View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"Credit, Currency and
Business"
W. P. G. HARDING
GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

•Published by
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA




"Credit, Currency and
Business''
Address by
W. P. G. HARDING
GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

before the

Southern Wholesale Dry Goods Association




Birmingham, Ala.
May 10, 1922

%

Published by
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA




"Credit, Currency and Business"
CIUESTIONS concerning credit and currency are of
vital interest to all classes of the community. They
concern producers, distributors and consumers alike.
The entire population is embraced in this classification and, indeed, in the last analysis the single word
"consumer" covers all. While there are many who
produce more than they consume and who, therefore,
naturally view economic problems from the producer's standpoint, it follows, nevertheless, that as
everybody is a consumer the broadest interest is
that of the consumer.
The distributors are consumers, but are not producers except in so far as they furnish the means of
distribution. Many varied interests are included in
the distributor class. All who are engaged in transportation are distributors in a sense and the banks,
the dealers in credit, play a very important part in
the process of distribution, just as they do in aiding
production and in facilitating the economic processes
of consumption. The great distributors of the
country, however, in the ordinary acceptation of the
term, are the merchants, both wholesale and retail.
Through them goods and commodities pass from the
primary producer or manufacturer to the ultimate
consumer. The merchant comes necessarily in close
contact with the banks, the purveyors of credit,
upon which he calls for accommodation both in making
purchases from the producer and in effecting sales to
the consumer, with the railroads and steamship lines
which make the physical transfer of goods from one
place to another; and his association with the consumer is necessarily intimate.
The merchant buys in order that he may sell, and
in ordinary times, in order to meet competition and
[3]




The Federal Reserve System
to satisfy the demands of his customers, he must sell
at a close margin, depending upon his volume of
business and frequent turnover for his profit. It is
to his interest, therefore, that there should be no
interruption in any of the various processes incident
to the transfer of goods from the producer to the
consumer; no congestion of credit and no stoppage of
transportation. The merchant must watch the markets closely in order to assure himself, as far as he
can, that he will be able to sell at a profit the goods
that he buys. He must keep a watchful eye upon
his operating expenses and upon his credits, in order
that he may offer terms to his customers as favorable
as those made by his competitors and meet obligations incurred in purchases by the proceeds of his
sales.
Anything which interrupts the ordinary flow of
goods to their ultimate market affects him adversely
and his own buying power is gauged by the purchasing power of his customers.
Coming, as he does, in contact with practically all
factors in the country's economic life, the merchant
can sense better, perhaps, than any one else, that
intangible but powerful entity known as public
opinion, and he can, and does, exert a potent influence
in moulding that opinion. In view of the facts to
which I have alluded, I feel that it is appropriate to
discuss before this audience, composed, as it is, of
wholesale merchants, some of the problems relating
to bank credits and currency with which it has been
the particular province of the Federal Reserve Board
to deal.
There is more or less confusion in the minds of
some with regard to the three C's—capital, credit and
currency. While these words are interrelated, they
are by no means synonymous, and an intelligent
[4]




Credit, Currency and

Business

differentiation of t h e m is necessary for a proper
understanding of our present financial and economic
problems.
Capital is the permanent fund of productive wealth,
the accumulation of the products of past labor capable
of being used in the support of present or future
labor. I t is t h a t p a r t of the product of industry
which, in the form either of national or of individual
wealth, is available for further production. More
specifically, it is the wealth employed in carrying on
a particular business or undertaking. I t is the actual
estate, whether in money or property, which is
owned or employed by an individual, firm, or corporation in business and implies ownership and
does not, without qualification, include borrowed
money.
Credit is the reputation of solvency and character
which entitles a m a n t o be trusted in buying or
borrowing. T h e word " c r e d i t " is derived from t h e
Latin word " c r e d o , " meaning " I trust or believe,"
and while credit itself is a liability and not an asset
to the m a n who obtains it, the ability to get credit
is one of the most substantial resources t h a t an
individual can possibly have, and is one which should
be guarded with the most jealous and watchful care.
One basis of credit is capital; b u t character—that is,
good reputation as to veracity, integrity and ability
—is also a basis of credit without which the capital
foundation would count for little. T h e processes of
production and distribution are profoundly affected
by credit conditions. Modern business is done on
credit. One of its life-giving principles is credit.
T h e mood and temper of a business community are
deeply affected by the state of credit. T h e ultimate
test of the functioning of a credit system is found in
what it does to promote the production and distri-




[5]

The Federal Reserve

System

bution of goods. Business rests upon its surest
foundation whenever there is a proper balance between the volume of credit and t h e volume of concrete things which credit helps t o produce and which
are the normal basis of credit. Abuse of credit
means shock and disturbance, and gross and continued abuse spells disaster.
Currency m a y be defined briefly as t h a t which is
current as a medium of exchange, t h a t is, which is in
general use as money or as a representative of value.
I t m a y be gold, silver or engraved slips of paper,
which do not require endorsement b u t can pass
readily from hand to hand. B y common consent of
all civilized nations, based upon the sentiment and
traditions of ages, gold is t h e recognized measure of
value and medium of exchange, and is the basis of
international settlements. I t s purchasing power is,
of course, not uniform with respect to all commodities
and varies from time to time according to the supply
of and demand for the various things for which gold
is exchanged, b u t it is the universal standard, economically, even where it is not legally.
I n this country, settlements growing out of business
transactions are made for the greater p a r t by checks
drawn upon banks, which are negotiable by endorsement. Bank checks, therefore, form an important
p a r t of our circulating medium, although in regular
course they are outstanding for limited periods of
time, soon finding their way into the drawee banks
for payment. T h e total a m o u n t of checks drawn by
firms and individuals upon their bank accounts
during the course of any single week of the year far
exceeds the total volume of all forms of money in
circulation.
T h e greater p a r t of the money in actual circulation
is in the form of paper currency, such as Federal

[6]




Credit, Currency and Business
Reserve notes, national bank notes, United States
Treasury notes, and United States gold and silver
certificates. These forms of currency circulate on a
parity with gold for the reason that they are redeemable in gold on demand,, with the exception of
national bank notes which are redeemable in lawful
money, and silver certificates which by their terms
are redeemable in silver dollars, but they in turn are
protected by the obligation and ability of the Government to maintain them at a parity with gold.
The older generation of business men can remember
the years following the Civil War, when the currency
in circulation was composed of national bank notes
and Treasury notes, known as greenbacks, which
were not redeemed in gold. Consequently, gold coin
ceased to be a medium of circulation and became an
article of commerce, its value in terms of paper
money fluctuating from day to day and prices and
wages were expressed in terms of this irredeemable
paper, just as is the case in Continental Europe and
to some extent even in England today.
Merchants in those days who bought goods abroad
paid for them on the basis of gold and resold them in
terms of paper currency which had a fluctuating
value in terms of gold. Since the first of January,
1879, the United States has been on a gold basis and
the purchasing power of a paper dollar has been at all
times the same as that of a gold dollar. There have
been times, however, when the suspension of gold
payments and a return to a fluctuating paper currency seemed imminent, but these crises have always
been passed successfully and today all currency of
the United States is redeemed in gold without question and is on a parity with gold both at home and
abroad.
There has always existed, however, in this country




[7]

The Federal Reserve System
some latent sentiment in favor of paper currency
based not upon gold but upon the faith and credit of
the Government. This sentiment in favor of flat
money, that is, paper currency issued by the Government as such but not based on coin or bullion and
containing no promise to pay in coin, has always
become more intensified in the periods of reaction
and depression which have followed those of extreme
activity and prosperity. Before the panic of 1873 there
was much agitation for paper money. Later on, however, the soft money advocates were divided; some
favored a repeal of the Resumption Act and the issue
of more Treasury notes, or greenbacks, while others
clamored for the free and unlimited coinage of silver
dollars. The greenback idea was defeated, but in
1878 the compulsory coinage of a limited amount of
silver dollars began and continued until shortly after
the panic of 1893.
Following that panic, soft money advocates united
substantially in favor of the free and unlimited
coinage of silver at the ratio of 16 to 1, although there
was some sentiment in favor of state bank notes in
addition. In due time the economic forces of the
country asserted themselves, and there was gradual
and continued improvement in commerce and industry. In the course of a few years the free silver
doctrine ceased to be an issue.
It was realized, however, even during the good
times which preceded the panic of 1907, that there
were grave defects in the banking and currency
system of the country. There were more than 25,000
banks in the United States, each standing virtually
alone. In accordance with the requirements of law
and in order to be able to pay their depositors, all
banks kept certain amounts of gold and currency on
hand and most of them maintained credit balances
[8]




Credit, Currency and Business
with other banks in the larger cities, these balances
being in most cases part of their required reserves.
In ordinary circumstances, the funds on deposit with
the city banks could be withdrawn in currency by
the country banks whenever they desired, but when
business and credit conditions were disturbed, and a
spirit of mistrust and suspicion pervaded the country,
many banks would seek to increase the amount of
actual cash on hand in order to reassure depositors
who might otherwise wish to withdraw their money.
I t was in those times that the large city banks
were least able to supply the currency, for the available supply was limited and there was no quick way
of increasing it. A large part of the circulating
medium in those days consisted of national bank
notes which were secured by Government bonds.
Under the law no national bank notes could be issued
by any bank in an amount in excess of its own
capital stock and as many national banks had
already issued their maximum quota in order to realize
the small profit obtainable thereby, while others
found it impracticable to acquire the bonds which
were necessary to secure additional circulation, it
was impossible to increase the supply of national
bank notes rapidly or to any great extent.
Our inflexible currency system had much to do
with the money panic of 1907. Fearing trouble,
many of the 25,000 banks sought, each for its own
protection, to withdraw such currency as it could
from other banks and pay out as little as possible
to depositors. Emergency measures could not be
resorted to in advance of actual panic, for they would,
in themselves, have produced a panic, and while steps
were taken finally to conserve the cash resources of
the banks they came too late to prevent trouble and
the existing banking machinery fell apart into thou-




[9]

The Federal Reserve System
sands of separate units. Each bank was obliged to
rely largely upon its own cash resources, because, however willing, other banks felt that they could not
surrender much of their own cash, for by doing so
they might impair their ability to meet the possible
demands of their own customers. Thus each bank,
in seeking to protect itself, weakened the banking
structure as a whole. The defenses were weakest
when the danger was greatest.
The panic of 1907 convinced the country that
something must be done to prevent similar occurrences
in the future. In the following year Congress created
a Monetary Commission which after a long and
thorough study of the banking systems of the world
submitted an elaborate report, and a draft of a new
banking and currency bill. During the year 1912
a committee of the House of Representatives investigated banking methods in this country and in its
report pointed out the fundamental defects in the
system then existing. Early in the year 1913 Congress took up the matter of banking reform in earnest
and the Federal Reserve Act was put upon the statute
books before the close of that year.
There has been no money panic in this country
since the Federal Reserve Act became a law. This
statement, in itself, has no particular significance,
for less than nine years have elapsed since the passage
of the Act, and there have frequently been periods
of more than nine years when the banks of the
country have been able at all times to supply the
currency demanded of them. But when we consider
the events which have taken place during the past
nine years, and what has been accomplished and
prevented by reason of the operation of the Federal
Reserve System, the conclusion is inescapable that
the enactment of the Federal Reserve law was a
[10]




Credit, Currency and

Business

most conspicuous example of valuable constructive
legislation.
T h e Federal Reserve Banks were not opened for
business until nearly a year after the passage of the
Federal Reserve Act and consequently t h e Federal
Reserve System could do nothing to mitigate the
shock which the banking, commercial and industrial
interests of the country experienced when the great
European War broke out unexpectedly in August,
1914. T h e Federal Reserve Act, however, continued
in effect until June 30, 1915, the provisions of the
Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908, which would otherwise
have expired by limitation on June 30, 1914. Under
this law it was possible for national banks, by forming
themselves into associations, to issue national b a n k
notes, on approved collateral other t h a n United
States bonds, such notes being subject t o a t a x a t
the rate of 3 per cent per a n n u m upon the average
amount in circulation for the first three months,
with a graduated increase of one-half of 1 per cent
per a n n u m for each m o n t h thereafter until a maximum rate of 6 per cent per annum was reached.
Under the provisions of this Act, as extended, the
national banks of the country were able t o provide
for themselves and for their state b a n k neighbors
sufficient currency t o meet the demands of business
and of nervous depositors, without resorting t o the
suspension or restriction of cash payments, which
expedients were employed during former crises.
After the Federal Reserve Banks began business
in November, 1914, and up t o the entrance of our
own country into the War in April, 1917, the stabilizing influence of the new system was so great t h a t
events which otherwise would have been most
disturbing produced not the slighest tremor in banking circles.




[ii]

The Federal Reserve

System

Let us now contrast the effect upon our present
banking system of our participation in the greatest
war of all history with the effect upon our earlier
banking structure of the Civil War. I t is true t h a t
t h e country h a d increased greatly both in population
and wealth between the years 1861 and 1917, b u t
wars in the '60s were conducted on a far smaller and
less expensive scale t h a n now. President Lincoln's
first call for troops was for 75,000 men and in no
battle of the Civil War were more t h a n this number
actively engaged on a side. One modern battleship
represents a greater cost t h a n the entire United
States N a v y in the Civil War, and aerial warfare
was, of course, undreamed of sixty years ago.
With the imminence of the Civil War, the banks
generally suspended specie payments and after a
brief period of resumption later on were forced t o
suspend t h e m again for m a n y years. B o t h the
United States and Confederate Governments were
obliged t o resort t o the issue of paper money. T h e
gold value of United States currency declined a t
one time to about 40 per cent of par, while Confederate currency, constantly depreciating, had its further
decline accelerated with each successive new issue
until toward the close of t h e struggle its purchasing
power was hardly as great as t h a t of some of t h e
European currencies of today.
During the years 1917 and 1918 the United States
had under arms at one time as m a n y as 4,000,000
men, exclusive of its vast naval establishment.
There were floated between J u n e , 1917, and October,
1918, four issues of Liberty Bonds, aggregating in
all $16,978,000,000, and during these two years t h e
Federal Government collected $5,425,000,000 in
taxes. Notwithstanding these vast financial operations, there was no money panic, nor at any time
[12]




Credit, Currency and Business
any serious credit disturbance. The volume of
Federal Reserve notes in circulation, which stood at
$376,510,000 at the beginning of the War, amounted
to $2,558,196,000 at its close, but the gold parity of
these notes and all other forms of currency was
maintained and there was never a time when the
purchasing power of a $20 Federal Reserve note was
not the same as that of a $20 gold piece.
The maximum amount of Treasury notes, or
greenbacks, outstanding at any time during the
Civil War was $449,338,902, and the purchasing
power of these notes at one time was little more
than one-third of a corresponding face amount of
gold.
The crucial test, however, of the Federal Reserve
System came after the end of the World War.
It was realized that the signing of the Armistice
which ended the war from a military standpoint did
not end it in a financial sense and during the early
months of the year 1919 there was a lull and much
hesitation in business. The successful flotation,
however, of the Victory Loan in May of that year
was regarded as the end of the war in a financial
sense and a period of great activity set in.
It was evident that four years of war had greatly
impaired the productive capacity of Europe and had
greatly reduced stocks of goods and supplies of all
kinds. There was a general impression that there
was a world-wide shortage of goods and that Europe
in replenishing her supplies must continue to draw
heavily upon the productive capacity of the United
States, just as had been the case ever since the year
1915. This impression was deeply engrafted upon
the minds of the public and for a time European
needs were so urgent that they had to be supplied
at any sacrifice. At the same time a substantial
[13]




The Federal Reserve System
part of the sum which during the war the United
States had agreed to advance to foreign nations was
still unexpended and these funds were used during
the year 1919 in payment of goods exported to
Europe.
Many shrewd business men looked forward confidently to several years of commercial and industrial
activity and made their plans upon the assumption
that prices would either advance or remain stable
and that a return to the pre-war level or a serious
decline in the immediate future was most improbable.
Farmers incurred obligations for additional land at a
valuation based upon the commodity prices then
existing, merchants extended their business and
manufacturers prepared to increase their productive
capacity by making additions to their plants, regardless of the fact that such additions could be made
only at costs much higher than normal.
The prevailing opinion was that we had entered
into an era of high prices and that there would be
for some time a serious shortage of goods. Many
jobbers called in their salesmen and were obliged to
scale down the orders which poured in by every
mail. Prices advanced week by week and many
producers and merchants were reluctant to sell,
for advancing prices were accompanied by higher
wages and greater production costs.
Credit was freely used, not only in production at
high cost, but in withholding goods from the market,
and inventories and bank statements everywhere
showed an expanded condition which would have
been regarded as unthinkable a few years before.
It is not difficult now to point out the essential fallacy in the position which was taken and to explain the
logical and inevitable reaction which took place, a
reaction, however, which many did not foresee until
[14]




Credit, Currency and Business
too late. The error lay in the incorrect estimate of
consumptive requirements. We can see now that
instead of there being a shortage, there was in fact a
fictitious demand, if not in some industries an oversupply. A grave mistake was made by manufacturers, merchants and farmers in basing their plans
upon the normal relationship between production
and consumption at a time when conditions were
anything but normal. There was, indeed, no question as to the need of Europe for American goods and
supplies, and estimates as to American consumption,
perhaps justified potentially, did not take sufficiently
into account the effect of extremely high prices upon
the volume of consumption. A continued demand
for goods depends in the long run upon the buying
power of the consumer. What one can not get at
all, he must do without, and when he cannot obtain
all that he needs he must be satisfied with a part.
The mere need for goods, however urgent, does not
create an economic demand. There must be an
ability on the part of those needing goods to satisfy
the need, by exchanging other goods, by rendering
service, by paying cash or by tendering some acceptable form of credit obligation.
Millions of people in some of the European countries were obliged to deny themselves a part of their
accustomed food supply, to forego purchases of
clothing and other things which ordinarily would be
regarded as absolutely necessary. Luxuries were impossible and in many cases articles so classed were
sacrificed in order to provide the irreducible minimum
of the necessities of life.
The effect of high prices in this country was
reflected finally in reduced consumption and in the
latter part of March, 1920, those who had dreams of
a long continuance of the conditions which had
[15]




The Federal Reserve System
existed up to that time were rudely awakened by the
collapse of the silk market in Japan. By this time
public opinion began to undergo a change and public
opinion is a powerful force, more potent than banking
boards, or legislative bodies. The curtailment of
buying became more and more noticeable. What
has since been referred to as the "buyers' strike"
manifested itself everywhere throughout the United
States and in other countries as well; and in quick
succession the drastic reactions in commodity prices
began to take place. Many who had been anxious
to buy cancelled orders and withdrew from the
market, while others who had been reluctant to sell
became nervously eager to dispose of their goods.
Banks began to find that loans which they had
regarded as being collectible at any time desired
could not be repaid in the altered circumstances and
must be carried along. Recourse was had in increasing degree to the Federal Reserve System which
responded to all legitimate demands and which should
be credited with preventing the commercial crisis
which followed from developing, as would otherwise
have been inevitable, into a most disastrous money
panic.
During the year 1920, when these drastic changes
in price levels were taking place, the total earning
assets of the Federal Reserve Banks, which include
rediscounts for member banks, increased from $3,»
039,000,000 at the end of January to $3,396,000,000
at the end of October. At the same time there was
not only no contraction in Federal Reserve note currency, but on the contrary there was an almost
continuous expansion in the volume of Federal
Reserve notes in circulation, the amount increasing
from $2,844,000,000 on January 23rd to $3,404,000,000 on December 23rd, 1920, a record high mark.
[16]




Credit, Currency and

Business

These figures should be impressed upon the minds
of the public, for the unwarranted statement is
often made t h a t the Federal Reserve authorities
deliberately set out to bring about deflation and to
accomplish this purpose caused sharp curtailment of
credit and drastic contraction of the currency.
T h e Federal Reserve Banks are required by law to
maintain certain specified reserves against their
deposit and note liabilities. Provision is made for
the suspension of reserve requirements, under certain
penalties, and the law authorizes the Federal Reserve
Board t o permit or require one Federal Reserve
B a n k to rediscount paper for another, in order t h a t
a p a r t of the cash resources of a bank having excess
reserves m a y be diverted temporarily t o another
bank which otherwise would be deficient in reserve.
T h e Federal Reserve Board is also empowered by
law to reject in p a r t or altogether any application
made by a Federal Reserve Bank for Federal Reserve
notes, and it is permitted at its discretion to impose
an interest charge on t h a t part of the Federal Reserve
note circulation which is not specifically covered by
gold, b u t such a charge was never imposed.
At one time during the fall of 1920, when the strain
was greatest, one Federal Reserve Bank was neither
borrowing from nor lending to other Federal Reserve
Banks, and three Federal Reserve Banks were
lending large amounts to the remaining eight Federal
Reserve Banks. Interbank rediscounting was a continuous process all during the year 1920 and during
p a r t of the year 1921.
I n t e r b a n k rediscounts reached their peak late in
October, 1920, when they amounted to $267,000,000.
I n the a u t u m n of 1920 the total accommodation
extended by all Federal Reserve Banks t o their
member banks aggregated approximately $2,750,[17]




The Federal Reserve

System

000,000, as compared with a total of $59,000,000 of
rediscounts and bills payable for all national banks in
the United States in the a u t u m n of 1907, just before
the panic of t h a t year.
H a d the Federal Reserve Board desired t o curtail
credits and contract the currency, it could have done
so most effectively by the exercise of its legal authority to refuse t o permit one Federal Reserve B a n k to
rediscount for another, and to decline applications
for Federal Reserve notes. B u t the Board arranged
promptly all rediscounts asked for, and approved
immediately all requests for Federal Reserve notes.
T h e events of the past two years have shown t h a t
there is often no clear and immediate relationship
between commodity prices and the volume of credit
and currency. According t o the quantitative theory
of money, broadly speaking, as the supply of money
increases its value decreases and consequently t h e
value of the things for which money is exchanged
increases. B u t it is obvious t h a t this is subject t o
very definite limitations and involves other factors,
such as the volume of t r a d e and production, the
rapidity of turnover or velocity of exchanges, and
likewise public confidence. Loss of confidence m a y
often lead t o heavy hoarding, and what have recently
come t o be known as "frozen l o a n s " slow up greatly
t h e turnover of credit. B o t h m a y result in an actual
contraction, although there is no apparent change in
the nominal amounts outstanding.
During the years 1915 and 1916, when there was
an influx of gold into this country of more t h a n one
billion dollars, in p a y m e n t of purchases of American
goods by the warring nations of Europe, prices and
wages advanced sharply. On the one hand, there
was an increase in our basic stock of money and on
the other, no corresponding increase in the volume
[18]




Credit, Currency and Business
of goods available for domestic consumption; an
advance in prices and wages was a natural consequence. Had it been possible to increase the volume
of goods and commodities as rapidly as the volume
of gold increased, the advance in prices would certainly have been less pronounced.
Then again, when specie payments are suspended
and a country undertakes to meet the enlarged requirements of its government and its commerce by
increasing its issues of irredeemable paper currency,
prices and wages naturally advance. It should be
remembered that the issue of irredeemable paper
currency, while sometimes unavoidable in times of
war, is merely a forced popular loan and that one
issue tends to bring on another, each successive step
adding to the depreciation. Germany, by turning
loose a flood of paper money has reduced its value
more rapidly than she has added to the quantity.
The German mark, whose normal value was about
4 marks to the dollar, has now depreciated to a point
where one dollar of American money will purchase
about 350 marks. Russia has carried its currency
inflation to such extremes that she has practically
destroyed the value of her paper money altogether.
Normally a dollar would buy about 2 rubles, while
now one dollar will purchase about 4,000,000 rubles.
Gresham's Law lays down the principle that a
superior and inferior currency cannot circulate
together, that the inferior drives the superior out
of circulation and into hiding. The depreciation of
currency in some European countries has gone so
far as to make it very difficult and inconvenient to
transact business through the medium of these
currencies, the physical volume of an amount
sufficient for ordinary retail transactions being so
great as to make it impossible to carry it around
[19]




The Federal Reserve

System

on one's person. T h e n again as the depreciation is
continuous and constant, traders are unwilling t o
accept paper money unless they can exchange it
immediately for something else. Consequently in
those European countries where the currency is
most greatly depreciated, direct exchanges of goods
for goods are m a d e ; and in some places gold is being
brought out of hiding and is performing once more,
in a limited way, its accustomed function as a medium
of exchange. T h u s it is apparent t h a t when a currency has depreciated t o t h e vanishing point,
Gresham's Law no longer holds good.
I t is not the function of the Federal Reserve
System nor of a n y banking system t o a t t e m p t t o
fix or control prices; and the Federal Reserve
discount rates have never been established with
t h a t idea in view. As a m a t t e r of fact, they have
always been lower t h a n current rates given by
member banks to their customers, and due to peculiar
circumstances have in fact followed rather t h a n led
the rise and fall of current rates. Banks are chiefly
concerned with prices only in so far as t h e security
of their loans m a y be involved, and they are interested more in the stability of prices and their margin
of collateral t h a n in the general price level itself.
Banks do not create general conditions but they m u s t
adjust themselves to changing conditions, which, in
recent eventful years, have been brought about by
unseen and irresistible forces throughout the world.
Federal Reserve notes have never been issued or
redeemed with a view to affecting prices. T h e y are
in fact b u t a very small element in the volume of
credit through which the vast exchanges of the nation
are made. Increases or decreases in the volume of
Federal Reserve notes in circulation accompany
advancing or declining business activity, prices and
[20]




Credit, Currency and Business
wages. An increase or decrease in the volume of
Federal Reserve notes outstanding is not the result
of any preordained policy or premeditated design,
for the volume of such notes in circulation depends
entirely upon the activity of business, or upon the
kind of activity which calls for currency rather than
book credits.
Federal Reserve notes can be issued only against
collateral in an amount equal to the sum of the
Federal Reserve notes applied for, which collateral
security must be notes and bills discounted or
acquired by the banks or gold or gold certificates.
The law requires each Federal Reserve Bank to
maintain a reserve of 40 per cent in gold against its
Federal Reserve notes in actual circulation.
The Federal Reserve Banks do not make loans
direct to the public. They can rediscount only
eligible paper bearing the endorsement of a member
bank which paper represents loans made by such
member banks to their customers. Federal Reserve
Banks have nothing to say to member banks about
what loans they shall make to their customers. In
ordinary times member banks make such loans out
of their own resources and do not call upon the
Federal Reserve Banks for accommodation except for
seasonal requirements or in emergencies. During the
peak of the credit strain the maximum rediscounts
and bills payable of member banks with the Federal
Reserve Banks did not exceed 14 per cent of their
total loans and discounts. It follows, therefore, that
the volume of rediscounted paper carried by Federal
Reserve Banks fluctuates far more sharply up and
down than the total of loans and discounts of the
member banks. As the credit strain relaxes, customers reduce their loans with the bank with which
they deal, and that bank naturally reduces its line




The Federal Reserve System
of rediscounts at the Federal Reserve Bank, and thus
as the credit strain relaxed during the year 1921, the
loans of the Federal Reserve Banks to their member
banks decreased in the natural and orderly course of
business about $1,500,000,000. Furthermore, concurrently with the payment of the paper discounted
with Federal Reserve Banks, Federal Reserve note
currency has come back to the Reserve Banks and
in the absence of a demand for it, has not been
reissued. When the demand for Federal Reserve
notes falls off the banks which hold them send them
to the Reserve Banks for credit, and there necessarily
results an automatic increase in the percentage of
gold reserve available for their redemption. Federal
Reserve notes are not legal tender, nor do they count
as reserve money for member banks. They are
issued only as the need for them develops and as
they become redundant in any locality they are
returned for credit or for redemption to the Federal
Reserve Banks or to the Treasury at Washington.
Thus, there cannot be at any time more Federal
Reserve notes in circulation than the needs of the
country at the prevailing level of prices and wages
require, and as the demand abates the volume of
notes outstanding will be correspondingly reduced
through redemption.
Federal Reserve notes being but a small element
in the total volume of credit, and the bulk of our
business being carried on by checks drawn against
bank deposits, the really important thing is the
total volume of bank credit and whether this can
increase or decrease automatically according to the
needs of business and agriculture. Under the Federal
Reserve System, as business expands, as labor is
more fully employed and as production increases and
distribution becomes more active, there follows a
[22]




Credit, Currency and Business
demand for greater discount accommodations and a
need for more currency, and the increased volume of
discounts furnishes a means of providing the increased
volume of currency required.
While the general level of prices and the total
volume of credit—that is deposits and currency—
correspond roughly in their movements, prices of
individual commodities often fluctuate in directions
opposite to the general movement. For example,
last September there was a sudden and marked
advance in the price of cotton. This advance was
not due to any increase in the loans of Federal
Reserve Banks nor to any expansion of the currency.
In fact, the amount of Federal Reserve notes in
circulation on September 15th, when cotton was
selling at about 21 cents a pound, was about $500,000,000 less than when cotton was selling at 11 cents
a pound in the Spring. The advance in the price of
cotton was due to economic causes and to the operation of the law of supply and demand. After the
report of the Department of Agriculture, early in
September, the world awakened to the fact that
the cotton crop was abnormally small, and it was
thought at one time that less than seven million
bales would be produced. As the ginners' reports
were made, it became evident that the Department
of Agriculture had under-estimated the size of the
cotton crop and the price declined four or five cents
a pound.
This decline took place notwithstanding the reduction which was made about the same time in the
discount rates of all Federal Reserve Banks, including
those in the South. The fact should be emphasized
that the net advances which have taken place in
recent months in the price of cotton and other
agricultural products have been due, not to credit or
[23]




The Federal Reserve

System

currency expansion, b u t to smaller supplies and t o
increased demands for consumption.
For reasons already explained there has been a
steady and practically continuous decrease in the
volume of Federal Reserve notes in circulation since
the latter p a r t of December, 1920, reflecting general
conditions. As I have said, most of the business of
t h e country is carried on through the medium, of
b a n k checks, and the volume of currency in use
depends largely upon the activity of the industries
and retail trade.
Notwithstanding the smaller
volume of Federal Reserve notes in circulation, b a n k
deposits now show a tendency t o increase. On
M a r c h 10, 1922, the deposits of all national banks in
the United States aggregated $15,390,438,000 as
compared with $14,560,852,000 on September 6,1921.
Prices of farm products, the things which the farmer has t o sell, declined more rapidly t h a n the price
of merchandise and various things which the farmer
has t o buy. T h e result was a curtailment in farmers'
purchases which soon h a d a serious effect upon commerce and industry.
F o r several months past,
however, prices of farm products have shown an
upward tendency, while retail prices of goods have
declined.
Prices of some commodities, as furnished by the
Bureau of M a r k e t s of the D e p a r t m e n t of Agriculture,
on April 15, 1921 and April 15, 1922, were as follows:
Commodity

Market

Cotton
Corn
Wheat
Oats
Hogs

New Orleans
Chicago
Minneapolis
Chicago
Chicago

(*) Quotations for April 13, 1922.

[24]




Quotation
April 15
April 15
1921
1922
.16%
.111^
Middling
.533^ *
No. 2 mixed
.58%
1.57
Spring No. 2 1.45
*
.37
*
No. 2 white
.38^
10.15
Average price 8.50

Description

Credit, Currency and Business
Interest rates have declined in all sections of the
country. The 4)4 P e r cent Liberty Bonds have
advanced from an average price on April 15,1921, of
about $88.48 to within a fraction of par at the
present time. Twenty-five representative railroad
stocks advanced from an average of $51.70 on
April 15, 1921, to $62.25 on April 15, 1922, twentyfive industrials from $84.10 to $96.19, fifty railroad
and industrial stocks from $67.90 to $79.22, and forty
listed bonds advanced from an average of $69.89 on
April 15, 1921, to $79.97 on April 15, 1922.
The situation today in many respects is exactly
the reverse of that which existed at the end of the
year 1919. Surplus goods of all kinds have gone
into consumption and statements of merchants
throughout the country show a marked reduction in
the volume of goods on their shelves. The fact that
a revival in agriculture has come much sooner than
had been expected by those who regarded the low
prices of last summer as permanent has brought new
hope and courage to the agricultural districts and affords a basis for the belief that there will, in due time,
be a distinct business improvement in those districts.
While the situation abroad is still complicated and
will doubtless continue so for many years, there are
many indications of improvement. The exchanges of
some of the leading European countries have become
far more stable during the past twelve months and
the pound sterling in particular has made a distinct
advance toward its normal parity, the present quotation being about $4.44 as compared with $3.92 on
April 15, 1921.
American tourists are flocking to Europe this
summer in large numbers and the sums they expend
abroad will add to the ability of the foreigners to
buy American goods.




[25<]

The Federal Reserve

System

T h e past seven years have been full of momentous
and stirring events and merchants have h a d their
trials and their burdens to bear as well as all other
classes. T h e world-wide reaction which followed the
abnormal activities of the early post-war period h a d
a serious effect upon the business of wholesale
merchants, b u t it is gratifying t o know how well
they have stood u p under the strain, and in view of
the evidences of improvement which are now apparent in all sections of the country it seems t o me t h a t
the time has come when the enterprising business m a n
m a y well let others indulge in lamentations and
recriminations over the past and devote his energies
t o working out the problems of t o d a y and preparing
for the business of tomorrow.
Remember t h a t this country of ours has never
failed t o demonstrate its tremendous recuperative
power and t h a t the processes of production, distribution and consumption will be continuous as
long as h u m a n i t y endures. Let the merchants
exercise their function as distributors. If business is
dull, send out your traveling m e n ; use printers' ink—
advertise liberally b u t judiciously, and the business
t h a t you thus create for yourselves will stimulate
production and by reducing the number of unemployed will add t o t h e purchasing power of your
customers.
I n the words of E d w a r d E v e r e t t Hale, let us
"Look up and not down,
Look forward and not back,
Look out and not in,
Lend a h a n d . "

[26]