The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Federal Reserve Staff Study- Volume I New Monetary Control Procedures Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System February 1981 Federal Reserve Staff Study New Monetary Control Procedures VOLUME I Stephen Axilrod Overview of Fmdmgs and Evaluation Richard Davis Monetary Aggregates and the Use of"Intermediate Targets" m Monetary Pohcy Jared Enzler Economic Disturbances and Monetary Pohcy Responses Jared Enzler and Lewis Johnson Cycles Resultmg from Money Stock Targetmg Margaret Greene The New Approach to Monetary Pohcy-A View From the Foreign Exchange Tradmg Desk Dana Johnson and Others Interest Rate Vanabihty Under the New Operatmg Procedures and the Imtial Response m Fmanc1al Markets Peter Keir Impact of Discount Pohcy Procedures on the Effectiveness of Reserve Targetmg Fred Levm and Paul Meek Implementmg the New Procedures The View From the Tradmg Desk https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Federal Reserve Staff Study of the New Monetary Control Procedure· Overview of Findings and Evaluation by Stephen H. Axilrod February 1981 (Appeared originally as appendix to Monetary Policy Report to Congress by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System dated February 25, 1981) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al- February 1981 APPENDIX Staff Study of the New Monetary Control Procedure: Overview of Findings and Evaluation This paper reviews experience with the new monetary control procedure established in October 1979 and evaluates implications for current and alternative control techniques. The new procedure involved employing reserve aggregates--on a day-to-day basis, nonborrowed reserves-as operating tools for achieving control of the money supply. Less emphasis was thereby placed on confining short-term fluctuations in the federal funds rate--the overnight market rate reflecting the demand for and supply of bank reserves. The change in procedure, it should be pointed out, represented a technical innovation rather than a change in the broader objectives of monetary policy or in the monetary targets themselves. Target ranges for various measures of the money supply, together with the actual behavior of money in the course of 1980, are shown in the charts on the next three pages. The paper is divided into three sections. Section I presents - an overview of findings about effects of the new monetary control procedure on economic and financial behavior based on evidence gathered in staff papers. 1 / Because the new control procedure was designed to strengthen the System's ability to control the money supply, section II (page AlS) provides certain additional background analysis relevant to assessment of the role of money as an intermediate target for monetary policy. Section III (page A21) then contains an evaluation of the current operating procedure, and alternatives. 1/ A list of staff papers prepared appears on page A33. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Growth Ranges and Actual Monetary Growth M-1A B1lhons of dollars 400 - - Range adopted by FOMC for 1979 04 to 1980 04 ~❖-9;,;:r Range adJusted for unexpected shifts -« ""~ into ATS and related accounts* 390 380 Rate of Growth 370 197Q 04 to 1980 04 5 O Percent 0 N 1979 D J F M A M J J A S 0 N D 1980 * The shaded hnes reflect ad1ustments that should be made for technical reasons to the original range for M-1 A to allow for unanticipated shifts of ex1st1ng deposits from demand deposits to interest-bearing transactions accounts, such as ATS (automatic transfer savings) and related accounts At the beginning of 1 980 1t appeared that such shifts would have Just a hm1ted effect on growth of M-1 A, and the longer-run growth range for M-1 A was set only ½ percentage point below the growth range for M-1 B Passage of the Monetary Control Act subsequently altered the financial environment by making permanent the authority of banks to offer ATS accounts and by perm1tt1ng all 1nst1tut1ons to offer NOW and s1m1lar accounts beginning 1n 1981 As the year progressed, banks , offered ATS accounts more actively and more funds than expected were being diverted 'to these accounts from demand deposits Such shifts are estimated to have depressed M-1 A growth over the year 1 980 by ¾ to 1 percentage point more than had been onginally anticipated The shaded range allows for these unant1c1pated shifts, and therefore in an economic sense more accurately represents the intentions underlying the ong1nal target https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Growth Ranges and Actual Monetary Growth M-1B 81llrons of dollars 420 - - Range adopted by FOMC for 1979 04 to 1980 04 l@%: Range adjusted for unexpected shifts ,\'-'- mto ATS and related accounts* 410 400 Rate of Growth 390 1971=( Q4 to 1980 Q4 7 3 Percent 0 N 1979 D J F M A M J J A S 0 N D 1980 * The shaded lines reflect adjustments that should be made for technical reasons to the orrgmal range for M-1 B to allow for unant1c1pated shifts mto mterest-beanng transactions accounts from savings deposits and other instruments not included m M-1 B At the begInnmg of 1980 1t appeared that such shifts would have Just a limited effect on growth of M-1 B, and the longer-run growth range for M-1 B was set only ½ percentage point above the growth range for M-1 A Passage of the Monetary Control Act subsequently altered the financial environment by making permanent the authority of banks to offer ATS accounts and by permitting all mstrtutIons to offer NOW and s1m1lar accounts begmnmg m 1981 As the year progressed, banks offered ATS accounts more actively and more funds than expected were being diverted to the accounts Such shifts are estimated to have increased M-1 B growth over the year 1980 by ½ to ¾ of a percentage point more than had been ant1c1pated The shaded range allows for these unant1cIpated shifts, and therefore In an economic sense more accurately represents the IntentIons underlying the ong1nal target Growth Ranges and Actual Monetary and Bank Credit Growth M-2 BIiiions of dollars 1700 - Range adopted by FOMC for 1979 04 to 1980 04 Rate of Growth 1979 04 to 1980 04 9 8 Percent 1600 1550 J FM AM 1979 J J AS 0 N D 1980 M-3 BIiiions of dollars 2000 Rate of Growth 1979 04 to1980 04 9 9 Percent 1900 1800 0 N D J FM AM 1979 J JASON D 1980 Commercial Bank Credit Billions of dollars 1280 Rate of Growth 9% 1979 04 to 1980 04 7 9 Percent 1220 1160 0 N 1979 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis D J F M A M J J 1980 A S O N D -A2I. Overview of Findings with Regard to Experience since Adoption of New Procedure Questions investigated in reviewing experience with the new control procedure included, among others, its impact on precision of money control, volatility of interest rates, the course of economic activity, and exchange market conditions. There were, of course, other influences on financial markets and the broader economy that were surely of far more importance than the particular technical innovations under consideration here. Indeed, a major problem has been to distinguish the impacts of the new procedure per'~ from larger influences operating on the economy. This difficulty is particularly acute given the relatively short period of time since the new procedure was implemented--a period of time that may have been too short for market participants to have fully adjusted to the new environment and a period of time in which markets were buffeted by changing inflationary expectations, fiscal uncertainties, credit controls, and oil price shocks. A. Relation between reserves and money 1. Over the operating periods between FOMC meetings, actual nonbor- rowed reserves fell below the Trading Desk's operating target by about 0.1 of 1 percent on average; the average absolute miss was about 0.4 of 1 percent. These deviations reflected in part errors in projection of uncontrollable factors affecting reserves (such as float). In addition, the Desk at times accommodated to variations relative to expectations in banks' demand for borrowing in the course of a bank statement week (for example, an unexpected willingness by banks to obtain reserves by borrowing heavily over a weekend). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Total reserves came out somewhat above -A3intermeeting period paths, by ahout 0.2 of a percent on average; the absolute miss averaged about 0.8 of a percent. The individual intermeet- ing period misses reflected deviation of money stock from short-run targets, variations in excess reserves, and multiplier adJustments to the original path (to take account of changes in required reserves for a given level of deposits) that turned out to be incomplete. 2. Econometric evidence from simulations of monthly money market models carried out with various reserve measures as operating targets (nonborrowed and total reserves and the monetary base), given the existing institutional framework, buttresses indications from actual experience last year that the relationship between reserves and money is relatively loose in the short run. Over the one-year period since October 1979, the mean absolute error of misses in the level of M-lB relative to target path during the 4- to 7-week operating periods between FOMC meetings was a little over 0.6 of a percent. This degree of variability was in line with--in some cases less than and in some cases more than--model simulation results (holding various reserve measures at predetermined target levels for the simulations) . .!./ In comparing the models and the reserve technique actually used, it should also be observed that model simulations generally implied more interest rate variability last year than proved to be the product of the technique actually in use. 1/ The root mean square errors of actual misses and simulated model misses ranged around .7 to .8 of a percent over short-run operating periods of a month or so. This would mean that, with disturbances similar to last year's, two-thirds of the time M-lB would generally come within plus or minus .7 to .8 of a percent of the intermeeting target path over approximately a one-month period (or, expressed in annual rate terms, within a range of plus or minus 8 to 10 percentage points over such a period). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A43. In the model simulations of the past year, control of money supply through strict adherence to a total reserves or total monetary base target produced more slippage than control through the nonborrowed counterparts of each. This phenomenon largely reflects the presence of multiplier disturbances on the qupply side that would be generated, for example, in the current institutional environment by changes in deposit mix and hence in required reserves for any given level of money supply. In the model simulations, use of total reserves or the total base as an invariant target over the control period does not permit these disturbances to be cushioned by changes in borrowings. 4.- Judgmental predictions of the multiplier relationship between reserves or hase measures and money made since the shift in operating procedure were generally superior to, though on a few tests not significantly different from, forecasts derived from econometric-models. 5. Over a longer period than a month (or than an intermeeting period) errors in the predicted relationship between money and reserves may be expected to average out--that is, over time, errors in one direction tend to be offset by errors in the other. Simulations of the Board's monchly model suggest that such a process is at work. In actual operations over a one-year period since October 1979, the absolute miss in the level of M-lB when individual misses relative to the short-run target paths are averaged over three or four intermeeting periods was reduced from a little over 0.6 of a percent (reported above) to over 0.4 of a percent. This represents a somewhat s111aller reduction than would have been expected from certain results, and may have reflected the nature of unusually large, unanticipated successive month-to-month changes in money https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A5demand last year, first in one direction and then in the other. These changes were related in part to identifiable special factors such as the imposition and subsequent removal of the credit control program. Accommodation to such special and temporary factors, as they emerged, might tend to lengthen the period over which deviations from monetary targets could be expected to average out, but would, by the same token, tend to dampen fluctuations in interest rates that would not have contributed to better control of money over time. B. Variability in money growth 1. Evaluation of the variability of money supply series is importantly affected by the seasonal adJustment process. Seasonal factors applied during a current year are unable adequately to reflect changing seasonal patterns in the course of that year; after a year is over, therefore, reestimation of seasonal factors often tends to smooth variability. Based on current seasonal adjustment factors for the year just past (that is, factors before seasonal revisions that take account of the influence of a~tual experience this year), variability in weekly, monthly, and quarterly growth of M-1 (and also M-2) was substantially greater than in any year during the past decade. However, when the variability in money growth during the year from October 1979 to October 1980 is compared with variability in earlier years--with earlier years adJusted_,using seasonal factors that were current in those years--nearly all of the heightened variability in weekly growth of M-1 and a sizable portion of the monthly and quarterly variability are removed. While this comparison makes it seem prohable that seasonal factor distortions are overstating variability in the year just past, the extent cannot be https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A6assessed with confidence until a number of years have passed. In general, it would appear that money has been more variable over the past year, especially on a monthly and quarterly basis--though so far as can be judged from the available data, still generally well within the range of foreign experience with money supply volatility.• 2. The variability in money growth of the past year appears to be related to an unusual combination of circumstances: a. There were large swings within the year in the demand for money resulting from sharp short-run variations in economic activity caused in large part by factors independent of the new monetary control procedure, such as the imposition and subsequent removal of the credit control program. The imposition and subsequent removal of the credit control program may have also increased the variability of money growth through a more direct channel, as the·associated large variation in bank loans was accompanied by temporary changes in demand deposits-for example, as large loan repayments were initially made from existing demand balances. b. In addition, econometric evidence from a variety of models suggests that there were "unexplained" factors other than economic activity and interest rates causing substantial fluctuations in money demand. In particular, money levels fell considerably short of model simulations (given GNP and interest rate~) in the second quarter, when money growth was negative. Relatively rapid growth in subsequent quarters reflected in part a tendency for money levels to move back toward more normal relationships with GNP and interest rates. 3. T~e money targets on which reserve paths were based reflected the intention to return money over time to the long-run obJective following https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A7divergence~. In 1980 the target for narrow money in the month following the F0MC meeting typically implied making up about 30 percent of the difference between the projected level of the money stock in the month of the meeting and the long-run target path. If disturbances in 1980 had been more representative of those prevailing in the 1970s, simulations using • the Board's monthly model suggest that the reserve operating technique would have kept money closer on a month-by-month basis last year to longrun objectives than actually was the case. These simulations also indicate a distinct trade-off between variability of the federal funds rate--and money market rates generally--and the speed with which attempts are made to return the money stock to its longer-term path once it moves off path. The more rapid the attempted return to,path, the larger are the implied fluctuations in money market rates. 4. Interpretation of money supply volatility is complicated by the large amount of noise in weekly and monthly changes in first published figures for the narrow monetary aggregates (and for monthly changes in M-2) resulting from transitory variation and seasonal factor uncertainty. Based on data for the 1973-79 period, the estimated standard deviation of the noise factor for monthly changes in M-lA and M-lB is about $1.5 billion (4-1/2 percent at an annual rate), and about $3.3 billion for weekly changes. ~or M-2, the estimated standard deviation of noise in monthly growth rates is 3-1/2 percent at an annual rate. The noise factor declines for growth rates over longer periods of time. c. Variability of interest rates 1. As had been expected, the federal funds rate has been more variable on an intra-day, intra-weekly, and inter-weekly b~sis since the new procedure was implemented. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Intra-day and day-to-day variability has tended -A8to be at least twice as large as before, as have weekly changes after adjusting for trend. This greater variability of the federal funds rate reflects the role of nonborrowed reserves as an operating guide for the Desk. 2. There has also been heightened variability of interest rates on Treasury securities of all maturities following adoption of the new operating procedure. Based on data from which cyclical movements were removed, the variability in Treasury yields measured on a weekly average basis has been at least twice as large as before October 1979. 1. The relationship over interest rate cycles between the federal funds rate and yields on Treasury securities of all maturities has been essentially the same before and after October 1979, suggesting that the underlying linkage between the federal funds rate and other market rates has remained about unchanged. At the same time, however, correlations between very short-run nonsystematic movements in the funds rate and other market rates have increased substantially since the new procedure was implemented. This higher correlation possibly reflects the sensi- tivity of market participants to day-to-day changes in the funds rate in the uncertain environment that prevailed last year but possibly also reflects concurrent adjustments in market interest rates generally, particularly short rates, that tend to occur as closer control is sought over the money supply, given variations in money demand. D. Effects on domestic financial markets The swings in interest rates last year, and the high levels reached, clearly affected behavior in financial markets. It is difficult to isolate the role of the new operating procedure, as such, in contributing https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A9to interest rate swings or changes in market behavior. It is likely that large cyclical variations in interest rates would have developed last year in any event if the basic monetary aggregate targets were pursued by other operating techniques in the face of cyclical variations in money and credit demands that were exceptionally large and compressed in time. And adjustments that took place in financial market behavior last year largely represented adaptations that would have been expected on the basis of past cyclical experience--for example, constraints on housing finance-or were related to the special credit control program. Market adjustments that might have primarily reflected adaptations to the new procedure as such are likely to be those more associated with a perceived greater continuing risk of short-term interest rate volatility--adjustments that would be difficult to detect in an environment like that of last last year, which was dominated by cyclical changes in credit flows, a credit control program, and inflationary expectations. 1. Mortgage markets. Greater interest rate volatility since October 1979 may have hastened the trend in process for a number of years toward more flexible mortgage instruments, such as variable-rate, renegotiable, and equity participation mortgages. In addition, mortgage bankers and other originators in their commitment policies appear to have attempted to avoid qome of the risk of interest rate changes occurring between the time a commitment is made and funds are extended. They have done so by setting rates or points at the time of closing, shortening the period for guaranteed fixed-rate mortgage commitments, and by imposing large nonrefundable commitment fees to discourage cancellation if rates should decline. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -AlO2. Dealer market for Treasury and Agency Securities. Wider bid-ask spreads on Treasury bills appear to have emerged last year. Evidence on such spreads for coupon issues is difficult to interpret; spreads rose considerably a few months prior to introduction of the new procedure, and thereafter remained wider than in earlier years. Greater uncertainty about interest rates may have influenced dealers to maintain leaner inventory positions relative to transactions; turnover of dealer inventories rose last year as a very large expansion in gross transactions outpaced the rise in the level of inventories. 3. Underwriting spreads on corporate bonds. Underwriting spreads on corporate bonds issued on a negotiated basis did not widen, on balance, over the year since October 1979. However, data on competitively bid issues suggest that spreads on such issues have widened. This might tend to raise bond costs, but any such effect last year would appear to have been very small relative to the more basic supply and demand conditions affecting markets. 4. Commercial bank behavior. Bank behavior last year was strongly influenced by a number of factors other than the new procedure, such as the imposition and removal of the special voluntary credit restraint program, marginal reserve requirements on managed liabilitie9, and increasing reliance, especially by small banks, on money market certificates as a source of funds. It is difficult to detect changes in behavior associated with the new procedure per~• There appears to have been some increased reliance on floating-rate loans, especially for term loans, but this trend was evident prior to October 1979. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -All5. Futures markets. Futures market activity expanded rapidly in the period following October 1979, raising the possibility that the new procedure led to an increased desire to hedge against expected greater interest rate fluctuations. ~owever, the expansion in activity represented a continuation of the trend of recent years, as has been the case with other market adaptations noted above. It is virtually impossible to separate growth in futures activity arising from attempts to reduce exposure to interest rate risk in the new environment from underlying trend growth connected with increasing familiarization by the public with the variety of financial futures instruments that are becoming available. 6. Liquidity premiums. An attempt was made to detemine whether there was an increase last year in liquidity premiums, manifested by a rise in long-term rates relative to short-term rates. Such a result might be expected if risk-averse financial market participants attempted to protect themselves from a perceived risk that the new procedure would make for greater interest rate variability and hence greater risk of capital loss on holdings of longer-term issues. There appears to be little, if any, evidence that liquidity premiums became greater last year--although as noted in paragraphs 2 and 3 above there may have been some increase of transactions costs in financial markets. E. Exchange market and other external impactg 1. The spot value of the dollar appreciated by more than 5 percent in the 14-month period subsequent to late September 1979, though there were pronounced cycles that coincided with intermediate-term movements of interest rates in the United States. 2. Day-to-day movement in money market rates related to the new procedure could have had some influence on very short-term exchange rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A12~ volatility. Spot rates have displayed more variability on a daily basis since the new procedure was adopted, reflecting greater daily variability of interest rate differentials between U.S. dollar and foreign currency assets. The evidence on weekly and monthly exchange rate movements also suggests more variability, but the evidence is not so conclusive as that for daily variability. 3. There _is little evidence of a significant increase in the variability of foreign interest rates, apart from in Canada~ on a monthly basis related to the new procedure as such. Some countries, especially developing countries with currencies tied to the dollar and with inflexible interest rate structures, appear to have experienced some tech~ical difficulties over this period connected, for example, with the impact of interest rate variability-on financial flows. 4. The evidence does --not suggest that the new operating procedure has contributed to the variable nature of gross U.S. international capital flows since the fall of 1979. Significantly greater contributing factors were the credit control program and marginal reserve requirements on managed liabilities. 5. The proposition that more short-term variability of exchange rates could have adverse effects on the domestic price level, because price increases caused by currency depreciation would not be fully offset by the reverse effect of currency appreciation, is not supported by econometric evidence. Therefore, the short-term variability of exchange rates since October 1979 would not itself appear to have raised the domestic price level. Meanwhile, the underlying trend toward appreciation since that time would have had a favorable effect on the price level. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A13F. Economic activity 1. Assessing the contribution of the new procedure as such to the pattern of economlc activity and inflationary expectations is complicated-as noted-at other points in this paper--by the force of other factors that were importantly influencing the markets for goods and services over the recent period, including the effect of the basic money supply targets themselves. Certain "fundamentals"--such as the previous sharp increase in oil prices, the relatively low saving rate, and the illiquid balance sheet of the household sector-suggest that economic activity would have contracted in any event in 1980. In addition, prices and real economic activity were strongly influenced by the highly sensitive state of inflationary psychology, the imposition and removal of the credit control program that lasted from mid-March to early July 1980, and erosion of fiscal restraint. 2. Nevertheless, to the extent that the new control procedure encouraged more prompt interest rate adjustments in response to cyclical fluctuations in money and credit demands, it probably exerted some influence on the pattern of economic activity. It may have hastened the slowdown in economic activity-especially in housing and possibly consumer durables--in early 1980 and also hastened the recovery in the summer, as interest rate~ advanced rapidly to peak levels and then contracted sharply. Psychological reactions to the credit control program, however, may have been an important influence on the depth of the recession and the promptness and strength of the subsequent rebound. There was a sharp contraction in spending following introduction of the program, and relief on the part of both financial institutions and borrowers as the program was phased out probably encouraged a sizable resurgence of spending. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al43. In view of the lags in the response of capital spending plans to changes in credit conditions, the new procedure does not appear to have exerted much influence on plant and equipment spending during the past year. The timing of inventory movements, by contrast, may have been altered to the extent that the new procedure had effects on the pattern of final sales and on movements in short-term financing costs. 4. The new control procedure was adopted in part to provide more assurance that inflation would come under control (as money growth was restrained), and thereby to reduce inflationary expectations. It is difficult to measure inflationary expectations, let alone to attribute changes to a technical change in monetary control procedures in so highly unsettled a period as last year. Indirect evidence about inflation expectations based on changes in interest rates is obviously difficult to interpret, since interest rates are also influenced by other factors. Some direct evidence about consumer expectations of inflation can be gleaned from the Michigan survey. No clear improvement in inflationary attitudes is evident until into the spring, probably related in large part to the sharp contraction of economic activity in the qecond quarter. There did not appear to be any significant worsening of expectations, as judged by the Michigan survey, in the latter part of the year as the economy strengthened. 5. The Board's large-scale quarterly econometric model, as well as two other much more simplified models used for comparative purposes, were employed to help evaluate the extent to which the actual fluctuations in money and interest rates affected economic activity in the course of the year. These models, of course, all suffer from an inability to take account adequately of attitudinal changes and other behavioral factors https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al5related to the special conditions of a particular year, including any attitudinal changes that might be occasioned by the shift in operating procedure. Simulation results suggest that, because of long response lags, the pattern of economic activity last year would not have been' particularly sensitive to efforts at smoothing the quarter-to-quarter pattern either of money growth or of interest rate variations~ though smoothing money growth had slightly more impact. The smoothing of money growth would have been at the cost of even greater interest rate variability than was actually observed over the last five quarters.· II. General Considerations Evaluation of the current and alternative operating techniques to be discussed in section III depends very much on the role accorded intermediate targets, particularly the monetary aggregates, in the formulation of monetary policy. This section examines advantages and disadvantages involved in employing monetary aggregates, or for that matter interest rates, as intermediate targets, and also examines'certain limitations on the feasible range of target settings. A. Advantages and disadvantages of monetary aggregates as intermediate targets 1. Advantages a. Money stock control tends to work toward stabilizing GNP when the economy is buffeted by disturbances to spending on goods and services and shifts in inflation expectations; such factors appeared to be an important influence on economic and financial behavior last year. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis If spending surges unexpectedly, for example, as it did in the -Al6second half of 1980, adherence to a money stock target would automatically lead to tighter financial markets, tending to offset some of the surge in spending. Similarly, if spending were to weaken unexpectedly--and very substantial weakness developed in the second quarter of last year--efforts to hold to a money stock target would lead automatically to lower market rates of interest, which would tend to partially restore spending to desired levels. b. Current approaches emphasizing control of monetary aggregates rest on the proposition that planned deceleration in monetary growth will lower inflation over time by limiting funds available to finance price increases and encouraging expectations and behavioral patterns consistent with reduced inflation. c. By clearly communicating to the public the Federal Reserve's obJectives for monetary policy, a monetary aggregates targeting procedure enables private decision-makers to better plan their activities and to make wage and price decisions that are more hamonious with noninflationary growth in money and credit. d. Targeting on monetary aggregates involves adjustments of market interest rates, in response to underlying changes in demands for credit, that might otherwise be unduly delayed, either on the down- or up-side. 2. Disadvantages a. Looseness in the relationship between money demand and nominal GNP reduces the significance of monetary aggregates as a target, particularly in the short run. Unexpected shifts in this relationship lead to undesirable interest rate movements with strict https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al7adherence to money supply targets. Last year, there was evidence of looseness in this relationship. For example, as noted earlier, econometric models suggest a sizable downward shift in the demand for money in the second quarter, given actual GNP and interest rates. b. Attempts to achieve steady growth in monetary aggregates on a month-by-month or even quarter-by-quarter basis can lead to large interest rate fiuctuations, given the high degree of variability in short-run money flows and the relatively interestinelastic demand for money over the near term. Large fluctuations in interest rates have certain risks; for instance, they might endanger financial institutions that are unable to make timely compensating adjustments in their balance sheets, adversely affect the functions of securities and exchange markets, and lead to confusion about the basic thrust of policy. c. Money supply targeting procedures might themselves introduce recurrent cyclical responses of economic activity following an economic disturbance. Whether this is a realistic risk depends on the nature of response functions in the economy. It would be a high risk in the degree that: (1) money demand was very insensitive to interest rate changes (and thus interest rates would need to change sharply to maintain steady money growth in response to an exogenous disturbance fron the goods market), and (2) there was no significant current impact on spending from such changes in rates but impacts were felt over later periods. It would be difficult to attribute the cyclical behavior of economic activity over the past year to https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al8- such a process, though, given model estimates of the interestelasticlty of money demand and of relatively long lags between interest rates and spending (with such lags implying a longer cycle than observed last year). d. The concept of money is elusive, and is becoming more so as new substitutes evolve for traditional transactions media and as improvements in financial technology facilitate the ability of the public to shift funds about for payments purposes. B. Interest rates as targets 1. Advantages a. Control over total spending can be strengthened by greater emphasis on stabilizing interest rates when disturbances stem mainly from the monetary sector rather than from markets for goods and services. b. Control over rates might make for greater short-run stability in ~inancial markets, since market institutions might be relatively certain about the terms and conditions under which they can "safely" meet near-term credit demands. 2. Disadvantages a. It is very difficult to determine the appropriate interest rate level, particularly in an inflationary environment in which shifting expectations of inflation are continuously altering the relationship between real and nominal market rates of interest. b. Efforts to stabilize interest rates tend to amplify economic cycles ~temming from cyclical variations in the demand for goods https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -Al9and services, since by stabilizing rates, pro-cyclical growth in money and credit would be heightened. An upswing in the demand for goods and qervices, for example, would be accompanied by an expansion in the volume of money and credit. By contrast, with a money stock targeting procedure, resistance would be introduced automatically through increases in interest rates ..!/ c. While interest rate targets could in concept be adjusted promptly so as to minimize the likelihood of a pro-cyclical monetary policy, in practice the institutional decision-making procedure often limits the ability to make sizable adjustments in the target. This could constrain interest rate variations when rates are taken as the intermediate target of monetary policy. c. Limitations in the targeting process Regardless of whether monetary aggregates or interest rates are selected as intermediate targets, there appear to be a number of limitations on the monetary authority's range of choice of the particular target setting and ,the precision with which the target is pursued. 1. The particular target setting must take into account the capacity of the economy and financial markets to adjust to the targets, and the degree to which the implications of those targets can be understood by and are acceptable to the larger public whose behavior patterns are involved. Inflexibilities in wage and price determination, for example, have implications for the degree to which monetary targets can be reduced, without risking unduly adverse implications for economic activity in the short 1/ Even with a money stock procedure such resistance may not be sufficient to hold nominal GNP down to a previously desired level if the upward shock in demand for goods and services involves a rise in velocity--as it well might if it resulted from, say, expansion in federal spending. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A20run. This would be less of a limitation to the extent that attitudinal shifts--either in response to announced monetary targets or other/factors-brought upward wage and price pressures down in line with monetary targets. Experience of the past year has not yet provided a basis for believing - J that the lengthy lags between money growth and price changes have been shortened significantly or that inflation expectations have begun to respond more rapidly to the money control procedure per~2. The question may arise as to whether disturbances in domestic, or foreign exchange, markets may on occasion require short-run departures from intermediate-term targets of monetary policy. However, these markets appear to have adjusted to a subgtantial degree of interest rate or exchange rate fluctuation during the past year. 3. Precise month-by-month control of money does not seem possible, given existing behavior patterns in the economy and financial markets and institutional factors. Nor is there evidence that such close control is needed to attain the underlying economic objective of encouraging noninflationary economic growth. Statistical investigation suggests that "noise" alone accounts for substantial variation in monthly money growth rates. Moreover, model simulations indicate that variations in money growth above or below targets lasting a quarter or so are not likely to have substantial economic effects. 4. Uncertainties involving the relationship between money demand and GNP--as evidenced by unexpected variations in such demand last yearsuggest the need for a degree of flexibility in target setting (ranges may be preferable to point estimates), and also suggest the possibility https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A21that, at times, ,there may be a need for large deviations from predetermined targets or for changes in the targets. On the other hand, deviations from target ranges involve the risk of changes in market expectations that are counter-productive (for example, when money supply runs strong relative' to target, inflationary expectations_may be heightened, compounding the difficulties of controlling inflation). In general, though, in the degree that there is success in achieving targets over time, expectations are less likely to be adversely affected by short-run deviations in money growth. III. Evaluation of Operating Procedures Because the past year was in many ways exceptional--and because a year, or 15 months, in any event is too short a time frame within which to judge whether observed relationships are accidental to the period or are lasting--evaluation of the new control procedure, and of possible alternatives, must at best be quite tentative. The choice of operating proce- dure would be influenced by the predictability of certain financial and economic relationships and by the capacity of markets to adjust to operating techniques without severe distortions--evidence about which was presented in section I. In addition, the desirability of retaining the present reserve procedure (with or without possible modifications), of shifting to an alternative reserve procedure, or indeed of shifting back I entirely to a federal funds rate operating guide depends in part on the value to be placed on relatively tight short-run control of money, given uncertainties about the likely sources of potential disturbances in economic and financial conditions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A22If there were complete certainty about economic relationships, the choice of operating procedure would not be particularly critical, for a given money stock target would be associated with unique, known values for the federal funds rate, nonborrowed reserves, and the monetary base. And the monetary authority could achieve its objectives no matter which of these instruments was selected for operating purposes. In practice, however, markets are continually subject to disturbances that are not knownl n advance. The principal kinds of disturbances are those occurring in overall spending (the market for goods and services), those occurring in the demand for money (independently of GNP and intereqt rates), and those affecting the supply schedule for money (such as deposit mix or banks' demand for excess reserves). Moreover, such disturbances- all of which were evident last year--can be of a temporary or self-reversing variety, or they can be permanent. Alternative operating procedures tend to produce different outcomes for the pattlrn of interest rates and money growth in the face of these disturbances. With some procedures, and depending on the source of the disturbance, interest rates would be changed more, while with others the money stock and other financial quantities would absorb more of the impact. The choice of operating procedure therefore involves, among other things, judgments about whether there is more risk to monetary policy's ultimate objective of noninflationary growth from procedures that·'tend -to emphasize interest ,rates ... as,, oper.atinghtarge,ts.,-wit;,h.-som,e~,,~. implication of a relatively gradual change in rates, or from those that tend to work more directly against money supply variations. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A23A. Assessment of present operating procedure The present reserve operating procedure proved flexible enough to permit some accommodation in the short run to unexpected shifts in money ~emand, given GNP and interest rates, that occurred last year. At the same time, the procedure worked to limit the extent to which changes in demands for goods and services (and thus in transaction demands for money) were reflected in actual money growth. Actual money growth devi- foted from short-run targets last year, but there were large accompanying changes in interest rates that tended, over time, to set up forces bringing money back toward path. Nonetheless, money growth over time deviated more from path than might have been expected relative to the average degree of looseness that seems to exist in reserve-to-money relationships. While the experience of last year may have been atypical because of the nature of disturbances during the year, still a number of modifications to the operating proced11re used since October 1979 might be considered for their potential value in reducing slippage in money relative to reserve paths. These modifications all have certain disadvantages, however, that need to be weighed aginst their varying advantages for more precise monetary control, to the degree that closer control in the shortrun is considered desirable. 1. Evidence of the past year suggests that during an intermeeting period relatively prompt downward (or upward) adjustments in the original '''"'~' nonborrowed reserve path may be.needed, tn an effort,t~ 8[f~~~~ ~Y~! t!m~,. increased (or decreased) demand for borrowing when money is strengthening (or weakening) relative to ,target. As an alternative, more prompt upward (or downward) adjustments in the discount rate would tend to discourage https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A24(or encourage) borrowing over time (in practice the actual level of borrowing will not change until money demand changes sufficiently to alter reserves demanded to meet reserve requirements).!./ These adjust- ments run the risk of increasing the volatility of short-run interest rate movements in view of the transitory fluctuations often experienced in short-run money demand. However, they could also dampen the amplitude of longer-term swings of interest rates by more promptly leading to adjustments by banks that bring money growth back toward path. 2. More fundamental changes in the administration of the discount window and in the way discount rates are structured and varied could be considered for strengthening the relationship between reserves and money. a. At an extreme, discount window borrowing might be limited to emergency needs. This is tantamount to adhering to a total reserves or monetary base path. However, this would eliminate the valuable buffering function of the discount window. The window buffers the money stock (and the markets) from disturbances affecting the supply of money (such as changing demands for excess reserves and changes 1/ Expe~ience has demonstrated that it is difficult to determine in advance the appropriate level of borrowing to be employed in constructing the nonborrowed reserve path consistent wtth the -;hort-run noney supply target. This level of borrowing would depend on a projection of market interest rates consistent with the money supply target path and knowledge of depository i~stitutions' willingness to borrow, given the spread between market rates and the discount rate, and could differ significantly from borrowing levels based on or ranging around recent experience. In attempting to forecast borrowings, evidence from models may be usefully weighed along with judgmental assessment of particular conditions at the time. However, in view of considerable uncertainties about interest rate projections, the high degree of year-to-year variability in the success with which models proJect economic and financial relationships, and the heightened variability in denands for discount window credit evident last year, projections of borrowing demand from interest rate forecasts and past bank behavior are subject to a considerable degree of error. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A25in the deposit mix affecting required reserves). Its role in that respect was evident from the results of model simulations showing a weak relationship between total reserves or the monetary base and money (when reserves or the base are treated as exogenously determined). In addition, the discount window cushions markets from the full impact of variations in money demand that may be transitory or which the FOMC may wish at least partially to accommodate. Finally, lagged reserve accounting requires access to the discount window in' the short run on occasions when required reserves run above the nonborrowed reserve path (if that path is to be maintained).!/ b. Another approach to consider would be to eliminate administrative guidelines at the discount window and to substitute a graduated discount rate schedule for adjustment credit--in contrast to emergency and other longer-term types of discount window credit--based on, say, size of borrowing. This approach would tend to make the relationship between borrowing and short-term market rates more'certain by eliminating from the decision to borrow the uncertainties connected with administrative guidelines. It also thereby transforms th~ highest discount rate on the schedule into an upper limit for the federal funds rate. There are, however, legal questions about the System's ability to use size of borrowing as a criterion, administrative problems in overseeing the adequacy of collateral and the financial condition of a vast number of potential regular borrowers, and difficult questions with ' ' re~ard to the appropriate gradient for the discount rate schedule. 1/ Even with contemporaneous instead of lagged reserve accounting, it is by no means clear that banks would be able to make needed adjustments reducing their required reserves within a statement week--except at the expense of relatively extreme interest rate movements. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A26Too steep a gradient risks undue market interest rate fluctuations, particularly at times when borrowing demands may be changing for transitory reasons, while too flat a gradient-and at the limit a perfectly flat one--would tend to eliminate the incentive of banks to make portfolio ad1ustments that would bring money supply back to targe~. c. The recent policy of applying a surcharge above the basic discount rate for frequent borrowing (by larger banks) represents a step toward a graduated discount rate structure within the present administrative guidelines and tends, when applied, to speed up the response of market rates to overshoots or undershoots of money relative to path. This approach has the dttraction of flexibility, but in practice it has proved difficult to assess because of the limited experience with it thus far. d. Another approach to speeding up the response of banks within present administrative guidelines would be to tie the discount rate to market rates, either as a penalty rate or not. However, this approach tends to limit flexibility and raises the danger of upward or downward ratcheting of market rates in the short run that may be excessive for monetary control needs and unduly disturbing to the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A27'- functioning of markets ..!/ While a tied rate accelerates the response of market rates, the change may be counterproductive-particularly if money behavior were going to reverse itself naturally or if the rise in borrowing were needed to moderate shocks from the supply sideand could intensify short-run money supply and interest rate cycles. 3. A closer snort-run relationship between reserves and money could be attained by measures that strengthen the link between required reserves and deposits in the particular money stock that is being controlled. One such measure would be a shift from lagged reserve accounting (LRA) to contemporaneous reserve accounting (CRA), which the Board has already announced that it is contemplating. Such a shift would make the link between current reserves and current deposits stronger, though -there still would be relatively sizable slippage between reserves and money from other sources. The monetary control advantages of CRA apply particularly to the short run. They have to be weighed against (1) the benefits of LRA for reducing the cost of reserve management by the banks, (2) the contribution of LRA to the Trading Desk's ability to assess reserve supply conditions, and (3) judgments about the adequacy of monetary control under LRA over a longer-term period. 1/ This danger is greatest tn the degree that the disco~nt rate is tied to a current or very recent market rate. If required reserves expand rapidly in the current week, banks will have to borrow the added required reserves that are not being accommodated by the nonborrowed reserve target. As a result market rates must rise to the point at which banks are willing to borrow from the discount window. With an attempt to maintain a "penalty" discount rate, the new market rate would therefore have to move temporarily above the discount rate, which could not be maintained, in those circumstances, above current market rates. Market rates would go up by the amount needed to reestablish the normal spread of market rates over the discount rate (that emerges from pressures generated by discount window administration and banks' reluctance to borrow). ~ut this rise in rates may well bring about a further rise in the discount rate if an attempt is made to reestablish a "penalty" rate, entailing yet a further rise in market rates, so long as required reserves remain at an advanced level. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A284. The present relatively complicated reserve requirement structure, even apart from LRA, makes for considerable slippage in the relation between reserves and money. While the Monetary Control Act has tended to simplify the required reserve structure, it will be a number of years before the new structure is fully phased in. Because of the unpredic- tability of shifts in deposit mix, in the ratio of currency to deposits, as well as in banks' demand for excess reserves, judgmental multiplier adjustments to original paths were made week-by-week last year as new information was obtained. Model simulations suggest money-reserve rela- tionships would have otherwise been more variable on average. Thus, there is no reason not to continue making such adjustments, though it remains unclear, because multiplier changes are so erratic, whether full adjustment should he made to each week's added infonnation. 5. It appears from tentative results based on the Board's monthly money market model that the faster the FOMC attempts to move back toward the longer-run target for money, once off target, the more likely is the long-run target to he hit, assuming no federal funds rate constraint. However, these results al~o suggest that the more quickly a return to path is sought, the more substantial fluctuations in money market rates are likely to be. And experience of the past year suggests these more substantial fluctuations would be transmitted broadly through the rate structure. Moreover, for a more rapid return beyond a certain speed--per- haps around three months--it seems as if the gain in reducing the chance of departures from longer-term money targets is small compared with the increasing chance of a wider range of variability in money market rates. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A29,B. Assessment of other targeting procedures 1. Monetary base or total reserves A. The principal reason for adopting these measures as day-to- day operating guides would be to ensure more precise control of money. However, there is no clear evidence that money can be controlled more closely through use of a strict total reserves or monetary base operating procedure under the present institutional framework than through current procedures. Indeed, most of the evidence suggested that these measures could produce more slippage because of supplyside shocks to the money multiplier. These shocks tend to be partially offset by changes in borrowing with a nonborrowed reserves day-to-day operating target. Under a total reserves or base target, there would not automatically be an offsetting tendency. In practice, though, the precision of a total reserve or base target would be improved through judgmental adjustments to the reserve path that offset multiplier shifts. Improvements could also be effected, and the need for judgment reduced, by further simplification of the reserve requirement structure (such as removal of the reserve requirement on nonpersonal ttme deposits if the FOMC wishes to control mainly narrow money) and by a return to CRA. While such changes would tjghten the linkage between reserves and money, shifts between currency and deposits would still tend to be a factor causing slippage--with model simulations indicating greater slippage with the monetary base as the operating target (whlch is essentially currency plus total reserves) than with total reserves. With a monetary base target, short-run volatility in currency would lead to large variations in https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A30money supply because changes in the public's holdings of currency would need to be offset by equal changes in bank reserves; and these changes in reserves would, given the fractional reserve system, force a multiple change of deposits in the money supply. With a reserves target, the changes in money supply would be no larger than the currency variation; consequently, money supply would be less volatile with a reserves target. b. In any event, strict adherence to total reserve or base targets appears to be impractical over short-run operating periods in the current institutional setting. clearly not feasible. With the present LRA system, it is If CRA were adopted, such targets might become somewhat more practical, though efforts to attain them would accentuate short-run interest rate fluctuations. Such fluctuations, given the inelasticity of money demand relative to interest rates over the short run, would stem from the inability of the reserve supply to provide at least partial accommodation to transitory money demand variations, and would also result from remaining multiplier slippage. In the process, borrowing at the discount window would fluctuate widely, as banks reacted to efforts by the Open Market Desk to reach the total reserve target. c. While there are practical questions about the feasibility of targeting on total reserves (or the base) on a day-to-day or week-toweek basis, in a longer-run context a path for such reserve aggregates, properly adjusted for multiplier shifts, could serve as a general guide in helping to make adJustments in the nonborrowed reserve path or in indicating the need for a change in the basic discount rate--as is, in fact, present practice. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis For example, when total reserves are -A31running strong relative to its adjusted path, this can be taken as an indication to hold back on the supply of nonborrowed reserves relative to its path (in order over time to offset the rise in borrowing) or to raise the discount rate (in order over time to discourage a rise in borrowing). 2. Federal funds rate target a. Model simulations, given existing institutional arrangements, indicated that in concept slippage in short-run money stock targets could be little different on the whole under a funds rate targeting regime than under a nonborrowed reserves regime. However, in practice--to be reasonably certain of attaining its long-run target--the FOMC would need to be willing to move the funds rate quite actively when it was the operating instrument and be able to predict fairly well the appropriate extent, and indeed the direction, of the required change. Uncertainties in those respect9 of course were runong the factors leading to a shift toward reserve targeting. b. A federal funds rate operating target would have advantages if the FOMC wished to provide more scope for being accommodative to variations in money demand, either because of uncertainties about the proper path of money growth within its longer-run target band or because of a belief that money demand disturbances are more likely to occur than disturbances in the market for goods and services. c. The federal funds rate range under the current reserve operating procedure has been much wider than under the earlier funds rate targeting regime. Moreover, the range under the new procedure has generally been changed as the limits were approached--a practice https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A32that has been consistent with evidence quggesting that a wide range of variation in the funds rate is a by-product of efforts to attain tight control of the money supply. In that context, a relatively narrow acceptable funds rate range would only have advantages in the degree that the FOMC (1) felt more qcope could be given in a particular period, for one reason or another, to variations of money from a pre-set target, or (2) felt that narrow funds rate limits provided a device that, given the need to make judgments about sources of economic and monetary disturbances, would prompt further assessment of underlying monetary and other conditions by the FOMC in the interval between meetings. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -A33- Monetary Control Project Staff Papers Davis, ~ichard. "~onetary Aggregates and the Use of Intermediate Targets in Monetary Policy." Enzler, Jared. "Economic Disturbances and Monetary Policy Responses." ---------,.,.. and Lewis Johnson. "Cycles Resulting from Money Stock Targeting." Greene, Margaret. "The New Approach to Monetary Policy--A View from the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk." Johnson, Dana, and others. "Interest Rate Variability under the New Operating Procedures and the Initial Response in Financial Markets." Keir, Peter. "Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the Effectiveness of Reserve Targeting." Levin, Fred,and Paul Meek. "Implementing the New Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk." Lindsey, David, and others. Opera ting Procedures." Pierce, David. "Monetary Control Experience under the New "Trend and Noise in the Monetary Aggregates." Slifman, Lawrence, and Edward McKelvey. "The New Operating Procedures and Economic Activity since October 1979." Tinsley, Peter, and others. Procedures." "Money Market Impacts of Alternative Operating Truman, Edwin M., and others. "The New Federal Reserve Operating Procedure: An External Perspective." https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Monetary Aggregates and the Use of nintermediate Targets" in Monetary Policy January 12, 1981 Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Richard G. Davis ,\. Ir.troduction The"obJective of this paper is to reconsider the rationale underlying the use of long-term monetary growth objectives as "intermediate targets" in U.S. monetary policy. to survey the following major areas: (1) The paper seeks The nature of "inter- mediate targets" and their use by the Federal Reserve. (2) The question of whether intermediate targets in general are an aid or a hindrance to effective policymaking -- the "decision theory" approach to intermediate targeting. (3) The "monetarist" case for money stock measures as intermediate targets. ( 4) Money stock targets conceived as the centerpiece of monetary policy's contribution to a long-term anti-inflation strategy. (5) Circumstances under which it might be necessary or desirable to suspend or modify efforts to track money stock targets -rate objectives? (6) a role for interest Alternative money stock measures as long- term intermediate targets -- reserve and monetary base measures, credit measures. (7) "Mixed strategies" in which long-term aggregate targets are blended with shorter-term focus on interest rates and financial market conditions. (8) Structural features of the economy limiting the Federal Reserve's flexibility in setting long-term aggregate targets. Each of these areas has been the subJect of extensive analysis both within and without the Federal Reserve over a period of years. While there can probably be said to be a fairly broad, if shifting consensus on some of these topics, virtually all the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 2 significant issues remain controversial to at least some degree. Under these circumstances, the aim of the present paper is mainly to lay out in one place the main strands of argumentation that surround the use of ~oney and credit aggregate measures in an "intermediate" target role, suggesting only as possible and appro, priate where the weight of relevant evidence may lie. B. Some Definitions It is necessary to begin the discussion of "intermediate targets" by trying to establish some terminology. tinction needs to be First, a dis- made between the ultimate "goals" of policy, such as price and output behavioi;which policy may be able to influence but which it cannot directly control, and the "instruments" of policy over'which the policymakers do exert direct control. Strictly speaking, the main instruments of monetary policy are confined to the discount rate, reserve requirements, deposit interest rate ceilings,and the level and composition of the System's open market portfolio. It does not seem very useful or convenient, however, to define the open market operations instrument in terms of the System's portfolio, even though moving to broader definitions quickly encounters problems. purposes, nonborrowed reserves and For present the nonborrowed monetary base will be defined as potential policy instruments. This seems appropriate since short-term obJectives for them can be hit subject to correct forecasts of the behavior of the "operating factors" affecting reserves, factors that are themselves https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 3 - essentially independent of the level of open market operations. At the same time, experi~nce has amply shown that the Desk can control the weekly average level of the federal funds rate with ,a,very high degree of precision in most weeks. Thus the funds • rate can clearly be included as a potential "instrument.." "Intermediate targets, 11 as the term suggests, fall somewhere between the measures that represent ultimate policy goals and the measures that can be treated as policy instruments. ~ Such measures cannot ~e directly controlled in the sense that policy instruments can be, but they are usually presumed to be much more closely subJect to control through manipulation of the instruments than are the goal measures. The term implies that for some period, short or long, policy instruments will be adJusted in line with the intermediate target,which, in turn, will itself be readJusted at longer intervals as required by pursuit of ultllllate policy goals. Since the Open Market Committee meets at discreet intervals rather than continuously, it is useful 11 ro distinguish between short-term 11 intermed1ate targets, defined as any intermediate tar- get set at each-Open Market Committee meeting to be pursued over the interval between meetings, and "long-term" intermediate targets, which are expected to be maintained over a multiTheeting horizon. It may be helpful to use these various distinctions to look briefly at how the Open Market Committee has used instruments and intermediate targets over the period since the accord. Until the first tentative use of money stock targets in the early 1970s, the Committee did not, in fact, make use of long-term https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis intermediate targets at all. , Various measures of money market conditions, net free reserves, the federal funds rate, and the Treasury bill rate were used alone or in combination as 'both the open market,policy 'instrument-and the short-term intermediate target. Indeed, until the advent of monetary targets there was really no need for the distinction between short-term "instruments" in the sense used here and the concept of "intermediate targets. 11 In the earlier years before money and credit targets, the settings of the various money market instrument/target measures were customarily readJusted at each meeting,and there was no particular expectation on anyone's part that a target setting voted at one meeting would be maintained at'subsequent meetings unless economic conditions just happened to make this appropriate. This picture was complicated slightly for a time by the introduction of a socalled "bank credit proviso clause" 1960s. in the directives of the mid- Under this procedure, a forerunner of the later "tolerance ranges, 11 the Desk was instructed to adJust the money market conditions target in art appropriate direction if current bank credit growth rates appeared to be deviating substantially from proJections. Thus, the currently projected rate of growth of bank credit became part of a 11 feetloack 11 mechanism that could lead to a resetting of the money market conditions target under certain conditions. In the early 1970s, the Committee began to orient its decisions regarding money market conditions around mu1tiperiod https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - s objectives,stated in ( the directive in qualitative terms, va~ious measures of the monetary aggregates. for While such aggre- gate targets could,of course,be reset each month, they began to take on some of the characteristics of true long-term intermediate targets in the sense that prospective failure to achieve them became a basi~ for readjusting the open market instruments at subsequent Committee meetings. The use of long-term inter- mediate targets became more formalized under HR 133 in 1975. The targets announced under this r.esolution were set for a fourquarter horizon and were to be restated each quarter. Given the frequent phenomenon of "base drift, 11 it is clear that in dollar terms, at least, if not in growth rate terms, the targets were in fact readJusted each quarter, but at least they functioned as long-t~r!U intermediate targets over the multimeeting period within the quarter. The intention to make use of long-term intermediate targets becomes even clearer under the provisions of the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 since one-year growth rate targets have subsequently been set only twice a year, always using the actual level of the long-term target in the fourth quarter of the previous year to define rates. the base for the targeted growth In principle, the FOMC may readJust its long-term targets at each meeting in light of changing economic conditions. If this were,in fac½ done, the long-term targets would, in effect, be converted into short-term intermediate targets. But it is reasonably clear that in operating under the act, the Committee will consider https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 6 - changes in previously announced targets only for very substantial reasons. Thus, both in practice and in theory, the present con- duct of monetary policy does revolve around the setting of open market instruments to achieve long-term intermediate targets that are, in turn, readjusted only relatively infrequently in line with changing prospects and objectives for the ultimate goal measures. C. The Case Against Intermediate Targets Somewhat paradoxically, as the use of long-term inter- mediate targets has become an increasingly dominant feature in the formulation of monetary policy, one strand of thought in the technical literature has arisen that_regards the use of intermediate targets as simply an inefficient or "sub-optimal" decisionmaking procedure. For want of a better term, this line of thought will be dubbed "decision theoretic" since it is concerned with "optimal" decisionmaking per se rather than with specific views on how the economy works.1/ (As used here, the term is intended to include but not to be confined to the work of 11 optimal control" theorists. ) l/ See, for example, BenJamin Friedman, "Targets, Instruments, and Indicators of Monetary Policy, 11 Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. l (1975), pp. 443-73; William Poole, 0ptimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments In a Simple Stochastic Macro-Model, 11 Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1970, pp. 197-216; Jack Kalchbrenner 11 and Peter Tinsley, 0n the Use of Optimal Control in the Design of 11 ~onetary Policy, Special Studies Paper 76, (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July 1975); Benjamin Friedman, "The Inefficiency of Short-Run Monetary Targets for Monetary Policy, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1977:2, pp. 293-335. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 11 11 - 7 Fundamentally, the argument made in this literature is that since movements in the intermediate measure are of no intrinsic significance to the policymakers and since the relationship of the intermediate targets to ultimate goals is likely to be subJect to various kinds of perturbations, the pursuit of intermediate targets is not an effective way to achieve the desired path of the goal variables. According to this view, it would be more efficient to set forth values of instrument variables such as nonborrowed reserves or short-term interest rates directly in terms of the desired behavior of such goal measures as nominal income. In this concep- tion, movements in such "intermediate" measures as the money supply would be treated as, at most, one among many sources of "information" on possible needed resettings of the instrument variables. Further, the presumption would be that while the Committee might set provisional multiperiod target paths for such 11 i:nstrument 11 measures as nonborrowed reserves, these paths would normally be revised at each meeting in light of incoming information. There would be no desire or expectation that any particular growth rate for either an instrument like nonborrowed reserves or an intermediate measure such as the money stock would be sought for its own sake. The case against using such measures as the money stock as longer-term intermediate targets in the context of this kind of analysis is easily stated. As long as the relationship between the path of the intermediate target appropriate to achieving the ultimate goals of interest is subJect to constant potential change, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 8 - and as long as there is a more or less steady inflow of information making possible a reassessment of this relationship, then the kind of long-term mu1 tiperiod intermediate targeting currently in use is hard to justify. Indeed, even as applied to short periods such as the period between FOMC meetings or the somewhat longer period between receipt of quarterly readings on GNP, the use of intermediate targets is, according to this line of analysis, generally not efficient. The use of such short-term intermediate targets implies, for example, that if a target measure (say M-1B} were drifting off course, the instrument measure, say nonborrowed reserves, would be adjusted to bring the intermediate target measure back on course. ~. But the critics of this approach note that there may be many reasons for an off-target drift of the M-18 intannediate measure. In one simple but widely used analyti- 1/ cal framework,- the possible sources of off-target drift in the money stock can be separated into three categories: (1) the ex- pected relationship between nonborrowed reserves and M-18 (the "supply of money function") may have shifted, (2) the demand for M-18 (\n relation to intQw.e and interest rat~s) may have shiftad~ or (3) the demand for goods and services (the neo-Keynesian "IS" curve) may be stronger or weaker than expected, pulling up (or down) both the levels of M-'iB and of i'llterest rat.es assochta.:i ,11ith the initial nonborrowed reserve path. 1/ See Friieduuat1,, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Iniefficie!!'lcy of Short-Run Monetary 'Targets. 11 - 9 - As this line of analysis points out, it is only ,r. the first case, where there is, in effect, a shift in the demand for ' reserves, that it will prove optimal to adhere to the intermediate money stock target. The reason is that it is only in this case that readjusting the supply of reserves to keep money on target will, at the same time, also keep nominal income and related macroobjectives on target. (Indeed, it should be noted, shifts in the demand for reserves are automatically accommodated under a federal funds rate instrument whether or not money stock measures are being used as intermediate targets.) To the extent that the second case prevails, however, a shift in the demand for money, it is appropriate to accommodate the shift rather than to resist it. In this case, adhering to the intermediate money stock target by tightening up on the reserves (or interest rate) instrument variable will merely serve to deflect the ultimate goal variables from their desired path. In the third cas~, a shift in the demand for goods and services, it would of course be more appropriate to maintain a money stock target unchanged than it would be to maintain an interest rate target unchanged. The reason is that adherence to a predetermined money stock target would at least permit interest rates to move in o/ a direction that would partially, but only partially, offset the e~fect of the initial shift in aggregate demand. However, because the 9ffset would be only partial, it would be necessary to move the money stock target itself to keep aggregate demand on target. in the case of a shift of aggregate demand, the use of a money https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Thus - 10 - stock intermediate target, while preferable to an interest rate target,is nevertheless not an optimal procedure to follow. \ Given the various possibilities, decision-theoretic analysis argues that movements in an intermediate measure such as M-18 cam at bes, D'.! .a :source of inforo.in:ion, ar,d on1/ -0.,e .among many, as to how changing relationships may require a resetting of the instrument to keep the goal variables on,trackG stronger than expected. For example, ' But given the highly erratic performance of monetary variables in the short run, and given the ready and prompt flow of direct information on the real and financial sides of the economy in the United States, it is difficult to see how movements in the money stock measures can even be 7egarded as a very useful source of information on the, economy. The net con- clusion of this line of analysis, then,would seem to be that intermediate targeting on the monetary aggregates is inef~icient. While the line of analysis that criticizes the use of intermediate targets from the point of view of decision theory I appears entirely correct on its own terms, it is by no ~eans the last word on the subJect. First, it proceeds from completely general assumptions about the structure of the economy in the sense that it assumes no specific restrictions on the relative sources of instability in the economy or on the size of cricital parameters such as the interest elasticity of the demand for money. If more specialized assumptions are made (as is suggested below in discussing one strand of "monetarist" support for the use of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 11 money stock targets), its skeptical conclusions about intermediate targets are undercut. ' More-importantly, however, the somewhat narrow focus of ~he decision-theory view of intermediate targeting fails to address some of the larger concerns and issues that have,in fact,generated widespread support for the use of long-term monetary targets over the past decade or so. D. The Case for Monetary Aggregate Intermediate Targets-Correcting ~r~,;1cJic;i1 Si~S:8!, iri •lJ,'-.:t_i t ?,D°:"'C'f One of the earliest arguments for the use of the mone- tary aggregate targets antedates both the increasing professional and public interest in "monetarism" of the:1960s and the emerging problem of accelerating inflation in the 1970s. thought, This line of which clearly continues to have some relevance, argued that the use of money market conditions instruments (whether net free reserves or short-term interest rates) in the absence of explicit attention to growth rates in measures of money and bank tions in money and reserve growth and can lead to systematic misjudgments of the impact of monetary policy around cyclical turning points. The argument starts from the proposition that the Open Market Committee will tend to show a natural caution in changing its money market conditions obJectives in the face of cyclical changes in the demand fo~ money and credit. The result, accord- ing to this view, is that such a targeting approach leads more or less inevitably to an acceleration in money and credit growth in https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis the ea~ly stages 'of economic expansi'.o:n 'as intere'st rate 'objective·s are not perm'.I. tted to rise rapi'.dl.y ''eno'tigh to ':modera'te the 'cyclical 'strength'eni'ng 'of money and credit demand and as "the rise in money market rates '(and correspond.1.n:g reduction in net free reserves) that does take place is misconstrued as a firming policy. The mechanism suggested by this argument does not explain how upper turning points in the business ·cycle occur, but it do'es suggest that once the economy begins to weaken, declining demands for money and credit will push down interest rates. If, using money market rate targets, the FOMC does not allow rates to fall rapidly enough, again misconstruing the decline in rates as a sign that policy is moving in an appropriately "easing" direction, the result will be a deceleration in money and reserve growth, or even outright declines in these measures. Thus, contrary to belief and intention, the actual impact of policy proves to be procycl ical, worsening the economic downturn. Something of this sort was alleged to have happened in early 196~when, with the economy moving into recession, the Open Market Committee progressively relaxed its money market conditions objectives but apparently not rapidly enough to prevent several months of outright declines in money and bank reserves. It may be, as this view argues, that the use of money market conditions targets produces problems of this sort if there is a systematic tendency for the Committee to adJust its targets "too slowly. 11 However, it does not follow from this that the proper remedy is to move to long-term intermediate monetary https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 13 - aggregate targets. In the language of the decision theory critics I of intermediate targeting already cited, an equally plausible conclusion might be that current and recent money and reserve behavior ought simply to be one of the "information variables" the Committee should take into account in setting its money market conditions obJectives. E. A "Strong Monetarist" Case for Intermediate Money Stock Targets What might be called a "strong monetarist" case for the use of money stock measures as intermediate targets can be derived in various ways by restrictions on the general assumptions of the "decision theory" critics of intermediate targeting. Basically, of course, the end product is simply the proposition that movements in monetary growth rates call the tune for movements in nominal demand. In the usual exposition of this view, the first im- pact of variations in nominal demand is assumed to be on real output, with the ultimate impact concentrated entirely on prices, but only after a substantial lag. More recently, under the in- fluence of the "rational expectations" theorists, some monetarists seem to have taken the position that the entire impact of variations in money growth rates that are nonrandom {and hence anticipated by the public) is on prices even in the short run. In this variant, only unanticipated changes in money growth rates have any effect on the real economy even in the short run. This "rational expectations" wrinkle, however, is inessential to the "strict monetarist" prescription of money stock intermediate targets in view of money's presumed dominating effect on nominal aggregate demand. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 14 - A "strict monetarist" case for money stock intermediate targets can be constructed even in the face of decision theory criticism of such targets in various ways. One possibility is to assume that the demand for money is essentially stable (stable "LM") and that the interest elasticity of the demand for money is negligible (vertical LM). These two assumptions are sufficient to assure that aggregate demand will track money quite closely. turbances in the demand for Dis- money are ruled out by assumption,and any disturbances in the market for goods and services (the "IS" function) will not cause aggregate demand to stray from the level implicit in the money stock target. Further, since disturbances in the market for goods and services cannot affect actual aggregate demand, it is apparently unnecessary to continually readJust money targets in light of incoming information in the manner suggested by the decision-theoretic critics of monetary targeting. Alternatively, some monetarists seem to argue that the private economy is "inherently stable" in the absence of monetary shockso Such a view suggests the interpretation that in practice disturbances in the market for goods and services are likely to be small. Such a conclusion, in turn, again in qonjunction with the assumption that the demand for money is stable, would also logically imply that the use of money targets is an effective way to regulate aggregate demand. Of course, "extreme" assumptions,such as absolute stability in the demand,for money or completely interest-inelastic money demand,should perhaps be regarded as limiting cases. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The - 15 majority of "strict monetarists" would perhaps regard them merely as approximations, but approgimations sufficiently close to reality to Justify the use of money stock targets even in the face of their nonoptimality under more general assumptions. The "strong monetarist" case for intermediate targeting on money stock measures must,of course,rest essentially on empirical evidence. Over the years, evidence that nominal income dances to the tune of money growth rates has been offered both from examination of the cyclical movements of money and the economy and from examination of the relationship of changes in nominal GNP to current and lagged changes in money. In addition, a number of economists have attempted to provide evidence on one of the main constituent arguments of the "strong monetarist" position, the stability of the demand for money. Both the particular results and the general methodological procedures involved in producing these variouE strands of evidence remain a source of substantial dispute in the economics professiono And in recent years, the case for stablemoney-demand has come under·particrirarly intense attack as a result of evidence that standard relationships began to break down in a rnaJor way around the rnid-1970s (as discussed further below). It should be noted that with some additional assumptions, the strong monetarist case can be extended to a case not only for long-term monetary targets but, indeed, for a monetary "rule" where the intermediate target once set and achieved-would never be changed except perhaps in the face of long-term structural https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 16 - changes in the economy affecting the trend rate of growth in output or in the demand for money. One such additional assumption is, of course,the familiar argument that while the economy dances to the tune of money, the effects of money on the dancer are uncertain in the sense that they operate with long and variable lags. In this case, it is argued, discretionary movements in the intermediate money target should be replaced with a fixed growth rate target adjusted ultimately to a rate of growth consistent with a zero (or perhaps slightly negative) rate of inflation. To be sure, faced with unfavorable initial conditions, such as a high embedded rate of inflation, such a final fixed setting of the intermediate target might have to be approached only gradually over time. An alternative assumption that also seems to produce a case for a monetary "rule" is the rational expectations argument' that systematic (and therefore anticipated) movements in the money 1/ stock affect only prices.- In this case also, there is no room for (systematic) discretionary adjustments in the money stock inter~.mediate target, which might g_ust as well-be fixed at·a-,·rate pro1 ducing the desired behavior of prices. Indeed, under the rational expectations argument, in the absence of long-term contracts, the intermediate money stock growth target could be moved right away 1/ See Thomas J. Sargent and ~eil Wallace, "'Rational' Expect2tions, the Optimal Monetary Instruwent, and the Opt1rral Money Surply Rl :e, 11 Journal of Political Econorey, vol. 83 {April 1975), pp. 241-54. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -·u· - 17 to its desired long-term setting -- at least if the authorities announce their intentions and are believed so that the shift in policy generates no "real" effects. F. A "Practical Monetarist" Case for Long-Term Money Stock Targets A different approach to the use of monetary inter- mediate targets starts from the search for a monetary policy strafegy to deal with the chronic inflation problem of the past 15 years. This alternative route to monetary targeting has been termed "practical m'onetarism, 11 although the main thing it shares with the "strong monetarist" approach is the conclusion that the Federal Reserve should indeed make use of long-term money stock objectives as intermediate ta,rge;ts. Practical monetarism takes no particular position on the extent to' which short-term movements in aggregate demand a.re dominated by the behavior of the money supply. But it does accept the view very widely (if not quite universally) held that in the long run, inflation rates will be no greater than are accommodated by the long-run rate of monetary growth. Under this view, excessive monetary growth, is a necessary condition for inflation, and reductior. in monetary growth is--a necessary condition for restoring reasonable price stability. A corollary of this view is that in the long run, monetary growth rates affect only nominal magnitudes (including the level of nominal interest rates) and have little or no effects on real output, real interest rates,or the composition of output-as between consumption and investment, for example. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Consequently, - 18 - if long-run money growth targets are to be set, their ultimate objectives should be framed entirely in terms of the desired behavior of the price level. It should be noted that in accepting excessive money rowth as a necessary condition for inflation in the long run, his view by no means rules out other possible sources of inflation over shorter periods and is therefore not committed to any tight relationship between the path of inflation and the path of monetary expansion. Moreover, it does not even rule out the possibility that nonmonetary forces may play a major role i,n initiating inflationary pressures, to which, in effect, money growth must be accommodated if the authorities are to avoid sharply adverse short-run effects on output and employment. The implication of these po~nts, in turn, is that monetary policy by itself may not be able, in any realistic sense, to bring inflation under control without appropriate cooperation from other types of policies and perhaps even from some "good luck"' in avoiding nonmonetary inflationary shocks. Nevertheless, the clear agenda for monetary policy implied by 0 practical monetarism" is that whatever else may be need- ed to bring inflation under control, the role of monetary policy will have to be to reduce monetary growth rates over the long run \ to rates compatible with' approximate price stability. Indeed, to the extent that the long-run real growth potential of 'the economy can be estimated and trend behavior of money velocity guessed at, it may be possible to quantify in rough terms the long-run obJective of policy in monetary growth rate terms. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Moreover, to the - ;I.9 - extent that current inflation ra;tes are at least partly "embedded" in ,the economy in the form of -long-term contracts (including the nomipal interest rates on outstanding long-term debt) and in JKJ~J· •form of inflationary expectations that are sub~ect only to gradual change, it follows that monetary growth rates will have to partially .. ... ~ accommodate the embedded inflation rate in the short run. Thus the objective of "practical monetarism" is to reduce money growth rates to noninflationary levels, but only over time. In effect, then, practical monetarism lays out a longterm strategy for monetary policy for dealing with inflation, a strategy that is compatible with a very wide range of views about the inflationary process and about the determinants of short-run economic fluctuations. The potential value of long-term inter- mediate targets for monetary policy couched in terms of monetary growth rates has several dimensions in this strategic context. First,it provides an internal guideline for the Federal Reserve itself against which shorter-term developments and decis~?M can be viewed, creating, in effect, a kind of self-disciplining procedure for keeping the longer-run objectives in view. Second, the use of money stock targets in the contex:t of winding down excessive monetary growth over time provides a means of communicat' ing~the objectives of policy with the rest of the government and with the public. To the extent that the Federal Reserve comes to provide a credible record of achieving its announced intentions, the very announcement of progressively lower monetary targets should have an independently favorable effect on inflationary expectations. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 20 ' And an improvement in inflationary expectations, in turn, would be' a major means for reducing the cost of reducing_ inflation in terms of temporarily-reduced o~tput levels. The use of monetary targets as a tool of communication might also be important in clearing up the•· wiaespread public confusion about the relationship between anti-inflationary monetary policies,· interest rates, and the· actual performance of prices. If it is understood that the objective of anti-inflationary policy is to reduce monetary growth and ultimately nominal interest rates, then the frequently 'Voiced complaint that "tight money" raises interest costs and thus actually abets inflation may become widely seen as a misconception. It should be noted that the possibility of defining an anti-inflationary strategy in terms of a long-term path for intermediate money growth rate targets, with its attendant ~dvantages for internal and external communication, apparently has no analog in interest rate targets. There is seemingly no satisfactory way to state a long-term anti-inflation strategy in terms of nominal or real interest rates as can be done in the case of money growth targets. As inflation comes down, nominal interest rates would undoubtedly also decline. But to aim at a policy of "gradually reducing nominal interest rates over time" to some presumed noninflationary 1sve1 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 21 - {that is, to some long-terni 11 natural 11 real rate of interest) appears to involve major risks that precisely the opposite of the intended results will occur. Reductions in nominal rates might prove to be exactly the wrong prescription in any particular period, and in the case of long rates, this might well be unachievable. Moreover, we have no way to estimate what the real long-term "natural" rate of interest may be or, finally, any particular reason to assume it is constant over time. It is, to be sure, possible to put a constraint on policy in terms of "real" interest rates such as "nominal rates should always be high enough to make real interest rates positive. 11 Indeed ,it seems reasonably clear that nega- tive real interest rates would be incompatible with price stability and probably even with a nonaccelerating rate of inflation. But there seem to be serious practical measure- ment problems in connection with the real interest rate concept that would have to be faced if it were to be used as a formal,quantitative intermediate target. These problems stem from difficulties of defining and measuring expected rates of inflation over the various relevant time horizons and the problems of determining appropriate tax adjustments for borrowers and lenders in different tax situations. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 22 - As indicated, the "practical monetarist" case for long-term money stock intermediate targets arises out of the desire to find an appropriate strategy for dealing with secular inflation. One implication of this might seem to be that if and when inflation were substantially eliminated, long-term money targets would no longer be needed -- and, of course, the Federal Reserve, in fact, had no such targets during the long period between the accord and the early 1970S3 when inflation was generally low by present standards. An alternative interpretation, however, I is that our recent experience with inflation has shattered the public's confidence in the long-run stability of the price level. If so, any actual return to price stability might prove very precarious because of the speedy and sharply unfavorable effects on inflationary expectations that any short-term re-emergence of inflation might produce. Thus a commitment to the maintenance of monetary growth at rates compatible with rough price stability might continue to be needed as a financial anchor. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - G. 23 - Problems With Implementing a Strategy of Gradual Monetary Deceleration -- Is Rigorous Adherence to Money Targets Desirable? While the "practical monetarist" position clearly im- plies-the desirability of setting and-achieving money grewth targets over some "long-run, 11 it does not necessarily imply that such targets should be followed rigorously over shorter periods of time. Indeed, a number of questions can be raised about the desirability of seeking to continuously reset instruments to keep money growth along some predetermined track. (Questions about the feasibility of rigorously tracking money targets are not discussed in this paper.) The questions about the desirability of attempting rigorously to adhere to money growth targets are well known. In the first place, rigorous control of money growth implies sacrifice of any ability to influence interest rates, let alone to seek specific interest rate objectives. There are many reasons why the _ Federal Reserve may have a legitimate concern for. interest rate behavior per se. On the international side, foreign exchange rates are highly sensitive to interest rate differentials. times when the policymakers There may be may prefer to constrain interest rate movements at the expense of a temporary loss of control of money growth to prevent adverse developments in the exchange markets. Similarly, on the domestic side, the performance of interest rates per se can be of immense importance to the cyclical performance of the economy and to the functioning of financial markets and to financial health generally. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis There is, for one thing, - '24 a whole group of credit market "stress" phenomena that can -arise when sharply rising open market interest rates collide with various kinds of institutional or other frictions. These phenomena include _disintermediation,, .credit "-c:c:unches, 11 and other types of market, "failures" that may result in part from institutionally created frictions (such as interest rate ceilings on deposits or lending rates) or simply from the difficulties financial intermediaries may encounter in coping with sharply negative yield curves that often materialize in "tight money" periods. This whole array of phenomena may, as some believe, have major significance for the way monetary policy impacts the economy in the cyclical context, and, of course, it is clearly relevant to the "lender of last resort" function in the face of threatened financial breakdown. Given such financial problems, or the risk that they might emerge, concern with the behavior of open market interest rates might well at times supersede the desire to keep monetary targets on track. ~To bersure, some proponents of money growth targets would argue tha-c in the fot~rest of foreign exchange market stability interest rate stability and the avoidance,of financial breakdown are best served in the long run by stable monetary performance. This may well be true, but it provides no guidance on the extent to which monetary targets should be superseded in the short-run in the event of imminent or ongoing foreign exchange or domestic financial market problems. Perhaps more subtle and pervasive questions about the desirability of pursuing rigorously monetary growth targets are https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 25 - raised by questions about the stability of the "demand for money" -- that is, the stability of the amount of monetary assets (however defined) the public will seek to hold under given interest rate and aggregate demand conditions. The extent to which the demand for money can be regarded as "stable" is controversial and is deeply enmeshed in unsettled econometric issues of considerable complexity -- although there is at least agreement that conventionally formulated demand functions for "money" in any of the thenconventional definitions did break down in a serious way in 1974 and for some time thereafter. It may be useful to think of problems imposed by potential money demand instability in short, intermediate,and secular terms. Consider first a "short-run," defined, for example, as movements within the calendar quarter, the usual unit of observation for econometric money demand functions. Even if the demand for money is "stable" in the usual sense, normal stochastic developments not accounted for in the equation may lead to substantial deviations of actual from predicted money demand in the , short runo To ,be sure, if the function is . properly formulated and 1s truly II stable, 11 these errors will be random and will tend to wash out over time. But this may not prevent these movements from presenting significant practical problems for policytT1akers. In theory, once unexpected deviations in money growth are known to represent genuine "shifts" in money demand, it will probably become appropriate to accommodate to them by readjusting money targets https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 26 - accordingly. The difficulty for the policymaker lies in the fact that if the normal random errors in money demand functions are large (relative to the size of target ranges), it may take a large number of observations of money demand "errors" before "permanent" shifts in demand can be identified by the usual statistical tests. Thus in the presence of errors that may or may not prove in retrospect to have been random and selfreversing, the policymaker is faced with uncertainty as to whether and how to respond. Given the difficulties of identify- ing a "shift" with the usual statistical techniques until several quarters of data are available, this problem has., in fact., been troublesome on a number of occasions. In the short run, a shift of money growth from expected values is automatically accommodated under a federal funds ( rate target unless it is substantial enough to trigger the sort of feedback mechanism formerly provided by the "tolerance range" errtployed by the FOMC in conjunction with its federal funds rate targetso Under a nonborrowed reserves approach, a movement of money growth (for whatever reason) from the rate implied by th~-intermeeting nonborrowed reserve path will automatically set off changes in interest rates. The point is that under either approach, off-target behavior of the money stock will at some point force a decision to be made as to whether the behavior represents a demand shift that should be accommodated. A federal funds rate approach tends to err on the side of assuming (implicitly) a demand shift and accommodating it. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A nonborrowed reserve approach, on the other - 27 - hand, never fully accommodates unexpected money behavior whether due to a temporary shift demand or to some other cause since it does set off partly offsetting movements in interest rates. As already suggested, the sort of long-term shift in the demand for money that apparently occurred around 1974 requires either that the money targets be changed to a~commodate the shift or, where appropriate, that "money" be redefined and new targets set. Again the problem is that knowledge that the demand curve has shifted is never absolutely firm and can, at best, only emerge gradually over time. And again the point is that judgment must be made whether to suspend or modify pursuit of existing target growth rates. More generally, the experience of recent years has suggested to many that forces are in place that tend to generate, however irregularly, a long-term downward drift in the demand for money that will at the least complicate the implementation of the "practical monetarist" strategy. One source of such long-term forces would be delayed institutional, technological, and capital ~ investment responses to rising incentives to economize on the use 1/ of transactions balances paying below-market rates of interest.Another possible source of long-term shifts in the demand for money is the increasing sophistication of computer and electronic l! See Thomas D. Simpson and Richard D. Porter, 11 Some Issues Involving the Definition and Interpretation of the Monetary Aggregates,' 1 a paper presented at the 1980 Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference on Controlling the Monetary Aggregates, Bald Peak, New Hampshire, October 7, 1980. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 28 - technology. Technological ~dvances have encouraged the, cr~~tion of new, quasi-transactions instruments paying market interest rates as well as new means of minimizing holdings of the more traditional instruments. The future progress of such development~ is of course unknown. But the prospect is that emerging alternatives to transactions instruments that pay below-market rates will be exploited, possibly at an accelerating rate. Obviously, such a prospect makes more uncertain the path toward noninflationary monetary growth envisioned by practical monetarism as well as the ultimate distination of such a path. Indeed, it raises questions about the very future of any transactions in$trument that must face the competitive hurdle of a reserve requirement 11 tax. 11 H. Which Aggreg~te To Use?. Different approaches to the use of monetary aggregate measures as long-term intermediate targets may imply different answers to the question of just which aggregate or aggregates to target. As noted, the "decision theory" approach in general concludes that any intermediate target would be inefficient. It does suggest, however, that the relative value of alternative measures as monetary "indicators" should be evaluated in terms of their relative value as sources of information on current movements in the goal variables. The strong monetarist view, of course, implies t h a t ~ money stock measure should be used, but monetarists (like other economists) have been divided over the years as to Just which money measure might be best. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 29 The "practical monetarist" approach does not appear to imply any particular measure of money. Indeed, it does not even seem to rule out the possibility that some nonmonetary financial measure might be used to define the long-term strategy for restoring price stability. In principle, long-term targets defined in terms_'of credit or reserve aggregates, for example, might serve as well as money stock measures. As a matter of ab- stract theory, it appears that the stabilization of any financial magnitude in a deterministic model of the economy will stabilize y the price level in the long run. The practical question would seem to be which measure or measures have the most stable demand, have the tightest relationship to nominal GNP and other major macrovariables, have the closest relation to price performance in the long run; are most clearly subject to Federal Reserve control, and have the greatest value in terms of their impact on expectations and communication. Unfortunately no single measure, whether monetary or otherwise, seems to emerge as the clear choice given this multiplicity of crite~ia. / J Numerous-attempts have_been made over. the pas±.decade or so to discriminate among various definitions of money (and bank credit) on the basis of the closeness of the relationship of nominal GNP to current and lagged values of the various competing 1/ See Franco Modigliani and Lucas Padademos, "The Structure of Financial Markets and the Monetary Mechanisrr., 11 paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference on Control 1ing the ~onetary Aggregates, 1980. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 30 - aggregates. The results, in general, have failed to turn up clear- cut winners, and they have proved sensitive to apparent 11 deta1ls' 1 of equation specification and estimation period. With respect to money demand equations, conventional econometric equations for all the new and old money stock measures apparently underwent a shift in the mid-1970s. Moreover, t~e econometric properties of the demand equations for all the various measures have also apparently deteriorated in recent years, producing implausible coefficient values for individual explanatory variables. With respect to the breakdown of the equations after the middle of the decade, broader aggregate measures that include the new instruments, such as 1~0W accounts and money market funds, show substantially smaller cumulative drift than narrow measures. However, there seems to be little agreement as to the precise source of the better performance and hence some problem in prescribing the best measure for future use. One recent survey of the econometric properties of the various money stock measures concluded that "one unambiguous result these statistical exercises provide is that money demand and reduced-form equations ..,, have no power - to discrim"' --- ... inate among alternative aggregate definitions. all While this may overstate the case, it is clear that the econometricians have not yet been able to resolve the problem in any decisive way. 1/ Neil Berlanan, "hbandoning Monetary Aggregates, 1 paper presented to the Federa 1 Reserve ~ank. of Boston Conference 011 Colltro 11 i ng the Monetary Aggregates, 19809 p. 22. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 31 - A priori considerations also seem to fail to point to a clear choice. It has been suggested from time to time, for example, that money stock measures ought to make better policy targets than bank credit measures -- to which they are obviously related on the supply side -- because there are allegedly fewer substitutes for "money" (at least as defined in transactions terms) than there are for "bank credit" and because "money" as an aggregate is allegedly more homogenous than "bank credit. 11 The implication presumably is that money mea- sures should have more stable demand functions than bank credit and that money demand is less likely than the demand for bank credit to be disturbed by financial market innovations and by market developments affecting relative interest rates. If these propositions were true in the past, their plausibility would seem to have been considerably weakened by the financial innovations of recent years. With regard to choices among particular definitions of the money stock, a priori arguments again seem to fail to provide decisive answers. On the surface, rece.at experience with changes in the utilization of conventional transactionstype instruments and the invention of new ones would seem to point to a preference for broader money stock measures that include the new instruments and away from narrow measures such as M-18. Other considerations tend to undereut this conclusion, however. (1) As Regulation Q is phased out, a substantial proportion of the broader measures will become https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 32 - more competitive with market instruments, increasing uncertainty about the interest rate sensitivity of the demand for the broader 1/ measures over the transition period.- (2) The demand for the broader measures may be relatively sensitive to minor changes in relative yields -- such as the rate on money market funds versus open market rates, for example -- and hence may show a relatively unstable relationship to the average level of rates. (3) Growing portions of the broader aggregates are not currently subJect to reserve requirements, creating control problems in a reserveoriented tactical approach. (4) Finally, there is a good deal of uncertainty as to just how broad a measure to use once the decision moves beyond M-1B. Why exclude·(include) large CDs, for ,, example? Such decisions•could make a substantial difference in the short- to medium-term if only a single measu~e were to be targeted. Broad credit aggregates have been studied far less extensively in the literature than money stock measures. The available evidence suggests that a:: least some broad ~redit measures may be as 2/ closely or more closely related to GNP than the money measures~ What, if anything, this may mean in "cause and effect" terms is unclear from the existing research. 1/ For no apparent reason, See Simpson and Porter, "Some Issues, 11 p. 14. 2/ See Richard G. Davis, "Broad Credit Measures as Targets for Monetary Policy, 11 Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Quarterly Review, Summer 1979, pp. 13-22. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 33 - moreover, other broad credit measures evidently perform worse than the standard money measures and all the caveats associated with the methodology of "reduced form" equations and the sensitivity of their results to details of specification and choice of sample period need to be kept in mind. With broad credit measures, moveover, the problem of control by the Federal Reserve would presumably be even more difficult than it is in the case of money measures. Successful use of funds rate approach to finan- cial aggregates implies the existence of a reasonably stable demand function for the aggregate. But no one has even suggested that the demand for broad credit totals should be a stable function of aggregate demand and short-term rates, let alone provided evidence that such a relationship actually exists. A reserve tactical approach would appear completely irrelevant in the case of broad credit measures. Given the problems with money stock and credit measures, especially with respect to control, it is tempting to ask whether a measure such as total reserves or the total monetary base might not prove a suitable intermediate target? In some respe~ts the control problem is clearly easier to solve for these measures than for the money stock measures. The only slippage between a non- borrowed reserves (or nonborrowed base) instrument and a total reserves (or total base) target is obviously borrowings. Ignoring the short-term problem created by lagged reserve accounting, this clearly would be easier to deal with than the multiple slippages that exist between these instrument measures and the money stock https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 34 - measures. In the case of a funds rate approach, however, con- trol problems for total reserves would be similar to those encountered with money stock objectives. Apart from the controllability question there are some respects in which the total reserves or the monetary base seem inferior to the money stock measures, or at least no improvement. The available evidence does seem to indicate fairly decisively that the relationship of nominal GNP to current and lagged measures of total reserves and the base is substantially less 1/ close than the relationship of nominal GNP to money stock measures7 Moreover, any shifts in the demand for money will be transmitted into corresponding shifts in the demand for reserves and the monetary base to the extent that there are corresponding shifts in the demands for required reserves and/or currency. Finally, total reserves and the base have the potential for some special problems of their own that would tend to destabilize their relationshjp to aggregate demand and thus weaken their value as intermediate targets. These include shifts in the public's desired currency/deposit ratio, shifts in the demand for excess reserves, and shifts in the demand for nonmonetary reservable • 1/ See Richard G. Davis, "The Monetary Base as an Intermediate Target for Monetary Policy," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Quarter!~ Review, Winter 1979-80, and Carl Gambs, 11 Federal Reserve Intermediate Targets: Money on the Monetary Base?" Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review, January 1980, pp. 3-15. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - liabilities. 35 - In short, targeting on the base or reserves risks transmitting to the economy at large shifts not only in the demand for money but also 11 supply-side 11 shifts emanating from changes in the demand for reserves for given levels of the money stock. I. The Use of Mixed Strategies The preceding discussion suggests that even granting the desirability of setting, and meeting, long-term monetary targets, there remains a problem of bridging the gap between short-run decisionmaking and long-run strategy. If one takes the view that once long-run money targets are set, short-term decisionmaking should concentrate solely on the task of hitting them,-the problem of meshing short- and long-run decisionmaking is, to be sure, considerably simplified. But even \ in this case, the impossibility of hitting money stock targets precisely in the short-run requires consideration of how short-run tactics should be designed. Thus consideration has to be given to how the setting of short-run tactical instruments should respond to misses in keeping money growth on track. In particular, over how long a time horizon shou1d the Federal Reserve aim to restore money growth to its target when such misses have occurred? If one goes beyond the pure money control approach and takes the view that there may be good reasons for suspending pursuit of money targets from time to time or for changing them, the problem of meshing short-run decisionmaking strategy obviously becomes more difficult. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis with longer-term - 36 - Given the uncertainties in identifying demand shifts, for example, there are risks both in under-reacting to, off-target movements in money supply -- perhaps the natural bias of afeder~ funds rate approach -- and of ~-reacting, perhaps the natural bias of a nonborrowed reserves approach~ And the same kinds of problems of meshing short- and long-run decisions will, of course, arise at any time interest rate levels (or their volatility) become themselves a source of direct concern and thus a reason to suspend or alter money growth targetso In the face of issues of this kind an obvious suggestion is the adoption of some sort of "mixed strategy" combining, in some manneru the use of long-run intermediate targets with shortrun flexibility to respond to perceived shifts in money demand and ' the impact of interest rates on international and' domestic finan- cial markets. Such a strategy would attempt to achieve the main objective of the "practical monetarist" program: An orderly pro- gressive slowing over time in the monetary aggregates as a necessar: component of an overall anti-inflation strategy. It would start from the premise that whatever uncertainties there may be about ' shifts in the demand for money and about long-term changes in the trend growth of velocity, money growth rates, however measured and defined, have been too high in recent years and perhaps too variable over the business cycle. On the other hand, this approach would also take the view that money targets are not to be pursued mechanically, but that, as indicated, there will be, from time to time, good and sufficient reason to suspend or modify them. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 37 - This sort of "mixed strategy" is clearly open to competing dangers. On the one hand, overly rigorous concentration on sticking to money targets exposes policy to potential risks from shifts in money demand, from interest rate movements with undesirable market impacts, and from the generation of instability in interest rates and perhaps in the economy itself. The other side of the coin, however, is that the compromising of long-term money objectives risks continual postponement of movement toward a noninflationary financial environment and it risks the loss of Federal Reserve credibility. It thus threatens to throw away the potential expectational and communications benefits of monetary targets and the anti-inflationary strategy based on their use. Obviously it is easier to state these opposing dangers than it is to point a course between them. The attempt to achieve a reasonable balance of opposing risks requires consideration of the choice of operating tactics and of institutional arrangements, neither of which are within the preview of this paper. In any case, unless the Federal Reserve moves toward a rigidly inflexible pursuit of monetary aggregate targets, it will probably , not prove possible to solve the dilemmas of relating short-run decisions to long-run strategy in purely technical terms. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 38 - J. Structural Limitations on the Setting of Intermediate Policy Targets In concluding this discussion of intermediate targets it is important to emphasize an issue touched on at various points earlier in the paper: namely, the existence of structural fea- tures in the economy that may impose significant limitations on the settings of intermediate targets, however formulated. The issue of such limitations arises in part from the apparent fact that monetary policy initially impacts mainly on real variables and only more gradually on prices. To the extent this is true, ' settings of intermediate targets have to take into account limits on the tolerable short-run impact of such settings on output and other real variables and on a potentially fragile financial system. The existence of such limits has already been alluded to in de- scribing the practical monetarist_program as one of gradual reduction in monetary growth. The case for such gradualism rests on a desire to accommodate partially the embedded rate of in'flation and . thus to reduce short-run impacts on real variables and the finan- cial system. The speed with which inflation can be expected to respond to monetary policy, the ext~nt to which policy affects the real economy in the short run, and therefore the extent of the potential flexibility to adjust intermediate monetary targets are the subjects of debate. Monetary restraint (however indexed) is generally viewed as affecting inflation by,restricting aggregate demand. Lowered aggregate demand is visualized as creating market slack https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 39 - that leads to slower average rates of increases in prices and wages. In most versions of this process, the resulting experience of slower inflation gradually lowers the public's expected rate of inflation along with the actual rate. Tpe gradual decline in the expected rate of inflation, in turn, makes possible a progressive slowing in actual inflation as long as some level of slack in markets is maintained. The bulk of the econometric evidence (and indeed of more "casual" sorts of evidence) from the postwar period, however, tends to be pessimistic about the speed with which inflation can be slowed through this process and about the costs entailed in 1/ terms of less-than-potential levels of real activity.- This evidence suggests that given (1) existing rigidities in the pricing mechanism, (2) little or no direct favorable impact of policy actions on inflationary expectations, and (3) no assistance from other government policies, anti-inflationary policies that operate through aggregate demand alone could well require several years of slack to achieve major reductions in the underlying rate of inflation. Taken by itself, this evidence therefore suggests that efforts to reduce inflation through progressive reductions in targeted money growth would have to proceed quite gradually to avoid major adverse effects on real activity. 1/ A summary of findings on this matter is given in Arthur M. Okun, "Efficient Disinflationary Policies, 11 American Economic Review, vol. 68, (r1ay 1978), p. 348. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 40 - There are, to be sure, plausible grounds for a more optimistic view of the problem than these results by themselves seem to suggest. For one thing, it is possible that other kinds of government policies (such as policies to reduce/rigidities in the pricing mechanism and tax policies to reduce costs or to provide incentives to limit wage and price increases) could alter the structure of the economy in a favorable direction. ' Such changes could speed up the responsiveness of prices and wages to market conditions. Such a speed-up, in turn, would make possible a quicker re- duction in inflation at smaller cost, even without any favorable alteration in the way price expectations are formed. These develop- ments could thus make possible a more rapid implementation of the practical monetarist program. Further, it is possible that monetary policy itself could have a directly favorable impact on inflationary expectatio~s that would also speed up the process. The available econometric evi- dence generally does not allow for such an impact. Instead,it assumes that inflationary expectations are the mechanical product of past inflation history. This is a major factor accounting for the sluggishness with which inflation rates apparently respond to aggregate demand policies in this literature. Yet one of the in- tended potential benefits of defining a monetary strategy in terms of progressively reduced targets for monetary growth is precisely that such an announced policy, if credible, could by its very announcement lower inflationary expectations. Such an impact on expectations, in turn, would make a possible quicker lowering of actual inflation than is implied by the existing evidence. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 41 - In the limit, as some versions of the rational expectations theory suggest, the impact of an announced policy of monetary reduction might produce a more or less immediate correspond1/ ing slowdown in inflation with little or no loss of output.Such an outcome is at least imaginable to the extent that (1) money does affect prices proportionally in the long run and is neutral as to real effects, (2) the targeted slowdown in money growth is announced and the announcement is believed, (3) the public quickly foresees the ultimate price effects of the targeted money slowdown, and (4) markets are free to respond without frictions to the implications of these changed expectations. This extreme "optimistic" case, however, also seems open to serious' questions. The questions stem from the apparent existence of rigidities in the pricing mechanism and the likelihood that the generally expected rate of inflation may be subject to a substantial degree of inertia. First, there are significant institutional In "The Ends of Four Big Inflations," Working Paper 158, (Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis), Thomas Sargent cites the hyperinflations of four central European countries in the early 1920s that ended abruptly with, apparently, no more than relatively moderate and temporary adverse effects on real output following the announcement of policy reforms. The relevance of this experience to the present U.S. situation can, of course, be questioned because of thd differences in circumstances. Of particular importance to the present discussion is the fact that the policy changes made in these four countries included sweeping and binding restrictions involving both monetary and fiscal policy, in two cases imposed under agreementwith foreign creditors. These were clearly much more far-reaching changes than anything contemplated in the CGntext of the intermediate monetary target discussion. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis characteristics of the economy that would seem to prevent any immediate full translation of slower monetary growth into price effects almost whatever its impact on expectations. Thus there are many long-term contracts in the economy that implicitly embody some ongoing expected rate of inflation. Examples include multi- year wage agreements, utility rate schedules, rents subject to fixed-term leases, and fixed interest rate debt instruments. In markets where long-term contracts exist, changes in demand conditions are likely to have implications for the level of real activity since prices cannot irmnediately adjust.' Moreover, any actual change in the rate of inflation shifts the real terms of trade between the contracting parties and is thus likely to have ieal effects. 'I Apart from long-term contracts embodying existing inflationary expectations, the vast majority of labor and product markets depart substantially from the textbook model of organized financial and commodity markets in which prices react continuously . 1/ and sensitively to changed conditions.Instead, for whatever reasons, most prices and wages are set relatively infrequently so that demand pressures are likely to affect volume before they affect prices -- though, to be sure, wage- and price-setting practices are·themselves probably responsive to the rate of inflation in the longer run. 1/ See, for example, Arthur M. Okun, "Inflation: Its Mechanics and Welfare Costs, 11 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1975: 2, pp. 351-90. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 43 - With respect to inflationary expectations, the precise exte~t ,to which annottnced targeted reductions in monetary growth c9uld be expected directly to lower the expected rate of inflation is conjectural. The whole postwar economic experience might • well suggest to a "rational" public that there is an-inflationary bias in modern industrial economies and, indeed, in government policies, whatever their announced intentions. Moreover, the actual per,formance of monetary aggregate behavior relative to Federal Reserve targets since they were has itself been somewhat mixed. first announced in 1975 Thus the direct impact on in- flationary expectations 0£ an announced reduction in targets for monetary aggregates may not be very large -- at And it is possible least not by itself. to doubt, even under the most favorable circum- stances, whether inflationary expectations for the public at large are importantly influenced by announcements of monetary policy intentions. tions That such announcements might loom large in the expecta- of participants in sensitive and sophisticated financial markets is certainly plausible. That they would loom equally large in the wide range of less sophisticated markets seems much more open to doubt. Thus, it seems likely that, 11 rational" or not, the public's expectations of continuing inflation are not likely to be easily overcome. And for this reason as well, it appears that intermediate monetary targets settings would have to accommodate ongoing inflation to some degree to avoid unacceptable effects on real output. Finally, the point already mentioned that the feasible settings of intermediate targets, of whatever kind, may be https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 44 - constrained at times by structural features of the financial system also needs emphasis. Reductions in monetary growth rates, to the extent they lower the rate of inflation, will also lower nominal interest rates over time. But for reasons already noted, the full I 1 For effects ~n inflation are likely to be ~elt only gradually. related reasons, the immediate effects of slower monetary growth may well be higher rather than lower interest rates -- or at least in the short-term sector where prospective longer-term beneficial effects on the inflation premium loom less large. Clearly, for reasons mentioned earlier, there may be limits to the extent to which interest rates can rise in the short run without creating serious problems for financial institutions and the functioning of markets and thus ultimately for the "real" economy. Such limits would therefore also restrict the extent to which financial aggregate targets could be lowered at any given time. In summary, there appear to be important structural characteristics of the economy that put , ' limits on the feasible settings ' of potential intermediate targets measures however defined. To be sure, the use of such targets may have directly favorable effects on inflationary expectations. To that extent, they can lessen the problems created by these structural features. Nevertheless, the structural rigidities themselves would remain, whatever intermediate target or targets may be used. Thus the choice of whether to use such targets at all and, 1f so, which target or targets to use seems unlikely to dispose of significant limitations on the use of monetary policy. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ECONOMIC DISTTJRBANCES AND r,,1'0NETARY POL I<~Y RESPONSES Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of ~onetary Control Procedures by Jared J. Enzler Contributions to the paper were Made by J. Herry, n. 8attenberg, C. Corrado, and W. Davis from the Hoard staff; by B. Figgins and V. Roley froM the Kansas City Rank; and by J. TatoM from the St. Louis Bank. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ( ECONOMIC DISTURRANCES AND MONETARY POLICY RESPONSES Section I: Introduction The central topic of this project is an evaluation of the rela- tive merits of using the federal funds rate or a bank reserve measure as the monetary policy operating instrument. While much of the project is concerned with the ability to achieve intermediate monetary-aggregate targets, this paper is mainly concerned with the ability of policymakers to achieve their overall objectives for the economy. Using both reduced forms and the Board's quarterly structural econometric model, the consequences of various disturbances to the economy under selected monetary policy operating rules are examined. It should be noted at the outset that the models used in this paper, which are quite representative of the types in current use, do not take into account the recently popular notion that the structure of the economic system may depend on the existing policy rules. Practical models which incorporate this notion are not yet available; if they were, they would undoubtedly produce quite different results from the ones reported below. Whether good models should incorporate this notion in a very power- ful way is, of course, still a matter of great dispute. Section II is backward looking. The year since October 6, 1979, has been characterized by dramatic fluctuations in both short-term interest rates and money ~rowth. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The consequences of following a smoother money -2growth rate policy over this period are investigated using both the quarterly model and some reduced-form models. Then the results flowing from a smoother interest rate policy are examined. Section III addresses the consequences of deviations in monetary policy instruments from desired paths. In particular, it examines the effects of various re-entry paths for policy instruments which have strayed from planned values. Once again, the question is addressed using both the quarterly and reduced-form models. The analysis presented in Section III turns out to be somewhat unsatisfying. It is argued in Section IV that in analyzing the consequences of deviations of policy instruments from planned paths, it is very important to understand what caused the deviations. It is demonstrated, using the quarterly model, that the consequences of an economic disturbance depend both on the nature of the disturbance and on the policy response. It follows that the choice of policy responses should depend on historically based knowledge concerning the relative frequencies and severities of the different kinds of disturbances, and also should take into account any infor-, mation available concerning the sources of the disturbances as they occur. Section II: Smoothing the Policy Instrument Path In the past year both money growth and the federal funds rate have been extremely volatile. Table 1 reports quarterly average historical values for the federal funds rate and the growth rates of various money stock concepts used by the models analyzed in this section. The funds rate was even more volatile than the quarterly average numbers reported in the table suggest. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The average rate for the month of April 1980 reached -1- a cyclical high of 17.6 percent. By July the rate was down to 9 percent, and by December it had climhed to lR.Q percent. Table 1 1979 Federal funds rate Quarterly average M-lAl End-of-quarter M-lA 1/2/ Quarterly-average M-1R 1 1980 03 04 03 Q4 01 02 10.9 13.6 15.0 12.7 9.8 15.9 R.R 4.7 4.8 -3.9 11.() 8.7 6.3 4.4 .1 2.1 14.4 o.oe 10 .1 'i. 3 -2.4 13 .s 11.4 e = estimated 1/ Percent increase at compound annual rates. 2/ End of quarter coMputed as the average of the two months surrounding the end of the quarter. It is natural to aqk what the economy would have looked like had the path of one or the other of theqe instruments been smoothed. terly econometric model can he used for this purpose. The quar- It can be simulated taking either the funds rate or money growth as a policy-determined instrument. models. It 1s also poqqible to adrlress the question using rerluced-form A number of rerluced-forfll. models which take money growth as the policy-determined variahle are available. them. He have choqen to use two of The first was developed by John Tatom of the St. Louis Federal Reserve Rank. It will hereafter he referred to aq SL-Ml. T~e second was developed by Byron Higgins and Vance Roley of the Kansaq City Federal Reserve ~ank and is lahelerl KC-Ml. The only availahle reduced-form model which takes interest rates as the policy instrument waq also rleveloped by Higgins and Ro]ey. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis It is referred to in this paper as KC-"t;'F. -4SL-Ml is a rather stanrlard reducecl-form equati,on which has been modified to take account of the relative price of energy. 1 , The SL-Ml model is 4 4 400 MnGNP = , wiA400tnMlt-i + E vi A n Et-i i=O i=O 6 e - .462 s + E ai 400 A 9,,n Pt-i + 2.59Q, i=O wo = .310 vo = .075 a.o w1 = .421 v1 = .038 a.1 = wz = .320 vz = -.023 a2 = -.031 w3 = .110 v3 = -.056 a3 = -.018 w4 = -.024 V/+ = -.043 a4 = -.060 = -.054 .039 a5 = .025 % = .1no where GNP is in current dollars, Eis current-dollar federal expenditures, S is a strike variable, pe is the relative price of energy, and Ml refers to old M-1 prior to 195() and M-l'R thereafter. The KC-Ml model is simpler, containing only money erowth: 4 400 tiGNPt/GNPt-J = 3.17R9 + E Bi 400 tilllt-i/Mlt-i-1 0 Bn = .52?3 83 = .430R 61 = .1868 84 = -.3304 82 = .1741 Ml in this case refers to t,f-11~. 1/ SL-Ml is presented by John A. Tatom, "Energy Prices and Economic Performance: 1979-81," working paper (Federal Reserve Board of St. Louis, 1')(11). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -5- The KC-FF model isl 24 400 ~GNPt/GNPt-1 = 14.3168 + r Yi400*MFFt-i/RFFt-i-1 1 YI = -.0147 Yq -.0263 Y17 = -.0233 Y2 = -.0218 YlO = -.0276 Y18 = -.0209 Y3 = -.0243 Yn = -.0288 Yl9 = -.0186 Y4 =, -.0247 Y12 = -.0295 Y20 = -.0166 Y5 = -.0243 Y13 = -.0296 Y21 = -.0151 Y6 = -.0240 Y14 = -.0290 Y22 = -.0136 Y7 = -.0243 Y15 = -.0276 Y23 = -.0115 YB = -.0251 Y16 = -.0257 Y24 = -.0076 = RFF is the federal funds rate. It should be noted that the functional form of the KC-FF model is difficult to justify (its authors are fully aware of the problem). It appears that no standard structural model of the economy in which prices are affected by monetary policy can be collapsed to the KC-FF reduced form. The shortcomings of KC-FF can be seen easily by noting what happens if' for example, the funds rate is either lowered to 1 percent and kept there or raised to 100 percent and stabilized. Either policy eventually leads to a growth rate of 'nominal 'GNP of -14~.•3· percent~· ·Obviously, in -a,·world •where inflation rates can change, a drastic lowering of the funds rate would eventually lead to very high nominal GNP growth rates as inflation spiraled 1/ The KC-Ml and KC-FF models can be found in Byron Higgins and Vance Roley, "The Sensitivty of Nominal Spending to Interest Rates and Monetary AgP,regates: Evidence from Reduced Form Equations~' (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1981). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -6upward, and a high enough interest rate setting would lead to the elimination of inflation and thus nominal GNP growth rates much below 14.3 percent. Nevertheless, if prices react rather sluggishly to monetary policy, the KC-FF model may be adequate for short-run (not more than a few quarters) analysis. The money demand equations in the quarterly econometric model use end-of-quarter values to preserve certain end-of~quarter balance-sheet identities. However, because most discussion of monetary policy issues,is now conducted in terms of quarterly average values, staff work done with the model is usually based on end-of-quarter values interpolated from quarterly averages. While this procedure is sufficiently accurate for most purposes, it leads to difficulties in describing simulation results when the focus of attention is on the quarter-by-quarter paths of money and interest rates. Consequently, end-of-quarter money stock values are used in this paper for the quarterly model work. Table 2 reports the simulated consequences for the 1979Q4-1981Q4 period of eliminating the fluctuations in money growth in the year after October 6. The consequences were estimated using the structural quarterly model, the SL-Ml model, and the KC-Ml model. were done. In each case two simulations In the first simu~ation the relevant exogenous M-1 concept-was - held at historical values in the 197904-1980Q3 period and at proJected ' values thereafter. In the second simulation money growth was held at its average value for 1979Q4-1980Q3 and at the same projected values for subsequent periods that were used in the first simulation. Table 2 reports differences between the two simulations for each model. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Smoothing the money growth path requires increasing the money growth -7' Table 2 Simulated Effect of Stabilizing M-1, Growth, 1979Q4 to'1980Q3 1979 ci4 Ql Q2 1980 Q3 Q4 Ql Q2 Y 1981 ~Q_3__Q-"--4_ M-1 (percent increase in level) Quarterly model (end-of-quarter M-lA) .2 1.4 2.3 .o .o .o .o .o .o SL-Ml (quarterly average M-lB) .1 .o 2.0 .o .o .o .o .o .o KC-Ml (quarterly average M-lB) .1 .o 2.0 .o .o .o .o .o .o Nominal GNP (percent increase in level) Quarterly model SL-Ml KC-Ml .o .o .o .3 .6 .7 .5 .4 .4 .3 .3 .1 .7 .8 .6 .2 -. 1 .o 1.0 .4 .3 .8 -.7 .o .o .o .o -.6 -4.1 -3.7 3.6 2.5 .6 .1 .7 .8 .s .5 .4 .4 .3 .2 Federal funds rate (points) Quarterly model Real GNP (percent increase in level) Quarterly model .o .2 1/ For comparison purposes the level and annual rates of growth of nominal GNP for the 1979-Q4 period are listed here: Nominal GNP Level (billions of dollars) Percent increase (annual rate) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Ql Q2 Q3 2546.9 2520.8 2521.3 2586.5 10.S 10 .8 .1 10 .8 Q4 -8"J;able 3 Simulated Effect of-Holding Fu~ds Rate at Average 1979Q4 to 1980Q3 ' Levels'during That Period 1979 Q4 Ql Q2 1980 Q3 !/ 1981 Q4 Ql g2 Q3 Q4 Federal funds rate (Eoints) ,. . Quarterly model -.8 -2 .2 .1 3.0 0 0 0 0 0 KC-FF -.8 -2.2 .1 3.0 0 NR NR NR NR Nominal GNP (percent increase in level) Quarterly model .o .2 .3 .2 .1 .2 .2 .2 .3 KC-FF .o .1 .4 .6 .4 NR NR NR NR .8 .4 -.6 .o .o .1 .2 .3 .2 .1 .1 .2 .2 .2 .2 M-1 (percent increase in level) Quarterly model .2 Real GNP (percent increase in level) Quarterly model .o .1 N.R. Not reported. See discussion of KC-FF model, p.5, and footnote 1, p. 9. 1/ For historical GNP levels, see footnote 1, Table 2. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -- - - - -9rates in each of the first three quarters of the period and reducing it sharply in the last quarter. On average the level of money is higher. The smooth money path does appear to diminish the output fluctuations that occurred, but the various models agree that the impact on nominal output would be relatively small compared to the size of the recent recession. The quarterly model channels from money and interest rates to output contain relatively long lags so the reaction of simulated output is slow and fairly small. The monetarist reduced-form models show a somewhat greater tendency for the smoothed money path to smooth GNP. In the SL-Ml case, output growth in 1980Q2 is about 2-1/2 percent greater at annual rates; in the KC-Ml case it is about 4 percent stronger. Table 3 reports the simulated effects, using both the quarterly and the KC-FF models, of smoothing the path of the federal funds rate by holding it at its historical 1979Q4-1980Q3 average over that period. This requires holding the federal funds rate down early in the period, and increasing it in the later part. The changes in the funds rate needed to accomplish the smoothing (Table 3) are on average smaller than those simulated by the quarterly model when the money growth path was smoothed (Table 2). As a result the simulated effects on GNP are smaller. Like the monetarist reduced-form models, the KC-FF model (which is certainly not monetarist) shows a somewhat larger change than does the quarterly model as a result of the smoothing.1 Once again, however, both 1/ Smoothing the interest rate path causes the KC-FF model to produce higher output in 1981. This appears to be a result of the fact that the KC-FF model works off percentage changes in the funds rate. A volatile rate path needs bigger percentage increases than decreases on average if it is to be trendless. It seemed doubtful that this characteristic of the model corresponded to the true structure of the economy. Consequently, KC-FF results for 1981 were not reported. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -10models show simulated effects which are relatively s~all compared to the size of the 1980 recession. These results should be accepted only with great caution. Eco- nometric relationships are the result-of theory and of average historical relationships. Average relationships do not hold at each point in time. Some argue that behavioral relationships (as they are usually measured econometrically) vary with the public's perception of economic policy rules. It may be that if the-alternative money growth or funds rate paths examined above had been followed, public perception of policy would have been very different. A substantial number of observers appear to believe that a policy like the steady funds rate policy would have resulted in higher inflation expectations in this period and that the downturn in production which occurred in early 1980 might not have taken place. turn, would have been worse. Inflation, in Whether these views are correct is beyond the scope of this paper. Even if one r~jects the caveat of the previous paragraph, one should not conclude from the simulations presented in Tables 2 and 3 that all temporary deviations in policy instruments from planned paths have negligible effects on output. In the exercises performed above the levels of the policy instrument variables differ from quarter to quarter, but on average over the one-year period they are the same. If a policy instrument variable were to deviate from its planned path, and if its return to the planned path were to be delayed or not compensated for by an offsetting deviation on the other side, the effect might be considerably larger. possibility is the subject of the next section. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis That -11Section III: Policy Instrument Deviations and the Return to Targeted Paths In recent years the Federal Open Market Committee has set longrun target ranges for monetary aggregates. For a variety of reasons, the aggregates do not grow smoothly along the target paths. It will be argued in the next section that the consequences of any such instrument deviation depend on the deviation's causes. In this section, however, we will assume that the deviation is deliberate (at least in the sense that the FOMC or the Desk acquiesced in the deviation). long-run target path for money. For example, suppose the FOMC adopted some The FOMC would have some expectations about the path of interest rates, prices, and output. Further suppose a situation arose which caused the Committee to wish temporarily to miss its targets. The size of the effects would depend on the ma~nituae and duration of the policy variable deviations. This section explores the consequences of different re- entry paths for the policy instrument variables. It should be stressed that the instrument deviations analyzed in this section are not the usual sort which are caused by either the level of economic activity of money demand being stronger or weaker than expected. That subJect will be addressed in the next section. The deviations studied here are ones in which the Committee or the Desk have deliberately allowed the instrument to stray from its long-run target path. 1 Table 4 presents the results of a set of simulation experiments in which the money stock was caused to rise 1 percent above target in the 1/ There is one realistic type of unintentional deviation to which the analysis of this section applies. If the Committee has a long-run aggregate target which it attempts to achieve using a bank reserves instrument, unexpected values of the reserves/deposit multiplier could cause deviations to which this section is applicable. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -12first quarter and then returned to the target path along a variety of traJectories. In the first trajectory examined, the money stock is returnerl all the way to the target path in the second quarter. The quarterly model shows little effect on nominal output of the deviation in the initial quarter, but the effect builds to about 0.2 percent after four quarters, then starts to decline. The monetarist reduced-form equations show a sharper initial effect. The SL-Ml model gives a 0.29 percent response in the initial quarter. The effect builds to 0.4 percent in the second quarter, then falls rapidly to zero. The KC-Ml model shows an even sharper initial effect. Output is about 1/2 percent higher in the first quarter in this model, then returns by an erratic route to very near the undisturbed path in the fifth period. Table 4 also shows simulated effects on the federal funds rate taken from the quarterly model. The second and third traiectories investigate the simulated effects of more persistence in the overshoot on money. In the second trajectory the overshoot is not eliminaterl until the third quarter. the overshoot lasts three full quarters. In the third trajectory As one would expect, increasing the persistence of the overshoot increases the size and prolongs the duration of the simulated effects on nominal GNP. In the case of the three-quarter over- shoot (traiectory 3) the quarterly model estimate of the maximum effect is about 0.6 percent after five quarters. The monetarist reduced forms show a percentage increase in nominal output nearly as larP,e as the percenta~e increase in money by the third overshoot quarter. The fourth and fifth tra1ectories examine the effects of returning money gradually to the target path after the initLal overshoot. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis As expected, -13Table 4 Effect of Temporary neviations of M-1 from Planned Path 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 0 0 0 0 0 .19 . 30 . 17 .21 .16 . 40 . 18 • 11 .oo .oo -1.8 .5 M-1 Deviation (percentage points from desired level)..!/1.0 1. 0 1 (1) M-1 Deviation (percentage points from desired level)_!/1.0 8 -, - O· Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-Ml KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, ()uarterly Model) ( 2) . 08 . 29 .49 • 18 .21 .oo .45 • 21 -.02 -.30 .14 .01 .01 .01 .5 .4 .2 .4 .2 .2 0 0 0 0 0 0 .35 . 70 .34 .3Q . 41 .57 .40 . 08 .10 .38 -.02 -.30 .oo .oo .01 .01 Percentage Effect on Level of Nor111nal GNP Quarterly Model SL-1'11 KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, Quarterly l-fodel) (3) . 08 . 29 .49 . 25 . 69 .67 .32 • 24 -1.8 -1.3 1.0 .9 .5 .4 .5 .4 Deviation (percentage points from desired leveJ.J../ 1. 0 1. 0 1.0 0 0 0 0 0 .57 .80 .74 .58 . 38 .57 • '50 • 08 .oo • 26 • 10 -.02 -.30 .6 .7 }1-l Percentage Effect on Level of tTominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-Ml KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, ()uarterly Model) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis • 08 . 29 . 4g -1.8 • 25 • 69 .67 -1.3 .44 . 99 .83 -.8 1.5 1. 1 .8 .40 .01 -14Tabl'e 4 (cont'd) Effect of Temporary Deviations of M-1' from Planned Pa,tb 1 (4) M-1 Deviation.(Eercentage points from desired level).:!/'1.0 2 3 4, 5 6 7 8 .67 .33' 0 0 0 0 0 .32 .66 .44 .41 .44 .57 .39 .15 .02 .38 .02 -.07 -.09 .oo .oo .2 .9 .6 .s .4 .4 0 0 0 0 0 0 .27 .50 .25 .30 .26 .49 .30 .02 -.10 .29 -.01 -.15 .oo .oo .oo .oo Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-Ml KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, Quarterly Model) (S) .08 .29 .49 .23 .59 .so -1.8 -.7 ,, M-1 Deviation (percentage Eoints from desired level).!/1.0 .5 .32 .oo .2s Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-Ml KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, Quarterly Model) (6) .08 _zq .49 .21 .54 .42 .23 .17 -1.8 -.4 .8 .6 .4 .4 .4 .4 M-1 Deviation (Eercentage points from desired level)l/1.0 -.5 .o .o .o .o .o .o .14 .25 -.06 . 1() .10 .09 .13 -.04 .33 .11 -.07 -.49 .11 .02 .16 .oo .oo .01 .01 1.4 .2 .1 .o .2 .2 .2 Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-1'11 !ZC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, Quarterly Model) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis .08 .zg .49 -1.8 .07 .04 -15Table 4 (cont'd) Effect of Temporary Deviations of M-1 from Planned Path 1 (7) M-1 Deviation (Eercentage Eoints from desired level).!/1.0 3 4 5 6 7 8 0 0 0 0 0 0 .10 .10 -.30 .02 -.09 .oo .oo .03 -.19 .26 -.12 -.68 .01 .03 .33 -.03 .01 .02 -.03 .01 2.4 .o -.1 -.2 .1 .o .o 2 -LO Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model SL-Ml KC-Ml Effect on Funds Rate (points, Quarterly Model) !/ .08 .29 .49 -1.8 .02 Deviations are for end-of-quarter M-lA in the case of the Quarterly Model, and for quarterly average M-lB in the cases of the SL-Ml and KC-Ml models. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -16the effects on output are in both cases greater than when the overshoot was corrected promptly and smaller than when it was allowed to oersist for more than two quarters. All the above trajectories lead to output being higher on average than would have been the case if money had remained on the target path. The simulated effects on output can be reduced by balancing the initial money overshoot with an offsetting later undershoot. In traJectory number 6, the 1 percent excess of money in the initial quarter is followed by a 1/2 percent deviation in the opposite direction in the succeeding quarter. This largely eliminates significant output responses in the quarterly and SL-Ml models, but at the cost (according to the quarterly model) of a rather choppy interest rate path. The uneven lag structure in the KC-Ml model leads to a somewhat irregular output response. Trajectory 7 shows the simulated effect of creating an instrument deviation equal and opposite in sign in the second quarter to the deviation in the first. This damps even further the output responses of the quarterly and SL-Ml models. The KC-Ml response is now still more erratic. Table 5 reports the results of similar experiments using the federal funds rate as the policy instrument. model only.1 Results are reported for the quarterly In these simulations it is assumed that the VOMC has set a long- run target path for the funds rate and then for some reason allows a temporary deviation. The deviation amounts to 300 basis points in the initial quarter. Five trajectories are then examine<l which take the funds rate back to target levels by different paths. 1/ The ~C-VF model was simulated but the results were not reported in view of the problem described on page 5 and 10 the footnote on page 9. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -17Table 5 Effect of Temporary Deviations of Federal Funds Rate From Planned Path Quarter (1) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 3.0 ' .o .o .o .() .() .o .o -.1 -.3 -.5 -.6 -.7 -.8 -.9 -1.0 -1.8 -.5 -.6 -.6 -.5 -.6 -.6 -.7 3.0 3.0 0 0 0 0 0- 0 -.1 -.5 -.8 -1.1 -1.3 -1.5 -1.7 -1.8 -1.8 -2.2 -1.1 -1.1 -1.0 -1.1 -1.2 -1.3 3.0 3.0 3.0 0 0 Quarterly Model _ -.1 -.5 '-.9 -1.4 -1.8 -2.2 - --2.5 ' -2.7 Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) -1.8 -2.2 -2.7 -1.7 -1.6 -1.6 -1.9 Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) (2) Funds Rate Deviation -From Desired Level (points) Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) (3) Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) 0 0 0 Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -1.7 -18Table 5 (cont'd) Effect of Temporary Deviations of Federal Funds Rate From Planned Path ' Quarter (4) Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) - . -- -- 1 2 3 4 - 5 6 7 8 3.0 2.0 1.0 .o .o .o .o .o -.1 -.4 -.7 -LO -L3 -L5 -L7 -L8 -L8 -L6 -L4 -Ll -LO -Ll -L2 -L3 3.0 L5 .o .o .o .o .o .o -.1 -.4 -.6 -.8 -LO -L2 -L3 -L4 -L8 -L3 -.8 -.8 -.7 -.8 -.9 -LO 3.0 -LS .o .o .o .o .o .o -.1 -.3 -.3 -.4 -.4 -.5 -. 5 -.5 -L8 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.2 -.4 -.4 -.4 Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) (5) Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly Model Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) (6) Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) Percentage Effect on Level of Nominal GNP Quarterly !fodel Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly Model) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -19- Table 5 (cont'd) Effect of Temporary Deviations of Federal Funds Rate From Planned Path 1 (7) Funds Rate Deviation From Desired Level (points) 2 3 4 Quarter 5 6 7 8 3.0 -3.0 .o .o .o .o .o .o -.1 -.2 -.1 ,-. 2 -.1 -.1 -.1 -.1 -1.R 1.2 -.1 .I) .1 -.1 -.1 -.1 Percentage Effer.t on r.evel of Nominal GNP https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Quarterly Model Percentage Effect on Level of M-lA (Quarterly MoQel) --- -20The first trajectory returns the funds rate to the target path in the second quarter of the simulation. this is a rather serious deviation. The quarterly model indicates that Nominal output is lowered by about 1/2 percent after one year and nearly a full 1 percent after two years. This is in some contrast to the results for the one-period deviation from money targets shown in the first panel of Table 4. difference. There are two reasons for'the The first is merely a matter of scale--the initial deviation being examined is nearly twice as big. The deviation of 300 basis points on the interest rates initially cause~ money to deviate 1.8 percent from its expected path, whereas in Table 4 money stock deviations of 1 percent were being analyzed. The second reason, however, is fundamental. est rate is raised, output is reduced. When the inter- When the rate is then returned to the long-run path, output remains lower and consequently so does money. The consequences for the money stock (as simulated by the quarterly model) can be seen in the last line of the first panel of Table 5. all the way to its undisturbed value. It does not return Thus the interest rate traJectory analyzed here is the equivalent of a more persistent deviation of money from its target path than anything presented in Table 4. This suggests that "misses" from an interest rate target path must be eliminated more quickly, or be more completely compensated for by making offsetting "misses" on the other side, than is necessary for "misses" from a l'lOney stock target. Trajectories 2 and 3 investigate the effects of more persistent deviations of interest rates from target paths. The effects on nominal out- put are roughly proportional to the number of quarters the deviation is https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -21allowed to persist. Trajectories 4 and 5 simulate gradual returns to target after the initial miss. TraJectories 6 and 7 examine the possi- bilities of creating offsetting deviations from the funds rate target. Only in the case of an equal offsetting deviation (trajectory 7) is the effect on nominal output largely eliminated. Section IV: Policy Responses to Economic Disturbances With perfect knowledge of the working of the economy the conduct of monetary policy would be relatively simple. The range of feasible outcomes for ultimate targets such as output, employment, and inflation would be known; and it would be possible to achieve a desired path for any particular single target variable (such as a time path for output or inflation), or to attain the most desirab1e of the many feasible combinations of ultimate targets (such as output and inflation). Unfortunately, knowledge of the economic system is far from perfect. While the main determinants of the value of each economic variable may be known, there is a remaining unknown component. Economists may say that real consumption depends on current and recent real disposable income, for example, or that the quantity of money demanded depends on income, the price level, and interest rates. But while these variables may explain most of the variation in consumption and money holdings, they will not explain all of it. The remaining variation is due to other causes, and is referred to as the uncertainty in economic relationships. Policymakers must attempt \ to achieve their goals in the presence of this uncertainty. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis \ \ '\ \ \' ' ' -22Through the use of simulations it will be demonstrated below that the consequences of a surge in the unpredictable component of any relationship will depend on which relationship suffered the disturbance, and on the reaction of the monetary policymakers to that disturbance once it happens.I We will demonstrate that a particular policy response pattern which has relatively favorable consequences in the face of one type of disturbance may have unfavorable consequences in the face of a different disturbance. Since past experience suggests that the uncertainty component of some relationships is larger than for others it follows that some policy reaction rules will on average work better than others. In the material that fol- lows, various simple monetary policy reaction rules will be hypothesized. Then, given an empirically based structural representation of the economy (i.e., the quarterly model) the consequences of various economic disturbances will be simulated, tabulated and discussed. The Policy Rules Three simple policy rules are considered in this paper. Under the first rule it is assumed that a path for the Federal funds rate is chosen, and that the path for this instrument is adhered to regardless of any events which may later occur but which were not expected at the time the funds rate path was chosen. Obviously this policy rule is something of a straw man. 1/ Readers familiar with the literature in this area will recognize that the analysis developed here is descended from the work published by William Poole in "Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 84 (May 1970), pp.197-216. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -23Under the second rule, the central bank is assumed to set and achieve a path for M-1 regardless of subsequent events. This policy rule is considerably more realistic than the first and in fact has many advocates. The third policy rule is a combination of the first and second. Policymakers are assumed to have a target path both for the funds rate and for M-1. The interest rate path is adjusted upward or downward whenever money exceeds or falls short of its target path. Specifically, this rule is tnRFFt = inRFFt-1 + A tn(M/Mtarget) + 8 ln RFFtarget, where ~FF is the funds rate and Mis M-lA. As A approaches infinity, this policy rule approaches a money fixed rule (rule 2). As A approaches zero it becomes a fixed path for interest rates (rule 1). In the simulations reported below A= 15 so that a 1 percent deviation in money from its target value causes the funds rate to be increased by 15 percent (say from 10 to 11.5). The Economic Shocks Four different shocks were tested under each policy rule. 1) Real consumption was depressed by 1 percent. Specifically, this means that the consumption function of the model was altered so that whatever the values of the usual determinants of consumption, the consumption function produced 1 percent less consumption that it normally would given those determinants. 2) cent. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The demand for demand deposits was shocked upward by 2 per- -243) The level of wages was depressed by 1 percent. 4) The level of prices was depressed by 1 percent. In each case the shift in the relationship was assumed to be permanent. Table 6 shows the simulated result of lowering consumption by 1 percent relative to its usual determinants. This weakens real GNP, of course, although that may not be immediately observable. The monetary policymakers are first likely to observe a tendency for short-term interest rates and money to fall below their expected levels. What happens next depends on how the policymakers react. If the policy reaction is to keep the federal funds rate on its predetermined path, the simulated results are those given by the top line in each panel of Table 6. The funds rate is, of course, unchanged. Real GNP and nominal money balances both fall steadily further from the values they otherwise would have had. In the case of this particular shock, a fixed interest rate path turns out to be the worst policy examined. Holding nominal money balances at their predetermined levels works out much more satisfactorily. in output. The funds rate falls and this resists the fall These first two simulations support the usual contention that monetary aggregates are a superior instrument to interest rates in the presence of shocks to aggregate demand. The last policy examined assumes the policymakers change interest rates in response to deviations of money from the target path, but not by enough to make up all the discrepancy. This policy turns out to be less stabilizing than the second one but more stabilizing than the first. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -25Table 6 Simulated Effect of Sustained 1 Percent Reduction in Consumption Relative to its Determinants Policy reaction function 1 2 Quarter after shock 3 4 12 8 Effect on GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed -9.6 -18.0 -n.3 -25.5 -36.8 -43.0 (2) M-1 fixed -9.4 -17.1 -18.9 -20.5 -20.1 -7.8 (3) Money target -9.6 -17.7 -20.2 -23.0 -23.8 -10.5 Effect on M-lA (billions of current dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed (3) Money target -.3 -1.2 -2.6 0 0 0 -.2 -.7 -3.9 -9.3 -16.7 0 0 0 -1.2 -1.4 -.9 -.7 Effect on federal funds rate (percentage points) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) (3) y 0 0 0 0 M-1 fixed -.4 -.8 -1.1 -1.3 -1.7 -3.0 Money target -.1 -.4 -.7 -LO -1.8 -3.2 0 0 Contro-1 simulation values of the variables whose responses are tablulated above are as follows: Quarter 1 GNP (1972 dollars) M-lA Funds rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1220.0 285.7 6.2 2 1227.9 288.6 5.4 3 4 8 12 1259 .5 293.3 4.8 1267.4 296.2 5.2 1331.2 317.0 5.2 1395.2 342.9 7.3 -26Table 7 shows the results of the same experiment for a permanent upward shift in the demand for demand deposits. Unlike the case of the consumption shock, the first' observable consequences of this shift are likely to be a tendency for interest rates and money balances to rise above expectations, although,as it is with the consumption shock, the effect on aggregate spending is downward. Policy 1--the fixed path for the funds rate--works quite well in this case while, as expected, the fixed M-1 path works poorly. Policy 3, like the money fixed policy, does not perform well because it reacts to a change in money demand that should be accommodated. Table 8 reports the results of a sustained downward shift in prices and profit margins. ways in the short run. money stock. This shift increases simulated real output two First, the reduction in prices increases the real Second, the reduction in profit margins shifts real income from businesses to wage earners. ginal propensity to spend. Businesses have a lower short-run mar- The first effect the monetary policymakers would observe is a tendency for interest rates and money balances to fall below expectations. The proper response is less clear in this case than it was in the case of the shocks to consumption and deposit demand. Presumably, the authorities would, if they had full information about what was happening, prefer to keep output relatively unaffected and accept the reduction in the price level. This could be accomplished by raising the funds rate for a period of time. The policies which emphasize aggregates (2 and 3) tend to reduce the funds rate, which is inappropriate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Holding to the planned funds rate -27Table 7 Simulated Effect of Sustained 2 Percent Upward Shift in the Demand for Demand Deposits l/ Policy reaction function 1 2 Ouarter after shock 3 4 12 8 Effect on GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed -.o -.o -.o -.o -.2 -.6 ,-.9 -2.6 -4.9 -7.4 -15.~ -17.R -.4 -.8 -2.4 -4.1 -13.4 -18.4 ~ (3) Money target -. Effect on M-lA (billions of current dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed (3) Money target 2.2 4.3 4.4 4.4 4.6 4.6 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.4 2.2 1.1 -.7 -.9 .3 Effect on federal funds rate (percentage points) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed (3) Money target )j 0 0 0 0 3.1 1.9 1.2 1.0 .3 -.7 .9 1.4 1.4 1.5 .8 -.2 0 0 Control simulation values of the variables whose responses are tahlulated above are as follows: Quarter 1 GNP (1972 dollars) M-lA Funds rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2 3 1220.0 285.7 1227.9 288.6 6.2 5.4 1259. 5 293.3 4.R 4 1267.4 296.2 5.2 8 12 1331.2 13Q5.2 317.0 5.2 342.9 7.3 -28Table 8 Simulated Effect of Reducing Prices 1 Percent by Reducing Markups over Costs 1/ Policy reaction function 2 1 Quarter after shock 3 4 8 12 Effect on GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed 2.1 3.3 3.3 J.Q 8.5 15.6 (2) M-1 fixed 2.6 4.6 5.7 7.4 15.5 20.5 (3) Money target 2.4 4.0 4.8 6.5 15.7 22.5 Effect on M-lA (billions of current dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed (3) Money target -.8 -1.5 0 0 -.5 -.8 -1.6 -2.0 -1.8 0 0 0 0 - .1. -.1 .4 .7 -1.5 Effect on federal funds rate (percentage points) 0 0 0 0 0 M-1 fixed -.1 -.6 -.4 -.3 -.o .a Money target -.3 -.4 -.4 -. 5 -.2 .6 (1) Funds rate fixed (2) (3) 1/ 0 Control simulation values of the variable_s___whose responses are tabluldted above are as follows: Quarter GNP (1977. dollars) M-lA Funds rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1 2 3 4 8 12 1220.0 285.7 1227.9 288.lj 5.4 1259.5 1267.4 2'lJ .3 2%.2 4.8 5.2 1331.2 317.0 5.2 1395.2 342.9 7.3 6.2 -29path 1 works better. None of the strategies considered makes the appro- priate response. Table 9 presents the simulated result of shifting wages down by 1 percent. This shift has two major short-run effects. wages lowers prices and increases real money balances. is shifted temporarily from wage earners to businesses. First, lowering Second, real income In the short run this depresses output. Once again, a value judgment is needed in determining the appropriate response. Policymakers might wish to resist the initial fall in output, but it seems unlikely that they would wish to take output above its undisturbed levels and thus dissipate the gain the shock produced in fighting inflation. The aggregates policies (2 and 3) resist the initial decline in output by reducing interest rates. If allowed to stay in effect, however, they would eventually increase output enough to return prices to their undisturbed levels, which seems undesirable. The funds rate policy, 1, does not resist the decline in output, but has the desirable property that it does not reflate. Thus again, none of the simple response rules tested works very well. A more satisfactory response rule would be more complex and would take into account knowledge about which relationship had suffered the disturbance and the sign and magnitude of the disturbance as quickly as that knowledge became available. Conclusions This section has looked at simulations of the effects of a number of possible shocks to the economic system under a number of different mone- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -30Table 9 Simulated Effect of Reducing Wages by 1 Percent Policy reaction function Quarter after shock 1 3 2 4, 12 8 Effect on GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed ' -1.4 -,2. 7 -3.3 -{.,.2 (2) M-1 fixed -1.2 -1.7 -1.0 (3) Money target -1.3 -2.5 -2.3 -,4.0 -.1 -7.2 " 5.7 -1.8 3.8 15.9 , I ._. I 15.5 Effect on M-lA (billions of current ' dollars) (1) Funds rate fixed (2) M-1 fixed (3) Money target -.5 -1.3 -2.0 -2.6 -s.1 -8.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -.6 -.8 -.8 -.7 -.1 .5 Effect on federal funds rate (percentage points) (1) Funds rate fixed 0 0 0 0 0 0 (2) M-1 fixed -.s -.7 -.7 -.8 -.8 -.8 (3) Money target -.2 -.4 -.s -.7 -1.0 -1.1 1/ vControl simulation values of the variables whose responses are tablulated above are as follows: Quarter GNP (1972 dollars) M-lA Funds rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1 2 1220.0 285.7 6.2 1227.q 288.6 5.4 3 1259.5 293 .3 4.8 4 1267.4 296.2 5.2 8 1331.2 317.0 5.2 12 1395.2 342.9 7.3 ~ -31tary policy response rules. It has found that some of the policy responses are better for one type of shock, other responses better for another type. None of the policies examined is clearly dominant. The material provided here suggests that a good policy rule--which would necessarily be much more complex than any considered here--would take into account both the relative likelihood of the variou~ kinds of shocks in the period before the nature of the shock could be determined, and the nature and magnitude of the shock once the determination could be made. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CYCLF.<; RESULTING FROM MONEY STOCK TARGETit-IG Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Jared Enzler and Lewis Johnson The assistance of Nancy Artz is gratefully acknowled~ed. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CYC:LES RESULTI~G FR.OM MONEY STOCK TARGETPTG Section I. Introduction This paper examines the possibility that money stock targeting may introduce a cyclical mechanism into the economy._!_/ The hypothetical mechanism contains the following elements: 1. A standard IS-LM macroeconomic system in which economic activity responds to interest rates, but only with a la~, 2. A money demand function with a low interest elasticity of demand for money and a substantial ~ncume elasticity, 3. A monetary policy which consists of raising or lowering interest rates whenever money exceeds or falls short of some target path. It is easy to see that this set of assuMptions could lead to a cyclical mechanism. Suppose some disturbance were to cause aggregate output to fall below levels the monetary policymaker had expected. Because the demand for money responds to falling income, money balances would fall below target. The postulaterl policy response would be a reduction in interest rates. Eecause of a low interest elasticity of money demand, anrl lags in the effect of interest rates on income, this policy would initially have negligible impact on money balances, leading the policymaker to further reduce interest rates. Eventually, the initial reduction in interest rates would return output to its original level, which would return money balances to the 1/ The possibility was suggested by Governor Gramley, and this investigation was originally undertaken at his request. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 2 - target level. Subsequently, the later interest rate reductions would cause income to rise and money balances to exceed target. As will be seen, the resulting cycle could he either damped or undamped. To examine the nature of this cyclical process, a small macro model was created and sinulated. The sensitivity of the amplitide and periodicity of the cycle to variations in parameters was examined to shed light on three issues: (1) Would plausible values of the system's parameters result in cyclical responses to disturbances under a monetary policy of the sort described in assumption 3? (2) Could this mechanism be invoked to explain the pattern of aggregate output in the United States in 1979-80? (3) Could alternative monetary policies be formulated which would eliminate or greatly attenuate the cycle for sets of parameter values which lead to cycles? In Section II the simulation model 1s presented. It 1s a simple dynamic IS-LM model extended by the addition of an expectations-augmented Phillips curve and a policy function. It should be noted that this model contains relatively sinple adaptive expectations, explicitly for goods prices and implicitly for interest rates. The incorporation, instead, of the widely discussed "rational" expectations mechanism, would certainly alter and probably eliminate cyclical characteristics from the model. For a particular set of parameter values, the model presented 1s shown to have cyclical responses to exogenous disturbances. It exhibits (at least) two basic cycles -- a short cycle (of 3 to 5 years) resulting from the interaction of the hypothetical monetary policy with the IS and LM curves and a long cycle (more than 15 years) resulting from the interaction of monetary policy with the Phillips curve. In Section III the nature of the short cycle is explored in isolation by "disconnecting'' the model I s Phillips cttrvE!'. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The SenHtivity of tl'f'e snort - 3 - cycle's duration and degree of damping to changes in behavioral parameters and policy reponses is examined. In Section IV the performance (both short run and long run) of various policies is considered with the Phillips curve re-activated. Policies based on final targets (income and inflation) are found to be reasonably effective in damping the cycle. Results are summarized and conclusions drawn in Section V. It is concluded that while plausible parameters do indeed give rise to cycles, the parameters needed to ~enerate a cycle as short as the one observed between late 1979 and late 1980 are not plausible. II. The Model The analysis will be of a simple dynamic IS-LM model, generalized by the addition of a Phillips curve and a policy function. The model is fully specified by equations (1) through (4): n + a 1 lny_1 - 1.ai(r - Y)_i + e y 1 p (1) lny = Ct (2) lnM = B0 + B1lnM-1 + Bzlny - B3lnr + R4lnP + eM (3) P/P 0 m (4) p + Un(y/y*) + ep lnr_l + Y1ln(M/M*) + YzMn(M/M*) lnr = y y* = real output = "capacity" output where https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis r.ci (f)_i 1 r (corresponding to the "natural" unemployment rate) = the "short" nominal interest rate - 4 - P = the = the = the = the price level inflation rate M money stock M* target monev stock ey, em, ep are disturbances h indicates a first difference P/P Equation (1) represents an adjustment process for the goods markets (it is a dynamic analogue of the IS curve). The aggregate demand for goods presumably depends upon income and the "long" real rate of interest - assumed to be generated by a distributed lag on short nominal irtterest rates less oneperiod inflation rates. This equation may be interpreted as postulating that the current rate of growth of output will be proportional to the preceding period's excess demand for goods. possible.) equation. (An equilibrium interpretation is also The coefficients ai are based on estimates of a somewhat different Simulation of the MPS quarterly model reveals implicit coefficients roughly comparable to those used here. The coefficients a 0 and a1 were arbitrarily chosen to yield a plausible steady-state real interest rate of about 1.2 percent. Equation (2) is a conventional money demand equation, with desired real balances (real because the long-run price elasticity is assumed to be 1) depending upon real income and the short nominal interest rate. Actual money holdings are adjusted to desired levels by a partial-anjustment mechanism. The long-run real income elasticity of money demand is assumed to be 0.75. The remaining parameters of this equation will be varied over plausible ranges subject to the constraint that in the lon~ run the demand for nominal money is always proportional to prices. equation (3) is analogous to an expectations-augmented Phillips curve. The distributed lag on past inflation rates represents the expected rate of inflation. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The ci are geo~etrically declining and sum to 1.0. (The - 5 - long-run Phillips curve 1s vertical.) Excess rlemand is measured by the ratio of output to capacity output and it~ coefficient, A, has been set at 15 broadly consistent with typical estimates of the responsiveness of the ~hillips curve. In this model expectations of both future short-term interest rates (equation 1) and future inflation rates (equation 3) have been representen as distributed lags on past rates -- expectations are assumed to be formed adaptively. In this respect, our model is representative of all maJor econometric forecasting models. A currently fashionable alternative is to assume that expectations are formed in such a way as to be consistent with the model's own predJctions. The behavior of the model would likely be dramatically different under this "rational" expectations alternative. Finally, equation (4) specifies the policy followed by the Federal Reserve. This particular specification would have the Fed attempt to achieve a target money growth path by raising the short-term interest rate when money is above target and lowering the rate when money is below target. Alternative policies will also be considered. Ranges of parameter values used in simulations of this model are shown in Table 1. It should be noted that in equations (1) and (2) the "dependent" variable appears lagged once on the right-hand side of the equation. This means that if an explanatory variable is chan~ed permanently the effect of that change will cumulate over time. For example, if income were permanently increased by 1 percent in equation (2), the demand for money will be increased by 82 percent in the first quarter (8z is sometimes called an impact elasticity). In the second quarter money demand will be greater not only because income is higher but also because money demand was greater by~~ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 6 - in the preceding quarter. Accordingly, money demand will be inLreased by (B2 + B182) perLent in the second quarter after the change. The cumula- tive effect after income has been at its higher level for a very long time approaches [82/(l-B1)J -- referred to as a long-run elagticity. It is ranges for long-run elasticities that are shown in Table 1. Table 1 Ranges Considered for Parameters of Simulation Model IS curve: . 7* fa .029* i Money demand· 81 .25 8 2 (l-A1) .7* B 3 (l-B1) .02 to .058 to .S* to .1()* ,~ R (1-B1) Phillips curve: 1.0* A Policy function: 1.0* 0 to 15* 0 to 10 The values with a(*) supersLript are approximately the magnitudes usually found in empirical estimates. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 7 - To simulate this model, lagged values of income, interest rates, inflation rates, and the money stock are required as inputs as well as the paths of the target money stock and of capacity output. As is evident by inspection, this model has a steady-state solution (for A/ 0) if the target money stock follows a constant growth path. In that steady state the rate of inflation equals the target rate of money growth, real output equals capacity output, and interest rates are constant. Our procedure is to examine the responses of the system when it is disturbed from a steady state in which capacity output is constant at the level of actual output in 1980 Q2 and money growth is targeted at 7 percent per annum. The steady-state values of endogenous variables are shown in Table 2. Table 2 Steady State of Simulation Model 1524.5 y r 8.3% P/P 7.0% 368.9 M/P billion measured in period 1 dollars billion measured in period 1 dollars Using these steady-state values for all lagged variables, and a 7 . percent money growth target, the system will merely remain at its steady state if undisturbed. The dynamics of the model may be prob~d by examining the time paths of deviations of key variables (usually y) from ~teady-state values in response to a shock. demand (ey = .01). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Consider a permanent 1 percent increase in aggregate - 8 - Ry equation (3), it can he seen that inflation will proceed at a constant rate only when output is equal to capacity (y tion, ,ci = 1. = y*) since, by assump- In the steady state, interest rates must be constant. Suh- stituting capacity output for y and Y-1• equation (1) may be solved for the equilibrium interest rate. It can he shown that the rate must be higher by cey) to offset the increase in aggregate demand. Real balances must, of [ai course, be constant and lower because of the higher interest rate (equation 2). By equation(~) interest rates wlll be constant only when money demand equals the target monev stock~*, which is growing at a 7 percent rate. For real balances to be constant, prices must also be rising at a 7 percent rate. While the system may be solved for its steady state, it will not necessarily approach that steady state when disturbed; the system may be unstable for some combinations of parameter values. unstable with fairly plausible parameter values. In fact, this model is Figure 1 displays the time path of deviations of output from the initial steady-state level (the output "multipliers") resulting from a permanent 0.01 inc.rease in aggregate demand with S1 = .5, [ai = .0088, $3 = .025, Yl = 15. The only "unlikely" value in this set is the one for ~3 (the impact interest elasticity of money demand), which is generally thought to be closer to 0.05. a 75-year period. The necessary compression of the time axis makes cycles appear unusually sharp. The vertjcal scale is truncated, which ' further exaggerates the appearance of the cycle. Due care must be taken in examining Figures 1 and 2 to note the scales on the axes. cycle emerge from Figure 1. 18 quarters duration. Two striking features of the First, there 'is a sharp, undamped cycle of about Second, there appears to be a muc.h longer c.yc.le -- about 60 quarters in duration -- as well. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The simulation was run over .. 0 Figure 1 0 0 _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _...,., ro ..q' 0 0 0 \D 1'- 0 0 '0 0.1 <D 0 0 0 0 t.O I I.O I 0 0 0 0 o - - -- O I - I N-+----..-------,----.------.----~----r------,-.--~---...-------1' -0 00 40 00 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 80 00 t 20. oo , 60. oo 200 00 Quarters 240 00 iso oo 320 oo 360 oo AOO co Figure 2 0 0 -- I � g1 0 0 - \ rJ) 0 0 � 0 ..n u'J 0 0 �IV Ll...g I ::i:�0 o- 0 I \ I I I \ � - \ \I I \ 1 I I I I Zo -o I I l v I I I -� I\ � I I \ \ I l I \ t-' 0 \ I \ \ \ - \ 0 0 \ - \.{'I �') \ I") -,.... V https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (""f'i V'-' rn oo & 80 00 120 00 200 00 160 00 Quarters � 240 00 280 00 • }2'.),00 3GO O'.) 4C)0 C ", 11 - Much can be learned about this system by examining the dynamics of this same model with the price equation "disconnected" A set to zero. In this case the expected and actual inflation rates will he permanently set at 7 percent. Figure 2 shows the output multipliers for the same 0.01 shock to aggregate demand. The shorter cyLle is retained, virtually unaltered, but the long cycle has disappeared. To focus our analysis on the effect of policy on the shorter Lycle, we suppress the effect of output on prices (A= 0) for a series of simulations discusserl in the next section. The analysis to follow will he restricted to the effects of shocks to the aggregate demand for goods (changes to ey)• The reason is that it is for this type of shock that policies focused on monetary aggregates are supposed to be desirable. Shocks to the demand for money, on the other hand, can (in this model) be completely absorbed by changes in money holdings with no effect on output if interest rates are simply held constant. III. The Behavior of the Models without Price Effects This section examines the properties of the shorter cycle of the standard model, abstracting from the longer price-expectations cycle by breaking the link between output and the price level (A= 0). This is purely a matter of analytical and expositional convenience and does not imply any judgment about the significance or relevance of the price-expectations cycle. In fact, as will be seen, ignoring the price cycle when making policy decisions can have disastrous consequences. "Before examining alternative policies, it is useful to learn more about the nature of the cyclical responses of the model and the sensitivity of the model rlynamicg to certain key parameters. Table 3 displays the resultg of varying the interest elasticities of money demand (~3) and aggregate demand (ra 1 ). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The table shows the turning points in the time path of output TARLE 3 Effect of Interest Elasticities on Output Hult1.pliers for a Sustained 1 Percent Increase in Aggregate Demand A = (3 3 1:a i y n, B1 = l/ .5 Values of output multipliers at turning points 1 1 .05 .0088 15 (5) 37.5 (13) 6.1 (23) 23.2 (32) 14.6 (41) lQ.2 16.7 .025 .0088 15 (4) 35.7 (13) 2 -2().6 (21) 43.0 (2Q) -29.7 (47) 50.9 (45) -40.3 (54) 59,4 3 .01 .0088 15 (4) 34.6 (12) -70.6 (21) 133.2 <2'n -451.4 (41) 294.1 (48) -1207.1 (60) -93.5 4 .05 .0088 30 (5) 36.4 (13) 7.6 (2?) 21.7 (31) 15.6 (40) 18.5 (4q) 17.1 (58) 17.8 (60) 17.7 5 .025 .0088 30 (5) 31.8 (11) -15.8 (lQ) 34.7 (26) -15.0 (34) 32.7 (41) -12.8 (48) 30.9 (56) -10.7 (4) 6 .01 .0088 30 31.2 (11) -65.0 (18) 115.0 (26) -423.6 (35) 172.3 (43) -948.9 (56) 29.0 (60) -1150.9 7 .05 .0176 15 34.3 (12) -13.S (lQ) 33.2 (26) -10.3 (34) 29.8 (42) -6.9 (49) 26.8 (57) -4.1 (60) 8.3 8 .025 .0176 15 (4) 32.3 (11) -45.9 (18) 93.1 (26) -184.8 (32) 232.1 ( 40) -614.1 (49) 287.7 (57) -910 .3 (60) -644.1 (4) (11) (18) (26) 9 .01 .0176 15 10.1 -96.1 250.3 (39) -724 .8 (47) -1524.S (60) -581.5 10 .05 .0176 30 ( 4) 31.0 (11) -10.3 27.8 (25) -3.3 (32) 21.4 (39) 2.4 (47) 17.1 (54) s.7 (60) 14.4 (3) (10) ( 2()) .025 .0176 30 30.4 -37.4 (16) 72 .1 ('B) 1r -122.3 161.9 (36) -365.0 ( /43) 248.1 (50) -647.1 179.9 .01 .0176 30 (3) 28.9 (9) 12 (15) 195.4 (22) -1100.0 (34) 467.? (42) -1524.S (4) -88.8 (18) -1122 (SO) (60) -42.0 (60) 13.6 ....N (60) 512.44 The autonomous shock to aggregate demand is 15.24 billion "dollars. " The number in parentheses above a value is the quarter in which that value occurs. All simulations are660 quarters long. The value for quarter 60 does not necessarily represent,a turning point. 1/ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (58) - 13 multipliers during a 60-quarter simulation in which there has been a permanent 1 percent increase 1n aggregate demand. behavior of the model with R3 demand of 0.1) 11nder a Yl = 15 = The first row of Table 3 snows the .05 (a long-run interest elasticity of money policy. The result is a noticeable but well- damoea cycle of about 18 quarters duration. LowerinP, R3 to 0.025 (row 2) shortens the cycle to about 16 quarters and makes it undamped. ing R3 to 0.01 (row 3) results in a violently unstable cycle. three rows of Table 3 repeat this experiment under a Yl = 30 Further lowerThe next policy. Again, the cycle becomes more violent as the interest elasticity of money demand is reduced. Reducing the interest elasticity of money demand increases the magnitude of interest rate response through the policy function to movements in output. It might be expected that making output more responsive to interest rates (but holding the lag structure constant) would have much the same effect -- and in fact it does, as is shown in the last six rows of Table 3. Doubling the sum of the ai coefficients makes the cycle less damped, Just as reducing the interest elasticity of money demand did (compare row 7 to row 1, row 8 to row 2, and so on). The first six rows of Table 4 show the result~ of shortening the lag structure on interest rates in the aggregate demand equation, from a mean lag of 6.4 quarters to a mean lap, of 4.0 quarters. r.omparing these responses to the first six rows of Table 3, it ts evident that the main effect is to shorten the duration of the cycle from about 18 quarters to about 13 quarters. Also, the cycle becomes somewhat less damped. Rows 7 throu~h 11 of Table 4 show the effect of an increase ln the speed of adJustment of money demand (~1 is reduced from 0.5 to 0.25) by comparison to rows 1 through 5 of Table 3. cycle with little impact on its duration. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis This change tends to dampen the TARLE 4 The Effect of Lag Structure on Output Multipliers for a Sustained 1 Percent Increase in Aggregate Demand ).. = 0 s3 Me,qn lag 'Y 1 s1 ---- .OS 4./) 15 .5 2 .025 4.0 15 .5 (4) 3?.l (10) -19 .2 (17) 47.1 (23) -43.3 (29) 73. 5 (36) -86.4 (42) 115. "i (49) -161.2 .s (4) 30.R (10) -59 .4 (17) 129.6 (23) -389.4 (32) 33Q.1 (38) -1179.4 (51) 397.7 (57) -1376.4 (l•) (10) .5 32.8 7.9 (16) 23 .s (23) 13 .9 (29) 19.9 (35) 16.1 (41) 18.5 (48) 17.0 (54) 17. 9 (60) 17.3 .s (3) 30.l (9) -14. 5 (15) 39.5 (21) -26.Q (26) 52.5 (32) -48.Q (38) 73.3 (43) -77 .9 (49) 97.2 (55) -127.0 (3) (9) -53.9 (14) 117 .5 (20) -417.6 (27) 265 .8 (33) -11Q9.9 (43) 277 .o (49) -1416.8 (60) 266.0 .01 4.0 15 4 .OS 4.0 1() s 6 .025 4.0 .01 4.() 30 30 .s 78 .s (-,. 0 (17) ?5. 5 (56) 18. 5 1 3 (11) Values of output multipliers at turning points (SO) (24) (30) (3) (43) 11.Q 21.5 14 .8 19.5 16.2 (4) 34 .1 (SO) 16.8 ~ +' (51) 16.Q (60) 17.9 34.7 (45) -15.1 (53) 34.3 -270.3 (38) 216.0 (45) -772 .2 (60) 338.1 (22) 21.4 (3?) 15.8 (41) 18.4 (SO) 17.2 (59) 17.7 (11) (l'l) -13.1 10.3 (26) -8.1 (34) 25.5 (41) -3.4 (48) 21.9 7 .07 5'};_/ 6.4 15 .25 37.1 (13) 7.2 (23) 22.4 (32) 15.1 18.8 8 .0375]:/ 6. 4 15 .25 (4) 35.0 (12) -16.7 (20) 35.4 (28) -15.7 .015.:U 15 .25 (12) -57 .4 (?.7) 6.4 (4) 33.2 (20) q 103.3 . or-,J:./ (S) 10 6 .4 30 .25 36.1 (13) 8.1 11 .037 5Jj 6.4 30 .25 (4) 33.5 (5) 1/ 2/ (42) (37) (60) -12.6 (56) .1 (60) 11.5 The number LTI narentheses ahove a value is the quarter in which that value occurs. The values of B3 preserve the long-run interest elasticities of money demand found in the first fLve lines of tl-i.1s table. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - l"i - To summarize the results thus far, we have seen that t~is model generates endo~enous cycles when perturbed ann that these cycles are reasonably well damped when the model coefficients are of the magnitude ordinarily estimated. However, the model produces undamped cyclical responses if the interest elasticity of money demand is much lower or the interest responsiveness of aggregate demand 1s much higher than usually estimated. The lag structure of interest rates in the aggregate demand equation affects the duration of the cycle with "reasonable" lag struLtures resulting in a cycle of from three to five years duration. or Yl = 30 monetary policies. All of these results are for Yl = 15 We turn now to consideration of a broader range of alternate policies. A policy of attempted control of the monetary aggregates can, of course, be pursued more or less actively. In equation (4), ~e can consider responses with Yl varying from n to arbitrarily large. These extremes cor- respond to fixed interest rates and constant money growth respectively, The effect of varying Yl on the cycle is shown in rows 1 through 6 of Tahle 5. In the case of Yl =0 (fixed interest rate9) output monotonically approaches a value "il.672 billion period-one dollars higher than the steady-state value. Examination of equation (1) will convince the reader that this must be the case. While this policy would eliminate the short cycle it would also be explosive when price linkages are present (X > 0). This should serve to remind the reader that these simulations without price linkages (X = 0) are being examined to facilitate learning about the nature of the short cycle and that any policy conclusions reached must be re-examined in the full model. It is apparent in Table 5 that for Yl = 15 and above, increasing the strength of policy response tends to damp the cycle; with Yl longer undamped even in the case where f33 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis = .025. = 30 it is no However, as may be seen in TABLE 5 Output Multipl1.ers for a 1 "Percent Sustained Increase in Aggregate Demand, Alternative Policies ;>.. =0 l/ 1 y 1 y2 y 3 Values of output multipliers at turning points l .05 0 0 0 Asymptotically approaches 51.672 (26) .05 15 0 0 (5) 39.9 (16) 2 2.3 27.7 3 .05 30 0 0 (5) 36.4 (11) 7.6 21.7 4 .02'l 0 0 0 5 .02') 15 0 0 (4) 35.7 (13) -20.6 (21) 43.0 (29) -29.7 (37) 50.9 (45) -40.3 (54) 59.4 (60) -42.() .025 30 0 0 (5) 31.8 (11) 6 -15.8 (19) 34.7 (26) -15.() (34) 32.7 (41) -12.8 (48) 30.Q (56) -10.7 (60) 13 .6 7 .025 Constant money growth (4) 30.5 (10) -7.1 (17) 23 .1 (24) 1.8 (30) 16.1 (37) 6.9 (43) 12.7 (50) 9.1 (57) 11.3 .os (5) 8 0 15 0 18.q (16) 19.Q (26) 25.3 (37) 23.6 (47) 24.7 (58) 24.0 ?4 .o 9 .05 0 30 0 (5) 37. 5 (14) 15.4 (25) ~3. () (34) 20.4 (44) 21.4 (54) 21.0 (60) 21.1 10 .02'l 0 15 0 (5) 37.6 (14) 11.6 (24) 22.6 (34) 18.1 (43) 20.0 (53) 29.2 (60) 19.5 .0'.?5 0 30 0 (4) 35.1 (13) 11 1. 8 (21) 21.1 (30) 12.6 (39) 17.0 (48) 14.8 (56) 15.9 (60) 15.7 0 0 5 (14) 18.5 (26) 23.8 (48) .025 (5) 37.6 (36) 12 22.3 72.7 (58) 22.6 13 .025 15 0 5 (4) 34 .o (12) -14.7 (19) 32.6 (27) -12.2 (35) 30.7 (43) -9.8 (51) 28.5 (58) -7.3 ~ 1/ (22) (37) 1().6 (43) 22.3 (57) 14.4 (31) 15.6 (40) 18.5 (49) 17.1 (60) 17.7 Asymptotically approaches 51.672 The number in parentheses above a value 1s the quarter in which that value occurs. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (58) 17.8 (60) (60) 10 .6 t-' .J"I - 17 - row 7 of Table 1, the cycle is present even when money growth targets are ad~ered to exactly. Instead of targeting the levels of money, one might wish to consider policy functions which target the rate of growth of money (the Y2 term in equation 4). Such a policy would resist undesired changes in the money stock, hut once made they would be "forgiven" (if Yl = 0), and policy would he directed at reasserting the desired growth rate of money. 11 show the results of Y2 = 15 and Y2 = 30. Rows 8 through These policies (with Yl = 0) fare much better than the Yl policies which focus on the level of money balances. Nevertheless, there is a distinct, although damped cycle. Since we have heen implicitly presuMing that the final obJective here is to smooth the path of income (at least in these cases where the rate of inflation is fixed) it seems reasonable to ~uppose that a policy which re~ponds directly to movement~ in income would be superior to one which chases some other endogenous variable. Accordingly, a more general policy might be written as follows: lnrt = lnrt-1 + Y1ln(M/M*) + Y2Mn(T>.f/M*) + Y3tilny; (4)' with Y3 > 0, this policy would have the Federal Reserve raise interest rates as the rate of growth of output increases. ~ow 12 of Table 5 reveals that a pure "direct target" policy fyt, Y2 = 0) is indeed superior to all other active policies considered so far. cycle. It virtually eliminates the short Finally, the last row of Tahle 5 sho~s that adding a monest response to monetary aggre~ates (Y1 = 15) to a direct target policy re-introduces the cycle. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - lR - VI. SiMulations with Price Linkages in Effect Tle have seen in the preceding SPction that the hypothetical monetary policy is the source of the short cycle in our model, and that if policy were to respond directly to an oucnut tarRet and not at all to money growth targets, the path of output would be convergent and much smoother. a policy Might have no protection from runaway inflation. Rut such These policies must, therefore, be reconsidered in the full model inclusive of price linkages Table 6 shows Lhe model responses un<ler different policies with price linkages in effect. The first row shows the results with R3 = .025 and our standard monetary targets (Y1 = 15) policy. ~his is merely a tabular presentation of the same data shown in Figure 1. The undamped 18- quarter cycle is readily apparent aq well as the presence of the longer (expectations) cycle. (y +5 = 5) By contrast, a policy which responds to output only shows no short cvcle but is explosive over the 60 quarters (row 3). As shown in the final column of Table 6, the inflation rate at the end of this simulation is 11.46 percent above the initial steady 7 percent rate. The problem here is the divergence between the real and nominal rates of interest. simulation. Real rates of interest are about -3 percent at the end of this tf policy were to focus on real interest rates by compensat1nP, for changes in inflation, the qystern should be expected to be damped in the long run. The policy function Might accordingly he modifie0 as follows: (4") where n* is the desired long-run rate of inflation. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TARLE 6 Multipliers for a 1 Percent Sustained Increase in Aggregate Demand, Alternative Policies A -y -y 1 1 ' 2 -y 3 15 -y 4 0 0 Fixed money ~rowth 15., R3 = .025 Inflation rate mult1.pl1ers at 60 quarters'.!:._/ Values of output multipliers at turning points ') 0 = (4) -%.5 (14) -40. l (22) 32.'3 (31) -63.4 (40) -53.4 (48) -53.4 (58) 7g_7 .68 (4) 30.7 (11) -16.8 (17) g_4 (25) -1g.5 (32} -4.2 (38) -11.9 (60) 11.0 .()0 (60) 205.0 11.46 (60) 3.3 1~20 3 0 5 () 0 40.2 (12) 35 .B 4 0 5 l.'1 0 (5) 35.6 (14) 5.6 (23) 11.9 (36) 5.6 (5) (14) 3.4 (22) 8.1 (60) -5.6 (15) .03 (21) 3.1 -9.5 (6) 1../ (40) 5.7 t-' 5 0 5 1.5 .02 35.5 6 0 5 1.5 .05 35.4 (5) 1/ 2/ (SO) -..0 .54 (60) -7.8 The nuMber in parentheses above a value iq the quarter in which that value occurs. Target rate of inflation assumeo to he 7 percent. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis .01 - 20 - As can he seen in row 4 of Table 6, with Y3 = 1, y1 = O, ~ = 1.5, and the system is very well damped in both the short and the long run. The main oh1ect1on to the re9ults of this nolicy is that the equilibrium inflation rate is permitted to change in response to shocks. In this partic- ular simulation the inflation rate appears to be approaching a new equilibrium level at above 8 percent; it is 1.2 percent above "target" at the end of 60 quarters. Thi9 happens because policy (4'') with y1 = 0 resists changes 1n the rate of inflation, but once the inflation rate changes, makes no effort to return inflation to anv particular level. The final two rows of Table 6 show that any significant response to the level of the inflation rate (y5 > O) . tends to increase the fluctuations in income, the effect increasing with the size of YS· 0n the other hand, inflation is held reasonably close to the targeten 7 percent rate for these runs. = The final targets policy with y1 .05 does about as well at holding inflation near its target as does the fixed money growth policy and it does much better at smoothing income responses. V. Summary and Conclusions The simulation properties of a simple dynamic IS-LM model have been examined at some length. It was found that the model responds cyclically to 9hocks under a fairly wide variety of monetary policies. appear to be two basic cycles: In fact, there a shorter cycle associated with "money target- ing" monetary policy responses and a longer price-expectations cycle (more than 15 years). The short cycle is especially noticeable with policies aimed at ach1eving a nartLcular monetary a~gregate level. This cycle hecomes ~uch more pronounced as the interest elasticity of money rlemand is reduced or as the interest ela9t1c1ty of the demand for goods is increased. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The strength - 21 - of policy response to deviations from monetary target levels 0r from growth rates priMarily affects the degree of damping in the system, leaving the frequency virtually unchanged. The la~ structure of the mo<lel, especially that of the demand for goods, determines the frequency of the short cycle: the shorter the mean lag of interest rates in the IS curve, the shorter the duration of the cycle. In all cases examined, though, this cycle is fairly long, ranging from about three to four and one-half years. It is not likely that for plausible sets of parameter values this model will be useful for explaining the erratic path of output for 1q7q Q3 through lq80 04. Finally, it was found that a policy based on final targets of output growth and inflation was under some circumstances superior to monetary aggregates policies in smoothing the system's output responses to shocks. These results are, of course, strictly valid only for the specific model consLdered. The scope of experiments performed was broad enough to give some reason to believe that these results would be qualitatively representative of a wide range of models of similar hut more elaborate structure (for example, the MPS model). The results would almost certainly not be representative, however, of currehtly fashionable models in which expectations variahles are specifjed to be identical with the model's outcomes for those ' variables. In most ratLonal-expectations Models, final target policies will ultimately do no better than monetary target policies. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The New Approach to Monetary nolicy A View fr~m the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk At the'Federal Reserve Bank of New York January 1981 Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Margaret L. Greene January 22, 1981 THE NEW APPROACH TO MONETARY POLICYA VIEW FROM THE FOREIGK EXCHANGE TRADING DESK AT THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK Margaret L. Greene The change in approach to monetary policy in October 1979 had a strongly positive l.Illpact on the psychology of the foreign exchange market. that time the foreign exchange markets had become thoroughly disappointed with the previous monetary procedures. To be sure, interest rates had increased progressively since the summer of 1977, and by the end of September 1979 the discount rate was at 11 percent--some 5 1/2 percentage points above its previous low. But, with the rate of inflation accelerating more rapidly and the growth in the money supply again far above target, monetary policy appeared to have little bite. In the view of most market participants, the Federal Reserve's continuing difficulties in reaching its targets reflected either an inability or an unwillingness to take whatever actions were necessary to put up a credible fight against inflation. Against this background, the fact that the Federal Reserve would take such a radical departure in the conduct of its open market operat1onf underscored its seriousness about dealing with inflation. In the foreign exchange market, the new procedures, which put more emphasis on bank reserves than on interest rate levels, were expected to be more effective in containing the growth of the monetary aggregates. If there were fewer dollars sloshing around the international markets, the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis By 2 argument went, then there would be less pressure against the dollar in the exchange market. Most market participants expected the new procedures to entail quicker and, at times, larger interest rate adjustments than before to changing economic or financial conditions. They also interpreted the change in approach as likely to lead to higher interest rates in the United States than otherwise, in view of our inflation record. The central banks abroad also welcomed the change in approach to monetary policy. They, too, viewed it as indicating seriousness of purpose on the part of the Federal Reserve and as providing for potentially more effective monetary control. For the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk, the change in approach to monetary policy did not entail any new procedures for the conduct of our foreign exchange operations. We anticipated that, if interest rates became more volatile as a result of the change in monetary procedures, central banks as a group might need to be quicker to respond to short-run disturbances in the foreign exchange market that threatened to render foreign exchange trading disorderly. But, for our part, we saw no need to resist the impact ?f interest rate changes on the excr.ange rate for the dollar. In the event that the dollar came under pressure, resources to finance U.S. exchange market intervention had been greatly enhanced as part of the November 1, 1978, package. Meanwhile, other central banks would find it easier to cooperate with us to help contain selling pressures against the dollar if any should develop. For one thing, they thought that, under the new procedures, they would be less likely to be drawn into a sustained intervention effort that nught pose complications for the control of liquidity in their own domestic https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 3 markets. For another, they were satisfied that the U.S. author1.t1.es had clearly taken action to restore balance to our domestic economy. If the dollar became well bid in response to the demand for money and credit in the United States, the Desk could take advantage of the dollar's strength to buy in the market and from correspondents the currencies needed to repay the Federal Reserve's swap drawings,cover the Treasury's foreign currency obligations, and rebuild currency balances for the U.S. authorities. In the process, our currency operations would help cushion some of the impact of U.S. interest rate volatility on the exchange rates and money markets of our trading partners. The experience with the new procedures to date has left the markets with the impression that U.S. short-term interest rates were higher on average during the past 14 months than they otherwise would have been. In any case, U.S. interest rates were more volatile on a day-to-day basiJ:./ and subJect to sharper, if shorter,cyclical swings. Also, expectations about likely interest rate developments shifted far more abruptly and strongly than before. The greater volatility in interest rates in the United States has imparted more volatility to the exchange markets as substantial changes in the relative cost of funds or yield on assets among countries created incentives for holders of the rapidly growing pool of internationally mobile and interest-sensitive funds to shift from one currency to another. On a number of occasions after October 6, 197~ the exchange markets became disorderly. Short-term movements in exchange rates, spurred freq~ently, but not exclusively, by interest rate considerations, have been far greater Jj Dana B. Johnson, "The Impact of the Federal Reserve' s New Operating Procedures on the Variability of Interest Rates" (BoJrd of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 1981). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 4 than can be attributed to the more gradual shifts in the underlying fundamentals. (See Chart 1 and compare with Chart 2 for the period November 1, 1978,to October 5, 1979.) Day-to-day movements in the pivotal dollar-German mark relationship have at times been wide and erratic and rank among the greatest 24-hour changes in exchange rates since the U.S. authorities resumed intervention in July 1973 after the floating of the dollar earlier that year. (See Chart 3 and compare with Chart 4 for the eariier period._g_/) Also, spreads between bid and asked rates widened,and foreign exchange dealers became reluctant to take dollars into their positions even for short periods during a day. On such occasions the Desk had to intervene, sometimes forcefully. The most problematic period from the point of view of the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk was April 8-July 16, 1980,when U.S. interest rates tumbled rapidly, falling to levels below those generally prevailing abroad, and when the two-phase elinunation of credit controls generated fears in the foreign exchange markets that the Federal Reserve was actively moving to an accommodative monetary stance. This process began with an abrupt turnaround in exchange market expectations that prompted a generalized • dumping of dollars around the world and pushed the dollar-mark spot rate down 5-1/2 percent in Just 24 hours. Subsequently, as traders recognized gj The data in these charts are derived from quotations in the U.S. market including the close of one day and the range of quotations during the entire succeeding trading session. Although they encompass a 24-hour period, the data do not include actual exchange rate quotations for the dollar-mark rate in Far Eastern or European markets. When trading is active, rates in these other centers are more likely to fall outside the range of rates quoted in the United States. Therefore, these charts systematically understate the variability of the dollarmark rate at times when the exchange markets are most volatile. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 5 that the Federal Reserve's approa~h to monetary policy implied that some easing in financial market conditions was appropriate as long as money and credit demand weakened and evidence of recession mounted, the dollarmark rate fluctuated 1-1/2 to 2 percent on each of several days during the remainder of the period. In this environment, the Desk made no attempt to hold the dollar rate. The obJective was merely to contain the pressures against the dollar so that they did not cumulate to the point of taking on a momentum of their own. ' this obJective, the Desk maintained a flexible To achieve approach in the market in order to take advantage of any opportunity to inject a sense of two-way risk to the exchange markets. we had the close cooperation of the Bundesbank. In this respect In addition, we were in frequent, often minute-to-minute, consultation with the Government Securities Trading Desk. Although that Desk did not basically have to alter its approach to the conduct of monetary policy,-l/ we found several opportunities to adjust the timing of operations to obtain maximum psychological effect for our foreign exchange intervention. In the end, the pressures against the dollar during the April-July period were severe but did not become as entrenched as they had been before. Although we sold $200 million equivalent of marks or more on five days during this period, we did not have as many days of large intervention as we did in 1979. Nor did we have to intervene as frequently. (See Table 1 . ) Apart from these periods of pressure, the dollar has generally fared well in the exchange markets during the period after October 6, 1979. The market was more confident of the dollar's underlying strength than before. ]./ In part this was because of the improvement in our Fred J. Levin, "Implementing the New Operating Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk" (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, January 1981). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 6 TABLE 1. U.S. OFFICIAL SALES OF GERMAN MARKS IN THE MARKET, NOVEMBER 1978-NOVEMBER 1980 1/ (in millions of U.S. dollar equivalent) Time Periods Total intervention of that period Number of days of intervention/ total business days in period Number of days when .. intervention exceeds $200 million equivalent Before October 6 measures November 1 December 29, 1978 $5,551.6 26/41 = 63% 11 June 15 July 26, 1979 $5,267.1 26/30 = 86.7% 11 August 30 October 6, 1979 $3,769.9 17/27 = 63% 10 After October 6 measures December 3, 1979 February 7, 1980 $1,340.9 15/47 = 31.9% 2 April 8 July 16, 1980 $3,221. 7 27/72 = 37.5% 5 !/ These figures include sales by the Desk in the markets in New York and the Far East. They exclude sales to correspondents. The sum of the intervention in the five periods represents 95 percent of all mark intervention from November 1, 1978,to July 16, 1980. The remaining $1,099.1 million equivalent was done intermittently outside of the five periods of heavy dollar pressure indicated above. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 7 current account position and in part because other countries had, and were more readily perceived ashaving, economic problems of their own. Interest rate differentials were strongly favorable to the United States at times during the year, attracting inflows from abroad that served to buoy the dollar in the exchanges. Moreover, uncertainty under the new monetary approach about the near-term course of U.S. interest rates added a new dimension of risk for anyone about to sell the dollar short. This more favorable attitude toward the dollar permitted the nesk to buy German marks and other currencies more often than it had sell and to restore the foreign currency position of the U.S. authorities. Because the market was more willing to hold dollars under conditions in which we were in the . market to buy currency, we had more leeway for covering the Federal Reserve's swap debt and the Treasury's foreign currency obligations. In all cases we operated to buy currency in a manner that would avoid leaving the impression that we desired to put a cap on the dollar's rise. But at times--particularly in early April and again in the period October 9-November 28--we did intervene quite forcefully to prevent the dollar's rise from becoming disorderly. ( See Table 2 . ) In the period October 7, 1979,to November 28 1980, the Desk was a net buyer o~ currency. On balance, we purchased $1,393,7 nullion equivalent of German marks in market operations. In other operations (including net correspondent purchases and purchases from the Bundesbank which do not reflect its intervention sales of dollars), the Desk acquired an additional $5,873,6 million equivalent net of German marks, bringing total net acquisitions of German marks after October 6 197~ to $7,267.3 million equivalent. Of this a.mount,$3,750,3 million equivalent was used to repay System swap debt and $2,493,3 million equivalent was put into 'Ireasury balances to cover its "Carter-bond" liabilities. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The 8 TABLE 2. U.S. OFFICIAL PURCHASES OF GERMAN MARKS IN THE MARKE'I NOVEMBER 1978-NOVEMBER 1980 1/ (in millions of U.S. dollars equivalent) Time pen.eds Total operations in market during that period Number of days of operations in market/ total business days in period Number of days when operationsexceed $150 mil. equivalent Before October 6 measures April 1 May 31, 1979 $2,647.1 31/43 = 72% 9 After October 6 measures February 22 April 16, 1980 $2,543.6 28/38"" 74% 6 July 29 October 8, 1980 $ 889.7 27/51 = 53% 0 October 9 November 28, 1980 $2,914.7 29/30 = 97% 6 1/ These figures include purchases by the Desk in the markets in New York, Frankfurt, and the Far East, both spot and forward,and also purchases from the Bundesbank which correspond to its intervention sales of dollars in the Frankfurt market. They exclude purchases from the Bundesbank not directly representing its sales of dollars in the market or purchases from other correspondents. The sum of tht amounts in the periods above is 99 percent of all market purchases from April 1, 1979,to November 28, 1980. The remaining $96.2 million equivalent was done intermittently outside of the four periods of dollar strength indicated above. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 9 remaining $1,023.7 million eqUJ.valent was also put into balances to establish, in effect, a long mark position for the System to be used as needed to finance future foreign exchange intervention. In addition the Desk purchased $507.9 million equivalent of other currencies, mostly Swiss francs and French francs. For the excqange markets in late 1979, volatility was not a new phenomenon. Ever since the dollar was floated, institutions participating in these markets coped with considerable exchange rate variability and had already proceeded to adJust their trading practices and operating procedures accordingly. Trading, credit,and position limits were reviewed,and new procedures for monitoring the trading operations of each bank or branch within separate guidelines were put in place. Even so, to take a "view" on a currency and hold a position for several months, as had been common practice under the par value system of exchange rates, had long beenconsidered risky. Instead, the professionals in the market, the dealers in the largest market-making banks, came to look for opportunities where they could make a profit in a single day so as to avoid exposing their position to the risk that exchange rates might move against them even in as short a time as overnight. This env1rorunent fostered daily "in-and-out" transactions that ballooned daily turnover, generated a large increase in spot trading at the expense of forward trading, and increasingly focused exchange market attention on transitory rather than fundamental factors affecting exchange rates. This change already had 1mpl1cations for the way the exchange market behaved. At times of economic or political uncertainty, the exchange markets quickly lost resiliency. In addition, the role ofrisk- taking over periods of time shifted from the professionals in the interbank https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 10 exchange market back to their customers and ultimately to consumers, workers, and investors whowereunwittingly being exposed to the effects on prices ' and incomes of exchange rate variability. After October 6, 1979,uncertainty over the implications of the new approach to monetary policy for the near-term outlook for U.S. interest rates added a new dimension of risk for the foreign exchange trading community. Indeed, the most active position-taking banks claim they took fewer and smaller short-dollar,long-mark positions for the period overall. There is little evidence to suggest, however, that these banks changed their position-taking activities in a systematic way. They assumed at times as large positions in German marks as before October 6, and the foreign exchange managers of the largest position-taking banks confirm that there was no effort to change the limits within which individual dealers or particular trading operations traded. Over the course of the year, some market participants sought ways to respond to the new source of rate volatility. At firs~ participants in the interbank market stepped up their "in-and-out" spot trading as banks either tried to take advantage of potential profit opportunities or acted defensively simply to protect their o.m positions. But as each bank fought to catch a turn in the exchange rate before its competitors, the whole market found that volumes continued to soar, as documented by this Bank's 1980 survey of foreign exchange turnov~r; but profits did not necessarily grow. Moreover, the back offices were encountering severe strains in processing the work needed to effect payments, the risk of costly payment errors was mounting, credit lines with counterparties were being exhausted, and the sheer volume of trading was exposing banks to an ever- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 11 increasing risk that settlement problems on a particular day could pose a severe problem. At the same time, exchange rates were increasingly domnated by short-term and technical factors that were unpredictable,and these erratic fluctuations merely accentuated the risk of carrying a foreign exchange exposure. Meanwhile,major money ~enter banks with a large comm.J.tment to the U.S. domestic markets found that they could use their expertise in the foreign exchange area to capitalize on the interest rate volatility while also dealing with these operating problems in their foreign exchange back offices. Their foreign exchange dealers had far more experience with volatile markets r than most of their domestic money and bond dealers. The forward markets in exchange can be used as an effective alternative to deposit-taking activities for taking a view on interest rate~/ while leaving the bank's currency position covered and not necessarily affecting the balance sheet of the bank.2/ In addition, a bank can utilize some of its position-taking a,uthori ty in currency to borrow where interest rates are relatively low and thereby reduce the cost of funding for the bank. of the more important trading banks began to shift expertise from spot trading per se toward Accordingly, a number their trading funding and arbitrage operations, while others incorporated such a shif't in their plans for 1981. To the extent that banks were to move in this direction, they would have less need to protect their spot positions. Therefore, as long as no clear ':±.I By doing a swap (that is simultaneously engaging in offsetting spot and forward transactions in the same currency), a foreign exchange dealer can either generate dollars to fund a loan or produce income in a manner similar to placing a deposit. 2/ If the near side of a swap is rolled on a day-to-day basis, all of the transactions are off-balance-sheet items. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 12 trend in exchange rates were to develop, the markets might prove to be more resilient to short-term and potentiaJ.ly reversible movements in exchange rates than before. Not all market participants can make such a shift in their approach to foreig~ exchange, however. Those banks that may not be connnitted to playing a major money .ro.arket role and may not have innnediate access to money market developments in the United States say they find the volatility of interest rates to be a major headache that serves to complicate their efforts to fund their dollar operations. If this volatility should persist, we may find that it has different implications for different types of institutions in the exchange market. Non-dollar-based banks that find they have difficulties with their dollar operations may have real incentives for seeking to shift a larger part of their international business into alternative currencies. Market participants have expressed their concern that investors, private or official, that have only an arm's-length relationship to U.S. markets may seek to protect themselves from the volatility of rates, lack of predictability over capital values, and the possibility that yields can drop to quite low levels by stepping up their efforts to diversify out of dollars. In conclusion, the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk's experience since October 6, 1979,has been generally favorable. Although we have had to intervene at times, the periods of selling pressure have been less prolonged than before,and on balance we have been able to build up foreign currency reserves. In part this more favorable environment for the dollar reflected the market's assessment that the economic fundamentals for the United States have improved both absolutely and relative to those for other countries. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis But to the extent that the new monetary procedures resulted in higher 13 interest rates than would otherwise have prevailed or increased uncertainty about the cost of funding a potential short dollar position, they may have contributed indirectly to a generally more resilient dollar. A longer-term assessment of the new monetary operating procedures, as seen from the Foreign Exchange Trading Desk, is more difficult to draw. So far,it is not clear whether the high degree of interest rate volatility experienced so far is an essential feature of the new procedures rather than an outgrowth of the imbalances in the economy at the time they were adopted. Moreover, the exchange market's adaptation to an environment of dollar interest rate volatility has not yet been completed. But, on the basis o~what fragmentary evidence we have obtained to date,it appears that, if increased interest rate variability becomes a perm.anent feature for dollar-based money markets 9 we face the prospect of a substantial growth in interest-arbitrage activities. we live.,an increase in the volume In the uncertain environment in which 0£ internationally based arbitrage activities could expose the United States to even more interest rate volatility in response to developments abroad. If this volatility were to pose an increased risk for the parties seeking outlets to commJ.t funds, it could~ in due course, provide further impetus for shifting 1nternational lending, and investing business out of dollars and into other currencies. In the long run, such a shift ~ould have far-reaching consequences for the dollar and for its role in the internatior.al monetary system. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chart 1 14 EXCHANGE RATES AND 3-MONTH EURO-RATE INTEREST DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN OM AND U.S. DOLLAR AFTER OCTOBER 6, 1979 OCTOBER 10, 1979 10 9i-------o---- - NOVEMBER 26, 1980 INTEREST-RA TE DIFFERENTIAL Scale Left ai------+---- 71------+--- 5--- 41-------'-----_3 " - - - - - - 1 - - - - - - ----I 2.00 -------1 1. 95 1.90 2i;__-----1----- £XCHANGE RAT£S - ~ 1.85 l"------1-- Scale Right 0 -----f ---------l 0 ND 1979 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis J FM AM J 1980 J AS ON 1. 80 1. 75 Chart 2 15 EXCHANGE RATES AND 3-MONTH EURO-RATE INTEREST DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN OM AND U.S. DOLLAR BEFORE OCTOBER 6, 1979 NOVEMBER 8, 1978 - OCTOBER 3, 1979 10 9i - - - - - + - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - t INTEREST-RA TE DIFFERENTIAL 8 Scale Left ----------f 1-----&------ - - - ~ 2.00 4- - - - - - - - - - - - - 3i-----+----------------11.95 - - - -........ 1.90 2 Scale Right 0! - - - - + - - - - - - - - - - - - 1.80 ! - - - - - ~ - - - - - - - - - - - - , 1.75 .._.__.170 L...L..L..1...L..1-JU,..L.J.~~~,__..................._.___._........,_.............___,_....___._............. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ND 1978 J FM AM J 1979 J A S 0 -.... c.Dc,:t· ___ == --==="""' ..., __... ---- ..... .... -==-- --= ....., ..... z :u a::11 : : - _...,=-== - B "-'I :::E ~ ll:::lllz:::! ie- ,::::a ID .... :::E 11:111:a:""' A. ....... ~--.=.. ---= - q = ....= ...== -== 16 = .., = :::3 =- ==.... =a:: = = ~= =~ =: ... =-----.:-- = c:::, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -=t ..., 31= ~ Ci) .... ,._ .., .... == c:,~ - ~ -x ::c c:::, - -.... = - ....,._ a: ..... ..... 0, c:::, --...= ..... c::::t - c.:, ;a: == t:::I ...., ::ai: C,jll)::E .... a:11a: -c Cl! (.) .:. ~z: ,c -a: ,:a::a:..., I.ii.I& a:: co -.... c,) z: c:::, ::IE D,_,IAolllCI ..... >,c c::a = c:::, ,_ c:::, c:::, .... c:::, c:::, .., 17 c:::, c:::, - c:::, c:::, ..,. ... = c::, + c.:, -= --=c:::, =z: -= - =:IE = == =- ..... ...__ ~-:::::; ~ ==1 z: 0, ,_ - ==3 =l ~ -....,. ::::::! ..... :z:: c:::, ='.:1CI ~ = --< __, = https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis INTEREST RATE VARIABILITY UNDER THE NEW OPERATING PROCEDURES AND THE INITIAL RESPONSE IN FINANCIAL MARKETS January 1981 Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Dana Johnson January 22, 1981 INTEREST RATE VARIABILITY UNDER THE NEW OPERATING PROCEDURES AND THE INITIAL RESPONSE IN FINANCIAL MARKETS CONTENTS I. II. Introduction and Summary 1 The Impacts of the Federal Reserve's New Operating Procedures on the Variability of Interest Rates 6 A. B. C. III. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis PAGE The Implications of the New Procedures for the Federal Funds Rate Empirical Findings on the Variability of the Federal Funds Rate Variability of Longer-Term Interest Rates Reactions in Financial Markets to the Increase in Interest Rate Variability A. B. C. D. E. F. Liquidity Premiums on Government Securities Before and After October 1979 Treasury and Agency Security Markets Underwriting Spreads on Corporate Bonds Reactions in Mortgage Markets to Increased Rate Volatility Commercial Bank Response to Rate Volatility Developments in Financial Futures Markets 6 11 20 36 36 45 53 63 72 79 INTEREST RA TE VARIABILITY UNDER THE NEW OPERATING PROCEDURES AND THE INITIAL RESPONSE IN FINANCIAL MARKETS* I. Introduction and Summary In an effort to achieve better control over the growth of the monetary aggregates, the Federal Reserve adopted reserves-oriented - operating procedures in October 1979. - It was widely expected:that the increased emphasis i~ daily operations on the supply of reserves would come at the cost of greater variability of the federal funds rate. It was unclear, however, to what degree the heightened variability of the federal funds rate would be reflected in other interest rates, and thus, it was uncertain whether there were likely to be significant repercussions in financial markets. Based on evidence from about one year's experience with the new operating procedures, this study has found that the federal funds rate has indeed been markedly more volatile than in other recent years and that this increased variability has been transmitted to other interest rates to a considerable extent. Also, some evidence of reactions to the increase in variability was found in key financial markets, though on the whole, such adjustments have been relatively modest. It should be emphasized that virtually all of the findings of this study are highly tentative. Given the turbulent economic environment of the past year, it has been difficult to identify with assurance what, ~/ Dana Johnson of the Federal Reserve Board staff was primarily responsible for the preparation of this paper. Major contributors to this study were Norman Mains, Jim O'Brien, Barbara Opper, Leigh Ribble, and David Seiders of the Board staff, and Ed Stevens and Bill Gavin of the Cleveland Federal Reserve Bank staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -2- in fact, the reaction to the new procedures has been. But even if this study has been relatively accurate in describing the initial ~esponse, it seems likely that the behavior of interest rates may continue to evolve in light of further experience with the new procedures. Likewise, the \repercussions tn financial markets that might be expected as·a result of increased interest rate variability may take considerably longer than a year to emerge. (1) A summary of the principal findings are presented below. Over the course of a day, from day to day, and from week to week, the federal funds rate 'has shown a marked increase in volatility subsequent to October 6, 1979. This past year, the range over which the weekly average funds rate moved was about comparable to the range of movement in the 1973-75 cycle, but of course, the swings in the funds rate recently have occurred much more quickly. Even after the data are smoothed by removing these cyclical swings, however, the funds rate on a weekly average basis was about three times more variable over the past year than over the previous 11 years. (2) Interest rates on Treasury securities across the maturity spectrum likewise have shown a clear increase in volatility. In the year since October 6, 1979, the standard deviation of the weekly change in rates for Treasury securities of various maturities has been three to four times greater than in the previous 11 years. Much of this increase in variability reflects, of course, the unusually sharp cyclical swings experienced this past year; but even apart from those swings, Treasury rates have shown considerably more nonsystematic variability since October 1979. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -3- (3) Despite the greater nonsystematic variability of the federal funds rate, its level has continued to be very highly correlated with the levels of rates on Treasury securities. Moreover, expressed either as a first difference or as a deviation from a moving average, the federal funds rate has been more highly correlated with ouher rates subsequent to October 1979. This surprising result may reflect the ~ difficulty under the new procedures of distinguishing between cyclical and random movements in the funds rate. This finding also may be related to the nature of the new procedure~which automatically respond to the growth of the monetary aggregates. Finally, the ability of banks to speculate on the interweekly movements of the funds by altering their behavior with respect to discount window borrowing and the carryover of excess reserves also may help to explain the closer association of the funds rate with other rates. (4) The greater variability of interest rates does not appear to have significantly increased liquidity premiums either on Treasury bills or on Treasury coupon issues. The measurement of liquidity premiums always has been difficult, however, and thus the inability to document that an increase in premiums has occurred is not-surprising,particularly for a period as short and as volatile as this past year. (5) Net positions in Treasury securities maintained by primary dealers were about the same size on average this past year as in the previous year. Trading volume rose more rapidly than gross positions this past yea½ indicating some increase in the turnover of dealer inventory. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Subsequent to October 6, 1979, bid-ask spreads and dealers' implicit -4- underwriting spreads appear to have widened for Treasury bills. There was no systematic evidence, however, of a comparable widening of bidask spreads on Treasury coupon issues. (6) The average underwriting spreads on publicly offered corporate notes and bonds narrowed rather than widened this past year. This overall result was due entirely to a relatively sharp narrowing in the average underwriting spread for issues rated Baa and below. Disaggregating the data further showed that average underwriting spreads widened on issues that were awarded to syndicates via competitive bidding in the period since October 6, 1979, but that spreads narrowed for issues on which the offering terms were negotiated. (7) A number of adjustments were made by various institutions to their mortgage connnitment and investment policies. Mortgage originators and investors have sought to shift some of their interest rate risk to mortgage borrowers. Originators have reduced their connnitment-period risks by imposing larger nonrefundable commitment fees, by shortening periods over which fixed-rate connnitments will be issued, or by writing floating-rate connnitments. Private investors have marketed more adJustable-rate mortgage instruments, or instruments involving equity participations. FNMA has restricted the assumability of the conventional long-term fixed-rate mortgages that it purchases and holds. Moreover, the availability of long-term fixed-rate standby purchase commitments has contracted to some degree both at FNMA and at the dealers in GNMA-guaranteed passthrough securities, and the cost of these put options has increased. The maJor GNMA securities dealers also have used the futures markets more heavily to hedge their positions, margin requirements on firm-delivery forward contracts have become more common, and bid-asked price spreads have widened somewhat. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -5(8) Commercial banks appear to have made only limited adjustments to the increase in interest rate volatility. The overall share of assets invested in rate-sensitive instruments has not changed much since mid-1979, although the share of term loans carrying floating rates has increased. At the same time, most banks continued to experience an increase in the share of their liabilities that are rate sensitive. Thus, on balance, banks do ~ not appear to have reduced their exposure to interest rate risk over the past year. (9) Activity in financial futures markets continued to expand over the past year. Sales volume increased for the major contracts now being offered, and the markets reportedly functioned smoothly despite the increased volatility of rates in both cash and futures markets. Open interest in Treasury bill' contracts declined on balance over the past year but grew enormously in Treasury bond contracts. The limited data available on hedging activity in futures market indicate that it continued to be substantial, but there is no indication that hedging is accounting for a larger share of overall activity. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -6- II. The Impacts of the Federal Reserve's New Operating Procedures on the Variability of Interest Rates* This section documents the extent to which the variability of interest rates has increased as a result of the switch to reservestargeting procedures. The first subsection develops a framework for interpreting the empirical results. That is followed in the second subsection by a description of the empirical findings for the federal funds rate. The third subsection investigates the extent to which other interest rates have reflected the increased variability of the federal funds rate. A. • The Implications of the New Procedures for the Federal Funds Rate For an extended period prior to October 6, 1979, the Federal Reserve's daily operating procedures were geared toward confining the ' federal funds rate to a narrow trading range.!/ Any tendency for the federal funds rate to move away from the desired level was resisted by providing more or fewer nonborrowed reserves. The Desk essentially was indifferent about the relative provision of nonborrowed and borrowed reserves and was prepared to alter the supply of nonborrowed reserves to keep the funds rate trading near the level desired by the FOMC. Figure 1 characterizes the interaction of supply and demand for nonborrowed reserves in the funds rate targeting regime. The demand curve indicates that for a given discount rate rd and a given level of required reserves RR there is an inverse relationship between the demand !/ For background on Desk operations see "The Role of Operating Guides in U.S. Monetary Policy: A Historical Review," by Henry Wallich and Peter Keir, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 65 (September 1979), pages 679-91. * The primary author of this section was Dana Johnson of the Board staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -7- Figure 1 Interest Rates Demand .;., ·Supply R* RR Nonborrowed Reserves Figure 2 Interest Rates r Supply Demand r https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis R* RR Nonborrowed Reserves -8for'nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate. Presumably, an increase in the discount rate would shift this demand curve upward and an increase in the level of required reserves would shift this curve to . h t.1/ t h e rig The Desk's willingness to alter the provision of reserves * is represented by the to hold the funds rate at a desired level rf horizontal supply curve. As shown in figure 1, the Desk would supply R* * nonborrowed reserves to hold the funds rate at rf. In this circumstance, borrowing at the discount window would total RR-R* ignoring excess reserves and carryover provisions. Under its new procedures, Desk operations are designed to achieve a targeted level of nonborrowed reserves deemed consistent with the desired 2/ path for the monetary aggregates.- There are, however, limits beyond which the funds rate is not allowed to fluctuate without the Desk showing resistance. regime. Figure 2 represents diagramatically the reserves-targeting The demand curve is the same as in figure 1. The supply curve now is vertical at the targeted level of nonborrowed reserves R* between the upper and lower bounds for the funds rate. trading range, E. and r At the limits of the in fl.gure 2, the supply curve becomes horizontal, indicating the Desk's willingness to alter its provisions of reserves when those limits are reached. Given the target for nonborrowed reserves * the equilibrium federal funds rate in figure 2 is rf, * and the level of R, of borrowing at the discount window consistent with this outcome again is * RR-R. 1/ Empirical estimates of the determinants of borrowing at the discount window confirm this assertion. See, for instance, Peter Keir, "Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the Effectiveness of Reserve Targeting," in this compendium. ~/ For a detailed description of the new procedures see the staff paper, "The New Federal Reserve Technical Procedures for Controlling Money" (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 31, 1980). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -9Figures 1 and 2 were drawn as if there were a stable relationship between the demand for nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate. Experience indicates, however, that the demand curve is relatively erratic, sometimes shifting substantially from day to day and from week to week as the distribution of reserves among banks changes and as expectations about the very-near-term outlook for the funds rate are revised.!/ This observa- tion has implications for the variability of the funds rate under the two operating regimes. Prior to last October, shifts in the demand curve from period to period resulted in a changed provision of nonborrowed reserves but had little impact on the funds rate. October 6. Just the opposite is the case after Assuming that the trading range for the funds rate does not become a binding constraint, a shift in the elastic port1on of the demand curve under current procedures would result in a changed funds rate but would leave the relative provision of borrowed and nonborrowed reserves unaffected. Thus, it appears that in response to nonsystematic shifts in demand the funds rate would tend to be more volatile in the very short run under the . 2/ reserves-targeting proce d ures.- There also is reason to believe that the new procedures are likely to result in frequent systematic changes in the funds rate. When the mone- tary aggregates deviate from the desired path, the new procedures are designed to automatically generate pressures that push money growth back toward the intended path. For instance, growth of the aggregates that was !/ For a discussion of the sources of variance in the relationship between money market interest rates and the demand for reserves, see Keir, "Impact of Discount Policy Procedures." 2/ This conclusion follows if it is assumed that the demand for nonborrowed reserves is at least as erratic after October 6, 1979, as before and that errors in the supply of reserves by the Desk both before and after October 6 are small relative to the variance of demand. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -10- faster than targeted would lead to an increase in required reserves relative to the provision of nonborrowed reserves. In terms of figure 2, there would be a rightward shift of the demand curve and equilibrium level of the funds rate. thus a higher Moreover, if the faster growth of the aggregates tended to persist, there would be a progressive rightward shift of the demand curve, putting increasing upward pressure on the funds rate. Under funds rate targeting, in contrast, a progressive rightward shift in the demand curve did not result automatically in upward pressure on the funds rate, although the directive did allow the Desk, within relatively narrow ll.mits, to adjust the funds rate target in response to growth of the monetary aggregates. Consequently, adjustments in the funds rate tended to be made in small but easily perceived discrete jumps. In sum, there are two dimensions to the increase in the variability of the federal funds rate: nonsystematic movements due to the new procedures and systematic movements reflecting the interaction of policy and the behavior of the economy. The increase in nonsystematic variability may turn out to be a lasting phenomenon. The sharp systematic movements in the funds rate, on the other hand, were associated with the unusually turbulent economic environment encountered this past year, and presumably were not primarily a consequence of the new procedures. Accordingly, in the empirical section that follows, attempts are made to disentangle these two types of variability in order to focus on the additional nonsystematic variability that is more clearly attributable to the switch to the reservestargeting procedures. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -11- B. Empirical Findings on the Variability of the Federal Funds Rate It is easy to document that the federal funds rate has been more variable over the past year than in other recent years. example, the data in Table 1. Consider, for On a daily basis, the standard deviation of the change in the funds rate in the year starting. October 1979 has been at least 50 percent larger than that in any other year since 1973. Likewise, the 1 standard deviations of weekly changes over the past year have been consid- erably greater than those in previous years. At a 95 percent confidence level, each of the standard deviations shown for 1980 in Table 1 is significally greater than the comparable standard deviations for each of the previous ~even years. Thus, these data clearly illustrate that the funds rate has ~een more variable over the past year; but,of course, these measures of variability reflect movements in the funds rate due both to the new procedures and to the interaction of policy with the turbulent economic conditions experienced this past year. The reserves-targeting procedures have been ~arried out ~nan environment of extremely sharp cyclical swings. On a weekly average basis, the funds rate rose about 7-1/2 percentage points between early October 1979 and early February 1980 ~d then fell 10-3/4 percentage points by late July. Between July and late December 1980, the funds rate rose again about 10 percencage points. When compared to previous interest rate cycles, the range of movements of the funds rate over the past year • '-was not unprecedented. Durfhg the''tast rate·cycle,from'1973 to-1975,- the funds rate rose and then fell about 8-1/2 percentage points. Those swings in the mid-seventies occurred, however, over a considerably longer period of time than was the case this past year. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Thus, the swings in rates this -12- Table 1 Standard Deviation of the Federal Funds Rate Daily Changes Mon. Weekly Changes.Y Tues. Wed. Thur. Fri. 1973 .58 .39 .99 1.33 .34 .34 1974 .59 .so .62 1.31 .39 .37 1975 .60 .26 .81 .91 .33 .32 1976 .25 .17 .17 .62 .14 .15 1977 .17 .14 .13 .30 .13 .15 1978 .18 .12 .16 .43 .16 .13 1979 .38 .23 .37 .63 .18 .21 1973 to 1979 average .39 .26" .46 .79 .24 .24 1980 .91 ·1.42 1.37 1.79 1.15 1.31 1. Data are for October of the previous year through September of the,year indicated. 2. Each series represents the change from the same day a week earlier. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -13- past year were not markedly wider than those that have occurred before, but they certainly occurred much more quickly. Accordingly, any measure of variability which fails to abstract from this cyclical experience is bound to show an increase in volatility compared to earlier years. One simple way to\abstract from cyclical volatility is to focus on very short periods of time. Before last October, the funds rate target 1 typically would be held constant for a given week, and over the past year, the nonborrowed reserves target usually was not revised as the week 1/ progressed except for technical reasons.- Thus, measures of variability of the funds rate over a day or within a statement week should reflect primarily the System's operating procedures. As a measure of movements of the funds rate within a single day, Table 2 shows monthly and quarterly averages of the daily trading range for the funds rate. The trading range was measured simply by taking the difference between the highest and lowest rate at which trades were reported to have taken place. Table 2 shows average trading ranges for all days of the week, for Wednesdays, and for days other than Wednesday. Looking first at the data that include all business days, there was a sharp increase 1n the trading range last October, but a peak was not reached until April,when short-tenn rates were near their cyclical highs. Over the summe~when the funds rate moved below the discount rate and was constrained by the lower bound of the FOMC's desired range, the average trading range tended to narrow and by September it was only slightly greater than was typical over the first three quarters of 1979. This fall and early this winter, the trading ranges again widened appreciably. 1/ See Fred Levin and Paul Meek, "Implementing the New Operating Procedures The View from the Trading Desk," in this compendium, for a discussion of how the nonborrowed-reserves-targeting procedures have been carried out over the past year. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -14Table 2 Average Daily Traaing Range of the Federal Funds Rate (Percentage Points) Period Wednesday All Days Quarterly . Non-Wednesday . 1978: QI QII QIII QIV ',94 1.11 1. 22 1.63 1979: QI QII QIII QIV 1. 80 1. 74 1. 65 4.00 6.20 5.28 5.08 8.56 . 65 . 84 . 77 2. 77 1980: QI QII QIII QIV 3.05 4.15 2.10 4.73 8.20 9.75 5.31 10.25 1. 75 2.64 1. 28 3.12 1979: Oct. Nov. Dec. 4.05 4.40 3.54 9.63 9.56 6.50 2.41 3.11 2.80 1980: Jan. Feb. Mar. 2.60 3.63 2.93 8.86 9.44 6.31 . 76 2.32 2.14 Apr. May June 5.95 3.90 2.59 15.85 8.31 5.09 3.04 2.87 2.00 July Aug. Sept. 2.26 2.08 1. 96 5.50 4.81 5.62 1. 31 1.43 1.10 Oct. Nov. Dec. 4.21 3.51 6.47 8.53 8.31 13.90 2.94 2. 14 4.28 2.56 3.97 3.96 5.09 ' . 51 . 3~ .48 . 67 Monthly https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -15- It is interesting to note that the trading range on days other than Wednesdays narrowed substantially but even this summer continued to exceed the average of the first three quarters of 1979. However, on Wednesdays, the last day of the statement week, the decline in the trading range was relatively more pronounced, averaging this summer about what it did "before October 1979. There'is some sense to this result. Even before last October, the Desk had only a limited ability to affect the funds rate on settlement days, particularly after about 1:00 p.m.,when it becomes increasingly impractical to conduct open market operations. On Wednesday afternoons, the supply of nonborrowed reserves becomes fixed, and the federal funds rate must adjust to clear the market. Thus, even before October 1979, the Desk by necessity lost some control of the funds rate at the end of the statement week. One might expect, therefore, that the new procedures would not result in as marked an increase in the volatility of the funds rate on settlement days as on other days of the week; and indeed, that appears to be the case. Table 3 displays a measure of the dispersion of the funds rate over a statement week. the tradlng range data. The data in Table 3 exhibit a pattern similar to that of There is a sharp increase in variability immedia- tely following October 6, a peak in volatility this past spring, some tendency for volatility to diminish over the summer, and a resurgence of variability late in the year. While this measure of dispersion has been consistently higher than it was before October 1979, it is interesting to note that in 1973 and 1974, it was higher than in subsequent years, suggesting that this measure may be affected by sharp cyclical movements even though it focuses on dispersion over one statement week at a time. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -16Table 3 Average Absolute Deviation of Daily Effective Federal Funds Rate from the Statement Week Average (Basis Points) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Period ' ' Annual Averages 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 " 29 22 16 7 7 9 Quarterly Averages 1979: QI QII QIII QlV 12 10 12 45 1980: QI QII QIII QIV 42 71 32 64 Monthly Averages 1979: Oct. Nov. Dec. 51 46 37 1980: Jan. Feb. Mar. 29 58 40 Apr. May June 83 76 53 July Aug. Sept. 26 39 29 Oct. Nov. Dec. 37 64 90 -17- A pattern apparent in these measures of intraday and intraweek variability is that over the past year they have tended to be relatively large at the times when the funds rate also was showing sharp cyclical movements. One possible interpretation is that even though those measures are for very short periods of time, they are reflecting the policy-related shifts in supply by the Desk. In my judgment, however, another, perhaps equally plausible,explanation is that the relationship between the demand for reserves and the funds rate becomes more erratic at times of rapid cyclical changes in rates. Early in a statement week, the demand for nonborrowed reserves, and thus also the level of the funds rate,depends importantly on market participants' expectations abcut the very-near-term outlook for the federal funds rate. At times of rapid changes, there is a greater potential for market participants to misperceive the level of the funds rate consistent with new reserve conditions. In such circumstances, Desk actions to affect the availability of nonborrowed reserves sometimes do not have the expected effect on the funds rate until late in the statement week,when actual reserve availability has a more dominant influence on the level at which funds trade. An important likely implication is that the additional volatility attributable to the change in operating procedures will be greatest at times of sharp changes in reserve availability associated with significant deviations in the monetary aggregates from the FOMC's desired path. Various measures of the variability of the funds rate based on statement-week averages are shown in Table 4. Summary statistics are shown for the intervals from January 1968 to September 1979, October 1979 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -18- Table 4 Standard Deviation of the Weekl) Funds Rate (Percentage Points Item Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 Levels 2.23 2.91 2.21 1.28 De trended Levels 1. 77 1.90 1.77 1.25 <llanges .37 .97 .35 .40 Changes of Detrended Levell . 23 . 62 .28 .37 Deviation from 3-week centered moving average .13 .37 .17 .21 Deviation from 5-week centered moving average .17 .55 .19 .27 Deviation from 7-week centered moving average .19 .73 .23 .29 Deviation from 9-week centered moving average .20 .92 .25 .29 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -19- to September 1980, January 1969 t~ December 1970, and January 1973 to June 1975. The latter two intervals were chosen to include relatively sharp cyclical movements in interest rates somewhat akin to the experience of the last year. Throughout the period from January 1968 to September 1979, the Federal Reserve operated under a funds rate targeting procedure. • The first two lines of Table '4 show the standard deviation of the level c£ the funds rate using unadjusted and detrended data~ In both cases, the greatest variability is apparent over the past year. The detrended data show, however, a less decided increase in variability this past year. The third and fourth lines of Table 4 show the standard devia- tion for the change in the statement-week average of the funds rate based on unadjusted and detrended levels. Again, these statistics indicate that the variability of the funds rate increased subsequent to October 6. As discussed above, the increased interweekly variability of the funds rate in level or first-difference form rs a reflection partly of the sharp cyclical swings in the funds rate that have occurred since last October. In an attempt to focus on the variability due to the new proce- dures, deviations from centered moving averages were calculated. The moving averages were intended to represent the cyclical movements in rates. The deviations from the moving averages are meant to represent unsystematic movements in the funds rate. As shown in the bottom 4 lines of Table 4, these deviations are,.substantiaH.-y,.more,.variable ,subsequent to ·October 6, ..... ..,,.. "•·•, even compared to those in the other periods of relatively rapid cyclical movements in interest rates. For instance, the data based on three-week moving averages appear to be two to three times more variable this past https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -20- year than in any of the other periods shown in Table 4.1/ These data strongly suggest that there has been a marked increase in interweek volatility due to the new operating procedures. C. Variability of Longer-Term Interest Rates While conventional theories of the term structure of interest ratesemphasize to varying degrees the importance of factors such as . liquidity premiums and market segmentation, they all have as a common element the proposition that expectations about the future course of veryshort-term interest rates are of fundamental importance.in the determinations of longe=-term rates.:?:./ Thus, there is general agreement that expectations about the future course of the federal funds rate are a central feature of interest rate determination in the United States. For instance, theories based on expectations would assert that the rate on a three-month Treasury bill embodies, among other things, the market expectations about the likely course of the federal funds rate over the three-month maturity of the bill. An important implication of these theories is that the greater volatility of the federal funds rate docunented above has the potential for making longer-term rates more volatile. The degree to which greater variability of the funds rate is reflected in longer-term rates should depend importantly on how sensitive expectations are to unexpected move~ents in the funds rate. Rational expectations, for instance, imply that market ·"!/'The standard deviations·of the sbattstics based on moving~averages·were significantly greater this past year than in the other periods shown in Table 4 at a 99 percent confidence level. :?:.I For a review of the literature on the term structure of interest rates, see J.C. Dodds and J.L. Ford, Expectations. Uncertainty and the Term Structure of Interest Rates (Barnes and Noble, 1974). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ,,_, -21participants would efficiently use all information that is economically available. Thus, a wide variety of information in addition to the actual behavior of the funds rate would tend to be used in formulating expectations about the future course of the funds rate. In particular, it would be expected that the change in operating procedures last year would be taken into account by market participants and that their response to the behavior of the funds rate might appear to be somewhat altered. But even if it were widely agreed that expectations are rational, it would remain -unclear to what extent movements in the funds rate would be discounted and therefore whether interest rates would appear to be more or less responsive to the funds rate. The nature of expectations is inherently an empirical issue. The evidence presented in Tables5 through 9 based on weekly average data suggests that the increased variability of the funds rate has had an impact • on other rates. Interest rates on Treasury securities across the maturity r spectrum have shown greater variability subsequent to October 6. Levels, changes, and deviations from moving averages all have been more variable over the past year than in any of the other periods shown in the tables. As predicted by expectation theories of interest rates, the variability of rates as measured in percentage points diminishes as maturity lengthens. (See Table 9 in particular.) In relative terms, however, there was a marked increase in the volatility of rates on Treasury securities throughout the range of available maturities. It is conceivable that rates on Treasury securities were more volatile this past year for reasons unrelated to the variability of the funds rate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Therefore, in assessing the influence of the funds rate, it is -22- Table 5 Standard Deviation of Three-month Treasury Bill ~ate (Weekly data, percentage points) Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Item Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 I Jan. 69 to Dec. 7p Levels 1.57 2.39 1.16 .10 Detrended Levels 1.17 1.53 .93 • 68 Changes .20 . 62 .33 .15 Deviation from 3-week centered moving average . 08 .22 .13 .07 Deviation from 5-week centered moving average .13 .:n .21 .10 Deviation from 7~week centered moving average .16 .43 .28 .12 Table 6 Standard Deviation of 52-week treasury Bill Rate (Weekly data, percentage points) Item Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 ..'.Jan. 73 Jan. 69 to to June 75 Dec. 70 Levels 1.39 1.92 .97 .68 De trended Levels 1.00 1.24 . 78 . 66 Changes .16 .48 .23 • 15 Deviation from 3-we.ek centered moving average .06 .15 .09 .06 Deviation from 5-week centered moving average .10 .22 .14 .09 Deviation from 7-week centered moving average .13 .32 .18 .11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -23- Table 7 Standard Deviation of Five-year Treasury Note Rate (Weekly data, percentage points) Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Item Jan. 73 to June 75 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 1.03 1.26 .62 .65 De trended Levels . 65 .81 .42 .56 Changes .12 .41 .14 .13 Deviation from 3-week centered moving average .05 .14 .05 .05 Deviation from 5-week centered moving average .07 .22 .08 .08 Deviation from 7-week centered moving average .10 ,30 .11 .10 Levels • Table 8 Standard Deviation of 20-year Treasury Bond Rate (Weekly data, percentage points) Item Levels Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan, 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to Dec . 70 1.08 . 84 .56 .40 De trended Levels .42 .48 .29 .28 Changes . 09 .29 .11 .11 Deviation from 3-week centered moving average ,03 .11 .04 .05 Deviation from 5-week centered moving average .05 .15 .07 .07 Deviation from 7-week centered moving average 07 .21 .08 09 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -24Table 9 Standard Deviation of Changes in Rates on Various Treasury Securities (Weekly data, percentage points) Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept . 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 1-month Bill .21 . 85 .33 .17 3-month Bill .20 .62 .33 .15 6-month Bill .18 .56 .27 .15 52-week Bill .16 .48 .23 .15 3-year Note .14 .46 .16 .15 5-year Note .12 .41 .14 .14 10-year Note .09 .32 . 08 .13 20-year Bond .99 .29 .11 .11 Type of security https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 -25revealing to examine the correlation of the funds rate with other rates. Correlations between the three-month bill rate and the funds rate using wee1tly a~nragP. data are shoiro in Table 10. Similar correlations of the funds rate with several longer-maturity Treasury securities are reported in Tables 11, 12, and 13. Focusing on the results in Table 10 for the funds and three-month bill rates, the correlation of the levels of rates shown in line 1 was essentially the same before and after last October. This finding is of major importance, as it suggests that the change in procedures has not markedly altered the'relationship between the level of the funds rate and the levels of other rates. down with the funds rate. Longer-term rates still tend to move up and This linkage is, of course, a critical aspect of the Federal Reserve's monetary control mechanism under either the funds rate or the reserves operating procedures. If this relationship had been loosened markedly by the change in procedure, it could have impaired the Federal Reserve's ability to influence the monetary aggregates. Interestingly enough, the correlation between changes in rates appears to have increased over the past year as is shown in line 2 of Table 10. Presumably, this result reflects pr1.marily the response of the three-month bill rate to the sharp cyclical movements of the funds rate over the past year. This interpretation is supported by the observation that the correlation between changes also was relatively high in 1973-75, another period characterized by sharp cyclical swings in the funds rate. Nevertheless, the high correlation of changes since October is somewhat https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -26'Tab'le 10 Correlation of the Funds Rate with the Three-Month Treasury Bill Rate ·(Weekly data) Item Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to 'Dec. 70 Levels .93 .92 .89 .82 Changes .11 • 72 .62 .09 Deviations from 3-week centered moving average -.02 .56 -.06 -.02 Deviations from 5-week centered moving average .01 .62 -.07 -.07 Deviations from 7-week centered moving average .04 .64 -.03 .06 Deviations from 9-week centered moving average .08 . 72 -.02 .05 Table 11 Correlation of the Funds Rate with the 52-Week Treasury Bill Rate (Weekly data) Jan. 68 Oct. 79 Jan. 73 Jan. 69 Item to to Sept. 79 Sept. 80 June 75 Dec. 70 Levels .90 .89 .91 .82 Changes .22 .65 .28 .07 Deviations from 3-week centered moving average .02 .43 .04 -.05 Deviations from 5-week centered moving average .10 .53 .19 .01 Deviations from 7-week centered moving average .17 .61 .28 .03 Deviations from 9-week centered moving average .23 .65 .33 .08 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis to to -27- Table 12 Correlation of the Funds Rate with the Five-Year Treasury Coupon Rate (Weekly data) Item Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Levels Oct. 79 Sept. 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 .68 . 74 .48 .55 Changes .19 .48 .22 .16 Deviations from 3-week centered moving average .01 .21 -.05 .03 Deviations from 5-week centered moving average .10 .41 .15 .05 Deviations from 7-week centered moving average .22 .Lis .27 .20 Deviations from 9-week centered moving average .29 .46 .33 .27 to Table 13 Correlation of the Funds Rate with the 20-year Treasury Bond Rate (Weekly data) Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept . 80 Jan. 73 June 75 Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 Levels •49 .53 .29 .oa Changes .09 .39 .11 .07 Deviations from 3-week centered moving average -.01 .18 -.04 .03 Deviations from 5-week centered moving average .01 .31 .04 .01 Deviations from 7-week centered moving average .08 .28 .10 .11 Deviations from 9-week centered moving average .10 .26 .09 .13 Item https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis to -28surprising. Given the greater short-term variability in the funds rate created by the new operating procedures, it might have been expected that market participants would have reacted more cautiously to changes in the funds rate. In any case, the relatively high correlations between changes in rates are another indication that the new Federal Reserve procedures did not weaken the tie between the funds rate and longer-term rates. The results presented in the bottom four lines of Table 10 were even more surprising. The data indicate that deviations from moving averages for the funds rate and the three-month bill rate were essentially uncorrelated previous to last October but quite highly correlated afterward. As was indicated above, the moving averages we~e used to approximate the cyclical movements of interest rates. The deviations from the moving averages were intended to represent unsystematic movements in interest rates. My initial expectation was that if this technique were successful in isolating the cyclical movements in rates, the deviations for the funds rate would not show much correlation with other rates, particularly since last October. The results shown in Table 10 appear to indicate, however, that abstracting from cyclical movements, interest rates on three-month Treasury securities have been more, not less, correlated with the funds rate over the past year. Moreover, as is summarized in Table 14, this result also holds for Treasury securities throughout the maturity spectrum. Even the rates on instruments with maturities as long as 20 years appear to have been moving closely with the federal funds rate subsequent to October 1979. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -29- Table 14 Correlation of the Funds Rate with the Rates on Various Treasury Securities (Weekly data, deviations from three-week centered moving averages) Jan~68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 1-month Bill .03 .24 .03 .04 3.'.:month Bill -.02 .56 -.06 -.02 6-month Bill -.02 .56 -.01 -.10 52-week Bill .01 .43 .04 -.05 3-year Note .01 .30 -.05 -.001 5-year Note .01 .21 -.05 .03 10-year Note -.03 .21 -.04 .04 20--year Bond -.01 .18 -.04 .03 Type of security https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Jan. 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to Dec. 70 -30- As can be seen in Table 15, the relatively high correlations of these deviations from moving averages that a~ apparent for various maturity Treasury securities do not merely reflect changed expectations for the very near term. To remove the impact of changes in relatively near-term exp~c- tations, forward rates implicit in the structure of rates on various maturity Treasury bills were calculated. The implied forward rates for a , three-month Treasury bill purchased in three months and for a six-month·Trea~ sury bill purchased in six months' both exhibited essentially th.e same pattern of correlation with the funds rate as did yields in the cash markets. In particular, the deviations from moving averages for the two forward rates both exhibited a higher correlation with comparable deviations for the funds rate after October 6, 1979. Thus, it appears that over the past year expectations about the future course of the funds rate beginning three months or six months into the future have been sensitive to what appears, at least in retrospect, to have been nonsystematic movements in the funds rate. The correlation coefficients presented in the tables indicate the degree to which various interest rate series have tended to move together but do not indicate the relative size of such movements. To assess this latter characteristic, simple regressions were run with the rate on Treasury securities of various maturities as the dependent variable and the federal funds rate as the independent variable. Using weekly average data and expressing interest rates as deviations- from moving averages, it was found that over the past year a change of 100 basis points in the funds rate has been associated on average with a change of 34 basis points in the three-month bill rate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The comparable responses for the 52-week -31- Table l5 Correlation of the Funds Rate with Implied Forward Rates (Weekly Data) Item Jan. 68 to Sept. 79 Oct. 79 to Sept. 80 Jan. 73 to June 75 Jan. 69 to t-l Dec. 70 3-month Rate for Delivery in 3 months Levels . 91 .90 . 92 .80 Changes .17 .66 .25 .oo -.001 .43 .04 -.14 Levels .85 .84 .84 . 79 Changes .20 .49 .29 .07 Deviations from 3-week centered moving averages .05 .20 .07 .003 Deviation from 3-week centered moving averages 6-month Rate for Delivery in 6 months https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -32- bill, the 5-year note, and the 2O-year bond were 17, 9, and 6 basis points respectively. Thus, as predicted by expectations theories of the term structure of interest rates, relatively short-term rates showed the largest reaction to deviations in the funds rate from centered moving averages. Comparable regressions run with data for the pre-October period consistently indicate that there was no statistically significant response of Treasury rates to deviations in the funds rate as would be expected given the finding reported above that such deviations were essentially uncorrelated. Thus, evidence from regressions as well as from simple correlations suggests that subsequent to October 1979, rates on Treasury securities tended to be more closely related to nonsystematic movements in the funds rate. Several complementary explanations for this unexpected finding are given below. The first explanation focuses on the difficulty of distinguishing between cyclical and unsystematic movements in the funds rate under the new operating procedures. Under the old funds rate targeting procedures. market participants usually knew with considerable precision the System's current funds rate target. By observing the Desk's intervention points, knowledgeable observers could easily see when the funds rate objective was _changing. The average funds rate showed some variance from week to week, but usually it was easy to distinguish unsystematic movements from policy-related changes in the funds rate. The situation is now, of course, quite different. It is often difficult for market participants to identify when,and particularly the degree to which,the interaction of Federal Reserve policy with the behavior of the economy is likely to have a lasting effect on the funds rate. Thinking back to figure 2 presented earlier in the paper, the public typically does not know now whether an observed change in the funds rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis , -33- is reflecting shifts in the supply or the demand curve or both. In this continuing state of uncertainty, it is understandable that risk-averse market participants typically would show some reaction to movements in the funds rate, even though in retrospect they often would realize that the cyclical pressures on the funds rate had been misperceived to some extent. Of course, when it does become apparent that rates had over- or underreacted to a change in reserve availability, the funds rate and other rates would tend to move together to their appropriate levels. Thus, after the fact, when the cyclical pattern of interest rates became more apparent, there would appear to be parallel deviations from the cyclical trend for both the funds rate and other market interest rates. A second explanation for the higher correlation of changes in market rates with changes in the funds rate is based on the more immediate response to unexpected changes in the monetary aggregates that typically occurs under the reserves-targeting procedures. For instance, growth in the monetary aggregates fast\ than desired would result in an increase in required reserves relative to the Desk's provision of nonborrowed reserves. Again returning to figure 2, the increase in required reserves would cause a rightward shift in the demand curve and thus a higher equilibrium federal funds rate. Presumably, other interest rates also would increase in response to this rise in the funds rate. Under the funds rate targeting regime, in contrast, there was no automatic mechanism that assured a prompt response in the funds rate target to unexpected growth in the monetary aggregates. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Market interest rates -34- often responded to the monetary aggregates data in anticipation of policy responses, but the System sometimes failed to validate market expectations of a change in the funds rate target for significant lengths of time. Thus, uncertainty about the precise timing or size of policy changes tended to reduce the correlation between the funds rate and other rates under the old operating procedures, when rates are expressed as first differences or deviations from moving averages. As has been noted above, however, the correlations based on levels of rates were essentially the same before and after October 6, suggesting that on average the response of longer-term rates to the funds rate has been comparable even though the timing of movements may have been less close in the earlier period. A third explanation for the higher correlation of rates hinges on the behavior of member bank borrowing at the discount window. Because banks are limited as to how often they may borrow_at the discount window, banks must make some judgement about when it will be most advantageous to borrow.l/ Thus, if banks come to expect that the funds rate will be rising relative to the discount rate in the near future, they might be somewhat more reluctant to borrow in the current period in hopes of borrowing when there is a greater rate advantage. This increase in the reluctance to borrow for a given spread between the funds rate and the discount rate would be represented in figures 1 and 2 as an upward shift in the demand for nonborrowed reserves. Under the funds rate targeting regime, such pressures were offset by changing the provision of nonborrowed reserves,and thus the change in expectations would not have much effect on the funds rate. In the new reserves-targeting regime, in contrast, such pressures on the funds rate would not be offset and could result in an increase in the funds rate. !/ Frequency guidelines in most Federal Rese~ve districts are in terms of hnT,T nf'f-on .<a h.<anlr m.<au https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis hn't",.nT.T in .<a t-hirt-i:>.P.n-week interval. -35- Carryover provisions also give banks s,ome ability to take advantage of anticipated interweekly movements in the funds rate. For instance, if the funds rate generally were expected to decline in the upcoming week, banks would have an incentive to carry over the maximum reserves deficiencies permitted. In terms of figure 2, the demand curve would shift down, putting immediate downward pressure on the funds rate. Such pressures, of course, would have been resisted by the Desk if they had emerged in the context of the funds rate targeting regime but are not resisted under current procedures. Thus, if banks do tend to alter their borrowing at the discount window and their carryover of excess reserves in response to anticipated movements in money market rates, a change in interest rate expectations in the context of reserve targeting could affect the funds rate along with other short-term rates, tending to make them somewhat more highly correlated. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -36III. Reactions in Financial Markets to the Increase in Interest Rate Variability The increase in the variability of interest rates associated with the Federal Reserve's new operating procedures exposes many participants in financial markets to greater risks. It is natural to expect that financial practices will evolve as market participants attempt to shield themselves from the adverse consequences of rate variability. In this section, various aspects of major financial markets are examined in hopes of identifying responses to the heightened variability of interest rates. begins with an examination of liquidity premiums. is a report on the Treasury securities market. This section The second subsection This is followed by a related piece on underwriting spreads in the corporate bond market. The fourth sub- section summarizes recent developments on the supply side of the mortgage market. Subsection E discusses the adjustments made by commercial banks to shield themselves from volatility. The final piece relates the growth of futures markets to recent developments. On the whole, the evidence pre- sented below indicates that the adjustments to the new policy regime were relatively limited over the past year. A. Liquidity Premiums on Government Securities before and after October 197' Theories of the term structure of interest rates often assert that longer-term interest rates embody risk premiums that compensate investors for the capital risk they are exposed to when they make multiperiod commitments In an environment of increased interest rate volatility, it might be expected that risk premiums would increase, since uncertainty about the future course *The primary author of this section was Jim O'Brien of the Board staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -37of rates is greater. Thus, there is reason to believe that the switch to reserves-targeting procedures, which is widely perceived to have made interest rates more volatile, might have led to an increase in risk premiums. As is reported below, however, there is little evidence at this point that such an increase has occurred. Liquidity premiums are associated with interest rates on forward loans--commitments to lend at a given interest rate at a certain time in the future. There are, of coursej markets in which forward commitments are made and traded. However, spot rates where the term to maturity extends for more than one period also contain implicit forward rates. A two-period spot rate, for example, may be thought of as a one-period spot rate followed by a one-period forward rate with a "delivery term" of one period. The liquidity premium embedded in a forward rate for a given security typically is defined as the difference between the forward rate and the interest rate expected to prevail on such a security at the appropriate time in the future. That is, if Ln denotes the liquidity t,m premium, then (1) where Fn is the forward rate at time t with a delivery term of m and a t,m n maturity of n, and E(Rt+m) is the market expectation of the interest rate to prevail at time tfm. The liquidity premium, as defined in (1) may vary for different maturity and delivery terms (n and m) as well as with the time at which the forward rate is quoted (t). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Typically, however, the -38- simplifying assumption is made that the premium for a given maturity and delivery tent is constant through time. Liguidity_,Premiums for Treasury bills. To estimate premiums implicit in the spot market quotations for Treasury bills, one-month (28 days) returns were calculatedforbills with maturities of one month (28 days) to thirteen months (364 days). 1 For example, the one-month return for a six-month bill is simply the actual return that could have been obtained by purchasing a six-month bill and then selling it one month late. Liquidity premiums then were estimated by calculating over various sample periods the average epread between the one-month return on n-month bills (n~l) and the known return that could have been obtained by purchasing a one-month bill and holding it to maturity. Defining this premium as L1 the formula for n-1, estimation is (n~2, ... , 13) (2) n is the one~month return on then-month t, 1 where Tis the sample size, R bill,and R! is the return on the one-month bill. It can be shown that this estimate of the liquidity premium is equal to the true liquidity premium plus the average error in market forecasts of the one-month returns on multimonth bills. Thus, on the "1 assumption that market forecasts are unbiased, L is an unbiased n-1 estimate of the true liquidity premium, and this estimate will have a standard error of (n-1)/T times the standard deviation of the market forecast errors. 1. The maturity structure of outstanding bills dictated the use of maturities with 28-day intervals. The returns were calculated using bid-side prices on Treasury bills. The monthly returns were calculated assuming continous compounding and all returns, and hence liquidity premiums are annualized. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -39Using month-end quotations for various Treasury bills, liquidity premiums were estimated for three sample periods: January 1973-June 1975 (32 monthly observations), July 1975-September 1979 (55 observations), and October 1979-0ctober 1980 (14 observations). The results are presented in Table 16 with the standard error of each estimate in parentheses. As can be seen in the table~ the premiums estimated for the most recent period often are positive but have large standard errors and are noc significantly differen~ from zero at usual significance levels. The large standard errors imply that market forecasts were very inaccurate during the past year. 1 Thus, the premiums cannot be estimated very precisely. For the two earlier periods, the market forecasts were subJect to smaller absolute errors~ giving more precision to the estimated premiums. Still, many of the estimated premiums for the two earlier periods also are not significantly different from zero. Finally, it might be noted that the premiums do not exhibit eny clear tendency to increase for Treasury bills of longer maturity. In Table 17 the differences between the estimated premiums for the post-October 1979 period and each of the two earlier periods are presented. The estimates of premiums for the past year tend to be larger than those of the two earlier periods for the shorter maturities but srlklller for the longer maturities. For all of the maturities, however, the differences between the recent premiums and those of the two earlier periods are not significantly different f~om zero even at low significance levels. Thus, these results provide little evidence that liquidity 1. The implied market forecast errors are obtained by multiplying the ~eported standard errors (in parentheses) by T/n-1. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -40Table 16 Liquidity Premiums on Treasury 1-Month Forward Rates with delivery terms of 1 to 12 Months 1/ (Percentage points) Delivery term of 21 Forward Loan (Months)- Jan. 1973 -June 1975 July 1975 mSept. 1979 October 1979 -October 1980 1 0.22 (0.20) 0.10 (0.05) 1.17 (0.68) 2 0.30 (0.36) 0.24 (0.10) 1.04 (1.26) 3 (0.56) (0.45) 0.48 (0.12) 1.14 (1.59) 4 0.68 (0 .64) 0.68 (0.20) 0.92 (2 .24) 5 (0.50) (0.75) a.so (0.25) 0.75 (2. 70) 6 -0.24 (0.84) 0.06 (0.30) -0.54 (3.00) 7 0.56 (1.05) 0.70 (0.35) 0.56 (3.64) 8 0.40 (1.12) 0.56 (0.40) -0.32 (3. 76) 9 0.45 (1.26) o.s4 (0.45) (4.50) 10 0.20 (1.50) o.so (0.50) -0.40 (5.10) 11 0.22 (1.54) (0.55) (0.55) 0.11 (5.39) -0.24 -.12 (0.60) (1.68) 1/ Standard errors of the sample means are in parentheses. "f_l One month equals 28 days. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 12 o. 72 -0.36 (5.76) -41Table 17 Differences in Liq_uidity Premiums l/ on Forward Rates with Delivery Terms of 1 to 12 Months(Percentage points) Delivery Term of 2/ Forward Loan (Months)- Oct. 1979-0ct. 1980 minus July 1975-Sept. 1979 1 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 0.94 1.07 (0.68) (O. 71) 2 0.78 (1.26) 0.78 (1.32) 3 0.66 (1.59) 0.57 (1.65) 4 0.24 (2 .28) 0.49 (2.32) 5 0.25 (2. 70) 0.25 (2.80) 6 -0.60 (3.00) -0.30 (3.12) 7 -0.14 (3.64) (3. 78) 8 -0.88 (3.76) -0. 72 (3. 92) 9 0.18 (4.59) 0.27 (4.68) 10 -0.80 (5.10) -0.50 (5.30) 11 -0.55 (5.39) -0.11 (5.61) 12 -0.24 (5.88) -0.36 (6 .OO) 1/ Standard errors in parentheses. One month equals 28 days. "'%../ Oct. 1979-0ct. 1980 minus Jan. 1973-June 1975 o.oo -42premiums have increased over the past year. Moreover, the same conclusion emerged when liquidity premiums were estimated for the future delivery of Treasury bills with maturities of two to four months. This conclusion is, of course, highly tentative given the difficulty of estimating premiums over a period as short and as volatile as this past year. Liquidity Premiums for Treasury Coupon Issueso Estimating JS more difficult for premiums associated with rates on Treasury coupon issueb than for Treasury bills. One aspect of coupon issues that creates con- siderable complications is the semi-annual payment of interest. Each payment presumably should be discounted at a rate equal to that on a discount loan whose maturity matches the duration of time elapsed before the coupon is paid. Consequently, the yield to maturity on a coupon security should be viewed as reflecting a type of "averaging" of discount rates for loan maturities appropriate to the security in question. Thus, each of the discount rates embedded in the rate on the coupon security will have its own liquidity premium. Nevertheless, the liquidity premium on a coupon security still can be defined as the excess of the issue's yield to maturity over the average expected yield on investments in one-period securities for the time during which the coupon is outstanding. In principle, the liquidity premium on the coupon issue co~ld be estimated by estimating the premiums in each of the discount ratei embedded in the coupon security's rate in a manner analogous to that used for Treasury bills. implement. This process, however, would be difficult to For this work, liquidity premiums were estimated as the average spread between the return for a one-month holding period on certain https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -43Treasury coupon issues and the return on the one-month bill. That is, for each of the three sample periods, we estimated -n -1 •~-R, (5) where Hi .,.:,Q is the sample mean of the one-month returns on Treasury coupons -1 with an n-period maturity and R is the average return on the one-month bill for the same period. The estimated premiums for coupon maturities of 5, 10, and 15 years are presented in Table 18. As indicated in the table, the premiums are very small, mostly negative,and quite insignificant. 1 Moreover, there, is no indication of the premiums tending to increase in the post-October 1979 period. These results are in general agreement with the results regarding the bill premiums in that there is little evidence of a significant increase in li~uidity premiums in the post-October 1979 period. Of course, the difficulty of obtaining precise estimates in a period of large forecast errors again should be noted. There is another difficulty in estimating premiums on coupon issues that might account for lhe tendency of the estimates of the premiums to be less than zero. Some of the income obtained from coupon issues purchased at prices below par is likely to be taxed as capital gains rather than as ordinary income. As securities selling below par mature, their prices have a tendency to increase toward their par value. These price 1. The coupon maturities actually varied from month to month for a given category (for example, for the five-year category) because the same maturity was not always available on a monthly basis. The average of the maturities for each of the three categories was about 4-3/4, 9-1/2, and 14 years, respectively, with respective ranges of 0-6 months, 0-9 months, and 0-2 years. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -44Table 18 Liquidity Premiums on Treasury Coupon Issues (Percentage points) Years to Maturity Jan. 1973June 1975 July 1975Sept. 1979 Oct. 19790ct. 1989 5 -.04 (.06) -.07 (. 06) -.29 (. 37) 10 -.02 (.03) -.01 (.07) -.02 (. 36) 15 -.05 (.07) .01 (. 07) -.21 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (. 38) -45appreciations are subject to the capital gains tax advantages. The price appreciation on Treasury bills, in contrast, is taxed as ordinary income. Since investors presumably are sensitive to after-tax yields, coupon issues selling at a discount tend to show a before-tax yield that, ceteris ~aribus, is less than that on a Treasury bill. 1 Therefore, the estimated premiums for coupons in Table 18, which are spreads between before-tax coupon and bill yields, may tend to have a negative bias. Whether the average size of this bias might have changed this past year is uncertain. Taken as a whole, the evidence presented in this section gives little indication that liquidity premiums have widened subsequent to October 6, 1979. As was noted several times, the relatively short period of time since the new procedures were introduced makes empirical estimates of risk premiums particulary imprecise. Even if considerably more data wet~ available, however, it is not clear that the empirical results would be ,~y more conclusive. The nature and stability of liquidity premiums have long been issues of considerable dispute, both on conceptual and on empirical grounds. B. 2 Treasury and Agency Security Markets* The secondary market for Treasury and Agency securities is an over-the-counter market maintained by a variety of dealers. The largest and most active of these dealers, designated primary dealers, regularly 1. A detailed analysis of the effects of the capital gains tax provisions on ½efore-tax yields on coupon securities of various maturities is presented in A.A. Robichek and W.D. Niebuhr, "Tax-Induced Bias in Reporting Treasury Yields," Journal of Finance, Vol. 25 (December 1970), pp. 1081-90. 2. For discussions of this dispute see Dodds and Ford, Expectations, Uncertainty and the Tenn Structure of Interest Rates, chap. S, and H.A.J. Green, "Uncertainty and the 'Expectations Hypothesis'," Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34 (October 1967), pp. 387-98. * The primary authors of this section were Ed Stevens and Bill Gavin of the Cleveland Federal Reserve Bank staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -46report a variety of information to the New York Federal Reserve Bank. Based on this as well as some other sources of data, this section examines several aspects of dealer behavior that might be sensitive to an increase in interest rate volatility. Currently, there are 34 primary dealers reporting to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. and 1 began. During 1980, 4 firms stopped reporting Over the previous 10 years, 23 £inns began reporting and 6 firms discountinued reporting. The relatively large number dropping out of the market in 1980 may be an indication that success in the dealer business has become more uncertain. Des?ite the net loss of three reporting dealers, the volume of dealer transactions ln the market for Treasury securities was 4? percent larger in the year after October 6, 1979, than in the year before (Table 19). At the same time, dealers' gross positions in Treasury securiti~s were 29 percent larger on average this past year so that average daily turnover rose from 68 percent to 75 percent of gross positions. Turnover of gross positions in Agency securities increased more substantially, from 18 percent to 35 percent, reflecting in larger part a 31 percent reduction in gross positions. These large changes in transactions and gross positions did I not result in any substantial change in dealers risk exposure as mea~~red by net cash positions. Net cash positions in both Treasury and Agency securities have been unchanged on average. About 80 percent of the expansion in gross positions in Treasury securities represented an equal increase in long and short positions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -47- Table 19 Treasury and Agency Securities Dealer Transactions, Gross and Net Positions (Daily averages, billions of dollars) ~Yp~ ~f security 10/6/78 - 10/5/79 10/6/79 - 9/3/80 $11.83 17.61 3.06 17.01 22.73 4.19 0.68 0.75 0.17 0.18 2.44 13.88 1.18 3.30 9.51 1.07 0.18 0.35 0.08 0.11 Treasuries Transac;t,ons Gross positions Net position Turnover: Transactions . gross P'Osition Exposure: Net posit1on t gross position Agencies Transactions Gross positions Net position TL.rnover: Transactions . gross position Exposure: Source: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Net position.gross position Federal Reserve Bank of New York. -48- More volatile rates might be expected to lead to wider bid-ask spreads. It has been argued, however,~that in periods of-uncertainty market participants gravitate to the more actively traded issues, making the deep 1 markets deeper and the thin markets thinner. Thus,the spread in thin markets would be more likely to widen, while spreads in actively traded markets might be less likely to widen if the redistribution of traders from thin markets to active markets offset the-overall tendency toward.wider spreads. Figures 3 and 4 indicate some widening of bid-ask spreads on the three-month and 52-week Treasury bills in October 1979. I The Treasury bill spreads are the Friday quotes of MerrillLynch published we~kly in the Money Manager. These data are list prices and are used as a proxy for transaction prices,which are not available. Many transactions take place at other than the list price, notably for regular customers and on large transactions. In the 1973-75 period, the bid-ask spread on the three-month Treasury bill was 10 basis points in all but six observations. The spread generally stayed at that level until the week of June 24, 1977,when it fell to 4 basis points. In the fourth quarter of 1977 the spread varied between 4 and 20 basis points. remained at 4 basis points. From January to October 1978 it generally After some variation at the end of 1978, the spread returned to 4 basis points and generally remained there until the tntroduction of the new procedure. Then in the week immediately 1. See K. Garbade and W. Silber, "Price Despersion in the Government Securities Market," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84 (August 1976), pp. 721-41. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis I 0'I I ~ ,-1 ,-1 .... ,:q l>-. 1-1 ::I en co 1-1 (I) E--1 .c: - ....i:: +J en i:: +J 0 P-1 ;:.:: I C"") C"") en 0 1-1 (I) 1-1 Ill .... ::I 00 4-1 co 0 .... fa« -0 ,:q ti) (I) 1-1 i:l. LI) ...... . .-f en N ...... C • cu ::, 'J 0 +J M ...... r-4 en . ...... 'J >, en ,::, ~ en 1 -0 •r-1 ,:q 0 C"l an , C"") 0 N an 0 N I, ~ '0 •= ~. an ,-i ,-i an 0 . . . . . . . . ...::t' ' 7/4/75 6/6/75 1/3/75 12/6/74 -11/1/74 .-f . 1,0 N s.. cu .0 Cl. ...,m •1-' I ~ 10/3/80 9/5/80 4/4/80 3/7/80 J/1/80 1/4/80 • 12/7/79 • 11/2/79 9/7/79 10/5/79 ..., en 8/3/79 QJ - _ ,_ 6/7/74 co ...... 1,0 en 0 -: _.. 5/3/74 7/6/79 3/1/74 '""4/5/74 ~ s.. a, 0 .0 u +J 5/4/79 4/6/79 10/6/78 12/1/78 11/3/78 3/2/79 - 10/5/73 - 9/7/73 '- 8/3/73 7/6/73 ,-i - 12/7/73 0 6/1/79 . - .-f -7/5/74 : 1...8/2/74 -9/6/74 10/4/74 en • 8/1/80 0 5/2/75 0 . 7/3/80 0 4/4/75 11"1 ,-i • 6/5/80 0 N 3/7/75 N 5/2/80 0 M 2/7 /75 0 co M . an. . an. . . . an. 2/2/79 -1/5/79 0 ~ -11/2/73 - 1/4/74 : : - 2/1/74 0 ,,, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis I I 0 I/'\ -.:I" Q) ~ ;::I co ~ "" .-I .-I r:Q "" ~ >, ;:I {I) ...... I/'\ 0\ ,-f . ca Q) ~ ...... N E-1 - ;:I Q) ,1-1 i:: .= :s ,-f >, . ...... . ,-f C'I ...... C") .w 0 {I) .c:0 = ,1-1 {I) ca "" {I) P-4 =f "8 !'.:I ~ 0 4-1 ca "Ce Q) ~ i:i. Cl) {I) ~ '1 "C r:Q "" 0 • C") I/'\ C") N I/'\ 0 N -- ~~ I/'\ 0 r-4 - ~ ~ r-4 0 - -- - -- r. ~- I.fl 0 . . . . . . . . -.;t -- - J 0 7/4/75 6/6/75 5/2/75 4/4/75 3/7/75 2/7/75 1/3/75 12/6/74 11/1/74 10/4/74 9/6/74 • 8/2/74 7/5/74 6/7/74 5/3/74 • 4/5/74 . 3/1/74 2/1/74 1/4/74 12/7/73 11/2/73 10/5/73 9/7 /73 8/3/73 . 7/6/73 0 en co ..-4 . U) N s.. a, ia, a, a. +> V) 0 +> 00 "' en . ..-4 '°s.. C1J ..., .0 0 u 0 0 . ~ - - -- - M 0 11"1 N 0 N . . . . C") I.fl : - . r-4 I.fl -~--~-- - ~~ - - -- r-4 0 - 0 I/'\ ~ - - - - - - - 0 . 10/3/80 9/5/80 8/1/80 7/3/80 6/5/80 5/2/80 4/4/80 3/7/80 2/1/80 1/4/80 12/7/79 11/2/79 10/5/79 9/7/79 8/3/79 7/6/79 6/1/79 S/4/79 4/6/79 3/2/79 2/2/79 l/S/19 12/1/78 11/8/78 10/6/78 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -51- following the introduction of the reserves~targeti~g procedures, the bid-ask spread rose to 10 basis points,around which it has continued to vary ever since. The bid-ask spread on the 52-week bill, and presumably on other bills as well, followed essentially the same pattern, as that for the three-month bill, widening in the early part of October 1979. A similar response to the introduction of the new procedure was not apparent on Treasury coupon issues. For example, Figure 5 shows for a five-year note the Wednesday quotations of Discount Corporation, which are published in the Money Manager. at 4/32nds. In the earlier period the spread stood By 1978 it had risen to 8/32nds. Two months before the introduction of the new procedure it rose to 32/32nds and generally has remained there over the past year~ at face value. Perhaps this result should not be taken As was mentioned above, it is well known that list-price quotations do not always accurately reflect the actual prices at which transactions occur. Also, ,there were this past year a fair number-of qualitative reports that bid-ask spreads did widen in the coupon market after the intro~uction,of the new OP.erat1ng procedures. il ~ ,..tt~~{:!-1 ➔-I,,-..,-. ~ _.,. 1 ... _ ~ C:. li,-',.1 l <--l ..... ... - >-~-r'T' ,<,1.t,.,~J .tl>-'11't -,, It may be that the widening of bidr~ ~~ ~:!" ..., " ~-- :, .J "" .... ,,.. .,. .. 1:1 .... ~l-"' ... ask spreads just before October 1979 would have been a temporary phenomenon, but that the heightened variability of rates that has emerged sustained the increase in spreads. More volatile rates also have been associated with an apparent increase in what may be called the "implicit" underwriting premium that the market extracts from the Treasury for the distribution of a new issue. Such a concession may be said to exist if the auction price of a Treasury security is lower than the prevailing market price of comparable securities. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis This I N I L/"'j U"'I Q) ~ ::s Q) .µ ~ --, '~ c' .-,, - ~ ~ I>, ::, - U') -,Ol " "N -~ . 11) 'Q)° ~,... E-4 .µ s:: tll 0 ~-,-4 r:, C: QJ tll '- ~ ('f') ~ "Ol . :::, - r:, -: - - -'°>, ' - : 0 - :::, 11-1 ~~ I L/"'j 0, ~.o 'l-l'i:o OD fz-4 -,-4 cw, ~...., "0 "0 i:: tUN Q) ~ ti) ~ l:IJ 1 -,-4 't, i::1:1 r - i 0 ..;t i I ID C""'I N I"") N CX) N ..;t ,-j '° ,-j N - - - - - - - -- - -- 0 N .... ~ i,,i,.1,, ~ ..::I" .,1,:1.- CX) -1-> ' 7/4/75 6/6/75 -~ '...,__ . N 00 ..;t 0 10/3/80 9/5/80 6l?/80 -- 5/2/80 u ,-j - ·' 12/1/78 ' 1{5/79 3/2/79 2/2/79' 4/6/79 5/!+/79 6/1/79 7/6/79 - 8/3/79 - 9/_7 /79 10/5/79 - 11/2/79 12/7 /79 1/4/80 2/1/80 3/7/80 2/7 /75 Cl' . r-4 N '° QJ S- E QJ .0 C. ~ QJ Vl 0 ~ 00 ~ "Ol . '° QJ S- .0 0 ~ 0 N 11/3/78 -:: 4/4/80 3/7/15 - 8/1/80 ..-4 ID 5/2/75 ,, N 0 1/3/80- ..;t 4/4/75 ,; 0 OJ, N 00 - 1/3/75 ' 12/6/74 ' 11/1/74 10/4/74 ,, 9/6/74 8/2/74 "" 7/5/74 6/7/74 5/3/74 - 4/5/74 ,.. 2/1/74 : ,- • ~/1/74 - - N C"l . 8/3/}3 C"l 10/6/78 - f 1/2}73 ~ - U4/74 • 12/7 /72 ~-- O"' ID '! :. ..;t ' 7/6/73 - .10/5{73 .- 9/7 /73 0 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -53spread would be expected to increase when interest rates become more volatile, as dealers seek compensation for the greater risk they assume in distributing Treasury issues. . The average implicit underwriting premium for the three-month Treasury bill before and after October 6, 1979, is shown in Figure 6 for both the bid and ask side of the market. Measurement of an implicit premium hinges on the choice of a comparable security whose price can be compared to the Monday auction price of the three-month Treasury bill. Three comparisons were made. One calculation used the just-issued three-month bill compared with its price observed at the market close on the Thursday prior to a Monday auction. The presumption is that this Thursday price is determined before mark~t participants have begun to be affected by the impending auction but close enough to that auction to assure comparability of other determinants of price. A second comparison used the clo\ing Monday price of the outstanding bill that has a maturity identical to that of the three-month bill being auctioned. The presumption is that.these are identical aecurities except that one has yet to be distributed and the other is already lodged in investors' portfolios. A third comparison was based on the Tuesday market price of the "when issued" three-month bill. The pre- sumption is that, with distribution under way, some of the tmderwriting premium will have been removed from price. In each of the three cases, the average implicit underwriting premium was higher after October 6, 1979, than before, measured on e-li.ther the bid or the ask side of the market. C. Underwriting Spreads on Corporate Bonds* A considerable body of empirical evidence has shown that underwriting spreads on both corporate and municipal securities are positively related to * The primary author of this section was Norman Mains of the Board staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -54Figure 6 ' IMPLICIT UNDERWRITING PREMIUMS IN 3-MONTH Bill AUCTIONS Mean Basis Point Spread from Auction Average Price 60 Weeks Before and After October 6, 1979 1 • Basis Points 30 25 After 20 + 15 10 + After 5 Before Before 0 • • -5 -10 -15 -20 -25 Thursday Prior to Auct1ona Mondayb Auction Tuesday Following Auct1onc (+) Mean spread ask price minus auction average price Each mean spread "after" Is s1gnif1cantly d 1fferent from "before" (95%) (•) Mean spread bid price minus auction average price Each mean spread "after" Is s1gmflcantly different from "before" (95%) except for Monday auction 1 a b c Introduction of FOMC New Operating Procedure Based on closing quotations for 3-month bill auctioned 3 days earlier Based on closing quotations for 6-month bill with same maturity as 3-month bill auctioned on that day Based on closing quotations for 3-month bill auctioned the previous day https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -55the "riskiness" of the securities. For example, studies have demonstrated that the underwriting spread for a longer-term corporate or municipal security offering is positively correlated with the rating awarded the issue by the recognized rating agencies such as Moody's or Standard & Poor's. Other studies have attempted to explain differences in underwriting spreads by postulating additional variables associated with the underwriting community's perception of risk at the time of the offering. 1 In this tradition, this section examines whether the increased volatility of interest ratesthis past year has been associated with a ~idening of underwriting spreads on corporate bond issues. Data on underwriting spreads for all publicly offered, nonconvertible corporate rtotes and bonds were assembled for the 18-month period beginning Aprill, 1979, and ending September 30, 1980, The bond ratings and initial maturities also were tabulated. 2 Over the entire 18-month period, data on underwriting spread, rating, and original maturity were available for 411 issues. On average, these public offerings of notes and bonds carried an underwriting sp~~ad of $10.79 per $~~~00.~o~d_(tabl~ 20). As expected, the underwriting spread tended to be larger on lower-rated issues. The average underwriting spread for the 117 issues publicly offered between April 1, 1979, and September 30, 1979, was $11.47 per issue. The average spread for the 294 issues publicly offered between October 1, 1979, and September 30, 1980,was $10.53 per issue, or $0.94 ~ than the average under- writing spread in the preceding six-months, A disaggregation of the issues by 1. For example, L.H. Ederington, '*Uncertainty, Competition, and Costs in Corporate Bond Underwriting," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 2 (March 1975), pp. 71-94, presented evidence showing an inverse relationship between the number of bids and the underwriting spreads on competitively bid issues. Ederington concluded that the ntnnber of bids was a measure of corporate bond underwriters' undertainty about the near-term outlook for interest rates. 2. Issues were classified according to the ratings assigned by Moody's Investor Services. For those issues not rated by Moody's, the bond rating of Standard & Poor's was used. -56- Table 20 Underwriting Spreads, by Bond Rating Bond rating£_7 Aaa & Aa No. Av. spread Baa & helow Av. spread Period All issues No. Av. spread 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 117 $11.47 47 $7.11 38 $8.61 32 $21.26 10/1/7g to 9/30/80 294 $10.53 109 $7.38 126 $8.61 59 $20.44 Hl.J79 ,to 9/3q/8o 411 $10. 79 _ .. 156 $7.30 164 $8.61 91 $20.72 'J:./ Issues classified by Moody's bond ratings. issues not rated by Moody's. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis No. A Av. spread No. Standard & Poor's ratings used for those -57ratings shows, however, that those rated Aaa and Aa had an average underwriting spread of $7.38 per issue over the more recent 12-month period versus $7.11 per issue for the earlier period, issues rated A averaged $8.61 per issue for both periods, while the issues rated Baa and below averaged $20.44 per issue in the more recent 12-month period versus $21.26 for the issues offered in the earlier 6-month period. These data show that, in the aggregate, underwriting spreads have not widened since the Desk implemented the new procedures. Instead, the data indicate that underwriting spreads narrowed somewhat, with this result due entirely to a narrowing of spread for issues rated Baa and below. State public utility commissions typically require regulated utilities to sell their debt obligations via competitive biddings, while most other businesses, such as industrial and financial concerns, usually sell their debt securities through investment banking organizations. It is possible that the underwriting process may have had an influence on the recent movements in underwriting spreads. Disaggregating the data into four maJor industry cate- gories shows that underwriting spreads have widened in the more recent period for corporations that tend to conduct their longer-term debt offerings via competitive bidding (Table 21). The average underwriting spreads both for electric and gas utilities and tor telephone companies have widened in recent months. Moreover, this result remains for each subcategory when the issues are grouped by their respective ratings. In the case of negotiated offerings, however, the average underwriting spreads for both industrial and financial corporations declined in the more recent 12-month period. One possible explanation for this narrowing of underwriting spreads may be related to the unprecedented decline in longer- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Table 21 Underwriting Spreads, by Bond Rating and Industry Industry group & ~riod E&G Utilities Telephone cos. Industrials All issues No. Av. seread Aaa & Aa No. Av. SEread Bond rating=. A ~o. Av. SEread No. Baa & below Av. s:eread 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 35 93 11 28 $6.51 $7.60 14 Li.3 $ 7.76 $ 8.84 $ 8.13 1() 22 $ 9.88 $11.81 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 7 33 $ 7.08 $10.17 4 16 $6.24 $7.88 3 16 S 8.20 $12.55 1 $ 8.75 $ 7.97 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 38 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 $16.58 11 107 $13. 20 27 $7.87 $7.81 11 51 $ 9.32 $ 8.09 16 29 $27.22 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 37 El $10.35 $ 8.58 21 38 $7.20 $6.70 10 16 $ Q.15 $ 7.5R 6 7 $23.38 $21.10 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 117 294 $11.47 $10.53 47 109 $7.11 $7.38 38 126 $ 8.61 $ 8.61 32 59 $21.26 $20.44 $27.57· I lJl 00 I Financial tos. All issues 1/ Issues classified by Moody's bond ratings. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Standard & Poor's ratings used for those issues not rated hy Moody's. -59term yields that occurred in the second quarter of 1980. This sharp decline elicited a record amount of note and bond financing by industrial corporations and a sharp increase in financings by financial'concerns. Corporate bond underwriters may have been willing to narrow their spreads if they·perceived that their risks were reduced in this market environment. the underwriting spread data supports this hypothesis. A disaggregation of For all issues, the average underwriting spread was $9.15 per issue in the second quarter of 1980 versus $11.55 per issue in the other three quarters subsequent to October 6, 1979 (Table 22). However, the average underwriting spread for both industrial and financial issues for the 12-month period excluding 1980Q2 is still less than the average underwriting spreads in the 6-month period prior to the adoption of the nonborrowed-reserves strategy. One other possible explanation for the recent narrowing of underwriting spreads for negotiated issues is a shift in the original maturities of the financings. Corporate bond underwriters traditionally charge their clients a smaller underwriting fee for short-term financings. Thus, the narrowing in average underwriting spreads for industrial and financial issues since October 1979 may reflect a reduction in the average maturity of offerings during the period. This hypothesis was tested by a further disaggregation of the underwriting spreads by initial maturity for both the industrial and financial issues (Tables 23 and 24). It was generally found that the disaggre- gation on the basis of maturity still showed a narrowing of spreads this past year, particularly on note offerings. It is interesting to note that for ' issues with original maturities of 20 years or more the underwriting spreads ' were about the same before and after October 6, 1979. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis In th~ case of note Table 22 Underwriting Spreads, by Bond Rating and Industry Industry group All issues Av. s:eread No. & J2!riod E&G utilities Telephone cos. Industrials Financial cos. All issues !! 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80: Excluding 1980 Q2 19801 Q2 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80: Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q.2 Bond ratinP.I7 A No. Av. spread No. Baa & below Av. soread 35 $ 7.97 11 $6.51 14 $ 7.76 10 $ 9.88 71 22 $ 8.94 $ 8.51 22 6 $7.56 $7.76 31 12 $ 7.91 $ 8.70 18 4 $12.42 $ 9.07 7 $ 7.08 4 $6.24 3 $ 8.20 21 12 $11.07 $ 8.60 10 $7.58 $8.38 11 $14.24 $ 8.84 1 $ 8.75 6 5 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80: Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q,2 38 $16.58 11 $7.87 11 $ 9.32 16 $27.57 51 56 $16.58 $10.12 , 13 14 $7.51 $8.09 21 30 $ 7.98 $ R.17 17 12 $31.54 $17.38 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80: Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q2 37 $10.35 21 $7.20 10 $ 9.15 6 $23.38 26 35 $ 9.09 $ 8.20 14 24 $6.55 $6.79 9 7 $ 7.87 $ 7.21 3 4 $24.7'3 $18.38 117 $11.47 47 $7.11 38 $ 8.H 32 $21.26 169 125 $11.55 $ 9.15 59 50 $7.31 $7.46 72 54 $ 8.90 $ 8. 2'3 38 21 $22.92 $15.95 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80: Excluding 1980' Q2 1980' Q2 Issues classified by Moody's bond ratin~s. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Aaa & Aa No. Av. s:eread Standard & Poor's ratings used for those issues not rated by Moody's. I 0 °' I Table 23 Underwriting Spreads for Industrial Bonds, by Maturity and Rating Maturity period & 20 years or more 4/1/79 to 9130/JCJ 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Memo 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q2 Less than 20 years 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Memo 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q2 All issues No. Av. spread Aaa & Aa No. Av. spread No. Baa & below Av. spread $9.97 $9.28 12 25 $26.52 $26.46 16 $0,03 $9.45 17 8 $2Q,34 $20.35 $8.57 $7.16 3 24 $7.60 $6.38 4 7 $30.74 $18.29 $7.60 $6.82 10 $5.93 $6.70 3 14 4 $22.84 $14.88 26 63 $17.32 $16.00 11 $8.71 $8.75 34 29 $19.lli $12.34 6 5 $8.75 $8.75 11 12 47 $15.72 $ 8.42 5 16 20 27 $ 9.05 $ 7.95 7 9 8 27 I 1/ Issues classified by Moody's bond ratings. by Moody's. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 6 Bond rating::,: A Av. Spread No. Standard & Poor's ratings used for those issues not rated °'I-'I Table 24 Underwriting Spreads fo~ Financial Bonds, by Maturity and Rating Bond Rating=:c Maturity & Period 20 years or more: 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Memo: 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Excluding 1980 Q2 1980 Q2 Less than 20 years: 4/1/79 to 9/30/79 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Memo· 10/1/79 to 9/30/80 Excluding 1980 ~2 1980 Q2 All issues No. Av. Spread 15 23 Aaa & Aa No. Av. Spreacl A Av. Spread No. Baa & below Av. Spread $10.80 6 11 $8.75 $8.59 5 6 $8.50 $8.75 4 $12.40 6 $16.75 $23.04 4 7 $8.12 $8.86 4 $8.75 $8.75 3 $34.91 12 $15.92 $ 9 .42 3 $11.17 22 38 $ a.n $ 6.27 15 27 $6.58 $5.92 10 $9.130 $6.88 2 1 $24.13 $ 9.50 16 22 $ 6.51 $ 6.09 10 17 $5.89 $5.94 5 5 $7.16 $6.60 1 $ 9.50 11 1/ Issues classified by Moody's bond ratine;s. by Moody's. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis No. 2 5 Standard & Poor's ratings used for those issues not rated I °' N I -63- ,_ offerings--issues with original maturity of less than 20 years--the data indicate a narrowing of spreads even when the issues are cross-classified by rating. D. Reactions in Mortgage Markets to Increased Rate Volatility* Announcement effects. Immediately following the Federal Reserve policy announcements in October 1979, a number of mortgage lenders shut down or severely reduced their fonzard commitment activity because of heightened uncertainty about the course of market interest rates and flows of loanable funds. A special survey of large savings and loan associations conducted by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board, for example, indicated that a fourth of the institutions ceased making any new commitments between October 6 and month-end, and that an additional 50 percent ceased making mortgage connnitments for certain classes of loans or borrowers. During the next few months, these associations gradually reopened their commitment windows or broadened the types of commitments being made, despite highly variable interest rates and a marked slowing of peposit flows; by mid-January 1980, only 7 percent of surveyed associations indicated that they were making no new connnitments at all. Although market conditions have settled down considerably, various participants have made adjustments to their commitment and investment policies since late last year, particularly in the case of long-term or "permanent" mortgage financing. Mortgage originators/bankers. Among mortgage market participants, mortgage bankers are susceptible to the greatest damage, relative to capital positions, from increased short-term variability in market interest rates. Indeed, the increased rate variability during the past year apparently has prompted some mergers of mortgage companies and acquisitions of smaller ones * https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The primary author of this section was David Seiders of the Board staff. -64- by larger ones. It might also be expected that the remaining institutions would attempt co shift more of their interest rate risks--associated with the issuance of forward commitments to borrowers and the carrying of mortgage inventories--forward to the borrowers, down the line to investors or dealers in passthrough securities, or to speculators in futures markets who seek to profit by bearing risk but do not intend to acquire the mortgage instruments. Mortgage bankers could minimize the size of their mortgage inventories or secure investor purchase commitments to cover larger portions of inventories held and outstanding connnitments made to borrowers. However, neither type of adJustment has been striking for the industry as a whole. The size of mortgage banker inventories has fallen substantially since September 1979, but the ratio of inventory to current origination activity has declined only moderately (Table 25). Moreover, the coverage ratio for mortgage bankers--outstanding long-term commitments received from investors (including FNMA and the GNMA securities dealers) divided by the sum of mortgage inventory and outstanding long-term commitments issued to borrowers--has changed little, on balance, since the fall of 1979. Nor does it appear that mortgage bankers have substantially increased their use of the GNMA futures market in order to hedge interest rate risks incurred during the mortgage origination/marketing process. Mortgage banker activity in the GNMA futures market has been quite limited since the creation of the market in 1975, for a number of reasons. For one thing, the delivery provisions of the maJor GNMA futures contract are rather cumbersome, calling for delivery of a Collateralized Depository Receipt or 11 due bill 11 that provides a claim on a pool of GNMA securities rather than the securities themselves. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -65- TABLE 25 Mortgage Company Inventory and Commitment Positions Long-term mortgage investor Ratio to current originations Commitment coverage ratio 1 {percent) Home Total lllortgages mortgages Period Amount ($millions) 1979-Jan. Feb. Mar. 8,750 9,500 8,640 1.99 71 2.36 2.57 66 67 85 79 79 Apr. May June 7,880 8,820 2.29 2.71 2.92 67 64 67 80 79 77 July Aug. Sept. 9,620 10,970 11,380 2.81 2.95 2.99 56 53 ,57 85 65 68 Oct. Nov. Dec. 10,620 2.84 9,920 8,960 2.88 2.95 60 61 63 73 79 80 1980-Jan. Feb. Mar. 8,500 8,080 6,310 3.00 2.79 2.06 59 64 75 74 80 89 Apr. nay June 5,800 5,760 5,680 2.49 2.35 2.11 74 5g 61 92 80 R3 July Aug. Sept. p 9,260 7,560 8,440 3.14 2.so 2. 78 63 58 73 RO 84 8,820 68 1. Outstanding long-term commitments received from investors divided by the sum of mortgage inventory and long-term commitments issued to borrowers. Source: Mortgage Bankers Association of America. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -66Moreover, the futures market requires posting of an initial margin and then maintenance of a specified margin. It appears that mortgage bankers, and some other originators, have attempted to shift some of the increased risk incurred during the mortgage commitment period primarily to mortgage borrowers, rather than to mortgage investors or to speculators. While comprehensive data are not available, field reports conducted regularly by FNMA and HUD have noted increased reluctance by mortgage originators to issue the standard long-term fixed-rate optional-takedown commitment to prospective borrowers. Adjustments generally have involved imposition of larger nonrefundable commitment fees to discourage cancellations of commitments by borrowers when market rates fall, shortening of periods over which fixed interest rates on conventional loans or fixed nlllllbers of points on FHA/VA loans will be guaranteed, or use of floating rates and discount points tied to some visible market indicators--such as the average yield determined in FHLMC's auctions of immediate-delivery purchase commitments. Of course, the extent to which mortgage originators can shift commitment-period interest rate risk to borrowers, or the cost of such risk shifting, will depend upon the state of competition in local mortgage markets. HUD surveys have noted significant declines in mortgage volume at some mortgage bankers>who have attempted to discontinue issuance of fixed-rate commitments. It does not appear that mortgage originators have sought to shorten the total length of the commitment period (in contrast to the fixed-rate portion), probably because this period is determined largely by the tl.Ille lags inherent in the real estate construction and sales process. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Available data -67for thrift institutions and life insurance companies (Table 26) indicate that the maturity distributions of mortgage commitments outstanding at these institutions have not changed appreciably since the fall of 1979 despite substantial declines in new commitment activity. GNMA securities dealers. FNMA. and FHLMC. Dealers who have made forward markets in GNMAs have found it difficult to contend with the increase in rate volatility. A number of dealers have left this market largely because of the increased capital risks, and the roster of prominent market makers has dwindled to a handful. Margin requirements have become more common at the large dealers that now dominate the market, as these dealers have sought to minimize their credit risks in the wake of some reneges on the standard "firm" or "mandatory" delivery forward contracts. Moreover, the dealers apparently have been hedging more of their interest rate risks, associated with inventory positions and uncovered commitments, in the GNMA futures markets. Bid-asked price spreads also have widened somewhat at the major dealers, apparently because of the increase in risk and possibly some erosion of competition in the dealer market for GNMAs. The bid-asked spread on new and recent issues of GNMAs generally has widened from 1/8 to 1/4 percentage point since the fall of 1979. Heightened interest rate uncertainty has made both the GNMA dealers and FNMA reluctant to issue long-term fixed-rate standby commitments, compounding the problem faced by mortgage originators/sellers. Such commitments have become unavailable or quite expensive at the GNMA dealers during the past year, reflecting the reluctance of private investors to enter into standby arrangements and the unwillingness of dealers to absorb credit risks on these contracts. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Around the end of 1980, moreover, FNMA made substantial changes to TABLE 26 Maturity Distribution of Outstanding Mortgage Connni tmen ts at Thrift Institutions and Life Insurance Companies (Percent scheduled to be taken down within the number of months indicated) Period 1 Insured savings and loans 3 months 6 months 12 months 2 NY State mutual savings banks 3 months 6 months 9 months Life insurance companies 3 6 months 12 months 1979 Jan. Feb. Mar. 61.0 62.1 64.0 79.5 79.7 80.6 93.8 93.8 94 .2 38.5 40.0 42.4 61.2 60.8 63.8 74.0 73.0 76.3 33.1 34.0 33.7 59.3 59.4 58.4 Apr. May June 63.9 64.2 62.9 79.9 80.8 80.1 93.8, 94.3 93.8 41.1 40.2 41.4 61.5 60.0 65.2 74.7 76.2 78.4 34.9 37 .4 37.1 61.3 61.2 63.3 July Aug. Sept. 62.2 62.1 62.2 79.8 78.8 78.4 93.6 93.1 92 .9 41.4 ,40.6 46.6 65.2 63.9 68.2 78.4 79.0 80.2 37 .9 35.7 37.9 64.0 63.0 62.1 Oct. Nov. Dec. 59.6 54.8 52.2 76.2 73.5 72.1 92.3 91.3 89.6 44.2 43.5 44.7 67.0 66.3 63.S 78.0 78.7 76.1 39.5 38.0 34.0 61.7 61.6 57.9 1980 Jan. Feb. Mar. 52.4 54.1 52.4 71.7 72.3 70.6 89.9 90.2 89.2 44.0 44.6 46.5 64.3 68.6 67.8 75.4 79.6 80.4 37.4 36.6 37.2 62.4 62.5 64.2 Apr. May June 48.7 48.3 53.6 68.2 68.4 72.0 89.9 90.4 90.9 45.0 44.1 41.5 64.9 62.6 64.2 77.7 76.8 73.4 35.4 36.7 35.8 60.4 60.6 60.1 July Aug. Sept. 59.1 60.7 61.2 76.2 77.2 78.0 92 .1 91.8 92 .2 43.9 47.9 53.8 65.5 66.7 67.4 76.9 77 .6 79.4 36.2 37.4 60.4 60.6 Oct. 58.6 76.6 92.0 f I 1. Insured S&Ls account for about 98 percent of the total assets of all operating S&Ls. 2. NY State mutuals account . for about 55 percent of the total assets of all operating mutual savings banks. 3. Reporting life companies account for about three-fourths of the total assets of the life insurance ipdustryr https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis a- 00 I -69its connnitment programs in order to reduce its exposure to rate variations . . The four-month optional-delivery purchase connnitments issued by FNMA through its biweekly Free Market System auctions now guarantee a mortgage rate for two months rather than four. In addition, the fixed-rate twelve-month standby program has been terminated, and longer-term convertible standby connnitments issued by FNMA are now subject to rate adjustment every two months. FNMA also increased the fees charged successful bidders in the biweekly auctions of optional-delivery purchase commitments, from 5/8 to 3/4 of 1 percent of the connnitment amount (effective January 19, 1981), and FNMA apparently raised its yield requirements to some degree during the past year. FNMA can exert a limited degree of control over the average yield on accepted bids by varying the proportion that are accepted. Th.is proportion was unusually low during the last quarter of 1979 and the first half of 1980 but returned 1 to its historical average in the latter half of the year. The lower proportions accepted in the three previous quarters reflected efforts by FNMA to boost sagging net earnings and apparently had little to do with increased short-run rate variability, per se. Mortgage investors. Traditional mortgage investors, including FNMA, have shown increased interest in shorter-term mortgage contracts, or contracts providing for equity participations, during the past year. Thu~ increased rate volatility has reinforced the desires of investors to move away from assumable fixed-rate, long-term mortgage assets--desires that had developed as 1. At FHLMC (which quickly resells most loans that it purchases), the proportion of bids accepted in its commitment auctions has not changed markedly during the past year, and commitment fees have not been raised. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -70- it became evident that expectations of short-term rate movements embodied in long-term mortgage rates agreed to in past years had been biased downward. Rate volatility has stimulated regulatory actions to permit thrift institutions and connnercial banks to offer variable-rate and renegotiablerate home loans as well as contracts that permit lenders to share in the price appreciation of mortgaged homes. 1 Thrift institutions have been aggressively marketing adjustable-rate mortgages in some areas of the country. A special survey conducted in September 1980 by the U.S. League of Savings Associations indicated that nearly one-third of all S&Ls were offering renegotiable-r~te loans. Moreover, many major life insurance companies recently have been requiring some form of equity participation when granting long-term incomeproperty mortgages. This practice has reemerged despite a rather checkered experience by life companies with equity participations during the late 1960s and early 1970s. FNMA has been considering programs for the purchase of adjustablerate mortgages, but has not as yet instituted such programs. FNMA has taken steps, however, to limit the assumability of the fixed-rate conventional loans it purchases in order to reduce its term-structure risks. For both FHA/VA and conventional loans sold to FNMA under commitments issued after November 10, 1980, assumptions will be permitted only after the rates on the loans have been adjusted to current market levels--except in 17 states where due-on-sale 1. In April 1980, federal S&Ls were empowered to acquire renegotiable-rate mortgages, and in September the FHLBB issued proposed regulations concerning graduated-payment adjustable-rate mortgages as well as shared-appreciation mortgages. Also in September, the Comptroller of the Currency issued proposed regulations that would authorize all national banks to offer adjustable-rate home mortgages (state law had posed restrictions in a number of areas). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -71provisions are prohibited. In those states where FNMA's new assumption policy cannot be fully implemented, FNMA will reserve the option to call conventional loans due and payable-in-full seven years from the date of origination. The value of prepayment privileges provided to mortgage borrowers naturally increases when mortgage rates become more volatile, since the likelihood of profitable refinancing is greater. Even so, most lenders apparently have not attempted to impose larger prepayment charges in order to discourage borrowers from exercising this option. Prepayment penalties may not be charged on F'HA/VA loans, prepayment charges on conventional loans made by federal S&Ls are fixed by regulation, 1 and several states have outlawed penalties or set maximums that apply to all types of lenders. The changing environment in mortgage markets may have had some effects on the level of mortgage interest rates and on the relationship between mortgage and other long-term yields. Aggressive marketing of adjustable:rate loans has placed some downward pressure on yields for this type of instrument and upward pressure on yields for the traditional fixed-rate contract. Mort- gage borrowers apparently prefer long-term fixed-rate contracts when the interest rate outlook is highly uncertain, even if the relationship between the long-term mortgage rate and the initial rate on adjustable-rate contracts is in line with the prevailing term structure. Correspondingly, field reports and trade sources indicate that S&Ls generally have been offering renegotiablerate loans at interest rates ordinarily 1/2 to 1 percentage point below going rates on fixed-rate loans even though the yield curve has been flat or inverted in the relevant range. 1. Up to 20 percent of the original loan balance may be prepaid without penalty during any 12-month period, and the penalty for prepayments in excess of 20 percent cannot exceed 6 months' interest (at the original contract interest rate) on the excess amount. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -72E. Commercial Bank Response to Rate Volatility* There are· several courses commercial banks might have followed in response to the October 1979 change in operating procedures, depending upon both their assessment of its contribution to interest rate risk and their risk preferences. Dn the one hand, if banks believed that the change in operating procedureswould increase very-short-run interest rate volatility but would not materially affect cyclical or secular interest rate movements, their response might be slight, since profits from rate movements on one day would be cancelled by losses on another day. On the other hand, if banks believed that the new operating proceduresalso would amplify cyclical or secular interest rate movements, they might alter their fundamental balance sheet positions. Banks seeking to avoid additional risk and believing their long-run portfolio-funding strategy before October 1979 provided the optimum amount of interest risk exposure would move to keep that exposure constant, for example by closer matching of rate-sensitive assets and liabilities; more frequent adjustments in their administered interest rates; and, to the extent those actions did not bring them down to their desired interest risk exposure, the use of futures contracts to hedge the remaining undesired risk. Other banks might try to profit from the larger expected cyclical and secular rate movements by altering their portfolio-funding strategies--and perhaps increasing their trading activity--according to their interest rate forecasts. * The principal author of this section was Barbara Opper of the Board staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -73Conunercial bank activity was analyzed in an attempt to detect which of these possible courses banks have taken. Unambiguous conclusions did not ' emerge, in part because of data limitations and in part because of difficulties in interpreting the changes that were measurable. Some large banks, and virtually all small banks, were not completely in control of their balance sheet positioning since October 1979 because of the nature of the market conditions that have prevailed since that time. For most of that period, rate-sensitive claims were the only liabilities banks could market; asset turnover, particularly at consumer-oriented banks, was inadequate to fund acquisitions of enough rate-sensitive assets to balance the rapid shift in their liabilities. Rate-sensitive portfolio assets. Large banks typically have allo- cated a large share of their total assets to short-term assets and to longerterm instruments having floating rates. Smaller banks in the past only had a small portion of such rate-sensitive assets,,which was consistent with the composition of their liabilities (Figure 7). Since mid-1979, there appears to have been little change in the allocation of large banks' assets invested in rate-sensitive instrmnents. When small banks' liabilities began to become significantly more interest rate-sensitive after the mid-1978 introduction of the six-month money market certificate, they began to increase their portfolio allocations of interest-sensitive assets. One method they used was to increase the incidence of floating-rate provisions on longer-term business loan acquisitions (Table 27). Another was to increase, in proportion to asset growth, their sales of federal funds and their acquisitions of other short-term loans and investments. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Figure 7 Percentage of Assets Funded by Rate-Sensitive Liabilities and Invested in Rate-Sensitive Instruments/ Insured Commercial Banks, by Asset Sizel I ,- I 30 I I .,. -' I 10 0 1976 1978 30 30 INVESTED ✓ I ---------- I I 20 I INVESTED FUNDED $100 MILLION-$! BILLION $25-100 MILLION UNDER $25 MILLION 1980 .. ,, I INVESTED ______ FUNDED _._ ✓ ✓ FUNDED "' 10 ----------------1976 1978 20 20 19-80 10 0 -1976 - - - - - - -1978 - - - - - - -1980 --- 0 OTHER OVER $1 BILLION MONEY CENTER I 70 70 60 60 INVESTED __________ .,,,. FUNDED 50 50 INVESTED 40 ✓ ,I' ... ________ ., .,. ti' FUNDED 30 1976 1. ,I' 30 1978 1980 1976 1980 1978 Rate sensitive assets are interest-bearing deposits, federal funds sold, reverse RPs, loans and government debt maturing in one year or less, and other loans with floating rates. Small banks do not report the loan detail, so their holdings of loans to financial institutions, construction loans, and purpose loans are included. Rate-sensitive liabilities are large time deposits and foreign office deposits due in one . year or less, federal funds, RPs, MMCs,and other short-term borrowings. Last plot: September 1980. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ~ . -.J ~ I -75- Table 27 Percentage of Gross Business Loan Exte~sions Having Floating Rate Provisions!/ .!lli. - 1980 Q2 Q3 19-77 19.78 1979 Q4 Ql 48 large banks 73.0 64.4 79.2 86.5 80.3 85.0 80.2 86.8 Other 39.0 45.1 38.5 46.9 44.7 56.0 48.2 48.2 48 large banks 65.8 63.5 62.8 69.7 55.1 53.9 31.6 54.4 Other 39.2 48.4 37.4 35.6 44.7 35.8 41.7 43.9 Item g4 Lon,g-term Short-term Short-term, excluding below-prime loans 48 large 65.2 68.7 68.1 78.4 73.7 68.0 67.8 61.6 Other 37.0 52.6 44.1 46.0 55.1 33.3 42.1 47.1 1. Annual data are averages of survey weeks. The Survey of the Terms of Bank Lending is taken as of the first full week of the middle month of each quarter. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -76Asset pricing. Large banks since mid-1979 have moved toward more aggressive manipulation of their prime lending rate. They have taken more control over fluctuations in the prime rate, in effect achieving better management of the interest sensitivity of their prime loan portfolios. adjustment is depicted in Figure 8. That The upper panel of the chart shows the interest rate spread to a large bank that issues a 30-day CD to acquire a prime-rate loan. The bottom panel of the chart depicts the prime-rate dif- ferential over the effective interest rate on commercial paper. The long period of adherence to a relatively stable pricing formula is clearly indicated by the stability of these differentials from late 1975 through late 1979; the departure from that formula also is clear, beginning with the small but abrupt increase in the differentials in late 1979 and extending to the unprecedented peak reached in early 1980. That change in pricing should not be attributed entirely to attempts to manage loan portfolio interest risk exposure, however. The sharp early 1980 decline in domestic office business loan growth at commercial banks--middle panel of the chart--was clearly consistent with the growth constraints prescribed by the Special Credit Restraint Program and with the incentives for large business borrowers to use commercial paper as a far cheaper alternative to counnercial bank loans priced at the prime. Rate-sensitive liabilities. Large banks typically have relied relatively heavily on rate-sensitive liabilities for their funding (dashed lines in Figure 7). further. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Since mid-1979 that reliance has increased somewhat Thus, on balance, large banks shifted toward a position that Figure 8 Business Loan Growth at Domestic Offices of Commercial Banks and Prime Rate Spreads, ' PERCENTAGE 'FOINTS I I. PRJME MINUS RESERVE-ADJUSTED 30-DAY .c:--:----::--..-. m ~ 1\, i'-v"'II ::,~~,~~:_--""'~~,:'v-j\/_....-,::1 .---~ =======1.=========j::1:_1_70" I :1 l ~ RATES • ~-.,._____ - 8 .d 0 4 PERCENT, SAAR I 80 60 cx:MIBRCIAL AND INDUSTRIAL IDAN GROWIH I I ~/:~M~1·I I j' . , _ _ _ . _ _ _ . . . _ " - . _ _ ~ . . . _ _ _ . . _ _ ~ ' - - ' - - ' ' - - - - ' - - - - ' ' - - - J _ _ _ j- - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- 20 20 PERCENTAGE 'FOINTS ' I I PRIME MINUS CDM-1ERCIAL PAPER. RATES Latest Plot: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 8 0 1960 * Serves break 1964 1968 (January 1973). November 1980, excent loan arowth (October). 1972 1976 1980 I --.J --.J I 0 ' V "'J 40 -78- implied that they began to fund some longer-term or otherwise rate-insensitive 1 assets with rate-sensitive liabilities. While large banks' interest risk exposure appears to have increased as a result of the shift toward more ratesensitive liabilities, the change has been far more dramatic at smaller banks. Although acquisitions of rate-sensitive assets of small banks have increased substantially since mid-1979, their issuance of rate-sensitive liabilities was far more pronounced. Smaller banks now are financing a sharply increased frac- tion of longer-term, rate-insensitive assets with liabilities carrying short maturities and interest rates tied closely to the short-term markets. This apparent shift toward increased interest risk exposure seems to be largely a result of conditions that are not easily controlled by many of these institutions, particularly the smaller banks. Despite their sharp swings, market yields have remained comparatively high since October 1979. With the opportunity costs to depositors of holding demand deposits or fixed-ceiling savings and small time deposits consistently high, banks efperienced attrition in those deposits. These outflows were, offset primarily by issuing money market liabilities and floating-ceiling, small time deposits. Use of the futures market by banks. tn principle, banks could hedge an increase in interest risk exposure in the financial futures markets. Although a few large banks use futures contracts in this way, most do not. An 1. Large banks did not issue a stepped-up volume of floating-rate intermediateterm liabilities. In 1978, public issues amounting to $20 million or more totalled $200 million; in 1979, they totalled $2 billion, all of which was issued in the first half of the year; and in 1980 through Novembe~ they issued $250 million. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -79important~impediment to widespread use of financial futures contracts to hedge portfolio positions js the present accounting treatment required by bank regulators. Futures contracts must be carried at the lower of cost or market value; any difference in the carrying value from one accounting period to the next must flow through the income account. Consequently, an asymmetry exists because the portfolio assets and liabilities that the contract is designed to hedge are not carried 'at market value; gains or losses stemming from the portfolio-funding positions are not reported until they are realized. This accounting treatment does not affect the final reported profit or loss resulting when the portfolio position/hedging combination reaches its maturity. It potentially does introduce, however, more volatility to interim reported earnings--volatility that is directly a function of the market interest rate movements that the futures contracts are intended to offset. F. Developments in financial Futures Markets* The greater variability of interest rates might be expected to attract greater trading interest in financial futures markets from both speculators and hedgers. From the point of view of speculators, an increase in the volatilit~ of interest rates provides more opportunity for profit (and loss) for t~ose willing to bet on the future course of interest rates. At the same time,, for those holding positions in the cash market, more volatile interest rates create greater risk and, therefore, more reason to hedge those cash positions in the futures markets, 1 Financial futures markets have, 1. As a simple example of hedging, a government securities dealer with a large inventory of Treasury bills could protect itself against a rise in interest rates by taking a short position in the Treasury bill futures markets. If interest rates did rise, the resulting profit on the dealer's short position in the futures market would at least partially offset the loss on the dealer's long bill position in the cash market. * The principal author of this section was Leigh Ribble of the Board staff. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -80indeed, continued to prosper and grow over the past year. It is by no means clear, however, to what extent this growth may be attributed to the greater volatility of interest rates, especially given that these markets have enjoyed strong growth each year since their inception. As may be seen in Table 28, sales volume has increased over the past year for each of the three major financial futures contracts now being offered, with trading activity in one of them--the CBOT's Treasury bond futures contract--more than tripling over this period. Thes~ sales figures are con- sistent with reports from market participants that financial futures markets have been functioning quite well. According to participants, it usually has been possible to put large transactions through in the major financial futures markets without greatly affecting price, even at times when it was not possible to do so in the cash market for the corresponding instruments. Open interest--the total number of contracts outstanding that have not been offset by opposite futures transactions nor fulfilled by delivery-has grown at an extraordinary pace in the Treasury bond contract since October 1979,and has increased somewhat in the GNMA-CDR contract as well. In the Treasury bill contract, however, open interest declined over most of the same period, Market professionals are uncertain about,_ th~, reasons for the 1 decline. The decline began in mid-1979, before the recent large fluctuations in interest rates, and continued until this past September, reaching a low of about 22,000 contracts. By early December, however, open interest had rebounded to 45,000 contracts. 1. According to some, the contraction in open interest since mid-1979 reflected the exit of speculators who entered the market aggressively earlier in 1979 trying to profit from what they expected to be a cyclical peak in interest rates. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -81- Table 28 Sales Volume and Open Interest in Financial Futures (Monthly averages in billions of dollars) Period 3-month Treasury bill (IMM) 1979-Ql 4.3 Q2 Sales Volume GNMACDR delivery (CBOT) Open Interest Treasury bond (CBOT) 3-month Treasury bill (IMM) .4 5 54.4 6.3 4.3 7.3 .5 .7 59.6 6.7 5.2 Q3 8 6 .5 .9 46.1 7 .4 6.3 ~4 10.6 .8 1. 2 39.2 7.8 7.3 1980-Ql 12 3 .8 1 6 29 7 6 2 6.9 Q2 14 6 1.0 2 5 27.0 5 8 7 7 Q3 10 6 7 2.5 22.6 6.7 11 6 Oct. 11. 9 9 3 0 23 5 7 0 13. 7 N'1V, 16.0 1.2 4.0 32.4 9.3 18 2 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis GNMA- CDR delivery (CBOT) Treasury bond (CBOT) -82It is particularly difficult to gain a reliable impression of the growth in hedging activity in financial futures markets over the past year. According to both the available data and discussions with market participants, hedging activity has continued to grow since October 1979, although perhaps no more rapidly than speculative and arbitraging activity in these markets. The primary source of data in this area is the CFTC's Commitments• of Traders report, which shows the open interest of large reporting traders in futures markets on the last day_ of each month. 1 In this report, large traders classify their positions as either speculative or hedging. 2 Table 29 shows the hedging counnitments of large traders in both absolute terms and relative to total open interest in the three major financial futures markets. 3 According to these data, hedging commitments of large traders in the Treasury bond futures contracts have increased enormously in absolute terms over the past year. Total open interest in the bond contracts has grown at an even faster pace over this period than large-trader hedging commitments in the contract. The absolute increase in hedging appears consistent with market counnents that the Treasury bond contract increasingly is being used to hedge 1. Traders are required by the CFTC to report if they hold or control large positions in any one futures contract. In the case of financial .futures, a "large" position is now defined to be 25 contracts. 2. As an additional source of information, the CFTC made surveys of futures market participants on November 30, 1974 and March 20, 1979. The first survey classified traders as either speculators or hedgers. However, the second survey did not attempt to make this classification, because of what was felt to be the difficulty of doing so. 3. Total open interest is the total amount of either the short contracts or the long contracts, while commitments of large traders are the sum of both the short and long positions of those traders. As a result of this double,counting the proportions calculated in the last two columns of Table 2 could theoretically be as large as 200 percent. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Table 2 9 Hedging Corranitments of Large Traders in Selected Financial Futures Markets (Averages of end-of-month figures) l:ombine.d Hedging Commitments -Large Traders Total Open Interest -All Traders (in Quarter; 1978 $ billions) 1980 1979 . (in 1978 Combined Hedging Commitments as a % of Total Open Interest3_/ \in percent) 1980 1978 1979 -- $ billions) 1980 1979 3-month Treasury bill contract (IHM) I Ql Q2 Q3 Q4 32.0 53.2 27.9 26 0 22.5 53.5 60.2 42.3 38 0 I 5.7 10 5 u.s 16 5 21. 7 16 7 15 3 11. 5 7 9 7 9 18 20 31 36 40 40 41 30 35 64 43 53 51 44 33 39 42 39 58 66 76 72 65 66 74 54 52 Treasury bond contract (CBOT) I Ql Q2 Q3 Q4 1.3 3.5 4.4 5.4 6.5 7.7 6.5 8 9 11. 7 .8 1.5 2.4 2.8 2.8 2.5 2 5 3.8 4 6 GNMA -CDR contract (CBOT) Ql Q2 Q3 Q4 4.2 5.9 6 3 6 8 7.4 7.9 - 5.6 6 3 6.6 2.4 3.9 4.8 4.9 4.8 5.2 4 1 3 4 3 4 I 1 Sum of short and long commitments. 2. Figures could be as large as 200 percent because of the double counting of hedging commitments. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis I CX) I.,.) I -84cash positions in Treasury coupons as well as corporate bonds and other longterm instruments. Cross hedging in the Treasury bond futures markets reportedly is being used, both by those wishing to protect current holdings of corporate and other bonds and by firms that anticipate borrowing in the bond market some time in the future. 1 In the GNMA contract,large-trader hedging commitments declined substantially, both in absolute terms and relative to total open interest. the three-month bill contract, hedging activity also declined. In Compared to the falloff in total open interest in that market, however, large-trader hedging commitments declined only marginally in relative terms. Yet another source of information on the use of futures markets··vy hedgers is data collected since February 1980 by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on the positions taken in futures and forwards by primary government securities dealers. Although these data are not available for a long enough time to compare developments before and after October 1979, they make clear that the government securities dealers were making active use of the bill . futures market in 1980. As may be seen in Table 30, the dealers' bill-futures_ position (column 2) fell to a deep net short in April, rose steadily to a sub-stantial net long in the summer, and returned to a deep net short in late November. These movements were much greater than those in the dealers' cash positions in bills (column 1), suggesting that dealers have been using the futures markets as a vehicle for speculating as well as for hedging. 1. A firm planning to borrow in the corporate bond market several months hence could protect itself against a rise in bond yields by taking a short position in the Treasury bond futures market. If interest rates did rise, the firm's profit in the futures market would at least partially offset its loss in the cash market (that is, its higher borrowing costs). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -85Table 30 Dealer Positions in Treasury Bills (Par value in billions of dollars) 19_80 Cash Futures Forwards Net Feb. 29 1.8 -4.5 -.3 -3.1 Mar. 12 3.0 -3.7 -.3 -1.0 31 4.4 -7.4 -.3 -3.3 9 8.5 -8.6 -.2 - 30 8.0 -5.1 -.1 2.7 14 4.1 -1.6 -.3 2 2 30 3.9 .6 -.2 3.1 June 11 4.1 - .3 -.7 3.1 30 1.4 1. 2 -.1 2.5 9 3.8 2.4 -.2 6.1 31 5.5 2.5 * 7.9 Aug. 13 5.5 4.3 -.1 :} . 7 29 3.1 3.1 i': 6. 2 Sept.IO 4.8 2.0 -.1 6.7 30 3.8 .4 * 4.2 8 2.4 -1. 2 * 1.1 31 3.1 -1. 6 * 1.5 Nov. 12 3.7 -3.0 .7 1.4 28 3.2 -7.9 .8 -3.9 Apr. May July Oct. *Less than $50 million. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis . .3 I https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis IMPACT OF DISCOUNT POLICY PROCEDURES ON THE EFFECTIVENESS OF RESERVE TARGETING January 1981 Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Peter Keir CONTENTS I. II. INTRODUCTION A. Role of Window in Reserve Targeting .............. 2 B. Questions Addressed by Paper .................... 4 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS A. B. III. ~ffects on ~~isting Dis_count_ Policy on Reserve-Targeting Strategy ..... . 6 Alternative Approaches to Managing Discount Policy.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 IMPACT OF EXISTING DISCOUNT POLICY ON RESERVE TARGETING EXPERIENCE SINCE OCTOBER, 1979 A. Relat1on of Actual to Expected Levels of Borrowing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 1 Econometric test of borrowing relatLonship ... 17 B. Relation of Borrowing to !Rate Spreads............. . . . 20 C. Sources of Variability in the Borrowing Relationship. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 IV. D. How Well Has the Desk Coped with Deviations of Actual Borrowing from Expected Levels? .......... 26 E. 1980 Experience with a Discount Rate Surcharge ... 30 ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO THE MANAGEMENT OF DISCOUNT POLICY A. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Maintaining the Discount Rate Consistently at a Penalty. . . . . . . . . ........................ 39 1. The case for a penalty discount rate ........ 41 2. The case against a penalty discount rate ... 42 i CONTENTS Page B. C. Adop~1on of a Tied Discount Rate .. 45 1. The case for a tied rate. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 2. The case against a tied rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 Establishment of a Graduated Structure of 1. Specifics of~ a- graduated. discount rate p'lan .. 1•53 2. The case for a graduated d1scoul}t rate. ·.·-·. . . 58 3. The case against a graduated disc'ou:wt,,.,r,ate ... 60 Appendix A. _Aggregat·e B0rr6w1pg and Money 'MaTr.ket ltnterest' Rates 11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ••r••··· •••..•. Introduction Because the FOMC's shift to a reserve-targeting strategy places a higher premium than the earlier federal funds rate strategy on estimates of expected levels of borrowing at the discount window, the question has been raised whether traditional a~proaches to establishment of the discount rate and to administration of the discount window are sufficiently supportive of the reserve-targeting process. Although discount policy procedures were modified somewhat by the recent revision of Regulation A, Reserve Bank discount officers still rely pri~arily on broad administrative guidelines to control borrowing by individual institutions. As a result, there is still considerable looseness in the relationship of total borrowing to changes in the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate. Moreover, since the discount rate continues to be adJusted to changes in market rates on a Judgemental basis and typically with an appreciable lag, its spread against other rates tends to vary substantially as market rates fluctuate This paper attempts first to sort out how these features of discount policy have affected the reserve-targeting process over the past year. Note https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Then it considers whether alternative While responsibility for drafting this paper was assumed by Mr Keir, the paper draws heavily on, and quotes liberally from, a set of papers on this subJect prepared for the Board's Discount Policy Group by Messrs Paul Boltz and James O'Brien, Dana Johnson and John Spitzer, Perry Quick, and Ms Karen Johnson. These other authors should not be held responsible, however, for the summary conclusions reached. - 2 approaches to management of the discount rate and the discount window might be more supportive of the process. Role of Window in Reserve Targeting Under the old FOMC strategy of targeting day-to-day transactions on the federal funds rate, erratic fluctuations in the volume of borrowing at the discount window posed no significant problem for the System Account Manager. The magnitude of fluctuation in borrowing was generally moderate, and there was no operating need for precise forecasts of expected levels of borrowing. Desk operations sought simply to provide or absorb whatever nonborrowed reserves were needed to maintain the federal funds rate within the Committee~s desired range. The level of borrowing was viewed essentially as an incidential source of economic intelligence. UnQer the new reserve-targeting strategy, however, the role of borrowing has become more important. Implementation of the strategy starts with a forecast of expected borrowing derived 1n part from recent discount window experience. The staff then establishes the nonborr0wed reserve path, which (when added to this expected level of borrowing) will provide the total reserves thought,to be consistent with the Committee's money growth targets. As the period between FOMC meetings progresses, Desk operations seek to keep nonborrowed reserves on this specified path. Any tendency for total reserves to deviate from their https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 3 desired path is then reflected in borrowed reserves. The obJec- tive of forcing more or less borrowi~g pn the banking system is to press market interest rates in the direction needed to nudge growth of money and total reserves back toward their desired target paths in subsequent weeks. If deviations in demands for total and borrowed reserves appear to be large, compensating changes may be made in the path for nonborrowed reserves in order to accelerate the process of adJustment in interest rates and the monetary aggregates!/ The reserve-targeting process will tend to be more complicated if tne linkage between changes in borrowed reserves and market i11terest rates proves to be erratic or unreliable. Since the discount window is administered on a decentralized basis by 12 different discount officers using rather general operating guidelines, it would not be surprising if different users of the discount window developed somewhat different attitudes regarding the potential costs of additional borrowing at the Federal Reserve. To the extent actual borrowings reflect such differences of view, there is some room for looseness in the relationship between changes in borrowing and money market interest rates. !/ This reserve-targeting process is described in more detail in pages 6-11 of the companion paper of this series by Paul Meek and Fred Levin, 11 Implementinq the New Operating Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk. 11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 3 desired path is then reflected in borrowed reserves. The obJec- tive of forcing more or less borrowing on the,banking system is to press market interest rates in the direction needed to nudge growth of money and total reserves back toward their desired target paths in subsequent weeks If deviations in demands for total and borrowed reserves appear to be large, compensating changes may be made in the path for nonborrowed reserves in order to accelerate the process of adJustment in interest rates and the monetary aggregates!/ The reserve-targeting process will tend to be more complicated if t11e linkage between changes in borrowed reserves and market iriterest rates proves to be erratic or unreliable. Since the discount window is administered on a decentralized basis by 12 different discount officers using rather general operating guidelines, it would not be surprising if different users of the discount window developed somewhat different attitudes regarding the potential costs of additional borrowing at the Federal Reserve. To the extent actual borrowings reflect such differences of view, there 1s some -room for looseness in the relationship between changes 1n borrowing and money market interest rates. 1/ This reserve-targeting process is described in more detail in pages 6-11 of the companion paper of this series by Paul Meek and Fred Levin, 11 Impl ementin<1 the New Operating Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk. 11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 5 last spring, and most recently--in which the basic discount rate was supplemented by a discount rate surcharge. The second section of the paper then assesses the pros and cons of alternative discount policy procedures that might be substituted for the traditional approach. are considered Three general options The first would establish a single discount rate and maintain it consistently at a penalty above the federal funds rate The second would establish a single basic discount rate automatically by tyina it in a fixed spread relationship to a key market rate (most likely slightly below the federal funds rate) The third alternative would establish a graduated structure of discount rates, with a base rate below the federal funds rate, one or more steps above the base rate and a peak rate set at a penalty above the funds rate Quantitative limits would be established on the amount of borrowing permitted at each step below the federal funds rate, but there would be no limit (other than prudent lending standards) on the volume of borrowing at the top (or penalty) step. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Summary of Findings Effects of Existing Discount Policy on the Reserve-Targeting Strategy 1. Even before the introduction of reserv~ targeting, the volume of borrowed reserves--at given spreads of the federal funds rate over the discount rate--s'howed considerable variability. Since the shift to reserve targeting, the variability of this relationship has been accentuated, and the average propensity to borrow (at given rate spreads) seems to have increased somewhat. These changes in borrowing patterns appear to have been strongly influenced by the heightened interest rate volatility that has emerged in money and securities markets since the inauguration of reserve targeting. 2. Despite the frequently wider spreads of market rates over the discount rate since October 1979, the operating guidelines that discount officers use t'o administer access to the discount window seem to have continued working reasonably well. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis This has been particularly true for the largest banks whose use of the window, although often sizable in absolute dollar terms, is largely restricted to situations late in the day and at the end of a statement week when misses on estimates of their reserve needs and a temporary drying up of market sources of federal funds sometimes force them into the window. For midsized regional banks with deposits ranging around $1 billion there may have been some modest erosion in the effectiveness of the guidelines as the spread of market rates over the discount rate has widened But where active use of the window by such banks has developed, this seems to have been partly attributable to accommodative procedures developed prior to adoption of the reserve-targeting strategy when discount officers were especially sensitive to the fact that banks in this size category were weighing the pros and cons of abandoning membership in the System. - 7 3. When actual borrowed reserves have deviated significantly from expected borrowing, the FOMC Desk has managed to adJust to these changes reasonably well, through counterbalancing changes in nonborrowed reserves. Since the Desk staff monitor the factors accounting for such deviations regularly, there is leeway to adJust the target for nonborrowed reserves on a timely basis if such changes appear to be needed. For various policy reasons, however, weekly respecifications of reserve targets to allow for latest developments do not always seek to correct completely fon deviations in total reserves. 4. When actual growth patterns in money and total reserves have drifted off the FOMC's desired target paths and borrowed reserves have adJusted to compensate for the change, the response of market interest rates has sometimes been quite loose. Once the shift to a different average level of borrowed reserves has become clear, market interest rates have responded in the direction needed to initiate adJustments in growth of the aggregates. But the process of clarification has sometimes taken several weeks, and the magnitude of the rate responses to given changes in the level of borrowing have been stronger in some periods than others,l/ 5. Changes in the Federal Reserve discount rate are, of course, used to help reinforce the responsiveness of market interest rates to adJustments in reserve-targeting policy. If pursued too aggressively, however, such discount rate actions risk inducing an overcorrection in market interest rates. A discount rate surcharge was introduced on two occasions 1n 1980 in an effort to provide a clearer signal on policy intent, while at the same time inducing a more moderate response in market rates than might have developed from an across-the-board increase in the basic discount rate of the same size as the surcharge. 1/ The additional question whether the responses in interest rates that'did occur were sufficient to induce timely adJustments in bank lending policies is a broader issue not directly addressed by this paper. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 8 These obJectives of the surcharge approach appear to have been realized, although it is difficult to isolate the impact of each surcharge on market rates, since other factors affecting financial markets were so different in the two surcharge periods. Since the surcharge was applicable only to large banks, smaller commercial banks with minimal access to money market sources of funds were still able to borrow at the very favorable basic discount rate. In the future, to keep the effective cost of discount window credit in somewhat closer alignment for different types of instit~tions that are active users of the window, any use of the- surcharge may need t~ apply to smaller, as well as to large, institutions. Since smaller institutions would have no effective access to money market sources of funds, how~ver, criteria for the application of any such surcharge would have to be more liberal for them than for large institutions. 6. While the evident looseness in the linkage between changes in borrowed reserves and changes in interest rates has not negated the effectiveness of the reserve-targeting strategy, it has posed the question whether there are alternative means for managing discount policy that might be more supportive of the strategy. Alternative Approaches to the Management of Discount Policy 1. Maintaining the discount rate consistently at a penalty. Advantages This approach, by reducing borrowing to negligible levels, would make nonborrowed reserves virtually the same as total reserves and thus improve the Desk's ability to hit its target for t9tal reserves. Since a penalty rate approach would reduce the role of the discount window as a buffer for adJusting the reserve positions of individual banks, any change in bank demands for reserves relative to the volume of nonborrowed reserves being supplied through Desk open market operations would exert a significantly sharper reaction on market interest rates than is now the case. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 9 This would tend to induce quicker offsetting reactions in bank lending strategies and lead to more rapid general responses of deposit growth throughout the banking system. The penalty rate would also be an advantage over the current system if it were thought that it was desirable to reduce the subsidy to banks implicit in lending them reserves at below market rates. Disadvantages https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Under a penalty rate approach, if the volume of nonborrowed reserves being supplied by the Federal Reserve were to fall significantly short of the volume of tota+ reserves being demanded by the banking system--as might sometimes be the case--the federal funds rate would rise especially sharply. In fact, under the present system of lagged reserve accounting, if nonborrowed reserves proved to be insufficient to cover banks' required reserves, this discrepancy could be covered only at the discount window In such circumstances, the federal funds rate could be expected to rise to a level above the discount rate. Even temporary needs for reserves--arising from such things as Desk misestimates of other factors, computer breakdowns, or unanticipated demands for reserves against nonmonetary liabilities--could thus be strongly reflected in money market rates, even though they were unrelated to changes in basic money growth rates. Sharp interest rate responses to these strictly temporary needs for reserves would tend to be counterproductive. To the extent swings in market interest rates were exacerbated under a penalty rate system, this could &ake it more difficult for outsiders to Judge the obJectives of monetary policy. While resort to a penalty rate would tend to minimize borrowed reserves and hence the Committee's need to forecast expected levels of borrowing, changes 1n - ,10 - borrowed reserves could still be sizable at times. Moreover, new wider margins of error would very likely be introduced into staff estimates of excess reserves, since banks when forced to rely more completely on the federal funds market for back-up liquidity would be more likely to adJust their cushion of excess reserves as their concerns about possible near-term changes in market rates waxed and waned. 2. Adoption of a tied discount rate. Advantages A discount rate tied in a fixed relationship to some market rate (most likely at a spread slightly below the federal funds rate) would help to insulate the volume of borrowed reserves against changes in market interest rates. Borrowed reserves would thus become less accommodative of changes in the public's demand for money While (under the current system of lagged reserve accounting) there would be a technical problem if the discount rate were tied to an immediate measure of the federal funds rate--since this could produce an explosive interaction, with changes in the two rates feeding on each other--this potential difficulty could be modified by selecting a moderately backward-looking rate average as the tJe. The tied rate approach--by minimizing the spread of market rates over the discount rate--would also reduce the implicit subsidy that bank users of the discount window obtain when market rates rise relative to an inflexible discount rate Disadvantages https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis As under a penalty rate scheme, the key disadvantage of a discount rate closely tied to a market rate is that borrowed reserves would be less responsive--not Just to interest rate pressures arising from basic shifts in the public's demand for money (which ought not to be accommodated through the window), but also to rate pressures arising from strictly temporary deviations in reserve factors (which should be so accommodated). - 11 - Where temporary reserve pressures of this latter type did arise, a tied discount rate procedure would, thus, accentuate changes in money market rates and tend to lead to destabilizing pressures on the monetary aggregates. Use of a tie that averages the rate series selected for this purpose over a month or so would help to deemphasize the effect of short-run stochastic deviations in reserve factors and focus on more fundamental changes in underlying money demands. But this compromise would at the same time continue to tolerate significant changes in the spread of market rates over the discount rate, and unless adJusted Judgementally would tend to place the discount rate in a lagging penalty-rate position when market rates were declining. The obJective of achieving more timely adJustments in the discount rate, which is the essential purpose of a tied-rate system, might be better achieved, with fewer technical complications and more balanced analysis, if Judgemental actions that emphasized a discount rate surcharge were used to supplement and reinforce changes in the basic rate. This approach would retain the key element of discretion, always so important in Judging the full range of policy considerations that are involved in any discount rate action. If a discount rate tied to a yield series on market securities were employed, in order to dampen the rate effects of temporary stochastic influences, the rate series used as the tie would have to be evaluated regularly to make sure that no temporary influences were distorting its relationship to the overall structure of market rates. Where central banks in other countries have introduced tied-rate procedures for setting their discount rates, they have typically had to face up to the issue whether the obJective of tying should take precedence over other policy considerations. Often, to accommodate other policy requirements, the rules for implementing the tied rates have had to be set aside. After a period of mixed results, these other ties have, therefore, generally been abandoned. 3. Establishment of a graduated structure of discount rates https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 12 _b.clv ,1,n tages A graduated discount rate policy--wh.icb for example,, mJ,ght establish a structure of di.scount rates, witbl a: given quantity of funds availal:He to eligi.b'le b'orrowers at each rate--would help to imprdve' the' ~ccura;ey of Federal Reserve forecasts of borrowed reserves. Since this approach could eliminate' aidm:un.s,traitJ v<:5 guidelines- on appropriatene·ss and frequiency, each eligible borrower would be encoura:g,ed! to ptl.ls,fo its use' of the window to the point whe·re· tlme mairg,1ma1] e0's,t 01:fr' its permitted quota of borrowJ!..ng eql!l!a:1'.]ed! the prevall]lJ.'.n'g, federal funds rate--i. e. ,, the· cost 0 1f ai]ternaitl!Ve' funds,. Also, because the structure of rates, wo-u]d al])p·J'.y to, a:m 1.nstitut1.on' s borrowing llE! each staitememt wee·k ,, there· would be no reason for 1. t to ]ook t01 llts· piais,t borrow.inig, record or its expectatllons about fl!ltl!l!re sp1reads betweem the discount and market rates. wbe·n 'ct1ee·:itcl.l"l!l!llg, whertl:ler t©l borrow. -· «:: "-4!.,f" ,, .,.. As a result, the Federal Reserve col!l!]dl "be· more· ccin;:l:'fd1en,t that any basic change in the v01lume· od[ borr0wedi reserves; would p,rodu.ce an associated! res,po,ns·e• iz:i1 mairke·t :i!mteres,t rates, which would! then feed! back a])Jp,r0,p1riaiteTy 0n mone)~ demands. Disadvantages. ln l..9'2'3, fo,]Jlowing protes.ts, fr0m the• lD•ankl!]!llg, l!1!10_l-1ms,tr)3/ abolll!.t the 011.gh marg1.na] d!J!s,e0,unt rat,es, tb,at, we1reJ l'.mp,0,s,e,c:il by some• Federal Rese•rv;e, BaI.J.,ks. cl!ur1mg the• llmme,d!J!aite, ]),0.s,t,World!. Wiar 1 period! o,f l!.F.l!f1at1.0Jn ,, the 11:eng,r,ess, riesc;imd'edl language l!.n the F'edera] Ries,e•rv;,e, Ac,t,, whilleh h,a:<11.1 art!l,tl:J.©>rJ.!z,e,d.1 gradua t1..on of the d!iscoi"t!.l!nt rate on the; 0as,1s, OJ:f t,he.: amm.1.n.t o,f crech t extended!. Flo)r thlls, re.:a:S,0Jll>, t,here is_, considerable doubt whether t,b,e Fled!e,ra:J! Re,se•rVte; n0,w, has., the authority to graduate the d'isc<D.il!ln>t. ra:t,e; on t;he bas1..s of q_uant1..ty borrowed!. Under the graduated d!l!. s,C©itl!nt rate pr0,ip,0,s,a:Jl ,, t:h.e-1 un,ll_= verse of regular users, o)f the chs,c,e>,l!l!nt w1:l!lil_d!_0,w, w€1ullcll jump to perhaps 2,0 ~ 00,0 ins;t}!tut 1.ons, ,, as, c,Qm~a:re,<i]!_ Wlll..t:b no more than 400 day-to-d!a,y 1!l!S_,e,rs, €1:tf the, w11a~cl~i\~ 1W:t:1idle..:r· present arrangements,. Op,eratl!.ng s,t,a:f:f n.ee..Cile..d! t:€1 ~..:r·:r•@.._ti~e.: loans,, administer co,llatera] ,, a:ndl m.Q.Ul!_t;Q,r fq,:r s,~ll-we.:a~G:¥' could!, therefore~ be expected t:0, :i_n.c,rea6.e.: s;1.Ji"li~;ta.xrt'.!!.a.lll.~- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 13 Because the mechanics of the proposed system are rather complicated and the number of potential borrowers would be greatly expanded, the transition to the new system would probably require considerable experimentation. As a result, for some indeterminate time, actual borrowing might well deviate from expected levels by more than it has under existing arrangements, and there would always be some erratic margin of error in the system because the expanded universe of borrowers could not be expected to effectively maximize its opportunities at all times. Moreover, within the current statement week banks would still need to make Judgements about the likely course of the federal funds rate, and their efforts to allow for such changes could continue to lead to some variance in the relationship between borrowing and money market rates. If the discount rates on the initial tranches of credit provided in the graduated structure were set consistently at levels below the federal funds rate and there were no administrative guidelines on borrowing, users might tend to view such credit as a low-cost basic borrowing privilege that could be used to finance longer-term uses than are permitted under existing discount window guidelines. To the extent this proved to be the case, although the amount ,of credit released to any particular borrower would not be large, the arrangement would entail an element of subsidy that might' not be warranted. - 14 Impact of Existing Discount Policy on ReserveTargeting Experience Since October 1979 To help Judge how existing discount policy procedures have affected the reserve-targeting process since its inception in October 1979, this part of the paper addresses the following questions. To what extent have borrowed reserves differed from their targeted levels? Where deviations have been apparent, what factors seem to have accounted for them? How has the Desk adJusted its operations to cope with such deviations? And finally, how successful have these Desk adJustments been in keeping deviations in borrowed reserves from hindering effective implementation of the reserve-targeting process? Relation of Actual to Expected Levels of Borrowing Table 1 compares actual with expected levels of daily average borrowing for the sub periods between FOMC meetings on which the Trading Desk focused its intermeeting reserve targeting operations As would be expected, actual borrowing tended to exceed anticipated levels by the widest. margins when growth in the monetary aggregates appeared to be pushing well above targeted rates and market interest rates were under significant upward pressures The most dramatic overshoot in actual borrowing occurred in the first half of of possible new administration March, when widespread discussion programs to control inflation triggered large anticipatory drawings on the discount window https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 15 Table 1 Actual Minus Path Levels of Borrowed Reserves For Target Periods Between FOMC Meetings From Early October 1979, to Mid-November 1980 (Millions of dollars) l/ Time period (1) Actual (2) Targeted (3) Deviation 1979 4 weeks ended October 31 2,119 1,500 + 619 3 weeks ended November 21 1,885 1,500 + 385 4 weeks ended December 19 1,607 1,700 3 3 weeks ended January 9 1,128 1,550 422 4 weeks ended February 6 1,251 1,000 + 251 3 weeks ended February 27 1,830 1,317 + 513 3 weeks ended March 19 2,982 1,650 +l,332 weeks ended April 23 2,427 2,600 173 696 1,525 830 4 weeks ended June 18 142 111 3 weeks ended July 9 68 73 1980 5 -------4 weeks ended May 21 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis + 31 5 - 16 Table 1 (continued) Actual Minus Path Levels of Borrowed Reserves For Target Periods Between FOMC Meetings From Early October 1979, to Mid-November 1980 (Millions of dollars) l/ Time periods (1) Actual (2) (3) Targeted Deviation 1980 5 weeks ended August 13 239 75 + 5 weeks ended September 17 697 225 + 472 " 164 5-weeks ended October 22 1,300 950 + 350 4-weeks ended November 1.9 1,841 1,450 + 391 !/ Computed from final data and adJusted paths. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 17 In the periods when growth of the aggregates appeared to be falling short of expectations--such as late 1979 and the spring and early summer of 1980--borrowed reserves ran below expected levels. While both the expected levels of borrowed reserves and the deviations from these levels (shown in Table 1) are generally consistent with patterns that would have been anticipated from a reserve-targeting strategy; the size and variability of some of these deviations raise a question whether the level of borrowed reserves is as closely linked to the spread of market rates over the discount rate as the logic of the reserve targeting strategy implies. Econometric test of borrowing relationship.!/ focus more rigorously To on the recent relationship of borrowed reserves to this interest rate spread, the weekly experience for the period since October 6, 1979, was compared through econometric analysis with the relationship that prevailed throughout the 1970s. This analysis suggests that for a given spread between the federal funds and discount rates, borrowing at the discount window has become considerably more erratic since October 6, 1979. It also suggests that borrowing at given spreads may have become somewhat than before October larger in the recent period 1979. 1/ This and the following two sections of the paper are taken largely from https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Dana Johnson and John Spitzer, Recent Behavior of Member Bank Borrowing at the Discount Window, paper presented at the Financial Analyst Conference at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, June 12 and 13, 1980. 11 11 - 18 - A variety of econometric relationships were estimated relating member bank borrowing to the spread between the federal funds rate and the discount rate and to an assortment of other variables that measure various aspects of conditions in the money market.!/ Weekly data running from the beginning of 1970 through September 1979 were used in the analysis.2/ The results strongly suggest that the level of borrowing is significantly correlated with the spread between the two interest rates but not with the absolute level of those rates. When the level of required reserves is added to the analysis, the results indicate that there is also some tendency, albeit quite weak, for member bank borrowing to increase along with the level of reserves. Also, borrowing appears to be greater in the initial week in which there is an increase in required reserves than in subsequent weeks. This suggests that the discount window is serving one of its desired purposes, namely allowing1banks to make an orderly adJustment to a change in required reserves by borrowing initially and then adJusting their portfolios. !/ 2/ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The appendix explains the specifics of this econometric analysis. The emergency borrowing by Franklin National Bank in 1974 was treated as if it were nonborrowed reserves and excluded from the data. For the recent period emergencv borrowing by the First Pennsylvania Bank was handled in the same way. - 19 A few variables tested that showed little relation to levels of borrowing also are important to note. Several different measures of the degree of administrative pressure for all member banks were added to the test models but were never close to being statistically significant. For example, such variables as the number of banks of all sizes that have borrowed relatively frequently in the preceding 13 weeks, and the dollar amounts of borrowing by such banks, do not help to explain the level of member bank borrowing. However, when the analysis is restricted to borrowing banks with deposits of $500 million or more, there is evidence that the past frequency of borrowing has had an influence on the spread The conclusion reached from the econometric analysis is that since October 9, 1979, the link between borrowing and the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate has become considerably more variable than it was before that date. In addition, it appears that at given spreads between these two rates, there may have been a greater willingness to borrow in the recent period. Specifically, this admittedly still tentative finding suggests that an increase of 10 basis points in the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate has been associated on average with an increase in borrowing at the window of $110 million, whereas for the period tested before October 6 a similar change in the spread was associated with an increase in borrowing of only $40 million. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 20 - Relation of Borrowing to Rate Spreads Because borrowed reserves have expanded in tandem with the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate, some analysts believe that such changes in spreads have operated as an incentive for banks to expand their use of Federal Reserve credit and that this has contributed in the process to an excessive growth of the monetary aggregates. However, the same evidence on the relationship of borrowing to rate spreads can also be interpreted as support for th~ traditional view that greater bank reliance on borrowed reserves helps to dampen the expansion of money and bank credit As noted earlier, when incoming data indicate that growth in money and total reserves is exceeding desired rates, the Desk holds to its target for nonborrowed reserves and forces ' banks to increase their borrowing at the discount window. If the overshoot in growth rates seems very large, the target for nonborrowed reserves may also be adjusted downward, forcing a still larger volume of borrowing on the banking system. Since individual banks are expected to utilize alternative sources of funds before coming to the discount window,they turn first to these other sources, in the process, they bid the funds rate and other short-term market rates up relative to the discount rate. Because the volume of nonborrowed reserves available to the banking system is being constrained by the Desk, the supply of federal funds actually available to accommodate bank demands https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 21 is more constrained than before. Consequently, some banks are forced to expand their borrowing at the discourit window and are brought under increased administrative pressure. Looking back on any such shift in the mix between nonborrowed and borrowed reserves, it will generally be evident that the increase in borrowing was significantly correlated with a widening of the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate But the causation can be viewed as coming primarily from the Desk, since it forced more borrowing on a reluctant banking system by reducing the relative availability of nonborrowed reserves. Bank decisions on when to borrow at the discount window are, of course, influenced by prevailing and expected spreads between the discount rate and market rates. The step- up of borrowing that developed in the weeks of 1980 when increases in the discount rates were widely anticipated is one obvious example of such behavior. But the econometric analysis suggests that erosion in the effectiveness of the traditional guidelines for administration of the discount window since the shift to reserve targeting has actually been substantially less than might have been expected. If any sizable number of banks were now persistently abusing their use of the window in an effort to maxmize returns from favorable interest rate spreads, one would expect to see much less upward pressure on the federal funds rate relative to the discount rate than has actually developed. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 22 - When one considers the uses to which Federal Reserve credit is expected to be limited, it is not so surprising that wider spreads between the discount rate and rates on market sources of funds have failed to produce larger changes in the borrowing relationship. Use of the window to expand investment portfolios or to promote a program of concerted expansion in lending is strictly prohibited, as well as borrowing to sell federal funds, or to reduce regular patterns of reliance on sales of large CDs and Eurodollars. On the relatiyely rare occasions when maJor banks with ready access to domestic and international money markets do turn to the discount window, they are generally expected to repay these borrowings on the next business day and to limit such uses to no more than a limited number of weeks in any quarter. While medium-sized and smaller banks that lack such ready access to money markets are granted leeway to turn to the Federal Reserve more often and for somewhat lonqer periods, their use of the discount window is also substantially constrained.!/ Sources of Variability in the Borrowing Relationship The econometric analysis did, nevertheless, identify considerable variability in the relationship of borrowed reserves !/ Some analysts have asked why--if increased use of the discount window is supposed to dampen banks' enthusiasm for expanding credit--there was not more evidence in the latter part of 1980 that bank lending activity was being so constrained. One answer to t~is question is that even though use of the window was relatively large in certain periods of 1980, for large banks funds obtained through the window still represented a small margin of their total fund availability. For smaller bank8 that used the window, the need to repay borrowing at the discount unndow did exercise a more evident constraint, presumably because t~ey have few alterhative sources. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 23 to the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate. While there was variability of this type even before October 1979, it appears to have increased significantly since then. This raises two questions first, what accounted for the variability in the relationship before October 1979, and second, what accounts for the evident increase since then? The primary explanation for the normal variability in the aggregate borrowing relationship is that banks' attitudes about borrowing are quite diverse. Some banks choose to avoid . borrowing at the discount window under virtually all circumstances, others choose to borrow somewhat more freely but considerably less often and for smaller amounts than the numerical guidelines permit, while still others apparently attempt to borrow as much and as often as the rules permit if it 1s profitable to do so. In such circumstances, aggregate borrowing behavior in a given week reflects the composition of the group of banks that need to obtain additional reserves. For example, the federal funds rate may tend to be a bit lower for any given provision of nonborrowed reserves in the weeks in which banks with high propensities to borrow at the discount window happen to have relatively large reserve shortages. Another possible source of variability in the intensity of borrowing has been the fact that banks have been subJect to administrative standards that have varied slightly in their relative stringency from Reserve District to Reserve District. Numerical guidelines used to oversee the legitimacy of borrowing https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 24 requests have not been wholly uniform. And the interpretation of what constitutes "appropriate" borrowing has sometJ.mes differed a bit from one discount officer to another. As a result, some bor- rowers may have had more leeway than others to take occasional indirect advantaf;e of the arbitrage opportunity that exists when there is a large spread between the federal funds rate and the discount rate. If in ~ny given circumstance, a disproportionate number of banks that are subJect to somewhat more stringent borrowing guidelines need to obtain additional reserves, relatively more pressure will tend to develop in the funds market. Both of these explanations for the normal variability of the borrowing relationship stem from aggregating banks with different propensities to borrow. The variability among banks in their attitudes about borrowing and the slight difference in adl.111nistrative practices from Reser1S.Te District District to Reserve may have created a situation in which the aggregate level of borrowing has fluctuated as the banks that are choosing between borrowing reserves in the funds market or borrowing directly from the discount window have changed from week to week. Neither of these explanations, however, would appear to explain adequately the increase in the variability of borrowing since October 1979. Even though there is evidence that banks in the aggregate have been slightly less reluctant to borrow since October 6, there is little reason to suspect that banks' attitudes towards borrowing have become dramatically more disparate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 25 Moreover, there is no evidence to suggest that adm1n1strat1ve practices have become more variable from District to District since October 6. In fact, with the recent revision of Regulation A and the introduction of uniform operating guidelines, any lingering variation in discount window administration across District lines should be effectively minimized. The most plausible explanation of the additional vari- ability in the borrowing relationship is the substantially increased volatility of interest rates that has emerged over most of the period since October 1979. Limits on the frequency and amount of discount window borrowing, whether self imposed or not, imply that a bank when deciding whether to borrow today may consider the likelihood of wanting to borrow in the near future Hence the expected future behavior of the spread between the discount rate and the federal funds rate, in addition to the current spread, may influence its borrowing decision. The increased volatility of the funds rate reflects the fact that demands for reserves are not accommodated under the new reserve-targeting procedures. For this reason the near- term outlook for the funds rate is now far less certain than it was before October 1979, when even week~o-week changes in the funds rate usually were relatively minor and a bank could often safely assume that the spread was likely to continue to be about the same for the foreseeable future. A bank, therefore, is now much more uncertain about the relative advantage of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 26 borrowing at any particular time. Under the new procedures, banks must try to assess the demand for money and whether such demands are likely to lead to increased or decreased pressures in the funds market. For example, if it were generally expected that money demand would start exceeding the Federal Reserve's near-term targets, banks might become somewhat more reluctant to borrow, anticipating that the funds rate would soon rise relative to the discount rate and make future borrowing more attractive than current borrowing. How Well Has the Desk Coped with Deviations of Actual Borrowing from Expected Levels? The fact that actual borrowed reserves can deviate significantly from expected levels obviously complicates the task of implementing the reserve-targeting strategy. However, as described in the previously cited paper by Messrs. Meek and Levin, the Desk has exhibited sufficient operating flexibility to hit its targets for nonborrowed reserves quite effectively. By making selective adJustments in nonborrowed reserve targets from time to time, it has also managed to offset a sizable part of weekly deviations in borrowed reserves from their expected levels. This has not kept total reserves from tnissing their target paths at critical points. But these misses have been partly a reflection of policy Judgements that corrections for such deviations should be accomplished over more extended periods than the immediately succeeding statement weeks. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Thus, the new - Z7 target levels for nonborrowed reserves ' that were specified following receipt of new weekly data on depos1ts~and-resertes often did not seek to correct completely for recently observed deviations in borrowed and total reserves For this reason, , it is not vaild to assume that observed overshoots or undershoots of 1ntermeeting targets for total reserves are attributabl~ in any significant degree to the.staff's 1nabil~ty to correctly forecast borrowed reserves~ In fact, devia~ions- resultin~ from ~ misspec1ficat1ons of expec~ed eorrowing do not appear, by them- • selves, t~ have imposed a maJor obs~acle to reasonable at\ainment- ef the desired reserve targets. Interest rate response. As- might have been ex1>-ec-ted.,- the ~ink between polfcy-induced changes in- the level of boFrowed reserves and the interest Fate responses needed to encourage banks to adJust their creation o~ deposits and credit has proved to be more tenuous. Like the FOMC Desk, market parti- cipants cannot be sure whether any observed change in the current level of borrowed reserves reflects strictly temporary influences ' likely to be soon reversed or something more fundamental. As a result, immediate changes in borrowed reserves are not generally viewed by the market as reliable signals of adJustments 1n the FOMC's policy posture. Thus, over short time periods .,. changes in borrowed reserves and money market rates are not very tightly linked, as can ~e seen in Chart I In fact, directions of change 10 the two are occasionally divergent https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Cha1;tt Borrowings (Billions) 2.0 i Changes in Adjustment Credit Bor~ow!~gs CQmp~red with th~ Difference pf the Fede~al Funds Rate M~nus the O!sc~unt:~~t~ (Weekly averag~li) Rate Differential (Pevcentage points) ---"1"------------"1""----,.,--------........------...-----..--------------- 3, o ... Solid Curve - left scale 1.6 2.4 Dashed Curve - right scale I ~ - ' " 11 1.2 ,. ,1 I 1 I I 11 I 1 - • l I I .8 I 1 I I I I I I t, I I -l ,4 I 0 1.2 '' I 1 I I J I I l +-- Dtscount ~t,a-.,,;.;..,.+ a~ Penalty I I • J 1 I I I \ l I .6 t,.:) CXl ,, 0 . 1 \ ,4 1.8 II .6 \ 'I ' I .8 I I l 1.2 1 6 1.2 l 'l'•. '-------'----'--------'----".,___ __.,____.,_r-_,.,...-,....,............._....,...,___ _..,_____....,..,______..._..,___. 2,4 Jul. Aug. 'S~pt. Oc~. Nov. nee. Oct. Nov. Jan. Mar. Apr. Dec. Feb. 1979 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1980 - 29 - Nevertheless, any persistent tendency for borrowed reserves to expand or contract over several statement weeks is usually reflected (as the chart also suggests) in changes of money market rates that move in the same direction, even though the degree of rate response to given changes in borrowing has been varied.l/ In the late summer and early fall of 1980, for example, a significant pickup in the level of borrowing was not associ- ated with as large a rise in money market rates as the Desk was anticipating Undoubtedly this sluggish response reflected the fact that the banking system had been virtually out of debt at the Federal Reserve over most of the summer. Since few banks were even close to coming under administrative restraint at the discount window, the sizable dollar increase in borrowing apparently exerted less than normal pressure on money market rates Later in the fall, however, after many banks had begun to come under administrative pressure at the discount window, the imposition of a discount rate surcharge on top of an increase in the basic rate produced a somewhat sharper general reaction in market interest rates than was initially expected. The uncertain dimensions of interest rate responses to changes in the level of borrowed reserves 1s not so surprising 1n a money market where participants I expectations are l/ These relationships are also discussed in Levin and Meek, 11 Implementing the New Procedures. 11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 30 affected by such a wide range of influences, particularly since the volume of borrowed reserves is often not a maJor element in this total complex. Nevertheless, in view of the general importance of interest rate responses to the logic of the reserve-targeting process, the evident looseness in the relationship between borrowing and interest rates is a cause for some' concern. Such doubts lead logically to the question whether there is an alternative means of managing discount policy that might make it easier to predict both the likely volume of bor-, . rowed reserves and the relationship of changes in that borrowing to changes in money market rates Before turning to a considera- tion of alternative discount policies, however, the 1980 experience with a discount rate surcharge needs to be reviewed, since this represented a rather significant effort to improve the flexibility of existing discount policy. 1980 Experience with a Discount Rate Surcharge A surcharge was added to the basic discount rate at two points during 1980, first between March 17 and May 7, and then again starting on November 17 and running into 1981. In each case the surcharge was applied to borrowings by banks with deposits of $500 million or more, where the borrowings occurred in two successive statement weeks or in more than four statement weeks of a quarter https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 31 - The spring surcharge of 3 percentage points was added to the then prevailing basic discount rate of 13 percent. fall surcharge when initially imposed in mid-November The was 2 percentage points and was introduced in conJunction with a 1 percentage point increase in the basic discount rate, from 11 to 12 percent. On December 5, after market interest rates had experienced further steep advances, both the surcharge and the basic discount rate were raised an additional percentage point and were still in effect at the turn of the year Table !.which compares the number of banks and the amounts of borrowing that were subJected to the surcharge during the spring and fall periods, shows that the incidence of the fall surcharge was greater. Much of this difference is attributable to the fact that the fall surcharge, although introduced in the middle of the quarter, looked back to the number of weeks of borrowing in the quarter as a whole-in determining when banks had exceeded the four weeks per quarter trigger that subJected them to the surcharge. The spring surcharge, on the other hand, looked only forward. Since it was introduced Just two weeks before the end of the January-March quarter, there https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 32 Table 2 Discount Window Borrowings SubJ ected to Surcharge }j Statement week endinq Surcharge (percent) Amount subjected to surcharqe (millions of dollars) Number of banks Spring surcharge period 03/26/80 3 77 7 04/02/80 3 68 3 04/09/80 3 55 2 04/16/80 3 101 4 04/23/80 3 110 5 04/30/80 3 135 5 05/07/80 3 11 1 11/19/80 2 124 5 11/26/80 2 463 24 12/03/80 2 669 30 12/10/80 3 182 14 12/17/80 3 395 18 Fall surcharqe oeriod 1/ "Extended" borrowing by the First Pennsylvania Bank during the - period March 26-April 22, 1980, is excluded from these data. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 33 - was no chance for the four weeks per quarter exemption to be exceeded until five weeks into the April-June quarter (1 e the statement week ending May 9), Because this was also the final week of the spring surcharge period, the banks that paid the surcharge in the spring period did so almost entirely because they borrowed in successive statement weeks. Banks subJected to the surcharge in the fall period, however, were also substantially affected because they had borrowed in more than four statement weeks of the quarter The two surcharge periods were further differentiated by the application of direct credit controls in the spring and not in the fall, and by the greater de~ands for bank credit that developed in t~e fall b~cause the ecoaomy was substantially stronger than in the spring. Rationale for surcharge strategy. The rationale for imposing a discount rate surcharge on top of the basic discount rate has been to achieve a more selective restraJnt on use of the discount window and thus a somewhat smaller general response in market interest rates than might have been expected from an equivalent across-the-board increase in the basic discount rate Under this selective approach, the greatest restraint is imposed on large institutions that have been the largest and most active users of the window, while institutions that have been infrequent borrowers and small institutions that have no effective access to national money markets are still charged only the basic discount rate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 34 Banks whose past use of the discount window makes them vulnerable to payment of the surcharge generally seek to avoid it by increasing their reliance on the federal funds market. N As a result, the spread of the funds rate over the basic discount rate tends to widen relative to what it was before imposition of the surcharge For the spring surcharge period this process apparently led to a widening of the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate that amounted to roughly two-thirds of the surcharge itse~f For the fall period, the widening of the spread appears to have been about equal to the surcharg9 Th8 fact that the spring discount rate surcharge was announced Jointly with a direct credit control program, at a time when there was growing evidence that the economy was weakening, apparently triggered a broad market consensus that a general interest rate downturn was at hand. Over most of the fall surcharge period, however, many market participants continued to anticipate significant further interest rate advances. Impact of surcharge on reserve targeting. To Judge how imposition of the discount rate surcharge may have influenced the effectiveness of the reserve-targeting strategy, two questions need to be addressed First, have deviations of borrowed reserves from expected levels been any more of a problem in surcharge periods than at other times? Second, has the response of market rates to changes in borrowed reserves provided any clearer https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 35 signal on the thrust of reserve-targeting policy during surcharge periods than at other times? Actual borrowed reserves ran unusually high relative to expected borrowing in the Mar~h 19, April 23, and April 30 statement weeks of the spring surcharge period. But these overshoots were essentially a reflection of other influences. In the week ending March 19, borrowing rose in anticipation of the widely presaged general credit control program, while at the end of April overshoots of borrowing relative to the staff's reduced estimates reflected the fact that the market had not yet caught up with the Desk's shift to a strategy of more liberal provision of nonborrowed reserves In general, the existence of a surcharge does not seem to have made the Desk's task of coping with misses in borrowed reserves any more difficult than it was in weeks when there was no surcharge. Moreover, the 1980 experience suggests that a discount rate surc~arge can be helpful in communicating the current thrust of reserve-targeting policy to market participants When a surcharge is first introduced, it has an announcement effect similar to that of a change in the basic discount rate. Consequently, if future use of the surcharge were to lead to more frequent changes in the structure of discount rates, this could be expected to communicate the thrust of policy to market participants more clearly than a strategy that relied largely on shifts in the mix of borrowed versus nonborrowed reserves https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 36 as the catalyst for inducing desired adJustments in market interest rates. Use of a discount rate surcharge has sometimes been advocated as a means of narrowing the effective spread between the basic discount rate and market interest rates. Under a reserve-targe~ing procedure, however, this result could be effectively achieved only if--after the surcharge was imposed--the FOMC were willing to adJust its target for nonborrowed reserves upward That is, after the action, a larger share of total reserves would need to be provided through open market operations and a reduced share through bank reliance on the discount window. Such an approach might be rationalized if it were thought that further general advances in market interest rates ought to be constrained. If after the imposi- tion of a surcharge, the Desk did not change its target for nonborrowed reserves (as was the case in 1980), banks seeking to avoid payment of the surcharge would simply bid the federal funds rate and other market rates higher, reestablishing spreads over the surcharge that were not too different from the spreads over the basic discount rate that had prevailed before. Even though more frequent use of a discount rate surcharge could be expected to help reduce confusion in market circles rega~ding the direction of interest rate responses to reserve-targeting policy, there could still be considerable uncertainty as to the likely degree of interest rate response https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 37 The smaller reaction of market rates in 1980 to the spring surcharge than to the fall surcharge is a useful reminder that any actual response of market rates can be significantly influenced by the nature of other market forces prevailing at the time. The application of the 1980 surcharge only to large banks permitted many users of the discount window--particularly smaller banks--to continue obtaining Federal Reserve credit at the basic rate The basic rate sometimes ranged to as much as 7 percentage points below rates that depository institutions were paying for funds in the market, or that thrift institutions were paying to borrow from their special industry lenders. To help minimize such differences in the future, it may, therefore, become necessary to apply any needed discount rate surcharge to borrowings by institutions of all sizes--not Just to large institutions If this approach were followed, criteria for applying the surcharge (on consecutive weeks of borrowing, and number of weeks of borrowing within a quarter) would have to be more liberal for smaller than for large institutions, since the former have little access to money market sources of funds. In the past the substitution of a discount rate surcharge for a general change 1n the basic rate has always been https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 38 advocated as a means of limiting the risk of overkill in discount rate actions But if the surcharge were applied more generally to institutions of all sizes, its potential advantage as a selective instrument in discount rate administration would tend to be reduced. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 39 Alternative Approaches to the Management of Discount Policy If looseness in the relationship between changes in borrowed reserves and money market interest rates should prove to be greater than can be tolerated under existing procedures for managing discount policy, are there alternative approaches that might be more supportive of the reserve-targeting process? As suggested earlier, the three discount policy approaches that seem to capture the range of alternative possibilities most effectively are: (1) maintaining a single discount rate consistently at a penalty above the federal funds rate, (2) tie1ng a single discount rate at a fixed spread somewhat below the federal funds rate, and (3) establishing a structure of discount rates graduated according to the quantity of borrowing, with the base rate in the structure set below and the peak rate at a penalty above the federal funds rate. Assessment of the pros and cons of these various options against the background of actual experience with existing procedures will help to place the relative merits of both in better perspective Maintaining the Discount Rate Consistently at a Penalty!/ The rationale for shifting to a policy of maintaining the discount rate always at a penalty above the federal funds rate is to make the volume of borrowed reserves more predictable by reducing it to minimal levels Because of the penalty rate, use of the discount window would be effectively constrained to l/ This and the section on a graduated discount rate drew heavily from a paper prepared by Perry Quick, "Discount Window Policies without Administrative Pressure. 11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 40 infrequent--but (on a day-to-day basis) relatively predictable-borrowing for emergency purposes plus a small amount of frictional borrowing for adJustment purposes largely Since this approach would make nonborrowed reserves virtually the same as total reserves, the Desk's ability to hit its total re~erves target should be less affected by deviations in borrowed reserves. Adoption of a penalty rate arrangement would obviously diminish the role of the discount window as a buffer for adjusting the reserve positions of individual banks. Banks seeking to cover reserve deficiencies would rely largely on the federal funds market as the less expensive source of credit and would turn to the discount window only when their access to cheaper market sources had been temporarily shut off, or when they had developed an emergency need for funds Similarly, banks with reserve sur- pluses would rarely use them to repay debt at the discount window since there would be few such loans outstanding. With the discount window thus relegated primarily to a lender of last resort role, the supply of total reserves would be less adJustable than under the present system. As a result, any change in bank demands for reserves relative to the volume of nonborrowed reserves being supplied through Desk open market operations would exert a significantly sharper reaction on market interest rates than is now the case. Thus, the key question at issue about this option is whether these sharper interest rate responses would facilitate or inhibit the implementation of monetary policy https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 41 The case for a penalty discount rate. Those favoring a penalty discount rate Jase their case on two maJor points. First, they believe it would avoid certain key difficulties that have emerged under the existing system. Second, they believe it would make monetary policy respond in a much more timely fashion to the critical changes in money demands that are linked to undesirable movements in economic activity. Under existing arrangements banks tend to view their borrowing at the discount window as Just another form of managed liability. The volume of Federal Reserve credit demanded, therefore, tends to reflect relative spreads between tne discount rate and other money market rates However, borrowing by in- dividual banks also reflects their varying individual assessments of the implicit costs of running afoul of the administrative guidelines discount officers use to control use of the window. Since the Desk has had considerable difficulty forecasting how the combined effects of these two types of influences are likely to be reflected in the level of borrowed reserves for any given statement week, a penalty rate system that minimizes their importance should help to avoid inaccurate estimates of borrowed reserves. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 42 - Finally, under the penalty rate approach a shift in banks' demands for reserves stemming from changes in the public's demand for money would induce a much sharper movement in the federal funds rate than before. This would induce quicker, offsetting reactions in bank lending strategies and lead to more rapid general responses of deposit growth throughout the banking system The case against a penalty discount rate. The con- tinuous maintenance of a penalty discount rate would amount to the pursuit of a total reserves or monetary base path Adherence to such a policy would, therefore, effectively eliminate the important role of the discount window as a buffer for accommodating temporary needs for services that have no relation to changes in underlying demands for money (such as changing demands for excess reserves, or changes in the deposit mix affecting required reserves) Under such an arrangement, any discrepancy between nonborrowed reserves provided by the Federal Reserve and total reserves desired by banks would thus lead to very sharp interest rate adJustments. As a practical matter, a strict penalty system of this type would not be possible under the existing system of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 43 lagged reserve accounting, the only way the path for total reserves could be maintained when Desk misestimates of reserve factors failed to supply the nonborrowed reserves needed to cover banks' required reserves would be for the federal funds rate to rise temporarily to a level above the discount rate. This would then induce the volume of borrowing needed to make up the reserve deficiency. Under present arrangements, the penalty rate approach would, therefore, have important deficiencies. stantially accentuate It would sub- the short-run volatility of interest rates, leading at times to much sharper interest rate reactions than were consistent with the FOMC's obJectives on money and reserve growth. Although it would effectively minimize the volume of borrowed reserves, there would still be occasional needs for adJustment borrowing because the Desk failed to provide the appropriate volume of nonborrowed reserves Consequently, variability in the volume of borrowed reserves might remain unexpectedly sizable. The increased volatility of money market rates likely to develop under this approach could also be expected to make staff estimates of excess reserves more difficult. In weeks when banks were uncertain whether money market rates might rise, they would tend to carry a larger cushion of excess reserves than at other times. On average, therefore, fluctuations in the level of excess reserves could become significantly wider https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 44 and less predictable than they are now. Consequently, there would be a significant potential for the multiplier for total reserves to become quite erratic under this scheme. If this contributed to more erratic short-term movements in money market interest rates, it could distort and delay bank responses to System policy initiatives. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 45 Adoption of a Tied Discount Rate!/ As a second possible alternative to existing discount policy, it has been suggested that the discount rate might be tied 1n a constant spread relat1onsh1p slightly below the federal funds rate, or 1n some fixed spread relationship to a key alternative money market rate series. Like the penalty rate option Just discussed, the obJective of this approach would be to insulate the volume of borrowed reserves against changes in market interest rates so that adJustments to per- sisting deviations from targeted money growth rates would occur more quickly. The precise effects of any tied rate scheme on the reserve-targeting process w1ll 1 of course, depend importantly on the particular market rate selected as the tie, and the mechanics of how the tie 1s applied.2/ Most recent proposals for a tied rate recommend that the federal funds rate be used as the tie. the fact that among banks that This choice reflects account for the lion's share of borrowing at the discount window, purchases of federal funds are the closest substitute for borrowed reserves. Some older tied-rate proposals that were designed primarily to minimize 1/ Much of the discussion 1n this section 1s drawn from a staff paper prepared by Paul Boltz and James 0' Brien, "Tyinq the Discount Rate to Market Rates of Interest" (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve 2/ System} May 1980. The option of tying the discount rate at a constant spread above the federal funds rate is not considered because of the difficulties-described in the preceding section--that such an approach would have in achievinq an eouilibriurn under lagqed-reserve accounting. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 46 - the announcement effect of discount rate actions,. by making them automatic, recommended use of the 3-month Treasury bill rate as the tie--or alternatively some broader index of 1- to 3-month money market rates. Rates on , .. to 3-month debt maturities would also have certain advantages as a tie for reserve-targeting purposes, since they are less influenced than the rate on 1~day federal funds by stochastic shifts in bank needs for reserves that are unrelated to changing money demands, If the federal funds rate were selected as the tie, any attempt to link the discount rate to very recent levels of the federal funds rate could produce large, possibly explosive, movements in both the federal funds rate and other market rates. For example, if today's discount rate were tied to yesterday's federal funds rate, anything causing a change in yesterday's funds rate would lead to a further change in today's funds rate because of the tied increase in today's discount rate. This would induce still further changes in tomorrow's discount and funds rate, and so on. If the initial change was an increase in the funds rate, rates would continue to move higher over the statement week and into future statement weeks. While the public ultimately would begin to respond to large rate increases by reducing its demand for money, this would probably not occur very rapidly. Any such rapid escalation of market rates could pro- bably be expected to force a change in either banking practices https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 47 or Desk procedures. Banks might begin to hold larger amounts of interest sensitive excess reserves, or the Desk might act to offset the destablizing effects of the contemporaneously tied discount rate by altering its provision of nonborrowed reserves. If the Desk did act to halt the interest rate spiral, however, this would reflect the imposition of a federal funds rate limit. The technical problem of induced interest rate volatility could also be damped if the discount rate were tied to some lagged value of the federal funds rate instead of a very recent rate. For example, if the discount rate were a monthly average of the funds rate, demands for reserves would begin to be adJusted before any induced sequence of interest rate movements proceeded very far. As a result, interest rate movements would be better coordinated with counteracting changes in the public's demand for money.!/ l/ Under a contemporaneous reserve accounting system, tyinq of the discount rate to a current level of the federal funds rate would create less of a problem, since the effects of a change in the level of the discount rate would be partly absorbed by some immediate change in the public's demand for money and this would exert an immediate influence on banks' demands for reserves. Nevertheless, the sequence of interest rate adJustments could still be quite substantial if the public's demand for money were highly interest inelastic. If, for example, there were an initial increase in the public's demand for money balances, this would raise the federal funds rate and, with it, the discount rate. Rat~s would continue to rise until they became high enough to bring the level of desired money balances and back reserve needs back to their initial level. In practice, the increase in market rates required to force the public's demands for ' money back to this initial level right away could prove to be very large indeed. If this were generally so, the situation would be essentially the same as for lagged reserve accounting. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 48 The case for a tied rate. Those favoring a discount rate tied automatically to a market rate typically recommend either a link to a backward looking weekly or monthly average of the federal funds rate or a link to a more current weekly rate average for some market security, such as the three-month Treasury bill. The rationale for a backward looking federal funds rate tie is essentially twofold. First, it will allow for some variation of the spread of the current federal funds rate over the discount rate and thus, by ~olerating some increase in the volume of borrowed reserves, limit the risk of an interaction with the discount rate that ratchets the federal funds rate upward. This will help to minimize the possible pitfall of linking the discount rate too tightly to a current rate series that is heavily influenced by strictly temporary shifts in demands for reserves and not reflective of a basic trend demand for money. in the At the same time, however, a lagged tie of this type wilJ keep spreads of market rates over the discount rate from reaching the unacceptably large proportions that have developed at critical points under the existing system of establishing the discount rate on a discretionary basis. By reduc1Dg the average size of the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate, the risk that the administrative guidelines will cease to be effective in controlling use of the disco1rnt window will be minimized https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 49 - The case against a tied rate Those opposed to an automatic tie of the discount rate to the federal funds rate believe that this approach would inevitably encourage too close a linkage to relatively current adJustments in money market conditions. They fear that such a tie would accentuate interest rate volatility and lead to excessive, counterproductive swings in growth of the monetary aggregates around their targeted longer-run paths. Moreover, they note that although a tied rate approach would make the average volume of borrowed reserves more stable than it is now the short-run variance of borrowing could be exp~cted to remain sizable Proponents of a tied rate approach argue that an automatic trigger is the only means of assuring that timely actions will be taken to keep the discount rate in reasonable alignment with market rates. They believe the existing tendency for the Federal Reserve to delay Judgemental discount rate actions is essentially a reflection of the heavy publicity that surrounds them and that the only way this publicity can be defused so timely action can be assured is to make the discount rate move automatically in tandem with market rates. In practice, however, decisions on discount rate actions involve ~uch more fundamental policy considerations than concern about publicity. The adoption of a tied rate approach would make automaticity override these other considerations. Where other central banks have introduced tied rate procedures for setting their discount rates, they have had to wrestle with this issue of whether the obJective of tying https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis should take - 50 - precedence over other policy considerations. Generally, to accom- modate other overriding policy needs, the rules for those other ties have had to be breached frequently. After a period of mixed results, the experiments have usually been abandoned. To assure that the automaticity feature of a tied discount rate did not produce excessive volatility in market interest rates and money growth, it would be necessary to I introduce a significant backward-looking focus in any particular federal funds rate tie that was selected. Under such an arrangement the discount rate would still lag appreciably behind rapid changes in the federal funds rate. To control use of the window the administrative gu1delines would, therefore, still need to be retained. For this reason, there would still be room for much of the same type of uncertainty regarding the relationship between expected and actual levels of borrowed reserves that there is under the present system. More active use of the discount rate surcharge--possibly applied to a broader size spectrum of borrowers--could achieve some of the obJectives sought by a discount rate tied to the I' federal funds rate with a lag. The risks of excessive rate ratcheting would be less under this Judgemental approach, since detisions on establishing the surcharge would not have to sacrifice the key element of discretion that 1s so important when weighing the range of policy considerations involved 1n any discount rate action. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 51 - Use of a security rate as the tie, in lieu of the federal funds rate, to try to play down the importance of very temporary changes in reserve demands would introduce additional technical complexities that might prove troublesome. shows that in periods as short as For example, experience an intermeeting period, most market rate series will at times show temporary supply-demand distortions relative to the structure of other similar rates. Thus, any series used as an automatic tie would have to be reviewed regularly to determine whether any temporary market factors were creating distortions that indicated a need to set the automaticity aside. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 52 Establishment of a Graduated Structure of Discount Rates The earlier discussion of a penalty discount rate suggests that its relative inflexibility would amount to a policy of virtually "no accommodation" to unexpected reserve shocks, whether the shocks came from only temporary distortions in the supply of reserves or from more fundamental increases in underlying money demands. At the opposite extreme the former strategy of targeting open market operations on the federal funds rate amounted to a policy of "full accommodation" of any demands for reserves that tended to bid up the funds rate. With many analysts faulting both of these systems--the penalty rate approach for exacerbating interest rate volatility, and "fed funds" targeting for frequently funding excessively rapid money_supply growth-logic suggests that there may be a middle, more nearly optimum, ground that seeks to split the difference between these other approaches. I It would reJect both no accommodation and a full accommodation of reserve shocks, in favor of a partial acrommodatio11-0f course, the administrative guidelines now being applied by discount officers are already designed to seek such a middle ground, when taken in combination with the reserve targeting system. process»which forces more or less borrowing on the banking As banks borrow, discount officers exert pressure to repay on the particular banks that borrow too much or too frequently in the expectation that this will encourage them to constrain their loan and investment activity. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Even banks that seek - 53 - to avoid the imposition of these discount window constraints may act to constrain loan and investment activity in order to limit their use of the window. In effect, under this existing approach the implicit costs of additional borrowing at the discount window rise as the borrower approaches the limits of either his own or the Reserve Bank's constraints on his access to borrowed reserves. Unfortunately, the earlier analysis of actual reserve targeting experience suggests that these existing procedures for administering the discount window do leave something to be desired, because week-to-week levels of borrowing activity tend to be so loosely linked to the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate. To try to improve on this sometimes erratic per- formance, the Federal Reserve might introduce an alternative middle-ground approach. This alternative would establish an explicit schedule of discount rates that rose in steps as the quantity of an institutions's borrowing rose. The graduated rate structure would be uniformly applied at all Federal Reserve Banks and would apply to an insitution's borrowing in each statement week Specifics of a graduated discount rate plan. A set of discount rates graduated to increase as the quantity of an institution's borrowing expanded would have several dimensions that could be adJusted in various ways. Specific decisions would need to be made on (1) the level of the base or lowest rate in the structure, (2) the number of rates in the structure, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 54 (3) the size (or sizes) of the spreads between rate steps, (4) the volume of borrowing to be allowed at each rate step, (5) whether these volumes should be defined in absolute dollar terms or as a ratio to some measure of deposits or assets, and (6) whether the rate steps should be changed Judgementally, or tied automatically in a fixed relationship to the federal funds rate. While these questions are complicated, experience with the existing system of administrative controls would provide some guidance on what ought to be introduced as the initial settings in the graduated rate structure] The settings could then be adJusted as experience developedland to the extent specific policy obJectives were modified I 1 For example, the I slope of the graduated scale, as determi~ed by the size of borrowing tranches and the increment in interest rates between tranches, could be changed over time to reflect more or less accommodation of borrowing. To avoid the forecasting uncer- tainties that arise under the present system of Judgementally administered guidelines, the proposed system would have no guidelines on the appropriateness and frequency of borrowing. Under a system of this type institutions would pre- sumably increase their discount window borrowing until its marginal cost equalled the prevailing federal funds rate--i.e the cost of alternative funds Thus, the spread of the funds rate over the minimum borrowing rate would be determined by the aggregate shortfall of nonborrowed reserves from total reserve demand. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 55 For example, suppose the amount of borrowing allowed at each step in the graduated rate structure was $25,000 with increments of 25 basis points between each step, and that initially nonborrowed reserves were provided in an amount such that the shortfall from total reserve demand, given a funds rate of rf' was $1.1 billion. Suppose further that the minimum borrowing rate (MBR) was set 75 basis points below rf If there were no administrative guidelines on frequency and duration of ~borrowing,and,institutions could borrow even when they were -net sellers of federal funds, then all institutions would find it attractive to borrow each week up to the point where the marginal discount rate was equal to the funds rate institution would borrow roughly $75,000,!/ In this case, each For every 25 basis point change in the spread between the funds rate and the MBR, borrowing would change in the same direction by about $375 million Of course, there still would be some uncertainty about the intraweekly behavior of the funds rate. In Judging how much to borrow at the discount window early in the statement week, banks would have to have some motion of the level of the funds rate later in the week. Errors in such expectations would still lead to some variance in the relation between money market rates and borrowing levels. !/ If this agreement had been applied to the 15,000 member commercial banks that were eligible to borrow at the Federal Reserve in 1979, total borrowings would have amounted to $1 1 billion Regression equations of actual experience suggest, however, that this number probably ought to be raised by $500 million to allow for frictional borrowing that is not interest sensitive https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 56 A system that sets the tranches in absolute dollar amounts, as in the example above, relies on the interbank federal funds market to distribute the borrowed funds to those institutions with actual reserve needs. The borrowing pattern that results--with every institution borrowing a relatively small amount from the window--is quite different from the historical pattern for member banks, where borrowings for individual institutions range to millions of dollars Clearly, if a large institution suffered an unexpected deposit outflow of·several million dollars near the end of the day and was forced to the window because there were few funds available in the funds market, its marginal cost of borrowing would be quite high especially if this occurred toward the end of the statement week This type of situation might also induce sizable intra- day fluctuations in the federal funds rate, as institutions with reserve deficits would be willing to pay a larger premium for funds borrowed in the market to avoid the high marginal discount rate. An alternative approach, needs vary with size of institution, which recognizes that reserve would be to make each bor- rowing tranche a percentage of some size characteristic of the borrower--for example, required reserves, deposits, or capital The tranches could be set to yield roughly the same amount of borrowing as in the illustrative example above, but a much larger proportion of the borrowing would be done by the larger https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 57 institutions. Given the assumption that all institutions would borrow until their marginal discount rate equalled the funds rate, the aggregate borrowing schedule would still be more predictable since at each funds rate expected total borrowing could be derived by summing over the amounts each institution would be likely to borrow at that funds rate. If the amount of borrowing at a given spread between the funds rate and the MBR were, say, higher than desired, then 1 borrowing could be reduced in three ways without resorting to administrative pressure reduce the spread between the funds rate and the MBR, reduce the size of the borrowing tranches, or increase the increment in the borrowing rate between each tranche. Existing Reserve Bank practices for administering adJustment credit generally lead to an increase in administrative pressure on individual borrowers, when, among other things, its borrowing becomes more frequent. The alternative discount window procedure proposed here could, of course, be designed to continue some sort of frequency guidelines, along with the graduated rate schedule based on amount. Such a feature introduces "progressive pre3sure'' into the cost of discount borrowing sporadic borrowing due to temporary fluctuations in the supply and demand for reserves is accommodated, with no unnecessary movements in market I rates, but borrowing of longer duration, which reflects more https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 58 - permanent shifts in the need for reserves, will bear a progres- sively higher cost to borrowers over time and thus will be transmitted to increases in market interest rates. Although progressive pressure would permit the discount window to act as an offsetting factor to underlying shifts in reserve demand while inducing only a minimum of unwanted shortterm variability in market rates, it would also tend to weaken the ~esk's ability to predict borrowings. Any administrative rule that makes the effective cost of borrowing depend on the number of times banks borrow over a given interval creates uncertainty about the relationship between total borrowing and money market conditions because the potential costs for each borrower depend upon his past borrowing record and his expectations about future spreads between the discount rate and market rates The case for a graduated discount rate. The princi- pal advantage of a graduated rate approach is that it allows the Federal Reserve to spell out more precisely how the discount window will respond to demands for borrowed reserves instead of trying to rely on 12 individual Reserve Bank discount officers to provide uniform interpretations of a rather general set of administrative guidelines With a graduated rate arrangement, the System can be more confident that any basic shift in demands for reserves will produce a timely response in market interest rates, which then feeds back appropriately on money demand. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 59 This closer relationship between borrowings and money market conditions should make it easier for the Desk to Judge the ultimate impact of its actions on the money stock. While a structure of graduated discount rates like the example described above may seem somewhat cumbersome on its face, it could actually be expressed and explained as a relatively simple arithmetic calculation Moreover, because application of the rate graduation would start afresh with each new statement week and all administrative constraints on appropriateness and frequency of borrowing would be eliminated, the role of the discount window in borrowers' fund management strategies would be simplified. There would be no incentive to hold off borrowing this week in order "to keep one's powder dry" for possibly greater needs in later weeks. A graduated discount rate procedure would also be consistent with other possible innovative approaches to discount policy For example, the rate structure could be adJusted using either discretionary actions or by tying the discount rate automatically to the federal funds rate. If the structure of discount rates were changed by discretion, the System could continue to use such changes to signal adJustments in general monetary policy In fact, such an approach would add new dimensions for signaling purposes, since the Federal Reserve could chanQe the minimum rate in the structure, the slope of the schedule, or both. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 60 The case against a graduated discount rate. The initial problem with any plan that progresses the discount rate upward with additional amounts of borrowing is that the Federal Reserve's explicit authority to use this approach was withdrawn the Congress in 1923. The enabling provisions of the original Federal Reserve Act included language stating that the "discount rate may be graduated, ... or progressed, on the basis of the amount extended." Immediately after the First World War, when heavy member bank borrowing was thought to be exacerba~ing inflation, several Federal Reserve Banks did elect to scale their rates upward on the basis of amounts borrowed In some cases the resulting marginal charges reached levels of nearly 90 percent Because these steep rates created a substantial backlash of complaint among bankers, the Congress (in 1923) deleted the wording of the act that had authorized graduation of rates by quantity borrowed Board lawyers are presently examining the legislative history of subsequent discount window changes to determine whether the authority to implement progressive discount rates might have been implic1 tly restored by the Congress Absent such authorization, there is serious question whether the Federal• Reserve possesses the authority to graduate discom1t, -, -, rates by quantity without some new indication from the Congress that it believes this approach is acceptable. Even without this statutory impediment, other aspects of a graduated rate proposal could create significant difficulties. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 61 For example, since the lowest discount rates in any graduated structure would be below the federal funds rate, any institution eligible to borrow at the Federal Reserve would be attracted by this below-market opportunity. Because there would be no guide- lines requiring potential borrowers either to turn first to alternative sources of funds or to limit their borrowing to "appropriate" purposes, eligible institutions would be encouraged to draw all the Federal Reserve credit they were entitled to, up to the point where the marginal cost of such credit was roughly equal to the cost of funds from the private market. Information now being reported to Federal Reserve Banks shows that roughly 20,000 depository institutions are eligible to borrow at Federal Reserve Banks under provisions of the Monetary Control Act. Since it would be advantageous for all of these to use the discount window under a graduated rate scheme, the number of regular borrowers at the window would mushroom. In 1979, less than 2,000 member commercial banks borrowed at the window during the year, and on a week-to-week basis the number borrowing was seldom over 400, even during periods of peak borrowing. Since early September when the window was opened to nonmember institutions on a regular basis, the maximum number of such borrowers for any statement week has not exceeded 50. While borrowers under a graduated rate plan would no longer have to be monitored closely to assure that their use of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 62 - Federal Reserve credit was appropriate, they would still need to be monitored for creditworthiness. Because of the number and diversity of institutions involved, this would represent a maJor undertaking. Moreover, if most of the 20,000 institutions with access to the window took full advantage of their eligibility to borrow, the daily task of processing loans and loan collateral would require substantially larger staffs at the Reserve Banks. In addition, a graduated rate approach might be more complicated than presumed. In the initial stages of transition, it would take considerable trial and error to determine appropriate sizes for the rate steps and borrowing tranches. Consequently, in this possibly protracted period of experimentation, forecasts of expected borrowing at the window would probably be much more erratic than they are now. The presumption that past borrowing patterns of member banks could serve as a useful model for predicting expected future results would probably prove to be too sanguine. Not only would the abandonment of all administrative controls be likely to change the borrowing behavior of member banks substantially but it would al so be difficult to predict how soon and how completely other types of institutions would adapt to their new borrowing rights Finally, the different optional approaches that might be followed in implementing any actual plan raise several additional questions https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis One suggested option is to tie the structure - 63 - of graduated rates in a fixed spread relationship,to ~he federal funds rate, presumably so the base rate (or rates) will fluctuate at a constant spread(s) below the funds rate. If this approach were followed, borrowers would be assured of continuous tranches of credit at favorable rates. As they perceived this to be the case, they could be expected to begin allocating these assured tranches of borrowing to somewhat longer-term forms of lending. In effect, they would be treating these tranches as a basic borrowing privilege, which would operate in a limited way as a partial substitute for capital. To the extent this proved to be the case, the approach might prove quite vulnerable to attack as an unwarranted subsidy. Borrowing from the unlimited tranche provided at a penalty rate above the f/t'deral funds rate would have essentially the same purposes as those served by a single penalty discount rate system. But the provision of credit in tranches Just below the funds rate would tend to limit pressure on the penalty tranche and thus produce less general volatility in market interest rates than the single penalty rate system. The alternative approach of establishing a structure of graduated rates on a discretionary basis, without any fixed relationship to the federal funds rate, would provide more leeway to adJust the number of rate steps, spreads within the rate steps, and the size of the borrowing tranche at each step. This would add substantial flexibility to the graduated rate system https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - 64 - as a policy instrument with subtle announcement effects. But it would add to its complexity and in the process probably make forecasts of expected borrowing less predictable, at least te~porarily. I https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Appendix A 1../ Aggregate Borrowing and Money Market Interest Rates To test the linkage between borrowed reserves and the spread of the federal funds rate over the discount rate, a variety of econometric relationships were estimated relating borrowing to this spread and to an assortment of other variables that measure various aspects of conditions in the money market. Some of the more successful relationships are presented in Table 1.2/ All of the results were obtained from weekly data running from the beginning of 1970 through September 1979 ~/ As the table indicates, the spread variable alone accounts for most of the explanatory power of the various equations Using a constant, the spread, and the lagged error, somewhat more than 80 percent of the variance of member bank borrowing can be explained. The standard error of the regres- sion is about $250 million or about one-third the average level of borrowing over this period. A similar equation to model 1 was tested in which the discount rate and the federal funds rate were entered separately rather than subtracted one from the other. When this was done, it was found that the coefficients on the two rates were of opposite sign and of essentially the same magnitude. This result strongly suggests that it is the spread This appendix was excerpted from Johnson and Spitzer, 11 Recent Behavior of ~ember Bank Borrowing. 11 t-statistics for each coefficient appear in parenthesis. The emergency borrowing by Franklin National Bank in 1974 was excluded from the data.' https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 2 between the two interest rates that influences borrowing and that the absolute level of the rates has little if any detectable influence. Specifically, model 1 suggests that an increase in the spread of 10 basis points will be associated on average with an increase in member bank borrowing of $40 million. A clear implication of this result is that member banks historically have responded in a systematic way to the rate advantage of borrowing from the discount window. Model 2 in T~ble 1 is the same as the first model except that the spread variable is also used in the regression in a squared form l/ This specification improved the fit of the model marginally and implies that successive increases in the spread of equal amounts result in progressively smaller increases in borrowing 2/ Some improvement in the fit also can be obtained by adding the level of required reserves Model 3 shows the effect of required reserves without the spread squared variable and model 4 includes both of these additional variables The estimated coefficients indicate that for every $1 billion increase in required reserves, member bank borrowing increases on average by about $35 million In effect, this variable scales For values of spread less than zero, the spread squared is ' multiplied by -1. A somewhat implausible implication of this specification is that increases in the spread beyond about 5 percentage points are associated with progressively smaller levels of borrowing. During the period over which the equation was estimated, there was one brief period in 1974 in which the spread was above 5 percentage points on a weekly average basis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 3 Table 1 REGRESSION RESULTS: BORROWING AS DEPENDENT VARIABLE 1/ (Weekly data prior to October 6) Independent variables and summary statistics Model 1 2 3 4 5 Independent variables Constant Spread 493 (12. 3) 482 (14.0) 401 (15. 6) (12.6) 577 -641 (-2.3) (-LS) 392 (16.1) 567 (13.0) 570 (13.2) -57 (-4.5) -57 (-4.6) .033 (4.1) (3. 2) -57 (-4.4) Spread squared . 037 (4.0) Required reserves -4 36 -761 (-2.4) Change in required reserves .027 .034 (2.3) Summary statistics Standard error of regression 254 250 251 247 246 -2 R .836 .841 .841 .846 .848 Durbin-Watson 2. 28 2.29 2.25 2.25 2.24 .69 .65 .68 .68 ,n2 Rho 1. The spread is measured in percentage points, and the reserve aggregates are measured in millions of dollars. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 4 the regression and indicates that there is a weak tendency for member bank borrowing to increase along with the level of reserves The last version of the model shown in Table 1 includes the change in required reserves in addition to the level The estimated coefficients imply that borrowing is greater in the initial week in which there is an increase in required reserves than in subsequent weeks The desire to compare the borrowing relationship after October 6 to earlier experience raises an econometric issue. The regressions reported above were obtained from models that implicitly assumed that the spread between money market rates was determined by the Desk's actions and that the level of borrowing was endogenously determined In other words, the System's actions fixed the relative price of borrowed and nonborrowed reserves, and banks were free to choose, within the limits imposed by administrative practices, how much they would borrow at the discount window been reversed Since October 6, the situation has The System continues to fix the price of reserves borrowed at the discount window but not the federal funds rate, the price of nonborrowed reserves. Instead the aggregate level of borrowing is determined (ignoring the weekly variation in excess reserves) by the System's adherence to nonborrowed reserve targets Under lagged reserve accounting, required reserves less nonborrowed reserves necessarily equals borrowing at the discount window (again ignoring excess reserves) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis With A - 5 aggregate borrowing predetermined, the funds rate must adJust to clear the market for nonborrowed reserves. Thus, it is appro- priate subsequent to October 6 to treat borrowing as exogenously determined and the spread as endogenous. The description above oversimplifies the differences in behavior before and after October 6. The System still main- tians some limits on the range over which the funds rate is allowed to fluctuate. These limits sometimes have caused the Desk to alter its nonborrowed reserve targets With the level of borrowing sometimes affected by the behavior of the funds rate, the direction of causality is not entirely one way under current operating procedures Still, as was discussed earlier, the actual level of borrowing in most weeks has been fairly close to the level originally envisioned when setting the weekly targets, thus it seems that treating borrowing as exogenous is generally appropriate. It should be kept in mind that the same general demand curve for borrowing is being estimated using data before and after October. 1 above Equation 1 below corresponds to model 3 in Table One can transform this model by solving for borrowing and obtain equation 2. This is the sort of model that should be estimated using data subsequent to October 6 Moreover, the coefficients obtained can be related to the results obtained from the era when the funds rate was being pegged. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 6 (1) Borrowing= a+ b. (Spread)+ c. (Required reserves) + u (2) Sprea d 1 b = a+ b1 -b Borrovnng - bC (Required reserves) u Table 2 below reports results for a few models of borrowing behavior estimated with data from the first 33 weeks of experJ.ence with reserves targeting. The special borrowing of First Pennsylvania Bank was excluded from total borrowing, because such borrowing does not reflect funds rate pressures and was treated by the Desk as beLng in the nature of nonborrowed reserves In addition to the same type of variables used in the earlier models, a dummy variable set equal to one in the weeks that the 3 percent surcharge was in effect also was included. The regression results presented in Table 2 for the first 33 weeks of reserve targeting indicate that borrooing does help explain the spread but that required reserves do not. It should not be particularly surprising that required reserves were not significant, since they were included as a scale variable and there was little trend evident in this variable during the relatively short interval over which this equation was estimated The surcharge dummy also was significant and indicates that the spread was about 2 percentage points higher in the weeks in which it was in effect. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 7 Table 2 REGRESSION RESULTS: SPREAD AS DEPENDENT VARIABLE 1/ (Weekly data subsequent to October 6) Independent variables and summary statistics - Model 1 2 3 4 ,-0. 94 (-0.4) -9.21 (-0.8) -1.19 (-0.6) -7.25 (-0.7) .00084 (2.8) . 00080 (2.6) .00087 (3. 3) .00084 (3.1) Independent variables Constant Borrowing Required reserves .00013 (0.6) .00019 (0.3) Surcharge dummy 1.95 (3.1) 1. 91 (3.0) Summary statistics Standard error of regression . 984 . 991 .870 .880 -2 R .795 . 792 .840 .836 Durbin-Watson 1.20 1.20 1.52 1.49 .93 .94 • 92 .93 Rho 1. The spread 1s measured 1n percentage points, and the reserve aggregates are measured 1n millions of dollars. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A - 8 If the structure of this model had not changed subsequent to October 6, then the reciprocal of the coeff1c1ent on the spread 1n model 3 {Table l) should be roughly coeff 1c1ent on borrowing 1n model 4 {Table 2). does not appear to hold, however. equal to the This rel a t1onsh1p At-test 1nd1cates that the coeff1c1ent on.borrowing 1s s1gn1f1cantly smaller than the reciprocal of the estimated coeff1c1ent on the spread. Spec1- f1cally, model 4 of Table 2 1mpl1es that an increase 1n the spread of 10 basis points was assoc1zted on average with an increase of borrowing of $110 million as compared to the $40 million increase implied by the equations fitted with data before October 6. It thus would appear that for a given spread, banks on average were more willing to borrow from the discount window subsequent to October 6. While 1t can be concluded with a high level of confidence that banks have been more willing to borrow recently, it should be noted that the point estimate of the coefficient on borrowing obtained from recent data has a substantial variance and could be quite different from the "true" value of this parameter. It also appears that the borrowing relationship has become more variable since the advent of reserve targeting It can be shown that the reciprocal of the coefficient on borrowing 1n model 4 {Table 2) multiplied by the estimated standard error of that model should be roughly comparable to the standard https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A- 9 error of model 3 (Table 1) assuming that the underlying vari- ability of the relationship had not changed. appear to be the case. This does not An F-test indicates that the standard error of model 4 (Table 2) is significantly greater than the estimate of the standard error obtained from data prior to October 6. Specifically, the point estimates indicate that the standard error of the borrowing relationship was at least 35 percent greater after October 6 than before. In sum, it appears that the relationship between borrowing and money market rates spreads has changed and has become more variable suhsequent to October 6. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis IMPLEMENTING THE NEW OPERATING PROCEDURES THE VIEW FROM THE TRADING DESK January 1981 Paper Written for a Federal Reserve Staff Review of Monetary Control Procedures by Fred J. Levin and Paul Meek January 21, 1981 IMPLEMENTING THE NEW OPERATING PROCEDURES: THE VIEW FROM THE TRADING DESK CONTENTS Introduction and Summary I. II. III. Open Market Operations Under the New Reserve Approach A. Day-to-Dav Operations B. Frequency and Timing of Desk Operations Experience in Hitting Reserve c. Objectives The Market's Perception of Monetary Policy A. Operational or Institutional Changes IV. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Appendix: Technical Adjustments to the Reserve Paths PAGE 1 7 10 17, 19 26 34 A-1 Implementing the New Operating Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk* Introduction and Summary Open market operations have functioned reasonably well since October 6, 1979, under the new supply-oriented reserve strategy. The strategy itself entails a procedure for translating the FOMC's desired growth rates for the monetary aggregates into intermeeting Desk obJectives for nonborrowed reserves (NBR). The procedures allow for weekly adjust- ment for changes in the relation between required reserves and the appropriate money supply measures, and weekly decisions on whether to adjust the NBR path to speed up the correction of undesired money growth. Over all. the Desk views the approach as a significant improvement in generating the kinds of portfolio decisions and interest rate changes needed to resist sustained and potentially destabilizing movements in the monetary aggregates. The present memorandum analyzes how the Desk has implemented the new procedures since their inception, highlighting the operational changes that have resulted from the modification in strategy. It also examines how market parti- cipants have tracked monetary policy under the new procedures and whether operational or institutional changes could reduce the variability of interest rate response without compromising *Fred J. Levin and Paul Meek were primarily responsible for the preparation of this study. Robert Van Wicklen provided able research support. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2 the new strategy. (An appendix discusses some technical issues involving intermeeting adjustments to the reserve paths.) (1) A summary of the principal findings follows: The new strategy shifted the focus of weekly Desk operations from the federal funds rate to nonborrowed reserves. The Desk depended more heavily on staff NBR estimates in determining the amount and timing of operations. Daily market operations were concentrated principally b~tween 11:30 a.m. and 12:15 p.m. in order I I to emphasize that they were addressed to managing I reserves and were largely independent of the existing I I I level of the 1ieder,al funds rate. (2) • Reserve forecast errors continued to be quite large--with the miss in the weekly average of market factors equal to about $675 million on the first day of the statement week and $145 million on the last day of the statement week. The variability of Federal Re- serve float continued the chief source of forecast error. (3) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis As a supplement to the reserve projections, the Desk found the federal funds rate a somewhat useful, although not consistently reliable, indicator _of- - , " reserve availability. It did point in the right direc- tion about two-thirds of the time when sugqestinq a miss in the reserve proJections; for errors of $500 million or more it was accurate on seven of nine occasions. 3 (4) The number of Desk operations to supply or absorb reserves in the market through repurchase agreements and matched sale-purchase transactions were about one-third less than in the previous year. Such temporary actions were notably less frequent before the weekend than had been true earlier. (5) The absolute deviation in nonborrowed reserves from path averaged $184 million over fifteen separate reserve periods. There was a tendency for nonborrowed reserves to come in below path in contrast to total reserve~ which ran above path. The average shortfall in nonborrowed reserves was $130 million. (6) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis To a considerable extent, deviations from the nonborrowed reserve path were tolerated, after consultation with the Board staff and Chairman, whenever it was potentially misleading to market participants to seek sharp changes in member bank borrowing in the final week of a reserve period from what had recently prevailed or was likely to result from new FOMC instructions. Deviations also arose when borrowing ran sub- stantially above or below expectations built into the reserve paths during the early part of the final week. Confronted with the alternative. of sharp declines or increases in borrowing and interest rates after the week.end, the Desk sometimes accepted a miss in the nonborrowed reserve path. In the broader context, this 4 smoothing process has not interferred with the shifts in I , interest rate levels resulting from the changing impact of the demand for reserves relative to the nonborrowed reserves path. (7) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The perceptions and actions of market participants have been significantly affected by the variability of interest rates associated with the supply-oriented strategy. Market participants continue to use the fecPral funds rate as t~e pri~~ry indicator of policy's current thrust, despite the Desk's focus on reserve considerations. An analysis for the past 14 months of the relation between borrowing and the spread between the fed~ral funds rate and the discount rate suoaests that the relationship is considerably more variable than in 1972-74. In addition, changes in borrowing appear to have less impact on the rate spread in the recent period than earlier. The supply-oriented strategy produced a rapid increase in borrowing from a low level between midAugust and mid-September 1980, but the impact on the federal funds rate was MO(h.5t. In such a situation. when banks have had little recourse to the window for some months, the System could perhaps be somewhat more aggressive in lowering the NBR path to speed up achievement of the FOMC's monetary obJectives. However, in 1980, subsequent increases in the discount rate and restoration of a rate surcharge constituted effective actions in the same direction. 5 (8) The variability of the relationship between borrowing and the rate spread adds to the market's difficulty in tracking the Federal Reserve's current policy posture. This variability contributes to the short-run volatility of interest rates, which,in turn, may well add to underwriting costs in the money and capital markets. However, the market's overreactions tend most of the time to reinforce the System's efforts to attain its objectives. (9) If ool icymakers consider it desirable to reduce the noise content of the market's perceptions of System policy, one might reduce the variability of the rate response to borrowing changes by modifications of (a) the discount window or (b) the routine conduct of open market operations. Whether one considers this desirable depends upon where one strikes the balance between reducing interest rate volatility and insuring that short-term interest rates are free to respond to changes in both reserve pressures and market expectations of further change. (10) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Two issues involving procedures for adJusting the reserve paths between Committee meetings to reflect changes in the money-reserve relationship deserve further attention. First, there is the question of whether the current practice of typically making only partial adjustments to the paths each week for technical factors should be cont~nued or whether all potential adJustments should be incorporated into the paths (even though this would https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 6 mean revising the adjustments weekly on the basis of new information). Second, there is the question of how much policy weight should be given between meetings to the broad versus the narrow money measures. Currently, because of the structure of legal reserve requirements, the primary emphasis is on the narrow aggregates. Moreover, their relative weight will increase further as the provisions of the Monetary Control Act are phased in. The Committee may want to consider whether path procedures should be modified so as to increase the weight given to M-2 in operations between meetings. 7 Open Market Operations Under the New Reserve Approach Since October 6, 1979,the Desk has worked between Committee meetings with paths for total and nonborrowed reserves designed to be consistent with the Committee's short-run objectives for growth of the monetary aggregates. Operationally, the major focus has been on hitting the nonborrowed reserves path, the reserve measure which is reasonably subject to short-run Desk control. The Desk's primary concern has been to achieve average path levels for nonborrowed reserves over blocks of weeks encompassing either the full intermeeting period or two separate subperiods when the meetings are relatively far apart. The Desk begins each intermeeting period with a path for nonborrowed reserves (the total reserve path estimated by the Board staff less the Committee's initial assumption for borrowing at the discount window). Each week, as new information becomes available, senior Board staff and the Account Management review, und revise,if appropriate, the reserve paths to maintain their consistency with the Committee's aggregate objectives. Then the Desk must translate the reserve paths into weekly operating obJectives for nonborrowed reserves. in the following way: This is done First, the staff proJects the demand for total reserves--that is, required reserves based on actual or estimated deposits plus excess reserves. Second, the average projected demand for total reserves over the period is compared to the average nonborrowed reserve path over the period. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis This, given actual levels of borrowing in earlier 8 weeks, provides an estimate of average borrowing over the remaining weeks if the average nQnborrowed reserve ~ath is to be achieved. Finally, this steady level of borrowing is subtracted from the projected demand for total reserves in each of the remaining weeks to give a series of weekly nonborrowed reserve objectives. Using this averaging approach, the procedure tends to smooth weekly changes in money market conditions but not at the expense of delaying the interest rate response to a monetary overshoot or a shortfall. Indeed, the approach tends to speed up the response by about one week from what it might otherwise be under lagged reserve accounting. For example, if deposit growth exceeds path in the first week of a reserve period,the Desk's procedure calls for an estimated higher level of borrowing in the second week to be sustained over the remainder of the period. Otherwise, given lagged reserve accounting, the rise in borrowing would not be expected to occur until week three, when the demand for required reserves was boosted and the resulting increase in borrowing would be sharper. As the Desk works to keep the supply of nonborrowed reserves in line with its average path level, money market rates tend to adjust automatically ,.whenever.growth of the monetary ... - " .,.~ ~ aggregates deviates from the Committee's objectives. For example, in the spring of 1980, when monetary growth fell below these objectives, the demand for total reserves (required reserves https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 9 plus banks' normal desired holdings of excess reserves) exceeded the nonborrowed reserve path by less than the initial borrowing assumption. With the Desk supplying nonborrowed reserves in line with its path, money market rates eased dramatically as banks found reserves plentiful and thus were encouraged to cut back on their borrowing from the discount window. More recently, in fall 1980, as monetary growth ran above the Committee's objectives and, hence, the demand for total reserves exceeded the nonborrowed reserve path by more than the initial borrowing assumption, money market rates rose sharply as banks were forced to step up their borrowing from the discount window in order to meet their reserve requirements. In each case, the resulting changes in money market rates tenoed to encourage banks and the public to alter their portfolio behavior in a way that worked in time to bring monetary growth back in line with the Committee's objectives. At times, as seemed appropriate, the senior Board staff and Account Manager, in consultation with the Chairman, accelerated the adJustrnent process by changing the nonborrowed reserve path relative to the total reserve path. The nonborrowed reserve path was lowered when the demand for total reserves was running significantly above path and raised when the demand for total reserves was running significantly below path. This tended to encourage even sharper changes in borrowing and money market rates, and thus tended to promote a speedier return to desired growth rates for the monetary aggregates. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Increases 10 in the discount rate also worked to hasten the adjustment process. Normallyv the System does not respond to a discount rate change by altering the nonborrowed reserve path. result, banks have bid up the federal As a funds rate to maintain roughly the same spread previously prevailing between the two rates. Day-to-Day Operations In facing its operational task each day, the Desk has before it an objective for average nonborrowed reserves to be achieved in that week and in subsequent weeks. It also has projections, prepared independently by the Board and New York staffs, of the supply of nonborrowed reserves for several weeks ahead, assuming no further actions are undertaken by the Desk. These projections reflect estimates of technical factors such as Federal Reserve float, currency in circulation, and Treasury balances held at the Reserve Banks. (The proJections normally assume that the pool of foreign account short-term investment funds will be arranged internally with the System, although the Desk can choose to execute all or a portion of these orders in the market as one way of supplying reserves.) A comparison of the nonborrowed reserves objective with the projected supply of nonborrowed reserves leads to an indication of the amount of reserves that needs to be added or withdrawn to meet the objective for the week. These comparisons are the primary determinant of open market operations under the current approach. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis However, a number of factors make the Desk's 11 t1sk considerably more complicated than simply p~oviding or absorbing reserves according to the difference between the projected reserve supply and the reserve objective. For one thing, the level of borrowing within a statement week can, on occasion, deviate significantly from what was expected in the construction of the nonborrowed reserve path. For example, if borrowing runs far enough above expecta- tions during the early days of a week, mathematically there might be no way of attaining the average borrowing level implied by the nonborrowed reserve objective for the week as a whole. The Desk is then faced with the alternative of adhering strictly to its nonborrowed reserve objective and, hence, allowing huge excess reserves and an overshoot in total reserves or else absorbing some of the excess reserves and coming out below its objective for nonborrowed reserves. On the opposite side, if borrowing runs well below expectations during the early part of a week, the Desk is faced wi~h the alternative of forcing huge borrowing on the final day or else accommodating some of the shortfall and coming out above its obJective for nonborrowed reserves. The problem with forcing a big bulge in borrowing, or encouraging overly abundant reserves-, on the final day of a week is the risk that banks may overreact in managing their reserve positions in the following statement week. An unduly tight Wednesday can carry over to sharply higher money market rates and greater-than-desired borrowing levels in the next week, while an unduly easy Wednesday https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 12 conversely may tend to result in sharply lower money market rates and under borrowing in the next week. The Desk sought to avoid these difficulties by directing the intraweekly pattern of open market operations in a way that would encourage the amount of borrowing desired over the week. For example, if borrowing were starting out the week on the high side of expectations, the Desk might add reserves before the weekend in order to ease market pressures and reduce borrowing~ even though there was no projected reserve need for the week as a whole. Then,having provided reserves early in the week, it would absorb the resulting excess later on. Despite the Desk's efforts, however, there . were many weeks when borrowing deviated significantly from expectations, and the Desk chose to accept a miss on its weekly nonborrowed reserve objective rather than provide overabundant total reserves or force a huge end-of-week rise in borrowing, (For a further discussion, see below.) Another operational problem is that the reserve projections themselves are subJect to a wide margin of error. For example, on the first day of the statement week the average absolute projection error of weekly average nonborrowed reserves (apart from System actions to affect reserves) over the October 1979-80 period amounted to about $675 million, or about l 1/2 percent of nonborrowed reserves (see Table 1). The accuracy of the projections naturally improves over the week as data become available each day on the actual supply of reserves on https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Table 1 FRBNY Resei:ve Projection Errors by Major Corrponent for Selected Years* {Weekly average, millions of dollars) Nonborrowed One week ahead (Thursday) forecasts reserves ~rrket fac!ors) 8 A Addendum: CUrrency Treasury Float deposits I'll I in circulation lei Other factors ,~r !Al 628 31 597 IA! l~I - IAI iel i~I lel 873 409 1,681 152 453 158 required reserves 1977-78 711 1,867 592 1978-79 887 1,435 861 1,189 334 692 140 519 221 776 65 707 1979-80 673 1,057 619 350 535 170 551 176 646 155 724 918 I-' N Pl One day ahead (Wednes~~}- forecasts 41 1,681 52 453 55 628 17 597 182 1,189 49 692 54 519 73 776 35 707 140 37 535 30 551 73 646 48 724 1977-78 118' 1,867 110 1978-79 176 1,435 1979-80 144 1,057 873 918 * From third staterrent week in October to second statenent week in October of following year. jel = mean absolute forecast error. l~l = nean absolute https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis change. 13 the previous day. However, even on the last day of the week, the average absolute projection error of weekly average nonborrowed reserves came to about $145 million over the period and last day errors of $500 million or more for the weekly average were not unknown. The major factor accounting for reserve projection errors continues to be misestimates of float. Indeed, the forecast errors of float amount to almost as much as the errors of all other technical factors combined. A number of studies have been undertaken over the years to improve the accuracy of the float projections. The most promising approach, however, would seem to be through institutional changes in the check collection system and Federal Reserve procedures that would reduce its variability. When large projection errors occur,they can hamper the Desk's efforts to achieve its nonborrowed reserve objective and mislead market participants on the System's policy stance. For exampl~ an overestimate of reserve availability, which leads the Desk to supply less than the reserves needed to meet the nonborrowed reserve objective, can leave banks scurrying to the discount window to meet their reserve requirements, accompanied by a sharp rise in the federal funds rate at the end of the week as banks seek out other sources of reserves as well. The market could interpret this as a tightening of System policy, and other short-terro rates would then adjust https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis l upward accordingly. 14 The result might be that banks would continue to borrow heavily in the following week, and it might take a week (or several weeks if there is a string of projection errors in the same direction) until borrowing could be brought back in line with the level assumed in constructing the nonborrowed reserve path. Because the projections are subject to a high degree of error, the Desk also looks at other indicators of reserve availability, such as conditions in the federal funds market and the volume of dealer offerings at various rates when it solicits propositions for repurchase and matched sale-pur9hase transactdons. Given the level of the discount rate and a rough notion of the demand function for borrowing, the Desk has some idea of the range within which the funds rate could be expected to trade consistent with the mixture of nonborrowed and borrowed reserves that it is seeking. If actual trading levels for funds deviate significantly from expectations,this can be an indication of a miss in the reserve projections. The behavior of the funds market, however, is also not a wholly reliable indicator of reserve availability. buying or selling federal In funds, banks themselves are working with projections of their own positions that uncertain and changeable throughout the week. are highly The funds rate, therefore, can move contrary to actual reserve supplies in the banking system if only a few large banks misjudge their positions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Moreover, the money center banks,in particular, 15 try to anticipate what actions other participants might take that would influence the funds rate, including actions by the Desk. They are also conscious that their own actions, or inactions, may affect the funds market significantly. Thus, banks tend to hold back in bidding for funds if they expect that the Desk will soon be entering the market to add reserves, or to sell funds if they believe the Desk is likely to be in the market to drain reserves. The observation that the Desk has a normal time period in the day in which most of its transactions are initiated leads banks to be especially likely to defer action during that time. Ironically, the more the Desk confines action to a specified time of day to divorce operations from the federal funds rate, the less reliable the rate becomes as a reserve indicator because of the tendency for banks to await Desk action. For these re,.asons, the Desk is cautious in using the-funds rate as a reserve indicator. The data in tables 2 and 3 attempt to measure how useful the funds rate has been as a check on reserve projections since the inception of the October 6 program. They show the number of days in which the Desk either took or deferred actions that would have been called for by the New York reserve projections because federal funds were trading at rates out of line with expectations,-~hus suggesting a miss in the ' reserve projections. For each of these days, they measure the error in reserve projections as reflected by the difference between projected average free reserves for the week and actual https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 15a Table 2 Federal Funds Rate as Indicator of Reserve Supplies, Surmiary October 8, 19791 throuQ!i December 17, 1980 Days when f edera 1 funds trading influenced open market operations by suggesting error in FRBNY reserve projections Total period Nuni:ler of days 31 Federal funds rate: Useful indicator Fa 1se indicator Subperiod when projection errors of weekly average :reserves exceeded $500 million 21 10 9 FedP"cll funds rate: Useful indicator False indicator https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 7 2 15b Table 3 Federal Funds Rate as Indicator of Reserve Supplies October 8, 1979 through Decerrber 17, 1980 Dates when f edera 1 funds trading influenced open narket operations by suggesting error in FRBNY reserve projections Funds rate suggested that reserve projections: overstate actual supplies+ llllderstate actual supplies - Reserve projection error: Projected less actual free reserves, excluding open market operations (weekly average, millions of dollars) 1979 Wednesday, October 17 Ivbnday, October 29 Tuesday, October 30 Wednesday, October 31 Friday, November 23 Monday, November 26 Tuesday, November 27 Wednesday, November 28 Tuesday, December 4 Tuesday, December 11 + + + + + -94 +1,173 +444 +381 -1,993 -745 -637 -311 -616 +279 1980 Wednesday, January 9 Monday, March 17 M:Jnday, April 7 Tuesday, April 8 Friday, April 11 Wednesday, May 14 Wednesday, June 18 M:mday, July 7 Thursday, July 31 Friday, August 1 Monday, August 4 Tuesday, August 26 Wednesday, August 27 Thursday, September 11 Friday, Septeni:)er 19 Friday, October 3 Thursday, November 13 Wednesday, November 19 Thursday, November 20 TUesday, November 25 Monday, December 1 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis + + + + + + + + + +38 +38 -+46 -81 +810 +56 +86 -126 ·+10 , -239 -209 -363 + + + + -138 +429 -35 +693 +1,781 +319 +2,505 +260 +43 16 free reserves (excluding any subsequent open market operations) . 11 Of the 31 days in which Desk action was affected by the funds rate relative to expectations, there were21 days in which it provided useful information on reserve supplies--that is, when the funds rate was relatively high, projections were in fact overstating actual reserves, and when the funds rate was relatively low, projections were in fact understating actual reserves. The funds rate was a more accurate barometer on days when projection errors turned out to be sizable. For errors of $500 millio~ or more the funds rate was accurate on seven 1 out of nine days.- Aside from using the f~deral funds rate as an indicator of reserve supplies, the Desk also monitors the rate to insure that it stays within the limits of the Committee's broad range. 1/ Free reserves was chosen as the reserve measure in order to pick up misses in estimates of required reserves. While these were generally small, as one would expect given lagged reserve accounting, there were a few sizable errors that reflected misestimates of reserve ratios that the Desk would have accommodated in full if correct figures were known. Using nonborrowed reserves rather than free reserves as the reserve measure would not significantly alter the general conclusions reached in the text. 2/ It is interesting to note that the funds rate was a better indicator of reserve supplies in the early months of the new reserve approach when the Desk was first establishing the practice of largely confining Desk entries to a regular time period during the day and the market was unsure of the Desk's new strategy. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 17 The Desk looks at these limits more as defining acceptable weekly average federal funds rate trading rather than limits for individual days or points of time within days. Since the ranges have been fairly wide, varying between 4 and 8 1/2 percentage points, there have,in fact,been only a few occasions when the funds rate actually breached or threatened to breach the limits. On each occasion, tne effect on open market opera- tions was only temporary as the rate moved back within the range or the Committee adjusted the range. Frequency and Timing of Desk Operations With the Desk no longer aiming for a particular federal funds rate objective, the new reserve approach seems to have had a significant impact on the frequency of System operations in the market. The number of Desk interventions to arrange repurchase and matched sale-purchase transactions over the October 1979-0ctober 1980 period, for example, was down about one-third from the level of the previous year (table 4). Declines were registered each quarter and were not concentrated ~ in any particular part of the year. Judging from a four-month sample ( table 5) the sharpest drops were in the number of relatively small transactions (defined as less than $1 billion). Under the federal funds rate strategy such transactions were often used to signal the System's funds rate intentions even though projections showed no need for action. Under current procedures small transactions are usually arranged when the reserve need itself is small. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis While other factors 17a Table 4 NUmber of Desk InteJ:ventions in Market to Add or Drain Reserves on a Tenporary Basis 1977-78 1978-79 1979-80 51 41 Jan.-March 39 60 60 38 April-Jtme 68 60 July-sept.J/ 74 90 54 Total period 241 261 3.75 8 30 9 .Additional rounds 63 56 15 Preannounced for Thursday 15 7 outright transactions 20, 19 18 Foreign RP.s in market. 32 47 54 Period ocP. -Dec. 42 Mano items: Extemed rounds Y. Begins with thim statement week in OCtaber. 21 Ends with second statement week in October. Notes 1. IncludEsonly RP and MSP transactions in market (both for foreign customers and System Account). Outriqht transactions for System Account in market shown as memo item. 2. Exclude;pmannounced transactions far Thursday. These shown separately as IlB10 item.. 3. COUn1Sextended murds as one narket entr:y. Number of extended rounds shown as meno item. 4. COOn1s sinultaneous announ.cenent of transactiai with various maturities as one market entry~ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 17b Table 5 Number of Desk Interventions in Markett to Add or Drain Resexves on Tenporary Basis: by Day of Week fQlC' Varioos AlJIOtmts, of ReserVes Jj ______(JUn_e ~.E,@_§e~ 1979-SOL $1 billion or less Day More than $1 billion 1979 1980 1979 1980 Thursday 4 1 13 6 Friday 7 2 16 11 MJnday 7 1 13 11 Tuesday 6 2 14 12 Wednesraly 4 3 14 11 29 9 72 51 TotD1 Table 6 Nmt)eJ: of Desk Interventiais in Market to Add or Drain Resei:ves on ~ a z y Basis: by Time of Day ]J (Jlme 1::hrough S e ~ 19 7 9-0 0) Time 1979 1980 Before 11,: 30 34 3 11:30 to 12:15 36 49 After 12:15 Total 31 lof 8 60 1/ Pericxls oover fran third statement week in October to second etate:ri.e.nt week in October of following year. See notes to table 3. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 18 can influence the frequency of Desk operations (for example, the variability of reserve projections from day to day) it seems likely, given the extent and persistence of the decline, that the adoption of the new procedures is the dominant explanation. The new procedures also seem to have had a significant impact on the timing of operations, both in terms of the day of week and the time of the day. Tbe Desk is now much less likely to intervene in the market before the weekend, especially on Thursdays when reserve projections for the week are the most uncertain and the Desk has to rely on a tentative estimate of the nonborrowed reserve objective made the previous week. A practice has also developed of initiating most temporary transactions (repurchase agreements or matched sale-purchase transactions) between 11:30 a.m. and 12:15 p.m., following the regular morning conference call,which reviews reserve projections and market developments. The Desk has tended to operate chiefly within that period to reduce the significance that the market attaches to the federal at the time of market entry. funds rate prevailing While some transactions still occur outside of this period for various reasons, they are relatively few ( table 6 ) . 3/ In contrast, under the federal 3/ An early entry to arrange repurchase agreements, for example, may occur wnea the Desk anticipates a market shortage of collateral, while a late entry (to arrange repurchase agreements or matched sale-purchase transactions) may reflect a revision in reserve projections. Early and late entries may also occur when the federal funds rate is threatening to breech the limits of the Committee's broad range. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 19 funds rate strategy the Desk was prepared to intervene in the market well beforell:00 a.m. or after 1:00 p.m. if funds deviated by 1/8 to 1/4 percentage point or so in either direction from its objective. Experience in Hitting Reserve Objectives Table 7 attempts to summarize the System's record in achieving its path objectives for nonborrowed and total reserves. Specifically, the table shows average deviations from paths and the factors underlying these deviations, for the 15 reserve periods running from the four weeks ended October, 31, 1979, to the four weeks ended November 19, 1980. The reserve periods, which vary in length from three to five weeks, generally correspond to intermeeting periods except, as noted earlier, that intermeeting periods were split into two reserve periods when meetings were relatively far apart. , Devi- ations ,are measured from adjusted (rather than original) path values since operationally these were the objectives that the Desk sought to hit. For nonborrowed reserves, deviations from average path levels ranged from a low of $13 million to a high of $670 million over the fifteen separate reserve periods. Ignor~ng ~ sign, they averaged $184 million per reserve period, or about 0.4percent of the average level of nonborrowed reserves ( table 7). As explained more fully below, nonborrowed reserves tended to come in below path values in contraEt to the experience for total reserves which ran above path values. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis On 19a Table 7 Comparison of Actual Reserves to Path: Four Weeks Ended October 31, 1979,to Four Weeks Ended November 19, 1980 Average deviation per reserve period (million of dollars) Average absolute deviation per reserve period (million of dollars) Average absolute deviation as percent of reserve measure (percent) Deviation from nonborrowed reserve path1 Total -129.7 Accepted or intentional· Transition between reserve periods -39.3 Weekly deviation of borrowing -24.o Special borrowing -8.4 Monetary aggregates growth -19.9 Federal funds rate constraint -1.2 Unintentional: Dealer propositions +9.5 Projection errors2 -46.4 57.0 50.7 .14 19.9 .12 .02 .05 1.2 .00 11.2 56.5 .03 8.4 .14 Deviation from total reserve pathl +81,3 325,0 3 Required Excess +122.2 -40.9 335.8 67.3 .78 Nonborrowed Borrowed -129. 7 183.9 +210,9 404.9 .43 .94 Total .75 .16 1 computed from final data and adjusted paths. 2Calculated as residual. 3rndividual components do not sum to total because of interaction of components. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 3 20 average, actual nonborrowed reserves fell below path by $130 million per reserve period. 41 In accounting for deviations between actual and path values for nonborrowed reserves, it is useful to distinguish between accepted or "intentional" misses and unintentional misses. Accepted or intentional misses, which accounted for over twothirds of the deviations, represented decisions to tolerate or even aim for reserve supplies either above or below average path values. They arose from a variety of considerations, but mainly reflected deviations from expectations for borrowing in the final week of a reserve period and a desire to maintain continuity in the degree of adjustment pressure on the banks in the transition from one control period to the next around the time of FOMC meetings. Unintentional misses, which accounted for less than a third of the deviations, resulted primarily from reserve projection errors and, to a lesser extent, from the inability of the Desk to arrange the volume of open market operations planned because of insufficient dealer propositions. 5/ ~/ Using preliminary estimates available just after reserve periods ended shows nonborrowed reserves about $109 million, on average, below path. Final figures for reserves tend to be lower than preliminary estimates largely because of negative "as of adjustments." 5/ A number of the sources of reserve misses interact. and thus a-fully satisfactory separation is not possible. The various categories shown in the table and discussed below are only meant to be suggestive. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 21 Of the intentional misses, the largest arose from System efforts to deal with cumulative deviations in nonborrowed reserves from desired levels as the FOMC meeting approached . . During several periods cumulative misses in weekly nonborrowed reserve objectives would have required large changes in borrowing in the final week had the Desk sought to achieve the average nonborrowed reserve path for the period as a whole. • For example, the implied borrowing level in the February 6, 1980, week would have had to drop to zero, with excess reserves of $900 million, to meet the average nonborrowed reserve path for the three-week period. In previous weeks borrowing had run about $1 billion to $1.8 billion; then at the February meeting the Committee chose a borrowing level of $1 1/4 billion for the start of the next period. and the federal Producing a sharp drop in borrowing funds rate, in this instance, would have confused market participants as to the System's restrictive posture. It would also have made it less likely that banks would have borrowed in accordance with the reserve objectives for the next period. Under such circumstance~ the Desk, after consultation with the senior Board staff and the Chairman, chose to aim for a weekly nonborrowed reserve objective that tended to smooth the implied change in borrowing rather than promote rapid changes in borrowing and rates that would have to be reversed in the following week. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 22 The second largest source of intentional misses in the nonborrowed reserve path arose when borrowing deviated significantly from expectations within the final week of a reserve period. As noted above, if borrowing ran well above expectations during the early days of a week, the Desk was then faced with the alternative either of allowing huge excesses and an overshoot in total reserves by strictly following the path or else of absorbing some of the excess and coming out below path. If borrowing ran well below expectations during the early part of a week, the Desk was faced with the alternative of forcing huge borrowing on the final day of the week or else of coming out above its obJective for nonborrowed reserves. Because borrowing more often ran above expectations than below, especially in the periods of rising interest ' rates, there was a tendency for the Desk to come out below its weekly nonborrowed reserve objective. If thi~ occurred· in the final week of a reserve period, it meant that nonborrowed reserves would also come out below the average path level for the period as a whole. Moreover, even if it occurred earlier in the period, it meant that there might be a large gap to fill in the final week, with the implication of a large drop in borrowing in that week, even when the ~OMC's new instructions might involve a rise in the subsequent week. As noted earlier, in dealing with the problem of transition between https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 23 reserve periods the Desk chose to avoid large swings in borrowing around the final week, and so it would aim for nonborrowed reserves to come out below the path value. (As defined here this latter source of miss would be captured under "transition between reserve periods.") There were several other less important sources of intentional misses in the nonborrowed reserve path. The Desk treated special borrowing--for example, borrowing resulting from a reserve need created by a computer failure--like a provision of nonborrowed reserves and, hence, aimed to come out below path by the amount of such borrowing. (Borrowing by a large bank facing a special extended need for accommodation during May through August was also treated like nonborrowed reserves, but because it was recurring and after a while fairly predictable it was formally built into the paths.) On two occasions the Desk cited the projected strength in the aggregates as a reason for accepting some shortfall from path. the federal Finally, funds rate constraint accounted for a relatively small deviation in only one of the reserve periods, the four weeks ended May 21. At the end of that period, the Desk drained reserves, even though projections indicated no need for action, when federal funds traded at rates below the lower limit of the Committee's funds rate range, In other periods, while the behavior of the funds rate on occasion had a very temporary and modest influence on open market operations, it did not constrain the Desk's ability to hit average path levels, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 24 Among the unintentional misses, there were many occasions when dealer propositions proved skimpy, and the Desk was unable to arrange the volume of open market operations plannedo When this occurred on the final day of a reserve period, which happened twice during the year, the Desk missed its average nonborrowed reserve path. A far more important source of miss ~ere projection errors of reserve supplies. According to the estimates shown in table 7, they accounted for an average miss of about $57 million (ignoring sign) per reserve period. However, this may understate the size of errors from this source because of the interaction of projection errors with other factors. For exaP1.ple, an overestimate of reserve supplies early in a statement week that led the Desk to hold back its provision of reserves might result in upward pressure on the federal funds rate and borrowing levels that exceeded expectations. If the Desk at the end of the week then chose to deliberately miss ' on its nonborrowed reserve objective because of the higherthan-expected borrowing, this would show up in the accounting as ''weekly deviations of borrowing . rather than a proJection •1' 6/ error. -- ' 6/ On the other hand, because the estimates of projection-errors were computed in the table as a residual-that is, after accounting for deviations from all other factors-there is the possibility that they could overstate their impact to some extent. An alt':=rnative P1.ethod of co-npm:1.ng t'rie devia-t.io~1 arisi.:.1.g f:'.:'om res·3rV3 rr.:,jection rr1isses is to j_oo,: at one~day forecasting errors of weeklv average reserve supplies on Wednesdays divided by the average number of weeks in reserve periods. This produces an estimate of about $37 million per reriodi which could be thought of as a lower bound estimate of the deviation one might expect from this source. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 25 For total reserves the deviations from path in absolute value were much larger than those for nonborrowed reserves. Over the fifteen reserve periods, they ranged from a low of $65 million to a high of $888 million and averaged $325 million (ignoring sign) or 0.75 percent of total reserves. On average, total reserves exceeded path by about $81 million per reserve period. Deviations from the total reserve path mainly reflected misses in required reserves and, hence, largely mirrored deviations from the Committee's monetary aggregate objectives. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 26 The Market's Perception of Monetary Policy A key issue under the new procedures is how the System's supply-oriented strat~gy affects the perceptions and actions of bank and financial market participants. How efficiently do market participants translate the levels of nonborrowed reserves (NBR) achieved by the Desk into the portfolio decisions and interest rate movements that will' promote attainment of aggregate objectives? Can operational or institutional changes improve the speed and appropriateness of the financial system's response to NBR changes? The design of System operations is clear enough. By supplying nonborrowed reserves in line with a desired path for growth in reservableM-2 deposits, the System assures the public that deviations in monetary growth will produce corresponding increases or decreases in the amounts that will have to be borrowed at the discount window to cover reserve requirements. So long as the demand for total reserves exceeds the NBR path, increases or decreases in such borrowing bring upward, or downward, pressure on the federal funds rate and encourage portfolio adjustments that should work toward offsetting the overshoots, or shortfalls, in money growth. If the System wants to speed up the adjustment process, it can lower or raise the NBR path and/or change the discount rate. Whenever the demand for total reserves falls below the NBR path, then the procedure calls for supplying reserves in excess of the volume demanded, producing a drop in the federal funds rate toward whatever lower limit the FOMC sets as a constraint on operations. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 27 While the broad outlines of this strategy are well understood by financial market participants, they find it harder to assess the current and prospective thrust of monetary policy under the present procedures than previously. Before October 1979, the Desk's operations gave the market an immediate reading on a change in posture with regard to the federal funds rate. At present, market participants can follow the actual behavior of borrowing"at.the window on-a weekly basis--and assume that on average it reflects the Desk's new operating procedures. But the federal funds rate associated with each borrowing level can range fairly widely. Confronted with a choice between borrowing or the federal funds rate as an indicator of the Federal Reserve's operational stance, market p~rticipants have a natural preference for the latter. Not only is the rate observable continuously but market participants also know the direction the rate has to move to correct monetary growth when it is too rapid or too slow. ,The rate also bears directly on the costs incurred by banks in borrowing short term and by investment houses in financing their positions. For market observers, the supply- oriented strategy boils down to a procedure for generating movements in the federal funds rate. The new strategy is thus marked by some ambiguity in the signals the market reads of policy's current thrust from the funds rate. The Desk can hit its NBR targets--and the levels of borrowing that correspond--reasonably well over an intermeeting interval. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis But the federal funds rate, the 28 market focuses on as a policy indicator, can vary widely for a given level of borrowing. Changes in the federal funds rate appear to be strongly influenced not only by the borrowing level itself but also by past borrowing experience and by market expectations of future rate developments. For an earlier period, July 1972-Decernber 1974, the relationship between member bank borrowing and the spread between the federal funds rate and-the basic discount rate • 7/ is shown in chart 1. - In this period,, the rate spread exhibited considerable dispersion in relation to borrowing when the latter moved beyond about $1.5 billion. the But since federal funds rate was the control instrument, it was a , matter of indifference to both the Desk and market participants that borrowing was bouncing around. Of greater inter- est for current purposes is the fact that the relationship shifted to the right in the October 1979-November 1980 peri-' od. jl/ As the chart shows, member bank borrowing after October 6, 1979,involved a smaller average impact on the federal funds rate for a given change in bo~rowinq than 7/ The period is chosen because borrowing ranged widely and-discount rate policy allowed a sizable positive gap to develop between the federal funds rate and the discount rate. In the 1977-79 experience, the discount rate was kept in closer alignment with the federal funds rate, so that borrowing infrequently rose much above $1 billion. 8/ Discount window borrowing excludes emergency borrowing In both periods. The period in which the federal funds rate was below the discount rate was eliminated from analysis of the recent period since the level of borrowing in such a period is typically not sensitive to the size of the negative spread prevailing. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CHART 1. ADJUSTMENT BORROWING VS. THE SPREAD BETWEEN THE FEDERAL PUNDS RATE AND THE PEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT RATE~ - - - - - - - - - - • 7172 TD lZ/7-t lfl.ftTIUNSHir - - - - 10/79 10 11/&) RELA'rION9fIP (C ----------------------- la.] f-t a: 0:::: Ln (> f-t z ::::) <) <) D c.:,~ (/) ......, □ (/)~ I\,) z ...... Ill ::::) CX) L'. u.J N H a: n:: CJ) □ z ::) ,.... La... i<> CJ ......__~◊--'----~--~---------,.,___ _ _ _ ___ 0.0 500.0 1000.0 1500.0 2000.0 2500.0 ADJUSTMENT BORROWING https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis N..lJLl J97Z TD ~EMBiR 197i - 3 N£EK 11:JVING ft~Rf&f 3000.0 3500.0 29 the earlier period. :11 The relationship between borrowing and the rate spread also exhibited a much looser fit after October 6 than in 1972-74. (An R2 of 0.48 compared with one of 6 the 0.83 for the earlier period for a linear relationship in the logs.) As noted below, one factor at work was the intro- duction of a surcharge on the discount rate for frequent use ' of the window by large banks. On closer examination, the recent experience is not all of one piece. The da,ta suggest, instead, a basic rela- tionship fitted to 23 of the 41 weeks of the period when the yield spread was positive. logs graphed in chart 2.) (See linear relationship in the Th~ basic relationship (R 2 equal to 0.8~ suggests a greater shift in bank borrowing behavior since 1972-74 than the regression line of chart 1, all the weeks of positive spread. which used The basic relationship suggests that member bank borrowing of about $2.3 billion was needed to produce a 2 percent rate spread in the recent period, whereas $1.5 billion of borrowing was associated with such a spread in 1972-74. The market's perceptions of rate vari- ability relate much more, however, to three distinctive episodes, in which the spread departed dramatically from the basic relationship. '}J An even stronger shift in borrowing behavior was found in the paper by Peter Keir, written for this staff review. That paper suggests that a change of $BO mill ion in borrowing is associated with a move of 10 basis points in the federa fu~ds rate after.October 6, whereas a change of only $40 million was associated with such a move earlier. See Peter Keir, "Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the Effectiveness of Reserve Targeting, 11 p. 27. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CHART I ~ 2D ~ ADJUSTMENT BORROWING VS. THE SPRLAD BETWEEN THE FEDERAL fUNDS RATE ANO THE fEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT RATE* ONfflIN9 NfEK5 H l"UNJ, MTC Wft5 BEL<M "JHt: 0]5DOUNT we - - - - 10/18 ro 12/80 REDR:SSI0N RELR:rU)ISHlP E><CLLDJND OU'D..]ERS 0 INO.UCID [N ftf2ESSIDN A EXO.WEO rRJH RE~ION w------------------------ w ~ cc et::: IJ1 ~ t-t I z :::) I ! CJ) / I ......... D I j. (f)~ jf 9/80 TO 12/80 :::) z 1--f / ~/ 1/ / E / WN ~ E--f Ai -=p--~"jG,---0 0::: 6---0.. a: e, er, (f) D ~ I D~ (...J z ::) , r-t ,~ 11/79 TO 1/80 la.. □ 0.0 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 500.0 1000.0 1500.0 2000.0 2500.0 ADJUSTMENT BORROWING II nl'!''TT'1AS:-I' , a?CI '1n nF"l"S:-MRF'IRP , aAn - "ll: Nn.JTM Nnll TtJI! Rvr:'IPA::r' 3000.0 3500.0 30 In the first, borrowing declined from the $1.9 billion level of four weeks in November 1979 to the $1.3 billion level of the five weeks in January 1980, but the rate spread actually increased by about 1/2 percentage point. A part of the explanation doubtless lies in the fact that high OctoberNovember borrowing levels had forced many banks into the window so that maJor banks were prepared to continue bidding aggressively for window. federal funds in order to stay out of the Year-end expectations of economic weakness in 1980 may also have led the major banks to shorten up a bit on their funding, exerting a bit more pressure on the money market. Also at work may have been the banking system's response under the new regime to financing seasonal loan demands, which typically peak in December. The rate spread did fall back somewhat in mid-January, but it remained on the high side for some weeks. Perhaps one influence on the banks after mid-January was the increase in loan takedowns as borrowers became increasingly concerned that some form of credit restraint would be a part of the anti-inflationary package then being put together by the administration. In this atmos- phere the increase in the discount rate from 12 to 13 percent on February 15 led banks to bid up the federal funds rate a corresponding amount almost immediately so that the spread relationship was not affected. The second episode began with the announcement on March 14 of the credit control program and a 3 percentage point surcharge on the discount rate for large banks. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ~ 31 Nearly the full amount of the surcharge seems to have been translated into a higher federal funds rate within three weeks as evidenced by the sharp rise in the spread. The rapidity, with which this occurred, probably reflected the restrictive thrust of the credit control program at a time when bank loan demand was running very high, as well as the sustained recourse of the banking system to discount window borrowing. The sharp rise in the federal funds rate appar- ently reflected the efforts of the larger banks to stay out of the window. Surcharge borrowing was, in fact, very low. Once the money supply began falling far below path in April, borrowing fell rapidly under the new procedures and the federal funds rate fell below the discount rate by the first week in May 1980.' The third, and in some respects, most interesting episode began in August 1980, when a surge in money supply led to an'irnmediate rise in discount window borrowing as the 'l.0/ demand for total reserves exceeded the NBR path.- However, since member banks had been essentially out of the window for some months, upward pressure on the federal modest. funds rate was After having risen from 9 percent to the 10 percent dis- count rate in late August, the federal funds rate rose only 10/ Between early May and early August, the discount rate surcnarge was eliminated and the basic rate was lowered in thl:;-ee. ateps to 10 percent. Each of these changes reduced the spread between the discount rate and the federal funds rate without affecting the latter, whereas discount rate increases translate quickly under reserve targeting into a corresponding rise in the federal funds rate. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 32 about 1/2 percentage point further by mid-month. Member bank borrowing rose from the frictional levels prevailing in midAugust to around $1.2 bil~ion in mid-September, an increase that was rapid by historical standards for a period of economic recovery. the federal Market participants took the moderate rise in funds rate as an inadequate response to the con- tinued rapid expansion of the money supply after August's 19.3 percent annual rate of growth in M-lA. A major revision of expectations regarding the . outlook 'for the economy and inflation had already begun by mid-September. While the feoeral 150 basis points since July, funds rate had advanced six-month and one-year Treasury issues had,risen 300 basis points. Long-term bonds had risen over 1 percentage point in yield, as evidence accumulated of a resumption in economic growth and as buoyancy in producer prices eroded earlier hopes of near-term progress in reducing inflation. federal The market wa5 disappointed that the funds rate did not rise more vigorously. Talk that the Federal Reserve was not following through on its moneiary I objectives probably contributed to the widespread resurge~ce of inflationary expectations. I j The rise in the Federal Reserve discount rate from I 10 to 11 percent on September 26 seemed to dissipate suchl concerns and contribute to expectations of still higher rates ahead. The federal funds rate moved up by more than l pet- I centage point so that the spread between it and the discount I I rate widened. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis In succeeding weeks the spread rose from 33 1 percentaqe ~oint to over 2 percentage ooints in late October-early November, for similar levels of borrowings. As borrowing increased further under the new procedures, the spread continued to rise l percentage point or more above the fitted rel~tionship of chart 2. The rise in the dis- count rate by 1 percentage point on November 17 and the institution of a 2 percentage point surcharge were quickly translated into further increases in both the federal rate and the spread, much as in March. funds And a second 1 per- centage point increase in basic rate and surcharge on December 5 had a similar effect. , The extraordinary rate increases between midOctober and mid-December, with federal funds rising from a bit over 12 percent to 19 to 20 percent--appear to reflect an interaction of bank and market expectations with Federal Reserve actions. The increase in the spread after the September discount rate increase seems,related to both the general shift in expectations concerning interest rates and the rapid ,increase in business loans at banks since midsummer. The fact that rapid money supply growth threatened achievement of the FOMC's 1980 objectives fed expectations that rates would move higher. The markets quickly translated these expectations into higher rates in a self-reinforcing process. Participants repeatedly talked up the likelihood of discount rate increases as the federal funds rate rose further above the discount rate--apparently on the theory that catch-up increases were needed under the flexibility https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 34 principle specified in the announcement of the new strategy in October 1979. This interpretation became a part of the market's assessment of Federal Reserve dedication to monetary restraint. The rise in the spread was taken as indicating a further need for discount rate change rather t~gn g meas~re I of the pressure of banks' efforts to avoid recourse to the window. Operational or Institutional Changes An important question raised by the experiencelwith I I 1 the supply-oriented strategy is whether changes in the SI stem's procedures or the operation of the discount window could increase the predictability and speed of market and bank r sponses to changes in the supply of nonborrowed reservesl One part of the question relates to drawing the reserve paths, I I the other to the predictability of the rate effects flowing from the supply-oriented strategy. The data embodied in the basic relationship shown in cnart 2 raise doubts whether the System was vigorous enough in August and in September in lowerinq the NBR path as a result of overruns in the demand for total reserves in relation to path. The rise in borrowings from frictional levels to over $1 billion between mid-August and mid-September may have been rapid by past standards, but the resulting increase in the federal funds rate of about 5/8 percentaoe ooint aopeared small to the market in relation to the overshoots reported weekly in the money supply. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis With the benefit of hindsight, 35 a quick rise in borrowing levels nearer to $2 billion would have carried greater conviction, both to the markets and discount window borrowers as well. A related issue is the trade-off between increases in borrowing levels and increases in the discount and/or surcharge rates. Had the System lowered the NBR path more vigor- ously in August and September, the federal funds rate would have risen more rapidly. Some bankers argue that attaining a critical mass of borrowing--say $1.5 to $2.0 billion--exerts availability effects on bank behavior that can substitute for the restraint generated by the rise in the federal funds rate. Whether high borrowing levels could have achieved the same degree of restraint at somewhat lower levels of interest rates is problematical. The possibility deserves further analysis. Would improving the predictability of the interest rate effects of a reserve strategy be desirable? The answer depends upon where one strikes the balance between reducing interest rate volatility and insuring that short-term interest rates are free to move. The present strategy involved a clear break with the 1978-79 strategy, in which stability considerations weighed rather heavily. Policymakers in still earlier periods--for example, 1973-75--were often more aggressive in moving the federa 1 funds rate than was the case in 1978-79.) 1978-79.} The volatility of short-term interest rates from day to day and week to week over the past year 1.s a natural https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 36 consequence of the change in operating strategy. If market participants base their interest rate forecasts more than before on projections of economic activity in an inflationary environment, then short-term rates, including the federal funds rate, are likely to reflect shifts in expecta- tions as new data on the economy come in. The difficulty that market participants have had in reading Desk operations adds to uncertainty and the scope for'rate movements. One can argue that expectational shifts have generally tended to work in the direction needed to effect desired changes in the growth of the aggregates. of sluggish growth, the federal In periods funds rate has tended, to fall more rapidly because of expectations. When aggregate growth has been excessive for a sustained period, the funds rate has tended to rise faster than one would expect on the basis of the increases in adjustment borrowing that have occurred. The variability in the relation between borrowings and the federal funds rate has seemed to operate in the direction needed to bring monetary growth back to path more quickly. On the other hand, the present procedures involve a considerable amount of short-run rate volatility as the markets seek to appraise the Federal Reserve's current posture as well as the economic outlook. This probably has imposed considerable cost on the Treasury and other borrowers in financial markets, who ultimately pay for the greater underwriting risks encountered in rapidly changing markets. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 37 The question is whether changes in System procedures or financial institutions could moderate this volatility without impairing the advantages of the supply-oriented strategy. An institutional way of imposing a more predictable relatidnship between discount window borrowing and the f edera 1 funds rate would be to provide access to the window through ·a tferetl structuring of credit lines, which would be available to banks at escalating rates without administrative constraint. The interaction of the demand for total reserves with'the supply of nonborrowed reserves controlled by the Desk would, as now, determine the aggregate volume of borrowing. The structure of credit lines and related discount rates would also essentially determine the federal funds rate since banks would be able to arbitrage between the discount window and the money market. Under this system, changes in borrowing levels because of either a rise in the demand for total reserves or a lowering of the NBR path would lead to a fairly predictable change in the federal funds rate and reduce this source of uncertainty to the market. A tiering of-credit lines -and discount rates would, of course, pose' ' serious equity questions by differentiating access to the window among various classes of institutions. Designing the gradient of the rate schedule would be difficult, and adjustment of the schedule would be cumbersome if one wanted to reduce, or increase, the rate impact of changes in borrowing levels. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 38 The same reduction of instability in the relation between borrowing and the federal funds rate miqht be achieved with less impact on institutional relationships by introqucing 1 a flexible or 2 percentage point, band for the federal funds rate into the Desk's conduct of open market operations. The Desk could pursue its weekly nonborrowed targets mor,e, ,, flexibly, being somewhat more aggressive in supplying reserves toward the upper end of the band and in absorbing reserves ,at the lower end of the band. The NBR weekly target would •remain the primary obJective, but the Desk would provide some resistance to over- or undershooting, especially during times of rapid dynamic change in borrowing levels or the discount rate. The purpose would be to smooth the transition in rates from one level to another, in order to reduce short-term instability. To be sure, such an approach could generate concern among market and academic observers that the System was re-. verting to a policy of restricting movements in the federal funds rate. However, System practice could soon allay such concerns by continuing to allow rates to move when money growth was excessive or deficient. The shift to the supply-oriented'strategy reflected a need to restore credibility to System policy after an extended period in which oolicymakers did not allow interest rates to move sufficiently to cJntrol money growth. The System's subsequent commitroent to pursuing its monetary objectives through this strategy, augmented by discount rate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 39 policy, has been much in evidence. The short-term volatility of interest rates, as distinct from their cyclical variability, has been one consequence. It seems possible that this volatil- ity could be reduced somewhat through the conduct of open market operations without involving significant risk of reverting to the former federal funds rate strateqy. The gain would be a reduction of short-run uncertainty and the associated rise in underwriting costs by smoothing of the interest rate changes produced by a supply-oriented strategy. One might, of course, diminish in the process the self-reinforcing effects of expectations, which at times can speed up the monetary control process. Where one strikes the balance in such matters depends on the relative weights one attaches to these considerations. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis APPEN~IX A-1 Technical Adjustments to the Reserve Paths Regular procedures have been developed for adjusting the reserve paths over the intermeeting period for technical changes affecting the money-reserve relationship. The original paths, estimated shortly after the FOMC meeting by the Board staff, incorporate explicit assumptions for excess reserves and required reserves needed to support the growth of reservable liabilities not contained in ~-2, such as large time deposits, net interbank deposits, and Treasury deposits. They also incorporate assumptions regarding the mix between deposits and cu~rency, the composition of deposits by type and maturity, and their distribution among banks by size and membership status. As new data become available each week, the paths are reviewed (generally on Fridays) by the senior Board staff and the Account Manager to see whether changes are needed to maintain their consistency with the Committee's aggregate objectives. For example, if net interbank deposits are growing more rapidly than originally projected, less reserves would be available to support the de~osit components of M-2. Such a circumstance would normally call for an upward adjustment to the paths. Similarly, if currency growth is running above expectations, the growth of other components of M-2 would need to be restrained an~ hence, a downward adjustment to the reserve paths would be called for. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis J A-2 While the procedures for adjusting the paths for technical considerations are for the most part straight~orward, two issues raise difficult conceptual questions and deserve further study. On~ involves the question of how quickly and by how much the paths should~be adjllsted as new information becomes available. The more typical practice has been to apply only a portion of potential adJustments to the paths each week since the technical factors are volatile from week to week and, hence, full application may have to be reversed in succeeding weeks. There is also the practice of making adjustments only when their size is deemed significant, and so the paths are generally not adJusted if the potential amount is less than $50 million. These practices, however, can be questioned on several grounds. In the first place, many of the adjustment items--for example, reserves to support net interbank deposit and Treasury deposits--are fully reflected in the projected demand for total reserves.· Since it is the difference between the projected demand for total reserves and the nonborrowed reserve path that largely determines the estimated borrowinQ level for the week, the practice of not fully adjusting the path for these items introduced unnecessary changes in borrowings, and hence in money market rates, that are not related to growth of the monetary aggregates relative to the Committee's objectives. Secondly, even those adjustment items that do not directly https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A-3 affect the demand for reserves (for example, those involving currency growth) still represent the staff's most up-to-date judgment of the changes which are necessary to keep the path in line with the Committee's monetary aggregate objectives. Nd:to adjust the paths in full for these items, seems to imply some special significance to the estimates made immediately' after the Committee meeting even though they were based on less information. Finally, ignoring even small potential adjustments to the path can have significant implications for money market conditions. This is especially true when the adjustments occur either in the latter weeks of a reserve period, as they have a multiple effect on the borrowing estimate, or when banks are already relying heavily on the discount window and, therefore, are especially reluctant to increase their borrowings further. The other issue that deserves further study--and which could also benefit from Committee consideration--involves how much policy weight over the intermeeting period should be given to the broad versus the narrow aggregates. Currently, the primary emphasis under the reserve approach is on the narrow measures. Deviations in their growth from the Committee's shor~-run objectives affect 1 the demand for reserves relative to the nonborrowed reserve path and thus influence the borrowing levels and money market rates that develop over the intermeeting period. Many of the components of M-2, however, are nonreser,vable and so their growth has no policy significance between meetings. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A-4 These include personal savings and small time deposits at thrift institutions, money market mutual fund shares, overnight repurchase agreements, and overnight Eurodollars (held at Caribbean branches),which together constitute nearly one-half of M-2. Moreover, the short-term policy weight attached to M-2 will diminish further under the provisions of the Monetary Control Act as reserve requirements on personal savings and small time deposits at commercial banks are phased out. When the Act is fully implement~d for member banks in 1984 and, hence.transactions balances become virtually the only M-2 component subject to reserve requirements, open market operations between meetings, in effect, will be focused almost entirely on control over the narrow monetary aggregates--if current procedures are maintained. There are two ways the Committee can increase the role of M-2if it so chooses. One approach would be for the Committee to give more emphasis than currently to M-2 at each meeting when it selects its short-run aggregate growth objectives and determines the initial borrowing level used in constructing the nonborrowed reserve path. The aggregate objectives themselves could be specified in terms of growth . of the narrow measures. However, in choosing these objectives and the initial borrowing level, the Committee could give greater recognition to whereM-2 (and perhaps still broader money and credit measures) stand in relation to their yearly range~. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis For example, if M-2growth was running above its A-5 yearly range . , this would be strong reason for considering relatively low short-run growth objectives for the narrow ' aggregates and/or a relatively high borrowing level--even if the narrow aggregates were behaving satis~actorily. The other alternative woul~ be for the Committee to indicate to the staff some specific short-run weighting scheme for its aggregate obJectives similar to what was done under the federal funds rate procedure. For examole, the Committee ' • could direct the staff to construct and maintain the reserve paths in a way that gave equal weight to achieving its short-run obJectives for growth of, say, M-lB and M-2. The staff's procedures for drawing up the initial paths would remain the same, but subsequent adjustments would insure that the Committee's priorities are being reflected in the paths rather than a weighting scheme based on the structure of legal reserve requirements. This would involve making adjustments between meetings to the reserve paths for deviations of growth from the Committee's objectives in nonreservable deposits similar to those that are ; currently being made for currency. Such an approach can have significant effects on short-run policy. For example, had the above mentioned 50-50 weighting scheme been in effect in 1980, it would have called for sizable downward adjustments' to the··' nonborrowed reserve paths over the summer months. This would have given an earlier start in letting interest rates adjust upward over the balanc,e of the year. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - ~ ... - "II .c