View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

JULY 1990
NUMBER 35

Chicago Fed Letter
W hat we know about the
deposit insurance problem
When the final bill is in for the
1980s, the difference between assets
and liabilities at insolvent banks and
thrifts may well turn out to have
been as great a $200 billion—over
$2,000 per household. The magni­
tude of the losses has propelled the
debate over deposit insurance re­
form to the top of the political and
regulatory agenda.
Economists have argued about de­
posit insurance reform for many
years. For most of that time, their
arguments—both pro and con—
were based more on theory than on
empirical evidence. But events in
the financial services industry, espe­
cially in savings and loans (S&Ls),
have now provided the needed em­
pirical underpinning. Recent re­
search has further amplified our
knowledge of the effects of deposit
insurance and the importance of
market forces in the regulation of
banking.
Based on the accumulated evidence,
this Chicago Fed Letter asserts several
propositions that should form the
basis of future debates on deposit
insurance.
1. Deposit insurance is different

What has become abundantly clear is
that deposit insurance is very differ­
ent from other forms of insurance.
With other forms—life, auto, etc.—
the insurer has only limited control
of risk once the decision to insure
and the terms of the contract are set.
With deposit insurance, the insurer
can control risk. Indeed, losses are

only incurred when the insurer has
failed to act promptly with the regula­
tory tools it has at its disposal— par­
ticularly its power to close an institu­
tion before, or as soon as, it becomes
insolvent. Thus, the costs of deposit
insurance can be made arbitrarily
small by forcing recapitalization,
liquidation, or merger before losses
begin accruing to the insurer.1

vent today were also the most insol­
vent in 1982. This fact suggests, and
several studies confirm, that these
institutions were engaged in end-ofgame play—going, as it were, for
broke. This kind of behavior was
made much easier by deposit insur­
ance and the failure of the regula­
tory agencies to enforce meaningful
capital guidelines.

2. Moral hazard is real

The failure—for whatever reasons—
of the regulatory bodies to use their
preventive tools to avert deposit in­
surance losses represents, in effect, a
subsidy to insolvent and poorly capi­
talized financial institutions. The
availability of this subsidized deposit
insurance gives beneficiaries an in­
centive to increase their expected
profits by taking additional risks.
This is known as moral hazard. The
evidence that moral hazard is an
im portant part of the deposit insur­
ance problem takes several forms.
For example, Charles Calomiris
found that during the 1920s failure
rates for banks participating in staterun deposit insurance schemes were
more volatile than failure rates for
uninsured national banks. This sug­
gests that insured banks were taking
greater risks than uninsured banks.
O ther evidence comes from the thrift
industry during the 1980s. Capitaldeficient and insolvent thrifts were
the ones most heavily involved in
nontraditional activities at that time.
What is less well known is that most
of these thrifts were already insolvent
when they began their expansion
into nontraditional activities follow­
ing the passage of the Garn-St Ger­
main Act in 1982. Indeed, those
institutions that are the most insol­

<2

2-4
4-6
years insolvent

>6

S O U R C E : James Barth. Based on generally accepted
accounting principals.

Several recent studies suggest that
poorly capitalized institutions have
actively sought to take additional
risk. George Benston and Michael
Koehn found that increased empha­
sis on riskier nontraditional activities
by these thrifts resulted in greater
stock price volatility. In contrast,
shifts toward nontraditional activities
by healthy thrifts reduced stock price
volatility. This suggests that dis­
tressed thrifts were acting to maxi­
mize the value of deposit insurance.
Elijah Brewer tested the hypothesis
that shareholders of distressed thrifts
rewarded additional risk-taking by

h h h b h HHHHHHNI

|||::||||lillll||||||®|■ I :||||11|||||||||| ■
|i' I:
||||||111|||'|||.§ |§ I11||||I||.|||||§|||I|||||| i I ®
| §1
|fgs

_

management. He found that the
announcem ent of shifts in asset com­
position toward nontraditional activi­
ties resulted in a one-time increase in
the market value of equity for dis­
tressed institutions but had no effect
on healthy institutions. This suggests
that the shareholders encourage
moral hazard by rewarding actions
that raise the value of the insurance
subsidy.
The evidence of moral hazard in
banking is weaker than it is in S&Ls,
perhaps because only a small portion
of the industry has been insolvent at
any one time. However, there is evi­
dence that the same factors are at
work. Gregory Gajewski used a fail­
ure prediction model to identify 600
small banks that were “ persistently
vulnerable” to failure. A third of
these 600 banks displayed the same
rapid growth of assets that has been
associated with end-of-game play in
the thrift industry.

...................................................................................... :

oped countries (LDCs). Also during
the 1980s, Congress gave preferential
treatm ent to small agricultural banks
facing capital problems.
The final piece of evidence is that the
banking system is incurring more
losses today, when it is shielded from
the market by deposit insurance and
forbearance, than it did prior to the
creation of federal deposit insurance.
Losses per dollar of deposits are
higher today than in the 1930s. This
is particularly striking because GNP
fell 30% in the early 1930s while it
rose during the 1980s by 28%. (See
Figure 2.)
One could argue that the 1920s pro­
vide a more relevant comparison.
And here the contrast is even more
striking. Loss rates during the 1920s
were about 0.1% of all deposits while
in the last half of the 1980s they were
about 0.7% of all deposits.
4. Market forces are valuable

3. Forbearance is costly

Allowing an insolvent financial insti­
tution to remain open is known as
forbearance. Deposit insurance cre­
ates a climate that fosters forbear­
ance. Those who stand to lose from
closures—stockholders—can apply
great political pressure to regulators.
Regulators themselves may be reluc­
tant to admit that banks under their
supervision need to be closed. Dur­
ing the 1920s, for example, Nebraska
regulators perm itted some insolvent
banks to operate for 10 years before
they were closed.
Forbearance was endemic in the
thrift industry during the 1980s.
James Barth, former research direc­
tor for the Federal Home Loan Bank
Board, reports that 45% of the thrifts
that were insolvent in 1988 had been
insolvent for four or more years.
(See Figure 1.)
During the 1980s, forbearance has
also occurred in commercial bank­
ing. Bank regulators did not force
commercial banks to reflect fully
their losses on loans to less devel­

Market participants do not necessar­
ily have better information. How­
ever, they have different incentives to
make use of the information they do
have. Depositors at uninsured banks
have an incentive to run as soon as
they have doubts about the condition
of the bank. In this environment,
forbearance is more difficult to
achieve. With deposit insurance in
force, however, the closure decision
becomes entirely a regulatory event.
The elimination of uninsured credi­
tors also has political implications.
When uninsured creditors are pres­
ent, effective forbearance merely
redistributes money from these credi­
tors to shareholders. For every
shareholder who benefits from for­
bearance, there will be an uninsured
creditor who loses. Thus, forbear­
ance generates few benefits for poli­
ticians or regulators. With the elimi­
nation of creditor discipline, the only
market influence left is from share­
holders. The goal of the sharehold­
ers of an insolvent bank is simple—to
keep the bank open as long as pos­
sible. To do so, shareholders will

lobby anyone and everyone in sight.
The result is greater forbearance and
a more costly deposit insurance sys­
tem. Deposit insurance reforms that
restore creditor discipline will be
doubly effective because they will
also restore political discipline.
5. Banks— and regulators— need
sensible, explicit directives

One of the reasons the current sys­
tem has broken down is that regula­
tors have, rightly or wrongly, been so
concerned about deposit runs that
they have been unwilling to perm it
uninsured depositors to suffer losses.
But, lowering insurance limits will
not be sufficient to restore creditor
discipline. Congress must either
explicitly tell regulators that it wants
these losses imposed, or Congress
and regulators must find a way to
restore creditor discipline without
relying on deposit runs.
Indeed, the experience of the 1980s
has shown that at least some creditors
of large institutions can be penalized
without creating spillover to the rest
of the system. The best support for
this proposition comes from our
experience in Texas. Creditors at
several large Texas holding compa­
nies suffered significant losses during
the 1980s. The systemic effects of this
have been minimal. Clearly, if the
notion that some banks are too-bigto-fail has any implications, they are
about who in the private sector
should bear losses, not whether or
not the losses should be borne by the
private sector. This suggests that
proposals to place the primary bur­
den of creditor discipline on subordi­
nated creditors,2 on private insurers,
or on mutual guarantee systems may
be more compatible with regulator’s
incentives, and hence more useful,
than a proposal to simply adhere to
dejure insurance limits.
How can the regulatory system pro­
mote rapid closure? The SEC’s regu­
lation of broker dealers provides an
example. Minimum capital require­
ments, market-value accounting,
uninsured debt, “ haircuts,” and a

turing insolvent institutions. Second,
there ceased to be a political con­
stituency interested in seeking the
rapid closure of insolvent institu­
tions. This led to delays in closing
insolvent institutions and in turn cre­
ated a serious moral hazard problem.

_________: ----------------------------------losses as a percent of all deposits

A
/\
/ \

a.O
1Q

/

4O
1

J

06

S
^

------------------------ --------------------------0.0
,
1922
1978

‘23
79

’24
’80

*25
’81

f

J

1 2 -3
92 3

\
11978-89

____1
________1
________1
________ 1
________1
________ 1
________ 1
________1
________
’33
’28
’29
’30
’31
’32
’26
*27
'89
’84
’85
’86
'87
'88
’83
82

S O U R C E : Bert Ely, Ely and Company., Inc.

closure rule that shuts firms down
while they still have positive capital
work together to control losses aris­
ing from asset portfolios that are
much more volatile than those held
by banks. Similar systems are em­
ployed by futures clearinghouses to
regulate clearing members. It is
interesting to note that, despite the
risky nature of the business they con­
duct, no clearing member of the
Chicago Board of Trade or the Chi­
cago Mercantile Exchange has ever
failed. Bank regulators would do
well to study these sorts of systems
more closely than they have.

Why the difference between the two
industries? As noted earlier, BHC
creditors have sustained substantial
losses. Because creditors will be at
risk, BHCs’ subsidiaries will not be
able to fund themselves unless they
make prudent investments. In this
case, firewalls perform the vital func­
tion of keeping nontraditional activi­
ties from being funded with insured
deposits. The lesson is clear: With
creditor discipline, expanded powers
are beneficial. Without creditor dis­
cipline they are a disaster.

6. Reform should precede
new powers

The heavy losses suffered by insol­
vent banks and thrifts during the
1980s make clear the im portant role
that the closure decision plays in con­
trolling the cost of deposit insurance.
Had creditors or regulators closed
down these institutions as soon as
their condition had become imper­
iled, the losses to the deposit insur­
ance funds would have been much
smaller. However, the governm ent’s
dejure and de facto guarantees elimi­
nated depositor incentives to with­
draw funds from capital deficient and
insolvent institutions.

When high-risk activities can be
funded with artificially cheap insured
deposits, expanding banks’ powers
only serves to broaden the opportu­
nities for bank risk-taking. However,
with proper restrictions in place,
expanded powers can be beneficial.
In another study, Brewer examines
the impact of expanded powers on
bank holding companies. The find­
ings are instructive. In contrast to
the thrift experience, Brewer finds
that nontraditional activities were
risk-reducing for all holding compa­
nies and were most beneficial for
holding companies that initially had
the greatest risk of failure.

These developments underline the
crucial role that creditor discipline
plays in controlling risk-taking. They
also suggest that deposit insurance
reforms that fail to create a private
sector constituency for prom pt clo­
sure begin their operations with a
possibly fatal flaw. If legislators and
regulators wish to avoid failure of
future deposit insurance systems, it is
im portant that creditor discipline be
reintroduced and that regulators
have an incentive to permit that disci­
pline to work.
—H erbert L. Baer
^ e n s t o n , G e o rg e J., R o b e rt A. E isenbeis,
P aul M. H orvitz, E dw ard J. K ane, a n d
G e o rg e G. K aufm an, Perspectives on Safe
and Sound Banking: Past, Present, and Fu­
ture, C a m b rid g e , Mass.: M IT Press, 1986.
2See, fo r in sta n c e , Silas K eehn, B anking
on the Balance: Powers and the Safety net,
F e d e ra l R eserve B an k o f C hicago, 1989.

Conclusion

This loss of creditor discipline had
two consequences. First, the govern­
m ent regulators were forced to bear
the entire responsibility for restruc­

Karl A. S cheld, S en io r Vice P re sid e n t a n d
D irecto r o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P re sid e n t a n d A ssistant D irecto r o f R esearch;
E dw ard G. N ash, E ditor.
Chicago Fed Letter is p u b lish e d m o n th ly by th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t o f th e F ed eral Reserve
B ank o f C hicago. T h e views ex p ressed are th e
a u th o r s ’ a n d are n o t necessarily th o se o f th e
F ed eral Reserve B ank o f C hicago o r th e
F ed eral R eserve System. A rticles m ay be
re p rin te d if th e source is c re d ite d a n d th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t is p ro v id ed w ith copies
o f th e rep rin ts.
Chicago Fed Letter is available w ith o u t ch arg e
fro m th e Public In fo rm a tio n C e n te r, F ed eral
Reserve B ank o f C hicago, P.O. Box 834,
C hicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.

ISSN 0895-0164

After rebounding in February and March from January’s depressed auto
production levels, manufacturing activity in the Midwest dropped sharply
(down 1.8%) in April. Most industries experienced the decline, led by trans­
portation equipm ent and primary metals. Only industries in the chemical
sector continued to expand in April. Nationally, manufacturing activity de­
clined 0.3%.
The pattern in manufacturing activity is being heavily influenced by auto
production. Auto production dropped to a 4 million unit annual rate in
January, from over a 7 million rate at the end of 1989. After rebounding to a
7 million unit rate in March, production dropped again to a 6 million rate.

Chicago Fed Letter
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO
Public Information Center
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690
(312) 322-5111

11
3S10
NANCY AHLSTROM
RESEARCH

CHI

N O T E: T h e MMI a n d th e USMI are co m p o site
in d ex es o f 17 m a n u fa c tu rin g in d u stries a n d are
deriv ed fro m e c o n o m e tric m o d els th a t
estim ate o u tp u t from m o n th ly h o u rs w o rk ed
a n d kilow att h o u rs data. F or a discussion o f
th e m eth o d o lo g y , see “R eco n sid erin g th e
R egional M an u fac tu rin g In d e x e s,” Economic
Perspectives, F ed eral Reserve B ank o f C hicago,
Vol. X III, N o. 4, Ju ly /A u g u s t 1989.