View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ECONOMY MATTERS

ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Untangling the Complex Causes of Inequality
December 4, 2018
ANNUAL REPORT

ECONOMIC RESEARCH

BANKING & FINANCE

REGIONAL ECONOMICS

COMM/ECON DEV

INSIDE THE FED

DEPARTMENTS

Financial Tips
Podcast
Quizzes
Staff & Credits
Subscribe to e-mail
updates

As concerns about widening gaps in income and wealth permeate economic policy discussion, the Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta assembled some of the field's leading thinkers to explore the roots of inequality from various perspectives. When
considering a topic as complex as inequality, economists and policymakers advance numerous questions such as the role of
education and school quality in the intergenerational transmission of income, the economic importance of a person's physical
location, and the role that higher education financing occupies in economic potential.
Indeed, Harvard University economist Raj Chetty recently grabbed headlines with his trailblazing Opportunity Atlas, a look at
how one's physical location can affect social mobility. Chetty recently visited the Atlanta Fed to discuss his work as part of the
Bank's ninth annual employment conference, "The Changing Nature of Inequality across Firms, Geography, and Generations."
Melinda Pitts, research economist and director of the Atlanta Fed's Center for Human Capital Studies, organized the conference
along with Richard Rogerson of Princeton University and Robert Shimer of the University of Chicago.
Atlanta Fed research conferences showcase new analytical work on important economic questions. In this case, inequality
intrigued Pitts and her team because the divergence of income, wealth, and opportunity is a pressing concern in research and
policy circles. Perhaps as a result, some of the most interesting labor market research today explores these matters, she said.
"We like to bring in a diversity of research methods—micro, macro, theoretical, and applied—so that
the focus is big-picture and policy oriented," Pitts explained.
While focused broadly on inequality, the conference convened economists who are exploring the
subject from different angles, ranging from the implications of hyper-productive "superstar firms" to
economic mobility in underserved neighborhoods. The conference's keynote presenter was Raj
Chetty, the Harvard economist whose work on economic mobility by individual census tract has
garnered widespread acclaim.
Additional conference papers examined the stagnation of median lifetime incomes over the past half
century, states' financing of higher education, and the degree to which a few large employers
dominate local labor markets, among other topics.
The Atlanta Fed's Melinda
Pitts, one of the conference
organizers. Photo by Keith
Gray

Below are summaries of some of the papers presented at the conference. Please visit the
conference web page for links to the complete papers.

Superstar firms pay well but contribute to lower labor share of GDP
A widely cited 2017 paper presented at the conference, "The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms," examines
the rise of "superstar firms" that are so productive they have amassed huge profits and increasingly large market shares in
various industries. These companies do not appear to skimp on salaries, said David Dorn, a coauthor who presented the paper.

Rather, they contribute in a different way to the declining share of overall income that flows to labor, what economists call "the
labor share." These companies are so profitable, with fewer employees relative to traditional large firms, that more of their
income flows to capital as opposed to labor, thus exacerbating an ongoing trend throughout the economy.
In retail trade, the combined market share of the four biggest firms has more than doubled since the
early 1980s, rising to 30 percent, Dorn and his coauthors found. Meanwhile, the share of those sales
flowing to payroll has dipped by about 7 percent.
Dorn and his fellow authors find that industries where sales have concentrated most show the
sharpest declines in the share of income funneling to workers.
It's not entirely clear what is causing this concentration of market share. However, the researchers
point to technology as a probable reason. The rise in concentration of sales, according to the paper,
is "disproportionately apparent in industries experiencing faster technical change … suggesting that
technological dynamism, rather than simply anticompetitive forces, is an important driver of this
trend."
David Dorn at the Atlanta Fed
conference. Photo by Keith

The rise of superstar firms and decline in the labor share of income also may be related to the
proliferation of outsourcing, according to Dorn. Large employers, he explains, increasingly use
contracting firms, temporary help agencies, and independent contractors for a wider range of work
that traditionally was done in-house.
Gray

Incomes stagnating across generations
Another paper discussed at the conference analyzes the trajectory of workers' career-long incomes. In a nutshell, the news is
not good.
The researchers' findings are significant. Such a sweeping examination of lifetime income distribution is unusual, as most
research looks at incomes at a particular point in time—say, comparing what people in different generations earn at age 40—
because the mass of data needed to explore ongoing incomes of millions of people across decades has typically been
unavailable.
In fact, the presenter, Fatih Guvenen of the University of Minnesota and the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and his
coauthors write that they believe their paper—titled "Lifetime Incomes in the United States"—is the first analysis of lifetime
income distributions for a large number of age groups in the United States. The researchers examined a 57-year-long set of
data, from 1957 to 2013. The oldest group they analyzed turned 25 years old in 1957, and the youngest turned 55 in 2013.
Guvenen and his coauthors found that for a vast swath of the workforce, median lifetime incomes adjusted for inflation declined.

For example, the group that began their careers in 1983 have a lifetime median income that is 10 to 19 percent lower than that of
the group that entered the labor market in 1967. In particular, lifetime income showed little to no increase for those in the bottom
75 percent of male lifetime income distribution. More generous employer-provided health and pension benefits somewhat offset
those results, but that "does not alter the substantive conclusions," wrote Guvenen and his coauthors.
Median lifetime income for women increased sharply, by 22 to 33 percent, during the same span. However, those gains came off
very low incomes for the earliest age group, the researchers point out. Median incomes stagnated mainly because of substantial
changes in income early in careers, especially for men.
The economists conclude that to determine why the distribution of U.S. income has tilted dramatically toward the top of the
spectrum over the past 50 years, we must better understand what is happening early in the careers of more recent generations
of workers and how their experiences differ from those of previous generations.
Findings from other papers include:
States that invest more public money in higher education have larger proportions of college-educated workers in their
labor force than states that invest less. The author, John Kennan of the University of Wisconsin-Madison, also
estimates that a uniformly inexpensive national tuition rate would significantly boost the share of college graduates in
the country. The resulting increase in income taxes paid by more high-earning workers would almost completely offset
the loss in tuition revenue, his model suggests.
School quality is probably not a huge factor in differences in economic mobility among children in different
neighborhoods. That is not to say that school quality is unimportant, emphasized the author, Jesse Rothstein of the
University of California-Berkeley. But strictly in terms of the variation among locales in intergenerational income
transmission—basically, kids earning more than their parents—evidence indicates that factors other than school
quality may matter more. Those include cultural tendencies toward early marriage and the presence of "labor market
networks," which essentially means knowing neighbors and friends who are employed and may be able to help you
find a job.
A paper presented by Esteban Rossi-Hansberg of Princeton University explores
why people stay in less-promising locations rather than moving to places that
offer better prospects for them and their families. Rossi-Hansberg and his
coauthor argue that we can understand location decisions as an investment in a
"location asset." Their work suggests that "savers" choose to spend more today
by living in a more expensive area that offers better future returns. On the other
hand, "borrowers" go to cheap locations to avoid bigger expenses today, in
some cases—such as a blue-collar worker with little wealth who has lost a job—
because that is all they can reasonably afford.
Interactions among inventors and researchers are crucial to productivity and
economic growth. The authors of this paper used a new set of data on millions
of European inventors to bring hard statistics to a body of research that had
been largely theoretical, allowing researchers to better quantify typically
Jesse Rothstein discusses his
ambiguous concepts such as interactions, productivity or knowledge, and the
value of research teams. According to presenter Stefanie Stantcheva of Harvard research. Photo by Keith Gray
University and her coauthors, their model could be used to study policy questions such as how immigration policies
affect the inflow of inventors and ideas.
In the average U.S. labor market—for example, a metropolitan area—workers have limited choices of employers. This
labor market concentration is associated with significantly lower wages advertised in job listings, according to an
analysis based on the most frequent occupations posted on the employment website CareerBuilder.com.

Charles Davidson
Staff writer for Economy Matters