View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
7:15 p.m. EDT
March 30, 2015

Nonbank Financial Intermediation, Financial Stability, and the Road Forward

Remarks by
Stanley Fischer
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
“Central Banking in the Shadows: Monetary Policy and Financial Stability Postcrisis”
20th Annual Financial Markets Conference
sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Stone Mountain, Georgia

March 30, 2015

It is an honor to speak at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s 20th Financial
Markets Conference, and I am grateful to President Lockhart and the organizers for
inviting me to do so. 1 This evening I would like to take stock of progress on financial
reforms in the nonbank financial sector and highlight some principles for approaching
prudential regulation of this sector to further strengthen financial stability.
The nonbank sector includes firms with diverse business models and practices,
many of which differ greatly from those of banks. Even so, nonbank firms and activities
can pose the same key vulnerabilities as banks, including high leverage, excessive
maturity transformation, and complexity, all of which can lead to financial instability.
The reforms undertaken to date reflect both the differences and similarities between the
nonbank and bank sectors.
While there has been progress on the financial reform front, we should not be
complacent about the stability of the financial system. Regulation often creates
incentives for activity to move outside the regulatory perimeter, and market participants
respond to incentives. Thus we should expect that further reforms will certainly be
needed down the road.
The Nonbank Sector Was an Important Source of Vulnerability in the Crisis
As you know, the nonbank financial sector in the United States is larger, and
plays a more important role, than it does in most other countries. In recent years, about
two-thirds of nonfinancial credit market debt has been held by nonbanks, which includes
market-based funding by securitization vehicles and mutual funds as well as by
institutions such as insurance companies and finance companies. Nonbanks are involved

1

The views expressed are my own and not necessarily those of others at the Board, on the Federal Open
Market Committee, or in the Federal Reserve System.

-2in many activities within the financial system as well, such as securities lending. The
nonbank sector has produced material benefits: increased market liquidity, greater
diversity of funding sources, and--it is often claimed--a more efficient allocation of risk
to investors. However, threats to the stability of the overall financial system have also
increased, as was evident in the recent financial crisis.
It is now eight years since major cracks in the financial system that led to the
Global Financial Crisis first appeared in nonbank entities and activities. While the causes
of the crisis were complex, I will start by telling part of the tale of how nonbank distress
was transmitted to the broader financial system. The story begins with nonbank
mortgage companies, which were important originators of subprime and prime mortgage
loans, typically securitizing them or selling them to investment banks to be securitized.
Rumors of troubles among these firms were circulating in 2006 as house prices started to
decline, and a large firm filed for bankruptcy in December 2006. 2 Then New Century, at
one point the second largest subprime lender, filed for bankruptcy in April 2007 because
its funding had disappeared as a result of fears about losses. Many more followed in
2007 and 2008. Replacement of nonbank lenders’ capacity to process mortgage
applications and to fund mortgage loans occurred only partially and slowly.
Next step: The distress in mortgage markets was amplified in the broader
financial system in several ways, including something similar to a bank run but which
instead occurred on asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) vehicles. These vehicles
invested in private-label mortgage securitizations and other long-term debt securities but
were funded with short-term commercial paper. Buyers of the commercial paper issued

2

Ownit Mortgage Solutions, one of the top 20 subprime mortgage originators nationally, filed for
bankruptcy on December 28, 2006. Virtually all such firms have since either failed or been acquired.

-3by the ABCP vehicles withdrew funding starting in the late summer of 2007. The
volume of assets in the vehicles was large, about $700 billion, and after the run, the
ability of the financial system to fund credit through many types of asset-backed
securities became constrained. 3 The runs on ABCP also put considerable pressure on the
banking system because of the liquidity backstops that banks had provided to the
vehicles. 4
Some of the guarantors also insured mortgage-backed securities, and when doubts
arose about the ability of the guarantors to pay claims on mortgage-backed securities, the
credibility of their guarantees of municipal securities was also reduced. Municipalities
then found it more difficult and costly to issue debt even though their activities were
otherwise unrelated to subprime mortgages. 5
Next, the crisis spread to nonbank finance companies, which made a substantial
fraction of consumer loans in the United States--for example, auto and credit card loans.
As the crisis went on, the ability of such lenders to fund themselves through
securitizations and commercial paper became increasingly constrained. For a period after
the failure of Lehman Brothers, many investors were unwilling to buy commercial paper
and asset-backed securities at any price, and, as a result, finance companies faced tight

3

See Daniel Covitz, Nellie Liang, and Gustavo Suarez (2013), “The Evolution of a Financial Crisis:
Collapse of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Market,” Journal of Finance, vol. 68 (June), pp. 815-48.
4
Runs on the repurchase agreement (repo) funding of asset-backed securities were also troublesome for
both banks and nonbanks. See Gary Gorton and Andrew Metrick (2012), “Securitized Banking and the
Run on Repo,” Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 104 (June), pp. 425-51.
5
Moreover, state and municipal borrowers had been issuing long-term debt while paying short-term
interest rates by using structures such as variable-rate demand notes (VRDNs), which gave holders the right
to put the securities back to liquidity providers on short notice. When the money market fund investors that
held VRDNs became worried about their ability to get their money out at short notice, the volume of
putbacks rose, and these developments ultimately led to increased payment obligations for some
municipalities.

-4funding constraints. In turn, the finance companies cut credit availability, which sharply
depressed purchases of consumer durables, including automobiles.
These examples highlight five lessons. One is that the recent crisis first
manifested itself in the nonbank sector and was worse for the nonbank sector than for
banks. Almost all the examples of financial distress mentioned so far occurred before
stress in the commercial banking system became acute, and in most cases well before.
For example, only three commercial banks failed in the United States in 2007, and
commercial bank distress did not peak until the end of 2008 and later.
A second lesson is that nonbank distress can harm the real economy. Mortgages,
auto loans, and credit through securities issuance became harder to obtain. Some of the
slack was taken up by commercial banks, but credit contracted sharply, and millions of
Americans suffered.
Third lesson: Many of the problems at nonbanks were similar to the problems
that plagued banks. These problems included insolvency, illiquidity (by which I mean
the loss of access to funding even if the nonbank was solvent), and a general loss of
confidence, in which counterparties of all kinds became reluctant to deal with some
nonbanks.
Fourth lesson: The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) can handle a
bank insolvency by keeping the bank’s functions running while it pays off depositors and
finds buyers for the bank’s assets. The Federal Reserve, as a central bank, can address
bank illiquidity using its lender-of-last-resort authority. Bank supervisory agencies can
address a loss of confidence by actions such as the stress tests conducted in the spring of
2009. However the lack of such powers for nonbanks made it much more difficult for the

-5authorities to address the distress of nonbanks and its influence on the financial system.
Before the crisis, the authorities had few policy levers to provide liquidity or to resolve
failures of nonbanks in a way that would avoid serious spillovers. Liquidity was
ultimately provided to some nonbank markets, such as the markets for securities backed
by consumer and business assets, but the facilities were far from simple and took
substantial time to create and implement. 6
Finally, nonbank distress can transmit to the banking sector through many
channels, such as counterparty relationships, disruptions in funding markets, and knockon effects of asset fire sales. The failure of Lehman provides a good example. It was a
nonbank, and its failure both imposed direct losses on its many types of counterparties
and disrupted many markets with negative effects on banks.
Principles for Prudential Regulation of Nonbank Intermediaries and Activities
It is widely understood that any regulation of nonbanks should fit their activities
and the vulnerabilities they pose, which implies that not every nonbank financial
institution or activity necessarily needs to be regulated. The two key principles for
prudential regulation of nonbanks when it is warranted, are simple: First, we should be
attentive to solvency and liquidity; second, we should recognize that the financial system
will change over time, and thus close monitoring and analysis of the system are essential.
Insolvency and illiquidity are classic financial stability concerns. And as
mentioned, they were common themes of the distress at nonbanks that we observed

6

See Gorton and Metrick, “Securitized Banking,” in note 4, op.cit.; Jeremy Stein (2012), “Monetary Policy
as Financial Stability Regulation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 127, pp. 57–95; Robin
Greenwood, Samuel Hanson, and Jeremy Stein (2014), “A Comparative-Advantage Approach to
Government Debt Maturity,” Journal of Finance, vol. 65, pp. 993–1028.

-6during the crisis. Thus, we will not go far wrong if we begin by considering how to
promote solvency and liquidity, taking into account the unique structures and activities of
each type of nonbank.
Liquidity challenges vary across nonbank firms and activities. In some, the issue
is whether a firm can fund itself in a distressed situation. For example, a broker-dealer
that relies heavily on short-term wholesale funding may find its funding evaporating at
the first sign of trouble--a situation that could force the sale of assets at fire sale prices.
One way to mitigate such problems is by having direct restrictions on the structure of
liabilities, such as on their duration or on the use of wholesale funding. Analogously
with banks, one could also imagine requiring some nonbanks to maintain buffers of
highly liquid assets that are sized according to the risk that their liabilities will run off
quickly in a stress situation.
In other nonbanks, withdrawable liabilities are part of the structure of the entity or
activity, and what varies is the degree of mismatch between the liquidity of assets and
liabilities. For example, some open-ended mutual funds offer daily withdrawal privileges
but invest in assets that take longer to sell and settle, giving investors an incentive to
withdraw quickly when distress arises. The fire sales of assets that may result can
depress asset prices and increase volatility, with knock-on effects on other institutions
and markets. Concerns have grown about this liquidity mismatch as the aggregate value
of less liquid assets in such funds has grown. In part because of this concern, in a
December Federal Register notice last year, the Financial Stability Oversight Council
(FSOC) requested public comment on potential systemic risks posed by asset manager
activities and products.

-7To promote solvency, one could impose ratio-type capital requirements, such as
leverage ratio requirements or risk-based requirements. An alternative is to require that
firms perform regular stress tests to demonstrate that they can remain solvent and
continue to lend even under stress. In the Fed’s case, it has chosen to impose all of these
requirements on banks, but these requirements cannot simply be applied, as is, to
nonbanks.
It is well known that solvency and liquidity can be difficult to separate during
stress periods because fears about solvency, even if unfounded, can prompt a run. Thus,
one could also imagine promoting both solvency and liquidity at some nonbanks by
imposing restrictions on their structure or activities in ways that reduce the likelihood of
runs. An example of this is recent changes by the Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC) in regulations for prime money market mutual funds. Starting in 2016, prime
institutional money funds will be required to publish a floating net asset value rather than
a stable value of $1 per unit. Stable-value funds, as we saw during the crisis, can be
vulnerable to an unexpected “break the buck” event that leads to a run. Under the new
rules, funds can also impose limitations on withdrawals of liabilities and can impose
liability redemption fees. The SEC considered requiring money market funds to hold
some capital but chose not to do so. Only time will tell whether the adopted reforms have
the intended run-damping effects, but if they do, capital will be much less necessary.
Some may raise concerns that increased regulation of nonbanks will only increase
moral hazard and increase risk to the system on net. But moral hazard may already be
present. Over the past 20 years and more, governments have sometimes acted to contain
damage from distress at nonbanks because of the economic damage that might have

-8resulted from a failure to act. We should always be mindful of moral hazard incentives
and seek to contain them, but well-designed regulation might reduce rather than increase
moral hazard. In the banking sector, bank regulators have focused on improving
resolution planning at banks and enhancing the ability of the FDIC to manage the
resolution of a systemically important firm in a way that mitigates spillovers to the
economy. For example, proposals are now under consideration to require the largest and
most interconnected banks to maintain a buffer of debt that could be converted to equity
or that could otherwise absorb losses upon failure. Such proposals could be viewed as a
form of solvency regulation and this form of loss-absorbing capital might be appropriate
for some of the largest and most interconnected nonbanks as well.
In addition, nonbank intermediation often involves complex chains of activity
encompassing many entities and markets. Such chains tend to increase the web of
interconnections in the financial system that, in some circumstances, can increase the
likelihood or severity of systemic stress. For example, movements in collateral values
can trigger margin calls and fire sales of assets, and thus activities that depend on marketvalued collateral can be vulnerable. The Financial Stability Board is currently
considering reforms for margins on securities financing transactions. Other
interconnections involve exposures to counterparty default. The new regulatory regime
for derivatives, which I will discuss in a moment, seeks to mitigate counterparty risk.
It is often said that stronger regulation of the banking sector will cause activity to
move outside the perimeter of regulation. This evolution also could lead to greater
complexity, such as longer chains of interconnections, which makes it more difficult for
market participants to understand the risks arising from their exposures. Examples of

-9migration that have already occurred include the movement of many loans made to large
corporations from banks to collateralized loan obligations, the securitization of many
credit card receivables, and the securitization of mortgages. This kind of migration
makes close monitoring by regulators particularly important. Authorities should monitor
for changes that may arise in response to the new regulations or to changing economic
and financial conditions. They will need information to do so, but for many nonbank
entities, the flow of information is currently nonexistent or very limited and informal.
Another force for evolution in the nonbank sector is the demand for safe moneylike assets. Some argue that this demand for private money creation prompted the growth
in “shadow banking” prior to the crisis. 7 Indeed, whenever shortages develop, we might
expect the nonbank financial system to create assets that appear safe but that could in
certain circumstances pose systemic risks.
Progress to Date
We have seen some progress in improving the regulation of the nonbank financial
sector. Let me mention four areas of reform. The first is the Dodd-Frank Act’s creation
of the FSOC and the power it was given to designate individual nonbank firms as
systemically important and thus subject to prudential regulation by the Federal Reserve.
The FSOC has designated four nonbank firms as systemically important. 8 The FSOC is
also a useful venue for regulators to collaborate on identifying emerging threats. And it

7

See Gorton and Metrick, “Securitized Banking,” in note 4; Samuel G. Hanson, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy C.
Stein, and Robert W. Vishny (forthcoming), “Banks and Patient Fixed-Income Investors,” Journal of
Financial Economics; and Zoltan Pozsar, Tobias Adrian, Adam Ashcraft, and Hayley Boesky (2010),
“Shadow Banking,” Staff Report 458 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, July; revised
February 2012), www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr458.html.
8
The four firms designated by the FSOC as systemically important are American International Group, Inc.;
Prudential Financial, Inc.; General Electric Capital Corporation, Inc.; and MetLife, Inc.

- 10 is an important mechanism through which agencies can cooperate in responding to
practices or firms that migrate outside of traditional regulatory perimeters.
Second: securitization reform. A regulation that is now in the process of
implementation requires securitizers to retain some of the risk of the securities that they
create. That should incentivize them to structure securitizations in ways that better
protect the holders of senior tranches from credit risk, although qualifying residential
mortgages are exempt from the requirement.
A third area is derivative reforms. To reduce complexity and pro-cyclicality,
these reforms include moving standardized derivatives to central counterparties (CCPs)
and requiring initial and variation margin for noncleared derivatives. Relatedly, as CCPs
have gained prominence, regulators have become more focused on and concerned with
their resilience, recovery, and resolution. In addition, regulators are working to improve
the quality and standardization of data reported to swap data repositories, and are actively
participating in international efforts to develop uniform identification standards to
facilitate the aggregation of such data. 9 A key issue is to understand how and to what
extent market participants who use derivatives are exposed to each other.
Besides the new money market mutual fund rules that I have already mentioned, a
fourth example is additional data collection on specific holdings of money funds, which
has enhanced stability by providing investors with more information to better evaluate
risks. In addition, the Dodd-Frank Act mandated the establishment of the Office of
Financial Research in order to help promote financial stability through the measurement

9

Due to the critical nature of overseas derivatives data and the need to standardize these data for regulatory
analysis, the CFTC and the OFR in 2014 formed a partnership to standardize and enhance the quality of the
data collected by CFTC-registered swap data repositories. Important work on standardizing derivatives
data is also under way at the international level.

- 11 and analysis of risks, the conduct of essential research, and the collection and
standardization of financial data. Data collection has begun for hedge funds and progress
is being made in collecting data on repurchase agreements and securities lending.
Nevertheless, some nonbank firms and activities – including concerning the volume and
uses of derivatives – are still opaque.

To sum up, much has been done to strengthen prudential regulation and
supervision of the nonbank financial system, but more will need to be done. We must
remain vigilant for changes in the system that increase systemic risk, and we should make
appropriate changes to regulation and the structure of regulation as necessary. Recent
regulatory changes, including a macroprudential approach on the part of U.S. regulators,
should help us to do that. 10 But we should never forget the International Monetary
Fund’s all-purpose warning whenever it has been tempted to give an economy a clean bill
of health: Complacency must be avoided.

10

This change is reflected in the setting up of the LISCC – the Large Institution Supervision Coordinating
Committee.