exciting to review a supply-side model created by one of the most prominent model-builders. The Evans model was commissioned by the Senate Finance Committee as an attempt to incorporate supply-side effects which were not in existing econometric models. My remarks are based on a version of the model furnished to me courtesy of Dr. Evans (Evans, 1980). Theory suggests a number of channels through which, in the long run, a reduction in various tax rates might substantially increase aggregate supply. This would make possible a higher level of real output without inflationary consequences. Four of these channels have been built into the Evans model. They are: l. Because workers bargain for after-tax wages, a reduction in personal tax rates decreases wage demands; 2. Because income taxes reduce the incentive to work, a reduction in the personal tax rate increases both the participation rate and hours worked; 3. Because business taxes reduce the incentives to invest, reductions in these taxes will increase the stock of business capital; and 4. Because interest rewards savings behavior, a rise in the aftertax rate of interest will increase savings. Although theory suggests the possible existence of these channels, it has little to say about their strength. Earlier model builders have found substantial empirical support only for the third channelbusiness taxes. Evidence for the others have been mixed at best and most other models do not contain them. Steven Braun is Economist, Wage, Prices and Productivity Section, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The views contained in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board or its staff. The author is grateful for discussions with Albert Ando and Jared Enzler, and thanks Ron Sege for research assistance. 93 94 / EVANS DISCUSSION Dr. Evans differs from others in claiming to have been able to measure these channels and he finds their strength to be considerable. I find this evidence unconvincing. Let us begin by introducing one of the devils of the supply-side pantheon. Figure I shows the average and marginal tax rates computed by Dr. Evans from the IRS tables. Except for the 1964 tax cut these variables show a strong upward trend-a fact which is important in understanding this model. For comparison purposes I have computed an average tax rate based on data from the national income accounts. Since this series allows for the standard and personal deductions, which are excludable from income used above, the tax rate level is lower, and its trend is slightly less steep. Now let us turn to some key equations which incorporate the various supply-side channels. Let me begin with the wage equation (which is the first equation in the Appendix). This wage equation is for the most part a rather standard looking inflation augmented Phillips curve. The rate of wage change depends on (ignoring the various dummy variables) the inverse of the unemployment rate, the rate of change in the CPI, the rate of change of output, and the level of the average personal tax rate. Presumably, the idea is that workers bargain for after-tax wages. But if this were true, the growth of taxes rather than the level of taxes should be included. The effects of this misspecification produce odd simulation results. A one time reduction in tax rates will affect the rate of wage growth not only in the following years, but for eternity. Using the coefficients of this equation, I have calculated that a reduction in the tax bill of, say, 3 percent will lower wages also by 3 percent after 6 years. But after 12 years, wages decline by 6 percent-twice the reduction in taxes! This equation is going to make the KempRoth tax cut look very good! Notice that the effect of prices on wages is very low (0.6) implying that workers suffer from money illusion so that even in the Jong run, a permanent higher level of inflation could lower unemployment. It appears that the tax rate is picking up some of the trend in inflation. Labor force participation rate equations are perhaps the most visible and the oldest of the supply-side features. Because of conflicting income and substitution effects, the sign of the wage variable could go either way. However, an upward sloping supply curve is plausible. Evans' participation equations (an example of which appears in the Appendix) does not seem to produce credible evidence for this proposition. Since one of the independent variables is the real after-tax wage bill, an increase in employment FIGURE 1 Average and Marginal Personal Tax Rates .45 .45 AO .40 Marginal Rate' .35 .35 .30 .30 .25 .25 Average Rate {NIA Basis)' .20 .20 .15 .15 ,__.......__...___.,_ _,______......__.__..,___,__ _.____._......__..__.__..___.,_..,j,.._........._.___, . JO 74 76 1978 66 68 1960 62 70 64 72 'Computed by Evans from IRS, Statistics on Income. This series includes state and local taxes and social security taxes, 'Computed by Evans from IRS, Statistics on Income. This series includes state and local taxes and social security taxes. 'Average tax rate computed on an NIA basis: (tax and nontax payments) + (personal contributions for social insurance) (personal income) + (personal contribmions for social insurance) 96 I EVANS DISCUSSION has the same elasticity as an increase in real after-tax wages. We all know what the trends are in employment and participation. Thus the coefficient of the wage rate in this equation is guaranteed to show the correct sign. Notice also that the level of unemployment does not enter this equation, only its first difference. Will the participation rate snap back to trend when the unemployment rate stops growing? The effect of tax rates on labor supply in this model is only partially captured in the labor force participation equations. Claiming that increased taxes reduce hours worked, Evans models a tax effect in the total manhours equation (shown in the Appendix). Here taxes are shown to reduce hours worked. This is a curious equation. If the level of productivity were included, rather than its growth rate, this equation would be close to an identity. However, productivity enters only through its growth rate. Because the omitted variable, the level of productivity, also has an upward trend just as the tax rate does, it is likely that the negative sign on the tax rate occurs because it is picking up the trend of the omitted variable. Even this negative sign is curious. For a given level of output, a decrease in the tax rate will decrease manhours worked. Since output is also in the equation, and therefore held constant, this means that productivity has fallen. Thus, productivity falls when the tax rate falls. I seriously doubt that this is the effect that Dr. Evans wanted to show. I understand that the model presented to the Senate Finance Committee does not simulate. Surely, this equation must generate some problems. Consider how this equation interacts with the participation equations. When the tax rate rises, manhours fall, causing the wage bill to fall. This in turn causes the participation rate to fall. So while it is claimed that the participation equations only captures part of the effect of higher taxes, we see that in simulations, this will not be true. The productivity equation is discussed at length in Evans' paper in this volume. However, this equation is really superfluous since productivity is implicitly computed in the total manhours equation. Besides the growth of productivity appearing in the manhours equation and the capacity equation, I do not see how else the productivity variable is utilized. If it were utilized, it would be inconsistent with the manhours equation. (By the way, why does the level of secondary workers and the level of government regulation affect the growth of productivity?) BRAUN / 97 This model claims the ability to evaluate the effectiveness on investment of several forms of corporate income taxation. Reducing the corporate tax rate, for example, is found to be more effective per Treasury dollar than increasing the investment tax credit. I find these results to be based on a peculiar structure of the investment sector (see Appendix). The demands for new orders is separately influenced by four elements of the cost of capital: an index of industrial prices, the corporate tax rate, the depreciation allowance, and the investment tax credit. Then a single cost of capital variable affects how new orders are translated into investment. This raises problems of double counting the effects of these taxes. Since consumer expenditures are also in both equations, there seems to be double counting here too. These extra terms in the investment equation raise the possibility that investments may occur without antecedent new orders. I know of no theoretical explanation for this peculiar structure, nor has one been offered. The effect of the interest rate on savings has long been a puzzle. As Keynes recognized, "Some of the subjective motives towards saving will be more easily satisfied if the interest rate rises, others will be weakened." 1 Since Dr. Evans claims a substantial effect, let us examine his equation (the fourth equation in the Appendix). Consumption is a function of lagged consumption, current and lagged income, and the after-tax real rate. However, wealth is omitted, and this omission is serious in interpreting the effects of changes in interest rates. Since the savings rate falls when wealth rises relative to income, and since wealth rises when the interest rate falls, the interest rate in this equation may be merely picking up the wealth effect. So after examining this equation, one still does not know whether the income or substitution effect dominates. With these remarks in mind, it is time to ask how this model can help analyze aggregate supply. Reducing the personal income tax to reduce wage demands is dependent on an equation in which tax levels influence wage growth. Reducing personal taxes to increase labor force participation is dependent on an equation that cannot distinguish an increase in wages from an increase in total manhours. Reducing personal taxes to add to labor input is dependent on an equation that omits the level of productivity. Reducing the corporate tax rate to spur investment seems to be dependent on an investment sector that counts this parameter twice. 'John M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employmenl, Interest, and Money, Harcourt, Brace & World Inc., !964, p. 93. 98 / EVANS DISCUSSION Reducing taxes on saving to encourage saving seems dependent on an equation that confuses the wealth effect with the interest rate effect. Each of these prescriptions seem to be directly connected with an error in the model. What then have we learned about the world? REFERENCES Evans, Michael K. "Supply-Side Model." Evans Economics, Inc., mimeo, 1980. Evans, Michael K. "An Econometric Model Incorporating the Supply-Side Effects of Economic Policy." In this volume, 1981. Keynes, John M. The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money. Harcourt, Brace, & World Inc., 1964. BRAUN/99 APPENDIX EVANS SUPPLY-SIDE MODEL' (selected equations) Wage Equation (page 8.11) WRM4 = - .9 + .004 STRIKES + .008 DWPP + .6 CPI415 (-3.l) (2.3) (3.3) (7.1) + .3 AVGSUMl8 +. I XIPM4 + .8 UNI18 (3 .5) (3.0) (5 .2) R'= .83 WRM4 = percentage change2 of the average hourly wage in manufacturing STRIKES = Dummy variable, auto and steel strikes DWPP = Dummy variable, wage-price freeze CPI415 = percentage change' in the CPI, (distributed lag) AVGSUM 14 = sum of average personal tax rates, (distributed lag) XIPM4 = percentage change2, index of industrial production 8 UNI 18 = I/( I UN8), where UN8 i=I = unemployment rate if <8 8 if unemployment rate ),8 labor Force Participarion Rare (Females, 25-54), (page 7.53) LFPF2554 = .335 + .036 WMARG14 - .02 UN13 + .82 CPI41 (14.2) (3.7) (-4.8) (3.0) + 1.3 CPI45 R'=.85 (6.0) LFPF2554 = Labor force participation rate, females 25-54 WMARGl4 = (real wage and salary disbursements)(l-marginal tax rate), (distributed lag) UNl3 = UN-, - UN-, CPI41 - percentage change" in the CPI, lagged ( -1) CPI45 = percentage change' in the CPI, lagged ( - 5) 'Based on Evans, 1980. The page numbers from this document are as indicated. 'These are not simple percentage changes. Rather, they are defined as, 4 X - (1/4) IX_; I 4 (l/4) IX_, I 100 / E V A N S D I SC U S S I O N Manhours (manufacturing), (page 7. 69) EHMFG40 = 33313 + 101 XIPMS + 64 XIPM14 (26.) (14.8) (6.1) - 41965 AVGSUMI 8 -- 1458 PRODQIS (--23.4) (-7.9) - 9.5 KPPRODIS (- 2.1) R'=.97 EHMFG40 = manufacturing manhours XJPMS = index of industrail production, manufacturing XIPM14 = distributed lag of XIPMS AVGSUM I 8 = sum of average personal tax rates, (distributed lag) PRODQ18 = annual percentage change in private nonfarm business productivity (distributed lag) KPROD l 8 = (manufacturing capital stock) - (pollution control capital stock), (distributed lag) Consumption, (page 3. 19) C = constant + .336 C, + .296 Y + .299 Y-, - 2.04 r (estimated by principal components, long-run MPC = .89), R 2 = .997 C Y = total consumption expenditures per capita, 1972$ = disposable income per capita, 1972$ r = after tax real rate of return Jnvestmenr Sector New Orders Equation, (page 4.68) NOR = 3.4 + .4 PWINOR + .I CDNOR + 3.6 IHSLI (.7) (5.0) (22.8) (8.0) + 45. DCPNOR + .08 XIPDSENO - 35.6 EFFTAX (9.0) (5.8) ( - 6.3) + 6.4 ZENOR + 6.3 DITC2 (2.5) (1.4) R 2 = .994 NOR = New orders, all manufacturing PWINOR = WPI, industrial commodities, (distributed lag) BR A UN / 101 CDNOR = consumption expenditures, durables and non-durables, (distributed lag) IHSLl = total housing starts, (distributed lag) DCPNOR = index of capacity utilization (special functional form). XIPDSENO = industrial production index, defense and space equipment EFFTAX = corporate tax rate ZENOR = tax savings from depreciation allowance DITC2 = investment tax credit, (distributed lag) Investment Equation, (page 4.80) IPE = ·- 12.5 + 1.3 NORL6 - 1.8 CREDLS + .09 CDNL (4.6) (17.1) (-6.1) (8.4) - I a; RCCPL3~; (5 .9) R'"" .992 IPE = business fixed investment, producers durables NORL6 = new orders, all manufacturing, (distributed lag) CREDL5 = index of credit rationing, (distributed lag) CDNL = consumption expenditures, durable and non-durables, (distributed lag) RCCPL3 = cost of capital, (distributed lag) Discussion of the Evans Paper ALBERT ANDO While the political discussion in the United States has suddenly focused on the so-called "supply-side effects," this is not a new discovery in the literature of economics. I don't believe any one has denied the theoretical possibility that labor supply may depend on the real wage rate, and that personal savings may depend on the real after-tax rate of interest. The question has always been about the empirical order of magnitudes of these responses. In the case of savings, there are two further questions: whether or not an increase in savings will necessarily lead to correspondingly larger investment in capital goods, and how much the additional investment will contribute to potential and actual output. Evans appears to claim in his summary (Evans, 1981) that he has resolved all these empirical questions, and his new model is now capable of predicting major effects of macro and micro policies aimed at supplies of productive factors. A detailed appraisal of his claims is difficult because they are embedded into a large model, and the model in question is not laid out for easy understanding. I therefore propose to look at one critical group of equations in Evans' model as a representative of the model. Since Evans himself says that the equation explaining productivity plays the central role in his model, let us look at this equation as the starter. It is given in his summary paper (Evans, 1981) and (Evans, 1980, pp. 7.88-7.89). First of all, we have to presume that Evans, when he defines PRD as private nonfarm business productivity, means by this variable output per manhour in this sector. The dependent variable in this equation is the rate of change of PRD. We may dispute the choice of variables that Evans introduces to the right-hand side of this equation. In order to concentrate our attention on less controversial issues, however, let us accept his choice as appropriate. There remains the question of the form of this equation. Albert Ando is Professor of Economics at the University of Pennsylvania. 103 104 / EV ANS D l SC USS ION The most curious thing about this equation is the lack of correspondence of dimensions among variables, and consequent implausible steady state characteristics associated with it. As I indicated before, the dependent variable of this equation is the rate of change of productivity per manhour. Yet some of the independent variables, notably the ratio of the number of secondary workers to total employment, and direct federal government expenditures on regulations in current dollars, are level variables. To understand clearly the nature of absurd results that follow from this setup, let us consider the situation in which all independent variables, including the two variables mentioned above, remain constant for a while, generating a constant rate of growth of productivity. Now suppose that the proportion of secondary workers in total employment increases by some fixed amount, say l 07o, and remains at the new level thereafter. Then, the rate of growth of productivity (not the level of productivity) declines by a fixed amount. (If I believe in the definitions and numerical values reported in Evans' paper, it does so by .84% per year. However, this is too large an effect for me to accept for the first year, the only period in which this equation makes any sense, and I suspect that there may be some misprint and/ or errors of units in the definitions.) Consequently, a once-and-for-all increase in the proportion of secondary workers to total employment will, according to the Evans equation, lead to a continual decline in the level of productivity relative to the reference path. Taking Evans' equation literally, if the ratio of the secondary workers to total employment rises 1%, say from 400-/o to 4i07o, and remains at the new level thereafter, the level of productivity will fall by .84% the first year, 8.7% during the first 10 years, and 18.3% during the first 20 years, and will continue to decline forever, The level of federal government expenditure on regulation is even more absurd. The variable entered is total expenditure in current dollars. Thus, if the total expenditure in current dollars rises slowly for whatever reason, perhaps because of inflation, perhaps because the scale of the economy increases, the rate of increase of productivity must fall even if the federal government expenditure on regulation is becoming smaller and smaller relative to total GNP in current dollars. (As an illustration, suppose that GNP in current dollars is growing at 7% per year, while the government expenditure on regulation in current dollars grows at 4% per year and the inflation rate is 5% per year. The rate of growth of productivity will still continue to decline, according to Evans' AN DO I 105 equation.) Since no other variable on the right hand side of this equation is an extensive variable that grows with the growth of the economy as a whole, the presence of this variable, the level of direct federal government expenditures on regulation in current dollars, must eventually make the rate of increase of the productivity negative, even though this expenditure as a proportion of GNP in current dollars becomes sma11er and smaller. Even some of the more reasonable-looking variables have their troubles. The ratio of business fixed investment to gross national product sounds like a reasonable candidate for influencing the rate of growth of productivity. But anyone who has worked with models of growth will soon realize that this is not really a sensible variable. The variable of this sort that can be fairly readily accommodated in this context is the rate of growth of capital stock per employee net of depreciation, not the gross investment-gross output ratio. His statement that the relevant ratio is investment in constant dollars to the gross output in constant dollars, and not the ratio of current dollar values is also a serious suspect. The only theory bearing on this point in a multi-goods model that I am aware of is my own (Ando, 1964); the conclusion in that theory was that the only aggregate ratio that could be interpreted meaningfully was the ratio of the value of capital goods to the value of output, not the ratio between implicitly deflated figures in national income accounts. But that proposition was in the context of a specific, well-defined model, and here we are dealing with an assertion by Evans, which is apparently not based on any coherent view of the world. On a basis of these observations, I conclude that Evans' equation explaining the rate of growth of productivity, the equation which, in Evans' own words, reflects the main thrust of his model (Evans, 1981), is not worthy of our further attention. Even though Evans imputes great importance to the equation for the productivity discussed above, the output of this equation feeds into only two places in Evans' model, and it is probably worth extending our review of Evans' model to cover these two additional groups of equations. The first group of equations in which output of the productivity equation plays a role is the equation expressing total manhours as a function, among other things, of total output and productivity. One typical such equation in Evans' model is given as the third equation in Braun's discussion (Braun, 1981), also (Evans, 1980, p. 7.69). Since productivity, PRD, is defined as output per manhour, if all 106 / E VA N S D JS C U S S I O N definitions are assured of consistency everywhere, then the manhours equation must be an identity, namely EHMFG40 = XIPMS · l PRO where EHMFG40: manhours in manufacturing index of industrial production, manufacturing XIPMS: PRO: productivity per manhour, private, nonfarm, business sector The identity does not hold because EHMFG40 and XIPMS refer to manhours and output in manufacturing industries while PRO refers to productivity per manhour in private nonfarm business sector, XIPMS is an index of production rather than total volume of production, and for a host of other definitional discrepancies. But I do not see anywhere in Evans' writing or in his handling of these equations any indication that Lhere are any important conceptual reasons why the above identity should not hold. Yet, the manhours equation Evans actually estimates and reports is basically of the form EHMFG40 = constant + cr,XIPMS + ai LPRO PRO + .. · · · where dots represent additional terms in the equation which are not related to output or productivity. In other words, Evans has substituted for the level of productivity, PRO, in the identity the rate of change of productivity, linearized the equation, and then introduced a host of other variables. I see absolutely no justification for this substitution or for linearization. That it has disastrous consequences should not come as a surprise to us. For instance, given a level of output and a rate of growth of productivity (not the level of productivity), other things equal, the manhours needed to produce this output remains the same. To put it another way, if output remained the same from year O to year IO, while productivity (output per manhour) increased at the constant rate of 3 % per year, then the man hours required to produce this same output in year zero and in year ten are nevertheless the same. If this statement sounds contradictory, it nevertheless accurately reflects the statement embodied in the equation. Clearly, such a characteristic of the equation cannot be reconciled with data, and something else must enter this equation to help ANDO / 107 reduce the manhour requirement per unit of output over time. The only variable introduced by Evans into this equation with the type of time trend for performing this function is, of all things, the sum of average personal tax rate. (This rate, computed by Evans, has a strong positive trend over time. Whether or not this is a reasonable concept is another matter, since one could also compute the average rate which does not have as much trend). It is therefore not at all surprising that the average personal tax rate acquires a strong negative coefficient. Evans seems to suggest that the definitional identity among manhours, output and the productivity does not apply here because manhours and output measures that enter the manhours equation reflect short-run, cyclical movements of these variables while PRD reflects the longer-run, secular trend of the productivity. This excuse does not wash because PRD is simply calculated as the ratio of output to manhours in each year, and to reflect this fact, the equation explaining the rate of change of PRD has explanatory variables that are strictly related to short-run, cyclical variation in productivity, such as the rate of change of GNP and the index of capacity utilization. l must conclude, therefore, that Evans' formulation of the manhours equation makes no sense, that its fit against data is purely accidental, and that the large negative coefficient for the sum of average personal income tax rates estimated in this equation is at best due to a combination of vagaries of the pattern of time series data and of serious misspecifications of the equation form. I would like to repeat here a curious feature of this manhours equation observed by Steve Braun (Braun, 1981). Since output and the personal income tax rate enter separately as independent variables in this equation given the level of output, an increase in the average personal income tax rate will reduce manhours. That is, the higher the average personal income tax rate, the higher the productivity per manhour. I am sure those who are interested in supply responses to a change in the tax structure are interested in getting an explanation for this phenomena. The only other place where the variable PRD plays a role is in the equation defining the maximum production. It is a definition rather than an estimated equation, and takes the form (Evans, 1980, p. 11.11) where 108 // 108 Ev VAN ON N F A N 5S 0DJ1 SSC C U S S5 II 0 XIPC: index of maximum production in the manufacturing manufacturing sector = 100.0 1967 = EM*: EM: "full “full employment" employment” supply of labor in manhours K: <lstock" “stock” of capital goods, somehow measured We shall not discuss the serious problem of how EM* and K are measured by Evans, since the focus of our discussion here is how the measure of productivity is utilized in the model. Evans says says that PRODQ is the annual change change in private nonfarm business productivity. Evans could not mean what he says, since if we take him literally, it makes no sense, and don’t believe that he could and II don't have generated the data reported by him preceding the specification of this definition (Evans, 1980, p. 11. lO). I therefore assume that 11.10). PRODQ is something that does make a minimum of sense, say, the the accumulated value of the rate of change of productivity starting starting from some initial period, with the initial value of it coordinated with the constant term in the definition so as to fit the data. Even then, this equation makes no sense. If PRODQ is some concept such as the one I suggested above, and in any case it is based on the measure of productivity per manhour, then anyone who has ever worked with growth models based on homogeneous production functions, particularly the Cobb-Douglas function, will know that that the productivity measure cannot be introduced into the the production function unmodified. This is because productivity per manhour already reflects the contribution of an increase in the capital-labor ratio, as Evans’ Evans' equation explaining the rate of of change of PRD PRD tries to describe. Therefore its introduction together with the capital stock into the production function without the proper restriction is a double counting. One possible, though rather naive and unrealistic way to handle this problem is to replace the term 00o by e1/,PRooo in the above equation defining XIPC (assuming, er• e~°°~ e~RODQ Evans' PRODQ is basically always, that my reinterpretation of Evans’ correct). At least, this will make the structure logically logically consistent. Even if PRODQ is introduced correctly into aa Cobb-Douglas Cobb-Douglas production function, it is most doubtful that such a formulation will be adequate for estimating the maximum productive capacity of the U.S. economy. On a year-by-year basis, at least least some of capital goods are not malleable. Hence, it is a doubtful procedure to utilize goods any production function for the whole economy (or a large segment of it) incorporating the concept of the aggregate capital stock in order to describe the production possibilities in the sense that Evans uses the concept concept of capacity or maximum output. Moreover, the AN DO / / 109 ANDO depreciation or abandonment of capital goods may very well depend on movements movements of relative prices. But this is really taking us the most too far afield away from the the subject subject at hand, namely, the Evans’ model. obvious defects of Evans' In this note, I1 have so far limited myself to discussing the the Evans’ model and two sets explanation of productivity in Evans' sets of his equations in which the productivity so explained is a critical input. I1 have, however, looked at the large, 850 page document (Evans, (Evans, 1980), which is an explanation of his model, and II must report that everywhere I turned, every equation that II have examined, I have objections rather similar in nature to the ones ones I have been discussing. Very few of his equations make "good “good sense" sense” as this convenient term is normally understood by most of us economists, and most of them imply what I would consider rather absurd behavior of the dependent variable when explanatory when one of its explanatory all other variables is changed from one level to another while all explanatory variables are held constant. That is, most of his equations have what may be called "unacceptable “unacceptable steady state properties.’’ properties." In his oral discussion, Evans took the position that that he did not care what properties individual equations possessed, so long as the whole system generated dynamic behavior in simulation that that appeared reasonable. Although Evans is not alone in taking taking this position, position 1, II for one do not consider this position a tenable one in building econometric models. Some misspecifications in short-run, short-run, of some subsidiary equation might be tolerated, dynamic behavior of after a careful examination to make sure that that such a misspecification did not affect the overall behavior of the system, either for good or for bad. The requirement that the whole system behave in an understandable, reasonable manner under a variety of shocks is a useful criteria in judging the quality and acceptability of any econometric model, but is a criteria in addition to, and not in place of, the traditional traditional one that each equation in the system be sensible. Evans’ two papers (Evans, 1980 My review of Evans' 1980 and 1981), then, convinces me that the whole model does not make much sense, and II cannot have any confidence in his model nor in any analysis based on his model. I have seen many errors and bad judgments in many econometric studies, including my own. Seldom have I seen, seen, 1 in II recollect that Jay Forrester Forrester tended to take a position somewhat similar to this in find a specific reference at his writings in Industrial Dynamics, but hut II am unable to find specific rererence the present time. 110 110 // EVANS EV ANS OtSCUSSION DISCUSSION however, a large-scale work such as this one of Evans, undertaken by a reputable and experienced econometrician, econometrician, where the pattern of such major defects have dominated so large a part of the entire work. This is really too bad, because the case for rationalizing the tax tax This and transfer payment structure of the United States seems to me to be quite strong. The shift from the personal income tax to the the expenditure tax originally proposed by Kaldor has its appeal, with adequate taxation of estates. II provided that is is combined with the vexing believe believe such a shift will make it much easier to handle the problem of capital gains, to cope with inflation and indexing of the tax base, and may possibly stimulate savings. A great deal of work is beginning to be done in this area. I believe the rationalization of depreciation allowances should be pursued, and the immediate and complete write-off of capital good purchases as cost should be considered as one possible alternative, more in the case of considered producers’ producers' equipment than in the case case of structures. Going beyond that, some form of integration of corporate profit tax, personal income tax, and the social security tax would would be worth analyzing. of taxation by An even more difficult problem is the coordination coordination of the the federal, state, and local governments. On the transfer side, any the movement to make payments less dependent on income of the recipient is likely to be helpful. The aim is, as it always has been, to recipient design the tax and transfer payment system which raises the needed revenue, approach the desired redistribution of income as closely as possible while minimizing the distortion of relative prices. There are many many careful studies of these possibilities, although although they are all quite quite incomplete, and further research on them as well as open public discussion of these issues should prove helpful in formulating our economic policies in the coming decades. A work such as Evans’ Evans' new model, undertaken at public expense, and well well publicized, claiming so much and yet so misleading, is likely to divert the attention of both economists economists and the public away from basic issues and focus it on questionable gimmicks, raising raising false will, in the end, retard expectations in the process. I fear that it will, rather than advance the cause of fundamental reform of our tax and transfer payment structure. I hope that I am wrong in this premonition. premonition. ANDO/ ANDO / 111 REFERENCES Ando, Albert. "An “An Empirical Model of United States Economic Growth: An Explanatory Study in Applied Capital Theory." Theory.” In Models of Income Determination, L. R. Klein, ed., Vol. 18 18 of Studies in Income and Wealth, National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964. "Comment on Evans’ Evans' Supply-Side Model.” Model." In this Braun, Steven. “Comment volume, 1981. 1981. Evans, Michael unpublished, J. 1. Supply-Side Model. Evans Economics, Inc., 1980. "An Econometric Model Incorporating Evans, Michael J. “An Incorporating the Policy." In this volume, 1981. 1981. Supply-Side Effects of Economic Policy.” Policy and Corporate Investment Tax Polky LAWRENCE H. SUMMERS 1NTROOUCT~ON INTRODUCTION The proposition that the level of business fixed investment in the United States should be increased commands almost universal support. Increasing the rate of investment is widely seen as a panacea for a variety variety of economic problems including inflation, declining productivity, and the fall of the dollar. While there is agreement as to the inadequacy of business business fixed investment, there shortfall. For example, in is little agreement as to the causes causes of the sho1tfall. a recent proceedings volume of the American Economic Review, Blinder concludes with Robert Hall that "The “The principal source Alan Blinder of inadequate capital formation has been our failure to do do anything about recessions, not our active use of anti-investment stimulative policies,” policies," while Martin Feldstein (1980) argues that that the interaction of inflation and taxation accounts for much of the decline in corporate capital accumulation that has taken place over the last decade. This paper presents an overview of the issues connected with the in the relationship between tax policy policy and corporate investment, investment. ln first section of the paper, post-war trends in capital formation and corporate sector profitability are examined. While the share of gross investment in GNP has remained almost constant, the rate of net productive investment expressed as either a fraction of GNP or the capital stock has fallen sharply during during the 1970s. of the l970s. This decline has been associated associated with a substantial fall in the market price of capital, and in the after-tax rate of return to investors in corporate capital, the corporate sector. The reduction in after-tax returns to corporate investors, while partially related to a fall in the the pre-tax rate of return on capital, is in large part due to the interactions of inflation and our non-indexed tax system. The second section presents a cautious view of the social gains from increased corporate investment. Even a large increase in net Summers is Assistant Professor of Economics, Lawrence H. Summers Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. 115 116 / TA X POL l C Y A ND C O R PO R A T E J N V E ST M E N T business investment would not be sufficient to offset more rhan a small part of the productivity slowdown. Given a fixed path of monetary policy, tax reductions to spur investment are likely to increase rather than reduce the rate of inflation. The real payoff from increased investment, it is argued, comes from the very favorable terms of trade between consumption today and tomorrow. Foregoing a dollar today leads to an increase in potential consumption of two dollars only seven years hence. At these rates, most persons would find more investment attractive. Traditional econometric studies of the relationship between tax policies and investment are reviewed in the third section. It is argued that the type of investment equations embodied in most large scale econometric models do not offer meaningful guidance as to the effects of tax policy on investment. Since output is traditionally held constant, the capacity effects of increased investment cannot be captured in these formulations. As fundamental, the usual approach yields results which are very inconsistent with the assumption that expectations are rational. As an example of the misleading nature of standard econometric investment equations, the role of general expansionary policy as a device for spurring investment is considered. It is argued that as long as one accepts the view that there is no long run Phillips curve tradeoff, it is not possible for the level of general stimulus to have any effect on the long-run growth of the capital stock. The accelerator does not offer a useful route to increasing corporate investment. An alternative methodology for viewing corporate investment incentives is presented in the fourth section. It is shown that an asset price approach to evaluating investment incentives avoids the difficulties inherent in traditional investment equations and avoids the "Lucas critique" of being unstable across changes in policy regimes. The effects of various tax policies on investment are analyzed using this approach. 1t is argued that through judicious policy choices substantial stimulus to investment can be achieved without any large revenue cost to the government. The fifth section examines the general equilibrium effects of a change in business taxation. ft is argued that business tax incentives can only spur investment if the supply of savings flowing to the corporate sector is increased. This can occur in one of two ways. An increase in the after-tax rate of return may raise the savings rate. Alternatively, it may lead to an increase in rhe share of wealth allocated to the corporate sector. Each of these mechanisms is s UM MER S I 117 examined briefly. The paper concludes by discussing the appropriate macroeconomic policy mix to accompany business tax reductions. INVESTMENT AND THE PERFORMANCE OF THE NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATE SECTOR This section examines trends in the rate of non-financial corporate investment, and profitability during the post-war period. The focus here is on corporate capital formation because its alleged deficiencies have received the most attention and it is most plausibly influenced by tax policies. It is important to recognize, however, that corporate investment makes up only about 60 percent of the total. About 25 percent of investment is residential and the remainder is done by non-corporate business. The trends illustrated here hold for total business investment as well. There have been rather divergent movements in the rate of residential investment and the valuation of housing capital. These are examined in the paper's final section. TRENDS IN THE RATE OF CORPORATE INVESTMENT Various measures of the rate of non-financial corporate capital investment are displayed in Table 1. The type of measure most usually relied on, a comparison of gross investment with gross output, is shown in Table 1. It has been surprisingly constant throughout the 1951-79 period, and has been close to its long-term average during the last decade. However, focusing on gross investment may be very misleading. The key variable for economic performance is the rate of growth of the capital stock. This depends on net investment rather than gross investment. The rate of net investment as a fraction of gross corporate product has declined quite sharply in the last decade as shown in column 2. 1 While it averaged 0.036 over the entire 1951-79 period, it averaged only 0.024 during the 1975-79 recovery period. This corresponds to a 33 percent reduction in the rate of net capital formation. There is a second important issue involved in assessing investment performance during the 1970s. Regulatory requirements imposed in order to protect the environment and workers' safety have forced JThese estimates are based on the assumptions of straight line depreciation and service lines of .85 Bulletin F. There is a strong argument to be made that both these assumptions are conservative and so these figures understate depreciation and overstate net investment. TABLE I Alternative Measures of the Rate of Non-Financial Corporate Investment Gross I Net I Pollution Adjusted Net I Pollution Adjusted Net I Year y y y K 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 0.138 0.134 0.138 0.137 0.136 0.146 0.146 0.131 0.124 0.131 0.128 0.129 0.125 0.130 0.141 0.146 0.139 0.136 0.138 0.133 0.129 0.128 0.135 0.140 0.123 0.120 0.127 0.124 0.127 0.045 0.038 0.042 0.034 0.039 0.047 0.044 0.021 0.022 0.030 0.025 0.033 0.031 0.039 0.053 0.059 0.049 0.047 0.048 0.037 0.032 0.035 0.043 0.040 0.016 0.017 0.027 0.028 0.032 0.045 0.038 0.042 0.034 0.039 0.047 0.044 0.021 0.022 0.030 0.025 0.033 0.031 0.039 0.053 0.059 0.047 0.045 0.046 0.034 0.027 0.029 0.036 0.033 0.009 0.010 0.021 0.022 0.025 0.043 0.036 0.041 0.031 0.038 0.045 0.041 0.018 0.021 0.028 0.024 0.032 0.032 0.041 0.057 0.064 0.050 0.048 0.048 0.034 0.027 0.031 0.039 0.033 0.008 0.010 0.021 0.024 0.027 SUMMERS/ SUMMERS / 119 119 TABLE 1I (continued) 51-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 0,137 0.137 0.137 0J29 0.129 0.140 0,133 0.133 0.124 0.040 0.035 0.037 0.051 0.037 0.024 0.040 0.040 0.035 0.031 0.050 0.032 0.017 0.038 0.032 0.031 0.053 0.032 0.018 T 51-79 0.133 0.036 0.034 0.034 0.034 Source: text. Source: as described in text. investment.' This investment does not add firms to engage in capital investment.’ to the productive (in (in terms of measured output) capital stock. Hence, Hence, it should not be included in assessing changes in capacity capacity expanding investment. Data is available from the Department of Commerce on the share of investment outlays devoted to pollution control but not for occupational occupational safety. These outlays have risen sharply during the 1970s. in In columns 33 and 4, net productive output, and investment is expressed as aa fraction fraction of gross corporate output, of the corporate capital stock. They show very pronounced declines during the 1970s. The rate of growth of the non-financial corporate sector’s 2.55 percent during sector's capital stock in column 4 averaged only 2. the 1970s compared compared with 3.9 percent during the 1951-1969 period. A similar pattern is exhibited by the data in column 3. The evidence suggests that the rate of corporate capital formation has declined significantly during the 1970s. This conclusion would be significantly This conclusion strengthened if account were taken of occupational safety strengthened investment expenditures, and the more rapid depreciation depredation of the the 3 prices.' capital stock, which has occurred due to rising energy prices. 'H should be emphasized that pollution control expenditures are productive, productive, irs in that 9t that for clean air and water. These they provide for These benefits are real even even though they do do not show sip up in measured GNP. However, there is no apparent reason why a social decision to increase environmental quality should lead to a decline in the rate of “normal” investment. Hence, "normal" Hence, the appropriate appropriate standard standard of comparison is investment net of pollution control expenditures, expenditures. net ‘The prices has been been to reduce substantially the value of iThe impact of higher energy prlCes is energy energy inefficient. inefficient, If this extra component existing capital which ls component were added to depreciation, estimated net investment would decline even further. If one assumes obsolete, the that the energy shock rendered even even 55 percent of the capital stock obsolete_. over oneS oneaverage net investment rate over the J)07, or over the last seven years declines by .007. fourth of its average level. fourth TABLE 2 Cyclically Adjusted Rates of Investment Pollution Adjusted Net I y Pollution Adjusted Net I y 1965 1966 1967 1968 ]969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 0.143 0.144 0.136 0.132 0.135 0.134 0.135 0.127 0.130 0.138 0.140 0.131 0.127 0.129 0.127 0.128 0.128 0.131 0.136 0.128 0.130 0.132 0.125 0.125 0.042 0.041 0.038 0.032 0.037 0.041 0.041 0.034 0.037 0.046 0.047 0.035 0.029 0.031 0.029 0.032 0.033 0.036 0.035 0.033 0.032 0.034 0.027 0.028 0.042 0.041 0.038 0.031 0.037 0.041 0.040 0.034 0.037 0.046 0.047 0.033 0.029 0.029 0.026 0.027 0.027 0.028 0.028 0.027 0.025 0.028 0.021 0.021 0.039 0.037 0.039 0.030 0.036 0.041 0.040 0.035 0.038 0.049 0.050 0.034 0.030 0.029 0.026 0.027 0.028 0.030 0.027 0.030 0.027 0.029 0.022 0.022 56-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 0.139 0.132 0.133 0.130 0.128 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.033 0.031 0.038 0.038 0.037 0.027 0.024 0.036 0.038 0.038 0.028 0.026 T 56-79 0.132 0.036 0.033 0.033 Gross I Net I Year y 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 Source; as described in text. K SU M M E R S / 121 Even casual inspection of Table 1 shows that the state of the business cycle has a large impact on the rate of corporate investment. The rate of investment by any of the measures peaks in the boom years of the mid-60s, and reaches its low in 1975. In assessing the long-term trends which should guide tax policy, it is useful to abstract from cyclical factors. This is done by calculating the cyclically adjusted rates of investment shown in Table 2. The cyclical adjustments are based on regression equations of the form: R, = ao + a,RUMMt + a2RUMMt-1 + lit where R1 is the rate of investment, and RUMM 1 is the married-male unemployment rate which is used as a cyclical indicator.• The " is calculated as: cyclically adjusted investment rate Rt A Rr = R1 - a, (RUMMt - RUMM) - a2(RUMMt-1 - RUMM) .It corresponds to the rate of investment which would have taken place if the unemployment rate had been at its mean level. The results show that the decline in net productive investment in the 1970s is not a cyclical artifact. The share of corporate product (column 3) going to this source on a cyclically adjusted basis has declined from 3.8 percent during the 1956-1959 period to 2.5 percent during the l 970s. Thus, the decline in investment is almost as great on a cyclically adjusted basis as on a cyclically unadjusted basis. This conclusion also holds for the other measures of the investment rate. The conclusion that the 1970s have witnessed a large reduction in investment, inexplicable on the basis of cyclical factors, appears almost inescapable. Below we examine some possible underlying causes including the rate of profit and the extent of capital taxation. TRENDS IN CORPORATE PROFIT ABILITY The data in Tables l and 2 illustrate the declines in investment. Table 3 shows how various indicators of corporate profitability have evolved over the last 25 years. The first column shows the pretax rate of profit of the corporate sector. While the rate of profit has declined somewhat in the 1970s, it appears to have been fairly constant at about 11 percent over the entire period. The second column shows the total tax rate on corporate capital arising from 'Similar results were obtained using other indicators of the cyclical conditions such as the unemployment rate of all men 25 and over, the GNP gap, and the rate of capacity utilization. TABLE 33 Corporate Sector Profitability Year aTotal 'Total Rate of Return bTotal hTotal Effective Tax Rate 1955 1955 1956 1957 1957 1958 1959 1960 1960 1961 1962 1962 1963 1964 1964 1965 1966 1967 1967 1968 1968 1969 1969 1970 1971 1971 1972 1972 1973 1974 1974 1975 1975 1976 1976 1977 1978 1979 13.2 11.4 11.4 10.5 9.0 11.2 10.4 10.4 10.3 11.7 12.4 12.4 13.4 13.4 14.5 14.5 13.0 13.0 13.0 13.0 11.7 9.6 10.0 10.8 10.5 8.2 8.6 9.5 9.7 9.7 9.1 66.5 72.4 71.7 70.7 67.3 66.5 66.4 61.5 60.6 56.2 55.1 56.0 56.4 62.6 67.3 70.5 67.7 62.5 70.1 70.l 90.1 72.4 68.1 68.l 68.3 72.2 74.5 hReal bReal Net Rate of Return cRatio of of 'Ratio Market Value to Cost Replacement Cost of Net Assets 4.4 3.2 3.0 2.6 3.6 3.5 3.5 4.5 4.9 5.9 6.5 6.4 5.7 4.9 3.8 2.8 3.2 4.1 3.1 0.8 2.4 3.0 3.1 2.7 2.3 0.92 0.92 0.85 0.87 1.04 1.02 1.14 1.09 1.20 1.29 1.35 1.35 1.20 1.21 1.25 1.25 1.12 0.91 1.00 1.07 1.01 0.75 0.71 0.80 0.73 0.68 0.65 Sources: “State and Local Local Taxes and the Rate of Return on on NonaFeldstein and Poterba, "State Financial Corporate Capital,” Capital," NBER Working Paper #508R, p. 10. 10. p. 23 bbJjjj~ Ibid., p. 23 CEconomic Report of the the President. 1980, Table B-85. '"Economic Report of President, 1980, Table B-85. SUMMERS/ 123 SUMMERS / 123 the combination of federal and state taxes at both the corporate and individual levels. A fuller discussion of the calculation of these effective tax rates is contained in Feldstein and Summers (1979) and Feldstein and Poterba (1980). (1980), These data clearly show a very pronounced increase in the the taxation of corporate capital during the 55.1 percent in 1965 1970s. The tax rate has risen from 55.l 1965 to 74.5 percent in 1979. This increase in taxes has largely been the result of inflation. Inflation increases the taxation of corporate capital in three ways. The two most important are historical depreciation, which added over $25 billion billion to corporate tax liabilities in 1979, and the taxation tax liabilities of nominal inventory profits which raised corporate tax In addition, the taxation of of nominal by over $30 billion in 1979.' 1979.’ In JO capital gains is estimated to have imposed a tax burden of over $$10 billion. It is frequently argued that that these effects are offset by the the fact fact that corporations can deduct nominal interest payments for tax purposes. This gain to corporations, however, is itself almost completely offset by the increase in individual taxes on nominal interest. Feldstein and Summers (1979) show that in assessing the burden on total tax hurden on corporate capital, the taxation of nominal interest nets out and can be neglected. The after-tax after-tax rate of return on corporate capital is displayed in the third column. In the late 1970s it fell to only about one-half one-half of its level during the late 1960s. seen l 960s. From columns 1I and 22 it can be seen that over half of this fall can be attributed to increased taxes rather than to a decline in the pre-tax rate of return. This suggests that it the return to capital may be taxation more than any decline in the which has accounted for the 1970s investment slowdown. The values of Tobin's Tobin’s q ratio of the value of the capital the market valne stock to its replacement cost are shown in column cost column 4. The large decline in the value of q during the 1970s of course stands during stands out. It is noteworthy that the 50 50 percent fall in q from the late 1960s almost fall in the exactly parallels the fall the net return to corporate capital shown in Table 3. It appears that a significant portion of of the the fall in the total market valuation of corporate capital can be attributed to the extra tax burdens imposed by inflation. If one accepts a "q" “q” theory extra of investment of the the type discussed in the fourth section, this investment of provides further support the hypothesis that increased taxation support for the 5 Ttñ; extra extra tax burden is in some sense voluntary since firms firms could avoid it by 'This switching to LiED LIFO inventory accounting, accounting, This does not make it less real. Firms FlED because, rationally or irrationally, they perceive presumably stay with FIFO perceive some so. Nonetheless inflation inflalion does penalize intramarginal economic gain from doing so, burdens. by raising their tax burdens, them by 124 / TAX POLICY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT has been an important cause of the decline in investment which has taken place during the 1970s. Before examining the data bearing on this question, we turn in the next section to an analysis of the potential gains from increasing the rate of investment. THE GAINS FROM INCREASED INVESTMENT This section examines the potential social gains from tax policies designed to increase corporate investment. The arguments which have received the most popular attention, those linking investment to productivity, inflation and unemployment, are examined first. It is shown that none of these considerations provide a strong case for investment tax incentives. A case for reducing the tax burden on corporate capital is then developed in terms of micro- and macrointertemporal economic efficiency. INVESTMENT, PRODUCTIVITY AND GROWTH The poor performance of productivity in recent years has often been attributed to the low rate of growth of the capital stock. It is argued that increasing the rate of investment could have a large effect on the rate of growth over the next decade. This prospect seems unlikely. Prominent studies of the productivity slowdown, Denison (1979), Norsworthy, Harper and Kunze (1979), show that even after full account is taken of the decline in capital accumulation, most of the productivity slowdown cannot be explained. The limited potency of increased investment in spurring productivity growth can be illustrated by a simple calculation. Consider an economy which evolves according to the following model: (la) yt "" KfL;· (1 b) Kt (le) It-l °"' dKt-1 (ld) Li "" (l + g)L[ - 0 (l-6)KH + + 11~1 yYt l Equation (la) is a standard Cobb-Douglas aggregate production function. Since the variable Y is to be interpreted as net output, it is plausible to take a = .15 in using the model to interpret U.S. economic performance. 6 The second equation (1 b} describes the 'The standard assumption !hat a ~ .25 is simply wrong in an analysis of this type. The figure of interest is the share of net return to capital in net output. For the corporate sector, this has averaged .15 over the !ast quarter century. SU MME RS / 125 TABLE 4 The Rate of Growth of Output Under Alternative Investment Policies Years y = .045 y=.060 y = .075 y = .090 0-5 6-10 l l-20 21-30 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.10 3.11 3.09 3.07 3.20 3.22 3.17 3. 13 J.30 3.3 I 3.24 3.17 accumulation of capital in the standard way. In the calculations reported below, it is assumed that 6 = .08. Equation (le) specifies that net investment is a constant fraction (y) of net output. This figure has averaged about 4.5 percent1 over the last two decades for the U.S. non-financial corporate sector. The final equation specifies that the effective labor force grows at rate g. In the calculations below g is taken to equal .03. It is apparent the model has a steady state with a capital output ratio of 1.5, and a rate of return on capital of .10. This is quite realistic. As shown in Table 3, the pre-tax rate of return on corporate capital averaged 9.6 percent over the last decade. The 1979 capital-output ratio was 1.48. By simulating the model it is possible to examine the effects of an increase in the share of output devoted to net investment. This is done in Table 4 which shows the rate of growth of output under alternative investment policies. The limited potency of increasing investment to spur growth emerges clearly. Even a doubling of the share of output devoted to net investment would increase the economy's rate of growth by only 0.3 percent per year over the next decade. The long-run gains are even smaller. In steady state the rate of growth is independent of the investment rate. The effects of more feasible increases in the rate of investment are much smaller. Increasing the share of net investment by one-third would only raise the growth rate of productivity by about 0.1 percent per year over the next decade. This calculation has assumed that all technical change is disembodied-that is, independent of the accumulation of capital. It might be argued that instead technical progress is embodied in 'This figure is greater than those in Table I, because ii takes account of growth in land and inventories. 126 / TAX POLICY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT new capital goods, so that an increase in the rate of investment raises productivity by speeding the introduction of new technology. The model can easily be modified to take account of this possibility by allowing technical change to affect the growth of the effective capital stock rather than the effective labor force. That is, the model becomes: = (2a) Y, (2b) KEFF( = (l+g)t-lfl-1 + (l-d)KEFFt-l (2c) Kt (2d) It (2e) Li = (l+n)L1 -i KEFFfL[-" = It-I = + (l-d)K1 _1 dKt-1 + yY1-1 where g is now to be taken as the rate of embodied technical change and n the rate of population growth. For the U.S. economy it seems reasonable to take n = g = .015. The results of simulating this model for alternative values of y are displayed in Table 5. They indicate that assuming that technical change is embodied does somewhat increase the estimated potency of increased investment. Even so, a doubling of the share of output devoted to net investment only raises the productivity growth rate by .6 percent over the first decade. This calculation surely is an overstatement since at least some technical change is disembodied. The conclusion of this analysis, that even a large increase in the rate of investment will have only a minor effect on productivity, may at first seem surprising. However, it is in line with most previous research. One of the striking discoveries of the "growth accounting" literature dating from Solow (1958) has been the unimportance of capital accumulation as a factor accounting for increasing affluence. Estimates of the sources of inter-temporal and international differences in productivity, Denison (1979), have consistently found that capital intensity plays only a minor role. The major factors appear to be human capital and technological progress. It is little wonder, therefore, that increasing capital accumulation is not likely to have major effects on productivity growth. Proponents of the view that increased investment would yield large output gains frequently point to the apparently high correlation across countries between capital formation and growth. It is possible that this is because high rates of capital formation spur research, or give rise to "learning by doing" effects. If so, SUMMERS/ 127 TABLE 5 The Rate of Growth of Output Under Alternative Investment Policies with Embodied Technological Change Years y= .045 Y"" .060 ye::: .075 y :::c .090 0-5 6-10 11-20 21-30 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.21 3.14 3.10 3.06 3.40 3.25 3.16 3 .11 3.59 3.36 3.23 3.15 convent1onal analyses may underestimate the gains from increased investment. However, it seems more pfausible that causality runs the other way and high savings rates are caused by rapid technological progress. This implication flows naturally from the standard Life.Cycle Hypothesis.~ INVESTMENT AND lNFLATlON It is difficult to know how to frame the question of the effects of policies to encourage investment on the rate of inflation. The outcome of such policies obviously depends on what other concurrent policy choices are made. We begin by considering the effects of measures to encourage investment holding the rate of growth of money constant. Unless there is a change in the velocity of money, the effect of increased investment on the rate of inflation is just the negative of its impact on the growth rate of real output. The calculations in the preceding section suggest that this is likely to be only a small effect on the order of several tenths of a percentage point per year. An investment oriented tax cut is likely to raise the returns available on stocks and bonds. This will reduce the demand for money, thereby increasing velocity and tending to raise the price level. Suppose, for example, that an investment stimulus raised the yield to bond holders by one percentage point. Assuming an initial 'Two other qualifications to the analysis in this subsection should be acknowledged. First, an increase in the rate of capital accumulation will tend to increase real wages, which may spur some labor supply response giving rise to extra growth. lt is easy lo show that this effect is likely to be negligible even if a very high labor supply elasticity is assumed. Second, the gains from additional investment may be slightly underestimated because no account is taken of the advantage from replacing energy intensive with energy conserving capita!. Preliminary analysis suggests that this effect could not possibly raise the estimates reported above by more than . l percent. 128 / T A X P O L l C Y A N D C O R P O R AT E ! N V E Si M E N T interest rate of 10 percent, and an interest elasticity of money demand of only .25, the price level would have to rise by 2.5 percent beyond normal inflation to restore asset market equilibrium. This inflationary pressure is much greater than the deflationary force from increased productivity growth. Hence, the net effect of an investment oriented tax cut is likely to be an increase in the rate of inflation unless the rate of money growth is reduced at the same time. Depending on the exact formulation of wage-price dynamics it is possible to argue that increases in productivity may make it possible to bring down the rate of money growth and inflation without causing unemployment. Essentially the argument is that productivity growth is like a favorable supply shock. A one-time shock, by reducing past inflation, may moderate wage demands leading to further reductions in inflation. This argument depends on the implausible premise that workers are not able to obtain higher real wages when increased capital intensity raises their productivity. It also suggests that any measure (e.g., cutting sales taxes) which reduces prices wiU reduce long-run inflation. Hence, it does not single out increased investment incentives as the way to fight inflation. In sum, it does not appear that tax policies to spur investment are likely to reduce the rate of inflation. This proposition is true a fortiori if account is taken of their effects on aggregate demand and the government defic5t. INVESTMENT AND EMPLOYMENT There is no reason to favor investment oriented policies as a vehicle for encouraging employment. As long as labor and capital are substitmable, either within individual production activities or through shifts in the mix of production activities, it will be possible to achieve full employment with any level of capital intensity. Fears that insufficient capital accumulation must cause unemployment are as groundless as earlier concern about unemployment due to automation. Indeed, since capital and labor are substitutes in production, unless output also expands increased capital accumulation will actually reduce the level of employment. lNVESTMENT AND !NTERTEMPORAL ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY The justification for measures to increase the rate of economic growth, if such a justification exists, must lie in the area of intertemporal economic efficiency. There are two types of issues SUMMERS/ 129 involved here which I will refer to as macro- and microintertemporal efficiency. Macro-efficiency here refers to society's decision about the allocation of consumption between those alive today and future generations. The huge literature on the Ramsey optimal economic growth problem is concerned with this issue. Micro-efficiency here refers to the distortion of individual consumption plans by capital income taxation. This is the subject addressed by traditional welfare analyses of the effects of capital income taxes. INVESTMENT AND MACRO-EFFICIENCY The allocation of consumption between current and future generations inherently involves ethical choices. Even a policy of consuming the entire capital stock and leaving nothing to future generations is Pareto optimal. Hence traditional welfare economics can offer little guidance. The problem -is normally formulated on choosing a growth path to maximize the discounted value of utility subject to the constraints imposed by the production technology. That is: co (3) Max J U(ct)e-<0 ·0 nJtdt s. t. 0 C ko = f(k) (n+ g)k - k = k where c is consumption, d the discount rate, n the rate of population growth, and g is the rate of Harrod-neutral technical change. It is not difficult to show (see Solow (1970) for an intuitive exposition) that an economy which is moving along a path which solves the maximization problem given in (3) approaches a steady state path with the property that: (4) f'(k) = d+rg where £ is the elasticity of the marginal utility function. A value of = - I implies that as consumption doubles, the value of a small increase in its rate halves. With£ = - 2, the value falls by 75 percent and so forth. Equation (4) can be used to make a judgment about the efficiency of the path currently followed by the U.S. economy. The data in Table 1 suggest that the marginal product of corporate capital, f '(k), approximately equals .10. The value of g is very optimistically assumed to be .02. The parameters £ and d describing £ 130 / TAX POLICY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT how the social marginal utility of consumption changes with the level of consumption and time cannot be estimated empirically. A value of £ = - 2 implying that society is willing to take a dollar from someone with a $30,000 income in order to transfer 12 cents to someone with an income of $10,000 seems very egalitarian. This implies that current levels of investment are insufficient unless d > .06. There is little that an economist can say about the value of d. 9 However, it is difficult to see a rationale for discounting the utility of future generations at a rate nearly as high as six percent. Ramsey himself saw no argument for any discounting at all. Thus, there is an ethical argument pointing to the desirability of more capital accumulation. It might be argued that this hardly provides a warrant for government policies to spur investment. The future will be provided for by bequests from parents to their children. The level of capital intensity ground out by the free market is almost bound to be the optimal rate. Careful consideration of this line of argument suggests that there is a presumption that private capital formation will be insufficient. First, the private return to capital is far less than the social return to investment. The data in Table 2 indicate the average return to corporate capital was about 10 percent during the 1970s. The after-tax return to investors is only about one-fourth as great, creating a presumption that insufficient provision will be made for investment. Second, as long as individuals' concern for posterity extends to the children of others, there is a benefit externality from increased capital formation. Third, there is no more reason to rely on private provision for the future than there is to rely on private charity to meet current social needs. The existence of a transfer motive is hardly sufficient to establish the sufficiency of the resulting transfers. While no definitive statement can be made, the foregoing arguments suggest that macro-efficiency considerations dictate the desirability of increased corporate investment. The amount of the increase is of course more difficult to judge. INVESTMENT AND MICRO-EFFICIENCY Even if taxation has no effect on the amount of capital accumulation, it may lead to substantial welfare costs due to the distortion of individual consumption profiles. This will be true even 'Note the term gin (4) already takes account of the fact that future generations will be richer than those alive today. SUMMERS/ 131 if the overall level of capital intensity is constant at its optimal level. Feldstein (1978), Boskin (1978) and Summers (1980) all estimate annual welfare costs of capital income taxes at current levels which exceed $ 100 billion annually. Below, I illustrate how capital taxes can give rise to large welfare costs, without having an effect on capital intensity. Consider the following model. Consumers live two periods supplying labor inelastically in the first period and consuming in both periods. That is, consumers maximize: (5) a= wT where C 1 and C refer to first and second period consumption, t is the tax rate on capital income, and WT is first period income. If the utility function is Cobb-Douglas, U ::c:: QC\~«, it is easy to show that Ci = a-WT independent of the capital income tax rate. Thus the tax has no effect on the level of capital formation which is given by: (6} K = WL ~ c, The welfare cost of the tax can easily be measured. Solving the maximization problem (5) it can be shown that the indirect function is given by: (7) V(t,r,WL) = WLa-"(l-a)"(l +(l--t)r)(h,J This expression can be solved to find the change in labor income necessary to compensate the representative consumer for any given change in his tax rate on capital income. The revenue yield of the tax can then be subtracted from this expression to calculate the deadweight loss. This model is highly stylized. Nonetheless, it can prov1de some insight into the orders of magnitude of the welfare losses from capital income taxation. It is assumed that each period in the model corresponds to a generation, or 25 years. Hence, the value of a is taken to equal .5, and the pre-tax rate of return is taken to be e· 10(25 l = 12.18. These parameters imply that relative to lump sum taxation, the welfare loss from a 75 percent tax rate on capital income is 8 percent of labor income, compared to 4 percent of labor income for a 50 percent capital tax rate, and 1 percent with a 25 percent tax rate. These welfare losses are very large-a 50 percent capital income tax has a welfare loss of over $50 billion annuaHy at current 132 / T A X P O L l C Y AN D C O R P O R A TE l N V E ST M E N T levels of national income. As is to be expected, the welfare loss rises much more than proportionally with the tax rate. Cutting the tax rate by one-third from 75 percent to 50 percent reduces the deadweight loss by one-half. A further halving of the tax rate to 20 percent reduces the loss by three-quarters. Thus the marginal gains in intertemporal efficiency from cutting high capital tax rates are large. The reduction in deadweight loss equals half the revenue loss in the case of reduction in the tax rate from 75 to 50 percent. This calculation omits two important features of reality. The result may be overstated because of the assumption that lump sum taxes are available. If the alternative is the taxation of labor income, then deadweight losses may also result from this source. However, it is not at all dear that consideration of variable labor supply would reduce rather than increase the estimated welfare losses from capital taxation. Capiral taxes, by raising the price of future consumption, reduce real wages as defined by an appropriate intertempora1 cost of living index. ' 0 Hence, they also distort the labor-leisure choice. Moreover, they distort the intertemporal allocation of labor, which is not affected by a labor income tax." Feldstein (1978), without considering the latter effect, found that there are substantial net gains which can be realized from a shift towards labor taxes. Considering the intertemporat labor supply effects would strengthen this conclusion. The calculation also is carried on as if all capital were located in the corporate sector. This means the final losses from the misallocation of capital are not included. Available evidence, Fullerton, et al. (1976), suggests that these losses may not be too great. Any reduction in the tax burden on corporate capital wou1d tend to reduce the wedge between the social return to capital and investors' private return, and so would reduce the deadweight loss. The calculation presented here suggests that even if the policy did not increase capital formation there would be substantial gains in intertemporal economic efficiency. If parameter values consistent ''This crucial point is overlooked by many authors who hold that with variable labor supply, optimal tax rules are compktely indeterminable. In the plausible case of separable utility, it is optimal to place no raxes on labor income regardle,s of the elasticity of labor supply, It is easy to construct e:-:ampks in which a subsidy to capital income is optimal. "A long tradition in labor ec(rnomics dating from the work of Mincer has recognized that the intertemporal elasticity of labor supply far exceeds tbe static elasticity. S Li M M E R S / 133 with a positive effect of investment incentives on saving had been assumed the estimated welfare gains would have been much greater. These results imply that there is a substantial scope for improving economic welfare through increased incentives for investment. The next sections discuss the empirical estimation of the extent to which tax policy can increase investment. TRADITIONAL APPROACHES TO EVALUATING CORPORATE INVESTMENT INCENTIVES This section examines previous empirical evidence on the relationship between corporate investment and tax policy. The large literature on this subject is based almost entirely on single equation econometric models of the demand for equipment and structures. A detailed survey and criticism of some prominent models may be found in Chirinko and Eisner (1980). There have been relatively few efforts to examine the effects of investment stimuli within plausible general equilibrium frameworks. The efforts of this type which have taken place have been carried out using large scale econometric models which are ill-suited to questions of long-run capacity growth. The standard method of evaluating the effects of tax policy on investment follows the seminal work of Hall and Jorgenson (] 967). They begin by postulating that the desired capital stock, K*, depends on the level of output, Y, and the cost of capital, c. The cost of capital is a complex function of the interest rate and tax parameters. A general expression for it is given by q [ (l - u) (8) C = Q - !L + 6 ] q (I - u) [I - k - uz] where q is the supply price of capital goods, u is the corporate income tax rate, Q is the opportunity cost of capital, 6 is the rate of economic depreciation, k is the investment tax credit, and z is the present value of the tax depreciation expected from a dollar of investment. From this point, empirical implementations differ across studies. It is usually assumed that the rate of investment depends on some distributed lag on K. * The distributed lag is usually justified as deriving from lags in the delivery of investment goods or in the formation of expectations. The equation is then estimated econometrically. 134 / TA X P O L I C Y A N D C O R PO R A TE I N V E S T M E NT Changes in tax policy are studied by examining the effects of a tax change on the cost of capital and then of the cost of capital on investment. Chirinko and Eisner (1980) present a detailed description of how this is done in the major large scale econometric models. While there is room for substantial disagreement about the proper way to carry out this procedure, these issues are ignored here. There are several fundamental problems which make this approach an undesirable way of evaluating investment incentives. First, by holding the level of output fixed, the investment equation approach makes it impossible to capture the effects which are at the root of the case for tax policies to encourage investment. If one believed that the level of output was in fact independent of the path of investment, it is difficult to see why investment stimuli should be advocated. The essence of the way in which investment stimuli are supposed to work is by reducing the cost of capital and encouraging firms to increase investment in order to supply more output. The second fundamental difficulty with these investment functions is that they are susceptible to the "Lucas critique." There is no reason to suppose that their parameters would remain constant if policy rules were changed. Hence they cannot provide useful policy guidance. A trivial example is provided by considering the difference between a variable and a permanent tax credit. It is easy to see that a temporary credit will provoke a much greater investment response since firms will all schedule their investment to coincide with it. Hence the estimated effect of the investment tax credit (ITC) will depend on what policy rule has been followed. A related point is that conventional investment equations offer no way of considering the effects of policy announcements. Taken literally, the investment equations in all the major macro.econometric models would imply that an announcement today that six months hence the corporate income tax would be abolished would have no effect at all on current investment decisions. Nor does anything in the equations suggest how they might be modified to meet this objection. The third difficulty with traditional investment equations is that they are really adjustment equations without a theory of adjustment. The question of ultimate interest is the effect of changes in tax policy on the long run capital stock. This question can be answered simply from the production function requirement, FK = c, holding that the marginal product of capital is equated to its SUMMERS / 135 rental cost. The investment equation is essentially irrelevant. Seen in this light, it is clear that the focus of efforts to examine the effects of tax policy should be on the aggregate production function rather than the investment equation. Worse, the production functions which are implied by the results of fitting investment equations are typically wildly implausible. The only role for an investment equation is in explaining the economy's adjustment path in response to a policy shock. Yet existing econometric investment equations proxy adjustment without any explicit treatment of adjustment costs. They can hardly be interpreted as offering useful guidance on the process of convergence to equilibrium because the equilibria they imply are typically so far wide of the mark. THE ROLE OF DEMAND Previous studies all suggest that the state of business activity is a prime determinant of the level of investment. It is this evidence that has led many observers to conclude that more vigorous antirecession policies offer the greatest hope for raising the level of investment. This conclusion typically emerges from both single equation studies (e.g., Clark (1979)) and full model simulations. This finding can be traced directly to the flaws in these studies noted above. In fact, economic theories which command almost universal support among Keynesians as well as classical macroeconomists indicate that reliance on the accelerator offers no route to increased capital formation in the long run. The high correlation between output and investment which is observed in the data does not imply that a permanent increase in the level of output will permanently increase the rate of investment. As emphasized above, output and investment are simultaneously determined and in the past have moved in tandem because of common causes. Indeed the apparent potency of the accelerator reflects, in large part, the impact of investment on total output. It does not follow that the correlation would be the same if general expansionary policy was regularly used to spur investment. There is a second important argument supporting this conclusion. Many, though not all, previous investment studies fail to impose the restriction that investment depends only on the growth in output not its level. Since high output has in the past been correlated with high output growth it appears that expansion is a potent policy to stimulate investment. A policy of permanent expansion would eliminate this correlation and so would be much 136 / TA X P O L I C Y A N D CO R P O R A T E I N V E S T M E N T less effective than conventional econometric specifications suggest. The analysis so far has been partial equilibrium in character. It has suggested that there is reason to doubt that a permanent increase in GNP would have a large impact on investment. There is, however, a much more fundamental flaw in the argument for expansionary policy to spur investment. Stated baldly, the natural rate hypothesis implies that there is no such thing as "permanent expansionary policy." Any attempt to keep the level of economic output performance above some "natural" level, will lead to accelerating inflation. If we rule out policy rules which will lead to steadily increasing rates of inflation, we are confined to policies which on average keep the economy at its natural rate. Permanent expansion or contraction is not possible. What about a policy of systematically more vigorous response to recessions than has been observed in the past? While this would increase investment, it would also lead to permanently accelerating inflation, unless an equal offset was applied in boom times. Such an offset would negate any gains which might be realized in terms of investment. EVALUATING INVESTMENT INCENTIVES This section summarizes the methodology for evaluating investment incentives developed in Summers (1980), and presents some estimates of the effects of alternative tax policies on investment. The method described here is an application of Tobin's q theory of investment. It yields estimates of the effects of tax policies on the valuation of the stock market as well as on rate of investment. Below I present a heuristic account of the method. For a fuller treatment, the reader is referred to my earlier paper. METHODOLOGY For simplicity, the dynamics of investment and market valuation are examined in a simplified model where all investment is financed through retained earnings and the only tax is a proportional levy on corporate income. In this setting it is reasonable to assume that investment depends on the ratio of the market value of existing capital to its replacement cost. Unless the market value of the firm will be increased by more than one dollar by a one dollar investment, there is no reason for it to be undertaken. Given costs of adjustments and lags in recognition and implementation, there is no reason to expect that all investments which will raise market value by more than their cost will be made immediately. As Tobin SU M M E R S / 137 (1969) has argued, these considerations lead to an investment equation of the form:' 2 (9) I(Y)K K 1(1) = I'> 0 0 where I represents gross investment and V /K is the "q" ratio of market value to replacement cost. The assumption that it is 1/K which depends on q insures that the growth rate of the capital stock does not depend upon the scale of the economy. It is assumed that equity owners require a fixed real rate of return to induce them to hold the existing stock of equity. This return comes in the form of dividends, equal to after-tax profits less retentions for new investment, and capital gains. Hence we have the condition: (10) which implies: V (11) = eV - (l-r) F'(K)K + I(y K )K- dK where T is the corporate tax rate, and F(K) is the production function for net output. It will be most convenient to examine the dynamics in terms of K and q = Y. Equations (9) and (11) imply that the system's K equations of motion are: (12) (13) K q = Qq = I(q)K - dK l(q)q +d q + I(q) - (1-T)F'(K) -d where cl is the rate of depreciation. The steady state properties of the model are easily found by imposing the conditions K = 0 and q = 0. These imply: (14) (15) q = 1- 1(d) (I - r)F '(K) = eq "A rigorous foundation for an investment equation of this type is provided in Abel (1979) and Hayashi (!980). An important implicit assumption of this approach is the homogeneity of capital. If capita! is heterogeneous, shocks may reduce the market value of existing capital but raise the return on new investment. The recent energy shock illustrates this phenomenon. 138 / TAX POLICY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT The former equation indicates that the steady state value of q must be greater than 1 by an amount just large enough to induce sufficient investment to cover depreciation. The latter equation holds that firms equate their net marginal product of capital to the cost of capital. Inspection of (14) and (15) makes it clear that a change in the corporate tax rate affects the steady state capital stock but has no effect on steady state q. This is a consequence of the assumption that it is investment relative to the capital stock which varies with q. The phase diagram of the system (12) and (13) is displayed in Figure I. It is readily verified that the pair of equations is saddle point stable". The arrows indicate the direction of motion and the heavy line represents the saddle point path along which the system will converge. A change in the corporate tax rate is depicted in Figure 2' 4 • If the expectations about pre-tax profits were static, the value of q would jump from E to A when the tax change took place. This expectations assumption has been used in previous works on the effects of taxation on the stock market, e.g., Feldstein (1979), Hendershott (1979). It neglects the effect of the induced changes in investment on the present value of future profits. With perfect foresight, as assumed here, the value of q will jump only to B. The magnitude of the jump will depend upon the speed of adjustment of the capital stock to the shock. The system of equations (12) and (13) can be solved numerically to estimate the impact of any type of shock on the path of q and the capital stock. The effect of tax changes on the level of the stock market can be easily calculated. This can then provide a basis for estimating the effects of tax changes. The model actually used to calculate the effects of tax changes is considerably more complex. It takes account of the complexities of the tax code and of the fact that investment is partially financed through the issuance of debt. The results reported below are based on empirically estimated production functions and investment relations for the corporate sector. RESULTS We begin by considering the impact of the investment tax credit, since this issue has been a focus of previous work. Standard single equation approaches to the investment function have yielded "This is a common feature of models with asset prices. "It is assumed that the market selects the unique stable perfect foresight path. SU M M ER S / 139 TABLE 6 Permanent and Temporary Removal of the Investment Tax Credita bTemporary Permanent Year l 2 3 4 5 10 15 20 50 Steady State V I K V l K -2.8% -3.0IIJo -3.0% -3.3% -3.5% -4.0% -4.4% -4.7% -5.6% -6.0% -4.80/o -4.9% -6.1% -6.2% -6.4% -7.9% -8.1% -8.8% OOJo -0.4% -0.9% -1.30/o -3.5% -4.8% -6.0% -8.9% -2.0% -0.5% -0.5% -0.6% -0.6% -0.3% -0.3% 0% 0% 00/o 0% -4.9% -3.7% 00/o 0% 0% 0% -0.lOJo -0.1% -0.1% -0.4% -0.9% -0.7% -0.6% 0% 0% -0.1% -5.6% -9.6% -9.6% 0% 0% 0% -L7% Notes_. •The numbers shown in the table are the changes relative ro the 8 percent inflation path in the absence of tax reform. bThe temporary investment tax credit is imposed in year 4 for three years. divergent results. In perhaps the most widely cited study, Hall and Jorgenson (1971) conclude that the investment tax credit has a potent impact, which reaches its peak after about three years. They estimated that the 7 percent credit on equipment enacted in 1962 raised the 1970 capital stock by about 4 percent above the level it would have reached in the absence of the credit. Other estimates typically suggest much smaller estimates of the effect of the credit. None of the estimates takes explicit account of the possibly temporary nature of changes in the level of the credit. In Table 6 the effects of alternative tax credit policies are considered, The first column considers the effects of a correctly perceived permanent removal of the credit. The results indicate that the credit has potent effects on investment, even though it has only a small impact on market valuation in the short run. Its immediate effect is to reduce investment by about 6 percent, and it decreases the capital stock by 8.9 percent in the long run. The estimated response is much more gradual than that predicted by standard 140 / TAX POL [CY AND CORPORATE l NV EST MEN T investment equations. The effect on investment declines between the first and second years and then rises steadily as the reduced capital stock requires less replacement investment. Since the change considered here is the removal of a 9 percent investment credit, these results indicate a slightly larger effect than those of Hall and Jorgenson, and a much larger effect than that found in most other studies. The right half of the table considers the impact of a temporary removal of the ITC. Such a measure leads to a sharp decrease in investment during the suspension period. This leads to an increase in net investment after the suspension is removed. Gross investment does not increase because the lower capital stock requires less replacement investment. Note that the catch-up following the restoration of the credit is very slow. Two-thirds of the gap caused by the suspension in the capital stock remains 15 years later. These results show the importance of the adjustment costs, which explain investment's sluggish response to q. In the absence of any adjustment costs, one would expect to see substantial disinvestment during the period of the suspension. Because the adjustment costs of returning to the steady state capital stock would be high, this does not take place. These findings illustrate the importance of considering expected future policy. If the credit suspension were permanent its effects on net investment in the short run would be far less pronounced. The effects of reductions in the corporate tax rate are examined in Table 7. An immediate rate reduction from .48 to .40 is constrasted with an announcement that in year 4, such a tax cut will take place. Both measures are equivalent in the long run, and raise the steady state capital stock by 15. 7 percent. They increase the long-run value of the stock market significantly more because the reduced corporate tax raises the effective price of new capital goods by diminishing the value of accelerated depreciation and the expanding of adjustment costs. The simulations show that the announcement policy has a significantly greater short-run impact on investment than the immediate implementation policy. The former raises the capital stock by 3 percent after three years compared with 2 percent for the latter. This occurs even though the immediate implementation policy has a greater immediate impact on the capital stock. The reason again is the effects of accelerated depreciation and the expanding of adjustment costs. Firms find it optimal to accelerate their investment plans to take account of the lower effective price SU M M E R S / 141 TABLE 7 Unanticipated and Anticipated Permanent Corporate Tax Cut a hAnticipated Unanticipated Year V I K V 1 2 3 + 18.6% + 19.4% +20.0% +20.4% +20.7% +22.3% +23.2% +24.1% +25.9% + 7.1% + 7.2% + 8.5% + 7.3% + 8.6% + 9.0% + 10.5% + 10.8% + 14.7% 0% + 0.5% + 1.1% + 1.6% + 2.0% + 4.5% + 6.5% + 8.1% + 13.5% +15.1% + 16.9% + 19.0% +20.9% +21.2% +22.7% +23.5% +24.3% +25.9% 4 K + 9.5% + 10.8% + 12.2% + 8.5% + 8.6% + 10.3% + 10.5% + 10.8% + 14.7% + + + + + + + + 0% 0.8% 1.6% 2.5% 3.0% 5.1% 7.0% 8.6% 13.8% 5 10 15 20 50 Steady +26.7% + 15.3% + 15.3% +26.9% + 15.3% + 15.3% State Notes: asee footnote (a) in Table 6 bTax cut takes place in year 4 of capital goods which prevails before the tax reduction actually takes place. This implies that if the goal of the corporate rate reduction is to increase capital formation, the measure should be announced well in advance of its enactment. Similar considerations suggest that a temporary increase in the corporate tax rate would actually spur investment. These findings have important policy implications. They indicate that a policy of announcing a future reduction in corporate taxes will spur investment with no current revenue loss. Indeed, the effect on investment would actually be enhanced if corporate taxes were raised immediately and then cut. By combining temporary corporate rate increases with temporary increases in the investment tax credit or accelerated depreciation it would be possible to provide substantial investment stimulus at no budgetary cost. Most previous analyses of the effects of investment incentives have neglected the role of individual tax measures. The effects of reforms in the individual tax system are considered in Table 8. Eliminating capital gains taxes would raise the stock market by 7 .3 142 I TAX POL f CY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT TABLE 8 Reforms in Individual Taxesa b Anticipated Dividend Relief Capital Gains Tax Eliminated Year 2 3 4 5 10 15 20 50 Steady State V I K V I K + 7.3% + 8.1% + 8.5% + 8 .9% + 9.3% + 10.8% +12.1% + 13.2% + 16. 1% + ll.9% + 12.0% + 13.4% + 12.2% + 13.6% + 16.7% +17.1% +20.30/o +26.5% 00/o + 0.9% + 1.8% + 2.7% + 3.6% + 7.5% +11.1% + 14.0% +24.0% +60.3% +68.50/o +77.3% +86.3% +85.7% +83.7% +82.5% +82.0% +79.3% +40.50/o +47.0% +53.70/o + 6.1 OJo + 6.2% + 5.1% + 4.0% + 2.7% + 1.5% 0% + 3.2% + 6.7% +10.7% + 10.2% + 8.5% + 7.0% + 5.7% + 1.7% 0% 0% + 17.3% +27.7% +27.7% +78.6% Notes: asee footnote (a) in Table 6 bExpected abolition of the dividend tax in year 4 percent in the short run. Because it would increase the advamages to the firm of retaining earnings, the impact on investment is substantially greater. Its long-run effect would be to raise the capital stock by 29.5 percent. The transition is however very gradual with only half the adjustment occurring within the first decade. The second reform considered is an announcement that in year 4, the dividend tax will be eliminated. This corresponds to an extreme form of partial integration of the corporate income tax. As explained in Summers (I 980), changes in the dividend tax rate have no effect on steady state capital intensity. The announcement that a dividend tax reduction will occur however gives firms a very large incentive to defer paying of dividends. This is done by accelerating investment. The simulations suggest that the announcement effect raises investment by 40.5 percent. The estimates of the potential gains from reductions in taxes on capital income described here are quite robust. As explained in the previous section, the long-run results depend almost entirely on the production function. The Cobb-Douglas form which provides the SUM MER S / 143 basis for the estimates reported here is widely accepted as a reasonable aggregate approximation, The propositions that the stock market's level reflects the present value of future profits, or that investment responds positively to q are also uncontroversial. This is all that is necessary to accept these results. Taken together the results indicate the large scope for tax policy to affect capital accumulation in the long run. Politically conceivable measures, such as the abolition of capital gains taxes or the allowing of replacement cost depreciation would have a very substantial impact on long-run capital intensity. Measures can be designed which have a large impact on investment with a relatively tow cost in foregone government revenue. A final conclusion which emerges from these simulations is the dangers of indiscriminate tax cutting. The incentive effects of announced and unannounced cuts vary greatly across tax measures so that careful policy design can increase the investment stimulus per dollar of lost government revenue. THE SUPPLY OF FUNDS FOR CORPORATE INVESTMENT The analysis in this paper so far has assumed that the rate of return required by investors in the corporate sector is fixed, independent of tax policy or the level of corporate investment. As Figure 2 illustrates, this is equivalent to assuming that the supply of funds to the corporate sector is perfectly elastic, Unless this condition is met, investment incentives wiH lead to increases in the rate of return required by corporate investors. In the limiting case where the supply of funds to the corporate sector is completely inelastic, and the KS curve in Figure 1 is vertical, investment stimuli will have no effect on capital accumulation. It is therefore crucial to assess the elasticity of the supply of capital to the corporate sector. A full discussion of this issue is outside the scope of this paper, but a few remarks are sufficient to establish that the elasticity is likely to be quite high. The elasticity of the supply of savings to the corporate sector depends on both the elasticity of total savings with respect. to the rate of return and the substitutability of corporate and non-corporate assets in wealth portfolios. These issues are considered in turn. Until recently, it was widely believed that the rate of saving was largely independent of the rate of return. This notion was supported by verbal reference to conflicting income and substitution effects, and to the near constancy of the saving rate. Recently, both 144 / TAX POL l CY AND CORPORATE l NV EST MEN T FIGURE l q L 7 q =0 ------------- ------------- -K theoretical and empirical evidence have accumulated suggesting that the elasticity is quite high. The "infinite horizon" model of intertemporal consumption decisions implies that saving is perfectly elastic with respect to the interest rate. Summers (1980) shows that plausible life cycle formulations almost inevitably imply a high interest elasticity of saving. It also demonstrates that the two period model which provided the basis for most previous theoretical studies of the interest elasticity of saving is likely to be very misleading. At the same time, recent empirical evidence tends to support a positive interest elasticity of saving. Boskin {1978) was the first study to use a measure of the proper variable, the real after-tax interest rate, in a study of the interest elasticity of saving. His study found an interest elasticity of about A. There are strong reasons to believe that this is an underestimate of the elasticity of response to a permanent change in tax policy. The variations in real after-tax interest rates during Boskin's sample period are almost all transitory. As Summers (1980) shows, the response of policy to a SU M ME RS / 145 FIGURE 2 q L 7 0 q = 0 '-----------------------------K transitory shock in interest rates is likely to be much Jess than the response to a permanent shock. Of greater importance, Baskin, in calculating the interest elasticity of saving, takes no account of the wealth effects of interest rate changes. Part of the saving response to increases in interest rates occurs because of induced changes in wealth. Taking account of these effects can easily raise the estimated elasticity from .4 to 2. These considerations suggest that there are strong reasons to believe that the supply of capital to the corporate sector is highly elastic. This conclusion is strengthened by considering the allocation of capital between sectors. The U.S. corporate sector accounts for only about one-fifth of American physical wealth and a much smaller fraction of world capital. Hence even if the total supply of capital were fixed, the supply of capital to the corporate sector might be quite elastic. There is no direct evidence bearing on the extent of these effects. Summers (1981) shows how the relative valuation and accumulation of corporate and housing capital over the last decade has been affected by increased taxation. 146 / T A X P O L I C Y A N D C O R PO R A T E l N V E S T M E N T In Feldstein and Summers (1978) an attempt is made to gauge the elasticity of the supply of capital to the corporate sector. This is done by examining the effects of changes in the MPIR-the Maximum Potential Interest Rates firms can afford to pay on a given investment project-on actual interest rates. The results indicate that a one percentage point increase in the MPIR raises interest rates by .25 points. Loosely speaking, this means that 25 percent of the stimulus afforded by investment tax incentives is offset by rising asset prices. This is further evidence that investment incentives are unlikely to be crowded out by rising costs of capital. If crowding out due to a limited supply of capital appeared to be a significant factor impeding corporate investment, government policy could easily increase the supply of funds to the corporate sector. This could be done through measures to encourage saving or more plausibly through increased public saving. The latter action could be achieved by reducing budget deficits and limiting commitments to future expenditures. The analysis here of the supply of funds to the corporate sector has important implications for policy towards investment. In particular it implies that measures directed at increasing national saving will have little effect on investment. In the limiting case where saving is infinitely elastic, such measures would have no effect at all. Policies to spur investment, if they are to be effective, must be specifically directed at corporate capital. Our analysis suggests that such measures are likely to have potent effects. SUM M ER S / 147 REFERENCES Abel, Andrew. "Investment Theory: An Integrative Approach." mimeo, 1979. Blinder, Alan. Discussion of Martin Feldstein. "Tax Rules and the Mismanagement of Monetary Polley." American Economic Review, 70 (May 1980), 189-190. Boskin, MichaeL "Taxation, Saving and the Rate of Interest." Journal of Political Economy, (April, 1978). Chirinko, Robert and Robert Eisner. "The Effects of Tax Policies on Investment in Large Scale Econometric Models." Paper presented at the 4th World Congress of The Econometric Society, August 28, 1980. Denison, Edward. Accounting for Stower Economic Growth: The United States in the 1970s. Brookings Institution, 1979. Feldstein, Martin. "Investment, Inflation, and Taxes." mimeo, 1980. _ _ _ _ _ and James Poterba. "State and Local Taxes and the Rate of Return on Nonfinancial Corporate Capital." NBER Working Paper #508R, July 1980. _ _ _ _ _ and Lawrence H. Summers. "Inflation, Tax Rules, and the Long Term Interest Rate." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1978:L _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ , "Inflation and the Taxation of Capital Income in the Corporate Sector." National Tax Journal, 32 (December 1979), 445-470. Fullerton, Don, et al. "Static and Dynamic Resource Allocation Effects of Corporate and Personal Tax Integration in the U.S.: A General Equilibrium Approach." NBER Working Paper #337, AprH 1979. Hall, Robert and Dale Jorgenson. "Tax Policy and Investment Behavior." American Economic Review, 57 {June 1967), 391-414. Hayashi, Fumio. "The q Theory of Investment: A Neo-Classical Interpretation.'' Econometrica. 148 / TAX POL l CY AN[) CORPORATE INV [ST MEN T Norsworthy, J.R., Michael Harper, and Kent Kunze. "The Slowdown in Productivity Growth: Analysis of Some Contributing Factors." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1979:2, 387-421. Solow, R.M. Growth Theory, Oxford University Press, 1970. Summers, Lawrence H. "Taxation and Capital Accumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model." American Economic Review, forthcoming. (1981). ______ . "Inflation, Taxation and Corporate Investment." mimeo, 1980. Tobin, James. "A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory." Journal of Money Credit and Banking, I (1969), 15-29. Estimates of Investment Functions and Some Implications for Productivity Growth PATRICH. HENDERSHOTT My original assignment was first to evaluate Larry Summers' paper as a description of the current state of the art regarding investment behavior and second to determine the adequacy of the investment sector of Michael Evans' econometric model (Evans, 1980) in light of Summers' paper. The late arrival of Larry's paper forced me to alter my strategy, and it is just as well. Summers' investment function is a very long-run relationship that does not purport to explain cyclical movements in business investment outlays, while Evans' relationship is a more traditional analysis of quarterly expenditures. 1• Moreover, Summers is concerned with only corporate investment, while Evans deals with all of domestic fixed investment. My revised strategy was to employ two papers recently presented at Brookings Conferences (Hendershott, 1980, and Hendershott and Hu, 1981) as the standard with which to contrast Evans' work. The first two sections of the present paper are concerned with nonresidential and residential fixed capital outlays, respectively. In each of these I first summarize my earlier work and then critique Evans' treatment of the same investment component. A general discussion of the relationship between the form of investment and productivity growth is the subject of the third section, and a Patric H. Hendershott is Professor of Economics and Finance, Purdue University. The author gratefully acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation under grant DAR-8016064 and the National Bureau of Economic Research for his work in the broad area of capital formation. ;Summers' equations explaining the annual ratio of gross real investment to the beginning period capital ,wck over the 1932-78 period have R' that range from 0.05 (no autocorrelation correction) to 0.75 (Summers, 1980, Table 2, p. 34). Of course, investment equations must have plausible long-run properties if they are to be useful in examining the long-run impacts of tax changes, but this does not rule out relationships that also explain cyclical behavior. 149 150 / l N VE S T M E N T F U N CT I O N S summary concludes the paper. Summers' imaginative work is referred to periodically when it bears on the issue at hand, but time and space constraints prevent me from discussing his analysis at length. NONRESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT GENERAL DETERMINANTS Investment outlays (or orders) can be thought of as the sum of four components: Those due to normal growth, to disequilibrium, to replacement, and to mandates of governments. The general determinants of each of these parts are the following:; Normal Growth (In): Normal growth in the economy requires greater production capacity. How capital intensive this is should depend on the real user cost of capital (c). Thus one can write where y represents any of a variety of variables that proxy for the expected growth rate in real output, and the expected signs of the partial derivatives are indicated above the arguments in the function. I emphasize here that the relationship is between net investment and the rate of change in output, not the level of output. As Summers (1981) and others have noted, the latter is a major misspecification of an investment function and has nonsensical macroeconomic policy implications. Disequilibrium (Id): Disequilibrium investment (positive or negative) arises when factor prices or aggregate demand change unexpectedly. Proxies often employed to represent disequilibrium are deviations between current and long run or "normal" values of Tobin's Q (the ratio of the market value of corporate debt and equity to the replacement cost of nonfinancial assets) and capacity utilization (CU). Thus Id = + + Id(Q-Q*, CU-CU*), where * denotes normal or long-run values (assumed to be constant). 'This analysis assumes a CES production function. The use of a variable elasticity function, such as the translog (see Berndt and Christensen, 1973), requires inclusion of either the user costs or quantities of other factors in the estimation equation. HEN D E RS H OTT I 151 Replacement (1,): In a pure putty-putty world where changes in the capital/labor ratio can occur both before and after the installation of capital, replacement investment is reasonably approximated by the product of the depreciation rate and the existing capital stock. But in a putty-clay world, where variable factor portions exist only for net investment and upon replacement of old capital, replacement investment also depends on changes in the real user cost since the capital being replaced was initially instaHed. More specifically, one can write 00 Ir L Yr(c_.Jc) = K-,6 T=0 where Yr equals LO for r "" 0 and 0.0 otherwise, if technology is putty-putty, or equals the fraction of each vintage of capital in the total existing stock, if technology is putty-day, and the symbol or denotes the optimal feasible replacement investment fraction/ Mandated investment Om): This investment is mandated by law and is thus reasonably treated as exogeneous. Combining the four investment (orders) components into a single function, + - + + (J) I "" HY, C' Q, CU) + ofK-, + Im. Our empirical results suggest the following. First, the user cost variable, which affects both t and Jf, is a fundamental factor affecting investment.' Second, the accelerator variable, y, works as expected. And third, the capacity utilization rate, but not Q, is an important determinant of disequilibrium investment. REAL USER COST OF CAPITAL Consider the following assumptions/ definitions: i) aU prices are expected to rise at rate rr forever, ii) the productivity of an investment declines at rated over an infinite holding period, 1 Putty~clay technology is a possible source of long lags in investment functions, bu! it is still diffkult to explain Summers' 16 year adjustment period to obiain half of the impact of an inflation shock (1980, Tab[e 4, p. 45). 'With d = 0.!3, Jf varies from a low ofO.! !5 in 1957:1 to a high of0.156 in 1971:4. Replacement of JK .. , with dfK -, in the estimated equation significantly raised the explanatory power. 152 / l N V E ST M E NT F U N CT I O N S iii) the statuatory income tax rate isµ, iv) the rate of investment tax credit is k, v) the present value of depreciation allowed for tax purposes on a dollar of capital is z, vi) pollution control outlays of 4' dollars are required for every dollar of capital investment, vii) the ratio of inventories based on FIFO accounting to the stock of capital is 11, and viii) the real after-tax financing rate is r. With these assumptions, one can derive the real user cost of capital as (2) C (1 +tp)q (1-µ)p[(l-k-µz) (r+cl) + µvn}, 00 where z "" L t""' l the tax q "" the p ""' the dxr (l+r+rr)l fraction of the capital price allowed to be treated as depreciation in period t, price of capital goods, and general price of output. This equation is identical, in appearance, to equation (4.2), p. 4,15 of Evans except for the addition of the inventory term to allow for the taxation of FIFO-based inventory profits. Assuming that a portion a of investment [(1-k)q] is debt financed, the debt and equity portions are expected to remain constant forever, and debt finance charges are deductible from the income tax base, (3) where i is the nominal debt yield and ea is the nominal after-tax cost of equity funds. A plausible proxy for e8 is the sum of the after-tax earnings-price ratio (E/P) and n/(l - a). The division by l - a reflects the fact that all inflation gains accrue to shareholders (except those indirectly built into i). Substitution into (3), 5 (3) I r "" a(l -µ)i + (l -a)E/P. 'This equation looks like an analogue to the Modigliani-Cohn stock market error: it appears that a nominal debt yield is being averaged with a real equity yield. ln faet, the expression is an average of two real yields (I -µ)i- rr and E/P + [a/{l -a)]n. The rr terms cancel when the expression is simplified. H E N D E R S H O TT / 153 EVANS' ANALYSIS The aggregate investment equations reported account for the normal growth and disequilibrium investment components in a reasonable fashion. A variety of sectoral income variables drive investment; the user cost variable generally performs as expected (more on this below); and the capacity utilization rate, the unemployment rate and stock prices all appear as disequilibrium proxies. The putty-clay optimal feasible replacement investment fraction does not appear, but the establishment of its relevance is of recent "vintage." However, I cannot even find the lagged capital stock in the equations, although it is referred to in the text. Even more disconcerting is the absence of mandated investment outlays. The importance of these outlays is emphasized by Evans and these outlays are incorporated in the calculation of the user cost, but the actual outlays are ignored in the estimation. To put these outlays in perspective, during the I 972-78 period they were roughly 4 percent of total new orders for equipment and 12 percent of net new orders (roughly t~o-thirds of orders were for replacement). One final point on these equations. An undefined index of credit rationing appears in the equipment equation with rationing (supposedly a slowdown in deposit flows) reducing equipment outlays. While outlays on trucks and autos (p. 4.67) may be reduced, as are housing starts (see below), it would seem to me that outlays somewhere in the economy should be stimulated. That is, if accelerated flows into open market paper, defined broadly to include large CDs and money market funds, are detrimental to outlays financed by regular deposits, then these flows ought to be favorable to the outlays financed by open market paper; rationing ought to have an allocative, zero-sum impact rather than a cumulative negative impact. Finally, if rationing matters for business investment, then business cash flows obviously matter to investment, a fact Evans denies on p. 4.10. Evans spends a great deal of time and effort in the construction of user costs of capital for business investments. For this he is to be commended. Unfortunately, there appears to be a number of errors in the calculations. First, consider the measurement of the real after-tax financing rate. In the aggregate investment equations (pp. 4.70 and 4.76), the yield is r = 0.4 i + 0.6 E/P. Note that the interest rate is before-tax when it should be after-tax." 'In the industry studies (pp. 4.19 and 4.42), the dividend-price ratio replaces E/P, and the 0.4 and 0.6 weights may have been switched. 154 / l N V E ST M E N T FUN CT ION S Also, there does not appear to have been any attempt to adjust earnings for the overstatement due to historic cost depreciation. Thus the real after-tax financing rate is clearly overstated by a significant amount. Second, depreciation rates of 0.095 (structures) and 0.181 (equipment) have been employed. These, too, are far too high (by about 0.05). Third, the effective (average) rather than statuatory (marginal) corporate tax rate is utilized. To the extent that the vagaries of the tax code are already accounted for-the investment tax credit, tax depreciation, and FIFO accounting-the statuatory rate is clearly the appropriate variable. Just as important, the average tax rate moves cyclically, being high when profits are great and low when profits are small, but the expected tax rate over the life of the investment, the relevant rate in the user cost calculation, is unlikely to move in this manner. This illustrates an important point about the user cost expression (2). All values in it denote expected values over the life of the investment asset. If these values are expected to change in the short run, then such expectations could have a large impact on the timing of orders or investments, even if only the long-run expected values affect Jongrun capital accumulation. To illustrate, a temporary increase in the investment tax credit would have a far larger short-run stimulative impact on investment (Lucas, 1976, pp. 30-35) than would a "permanent" increase. 7 Further, as Summers illustrates ( 1981) anticipations of tax changes can have major, and even surprising, effects. In summary, the Evans model has not advanced econometric modeling of nonresidential investment. Replacement and mandated investment are not accounted for, and there are significant errors in the calculation of the important user cost variable. Moreover, the measurement and inclusion of z in the user cost is hardly innovative, as is suggested on p. 4.16. This variable was included in early Jorgensonian formulations and has been part of the data bank for the various versions of the Federal Reserve econometric model for at least a decade. RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT AN OVERVIEW OF THE HOUSING MARKET My view of the determination of increments to the real housing stock is depicted in Figure 1. The major financial variables are circled: the mortgage payment constraint (roughly the product of the nominal after-tax mortgage rate and the real price of "Evans sta,es the opposite on p. 4.13. FIGURE lI Detennination of Chang~s Changes in the Housing Stock Determination Stock Mortgage Payment Constraint Interest Rates Tax Law Productivity of the Construction Sector Finanda! Structure Number of Real User Costs Credit Availability Tenure Choice: Buy vs. Rent Starts; Single vs. Multiple X Average Quality Per S!art Rea! value Value Real of Starts Real Change in Real Housing Stock Housing 156 / l N VE S T M E N T F U N C T I O NS structures), the user costs of capital for owner-occupied and rental housing (the former is approximately the product of the real aftertax mortgage rate and the real price of structures), and credit availability. (An inflation-induced increase in the mortgage payment constraint will limit the size of house purchases if imperfections in the capita! market prevent households from borrowing against future housing capital gains.) These variables depend on those in the box on the left: the level of interest rates, tax law, the financial structure, and the relative productivity of the construction sector (which determines the real price of structures). The three doublelined boxes represent the important economic decisions. Tenure choice depends on the rental price (user cost) of housing services generated by an owner-occupied dwelling versus that of services produced by a rental unit. This choice, along with total household formations and credit availability, determines the numbers of single and multifamily starts. The average quality (square feet, number of fireplaces, etc., valued in constant dollars) per start, in turn, is a function of real income per household and "prices," both the real user cost (user cost divided by the price of non-housing goods) and the real mortgage payment constraint. The product of the number of starts and their average quality is the real value of starts, and this is converted to real housing outlays or the change in the real housing stock with a short production lag, Implicit equations for single (SST) and multifamily (MST) starts and explicit equations for the average real qualities of single (SQ) and multifamily (MQ) starts are + + SST = 4s(hHH, b(c/r), AVAIL) MST = 4rn(AHH, A(c/r), AVAIL) SQ MQ = iµs( + + + + - y, c, m) + = t/!in( y, r), where HH is the number of households, c and r are the real user costs for owning and renting, AVAIL represents credit availability, y is real income per household, m is the mortgage payment variable, and the signs of the partial derivatives are indicated above the variables. Significant lags exist, particularly with regard to the tenure decision. H E N DE R S H O TT / 157 The above starts equations are consistent with a world in which prices of new housing units are a mark-up on costs and builders determine starts so as to equate the expected future supply and demand for incremental units. An alternative view, which I label the pure supply view, has the price of new units determined by the supply and demand for existing units and has builders responding to profit opportunities, as well as the availability of credit: ST = + + fp{Ph/p, Cost/p, AVAIL), where Phip is the real price of housing and Cost/p is the real cost of production. THE EVANS MODEL Starts equations appear in the Evans investment chapter, but average quality equations do not. Multiplication of starts by a housing price translates starts into nominal dollars, and a production lag converts these into nominal outlays on housing. How or whether real outlays are determined is unclear. Thus, my discussion relates only to the behavior of starts.• It is difficult to fit the Evans starts equations into either of the above frameworks. The equations are of the forms + ~ + + SST = 4c,(Y, m, rt1i, AVAIL) + + + MST = f, (y, RENT INT + RENT 'AVAIL, OVER), cm COST , WAGES where the signs over the variables are the signs of the estimated coefficients, rrh is the housing inflation rate, RENT /COST is a profitability measure, (INT + RENT)/WAGES is the ratio of NIA interest and rent income to wage income, and OVER is a measure of overbuilding (the cumulated difference since 1970 between 600 thousand and actual annual starts). The first equation has no cost variables and looks more like an average quality rather than number of starts equation. The inflation and mortgage payment 'One exception. It is stated that "most recent estimates indicate that the (income) elasticity (of housing) is now closer to L5 [than unity]" (p. 4.94). My estimate is 0.68 and those of the micro studies I have seen are only slightly higher. Possibly the studies referred to (not cited} intermingle the income and price effects. The price (user cost} is lower for households with higher incomes {in higher tax brackets}. If the income variable captures this price effect, then a higher elasticity would be estimated. 158 / 1 N V E S T M E N T F U N C T I O N S variables could be reflecting tenure choice, and the rise in income over time, too, likely reflects the shift towards home ownership, although there is no reason why higher income per se should increase ownership. Unfortunately, this would suggest that income should enter the multifamily equation with a negative sign. The multifamily equation also includes a profit variable, a factor share variable, and a measure of overbuilding consistent with desired starts over time being a constant 600 thousand and thus independent of any economic considerations. That is, the equation appears to include most any variable that "worked." Because Evans' credit availability index is undefined, discussion of its plausibility is impossible. However, the impact of the change in FHLB advances, another availability proxy employed, is subject to interpretation. This variable reflects what appears to be a common problem with econometric models of housing: availability of funds variables work far too well. During the 1976- 79 period, only 23 percent of savings and loan loans closed, net of refinancings, were used to finance new construction of dwelling units. Yet the coefficients on the advances variables in the starts equations suggest that a billion dollars of advances would generate $2 billion in nnv construction.• A quite careful specification of starts equations is needed to prevent a vast overstatement of availability effects. My own estimates are that a billion dollars of deposits generates only $0.3 l billion of 1-4 family housing, and even this seems to be too large an effect. Regrettably, the residential investment sector of the Evans model is no improvement on poorly formulated existing models. SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOM[CS AND THE PRODUCTIVITY OF CAPITAL Supply-side economics is concerned with increasing economic growth and thus the size of the economic pie. This can be achieved by increasing either the level of effort (more manhours ,vorked) or the quality of a given level (more output per manhour). One way of increasing productivity is to increase capital per worker, and this is most directly achieved by raising the saving rate. Thus the most important supply-side economic issues are the sensitivities of labor supply to real after-tax wage rates and of saving to real after-tax interest rates. Because neither of these topics relates to investment, it is fortunate that other means of raising productivity exist, In ''Somewhat similarly, Jaffee and Rosen, 1979. and Poterba, 1980, report that an additional billion dollars of thrift d~ro,it, would kad to $1.5 billion in construction, H EN D E R S H O TT / 159 order to focus on such means, I assume in what follows that labor supply and saving, respectively, are independent of wage and interest rates. Economic policy can affect economic growth in such a world via two routes. First, an increase in government saving that is not accompanied by an equal decrease in government investment or private saving will increase the capital stock. A reduction in government "consumption" outlays would reduce government borrowing and thus real interest rates, thereby stimulating investment. Alternatively, an increase in taxes on private consumption outlays would accomplish the same objective. Second, a reallocation of investment from less to more productive uses will raise the productivity of a given total stock of capital. There are two general means of channeling investment into more productive uses. There has been a surge in explicitly mandated investments in the last decade, some of which have been of questionable value. The massive retrofitting of transportation networks to allow access of the handicapped comes to mind. Similarly, government regulations implicitly require overinvestment in some areas. For example, our trucking fleet is larger than it need be owing to "gateway" requirements whereby trucks are forced to make empty return trips on suboptimal routes. A reduction in explicit and implicit mandated investments would free resources for more productive uses. A second means of improving the productivity of capital is to reduce the relative subsidy extended to owner-occupied housing. The user cost of capital for owner occupied housing tends to be low because neither the implicit rents from the unit nor the capital gain earned is taxed. Moreover, this user cost has declined in response to increases in anticipated inflation because real after-tax debt yields have fallen. Estimates of real user costs for owner-occupied housing and corporate structures in 1964 and 1978 are listed in Table L The 1964 data illustrate the relationships among user costs in a noninflationary period. The costs for housing are lower because of its preferred tax treatment, and the costs are lowest for those in the highest tax brackets. The 1978 data reflect the decline in real aftertax debt yields; the decline is largest for those in the highest tax brackets. The fall in the user costs for owner-occupied housing would have been greater but for a sharp rise in the real price of structures. Referring back to equation (2), the near doubling of the user cost for corporate structures reflects: l) a decline in z, the present value of tax depreciation, owing to the use of historic cost 160 / I N V E ST M E N T F U N CT l O N S TABLE l Real User Costs of Capital, 1964 and 1978 (Percent) 1964 Owner-Occupied Housing: 15 Percent Tax Bracket 30 Percent Tax Bracket 45 Percent Tax Bracket Corporate Structures 1978 9 5 8 7 15 2 0 27 Sources: Owner-occupied Housing, Hendershott and Hu, 1981a. Corporate Structures, Hendershott and Hu, 1981b. depreciation, 2) an increase in taxes paid on inventory profits, and 3) a rise in the real price of structures (q/p). Also, the real aftertax financing rate for structures has not fallen because the heavilyweighted equity yield component has risen by enough to offset the decline in the real after-tax debt yield. Given this movement in user costs, the surge in the levels of sales and production of singlefamily housing in the second half of the 1970s and the sluggishness of investment in nonresidential structures are hardly surprising. America is now investing resources in housing that has a net (or depreciation) marginal product of near zero and foregoing the construction of corporate structures that have a net marginal product of over 20 percent. The relative subsidy for owner-occupied housing and the resultant misallocation of capital can be reduced through a variety of methods. Most obviously, implicit rents and housing capital gains could be taxed. Not only does this appear politically infeasible, but the taxation of largely nominal capital gains has little appeal on equity grounds. Alternatively, a wide range of business tax cuts could be employed to offset the subsidy to owner-occupied housing: these include a switch to replacement cost depreciation, expanded investment tax credits, a reduction in the double taxation of corporate dividends and a general cut in the corporate income tax rate. The investment stimulated by these cuts would drive up real interest rates, thereby rechannelling resources from housing to nonresidential investments.'° Feldstein, 1980, has generalized this argument by calling for a switch from an easy-money /tight-fiscal "'See Hendershott and Hu, !980, for an analysis of the impact of these tax cuts on ,he user costs for business investments and owner-occupied housing. H EN DE RS H OTT / 161 policy mix, in which real after-tax mortgage rates are negative and the taxation of capital income is great, to a tight-monetary I easyfiscal policy mix, in which the reverse is true. My own favorite method of reducing overinvestment in owneroccupied housing is a large, say $12,000, exemption of interest and dividends from taxation, subject to the netting of personal (largely mortgage) interest expense. To illustrate, consider two households, each with $12,000 in interest income but one with a mortgage entailing an annual interest expense of $9,000 and the other with no mortgage and thus no interest expense. The former household would pay taxes on $9,000 of interest income (only $3,000 = $12,000 - $9,000 would be exempt), while the latter would pay no tax on interest income. This would reduce both the relative tax advantage to owner-occupied housing and the inequitable current taxation of largely nominal interest income. In effect, a tax break (cessation of taxation of nominal interest) would be extended to those not leveraging investment in owner-occupied housing. Finally, we should discourage any further subsidies to housing such as the use of tax-exempt financing (mortgage revenue bonds). SUMMARY It is not clear that the new emphasis on supply-side economics has implications for major revisions in the form of business investment equations. There is, of course, a need to account carefully for the interaction between inflation and taxes and to incorporate mandated investment outlays into the analysis. But existing models either already do this or can be easily adapted. Possibly as a result, the equations in Evans' model do not appear to be particularly innovative. Moreover, there seem to be some errors in the calculation of user costs, and replacement and mandated investment outlays are overlooked. The residential construction equations in existing models are not in as good shape as the nonresidential investment equations. The major problems are a failure to measure user costs as carefully as is done for the business sector, and a tendency to attribute far greater impact to credit availability than is remotely plausible. Unfortunately, the equations in Evans' model do not appear to address these problems in a useful manner. While the new supply-side emphasis should not be expected to alter greatly the form of investment equations, hopefully its emphasis on supply constraints will alter the type of policy 162 / I N V E S T M E N T F U N CT I O N S simulations run with the models. Too often in the past, simulations of policy actions or legislation designed to encourage a specific type of capital outlay have been run in the context of a world with unlimited resources or infinite supplies. The result implied by such simulations is, not surprisingly, an increase in not only the targeted capital good but in all capital and consumption goods. In such a world, any capital-specific policy should be pursued. In the real world, resources are limited. Even in the intermediate run, the only policies that should be analyzed are those designed to have zero aggregate demand impact. For example, a specific tax cut should be accompanied by other tax increases, expenditure cuts, or higher real interest rates (a more restrictive monetary policy). 11 Of course, if the policies are well-designed, then productivity and thus the total size of the economic pie, will increase. As Summers emphasizes (1981), however, significant quantities of these aggregate benefits will not be achieved quickly. "For discussion of the issue, raised in this paragraph, sec Hendershott, !980. H E N D E R S H OTT / 163 REFERENCES Berndt, Ernst R. and Laurits R. Christensen. "The Translog Function and the Substitution of Equipment, Structures, and Labor in U.S. Manufacturing, 1929-68." Journal of Econometrics, 1 (1973), pp. 81-114. Evans, Michael K. "Supply-Side Model." Evans Economics, Inc., mimeo, 1980. Feldstein, Martin. "Tax Rules and the Mismanagement of Monetary Policy." American Economic Re1Jiew, 70 (May 1980), 182-86. Hendershott, Patric H. "Analysis of the Impact of Capital Specific Policies or Legislation: Application to Reforms of the TaxExempt Market." Journal of Money Credit and Banking, (May 1980), 377-99. ~~--· "Real User Costs and the Demand for Single Family Housing." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: I 980. Hendershott, Patric H. and Sheng Hu. "Inflation and Extraordinary Returns on Owner-Occupied Housing: Some Implications for Capital Allocation and Productivity Growth." Journal of Macroeconomics, forthcoming (Spring 1981). ~~~~· "Investment in Producer's Equipment." ln Aaron and Pechman, eds., How Taxes Affect Economic Behavior. Washington: Brookings Institution, 1981. ____ . "The Relative Impacts of Various Proposals to Stimulate Business Investment." In von Furstenberg, ed., The Government and Capital Formation, Ballinger Publishing Co., 1980, 321-36. Jaffee, Dwight M. and Kenneth T. Rosen. "Mortgage Credit Availability and Residential Construction." Brookings Papers on Economic Acfivity, 2: 1979, 333- 76. Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique." The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, North Holland, 1976. Poterba, J. "Inflation, Income Taxes, and Owner-Occupied Housing." NBER Working Paper No. 553, September 1980. Summers, Lawrence H. "Inflation, Taxation and Corporate Investment." mimeo, I 980. ____ . "Tax Policy and Corporate Investment." In this volume. Discussion of the Summers Paper NORMAN B. TURE I believe that the term "supply-side economics" is a misnomer. The analytical system going under this name really consists of nothing new or fancy but merely the application of price theory to public policies concerned with major economic aggregates. This analytical approach and the public policies developed therewith do not focus particularly on supply conditions to the exclusion of effects of policy on aggregate demand. The distinguishing attribute of "supply-side" economics, and the principal issue it casts up, rather, is that it identifies the initial impact of public policies and actions in terms of alterations in (implicit or explicit) relative prices instead of changes in income. One of the principal consequences of this distinction is that if one wants to model economic responses to public policy actions in the supply-side context, one must make very certain that the behavioral functions in one's model preclude identification of first-order income effects of government actions. The mere addition of supply equations to a standard "aggregate demand" model does not convert that model into a supply-side model. The implications for policy of assigning first-order price effects to government actions and of rejecting the possibility of first-order income effects of such actions are enormous, but not because public policies guided by supply-side economics focus exclusively or primarily on aggregate supply conditions or because such policies primarily affect supply conditions. Rather, it is because supply-side economics dictates different policy strategies and tactics from those which have long been pursued and looks to results which differ in character and magnitude from those urged by the Keynesian aggregate demand approach. While Summers does not provide an explicit supply-side context Norman B. Ture was President, Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation, Washington, D.C., when this speech was presented. He is currently Under Secretary of the Treasury for tax and economic affairs. 166 / S t.: M M E R S D I S C U S S I O N for his discussion, his paper is very much in that spirit. Summers' provocative paper presents a wide-ranging discussion, each of the topics of which itself deserves and would make an interesting paper. I shall comment briefly on several of these, reserving more extended comments for two of his topics. Summers first turns his attention to the postwar trends in net capital formation in the non financial corporate sector. He shows that the decline during the last half of the 1970s in the rate of net investment (other than for pollution control facilities) and in such investment in relation to gross corporate product is associated with a decline in the real net rate of return. This, in turn, more reflects increases in the effective rate of tax on corporate earnings than decreases in the pre-tax rate of return. The increase in the tax rate, in turn, is attributable to inflation. Accordingly, Summers concludes that the interaction of the tax system and inflation accounts for the l 970s investment showdown. I take no issue with this conclusion or more generally with the proposition that tax factors materially influence the pace and volume of capital formation. The question is why the acceleration of capital formation is important. Summers properly identifies the popular concern with the adequacy of investment in terms of effects on productivity, inflation, and unemployment. He finds, however, that changing the rate of investment is unlikely to have a significant effect on the rate of growth over the next decade, that increasing investment is likely to accentuate inflation, and that there is no reason to seek to promote investment as a means of encouraging employment. With each of these conclusions and Summers' means of arriving at them, strong issue is to be taken. First, Summers' finding that increasing investment has an extremely limited potential for increasing growth in output is derived from a model the specification inadequacies of which include a labor supply function unrelated to anything but the passage of time and a capital supply function devoid of any behavioral arguments. Associated with this is an investment function specifying net investment as a constant function of net output. Summers' model is not useful for dealing with the question whether increasing investment implies significant gains in output and employment and decreases in the inflation rate. Nor can the model be treated as representing reality. Indeed, as specified, it serves no purpose other than to illustrate a proposition which needs no illustration, viz., if the elasticity of output with respect to a TUR E / 167 production input is very small, large increases in the amount of that input will result in relatively small increases in output. By the way, even in this unrealistically limited context, the effect on the growth rate of increasing the share of output allocated to investment is substantially more impressive than Summers' exposition would lead one to believe. He finds, for example, that doubling the share of output allocated to investment would increase the growth rate "by only 0.3 percent per year over the next decade." But this is more correctly read "0.3 percentage points" and amounts to a JO percent gain in the growth rate. A model correctly specified to analyze the effects of a change in the rate of capital formation on growth of output will show how the initial change in the capital: labor ratio increases the marginal value productivity, i.e., real wage rate, of labor, and the consequent increase in both the demand for and supply of labor services. These increases in labor inputs, along with the initial gain in capital inputs, result in gains in output of significantly larger magnitude than Summers estimates. Moreover, the second-order income effects of the output gains also generate an increase in the optimum stock of capital, hence a further expansion of capital inputs. Summers' line of analysis leads him to conclude that "Fears that insufficient capital accumulation must cause unemployment are as groundless as earlier concern about unemployment due to automation." This conclusion is, of course, dead wrong. It is arrived at by way of a mechanistic observation that since production inputs are substitutable it is possible to have some given amount of labor employed with virtually any given amount of capital. All this statement amounts to is that one can conceive production functions with any combination of exponent values one wishes. It is this analytically useless observation that leads to Summers' next assertion that increasing capital will decrease labor unless there is an increase in output. This is, of course, precisely the fear about the consequences of automation which Summers dismisses as groundless. Aside from being inconsistent, Summers is wrong. Other things equal (i.e., the pertinent demographics, the state of technology, the basic conditions of factor supplies, etc.), the only way to increase employment is by increasing labor's productivity which requires, unless the laws of production have been repealed, an increase in the capital: labor ratio. Indeed, the basic criterion for assessing the sufficiency or insufficiency of capital accumulation is whether it affords an increase in the capital: 168 / SUMME RS D l SC U SSIO N labor ratio sufficient to maintain an acceptable rate of gain in productivity, real wage rates, and employment. One of Summer's most startling conclusions is that if the rate of growth of the money stock is held constant, investment-oriented tax changes which increase investment, hence, one must presume, increase total output above levels otherwise attained, will result in an increase in the inflation rate. This conclusion derives from misspecification of the direct effects of the tax change and of the responses thereto. The correct specification is that the tax change reduces the real supply price for any given amount of capital, the response to which is a shift in the use of current income from consumption toward saving. Insofar as the reduction in real capital supply price is reflected instantaneously in an increase in the returns on stocks and bonds, this entails no shift from money to securities, as Summers claims, but from purchase of consumption goods and services to purchases of claims on capital assets. Nothing in this response mechanism necessarily pertains to any change in velocity. All that is left as a source of effect on the price level, therefore, is the effect of larger stocks of capital and the consequent increases in labor inputs on total output. As Summers correctly notes-but denies-" ... the effect of increased investment on the rate of inflation is just the negative of its impact on the growth rate of real output.'' To summarize to this point, on the score of the effects of increasing the stock of capital on output, employment, and the price level, Summers negative conclusions are derived from misspecification. While certainly not dismissing the welfare gains which Summers believes are the real payoff from increased investment, I think he grossly underestimates the gains in output, hence employment, which would result from increased investment in response to reducing the existing tax bias against saving and capital formation. Summers' discussion of how tax "incentives" affect investment behavior-the last three sections of his paper-are more useful. He is quite right in criticizing the treatment embodied in the standard large-scale econometric models. For the most part, these models depend on a capital stock adjustment formulation but take a nothink approach to the adjustment process. Yet as Summers himself points out, the lack of theory to explain the pace of adjustment from one optimum stock of capital to another is not, itself, a fatal flaw in analyzing the effects of tax changes on the economic TURE / 169 aggregates. To be sure, it impairs the usefulness of these models for forecasting purposes but the social welfare is little diminished by any such model imperfections. More to the point is whether these or any other models are so specified as to capture correctly the effects of tax "incentives" on the desired stock of capital. The relevant formulation for this purpose proceeds, as Summers notes, from the specification of the production function, from which the schedule of the marginal product of capital is derived. This is the capital "demand" function, obviously unaffected initially by any tax change, since it is not a behavioral function. The capital supply function is the schedule showing the amounts of capital individuals wish to hold at varying net, real rates of return, given the level of total income. With taxes of the character the U. S. relies upon, market or pre-tax rates of return required for each quantity of capital must, obviously, exceed the net or after-tax rates. It is the intersection of the downward sloping marginal product and upward sloping supply schedules which determine the optimum stock of capital. Clearly, changes in tax provisions affect this optimum by altering the capital supply schedule in pre-tax terms. A tax change per se can have no initial effect on the marginal product of capital. Nor has it any initial first-order income effect to alter the supply of capital. It affects only the pretax returns required to obtain the after-tax return at which a given amount of capital will be held. I belabor you with this simple exposition only to emphasize that the effect of a tax change on investment derives solely from the way in which taxes affect the supply of capital, hence saving behavior. With no change in the tax regime and other things given (i.e., the rate of technical progress, the condition of labor supply, etc.), saving= investment will increase with the increase in total income, hence the increase in the desired stock of capital, through time. Given the level of income, however, a change in taxes affecting the rental cost of capital generates a new optimum stock of capital at that total income level. It consequently impels a change in the amount of saving out of that total income, hence a change in consumption, as people seek to shift to the new desired stock of capital. It is, therefore, only through its effects on saving that tax changes can alter the stock of capital. For purpose of analyzing the ultimate effect of tax changes on the stock of capital, nothing more is needed. For purposes of estimating the effects of tax changes on saving= investing, i.e., the 170 / SUMMERS DISCUSS l ON adjustment from one optimum stock to another, far more is needed, specifically theory and data to explain the pace of the adjustment. The search for this explanation is complicated by virtue of the fact that few, if any, feasible tax changes will affect the desired stock of each component of the total stock of capital in the same proportion. Virtually all such tax changes will result in some change in the composition of the capital stock. The time required to effectuate that change will differ from one type of capital to another; it takes a good deal longer, ordinarily, to build a petroleum refinery than to manufacture a new machine tool. Searching the data for stable saving functions, therefore, is chasing a will o' the wisp. But instability in the saving function does not imply instability or shifting parametric values in the desired stock of a capital function. Accordingly, there is no real problem rising from changes in policy rules, of the sort Summers suggests, in the use of a properly specified cost of capital formulation. Set in the correct model context, this specification entails no difficulty whatever in differentiating the effects of temporary or permanent investment tax credit changes. Moreover, it generates the carefully differentiated, with respect to both magnitude and timing, estimates of the effects of different types of tax changes of the sort Summers illustrates without resort to the exotic sort of explanation Summers offers. I find myself mostly in agreement with Summers' conclusions about the relative magnitude of the effects of capital-favoring tax changes, despite the fact that I largely disagree with the way he arrives thereat. What this proves is that even when marching to different drummers, people can arrive at the same destination. It is heartening to discover that despite quite different perceptions of what supply-side economics is about, it is possible to come quite close together on tax policy prescriptions aimed at regeneration of economic progress. Income and Payroll Tax Policy and Labor Supply JERRY HAUSMAN INTRODUCTION Income and payroll taxes account for about 75 percent of federal revenues. The proportion of federal tax revenue raised by these two taxes has gone up markedly in the past decade with the amounts growing faster than the underlying inflation rate. The rise in the income tax collections occurs because of its progressive rate structure and insufficient indexing of tax brackets to account for inflation. The rise in the payroll tax has occurred because of legislative actions to fund social security payments. Both the tax rate of the payroll tax and the maximum earnings limit have increased significantly. In Table 1 we indicate the effects of the income and payroll taxes over the last two decades. Note that the combined percentage of the two taxes has risen from 56% of government revenues in 1960 to 76% of government revenues in 1978. This increasing trend is likely to continue in the future. The current social security law calls for further tax rate increases up through 1990 and beyond, and earnings limit increases up to 1982. While the income and payroll taxes have certainly received adequate attention from economists, it is probably fair to say that most economists accepted their structure as reasonably good. Most economists liked the distributional consequences and believed that the economic cost in terms of economic efficiency was small. This latter conclusion was based on limited empirical work and survey responses that the income tax caused little reduction in labor supply. Some evidence existed which indicated that wives labor supply might be affected by taxation, but the general view was that prime age males' behavior was hardly affected at all. Jerry Hausman is Professor of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Peter Diamond and Nan Friedlaender have provided helpful comments. Paul Ruud and Ken West were research assistants for this project. The NSF provided research support. 173 TABLE l Revenues from Income and Payroll Taxes (billions) Earnings Limit for Payroll Tax Year Income Tax Revenues Payroll Tax Revenues Income Tax% of Federal Revenues Payroll Tax % of Federal Revenues 1960 $ 40.7 $ 10.6 44% 12% 3.0% $ 4800 1965 48.8 16.7 42 15 3.625 4800 1970 90.4 38.4 47 22 4.8 7800 1975 122.4 75.7 45 29 5.85 14100 1978 198.5 106.1 46 30 6.05 17700 Tax Rate for Payroll Tax HAUSMAN / 175 Two mistakes arose from this common interpretation of the income tax. First, even if we grant the hypothesis that the income tax has little overall effect on labor supply, its economic cost might still be substantial. Income taxes have two effects on labor supply. Taxes lower the net wage and reduce labor supply by the compensated substitution effect. But taxes also have an income effect, which causes individuals to work more since they have been made worse off by the tax. The two effects have opposite signs and might well approximately cancel causing only a small net effect on labor supply from income taxation. But, the economic cost of the tax arises from the first effect alone. Thus, the conclusion by many economists that the cost of raising revenue by the income tax is very small is not supported by economic theory if, in fact, the income effect and substitution effect are cancelling each other out. The second problem occurs because virtually all empirical work on labor supply disregarded taxes. The market wage rather than the after-tax wage was used in the labor supply functions. Or alternatively, the tax system was treated as a proportional tax system rather than a progressive tax system. 1 In a recent paper, Hausman (1979c), I have built on previous research and conducted a study of the effect of tax policy on the labor supply behavior of prime age males, wives of the prime age males, and females who head households. When progressive taxes are entered into a model of labor supply we see a significant effect. The findings indicate that labor supply of the husbands is reduced by about 8% because of the income and payroll taxation while labor supply of wives is reduced by about 30%. Thus, income taxes do affect labor supply in an important way. But as I argue in the next section of the paper, economists should focus on the economic cost of income taxation more than on labor supply effects, My findings indicate that the economic cost of raising a dollar of government revenue by the income tax is about 25¢ on average in terms of lost welfare. The marginal cost of raising an additional $1 government revenue by this means is approximately 40¢. Thus, the economic cost of the income tax is substantial. At least three possible policy recommendations may follow from these conclusions. First, government expenditure might well be reduced given the cost of raising the necessary revenue. To recommend this policy we would need to study the benefits created 'Hal! (!973). Hamman and Wise (!976), Burtless and Hausman (1978), and Wales and Woodland (1979) provide the major exceptions for analyzing U,S. tax policy, 176 / INCOME TAXES AND LABOR SUPPLY by marginal government expenditure. Here and earlier, questions of income distribution become important. Income distribution considerations are discussed in this paper, but we have very little grasp of what constitutes marginal government expenditure or the benefits which arise from it. A further narrowing of policy options would be required to analyze the expenditure option more deeply. The second policy option is to consider raising a greater proportion of tax revenue from other federal taxes. To recommend this option, we need to know the economic cost of other taxes, such as the corporation tax, in terms of their effect on economic efficiency. We do not have adequate knowledge of the cost of other taxes to explore this option. Lastly, we could consider altering the income tax structure to raise the same amount of revenue but at lower economic cost. In the paper, we investigate progressive linear income taxes which seem to have favorable effects both with respect to economic cost and labor supply. Policy options one and three are investigated in this paper. Policy option one is similar to Kemp-Roth type proposals for a decrease in income tax rates. Since our model is partial equilibrium, we look at the effect on tax revenue and the economic cost of taxation holding other factors constant. Our findings indicate that income tax revenues in our sample would decrease by about 6.1 0/o for a IOOJo tax cut and by about 20.3% for a 300/o tax cut. Labor supply effects and the effects on economic cost are discussed in this paper as well as distributional effects of the tax cut. It is certainly possible that general equilibrium effects would eliminate the estimated reduction in tax revenues, but my results lead me to doubt this possibility, especially in the short run. The third policy option appears much more favorable. The progressive tax considered there is basically as progressive as the current tax system for low incomes but decreases the high marginal rates for high incomes. When raising the same amount of revenue as the current system, the economic cost is decreased by more than one half on average with even a greater decrease at the margin. On the usual efficiency grounds this policy option looks extremely good. But as we discuss in the last section of the paper, objections might well be raised to it because it worsens the income distribution. Questions of the tradeoff between the economic cost (efficiency) and income distribution (equity) are very difficult to treat without making judgments on unobservable preferences. Yet, the investigation of this paper is useful because it indicates the size of the potential tradeoff in terms of a marked reform of our income tax system. H AUSM AN / 177 LABOR SUPPLY, TAXES, AND DEADWEIGHT Loss In this section we first consider a model of individual labor supply of the type which has been used in most empirical analysis. The model is based on individual decision makers rather than some larger unit like a family decision process. In fact, in the empirical estimates which we present we consider only husbands and wives. Thus, our model has the husband's labor supply decision independent of the wife's labor supply decision. The wife makes her decision conditional upon her husband's choice. While this model set-up has been traditionally followed in empirical research in labor supply, I expect research in the near future to be more general in its approach. A more symmetrical treatment of family labor supply decisions would be helpful. A second limitation to the model is that it is both static and partial equilibrium. Intertemporal decisions such as the amount of education that a person receives which may well be affected by taxes are omitted.' Also, the model does not consider demand factors for labor in terms of types of jobs offered with respect to wage and hour packages. Again, a more complete model which incorporates these factors would be desirable. Once we outline the model of labor supply we will then consider the effect of taxes on labor supply. Labor supply has been the focus of much attention in recent discussions of supply-side economics. As a theoretical proposition, it is well known that the effect of taxes can either be to decrease or increase labor supply. However, the accepted hypothesis among supply-side economists has been that the effect of the current U.S. income tax system has been to decrease the labor supply. The labor supply model helps us to consider this question which is answered in the next section with the empirical estimates. But it needs to be emphasized that the labor supply cannot be the sole focus of discussion of the effect of taxes. Instead, measures of individual welfare need to be considered. Therefore, we introduce the appropriate measures of individual welfare, the equivalent or compensating variation. From the equivalent variation and tax revenue raised we then develop the notion of deadweight loss (often also ca1led excess burden). From an economists viewpoint, deadweight loss is the correct measure of the effect of taxation. While deadweight loss is a somewhat difficult concept, I believe it, rather than labor supply, should be the focus of informed discussion of the effects of taxation. If we accept the 'Other institutional factors such as pension and social security benefits are not treated due to lack of appropriate data. 178 / INCOME TAXES AND LABOR SUPPLY FIGURE I y y notion that the purpose of the income tax is redistributive as well as a means to raise tax revenue, then deadweight loss defines the correct way to measure the economic cost of the income tax. The error in considering labor supply only is that we can easily design feasible tax policies which raise a given amount of tax revenue while increasing labor supply from the no tax position even though the individual is made worse off by the tax. In this situation it would be incorrect to conclude that the tax is desirable due to its effect on labor supply when the individual's utility has decreased. Furthermore, the redistributive aspect of the income tax would be eliminated by this type of tax so that the change from the current type of system would not be acceptable. THE MODEL OF INDIVIDUAL LABOR SUPPLY The typical model of labor supply used in empirical work has a very simple structure. The individual is assumed to maximize a utility function over hours of work H and net of tax income Y, U(H,Y). 3 Thus, all consumption goods, except leisure, have been 'Some treatments replace hours of work H by leisure, T-H, where Tis total time available. However, since T is an unobservable variable this approach often leads to unnecessary empirical problems. HAUSMAN / 179 FIGURE 2 y -H H' 0 aggregated into a composite good which is represented by the expenditure variable Y. Note that since H is a supply variable, rather than a demand variable, the derivative of the utility function has a negative sign with respect to it. The budget constraint then becomes Y = y + w H where y is nonlabor income and w is the net after-tax wage rate. 4 In Figure 1 we present the two-good diagram which corresponds to this model of labor supply. The tangency of the indifference curve which arises from the utility function U(H, Y) with the budget line determined by non-labor income and the wage then leads to desired hours of work H*. In Figure 2 we then consider the effect of a wage change from w to w '. This change could occur if the government levied a wage tax and exempted nonlabor income, e.g., income from savings. In our subsequent analysis we also allow for taxation of non-labor income, but here look at the simpler case. 'In this formulation the wage and income variables are given in terms of the price of the composite good. 180 / I N CO M E TA X ES A N D L A BO R SU PP L Y Note in the diagram that after-tax hours of work H ' exceed pretax hours H*. Nothing pathological exists in Figure 2. We merely have the counteracting influences of the income and substitution effects which have opposite signs under normal assumptions.' The income effect along with the assumption that leisure is a normal good implies that labor supply increases when non-labor income decreases holding the wage constant. In Figure 2, the movement from point A to point B arises from the income effect. The dashed line which is tangent to the lower indifference curve at point B represents the income effect since it is drawn parallel to the original budget line and represents the same wage. The movement along the lower indifference curve from point B to point C, then represents the (compensated) substitution effect. It holds utility constant but lowers the wage from w to w '. Economic theory states that the substitution effect when the net wage falls will decrease labor supply. Thus, even in the most simple case of a wage tax, the income and substitution effects are of opposite sign. Econometric estimates are necessary to measure the total response and magnitudes of the two separate effects. In terms of the Slutsky equation we have the formula (I) JH Jw = JH ow IU + H JH Jy where the first term on the right-hand side is the substitution effect and the second term is the income effect. It is important to consider both the income and substitution effects when considering taxation and labor supply. As we will see shortly, it is the substitution effect alone which measures the amount of economic cost of a tax. But the income effect cannot be lost sight of because it normally serves to increase labor supply when a tax is levied and determines how much worse off an individual is made by the imposition of a tax. THE EFFECT OF PROGRESSIVE TAXATION We now consider the effects of two types of progressive income taxes. The first type is a linear income tax with a constant marginal tax rate while the second type of progressive tax has increasing marginal rates and is closer to the current U.S. tax system. The linear income tax has many favorable aspects. Since it has only one 'This example should not be confused with the textbook case of a Giffen good which may never have existed in practice. Given many empirical estimates of labor supply response, we might expect this behavior over a certain range of w and w '. H AUSM A N / 181 FIGURE 3 y y A marginal rate it would decrease socially unproductive behavior which individuals currently engage in to reduce their tax liability. The linear tax would lower top marginal tax rates decreasing the incentives for certain types of tax shelters. It can also be made very progressive at the low end through the use of a lump sum grant amount G or an exemption level E.~ In Figure 3 we consider the case of a linear tax with a given exemption level. For income up to point E the individual is not taxed so that he recovers his gross market wage w. Depending on his wage the exemption level E defines labor supply H beyond which the individual receives a net wage rate, w' = w(l- t) where t is the constant marginal tax rate. Note that while the marginal tax rate is constant beyond H the average tax rate is increasing, hence the progressive feature of the tax. And the tax can be made extremely progressive for low Y by adjusting E. However, a disadvantage occurs at the high end because the progression declines as the average tax rate increases toward the marginal tax rate t. "The lump sum grant makes the tax similar in part to the negative income tax proposals. For a model of individual behavior and empirical estimates under a negative income tax see Butt!ess and Hausman (!978) and Spigelman et al. (1978). 0 182 / l N CO M E TA X f_ S A N D L A B O R S U PP L Y FIGURE 4 -------- --- ----- _____ _ ...... y, H, 0 The general progressive tax case is similar to Figure 3 except with more linear segments.7 However, it differs from the previous diagram in that no exemption is present so that each budget segment is determined by a net after tax wage rate of wi = w(l - t,) and the income brackets over which t holds. After-tax non-labor income is given by y,. In Figure 4 we indicate such a budget set with 3 tax segments although the reader should note that the actual U.S. tax code currently has about 15 brackets. We now address the question of how to use our labor supply model when the budget set is no longer linear as in Figure 1. There we assumed that the individual chose H to maximize U(H, Y) subject to Y "' y + wH. Here we have a multiplicity of wage rates instead of just w. The appropriate technique to use is to define the "virtual" incomes Y; which correspond to the wages wi on a particular budget 'It is sometimes not recognized that the U.S. tax system is not progressive over its entire range because of the effects of the earned income tax credit, social security contributions, and the standard deduction. These tax provisions make the appropriate budget sets nonconvex instead of convex as in Figures 3 and 4. We do not treat this additional complication here but instead refer the reader to Hausman (1979c). H AUSMAN / 183 segment. Then along each budget segment the individual maximizes utility subject to Yi + wiHi. The resulting choice is constrained by the bracket limits which determine H, and Hi in Figure 4. That is, the chosen hours of labor supply must be feasible in the sense of being on the budget line in Figure 4. However, a more straightforward approach is to use a labor supply function (which may be determined from the original utility function) of the form (2) where Z is a vector of individual socio-economic variables and (3 is a vector of parameters to be estimated. We enter each set of net wages w and virtual income y and at most one tangency with the feasible budget set is found. The tangency then determines labor supply. This result follows because indifference curves for which g( ·) is derived are concave and the budget set is convex. If no feasible tangency is found then we will have bracketed one kink point, e.g., Hand it will be the optimum labor supply.s Thus, in the case of progressive taxes the situation becomes somewhat more complex, but the usual economic theory applies. Also, the notion of virtual income plays a crucial role in the measurement of the welfare costs of taxation which we now turn to. DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM TAXATION It is incorrect to measure the economic cost of a tax by its total effect on labor supply. As we see in Figure 2 the wage tax served to increase labor supply so on labor supply grounds the tax might be deemed favorable. Yet the individual has been made worse off by the tax since his post-tax indifference curve lies below his pre-tax indifference curve. Furthermore, even if the government returned the amount of tax revenue they raised, which is given by the line segment CD, in the form of the consumption good, the individual has still been made worse off by the tax. Thus, in our simple example the ''size of the pie'' has increased because the tax has brought forth more labor supply. But still the individual's utility decreases because of the tax. It seems clear that an appropriate welfare measure, rather than labor supply alone, is needed to measure the effect of taxation. The first component of a welfare measure is the effect of the tax on individual utility. Here the measure long used by economists has 'This approach is put forward by Hausman (1979b). Other approaches have been used by Ashworth and Ulph (1977) and Wales and Woodland (1979). See al.~o Burtless and Hausman ( 1978). 184 / J N C O M E TA X ES A N D L A B O R SU P P L Y been some form of consumers' surplus. Consumers' surplus corresponds to the concept of how much money each individual would need to be given, after imposition of the tax, to be made as well off as he was in the no tax situation. Measurement of consumers' surplus often is done by the size of a trapezoid under the individual's demand curve or here it would be the labor supply curve. But Hausman (1979a) has demonstrated that in the case of labor supply this method is very inaccurate. Instead the theoretically correct notion of either the compensating variation or equivalent variation must be used. 9 These measures, set forth by Sir John Hicks, are probably best defined in terms of the expenditure function. The expenditure function determines the minimum amount of money an individual needs to attain a given level of utility at given levels of wages and prices. ' 0 Its form is determined by either the direct utility function U(H, Y) or the labor supply function, equation (2). In our simple example of the wage tax of Figure 3 the compensating variation equals (3) C.V. (w, w', U) = e(w', U) - e(w,U) Equation (3) states that the welfare loss to the individual, measured in dollars of the consumption good, equals the minimum amount of non-labor income needed to keep the individual at his original utility level U minus his non-labor income in the no tax situation, y. Since utility is kept at the pre-tax level U, the compensating variation arises solely from the substitution effect in the Slutsky equation (I). The income effect is eliminated because the individual is kept on his initial indifference curve. In the more complicated case of progressive taxes, the only difference is that we use virtual non-labor incomes in equation (3) rather than actual non-labor income. 11 We need one more ingredient to complete the measure of the welfare loss from taxation. The government has raised tax revenue, and we need to measure the contribution to individual welfare which arises from the government spending the tax revenue. The assumption commonly used is that the government returns the tax 'These measures correspond to the area under the compensated demand curve which is determined by the substitution effect in the Slutsky equation (!}. For further discussion see Hausman (1979a) or Varian (1978). "For a more formal treatment see Varian (1978) or Dicwcn (1979). ''The alternative measure of the equivalent variation uses post-tax utility U' as the basis for measuring welfare loss. For labor supply in the two good set-up the equivalent variation typically gives a higher measure of welfare loss than docs the compensating variation. H A U S M A N / 185 FIGURE 5 y ... ' ' ... y -H H* H' 0 revenue to the individual via an income transfer. Here it would correspond to increasing the individual's non.labor income by the amount of tax revenue raised. Then the total economic cost of the tax is given by the deadweight loss (or excess burden) as (4) OWL (w, w', U) = = C.V.(w, w', U) - T(w, w', U) e(w', U) - e(w, U) - T(w, w', U) Equation (4) states that the deadweight loss of a tax equals the amount the individual needs to be given to be as well off after the tax as he was before the tax minus the tax revenue raised T(w, w ',U)." Dead weight loss is greater than or equal to zero which makes sense given that we expect taxation always to have an economic cost. Thus, even if an individual chooses to work more after the imposition of a tax as in Figure 2, he still has not been made better off by the tax. And the economic cost of the tax to him is given by the deadweight loss formula of equation (4). Of course, if no tax revenue is returned the compensating variation gives the welfare loss to the individual. In Figure 5 the compensating variation and deadweight loss are shown in terms of our simple wage tax example of Figure 2. "Here we follow Diamond and McFadden (1974) and use taxes raised at the compensated point. Kay (1980) has recently argued in favor of using the uncompensated point. As with C.V. and E.V. measures the problem is essentially one of which is the better index number basis. 186 / I N C O M E TA X E S A N D L A B O R SU P P L Y Here the effect of the tax is to reduce labor supply from H* to H '. The compensating variation is measured by the line segment yy 1 • We then decompose the compensating variation into its two parts. The line segment CD measures tax revenue collected while the line CE measures the deadweight loss of the tax. Since the taxpayer has been made worse off but no one has benefited from the amount of the deadweight loss, it represents the economic cost of raising the tax revenue. DEADWEIGHT LOSS AND TAX POLICY Much of public finance theory is concerned with the question of raising a given amount of tax revenue while minimizing the economic cost as measured by the deadweight loss.' 1 But in considering tax policy redistribution must be accounted for or otherwise we certainly would have no need for a progressive income tax. Suppose the government wanted to raise tax revenue equal to R dollars. The deadweight loss minimizing tax is a lump sum or poll tax of amount T = R/N where N is the number of taxpayers. Figure 6 portrays such a tax. The deadweight loss is zero because in comparison to Figure 2 or Figure 5 note that only an income effect is present in the movement from point A to point B. No substitution effect is present since the pre-tax wage and post-tax wage are identical. The compensating variation from equation (3) equals T, the amount of tax revenue raised. Thus, the first term of the Slutsky equation (1) is zero and the change in hours of labor supply comes totally from the income effect. No distortion in relative prices occurs and so no deadweight loss occurs. In equation (4) the compensating variation term is exactly cancelled out by the tax revenue term. Deadweight loss is zero. Furthermore, note that labor supply increases because of the income effect. The result of the lump sum tax is to increase labor supply while not creating any deadweight loss. On economic efficiency grounds it is an ideal tax and also would satisfy supply-side economists goals. 1• But it is doubtful such a tax would ever be acceptable on political grounds since the redistributive aspect of the current income tax has been lost. In fact, the lump sum tax is extremely regressive since the ''For an exposition and references see Chapters 12-14 of Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980). Mirrlees (1971) wrote the seminal paper on optimal income tax theory. See also Mirrlees (1979). "I do not claim to know what the exact goals or supply-side economics are. However, an increase in the national product certainly seems high on 1he list. HAUSMAN / 187 FlGURE 6 average tax rate decreases with labor income. Even with its favorable supply-side effects, it is doubtful that such a tax would be politically acceptable. The simple example of a lump sum tax raises a number of important issues. Taxes take away income from people. Taxes, therefore, make people worse off, even if they are nondistortionary. In Figure 6 the individual is on a lower indifference curve after the tax is levied. We measure the economic cost of the tax with the deadweight loss measure of equation (4). But if the tax revenue is not returned to the individual who paid it, he is still worse off. The question of individual losses from the income tax and individual gains to the recipients of tax revenue expenditures involves questions of redistribution. These questions cannot be avoided in discussions of tax policy. Taxes also effect individual behavior again even if they are nondistortionary. Along the lines of Figure 6 we can demonstrate that a lump sum tax which raises revenue T always involves greater labor supply than a linear income tax like Figure 3 or a completely progressive tax like Figure 4 so long as 188 / I N C O M E TAX E S A N D L A BO R S U P P L Y leisure is a normal good. Therefore, a tradeoff exists between the degree of progressivity that society wants in the income tax and the economic cost measured by the deadweight loss. Thus neither deadweight loss nor labor supply are sufficient measures alone in evaluation of the income tax. Deadweight loss gives the economic cost of the tax, but the "benefit" of the tax which arises due to its redistributive aspect must also be accounted for. Unfortunately, the correct degree of redistribution is difficult to reach agreement on, which makes consideration of income tax policy changes a difficult subject. AN EMPIRICAL LABOR SUPPLY MODEL AND THE EFFECT OF TAX REFORM PROPOSALS In this section we first briefly discuss an empirical labor supply model estimated by Hausman (1979c). The estimates from this model are used to evaluate the effects of income taxation. We then evaluate the effects of the current income tax via both deadweight loss and labor supply effects. Following the analysis of the current tax system, we consider two types of tax reform proposals. The first proposal is referred to as the Kemp-Roth proposal and here we consider reductions in the income tax rates of 10-30%. Besides deadweight loss and labor supply effects we are also interested in the effect on tax revenue. The change in tax revenue depends on the labor supply response when taxes are changed. If the labor supply response is not uniform across individuals, the change in tax revenue will be sensitive to whether the response is concentrated among high income or low income earners. The other type of tax reform proposal we consider is an equal yield progressive linear income tax like that in Figure 3. That is, we consider income taxes with constant marginal rates which raise the same amount of revenue as the current income tax. The overall tax will still be progressive by Jetting the exemption level vary across tax reform proposals. The linear tax systems that we consider are similar in progressivity at the low income levels but display much less progressivity at high income levels than the current tax system does. A linear income tax is attractive because it has the potential of sharply decreasing deadweight loss by decreasing high marginal tax rates. But how far it can do so while raising equal tax revenues depends on the labor supply response which we also consider. For each of the tax reform proposals we attempt to account for distributional effects by considering effects among population quintiles. It is important to emphasize that all our results are partial H A U S M A N / 189 equilibrium in nature. Potentially important general equilibrium results are not captured by the econometric model. AN EMPIRICAL MODEL OF LABOR SUPPLY The essential feature that distinguishes econometric models of labor supply with taxes from traditional demand models is the nonconstancy of the net, after-tax wage. As we saw in the previous section, the marginal net wage and the virtual income depend on the specific budget segment that the individual's indifference curve is tangent to. Econometric techniques have been devised which can treat the nonlinearity of the budget set. An econometric model takes the exogenous nonlinear budget set and explains the individual choice of desired hours of work. Our model is based on the linear labor supply specification (5) where w is the net after-tax wage, and y is the virtual income on budget segment i. The vector Z represents socioeconomic characteristics of the individual. The unknown parameters a, f3, and y are estimated using econometric techniques. Now actual hours h may differ from desired hours h* because of stochastic reasons. Another source of stochastic variation enters the model by allowing for a distribution of preferences in the population via random {3. The specific way in which these enter the model is described in Hausman (1979c). Also a zero constraint for hours as well as fixed costs to working enter the model. The model is estimated first for a sample of husbands who are between 25-55 years old for the year 1975.' 5 We then estimate the model over a sample of women who are wives of the husbands' sample. The husbands' earnings are treated as non-labor income for the wives. Thus, wives labor supply is conditioned on husbands labor supply. Wives also face initial marginal tax rates given by the last tax bracket which contains their husbands earnings. The federal income tax is represented in the model by 12 tax brackets. The first bracket is $1,000 wide with succeeding brackets falling at intervals of $4,000. Since we are interested in the taxes on labor supply, we consider only taxes on earned income. Because we do not have access to actual tax returns, a number of assumptions ';It is important to note that neither the model nor the simulations treat the young or old segments of the working population. We would expect a labor supply model to differ markedly for such individuals. Nor do we treat non-married individuals. 190 / I N C O M E TA X E S A N D L A BO R S U P P L Y are required. We assumed that all married couples filed jointly. In forming the taxable income we took account of personal exemptions and assumed that individuals used the standard deduction up to the (1975) limit of $16,250. The standard deduction was used on approximately 2/3 of all tax returns in 1975. Beyond $20,000 we used the average of itemized deductions for joint returns for each tax bracket found in Statistics of Income. We also take account of the earned income credit and social security contributions which were 5.85% up to a limit of $14,000 for 1975. Lastly, we take account of state income taxes by putting the tax laws of the 41 states who taxed earned income into the budget set calculations. Thus we had a reasonably complete characterization of taxes which individuals faced on their earned income.'" We briefly discuss the results from the model for the average individual in the sample. A more complete discussion is contained in Hausman (1979c). For husbands we found the uncompensated wage elasticity to be very near zero. This result is similar to the findings of previous research. However, by taking account of the tax system via the virtual incomes we find an income elasticity at the mean hours of work to be approximately - .177 for the mean wage in the sample. Thus, the presence of a non-zero income elasticity implies that husbands' labor supply decisions are affected by the income tax. Also the deadweight loss may be significant because the substitution effect of the Slutsky equation (I) will be non-zero given our estimates. For wives we find the uncompensated wage elasticity to be .906. The income elasticity for the mean woman who works full time is approximately - .504. 17 Thus, both the uncompensated wage elasticity and income elasticity are nonzero which indicates that taxes have an important effect on both labor supply and deadweight loss. Given the model specification and estimates, we can now apply it to evaluate the effect of income taxation. Suppose we want to evaluate a tax reform proposal. The estimated change in labor supply can be found from equation (6) by entering the new tax plan via the marginal tax rates w; and virtual incomes Y;- A micro simulation is done on the sample of husbands and wives, and the "City income or wage taxes could not be included due to lack of specific job location data. Minor problems may also be created because of the tax treatment by states or earnings of non-residents. "It is important to note that this elasticity is calculated at a mean virtual income of approximately $8200. The reason for the high virtual income is that husbands' earnings are included in the non-labor earnings of the wife. H AUSMA N / 191 change in labor supply is calculated. The specific manner in which stochastic elements of the model are treated in the simulations is given in Hausman (1980). To do deadweight loss calculations we need the expenditure function for equation (3). Hausman (1979a) derives the expenditure function which corresponds to the labor supply function, equation (5), to be (6) -/1Wi U +-a {1 W· I + a {12 Zy - {1 We take the marginal wage wi from the budget set and then calculated the deadweight loss from equation (4) using taxes raised at the compensated labor supply point. We then have our welfare measure of the cost of the income taxation. Two possible objections to our welfare measure are that we aggregate across individuals, giving each individual the same weight in the implicit social welfare function. Also different individuals are allowed different coefficients in their expenditure functions. The problems created for analysis of vertical equity considerations for these choices are discussed in Atkinson and Stiglitz (1976). But we attempt to indicate the importance of these considerations by looking at distribution measure across different income categories. CURRENT TAX POLICY AND KEMP-ROTH REDUCTIONS We begin our analysis of the current tax policy by considering the effect of the current tax system on the labor supply of husbands. First, we consider the mean individual in the sample. His before tax wage is $6.18 per hour and his non-labor income is $1266. Without taxes the labor supply model predicts he would work 2367 hours per year, but the effect of the current tax system is to lower his labor supply to 2181 hours per year. Thus, the effect of taxes is to decrease his desired labor supply by 8.2%. To calculate the welfare loss for these husbands we look at the deadweight loss (DWL) based on the compensating variation measure of deadweight loss from equation (3). For the mean individual we calculate the deadweight loss to be $235 which is 21.8% of the total tax revenue collected from him. It is 2.40Jo of his net, after-tax income. Thus, we see that taxes on earned income have an important effect on both labor supply and on deadweight loss. These results differ markedly from the received knowledge in the field, e.g., Pechman (1976), which is that taxation has almost no effect on the labor supply of prime age males. Also, the deadweight loss calculation indicates that the 192 / ( N CO M E TA X E S A N D L A BO R S U P P L Y TABLE 2 Mean Tax Results for Husbands Market Wage $ 3.15 4.72 5.87 7.06 10.01 DWL $ 66 204 387 633 1749 OWL/Tax Revenue OWL/Net Income Change in Labor Supply 9.4% 14.4 19.0 23.7 39.5 0.8% 2.0 3.1 4.5 9.9 4.5% 6.5 8.5 -10.1 -12.8 income tax is a relatively high cost means of raising tax revenues.'" If less expensive means to raise federal tax revenue do not exist, the large amount of redistributive expenditure by the federal government is being done at relatively high economic cost. Now the mean individual calculation leaves out two potentially important factors. First, because of the nonlinearity of the tax system, it may provide a poor guide to population averages. It can be shown that deadweight loss is proportional to the square of the marginal tax rate so that deadweight loss will grow quickly as marginal rates rise. Second, distributional considerations are neglected. We have emphasized that an important objective of the income tax system, in addition to raising tax revenue, is to redistribute income. We attempt to investigate distributional considerations by looking at quintiles based on the market wage. The market wage seems a better measure than income to base distributional categories on, because it is closer to the notion of the opportunity set of the individual. In an optimal tax calculation, the tax is based on the opportunities facing the individual instead of post-tax behavior. In Table 2 we look at the effect of the current tax system for five categories defined by the market wage. Overall, we find that the tax system decreases labor supply by 8.5% and the mean deadweight loss as a proportion of tax revenue raised is 28.7%. Thus, the results are not too different from the results for the mean individual. However we note important differences among the five categories. "Of course, the economic cost of raising revenue from other federal taxes would need to be investigated before an informal choice could be made. Federal taxes on labor income currently raise about 75% of federal revenues. H AUSMA N / 193 First, we see that deadweight loss rises rapidly with the market wage as we expected. In terms of the welfare cost of the tax we see that the ratio of deadweight loss to tax revenue raised starts at 9.4% and rises to 39.5% by the time we reach the highest wage category. Again we see that the cost of raising revenue via the income and payroll taxes is not negligible. In terms of a distributional measure we see that the ratio of deadweight loss to net income also rises rapidly. In fact, this measure indicates that individuals in the highest wage category bear a cost about 10 times the lowest category while individuals in the second highest category bear a cost 5 times as high. Without specific social welfare measure, we cannot decide whether the current tax system has too much, too little, or about the right amount of progressiveness. But the measures of Table 2 seem an important step in thinking about the problem. Lastly, note that the change in labor supply from the no tax situation again rise with the wage category. The high marginal tax brackets have a significantly greater effect on labor supply than do the low tax brackets. We now do a similar set of calculations for our sample of wives. While we found both significant deadweight loss and an important effect on labor supply for husbands compared to the no tax situation, the situation is more complicated for wives. First, about half of all wives do not work. In the absence of an income tax, the net wage would rise causing some of them to decide to work and others to increase their labor supply. But, at the same time their husbands' after-tax earnings would also rise which has the opposite effect on labor force participation. Thus, both effects must be accounted for in considering the effects of the income tax. TABLE 3 Mean Tax Results for Wives Market Wage $2.11 2.50 3.03 3.63 5.79 OWL DWL/Tax Revenue OWL/Net Income Change in Labor Supply 23 119 142 184 1283 4.6% 15.3 15.9 16.5 35.7 .3% 1.3 1.5 L7 8.6 +3L20Jo ~ 14.2 -20.3 -23.8 -22.9 $ 194 / INCOME TAXES AND LABOR SUPPLY Overall for wives, we find the ratio of deadweight loss to tax revenue to be 18.4%. But it should be remembered that this ratio understates the effect on labor force participants alone. For labor supply, we find that taxes serve to increase labor supply in the lowest wage category, but decrease labor supply as the wage rises. Overall, they decrease labor supply by 18.2%. Thus, again for wives we see that the current income tax system has both an important labor supply effect and imposes a significant cost in welfare terms for raising tax revenue. We now turn to a consideration of Kemp-Roth type tax proposals. We will consider two levels of tax cuts, 10% and 30%. The question which has been focussed on most is what effect these tax cuts would have on tax revenues. Our results are partial equilibrium so that general equilibrium effects are not accounted for. The main effect here arises from the change in labor supply. But increased labor also moves some individuals into higher tax brackets. Both effects need to be accounted for. In Table 4 we present the two Kemp-Roth simulation results. For the 10% tax deduction mean hours of labor supply for husbands rise 22.5 hours or 1.1%. Tax revenues fall by 7.4%. Even given the fact that our model is partial equilibrium, rudimentary calculations demonstrate that general equilibrium effects are very unlikely to be large enough to cause tax revenues from decreasing significantly in the short run as our results show. In terms of the welfare cost of the tax we see that the DWL falls significantly. The ratio of mean deadweight loss to tax revenue falls from 22.1 % under the current system to 19 .0% under the 10% tax cut plan. ' 9 For the 30% tax cut labor supply increases by 2.7% while tax revenue falls by 22.6%. Again we see that deadweight loss decreases significantly with the ratio of deadweight loss to tax revenues raised decreasing to 15.4%. Thus Kemp-Roth type tax cuts have large effects both in terms of decreasing deadweight loss and in decreasing government revenue. Without knowledge of marginal government expenditure, it is difficult to evaluate the tradeoff. But we cannot recommend KempRoth on welfare grounds alone given the substantial fall in government revenue. "A problem arises here because we are doing welfare calculations with different indifference curves because of the tax changes. But we are using a common basis of comparison, the no tax situation. TABLE 4 Kemp-Roth Tax Cut Proposals for Husbands 300/o Tax Cut 10% Tax Cut Market Wage $ 3.15 DWL/Tax Revenue DWL/Net Income Change in Labor Supply DWL/Tax Revenue DWL/Net Income Change in Labor Supply 8.50/o .7% +.4% 6.8% .4% + 1.3% 4.72 13.3 1. 7 +.5 10.9 1.1 + 1.6 5.87 17.4 2.6 +.9 14.5 1.8 +2.7 7.06 21.8 3.8 +1.1 17.9 2.5 + 3.1 10.01 36. l 8.2 + 1.4 29.5 5.3 +4.6 196 I I N CO M E TA X E S A N D L A B O R S U P P L Y For wives we do not present detailed quintile results because the overall pattern is similar to husbands. The mean results are given in Table 5. TABLE 5 Overall Kemp-Roth Tax Cut for Wives Tax Cut Change in Tax Revenue Change in DWL Change in Supply (Hours) 10% 30 - 3.8% -16.2 -10.6% - 17.4 + 50.2 + 117 .o Overall, we see that the labor supply response to a tax cut is greater for wives than for husbands. We expect this since the wage elasticity is about twice the income elasticity so we should have a net increase in labor supply. Furthermore the difference in the elasticities is about four times that of husbands, and we do observe a significantly larger response. For the 10% tax cut case labor supply increases by 4.1% and tax revenues fall by 3.8%. For the 30% tax cut case labor supply increases by 9.4% and tax revenues fall by 16.2%. Our overall evaluation of the Kemp-Roth tax proposals is that while tax revenues will decrease by significantly less than the tax cut, overall government revenue from the income and payroll tax will decline. An argument might be made that general equilibrium results may be large enough to reverse this conclusion, but I doubt that it is a valid argument, especially in the short run. Thus, unless a strong argument can be made for reducing government expenditures with little welfare loss from the recipients, the KempRoth tax cut proposals cannot be supported on the basis of our results. They certainly do not have the "free lunch" properties claimed by some of their supporters. A LINEAR INCOME TAX We now consider an equal yield change from the current tax system to investigate whether the welfare cost in terms of deadweight loss can be significantly decreased. The type of tax system which we consider are linear income taxes with initial H A USM A N / 197 exemptions like the tax system drawn in Figure 3. Thus, we specify an initial exemption E and then search our marginal tax rates until we find the minimum tax rate which raises the same amount of tax revenue as the current tax system. We might expect such a linear income tax to do well in two respects. io First, in Table 2 we saw that deadweight loss increases rapidly as marginal tax rates increase. Since the linear income tax will not have such high marginal rates, deadweight loss should be decreased. Second, we would expect a significant labor supply response given a decrease in the marginal tax rates. Thus, the tax rate should not have to be too high to raise equal revenues to the current tax system. Yet a potential problem still exists. Even if total deadweight loss decrease, some individuals may still be made worse off by a change from the current tax system to a linear income tax. Although overall deadweight loss will decrease, we have the problem of potential versus actual compensation which was the basis of the Kaldor-Hicks-Scitovsky-Samuelson debate of the l 940s. However, we will see that the linear income tax does so well that the problem may be overcome in some cases. In Table 6 we consider the equal yield linear income tax for husbands. Note first that the tax rate begins at 14.6% with an exemption level of zero and rises to 20.7% with an exemption of $4000. Each tax measure gives a substantial welfare gain. Since tax revenues remain the same the change in deadweight loss gives the welfare improvement. Note that even with the highest exemption level of $4000 the deadweight loss falls by 49% from the current system. The labor supply also increases substantially from the current system. My conjecture is that except for a lump sum tax, we have done about as well as possible because labor supply is now only approximately 1.5% below the no tax case. Lastly, we look at the question of distribution. By considering the average tax rate for various exemption levels, we see that either the $2000 or $4000 exemption is superior to the current tax system since the average (as well as the marginal) tax rate is lower at every tax bracket. The results are sensitive to various deductions and credits an individual taxpayer declares but yield the conclusion that approximately all taxpayers are made better off by this type of linear income tax system. 21 "Mirrlees (197]}, when he considered the optimal nonlinear income tax, found that the optimal tax was nearly linear for the particular labor supply function he considered. "The earned income tax credit is taken into account in these calculations. TABLE 6 Equal Yield Linear Income Tax With Initial Exemption for Husbands Average Tax Rate at: 4000 8000 16000 24000 Exemption Level Tax Rate Change in Deadweight Loss Deadweight Loss/ Tax Revenue Change in Hours 0 14.6% - 825.75 .071 + 170.0 .146 .146 .146 .146 $1000 15 .4 - 798.82 .083 + 169.3 .116 .135 .144 .148 2000 16.9 -765.31 .098 + 167.6 .085 .127 .148 .155 4000 20.7 -659.18 .145 + 163.0 0 .104 .155 .172 .119 .147 .173 .188 Current Tax Code IRS Code .287 H A U S M AN I 199 TABLE 7 Linear Income Tax for Wives Exemption Level Tax Rate 0 $1000 2000 4000 14.6% 15.4 16.9 20.7 Change In Taxes 5.1% .3 + 4.6 + 11.2 Dead weight Loss/ Tax Revenue Change In Hours .104 .110 .114 .143 +372.6 + 345.l +302.2 +232.8 We briefly consider what effect this type of tax system would have on wives. We assume here that each family gets only one exemption and faces the same marginal tax rates as her husband. We use the tax rates from Table 6 so that tax revenue for wives is not held constant. The results are presented in Table 7. As we expect, labor supply increases for women with the linear income tax because the marginal tax rate has decreased. Because of the increase in labor supply, the revenue changes are not that large. Tax revenues fall by 5 .1 % for a 14.6% tax rate but rise by 11.2% for the case of a 20.7% tax rate. The ratio of deadweight loss to tax revenues falls markedly from the current tax system. Thus, for wives as well as husbands, the linear income tax has favorable implications from an economic cost viewpoint. Our example bears out to some extent the lessons from the optimal tax literature. The crucial parameters there are the weighted (compensated) substitution response and the net revenue raised from each individual. We use the same weights for each individual in our deadweight loss calculations. Our results indicate the importance of the net revenue consideration. Because of the labor supply response, Tables 6 and 7 demonstrate that lower income groups can gain from lowering the top marginal income tax rates. Can anyone then object to the case for a linear income tax? The answer is unfortunately yes, if it is relative rather than absolute income or utility that matters for society's choices on distribution matters. 22 Economists used to the Pareto principle typically think of each individual's or family's welfare apart from the rest of the "Such cases are analyzed by Fair (1971) and Boskin and Sheshinski (1978). 200 / INCOME TAXES AND LABOR SUPPLY population. Since the linear income tax has the possibility of making everyone better off, most economists would favor it on these grounds. But by sharply decreasing the top marginal rates from say 50% to 20.7%, the highest paid individuals have a greater increase in welfare than do the lowest paid. Therefore, on a relative basis or by some income distribution measures, the linear income tax might not be an improvement from the current tax system. These arguments would need to be considered in tax reform discussions. I favor such a change in our tax system because I do not give great weight to the relative welfare argument. Favorable economic effects could occur with less progression in the tax system at higher income levels. This type of proposal emphasizes the economic efficiency aspects of the tax system. Thus, it seems that a more linear type of tax system is to be favored over the current system. The Kemp.Roth tax cuts do not do nearly as well by comparison. HA USMA N / 201 REFERENCES Ashworth, J. and D. T. Ulph. "On the Structure of Family Labor Supply Decisions." mimeo, 1977. Atkinson, A. B. and J. E. Stiglitz. "The Design of Tax Structure: Direct Versus Indirect Taxation." Journal of Public Economics, 6 (1976). _____ . Lectures on Public Economics, New York: McGrawHill, 1980. Auerbach, A. J. and H. S. Rosen. "Will the Real Excess Burden Please Stand Up? (Or Seven Measures in Search of a Concept)." mimeo, 1980. Boskin, J. J. and E. Sheskinski. "Optimal Income Distribution When Individual Welfare Depends on Relative Income." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92 (1978). Burtless, G. and J. A. Hausman. "The Effect of Taxation on Labor Supply." Journal of Political Economy, 86 (1978). Diamond, P. and D. McFadden. "Some Uses of the Expenditure Function in Public Finance." Journal of Public Economics, 3 (1974). Diewert, W. E. "Duality Approaches to Microeconomic Theory." mimeo, 1979. Fair, R. C. "The Optimal Distribution of Income." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85 (1971). Hall, R. E. "Wages, Income and Hours of Work in the U. S. Labor Force." in G. G. Cain and H. W. Watts, eds., Income Maintenance and Supply, Chicago: Academic, 1973. Hausman, J. A. "Exact Consumers' Surplus and Deadweight Loss." American Economic Review, forthcoming, 1979a. _____ . "Labor Supply with Convex Budget Sets." Economic Letters, 3 (1979b). ______ "The Effect of Taxes on Labor Supply." In H. Aaron and J. Pechman, eds., How Taxes Affect Economic Behavior, Washington: Brookings Institution, 1981. _____ . "Stochastic Problems in the Simulation of Labor Supply." prepared for NBER conference, October 1980. 202 / lNCOME TAXES AND LABOR SUPPLY Hausman, J. A. and D. Wise. "Evaluating the Results from Truncated Samples." Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 5 (1976). Kay, J. A. "The Deadweight Loss from a Tax System." Journal of Public Economics, 10 (1980). Mirrlees, J. A. "An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation." Review of Economic Studies, 38. ~~~-~· "The Theory of Optimal Taxation." mimeo, 1979. Pechman, J. Federal Tax Policy (3rd ed.) Washington: Brookings Institution, 1976. Varian, H. Microeconomic Analysis. New York: Norton, 1978. Transfers, Taxes and the NAIRU DANIEL S. HAMERMESH Just as war is too important to be left to the generals, the impact of taxes and transfers on the aggregate unemployment rate is too important to be left to the macroeconomists. I therefore subject the issue of how tax and transfer policy affects unemployment and aggregate supply to a detailed, microeconomic examination of the effects of individual tax and transfer program structures. This inductive approach is, I believe, likely to provide a far better guide to discovering how changes in these policies have worked through the economy than would a macroeconomic approach that ignored the programs' complexities. Throughout the discussion we need to distinguish the programs' effects on two different aspects of economic performance. First, they may affect the measured nonaccelerating-inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU). Such effects would be important for planning macroeconomic policy, though it is not clear how informative knowledge of any effects on the NAIRU is for learning about aggregate supply. Second, each tax and transfer policy may change the amount of employment observed at the NAIRU; assuming productive efficiency, this means that these policies will affect the amount of output, and thus per-capita incomes observed in the economy. It is this second set of effects that is more in the spirit of the supply-side discussions of recent years. Unlike the first effect, it is more than just an issue of measurement. Before proceeding to present first a macro approach to the issue, then a detailed micro approach, it is worth considering some wellknown (to labor economists) aspects of labor force change over the past twenty years. For selected years of roughly comparable aggregate demand pressures (though 1969 was probably somewhat tighter than the other two years), we present the aggregate unemployment and participation rates, and unemployment rates, Daniel S. Hamermesh is Professor of Economics, Michigan State University, and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper were provided by Alan Blinder. 203 204 / TRANSFERS, TAXES AND NAIRU participation rates and labor force shares of five demographic groups. Several features, in decreasing order of my estimate of their importance in the history of the U.S. labor market over the past 20 years, stand out: 1) The adult female participation rate has skyrocketed, causing that group's representation in the civilian labor force to jump from 30 to 38 percent; 2) As a result of the post-war baby boom, the teen-age share of the labor force has also increased, a rise that has been accentuated by the simultaneous rise in (mostly part-time) labor-market participation in this group; 3) The participation rates of older males have decreased drastically, substantially lowering their representation in the labor force. (This change is a major focus of my discussion in the fourth section below.); and 4) Partly as a result of the first two changes and their interaction (see Grant and Hamermesh, 1981), the unemployment rate of teenagers has increased sharply. Teenagers are indeed one of only two groups among the five whose pattern of unemployment rates across the three years departs obviously from the aggregate rate. (The other is older men, whose unemployment rate is lower in 1979 than in 1957.) A MACRO APPROACH TO THE EFFECTS OF TRANSFERS AND TAXES If you are an unreformed macroeconomist, and you believe that taxes and transfers have affected the NAIRU, your initial inclination should be to specify a time-series equation to estimate the direction and magnitude of their effects. In the case of unemployment insurance benefits, such a time-series model has been estimated by Grubel and Maki (1976). Postulating that the net effect will be positive, they find, in a regression of the logarithm of the aggregate unemployment rate on the gross replacement rate of UI benefits and other variables, that this effect is observed in the data. Unfortunately for believers in such models, the size of the effect is so large as to imply that unemployment would be reduced nearly to zero if the UI program were abolished. 1 Taking this simplistic approach to its logical conclusion, we estimate in this section an equation explaining variations in aggregate unemployment. The dependent variable is log (U* / 100-U*), a transform of the adjusted unemployment rate. Rather than using the published aggregate unemployment rate, we use a constantweight average of unemployment rates of teenagers, women 20 +, 'The implied effect of a . l increase in gross replacement by Ul in the Grubel-Maki study is an extra 6.31 percentage points of unemp!oymem ! HAMERMESH I 205 TABLE 1 Selected Labor Force Data, 1957, 1969, l 979 1957 1969 1979 Aggregate Unemployment Rate Participation Rate 4.3 59.6 3.5 60.1 5.8 63.7 Teens Unemployment Rate Participation Rate Fraction of Labor Force 8.8 49.7 .064 8.8 49.4 .086 16.1 58. l .092 Women 20+ Unemployment Rate Participation Rate Fraction of Labor Force 4.1 36.5 .297 3.7 42.7 .340 5.7 50.6 .378 Men 20-24 Unemployment Rate Participation Rate Fraction of Labor Force 7.8 87.0 .054 5.1 82.8 .065 8.6 86.6 .080 Men 25-54 Unemployment Rate Participation Rate Fraction of Labor Force 3.1 97 .1 .455 1.6 96.1 .395 3.4 94.4 .362 Men 55+ Unemployment Rate Participation Rate Fraction of Labor Force 3.5 63.4 .130 1.9 56.1 .114 2.9 46.7 .088 men 25-54, and other men, where the weights are their shares in the civilian labor force in 1957:1. This refinement circumvents the problem that growing replacement rates of transfer programs are observed to be positively correlated with an aggregate unemployment rate that is rising because of the very substantial changes in the demographic mix of the labor force that have occurred since 1957. 206 / TRANSFERS, TAXES AND NAJRU To represent transfer and tax policy, two variables are used, in each case with lags to avoid part of any problem that may be caused by simultaneity. These are: I) NRR, the net replacement rate of transfer payments in aggregate. This is computed as personal transfer payments, divided by wages and salaries minus personal contributions for social insurance minus a prorated (by wages' share in personal income) share of personal income taxes; and 2) TAX, the sum of personal income taxes on wages and salaries, and individual and employer contributions for social insurance, all divided by the sum of wages and salaries and employer social insurance contributions.' This is designed to measure any disincentive effects that taxes on wages and salaries may have beyond their effects through the financing of transfer payments. Also included in the model are a time trend variable and the change in the rate of growth of per-capita real GNP. 3 This acceleration term seems more appropriate than the growth rate itself, as it is hard to argue that the NAIRU will vary with the steady-state growth rate of an economy. The model is estimated over U.S. data from 1954:II through 1978:IV. Both simple lag terms in NRR and TAX are included, and variants that include polynomial distributed lags in these variables are also estimated.• All of the equations are estimated using the Cochrane-Orcutt technique to account for first-order autocorrelation in the residuals. The results of estimating four versions of the equation relating a logarithmic transformation of the adjusted unemployment rate to the variables defined above arc presented in Table 2. The change in the rate of per-capita real GNP growth has the expected negative sign. Interestingly, the trend coefficient is negative. (Remember, we have removed any trend effects produced by demographic changes in the labor force.) Including all lagged terms (in both NRR and TAX) significantly increases the explanatory power of the 'A TAX variable that excluded employer contributions from both nnmeralor and denominator was also used in place of the variable discussed in the text. While the results were qnalitativcly similar, the coefficient of detcrminaiion was in every case sllghlly lower. 'The model was also estimated with the theoretically improper variable, percent change in GNP. Though the R' exceeded those reported for comparable equations in Table 2, and though the implications of NRR and TAX were the same as in the table, the lack of a good justification for this variable suggests the discussion should be based on the model including its rate of change. 'The polynomial lags were estimated with the far end-point coefficients constrained to equal zero. A test of the validity of these constraints in the equation in column (4) yielded F(J,87} ~ .49. (The 95 percent significance level with these degrees of freedom is 2. 7 I.) TABLE 2 Effects on log (U* /100-U*) 1954:II-1978:IV Constant GNP-GNP._, (sum of four lagged terms) Time NRR_, (1) (2) (3) (4) -3.39 (-17.93) -3.34 (-12.79) -3.45 (-19.01) -4.26 ( - 9.91) - .036 - .037 -.047 -.045 (- l.64) (- 1.66) (-2.11} ( -- 2.04) -.011 -.Oll (-3.0]) (-2.71) -.014 (- 3.04) -.022 (-3.74) 6.71 (4.80) 6.22 (4.79) 6.15 (5.00) 5.91 (4.87) 2.21 (3.98) (4.44) NRR_, -.13 NRR_, NRR"", TAX._, 2.42 (- .17) .27 (.36) - .86 ( - 1.38) ( - .85) -.54 .15 (.13) - .361 (- .29) L56 (2.04) TAX_z TAX_, 2.01 (2.27) 1.49 (2.16) TAX_. Ri D-W Q .9320 l.31 .912 .9320 1.31 .911 .9348 L31 .902 .9384 1.29 .900 208 / TRANSFERS, TAXES AND NAIRU equation. s We thus base our discussion of these variables' effects on the results in column (4) of Table 2. Both the terms in the net replacement rate and those in the tax rate are significant, and the sum of each set of four coefficients is positive. Since NRR grew from .095 in 1954:II to .265 in 1978:IV (reaching a high of .290 during the 1973~75 recession), we may infer that the growth of transfer payments relative to net wages and salaries has induced an increase in the unemployment rate. A similar inference may be drawn from the positive coefficients on TAX and the increase in TAX from .167 to .301 (its highest value) during this period. However, lest this be reported in tomorrow's Wall Street Journal as proof positive of the deleterious effects of transfers and taxes on labor income, two considerations are in order. First, the coefficients imply incredibly large effects of taxes and transfers on the adjusted unemployment rate. For example, a one standard deviation increase in NRR from its mean is seen co induce an increase in U* from its mean, 5.00, to 7.85. Similarly, an increase in TAX of one standard deviation from its mean of .231 induces an increase of U* from its mean to 6.08. • Both of these are ridiculously large, suggesting other things are going on that we have not accounted for. Second, it may be the skepticism of one who has seen too much simple-minded macroeconometric "evidence," but l tend to disbelieve studies whose bold conclusions are based solely on time-series results. Accordingly, I would give little weight to the results in this section, and would instead base my conclusions on careful thought about the programs' effects and on cross-section evidence about their impact. SOME THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS Given my skepticism about using macro estimates of the effects of taxes and transfers on unemployment to deduce their effects on the NAIRU, it is incumbent upon me to propose some alternative method of answering this question. Help is provided by the approach of Perloff and Wachter (1979) and others who use aggregate production and pricing models to deduce what aggregate unemployment rate, adjusted for demographic change, is consistent with nonaccelerating inflation. This method is dearly the correct 'In an equation like that in column (4) from which TIME was excluded, the sum of the coefficients on NRR was 5.35, and that on TAX was 3.00. "NRR has a mettn of .171 and a standard deviation of .060; TAX has a mean of .Z3! and a standard deviation of .040. Their correlation is .933. HAMERMESH / 209 one for macro policy planning; it does not, though, as its users would readily admit, indicate whether changes in tax and transfer policy are responsible for changes in the NAIRU. (This approach really says little about the causes of changes in the NAIRU.) Thus, while it may be helpful for other purposes, it provides no evidence on the positive issues under consideration here. A second approach is simply to make grandiose statements about how the NAIRU has increased tremendously, or, depending upon one's political views, how unemployment much above four percent is evidence of a recession. In the former camp we have statements from at least one ex-Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors; sympathetic to the latter, a recent annual report of the Council of Economic Advisors made the bold admission that, "A number of forces have been at work ... to raise the overall unemployment rate at which inflationary pressures begin to appear above the neighborhood of 4 percent. .. ? 1 Neither statement has the least bit of scientific basis, and neither should therefore receive any serious attention. Nonetheless, because of the political importance of the issue, and because of the attention those making such statements command, they have infected the public debate. They do not, though, tell us anything about how or to what extent transfers and taxes have affected the labor market. A third approach is inductive; it tries to construct, from available estimates of the effects of individual tax and transfer programs, the likely impact on the NAIRU of the sum of such programs. The problem with this approach is that, unless one examines the underlying estimates carefully before basing one's conclusions upon them, one quickly comes to outlandish results. For example, taking Feldstein's (1973) estimate that unemployment insurance (UI) benefits and taxes induce a 1.25 percentage point increase in the NAIRU, and combining it with Clarkson and Meiners' (1977) estimate that AFDC and Food Stamps work registration requirements have raised measured unemployment by two percentage points, the absurdity of the exercise becomes apparent. It is impossible to believe that without these two fairly small programs, the unemployment rate in 1979 would have been reduced to below 3 percent. Either these effects are not additive, or the 'Herbert Stein noted, "I am not in a position to insist that it [l"ul! employment] is 7 percent unemployment. But it is a possibility that must be given weight. Suppose we accepted the idea that there is a 50-50 chance that we are now at full employment." ( Wall Street Journal, September 14, 1977, p. 22) The CEA statement is from the Report, 1978, p. 171. 210 / TRANSFERS , TA X ES A N D N A l RU underlying estimates are grossly overstated. (The former criticism may be correct, though I present no evidence on it; the latter does, as I show below, have substantial support.) Given these difficulties, this third approach is also not one that is likely to produce precise estimates unless great care is given to the interpretation of the underlying studies. What I do here is recognize that the NAIRU has increased since the 1950s, probably by the slightly more than 2 percent implied for 1977 by the Perloff and Wachter study. Of this increase a bit more than one percentage point has been attributed by Wachter (1976) to changes in the demographic mix of the labor force. Using the four groups underlying the calculation of U* in the estimates in the previous section, I find that the unemployment rate would have been .85 percentage points lower in 1978:IV had the labor-force weights of 1957:l prevailed. (I am somewhat uncomfortable with the assumption implicit in this approach that the relative unemployment rates of the various demographic groups must remain unchanged from 1957. In any case, those who loved the implications of this approach for the 1970s' labor market may be less enthralled with its implications for the late 1980s!) The task, then, is to consider on a program-by-program basis whether the remaining one percentage point increase could have been produced by changes in transfer policy. In conjunction with this we consider whether the slowdown in the growth of real output per capita may also have been in part induced by these policy changes. Although it is impossible to summarize in a succinct way the massive amount of theoretical work on the incentive effects of various transfer programs, I believe that there are sufficient general similarities among the programs' effects to make a general discussion of their likely economic impact worthwhile. The purpose of doing so is to point out some aspects of these effects that have been ignored by research that has been concentrated narrowly; to demonstrate the similarities among various strands of research; and to provide a focus for the discussion of specific programs' effects in the next section. Throughout this analysis we assume that leisure and unemployment are synonymous-both are voluntary. We also recognize that any attempt to synthesize a general model will surely ignore some important programmatic details within individual transfer schemes. We examine the likely effects of transfers under the assumption that each member of the adult population faces two separate situations vis-a-vis these programs. In the first the individual is H AM E R M E S H / 211 FIGURE l Budget Constraints Before Eligibility for Benefits Income B H E A '----------------------'---Leisure 0 ineligible for benefits under the program. Nonetheless, the program affects his behavior because of the incentives it provides to establish eligibility for benefits later on. This represents the entitlement effect discussed for Ul in Hamermesh (1979b), part of the effect of OASI on hours of work before age 62 implicit in Burkhauser and Turner (1978), and the work incentive effect of OASI through automatic benefit recomputation noted in Blinder et al. (1980). As Figure 1 shows, the budget line in the absence of the transfer scheme (and the taxes that finance it) is OAB. With the transfer program and its concomitant tax structure the line shifts to OACFGH. As compared to the budget line OADE, describing the choice set available to the worker who sees only the wage net of taxes, the constraint OACFGH induces substantial changes in behavior. (See Moffitt and Kehrer, 1980; Burtless and Hausman, 1978; and Hamermesh, I 980.) Some persons who would have been at the corner solution at A, or who would have found an internal maximum along AC, are induced by the entitlement aspect of the transfer program to increase their supply of labor and move to point F. (In addition to its effects in UI and OASDI, it may also be operative in affecting military enlistments, as the post-service educational and other benefits are an added bonus to enlistees.) Though this entitlement effect has no immediate impact upon unemployment rates, it may 212 / TRAN SF E RS , TA XE S AN D NA l RU FIGURE 2 Budget Constraints When Eligible for Benefits Income C A ,.___ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __.__Leisure 0 change the aggregate rate insofar as it increases labor force participation among persons whose probability of being unemployed differs from the average. So too, it will clearly increase market employment and thus measured real GNP. Once eligibility for the transfer is established, the individual faces a different set of constraints. Under UI and OASDI these can mutatis mutandis be described as resulting from a lump sum benefit paid if no work, or only a small amount of work, is undertaken; as reflecting the sum of the wage rate and a steadily reduced benefit as hours increase, until the point at which no more benefits are paid. The budget line OACFGHJ in Figure 2 describes this choice set. As compared to the case in which the only perceived effect is through the tax (along OADE), the impact of the program is to induce those who otherwise would have supplied labor along FC to reduce their supply (assuming leisure is a normal good). This effect likely occurs beneath the ceiling on OASI benefits (currently $5000 per year), though this does not appear to have been analyzed empirically; and the same effect is expected beneath the $280/month at which an individual no longer is eligible for Disability Insurance. In addition to the possible effect in shifting persons rightward from F in Figure 2, transfer programs also shift them from points to the left of F toward point F. These are the disincentive effects that have received so much attention in the literature (see Feldstein, H AM E R MES H / 213 1973, and Hamermesh, 1977, on regular UI; Munts, 1970, on partial UI benefits; Quinn, 1977, and Baskin, 1977, on OASI; and Parsons, 1980, Leonard, 1979, and Haveman and Burkhauser, 1980, on DI.) In each program there is some, occasionally nearly infinite, tax rate on additional earnings beyond point F such that labor supply is reduced. It is this effect that has been viewed as the culprit in reducing market employment and, in the case of leisure that is measured as unemployment, in increasing the unemployment rate. Throughout the discussion we have glided over the effect of taxes that finance the transfer payments. Since the concentration of this paper (and most of the literature) has been on the effects of transfers, that seemed appropriate. Nonetheless, some attention to this difficult issue is in order at this point. The following considerations seem relevant. 1) At least for transfer programs, the issue of what the financing method does to labor supply is unusually murky because of the extreme difficulty of extricating the effects of taxes that are, for some programs, experience rated (see Hamermesh, 1977, and Ehrenberg et al, 1978). 2) Assuming that the financing is through a payroll tax, a very complicated simultaneity problem seems to be operating. Without knowing the incidence of the combined employer-employee tax that finances OASI and DI, we cannot know the true shape of the budget constraint facing the worker-consumer. But, without knowing the shape of the constraint, we cannot deduce the labor supply elasticity that partly determines the incidence of the tax. This means that any consumer-theoretic analysis of the effect of a combined tax-transfer program rests on shaky ground. 3) Despite these problems, we do know that the payroll taxes are at least partly borne by workers, so that it makes sense to represent the slope of the budget lines OADE in Figures I and 2 as -w(l- st), where w is the wage rate, t is the (total) tax rate, and s is the fraction of the tax borne by workers. 4) Because of the ceiling on payroll taxes, there is a convexity in the budget constraint facing the workerconsumer over some range. This will affect labor supply and thus market output in that range. (Clearly, though, if one modelled the entire structure of taxes on earnings, one would find that the appropriate constraint is concave to the left of some point.) The net effect of taxes and transfers on aggregate supply combines all of these separate impacts implied by this general model. Entitlement effects, induced unemployment, bunching at notches in benefit structures, and behavior induced by taxes, either 214 / T RA NS FE R S , TA X ES A N D N A I R U general income taxes or earmarked taxes that finance a particular program, must be considered as we discuss how each specific transfer program affects the labor market, While our discussion abstracts from changes in the demographic mix that have affected the NAIRU, we should recognize that there are other changes in the composition of the labor force that are induced by transfer schemes and that will have an impact on the NAIRU. Within each demographic group, for example, those persons with the lowest market productivity (relative to their productivity at home) will be induced to leave by any given increase in transfer payments. So long as relative market-household productivity is positively (negatively) correlated with the individual's probability of being employed when in the labor force, this will induce a decrease (increase) in the measured unemployment rate within the particular demographic group. Though this is a change induced by transfers, it is also a measurement problem of a sort similar in quality to that which we have circumvented by assuming constant labor-force weights. EFFECTS OF SPECfflC TRANSFER AND TAX PROGRAMS That transfer payments have formed an increasing fraction of disposable income was made clear in our discussion in the second section, and it is underscored by the totals in the bottom two lines of Table 3. The growth of transfer payments has been very uneven, however; it is interesting to note that the phrase "welfare mess" is hardly apropos, as "welfare" -usually thought of as AFDC-has grown more slowly than disposable income. Disability Insurance payments have been the most rapidly growing among programs that were ongoing in 1966, and we have seen the birth and explosive growth of payments under SSI and Food Stamps. The data clearly suggest that transfers could, by virtue of their increased generosity and coverage, have induced substantial changes in the labor market since the mid-1960s. Whether this is in fact the case can be seen by a program-by-program consideration of the transfers' effects. Prompted by Feldstein's (1973) seminal work, there was a resurgence of research on the effects of UI on the labor market. Unfortunately the bulk of this work is on only one of the potential impacts of UI, namely on the duration of spells of unemployment. The twelve studies summarized in Hamermesh (1977, Chapter 3) show a substantial consensus that higher UI benefits do induce people to remain unemployed longer (as our discussion in the previous section suggested). Further work (e.g., Kiefer and H A M E R M E S H / 215 TABLE 3 Income Maintenance Programs 1966 and 1978 (billions of dollars) Program Old Age and Survivors' Insurance 1966 1978 Growth Rate (% per year) $ 18.07P $ 78.524a 12.2 Unemployment Insurance (state and railroad) 1.891 9.233 13.2 Workers' Compensation (state laws and federal programs) 1.320 6.760 13.6 General Assistance (AFDC) 4.306 10.700 7.6 4.595a Food Stamps (value of federal contributions) Disability Insurance (under OASDHI) 1.72P Supplemental Security Income All Transfer Programs Disposable Income 12.2143 16.3 6.551 44.7 224.1 13.4 510.4 1458.4 8.7 • fiscal year bas is Neumann, 1979, and Katz and Ochs, 1980) has done nothing to dispel this consensus, and even my synthesis "best-guess" impact.5 extra weeks of unemployment for each . I increase in the net replacement rate-seems supported by more recent studies. 8 There should be no doubt whatsoever that Ul benefits in the U.S. do induce longer spells of unemployment. Feldstein (1976) and Baily (1977) have shown how the partly experience-rated tax that finances UI can induce increases in 'The weak evidence available suggests that this effect is smaller in looser labor markets (Hamermesh, 1977, Chapter 3). 216 / T R A N S F E R S , TA X E S A N D N A l R U employment fluctuations and thus increases in the number of spells of unemployment. This is postulated to occur because the marginal tax cost to employers of another layoff is zero. Many employers' UI taxes already exceed the benefits paid to prior employees because of nonzero minima on state UI taxes, and some others' taxes are limited by maxima on state tax rates. (Elsewhere, Hamermesh, 1977, I have shown that roughly only 2/ 3 of Ul taxes are experience rated.) Recently, there has been some effort to quantify the impact of the tax structure on the labor market. Brechling (1981) has carefully parameterized state UI tax laws and shown that they appear to have a substantial effect in raising manufacturing layoff rates across states and over time. Halpin (I 979) has presented similar evidence for seasonal fluctuations in employment in several industries. I find this evidence, and the theoretical structure underlying it, to be nearly as convincing as that on unemployment duration. The provision of UI benefits represents a safety net under workers' participation in the labor market. As such, it induces the potential worker to choose to participate where she otherwise might not. This entitlement effect (Hamermesh, I 979b) is especially likely to be important among demographic groups whose attachment to the labor market is fairly loose. It will affect the composition of the labor force by increasing the weight accorded to such groups, and will raise (lower) the aggregate unemployment rate if these groups' unemployment is greater (less) than average. I have shown for adult women that this effect does appear important in increasing participation, and one might assume that it affects the behavior of teenagers and older workers too. Since these groups generally have higher-than-average unemployment, we may infer that it adds to the positive effect of UI on aggregate unemployment. However, by inducing persons marginally attached to the labor market to spend more time in the work force, it also increases market employment in these groups. The net effects of an expanded UI program-higher benefit amounts, longer potential duration and wider coverage-have been clearly demonstrated empirically: Unemployment duration is raised; employment variability is increased, and the composition of the labor force is tilted toward groups having higher-than-average unemployment. There is no question that UI raises the NAIRU, by an amount that I elsewhere (Hamermesh, 1977) have "guesstimated" to be .7 percentage points. Part of this effect has been added since the mid-I 960s, due to expansion of coverage of HAMERMESH / 217 this program and to recession-triggered extensions of the potential duration of benefits. The program also induces declines in employment (as unemployment duration is increased, and additional layoffs occur when product demand decreases), but may also increase market employment among secondary workers. The net effect on aggregate employment, and thus per-capita GNP, is an empirical question; however, as I have shown elsewhere (Hamermesh, 1979b) that even among adult women the net effect is negative, we may conclude it is negative in aggregate as well. As Table 3 shows, retirement benefits under Social Security represent the largest component of the transfer panoply. While our discussion in the previous section hinted at the program's major effects, there is one other effect that deserves mention first. Not only does OASI raise the cost of working for those eligible; the structure of benefits is also such that the cost is especially raised for younger eligibles. This occurs because: 1) at age 72 the earnings ceiling is removed, whereas it applies before then; 2) the increase in monthly benefits if a man (woman) postpones filing beyond age 65 (age 62) is far less than would be actuarially fair; 9 and 3) the ceiling on earnings is a more important constraint among younger eligibles, because their market wage rates are greater. These last two considerations coalesce to induce those eligible for benefits to file as soon as eligibility for full benefits is achieved. The removal of the ceiling at age 72 likely comes too late to have much impact on persons who have been out of the labor force, and whose skills have deteriorated. Far more important than the induced switches among eligibles, the system has provided increasing incentives for early retirement through expanded support levels. (In terms of an ultra-rational lifecycle model, though, the opposite is true: The ratio of expected benefits to OASI contributions has been falling since the 1940s. In such a model the income effect works toward greater lifetime labor supply. I doubt people are that rational, and the participation data for older males in Table 1 suggest they are not.) As Munnell (1977) showed, these rose sharply between the late 1960s and 1976, both because of ad hoc statutory increases and the now-repealed double indexing of benefits. Even though the 1977 Amendments will prevent further increases in gross replacement, the projected rises in 'Each month beyond age 65 in which benefits are not claimed raises ihc monthly benefit eventua!ly claimed by J/4 of one percent; each month before age 65 in which benefits are claimed reduces ihc monthly benefit by 5/9 of one percenl. (Department of Health, Education and Welfare, Social Security Handbook, 1978) 218 / T RA N S FE R S , TA X E S A N D NA I R U payroll tax rates, and a continuation of current trends in taxes on earnings, indicate that net replacement may continue rising. This suggests that the incentive that benefits give for early retirement will continue to increase unless further amendments to the Social Security Act are passed. The magnitude of the increases in net replacement is large enough to have had substantial impacts on the labor market. Quinn (1977) and Boskin (1977) provide some weak evidence for the empirical importance of these effects in cross-section data, and Pellechio (1979) has provided a very convincing demonstration that it is higher Social Security benefits particularly that are responsible for the earlier findings. However, Blinder and Gordon's (1980) estimates show only slight effects. One might infer that the data on labor-force participation rates for older men in Table I reflect the time-series analog of this cross-section evidence. This effect has served to decrease employment; it says nothing per se about effects on the NAIRU. Indeed, our arguments on composition in the previous section; the observation that the unemployment rate among older males decreased between 1957 and 1979; and the evidence that early retirement is more likely among less educated, lower skilled workers, precisely those for whom incidence of unemployment is greater, all imply that the increased generosity of OASI benefits may have reduced measured unemployment by inducing nonparticipation by older workers with the poorest labormarket prospects. We showed in the previous section that an entitlement effect can also exist in OASI payments, as workers seek to establish greater monthly retirement benefits later on through work before age 62. This effect is compounded by the incentive the system provides to shift hours of work away from periods of eligibility for OASI, when the implicit marginal tax rate on effort is 50 percent. Burkhauser and Turner (1978) use aggregate time series to "show" that inclusion of Social Security wealth explains much of the sudden halt in the decline in the workweek after World War IL I am skeptical about attributing so much of this important phenomenon to what appears to be so far-removed an incentive, and I refuse to be convinced by time-series evidence alone. Some cross-section evidence seems to be required. Even without this, though, we should note that this effect implies an increase in labor input and market output, and probably no effect on the NAIRU, as hours are increased among prime-age workers whose participation rates are already high. HA MERMESH / '.219 Because the shared payroll tax finances OASI benefits, one cannot assess the program's effects without knowing the burden of the tax. While some aggregate evidence implies the burden is entirely on workers (Brittain, l 971), other macro evidence (Vroman, 1974} and micro studies (Hamermesh, 1979a) imply that it is shared by workers and capitalists through higher product prices. It is likely that the tax reduces effort. (J believe that substitution effects outweigh income effects for some groups, and that they are roughly equal for others.) However, though this does imply a reduction in total labor inputs into production, it may also imply a reduced NAIRU, since the greatest labor supply elasticities are among groups with a high incidence of unemployment (compare Borjas and Heckman, 1978, and Cain and Watts, 1973). AH these considerations suggest that OASI retirement benefits change labor-force participation in such a way as to reduce the NAIRU: The composition of the labor force is induced to shift toward groups with a low incidence of unemployment. With the exception of the (to me) secondary effect on the distribution of hours of work over the lifetime, the theoretical arguments and empirical evidence suggest the major impact of OASI retirement benefits is to decrease employment. Because of increased net replacement and earlier eligibility, this effect has moreover likely increased since the 1950s, and has increased since the late 1960s for the first of these reasons. Federal Disability Insurance has since 1960 provided benefits to disabled workers of all ages. As Table 3 showed, the program has received increasing attention from potential eligibles, drawn by increased replacement rates and a not overly harsh interpretation of eligibility rules. While there is a five-month waiting period during which the person is not to be involved in substantial gainful activity, an initial denial of benefits still leaves the applicant four appeals levels; and the evidence (Haveman and Burkhauser, 1980) suggests that claimants are increasingly aware of this and increasingly successful in their appeals. Like OASI under Social Security, Disability Insurance provides incentives that affect the NAIRU and aggregate employment. Workers with low market productivity, either because of severe impairments or because of minor lmpairmems coupled with a lack of marketable skills, have a substantial incentive to apply for and continue to seek Dl benefits. (This is not, though, a decision to be made lightly: Once eligibility is established, the individual cannot earn more than $280 per month and then reapply successfully for 220 / TRANSFERS, TAXES AND NAIRU benefits.) We should thus expect low-wage workers, minority workers, older persons, etc., to be represented disproportionately among DI recipients. Indeed, one might view DI partly as a retirement program for those in their fifties. These predicted effects are exactly what we observe: Leonard (1979) shows that among males 45-54 nonwhites have twice the representation among DI recipients as they do in the labor force. He also shows that the probability of filing for DI is negatively related to one's past wage rate. ' 0 Haveman and Burkhauser (1980) show that the "overwhelming majority of DI benefits are initially made [sic] to workers age 50-64." The most clearly demonstrated impact of the program's increased legal and administrative attractiveness to potential eligibles is on the labor-force participation of older men. Among nonwhites, for example, Siskind (197 5) has shown using time-series data that much of the decline in participation can be attributed to the changes in the DI program. In a more complex model Leonard (1979) confirms Siskind's results. Parsons (1980) finds similar results for the participation of males ages 48-62 using cross-section data for 1969. He also finds that the effect of higher DI benefits in 1969 is greater among persons who died within the next few years and who presumably were in poor health when they filed for benefits. The results suggest strongly that the growth of DI has induced a decline in the NAIRU. AH the groups which the program data and empirical work demonstrate are induced to leave the labor force are composed disproportionately of persons with an above average incidence of unemployment. This means that the composition of the labor force is shifted by DI benefits away from persons with higher unemployment rates, and thus that measured unemployment is lower at a given level of labor market tightness. The effects of DI on the labor-market issues of interest-the NAIRlJ and the size of the work force-are the same as those of OASI: Market employment is reduced, as is the NAIRU. This rapidly growing program may well have contributed to reducing the rate of GNP growth, but it has also disguised some of the unemployment that would otherwise have been observed. While the Food Stamp program is relatively new and has grown rapidly, AFDC payments were established under the Social Security Ac:t and have grown relatively slowly in the last decade. '"Because of the problem of specifying full-capacity earnings to hold consrnnt rar the effects of health on the probability of filing, Leonard's results should be viewed as quite tentative. H A M E R M E S H / 221 Analytically, though, they can be lumped together for our purposes. The first consideration for each program is the work registration requirement each entails: Recipients of benefits must register with the state Employment Service and accept suitable work if such is found for them. Clarkson and Meiners (1977) have argued that this has induced a 2 percentage point increase in measured unemployment. The calculation is based on the assumption that no registrants would have been in the CPS labor force before the work registration requirement was imposed, and that all report themselves as unemployed in the CPS. Both assumptions seem highly questionable, and Cagan (1977) and Devens (1978) have argued that the Clarkson-Meiners number is greatly overstated. Without econometric evidence based on observation of the effect of Food Stamp or AFDC on labor force status, little credence appears owed to this finding. One would need longitudinal data to test the issue properly; though such are available, the test has not been undertaken. Perhaps the best conclusion on the issue, based upon consideration of the enforcement of the work-seeking requirements, is that there may have been some one-shot effect on the NAIRU in the early l 970s, but it was likely tiny. If one believes the registration effect on the NAIRU was important, one must also believe that the requirement has induced an increase in employment and thus in aggregate supply: Some of these induced to register presumably did find work when they otherwise would not have. Since I do not believe the effect on the NAIRU is large, I do not believe this positive effect on employment is large either. Far more important is likely to be the effect of the benefit structure under both programs. Saks (1975), for example, has shown that the implicit tax rate on AFDC mothers in New York in 1967 was .6, and that there was a substantial guarantee. (Casual evidence suggests the implicit tax rate is somewhat lower today.) Similarly, Food Stamps have increasingly substituted for the negative income tax that was never enacted: There is no longer a purchase requirement; a certain amount of Food Stamps is guaranteed, and the allotment is reduced by less than 100 percent as other income increases. This implies that both programs will induce the usual negative effects on labor supply that we know are associated with negative income taxes, assuming, as seems likely, that recipients' supply elasticities are positive (see Saks, 1975, for strong evidence on this). How much have the induced changes in labor supply resulting from AFDC and Food Stamps changed the NAIRU and aggregate employment in the past 15 years? Since AFDC has not expanded 222 / T R A N SF E R S , T A X E S A N D N A I RU relatively, it is hard to argue its effect has changed, so that one must conclude it has not contributed to higher unemployment or a changed employment rate. (Though, clearly, reducing the guarantee or the tax rate would increase supply.) Food Stamps are new since the mid-1960s, though; it is thus likely that they have affected unemployment and employment. However, as with the other programs that have reduced labor supply, one can reasonably argue that the reduction has been disproportionately among persons with the highest incidence of unemployment. Thus, if anything, the benefit structure of Food Stamps has reduced the NAIRU slightly. Without careful econometric evidence (and there is currently none), this conclusion is based only on a little logic and on an analogy to the demonstrated effect of other programs whose benefits can be modelled similarly to those of Food Stamps. There are numerous other transfer programs that one could examine, and some, such as Workers' Compensation or Supplemental Security Income, are fairly important. However, there has been little or no work studying the effects of these other programs on the NAIRU or on employment; since the discussion above has given the flavor of the likely directions of the impacts of most programs, there is little point repeating the analysis absent specific empirical results. Suffice it to say that these other programs most likely accentuate the effects we have already discussed. I have avoided analyzing the effect of income taxes on the NAIRU and on aggregate supply. While the latter issue has received tremendous popular attention (and far too little scientific analysis), the former has received none. There is no obvious direct effect of the progressive income tax on the NAIRU, though there may be some compositional effect of the sort we have stressed throughout this section. Whatever the impact of the income tax on the labor supply of high-wage earners, it is unlikely to have induced them to withdraw from the labor force. A reduction in weekly hours seems far more likely. Thus if anyone is induced to reduce market work to zero, it is probably those whose market opportunities are least attractive. To the extent that the income tax does affect supplyand, I stress, this has not been demonstrated directly-it has likely done so among persons with the greatest probability of being unemployed. Thus, if anything, the progressive income tax reduces the NAIRU by changing the composition of the labor force. The effect of the progressive income tax on hours of employment cannot be answered here. (Hausman's paper covers this in more detail.) Nonetheless, we should note that the induced reduction in H A MER MESH / 223 output (assuming wage rates reflect marginal productivity) is Z: t;rJ;W;N;, where t is the marginal tax rate on the i'th group of i potential workers; 11 is their labor supply elasticity; w is their market wage, and N is the number of persons in the group. Across different groups of workers both a higher marginal tax rate and a higher supply elasticity will induce a greater reduction in effort (and thus presumably in market output and real GNP). Among high,vage groups the marginal income tax rate on effort is fairly high; however, all the available evidence suggests I'/ is quite low (Borjas and Heckman, 1978). Thus it is unlikely that income taxes are inducing much shortfall of output from this group and, conversely, laughable to think that tax reductions will induce a sharp rise in workhours and total earnings. For low-wage groups the evjdence is much less clear. While it is true that most studies find fairly high values of Y/ for these groups (see Cain and Watts, 1973), some recent evidence suggests that, at least for women with children, these findings are due to fixed costs of entering the labor market {see Cogan, 1980). This suggests that the effect of increases in the marginal tax rate on hours of effort will be small. Also, the marginal tax rates on low-wage workers are not very high. Taken together, the evidence says that it is unlikely that the progressive income tax has reduced employment much. Moreover, it has, if anything, reduced the NAIRU. There may be difficulties with the current income tax structure in this country; taxes may be "too high''; but these statements should not be based on fears about any huge detrimental effects on the labor market. CONCLUSIONS I would like to give one grand number indicating the effect of income transfer programs on the NAIRU. I cannot. AH I can do is note that UI does raise unemployment, but that the other, often larger-scale programs have the opposite impact through their effects on the composition of the labor force. Since I have not been able to quantify these, I cannot weigh them against the effect of UI that I have previously "guesstimated." Nonetheless, if forced to pick one number to summarize the entire impact of transfers and taxes on the NAIRU, zero would appear to be a good choice. At the very least, it is a far better choice than that implied in the regressions in the second section or in much of the popular discussion. 224 / T R A N S F E R S , T A X E S A. N D N A 1 R lJ Zero would be a very bad estimate of the effect of taxes on aggregate employment. Every program we have discussed likely reduces labor supply on net, While we have not quantified this reduction for all the programs and taxes discussed, the studies that have done so for particular programs suggest the decline is substantial. That transfers induce such a reduction should be especially disturbing, as the tax structure in the U.S. economy already contains a (probably increasing) bias against market work. (Though, as we saw above, its effects may not be very large.) While guessing the size of the induced drop in employment is not possible, it is worth noting that, if even one-half of the decline in participation of men 55 + has been caused by changes in OASI and DI benefits and regulations, that alone would have induced a .8 percent reduction in aggregate employment since the mid-1950s. The effect for the entire labor force is likely somewhat larger than this. This guess, though, creates a conundrum: Why has aggregate labor force participation risen by 3.6 percentage points since 1969, at the same time we estimate that taxes and transfers have induced a decline? Have nonmarket substitutes for women's time in the home experienced such huge relative price reductions? Has the structure of tastes changed (a thought that is repugnant to me as an economist)? Perhaps the rea! issue we should be addressing is: Why has the aggregate participation rate grown so much, departing from its long-term near constancy just below 60 percent'? While this is not a policy paper, a few conclusions for policy seem clear, The evidence is abundant that we cannot ease program eligibility and pay higher benefits without inducing changes in behavior. This raises program costs, and thus the taxes that finance the programs, and it targets benefits toward persons who were not (at least apparently) meant to be targeted. At a time when the older population is becoming healthier, DI has induced substantial decreases in participation of men 55-62. OASI benefits have done the same for persons 62 + and caught them in what Maggie Kuhn of the Gray Panthers has called the "retirement trap": They are induced to leave the labor force early, find they cannot maintain their financial status during an unexpectedly long retirement, and discover it is difficult to reenter the labor force at the same rate of earnings." Clearly, unless we wish to see the growth rate of real per-capita income decline further, steps such as raising the , 'Case histmies and a discussion of this problem are presented in Waif Street Journal, November 5, 1979, p. l er. seq. H A M E R M E S H / 225 minimum age of eligibility back to 65 for men, and 62 for women, seem perfectly reasonable and consistent with a healthier and longer-lived population. Similarly, DI cannot be allowed to grow further into a retirement program, as that will reduce the benefits that the politics of the program will allow to be paid to the seriously disabled who do need them. In short, we risk hurting those persons for whom all these programs were designed by letting them expand far beyond their original purposes with no thought to the tax burdens they impose or their induced effects on production. 226 / T R A N S F E R S , T A X E S A N D N A I R U REFERENCES Baily, Martin. "On the Theory of Layoffs and Unemployment." Econometrica, 45 (July 1977), 1043-1063. Blinder, Alan and Roger Gordon. "Market Wages, Reservation Wages and Retirement." NBER Working Paper No. 513, July 1980. _____ and Donald Wise. "Reconsidering the Work Disincentive Effects of Social Security." National Tax Journal (December 1980). Borjas, George and James Heckman. "Labor Supply Estimates for Public Policy Evaluation." Industrial Relations Research Association, Proceedings, 31 (1979), 320-331. Baskin, Michael. "Social Security and Retirement Decisions." Economic Inquiry, IS (Jan. 1977), 1-25. Brechling, Frank. "Layoffs and Unemployment Insurance." In Sherwin Rosen, ed., Studies in Labor Markets, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1981. Brittain, John. The Payroll Tax for Social Security. Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1971. Burkhauser, Richard and John Turner. "A Time-Series Analysis on Social Security and Its Effect on the Market Work of Men at Younger Ages." Journal of Political Economy, 86 (Aug. 1978), 701-716, Burtless, Gary and Jerry Hausman. "The Effect of Taxation on Labor Supply; Evaluating the Gany Negative Income Tax Experiment." Journal of Political Economy, 86 (Dec. 1978), 1103-1130. Cagan, Phillip. "The Reduction of Inflation and the Magnitude of Unemployment." In W. Fellner, ed., Contemporary Economic Problems, Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1977. Cain, Glen and Harold Watts. Income Maintenance and Labor Supply. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1973. Clarkson, Kenneth and Roger Meiners. "Government Statistics as a Guide to Economic Policy: Food Stamps and the Spurious Increase in Unemployment Rates." Policy Review, I (Summer 1977), 27-54. HAMER MESH / 227 Cogan, John. "Labor Supply with Costs of Labor Market Entry." In James Smith, ed., Female Labor Supply: Theory and Estimation, Princeton: Prineeton University Press, 1980. Devens, Richard. "Food Stamps and the Spurious Rise in the Unemployment Rate Reexamined." Policy Review, 3 (Winter 1978), 77-83. Ehrenberg, Ronald, Robert Hutchens and Robert Smith. ''The Distribution of Unemployment Insurance Benefits and Costs." U.S. Department of Labor ASPER Technkal Analysis Paper, No. 58, 1978. Feldstein, Martin. Lowering the Permanent Rare of Unemployment. U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, 1973. - - - ~ ~ · "Temporary Layoffs in the Theory of Unemployment." Journal of Political Economy, 84 (October 1976), 937-958. Grant, James and Daniel Hamermesh. "Labor Market Competition Among Youths, White Women and Others.'' Review of Economics and Statistics, 63 {August 1981). Grubel, Herbert and Dennis Maki. "The Effect of Unemployment Benefits on U.S. Unemployment Rates.'' Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 112 (1976). Halpin, Terrence. "The Effect of Unemployment insurance on Seasonal Fluctuations in Employment." Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 32 (April 1979), 353-362. Hamermesh, Daniel S. "Entitlement Effects, Unemployment Insurance and Employment Decisions." Economic Inquiry, 17 (July 1979b) 317•332. - - - - - · Jobless Pay and the Economy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977. ______ "New Estimates of the Incidence of the Payrolt Tax.'' Southern Economic Journal, 45 (April 1979a), 1208-1219. ______ "Unemployment Insurance and Labor Supply.'' International Economic Review, (October 1980), 517-527. Haveman, Robert and Richard Burkhauser. "Economic Issues Regarding Public Policy Toward the Disabled." Unpublished Paper, University of Wisconsin, 1980. 228 / TRANSFERS, TAXES AND NAJRU Katz, Arnold and Jack Ochs. "Implications of Potential Duration Policies in Unemployment Duration." Unpublished Paper, University of Pittsburgh, 1980. Kiefer, Nick and George Neumann. "An Empirical Job-Search Model, with a Test of the Constant Reservation-Wage Hypothesis." Journal of Political Economy, 87 (Feb. 1979), 89-108. Leonard, Jonathan. "The Social Security Disability Program and Labor Force Participation." NBER Working Paper No. 392, August 1979. Moffitt, Robert and Kenneth Kehrer. "The Effect of Tax and Transfer Programs on Labor Supply.'' Research in Labor Economics, 4 (1980). Munnell, Alicia. The Future of Social Security. Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1977. Munts, Raymund. "Partial Benefit Schedules in Unemployment Insurance: Their Effect on Work Incentive." Journal of Human Resources, 5 (Spring 1970), 160-176. Parsons, Donald. "The Decline in Male Labor Force Participation." Journal of Political Economy, 88 (Feb. 1980), 117-134. PeUechio, Anthony. "Social Security Financing and Retirement Behavior." American Economic Review, 69 (May 1979), 284-287. Perloff, Jeffrey and Michael Wachter, "A ProductionNonaccelerating Inflation Approach to Potential Output; Is Measured Potential Output Too High?" In Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer, eds., Three Aspects of Policy and Policymaking, Amsterdam: North Holland, 1979. Quinn, Joseph. "Microeconomic Determinants of Early Retirement." Journal of Human Resources, 12 (Summer 1977), 329•346. Saks, Daniel. Public Assistance for Mothers in an Urban Labor Market. Princeton: Industrial Relations Section, 1975. Siskind, Frederic. "Labor Force Participation of Men 25-54, by Race." Monthly Labor Review, 98 (July 1975), 40-42. H AM E R M E S H / 229 Vroman, Wayne. "Employer Payroll Taxes and Money Wage Behavior." Applied Economics, 6 (June 1974), 189-204. Wachter, Michael. "The Demographic Impact on Unemployment." In National Commission for Manpower Policy, Demographic Trends and Full Employment, Special Report No. 12, 1976. Discussion of the Hausman Paper JEFFREY M. PERLOFF Jerry Hausman's paper makes major contributions to both the labor supply and taxation literatures. His paper provides the most reliable labor supply estimates to date since he takes account of the nonlinear budget constraint created by federal and state income taxes. His work also helps rectify the misleading approach taken by politicians, the popular press, and many economists which stresses the revenue effects of tax cuts: the relevant question is the welfare effect of tax cuts. Hausman is able (amazingly enough!) to rigorously cakulate the deadweight loss imposed by a tax. Of great policy importance is his conclusion that an across-theboard tax cut of the Kemp-Roth variety would lower welfare (and tax revenues), while a reduction in the progressivity of the tax could raise welfare. As Head argued in 1966, a progressive tax will have greater disincentive effects than a proportional tax so long as the economy is not in the prohibitive range where a reduction in the proportional tax rate would raise revenues.' If (as Hausman defines it) the progressive tax differs from the proportional tax in that some level of income is exempted from the tax, then revenues collected under the progressive tax system will be less than under the proportional system for any marginal tax rate, as shown in Figure l. Holding revenues fixed at R, so long as the economy is not in the prohibitive range (as Hausman 's estimates show), the marginal tax rate which corresponds to the proportional tax, t*, will be less than that under the progressive tax, t**. As a result, the proportional tax ·will have less of a disincentive effect, as shown in Hausman's estimates. While Hausman's research is destined to become one of the classics of applied econometrics, I have a few minor quibbles. First, Jeffrey M. Perloff is Assistam Professor of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, ·Head, J. G., "A Note on Progression and Leisure: Comment," American EconomicReview, V. 56, l966, pp. 172-179, 231 232 / H A U SM A N D I S C U S S l O N FIGURE I Revenue R revenues from a progressive tax ..__ _.._._ _ _.___ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _~ ' - - - ' - - - - - marginal iax rate t• t** the effects of taxation on the amount of education people undertake may be pronounced. This effect, however, is likely to reinforce the distortions Hausman estimates. 2 Second, the estimation process used assumes that the income effect is always normal, which seems unreasonable in genera!. Third, these estimates presume individuals know their marginal tax rates. There is some justification for this approach, however, according to Harvey Rosen and some of Hausman's other papers, so this potential problem is probably not serious. 1 Fourth, Hausman assumes that women are the secondary workers in a family, while it would have been more reasonable to assume that the lower wage family member was the secondary worker. Hausman is currently working on a model where the family makes a joint decision so that this problem will be eliminated in the future. In any case, in his sample, few if any households had women earning more than their spouses. 'Perhaps some handle on this effecr can be obtained by examining people who made their educa1ion decision~ before WWII when income taxation was relatively unimportant. 'Rosen, Harvey S., <;Taxes in a Labor Supply Model with Joint Wage-Hours Determination," Econometrica, V. 44, N. 3, May, !976, pp. 485-508. P E R L O F F / 233 One should show care in interpreting some of Hausman's results (though he is fairly careful about pointing out these limitations). Because utility levels are different across experiments, one cannot compare dead weight losses directly. Moreover, his implicit social welfare function, which is not very egalitarian, favors the policy prescription which he favors. Finally, his experiments where he compares progressive and proportional taxes are (necessarily) relatively arbitrary. A more reasonable experiment might be to reduce the number of kinks in the progressive tax constraint rather than eliminating all but one kink. That is, an intermediate policy might be even more favorable to Hausman's argument. Hausman also argues that his results, while partial equilibrium in nature, are likely to be dose to the general equilibrium effects. Since this proposition was not immediately obvious to me, I tried a few "back of the envelope" calculations to confirm this conjecture. A tax on labor income will have complicated general equilibrium effects. While the taxes are likely to influence capital, energy, output prices, and wages, Hausman's partial equilibrium analysis implicitly treats these variables as constants. The calculations reported here are actually less partial equilibrium than Hausman's rather than fully general equilibrium results, since capital and other variables are still treated as constants: only wages are allowed to adjust. In some sense, these results may be viewed as "short-run" general equilibrium ones, where the labor market has time to adjust, but the other markets have not yet adjusted. Suppose, for simplicity, the labor supply equation is written as (I) i = ( (1 - ti)w/iti, where i represents the hours worked by the ith group, t; is their marginal tax rate, W; is their wage, di their after-tax wage elasticity, and I is the nonearned income. The tax-supply elasticity is (2) ri· = 1 aiii 8t/t; d1-t; ,. = -=..!i_ The demand for each demographic group is derived from an aggregate translog production function (assuming competition): (3) wl = _Q_ (a· + L • l 1 j 0 y--lj In J ) =Q ~ M 1' l where Q is aggregate output and M; is the factor share of the i1h group (Mi = wii/total cost). 234 / HAUSMAN IJJSCUSSJON Combining (2) and (3) and differentiating, we obtain (4) £ii = ...ill.LL ot;ft; i d; l ( (Mi+Y;/M;)di - (d,+ 1)) I-ti (5) YulM, + M- and, if t, = ti = t, (6) Ej = aui = _t_ at1t 1-t cti x I - (yii / M; + Mi)/Mi + Yii /Mi - (di+ 1)/ di) ((Mi+ Yi/Mi)d; ~ (d; +I}) If the production function uses a single labor index, then only equation (6) is relevant. Using an aggregate production function with aggregate labor, capital, and energy factors, then in 1977 fourth quarter;• ct, e I 0.1 0.9748 0.2 0.9508 0.3 0.9279 0.5 0.8854 1.0 0.7944 2.0 0.6589 'This production function, the estimated coefficient\, and a description or the data is contained in Jeffrey M. Perloff and Michael L. Wachter, "A Produciion Function-Nonaccdcraiing Inllation Approad1 to Potential Output: h Mea,ured Potcmial Output Too High?" Carnegie-Rochester Conl"ercnce Series Vol. IO, 1979, Journal of Afoneiary Economics, pp. 113 - 163. PERLOFF/ 235 That is, the supply elasticity Y/i is only likely to deviate substantially from the equilibrium elasticity, Ej, if di is relatively large. For example, if di = .I, then Ei = 0.9748r,;; while if d; = 1.0, Ei = 0.7944r,;. There is substantial evidence, however, that it is inappropriate to aggregate labor into a single index. Grant and Hamermesh, using 1969 cross-sectional manufacturing data in a translog production function, have shown that it is reasonable to aggregate youths and white females, but that it is not reasonable to aggregate all of labor. Using time series data, Michael L. Wachter and I have estimated a comparable production function for the private economy using inputs of capital, energy, prime age males (M), and all other labor (0).' Using our estimated coefficients, the following adjustment factors can be calculated using equation (6): do d:vi 80 B:v1 0.1 0.1 0.1 1.0 l.O 0.1 0.5 1.0 0.1 0.5 l.O LO 0.982 0.991 0.999 0.832 0.839 0.846 1.000 0.907 0.813 1.192 1.082 0.969 Thus, if dM is approximately 0. I and d 0 is approximately 1.0, then EM ~ 1. 192r,M and r 0 ;:: 0.832r, 0 . That is, the equilibrium elasticity for prime age males would be almost 20 percent higher than the supply elasticity, while the supply elasticity would be almost 20 percent higher than the equilibrium elasticity. Of course, even if Hausman's estimates were off by as much as 20 percent, it would make no difference to most of his conclusions. Hausman's analysis is very useful in determining the costs of our income tax system. This cost must be balanced against the benefits of government goods and services and transfer programs. It should be noted, however, that a substantial part of funds collected at 'A similar model i, described in "Productivity Slowdown: A Labor Problem?" in or Boston Conference Series No. 22. June, 1980, pp. 115-142. The only difference in that model is !ha! one labor series consists of young people (under 25 years) and 1he other of older workers. The coefficients are: M 0 °· ,23465, M~1 = .49218, Yoo = .13152, Y\1\l •= .12096, Yo~1 = - .10972 The Decline in Produclivirr Growrh, Federal Reserve Bank 236 / HAUSMAN DISCUSSION some levels of government go to collecting taxes. Small U. S. counties (populations under 100,000) spent 7 .4% of their tax revenues, on average, on financial administration; while the federal government spent only about 0.7%. These figures are low, since they include only central fiscal operations (which reached $1,798 million for the federal government in 1976). The U. S. government spent 6.22% of tax revenues on general administration (which includes the cost of tax collection and all administration costs not directly attributable to specific programs). 6 'These statistics are discussed in Dick Netzer, "State-Local Finance and Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations," in Economics of Public Finance, (Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1974) and Jeffrey M. Perloff "Economies of Scale in Tax Collecting: Evidence for the U.S. and Abroad," Working Paper. Discussion of the Hamermesh Paper FREDRIC RAINES Daniel Hamermesh has undertaken an extensive survey of what we know about the impact of income maintenance programs on employment, unemployment and labor force participation. Reflected in this paper is an awesome amount of research, both that of others and his own. And, on balance, he has done an excellent job of synthesizing this literature. He is, certainly, the resident expert in this area among us. If this conference is a supplyside harvest, we may note that Hamermesh has been busy tilling the fields, and gathering the crops. However, there are problems. The first problem Hamermesh has is where to look for evidence of supply-side effects. He starts by looking at macro time series data, regressing log ~ (where U* 100-U* is the unemployment rate adjusted for shifts in demographic composition) on lagged values of two policy variables: (I) NRR-net replacement rate of aggregate transfers payments; (2) TAX-the overall tax rate on earnings. Unfortunately the results seem not to be to his liking, though they would warm the heart of a Lafferite. A one standard deviation increase in NRR from its mean raises U* from 5% to 7.85%, and a similar increase in tax raises U* from 5 % to 6. I 9%. Hamermesh then decides that truth may only be revealed by an examination of the effect of individual programs. But not everybody's examination. For instance, the 1973 study of benefits by Feldstein, which finds that Unemployment Insurance benefits and taxes have raised NAIRU by 1.25 percentage points, and a 1977 study by Clarkson and Meiners, which finds that AFDC (Aid to Families with Dependent Children) plus Food Stamps have raised the measured unemployment rate by 2 percentage points, are rejected as patently too large. Finally Hamermesh hits upon a solution. He takes the Perloff and Wachter (1979) finding that NAIRU has increased since the Fredric Raines is Associate Professor of Economics, Washington University in St. Louis. 237 238 / HAMERMESH DISCUSSION mid- l 950s by about 2 percentage points (of which slightly less than 1 percentage point is due to demographic shifts), and sees if, by an examination of individual programs, he can work up to that modest total. He also investigates what appear to be the more important effects of income maintenance programs-those on employment. A point about what it is we are trying to measure the effect on is in order here. Hamermesh makes it quite clear that a given program may have distinctly different effects on employment and unemployment. But the unemployment concept that he chooses, and the one commonly used in these studies-NAIRU-is, I would argue, incorrect. NAIRU refers to that rate of unemployment associated with balance in the product market. But the relevant concept for labor market studies is that unemployment rate which is consistent with a balanced-the number of job vacancies equal to the number of unemployed workers, say-labor market. Unless you are sufficiently neo-classical to deny or ignore differing adjustment speeds, these two concepts need not yield the same number. Indeed, if I define the latter concept as a "full employment" benchmark adjusted over time for demographic shifts-call it the natural rate of unemployment (NRU)-then I can cite the above Perloff and Wachter study as giving evidence that NRU and NAIRU have been diverging over time. But the point is that NAIRU might be consistent with a 5 percent unemployment rate at one point in time, and an 8 percent rate at another, without there being any implication or deducible inference for the impact of supply-side programs on unemployment. Putting this consideration aside, what does Hamermesh find? Examining research on four different programs: Unemployment Insurance (UI), Social Security, Disability Insurance (DI), and Aid to Families with Dependent Children plus Food Stamps (AFDC/FS), the consensus he finds is that the employment effects (and labor force participation effects) are negative in each case. However, the unemployment effects are mixed, implying reductions in NAIRU for Social Security and DI, and increases in NAIRU for UI and AFDC/FS. For the overall net effect on NAIRU of these programs, Hamermesh likes the number "zero." It should be pointed out that Hamermesh gets his reductions in NAIRU entirely through changes in the composition of the labor force. Those induced to leave the labor force due to the benefit structure of Social Security and DI, for instance, are assumed to be those with below average marketable skills and above average RAINES/ 239 unemployment rates. This is a testable proposition, and while Hamermesh does present some evidence, the full implications do not appear to have been explored. One implication is that average worker productivity should have been increasing as a result of these programs. If so, it was much more than wiped out by other factors. Another implication, which does seem borne out by overall participation data, is that the composition of the labor force is tilted toward younger workers. One may ask, is the Hamermesh approach of counting the trees to measure the forest a reasonable one? I strongly agree with him that the foundations of imputing a supply-side effect must come from observing micro behavior. There are just too many complexities that get washed out in aggregate data-and our policy proposals must deal with these complexities. At the same time, the effect of these individual programs may not be additive as Hamermesh is inclined to assume. For example, Hamermesh concludes that the net effect of AFDC/FS on labor force participation, employment, and NAIRU is slight. This conclusion is based in part on the gradual reduction in the AFDC implicit tax rate over time. But the AFDC implicit tax rate compounds with the food stamp implicit tax rate, and these compound with the implicit tax rate for Medicaid, Housing Assistance, Child Nutrition, and a few other programs. This is known as the "stacking" problem, and it implies overall effective tax rates in many cases in excess of 100 percent with numerous notches and kinks. If a 100 percent tax rate doesn't have any effect on labor supply then Laffer is really barking up the wrong tree. I have a final comment to make on "where to look" for supplyside effects. I think that, methodologically, we may want to examine the trees, but conceptually we should be thinking about the forest. The subsidies and implicit taxes of welfare programs, the tax system, and the pattern of government spending are imbedded in our institutions and our culture. I don't know what it means to say that if you abolish UI, the unemployment rate will decline by 3 percentage points. What is being held constant and what is changed? There are important trends to be explained-slow economic growth, virtually stagnant productivity, chronic inflation, dramatic shifts in labor force composition-and the causes may be bigger (or at least more subtle) than our independent variables. But the tax/transfer system, in toto, does make a difference: consider the following data on income distribution prepared by Watts & Skidmore (1977): 240 / HAMERMESH DISCUSSION INCOME SHARES OF HOUSEHOLDS lowest 40 percent highest 40 percent Before Taxes and All Transfers aAfter Taxes and Transfers 7.5% 76.2% 17.8% 64.7% aprograms include insured cash transfers, cash assistance, in-kind transfers, and income and payroll taxes. One way of looking at these numbers is to say that government programs currently move one third of the way toward instituting a completely egalitarian income distribution. I have no idea what a redistribution of this order of magnitude-and the policies that brought it about-entails for the economic behavior of individuals. But I would venture the guess that those seriously concerned about supply-side economics have bought themselves a rather large and complex research agenda. RAINES/ 241 REFERENCES Perloff, Jeffrey and Michael Wachter. "A ProductionNonaccclerating Inflation Approach to Potential Output: Is Measured Potential Too High." In Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer, eds., Three Aspects of Policymaking. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1979. Watts, Harold and Felicity Skidmore. "An Update of the Poverty Picture Plus a New Look at Relative Tax Burdens." Focus, Institute for Research on Poverty Newsletter, Fall 1977. The Power of Negative Thinking: Government Regulation and Economic Performance MURRAY L WEIDENBAUM Let me start off with a proposition duly overstated-which should fit comfortably with the remarks of other contributors to this conference on supply-side economics: it is futile to focus so heavily on tax incentives to encourage economic activity at a time when the governmental regulatory apparatus is imposing such a vast and rapidly expanding array of obstacles to economic activity. The lack of parallelism in my language is deliberate. It is not just a matter of the disincentives of regulation offsetting some of the incentives which can be provided by tax reform. Rather, it is a case of insurmountable government-imposed barriers which any increases in the normal, after-tax rate of return can do little to hurdle. For example, the most generous of tax credits will not help a company to market a product that has been banned by the government. The most liberal depreciation allowance will not assist a firm in obtaining the numerous permits which are essential to the operation of a new power plant. Indexing income tax rates will not encourage the job applicant who is turned aside by companies administering government-imposed quotas in their hiring. Nor will massive reductions in personal income taxes help the teenager who is priced out of the labor market by the latest increase in the compulsory minimum wage. Of course, this is not truly a matter of either/ or. We need not and should not choose between tax reform and regulatory reform. Rather, we should understand that the two go together. In practice, supply-side tax cuts and reductions of regulatory burdens are Murray L. Weidenbaum was Mallinckrodt Distinguished University Professor and Director of the Center for the Study of American Business, Washington University in St. Louis, when this speech was presented. He is currently Chairman of the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers. 245 246 / GOVERNMENT REGULATION/ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE mutually reinforcing. Both can increase the capacity of the economy to produce goods and services, the willingness of investors to take risks, of management to innovate, and of workers to produce. To put it less dramatically, but more specifically than I did in my opening statement, tax reform is a necessary but not sufficient condition for substantially improving the performance of the American economy. We must simultaneously deal with what I call the power of negative thinking-the ability of, or at least the tendency for, the regulatory apparatus (in truth I cannot call it a system) to make economic activity difficult to perform. So many government regulatory agencies have the power to say no to new economic undertakings; few, if any, have definite authority to say yes. To the typical entrepreneur, government is not a source of help, but the possessor of the power to stop or at least to delay and confuse. As a federal judge recently declared, "The federal bureaucracy is legally permitted to execute the Congressional mandate with a high degree of befuddlement as long as it acts no more befuddled than the Congress must reasonably have anticipated.'' It is fascinating to consider the attitudes of the proponents of that increased regulation: they view the modern corporation simultaneously as venal and omnipotent. That is, they implicitly assume that society can impose an endless variety of so-called social responsibilities on the business firm without affecting its basic ability to carry on its economic function, that of meeting consumer needs for goods and services. To bolster my point, let me cite high authority, a recent issue of the magazine Mother Jones. The editor was reporting on a conference of business executives that he had recently attended. He explained his surprise at the attitude that he had encountered. As he put it, "We had come to view executives as the sort of men who blithely market fire-trap cars, fill the Love Canal with lethal chemicals, dump hazardous products on Third World countries and conceal the dangers of asbestos from their workers ... To have perpetrated so much, unscathed-surely they must be a strong, confident breed, boldly planning new drives for profits." That is not satire, but journalism, I keep reminding myself. But the Mother Jones editor, to his surprise, found a different spirit among the executives, who "saw themselves as innocent, aggrieved producers-unfairly assaulted by environmentalists [and] regulatory agencies ... " He went on to point out, "The corporate sector, we WEIDENBAUM / 247 discovered, felt besieged. Barry Commoner, Ralph Nader, Leonid Brezhnev, Teddy Kennedy and Jane Fonda were all out to get them." It is not my purpose today to evaluate the innocence or the guilt of American business executives (whatever that would mean), but to point out the economic consequences that result from the massive range of government intervention in economic activity-which, in turn, has resulted from the pressures of the self-styled public interest groups. Subsequently, I will try to show how any effective, supply-oriented approach to public policy can take account of this phenomenon. THE MANY COSTS OF GtWERNMENT REGULATION Most public and professional attention to the costs of government regulation has focused on the direct burdens of complying with government directions. You may recall my estimate that, at the federal level, these costs were in the neighborhood of $ l 00 billion in 1979 and rising rapidly. Granted the imperfections of my rudimentary techniques-I note that nobody else has attempted to take on such a task -1 now acknowledge the important costs of regulation that I neglected to take into account in my computations. Let me enumerate some of these costs. It will become clear soon enough why I did not include them in my numbers. I am referring to the induced effects of regulation, the most diffuse and elusive aspect of measuring the impacts of regulation. But for the policymaker, what is truly important is not the precise dollar quantities but the direction of the impacts. Clearly, most of these induced effects of regulation impair the basic ability of the American economic system to perform. Let me enumerate the key types of induced regulatory costs. 1. The innovative product and process research and development that is not undertaken because corporate research and development budgets increasingly are being devoted to what is termed ''defensive research. " Many companies report that they devote large and growing shares of their scientific resources-from one fifth to one half -to meeting regulatory requirements or avoiding running afoul of regulatory restrictions. Surely, the longer it takes for a new product to be approved by a government agency and the more costly and uncertain the approval process, the more likely that innovation will be delayed and the rate of innovation reduced. Invariably, it is discouraging to the innovative instincts of business firms to undergo experiences like the one recently had by 248 / GOVERNMENT REGULATION/ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Monsanto, the chemical company, with its recyclable plastic bottle for soft drinks. The Food and Drug Administration banned this new product because it was made with acrylonitrile. The regulators say that if the bottles were filled with acetic acid (and not soda pop) and stored for six months at 120°F., an infinitesimal amount of the acrylonitrile could leak into the solution-and that would constitute a carcinogenic (and hence unlawful) food additive. On the basis of this less than brilliant experiment, Monsanto dosed down aH the factories making the product and laid off several thousand workers. But these problems are not just a matter of large companies or of one obstinate government agency. A small R&D oriented company, Nutrilite Products, reported similar negative experiences. After repeated efforts to obtain approval for a new "biological" form of insect control (instead of the more environmentally hazardous but traditional "chemical" approaches), the company concluded, "We're going back to making vitamin supplements and trying to stay as far away as possible from the Environmental Protection Agency." In effect, government is building what Lee Loevinger, former chairman of the Federal Trade Commission, calls " 'legal envelope' around existing technology.'' 2. The new investments in plant and equipment that are not made because of regulatory barriers and the diversion of investment funds to meeting government-mandated social requirements. The cost of potential new investments is raised by the uncertainties generated in the permit-approval process and by the cloudy future of new rounds of regulation. Delays surely have become the order of the day. In 1975, it took Deere and Company, the agricultural equipment manufacturer, only three months to receive a complete environmental permit review for constructing a new plant. Currently, Deere estimates the lag at two years. Although the company has received most of the permits it has requested, it reports that EPA has insisted that these permits contain reopener clauses in case the agency adopts more restrictive standards in the future. In another instance, after noting that 42 different federal, state, regional, county, and municipal agencies regulate his new aquaculture company, George Lockwood, president of Monterey Abalone Farms, stated in a paper to the AAAS that the major problem ls not the direct costs of compliance but "the great uncertainty" about whether any new activity wiH meet rapidly changing regulatory standards. Professor Ossar Lindbeck of the University of Stockholm has commented on this phenomenon which apparently is not unique to W E IDE NBA UM / 249 the United States. He points out that if laws and regulations change "violently" all the time, the returns accruing from correct speculation about the next moves of the regulatory authority often become higher than the returns from careful investment in skills, product development, choice of production technique, and marketing. Professor Lindbeck contends, and I tend to share his concern, that the sluggish behavior of investment activity in most Western economies during recent years is derived not only from low short-term profits, but also from increased uncertainty about future government policies and the future rules of the game. The problems facing firms which introduce new technology arc especially great. Here is the assessment of a task force of the U.S. Energy Resources Council on the overall impact of regulatory activity on the establishment of a new energy industry: "In summary, some of these [regulatory] requirements could easily hold up or permanently postpone any attempt to build and operate a synthetic fuels plant." The recent cancellation of the SOHIO pipeline project provides striking evidence that the regulatory uncertainties are not limited in their adverse impacts to new technologies or even controversial ones. Where government approvals are forthcoming, we find that a rising share of company investment is being devoted to meeting governmentally imposed social requirements. In recent years, outlays mandated by EPA and OSHA have come to about 10 percent of new capital formation in American industry. In a pioneering study, Edward Denison estimated that the diversion of this amount of new capital resulted in business productivity in 1975 being I .4 percent lower than it otherwise would have been. One percent may not seem like much but, in recent years, that would have been the difference between a rise and a fall in the overall productivity of the economy. Moreover, we cannot always assume that the loss of private productivity is offset by an improvement in some area of social concern. For example, Armco Steel Corporation was required to install special scrubbing equipment at one of its plants to reduce the emission of visible iron oxide dust. The scrubber does succeed in capturing 21.2 pounds per hour of the pollutant. However, it is run by a 1,020-horsepower electric motor. In producing the power for that motor, the electric utility's plant spews out 23 .0 pounds per hour of sulfur and nitrogen oxides and other gaseous pollutants. Thus, even though Armco is meeting government regulations on visible emissions, the air is actually 1. 8 pounds per hour dirtier because of the government's regulatory requirements. 250 / GOVERNMENT REGULATION/ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE The Armco case is no isolated example. Scrubbers are increasingly becoming required equipment for electric utilities that are attempting to comply with EPA regulations. The federal agencies, by being unable or unwilling to consider the adverse but indirect effects of their actions, are likely to produce more instances in which unintended but undesirable side effects swamp the benefits. Consider the sad story of the Pennsylvania Power Company. That utility has a new 825-megawatt complex that utilizes scrubbers. In extracting the pollutants from coal, it produces 18,000 tons of sludge a day. To dispose of the sludge, the company has been forced to build a 350-foot-high dam, the largest earth and rock enbankment east of the Mississippi River. Behind the dam, there is now a lake of sludge, which already covers 900 acres in a picturesque valley of Western Pennsylvania! Moreover, the regulations issued under the 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments will slow down, if not halt, industrial expansion in many parts of this nation. If and when the rulings are fully enforced, failure of a state to win EPA approval of its detailed clean air plan will result in an absolute prohibition of any new industrial construction in that state. 3. The workers that are not hired because federal regulations have priced them out of labor markets. A variety of serious academic studies has shown that the steady increases in the statutory minimum wage have reduced teenage employment significantly below what it otherwise would have been-without a comparable offsetting increase in adult employment. The DavisBacon Act yields similar results in government-financed construction -lower employment and higher inflation rates. 4. The immeasurable effects of government regulation on the basic entrepreneurial nature of the private enterprise system. To the extent that management's attention is diverted from traditional business concerns to meeting government requirements, a significant bureaucratization of corporate activity results. Many chief executives now report that one third or more of their time is devoted to governmental and public policy matters. Donald Rumsfeld, chief executive of a major drug company and former Congressman and Secretary of Defense, has described very personally the pervasiveness of government involvement in business: When I get up in the morning as a businessman, l think a lot more about government than I do about our competition, because government is that much involved-whether it's HEW, IRS, SEC, FTC, or FDA. l always understood the problem intellectually, but the specific inefficiencies that result from the government injecting itself into practically every aspect of our business-that is something one can feel only by being here. W E 1 D E N B AU M / 251 This bureaucratization of entrepreneurial activity, albeit undramatic, is not of modest dimensions. Professor Douglas North of the University of Washington contends that the key marg1n of decision making in our society today is access to government influence. As he describes the matter, the predictable result is "to shift the focus of the investment of resources into attempts to favorably influence the strategic government official or to prevent the enactment of government policies that will adversely affect the interest of groups." The point may be overstated. There are still many more opportunities for private undertakings. Moreover, the adverse public reaction to massive use of business resources in politics would, under present circumstances at least, be overwhelming. Nevertheless, North is indicating an important emerging development, especially in the case of the larger business organizations. Furthermore, Professor Lindbeck, from his different vantage point, has made a similar observation, As he puts it, "there will be great temptations," particularly for large firms, to bargain with politicians over the rules and to seek various "deals" with governmental authorities. Lindbeck notes the risk of businesses entering into "zero-sum games" where they concentrate on bargaining with governments rather than trying to increase output. APPROACHES TO POLJCY CHANGES It may, however, be easier to identify the regulatory problem areas than to develop effective strategies for change. At the outset, we must recognize the source of many of the pressures for regulation-the self-appointed, self-styled public interest groups. Large segments of the media, as well as many legislators, view these groups automatically as both "representatives" and as underdogs. This simpleminded attitude results in the characterization of people who disagree with them as the "heavies." But just because I may disagree with Ralph Nader or Jane Fonda should not inevitably be taken as my representing some special interest opposed to the public welfare. Why not think the unthinkable? It just may happen that, on occasion, Ralph (or Jane} may be wrong. Many-but not all-representatives of the public interest groups confuse their personal prejudices with the national well-being. Surely, I do not claim to represent the public interest. In all of my years in government, I never met a mortal man or woman who truly represented the public interest. As someone who was intimately involved in government policymaking, I know that 252 / G O V E R N M E N T R E G U L AT l O N / E CO N O M l C P E R F O R M AN CE making good policy is far more difficult than merely choosing, in a simpleminded fashion, between ''public" or "consumer" interests (which are presumably good and to be supported) and business interests (which are presumably evil and to be opposed), Effective policymaking consists not of dramatic confrontation, but of carefully balancing and reconciling a variety of legitimate interests -such as clean air and low inflation, safe products and high employment, healthy working conditions and rising productivity. In addition, the one thing this new breed of interest groups lack is a sense of humor. For example, they attacked OSHA for stopping the distribution of one of its pamphlets. OSHA had issued a pamphlet on farm safety which treated farmers like dummies. One of the newspapers in the nation's farm belt answered with the following editorial in the form of a Dick and Jane book, the kind you read in the first grade. Let me read it so you can decide for yourselves. DICK AND JANE V[SIT THE FARM See the book. See the little book. See the little OSHA book. What is OSHA? OSHA is your government. OSHA is the Occupational Safety and Health Administration, OSHA helps people. OSHA helps people to be safe. OSHA made the little book for farmers. What does the little book say? This is what it says: "Be careful around the farm . .. hazards are one of the main causes of accidents. A hazard is anything that is dangerous. "Be careful when you are handling animals. Tired or hungry or frightened cattle can bolt and trample you. Be patient, talk softly around the cows. Don't talk fast or be loud around them. ff they are upset, don't go into the pen with them. "Be careful thal you do not fall info the manure pits. Pu/ up signs and fences to keep people away. These pits are ve1y dangerous. '' WETDENBAUM / 253 See the farmer. See the farmer go to the mail box. See the farmer get the little book. The farmer can read. The farmer can read big words. The farmer can read long sentences. The farmer knows about fences. The farmer knows about manure pits. Now the farmer knows about OSHA. See the farmer kick the mail box. Hear the farmer say bad words. See the farmer throw the little book. See the farmer throw the little book into the manure pit. See OSHA. See OSHA write. See OSHA throw money into the manure pit. Say bad words about OSHA. Basically, we have to realize that the variety of regulatory activity requires a variety of reform approaches. Eliminating regulation makes good sense in those areas where the consumer is better served by market competition. Energy is a prime example. Eliminating the entire apparatus of energy price restrictions, allocation controls, entitlements, and reporting requirements would result in more domestic production, more conservation, and reduced imports of foreign oil. Deregulation of airlines, trucking, and railroads are also good examples of regulatory reform oriented to supply-side concerns. For the social regulations, there is no good alternative to revising the basic statutes under which the regulations are promulgated. The zero-risk approach of the Delaney Amendment to the Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act is a cogent example of unrealistic and unreasonable social regulation which can be effectively curtailed only by rewriting the law. Given the multiplication of regulatory statutes, what would truly help is, yes, yet another statute, one requiring compulsory benefit/ cost tests. Each agency should be required to demonstrate in advance that its rulings will generate more benefits to the nation than costs-hopefully, that the marginal benefits equal the marginal costs and that it has chosen the most cost-effective approach. The promulgation of rules, of course, is not rhe only means of accomplishing public objectives. As economists have been trying to 254 / GOVERNMENT REGULATlON/ECONOMlC PERFORMANCE explain to government decision makers, pollution taxes could constitute a far less costly method of achieving water quality objectives. Interestingly enough, the business community, which shows little enthusiasm for regulation, is adamantly opposed to this use of the price system. Not that it is necessarily relevant, but I note that environmental standards, unlike pollution taxes, tend to be rougher on new industries than on established facilities. But as we have learned over the years, the most adamant foe of government intervention eventually learns how to convert a government rule to a barrier to entry. As Lee Loevinger has noted, "Thus small enterprises are slowly squeezed out and barriers to entry are established by government fiat that would make an oldfashioned monopolist either envious or embarrassed." In many other areas of government intervention, notably consumer product safety, an information strategy is an alternative to compulsory standards or product bans. Interestingly enough, this approach often is favored in consumer surveys, although not by the more vocal consumer organizations. A word of caution: any realistic appraisal of government regulation must acknowledge that important and positive benefits have resulted from some of the regulatory activities-less pollution, fewer product hazards, a reduction in job discrimination, and other desirable goals of our society. But the "externalities" generated by federal regulation do not justify government attempting to regulate every facet of private behavior. CONCLUSION To sum up: the response of the economy to supply-oriented tax policy will be greatly enhanced by reducing the numerous regulatory obstacles to economic activity. Failure to eliminate or at least substantially cut back the regulatory inhibitions to work, invest, and produce will result in disappointing returns from tax policy changes. Government policymakers must come to realize the lack of symmetry in the two different policy mechanisms: tax changes can provide strong incentives to undertake private economic activity, but regulation can provide a simple but effective veto. Too many of the debates on supply-side economic policy have ignored or at least deemphasized the crucial power of negative thinking on the part of the regulatory apparatus. The Politics of Supply-Side Economics ORRIN G. HATCH We have, in the Congress, a thing called a "budget process." You may not have noticed it, but it's there. It was the subject of heated debate when it was established in the middle 1970s, when many legislators who were worried about spending voted for it on the grounds that it would force us all to think about the financial consequences of our various programs, to reconcile them, and to set priorities. It hasn't done that. In fact, deficits have gotten worse since the budget process began, and government spending is now approaching proportions of the GNP previously reached only in wartime. What the budget process did achieve was an infallible method of providing rationales for increased spending, usually in terms of an alleged rise in unemployment should government spending be reduced in the economy, but sometimes by means of specialized studies on technical issues. I might add here that the one area where the budget process did act to inhibit spending was defense, where it tended to challenge the specific requests made by the Pentagon and its friends in Congress. By coincidence, this reflected the political priorities of the party controlling Congress at the time and the predilections of the staff members coming onto the Hill during the Vietnam era. All this happened in spite of the fact that the Congressional Budget Act of 1974 set up a body called the Congressional Budget Office, which was supposed to provide politicians in both Houses with dispassionate, objective, and professional assessments of policy proposals. As it turned out, it was the CBO that provided the arguments for increased spending, and it backed them up with an imposing array of evidence from a variety of econometric models, much of it written in Greek and emanating from computerswhich, as you know, never lie. For that matter, since economics is a Orrin G. Hatch is U.S. Senator (R.-Utah) 255 256 /SUPPLY-SIDE POLITICS science, many legislators, although puzzled, concluded that economists couldn't lie either, and that if they said deficits were OK, they must be. There are in reality value judgments at the heart of the Keynesian orthodoxy, and particularly at the heart of the Keynesian proponents. This is not just a matter of Alice Rivlin (the supposedly impartial head of the CBO and one of what Newsweek magazine called the "half dozen leading liberal economists") dining with Senator Kennedy to prepare him for his challenge to Mr. Carter last year. (Another CBO projection bites the dust!) It isn't even just a matter of the faulty underlying assumptions contained in the CBO projections, although these are often rather odd. The CBO, as you all know from reading the literature, has for years systematically favored spending increases over tax reductions as a means of stimulating the economy, and, at one time, it was even using a model which assumed that a decrease in corporate taxation would reduce GNP. Where the element of faith in the Keynesian orthodoxy really comes into its own is in the CBO's steady resistance to any sort of analytical or empirical debate about its assumptions. We had a particularly graphic example of this in the spring of 1980. There is abroad in the Western world at the moment, a particularly lethal weapon that has totally altered the balance of power between employers and the employed. This weapon is called the Xerox machine, and some anonymous dissident on the Budget Committee staff used it to send us a copy of a memo (written to Ed Muskie, then Chairman of the Budget Committee, from his staff director) discussing detailed collaboration between the CBO head and the Democrats on the Committee to suppress Republican efforts for a hearing on the econometric models CBO uses. These models, of course, are under severe attack for ignoring the incentive effect, and we were hoping to get CBO to consider some of the supply-side thinking now going on, of which this conference is a symptom. The memo told Muskie: "Alice [Rivlin] doesn't really want to have hearings and would like to put Hatch off somehow. She says -and Susan Lepper (the Majority Economist) supports her in this - that the critics of the models CBO uses for forecasting are an extreme right wing claque who should not be given an audience, lest it legitimize their views and give Hatch a forum which should be denied him if we could. If we are to hold hearings, Alice believes they should involve noted economists telling the Committee that Hatch's witnesses are wrong .... " HATCH / 257 Later on in the memo, the staff director told Muskie: "I am tempted to have him [me] off on this tangent, which few people know or care about outside the economics profession, rather than leave him with time to become involved with something that might be more serious .... " None of this looks particularly objective or dispassionate, or for that matter even scientific, to me. Of course, I'm just a lawyer. I think the sad thing about all of this is that the people involved, whether political appointees like the Democratic staffers or civil servants like the CBO functionaries, ar; not in themselves dishonest or conniving people. The nature of the system causes them to act in this way because their own short-term interests are so very clearly involved. Although bureaucrats and politicians-at least certain politicians -do benefit from continual deficits and pervasive inflation, the system is unstable. Inflation is only a temporary answer to the problem of separating the taxpayers of this world from their earnings. For one thing, the dislocation it causes annoys and distresses them. For another, the combination of inflated incomes carrying more individuals into higher tax brackets, and government expenditures which are steadily mounting, means that the underlying resistance to taxes is steadily increasing. More and more people are being pushed into the fiscal free-fire zone. They are reacting by digging fox-holes, constructing tax shelters, and generally refusing to obey orders. This is a particularly acute problem for the economists of our "ruling class" -because that's what the Keynesians, in effect, are. Their system is entirely set up to suppress insurrections from people who believe in balanced budgets-and there are still a lot of them about, incidentally. All they have to do is show that balancing the budget will cause economic disruption, besides requiring either tax increases or spending reductions. But they don't have any way of dealing with the negative incentives of their system, except more government intervention to divide up the pie or to treat the symptoms of rising prices and wages. This is why we hear so much now about "zero-sum societies," lowered expectations, spiritual malaises, and so on. Tacitus said the Romans made a desert in Germany, and called it peace. We can say of the economic establishment that it has made a stagnant pond, and called it the Great Society. Still, it has been good for real estate prices in Georgetown. And it is causing us to rejoin the human race-with a command economy, with welfare for people and corporations. 258 / SUPPLY~ SIDE POLITICS In other words, supply-side economics has arrived in exactly the situation the late Harry Johnson diagnosed as existing at the time of the advent of Keynes, at the onset of the Depression: ... On the one hand, the existence of an important social and political problem with which the prevailing orthodoxy was unable to cope; on the other hand, [a new theory with] a variety of characteristics that appealed to the younger generation of that period-notably the claim of the new theory to superior social relevance and intellectual distinction, its incorporation in a novel and confusing fashion of the valid elements of traditional theory, the opportunity it offered to bypass the system of academic seniority by challenging senior colleagues ... [and] the advancement of a new empirical relationship callenging for econometricians to estimate. This may sound cynical, but it isn't really. As we have seen, economic policy is an area where even the most qualified professionals seem to have trouble keeping their minds open to new and inconvenient ideas. In that respect, it's unlike academic lifeI hope. If any theory is to flourish in this environment, it must be protected by its political mentors. Keynes, incidentally, was fully aware of this and used every trick he could think of to advance his views. He had an extremely active mind, so he thought of a lot of tricks. The best way of thinking about economic policy is by comparing it to a dog fight between World War II fighters. You have to aim at some point other than at the target itself in order to hit it, given your relative motion and so on. This is something that Keynes understood. He told Friedrich von Hayek that he realized his policy prescription would be inherently inflationary, but that when the moment came he would step in and turn public opinion around in six weeks. When Hayek tells this story, he always adds, with an ironic grin, that six weeks later Keynes was dead. But the point is that Keynes wanted to solve certain problems and he wanted to change policymakers' thinking about them, and the importance they put on them. In a sense, you could argue that there's an element of myth about all economic policy proposals-as defined by the French historian Sorel, who said many years ago that myths in human society were not factual statements, but were instead expressions of intentions to act. Keynes was successful in getting all of us-not merely liberalsto accept his values. And I believe that those who have developed the supply-side theories will be successful in shifting our attention once again to incentives and production and the economic applications of liberty. As I say, this isn't merely an academic achievement. It is a political achievement of no small merit. What HATCH / 259 the supply-siders have done is to point out that the war between the proponents of incentives and the federal government's spending constituencies is not necessary. It is possible to attack at another point: to get tax rates down and stimulate growth sufficiently to pay for the current rate of social services, hence bypassing the question of whether social spending is too high. Now, will these services be paid for out of tax revenues that have increased absolutely, while decreasing in terms of rates levied on individuals? Or will they be financed out of additional savings generated by increased production? Or will we in fact find further deficits, albeit in the context of a policy that promises to get the country moving again rather than sinking under taxes and regulation? There are various answers to these questions, but in a broader sense, these questions are upstaged by the new awareness in the public debate of incentives-that there is supply as well as demand. An example of this new awareness came in Mr. Carter's recently proposed tax package, which seems as if it were designed to catch attention as an alternative to Mr. Reagan's tax proposal. No one can deny the White House's exquisite sensitivity to currents abroad in the land-to style, if not to substance. When you look at President Carter's proposals in detail, you can see the extraordinary gains the supply~side offensive has made in the last two years-and also the stubborn and ferocious determination of the economic establishment to maintain and expand its power and that of the government, come what may. A recent H. C. Wainwright study by Paul Craig Roberts shows how President Carter's tax cut is really aimed at objectives other than tax reduction. In the matter of a few short months over the summer, President Carter went from teBing the American people that the $36 billion tax cut proposed by Governor Reagan would cause "fierce inflation" to proposing a $27 .6 billion tax cut of his own, which he said would be "anti-inflationary." Following on the heels of the Senate Finance Committee's proposal for a $39 billion tax cut, it put to rest the argument that the Reagan-Kemp-Roth tax cut was bad politics. So we can now move to the merits of the proposals and determine which would provide the most incentives to increase production. By comparison, the Kemp-Roth tax cut bill proposed by Governor Reagan is clearly a supply-side proposal, since it concentrates solely on reducing marginal tax rates, Measured by static revenue losses, it is more heavily weighted toward 260 /SUPPLY-SIDE POLITICS "individual" rather than "business" tax reductions. The Senate Finance Committee bill, although it wastes about $7 billion on enlarging the zero bracket amount, personal exemption, and earned income tax credit, is largely an application of incentive-oriented supply-side economics. It gives 56 percent of its cut to individuals and 44 percent to business. President Carter's proposal is more heavily weighted toward business, giving it 55 percent of the cut. But, although the Carter proposal is cloaked in supply-side rhetoric, a closer look shows that it is designed to achieve ends quite different from lowering marginal tax rates or increasing production incentives. One example is the refundable investment tax credit. The purpose of the investment tax credit is to boost the incentive for investment in new equipment; there is no economic sense to excluding firms with no tax liability. It is often new and rapidly growing firms that have no tax liability against which to apply a non-refundable credit. But the main problem with the refundable investment tax credit is the precedent it establishes. How could we hope to avoid making, say, the child care tax credit refundable for poor people if big business has it? The child care tax credit is expensive-up to $800 per eligible return-and making it refundable would be a big step toward expansion of the federal welfare system. The refundable investment tax credit would also expand the federal welfare concept to business. It would establish the concept of extending the dole to businesses that lose money. It would result in an institutionalized bail-out scheme instead of making the Congress consider it on a case-by-case basis. This is hardly the way to "make careful investments in American productivity" -Carter's way of differentiating his tax cut from Reagan's. Another part of the President's proposal that will contribute to the growth of government intervention in the economy is the additional 10 percent refundable investment tax credit targeted to revitalize depressed areas. Firms that want to qualify must obtain certificates of necessity from the Commerce Department, but the criteria for determining eligible areas are not defined. This would give the government the ability to reward its friends and withhold the credit from the uncooperative. Even if the system could be kept free of political corruption, government allocation of resources will certainly reduce efficiency in the economy. We should also note that President Carter is also suggesting that the Treasury Secretary be given the power to adjust depreciation rates at will. This is another expansion of the government's HATCH / 261 discretionary power. And it's likely that the accumulated effect of his proposed substitution of open-end for vintage accounting will tend to reduce the present value of the depreciation allowance for technical reasons. So the pro-business aspects of Mr. Carter's plan can be-and have been-exaggerated. On the individual side of the Carter tax package, an income tax credit is used to partially offset the scheduled increase in the social security tax out of general revenue funds. Instead of reducing marginal tax rates, it is a scheme to redistribute income and turn social security into a welfare program by taking the first step into general revenue financing. If the President were really interested in avoiding the economic damage that will result from the social security tax increases, he could just postpone or repeal the scheduled increase. The only reason for the income tax credit approach is to attack the contributory nature of social security and plunge into general revenue financing. This type of tax cut is likely to guarantee continuing revenue losses and deficits. Although it has the smallest static revenue loss, it would probably be the most expensive, net of feedback, because of the negative supply-side effects. On the whole, the Carter tax cut encompasses the welfare rather than the incentive approach to tax policy. Most of its provisions increase the discretionary power of the government to control the economy. It would divert resources from economic to political uses, and would lead to deficits and revenue losses that would prevent us from getting the incentive tax cuts the economy needs to grow. Furthermore, the Democratic Platform contains 70 separate items that will result in federal government spending. Over the next five years, the platform would cost $608 billion in budget authority and $431 billion in outlays. In comparison to the Senate Budget Committee's second budget resolution for FY 1981, the Democratic Platform would add $74 billion in budget authority and $30 billion in outlays in FY I 981, and $566 billion in budget authority and $389 billion in outlays over the FY 1981 to 1985 period. If enacted into law, the Democratic Platform would cause federal outlays to increase to 24. 7 percent of GNP in 1982, and this includes no additional outlays for interest on the public debt due to the higher deficits. Coupled with President Carter's tax cut, it would create a $261 billion deficit over the next five years as opposed to the $75 billion surplus Governor Reagan's plan would create. I want to conclude tonight by commenting on the checkered fortunes of the tax revolt since it first materialized in California in 262 / S U P P L Y - S l D E P O L I T I C S 1978. Since then, it has been periodically proclaimed to have run out of steam. Certainly the lobbying groups arrayed on the side of increased spending still seem to be alive and dangerous; victory has been by no means as automatic as it first appeared it might be. But it might be remembered that we are fighting a momentum that has built up over a period of decades. The proponents of income redistribution, deficits and government intervention took years to perfect their appeal to the broad electorate, and to overcome the doubts, scruples and skepticism of the American people about charity, the expropriation of property, and the surrender of independence that the welfare state entails. It will take us years, too-although the success we have had in forcing our opponents to steal our rhetoric is evidence of some sort of progress. And in the end, our task will be easier. It is the processes of liberty that we are fighting for, and they are intrinsic to the American tradition. After all, it was a dispute over taxation that triggered the American Revolution. It is not surprising-it is, indeed, highly appropriatethat we should have gathered here to think about tax policy in the consciousness that what we have been doing in reality is to contemplate at least the success and perhaps, ultimately, the survival of liberty itself.