View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 89-1
Wage Growth and the Inflation Process: An Empirical Note

Yash P. Mehra*
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
P.O. Box 27622
Richmond, VA 23261
804-697-8247
April 1989

*Research Officer and Economist. The views expressed are those of the authors
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Abstract
A central proposition in the Phillips curve view of the inflation
process is that prices are marked up over productivity-adjusted labor costs.
If that is true, then long-run movements in prices and labor costs must be
correlated. If long-run movements in a time series are modeled as a
stochastic trend, then the above noted implication of the 'price markup' view
is related to the concept of cointegration discussed in Granger (1986), which
says that cointegrated multiple time series share common stochastic trends.
The evidence reported here shows that time series measuring rates of change in
prices and labor costs are cointegrated. Furthermore, this cointegration
appears consistent with Granger-causality running from the rate of change in
prices to the rate of change in labor costs, but not vice versa as suggested
by the 'price markup' view.

A popular theoretical model of the inflation process is the
expectations-augmented Phillips curve model, which generally assumes that
prices are set as a markup over productivity-adjusted labor costs, the latter
being determined by expected inflation and the degree of demand pressure.1
is assumed further that expected inflation depends on past inflation.

It

This

model thus implies that wages and prices are causally related with feedbacks
in both directions.
However, in a recent contribution Gordon (1988) has presented
evidence consistent with the inference that changes in wages and prices are
not related in the Granger-causal sense.

This finding is in sharp contrast to

the results reported in the early empirical work (see, for example, Barth and
Bennett (1975) and Mehra (1977))2, which had found wages and prices are
related with Granger-causality running either in both directions or only from
prices to wages.
This article reexamines the relationship between productivityadjusted wages and prices using the recent technique of cointegration. The
essence of the 'price markup' hypothesis stated above is that long-run
movements in prices are related to long-run movements in productivity-adjusted

'This version has been closely associated with the work of Gordon (1982,
85, 88). See also Stockton and Glassman (1987).
2 The sample periods and the data used in these studies are different.
Barth and Bennett (1975) studied causal patterns between prices and wages over
the period 1947Q1 to 1970Q4. The measures of prices used were wholesale and
consumer prices, and wages were measured by the hourly wages of production
workers. They found Granger-causality only from prices to wages. Mehra
(1977) found feedbacks in both directions between consumer prices and money
wages at the two-digit level manufacturing industries over the period 1954Q1
to 1970Q4. Gordon (1988) measures prices by the fixed-weight GNP deflator and
wages by hourly earnings adjusted for overtime, employment mix, and fringe
benefits. In addition, Gordon (1988) also adjusts earnings for productivity.
The sample period covered in this study is 1954Q2 to 1987Q3.

-2 -

wages.

If long-run movements in a time series are modeled as a stochastic

trend, then the implication above is related to the concept of cointegration
discussed in Granger (1986), which states cointegrated multiple time series
share common stochastic trends.

It is shown that variables measuring the

rates of growth in wages and prices are cointegrated. However, the presence
of this long-run relationship between the rates of change in wages and prices
appears consistent with Granger-causality existing from the rate of change in
prices to the rate of change in wages, not vice versa as suggested by the
'price markup' view.

Thus, the results reported here are more in line with

those in Barth and Bennett (1975) than in Gordon (1988).
The plan of this article is as follows.

Section 1 presents a

Phillips curve model of the inflation process and discusses its implications
for the relationship between wages and prices.

It also discusses how tests

for cointegration and Granger-causality can be used to examine such wage-price
dynamics.

Section 2 presents the empirical results and Section 3 contains the

concluding observations.

1.

A PhilliDs Curve Model and its ImPlications for Wage-Price Dynamics
The view that systematic movements in wages and prices are related

derives from the expectations-augmented Phillips curve model of the inflation
process.

To explain, consider the following price and wage equations that

typically underlie such Phillips curve models (Gordon (1982, 1985) and
Stockton and Glassman (1987))

Apt = h. + h, A(wt - qt) + h2 xt

h3 Spt

(1)

A(wt - qt) = k. + k1 Apt + k2 xt + k3 Swt

(2)

+

-3 -

ApZ =

n

x Apt-

(3)

j-1

where all variables are in natural logarithm and where p is the price level;
w, the wage rate; q, labor productivity; x, a demand pressure variable;

pe,

the expected price level; Spt, supply shocks affecting the price equation and
St, supply shocks affecting the wage equation. A is the first difference
operator. Equation (1) describes the price markup behavior. Prices are
marked up over productivity-adjusted labor costs (w-q) and are influenced by
cyclical demand (X) and the exogenous relative price shocks (SP).

This

equation implies that productivity-adjusted wages determine the price level,
given demand pressures. Equation (2) is the wage equation. Wages are assumed
to be a function of cyclical demand (x) and expected price level, the latter
modeled as a lag on past prices as in equation (3).

The wage equation implies

that wages depend upon past prices, ceteris paribus.
2.

Testing Wage-price Dynamics: Issues of Cointegration and GrangerCausality
The price and wage behavior described above suggest that long-run

movements in wages and prices must be related.

Furthermore, if we allow for

short-run dynamics in such price and wage behavior, the analysis presented
above would also suggest that past changes in wages and prices should contain
useful information for predicting future changes in prices and wages, ceteris
paribus. These implications could be easily examined using tests for
cointegration and Granger-causality between wage and price series.
In particular, if long-term components in wage and price series are
modeled as stochastic trends and if they move together, then these two time
series should be cointegrated as discussed in Granger (1986).

Thus, the long-

-4 -

run comovement of wages and prices is examined using the test for
cointegration proposed in Engle and Granger (1987).
steps.

This test consists of two

The first step tests whether each of the variables of interest (such

as Pt, wt and xt) has a stochastic trend.

That is investigated by performing

the unit root tests on the variables. The second step tests whether
stochastic trends in these variables are related.

That is investigated here

by estimating the cointegrating regression (4) or (5) given below
72 Xt + 1V t

(4)

wt = St + St Pt + St xt + v2t

(5)

Pt= T 0

+

1l

Wt

+

and then testing whether the residual V1 t in (4) or V2 t in (5) has a unit root
or not.

If the residual in (4) or (5) does not appear to have a unit root

while dependent and independent variables had each a unit root, then price and
wage series are said to be cointegrated.
Granger (1988) also points out that if a pair of series are
cointegrated, then there must be causation in at least one direction. To
illustrate, suppose that Pt and wt are cointegrated. Then, as shown in
Granger (1988), these series satisfy an error-correction model of the form
Apt = (lagged Apt, Awt, Axt) + Al Vt l
Awt = (lagged Apt, Awt, Axt)

+ A2 Vt-l

where Vt is the residual from the cointegrating regression (4) or (5) and
where one of A1,

A2

t

0.

Since Vt

1

depends upon lagged levels of p and w, the

model above implies that either Ap or Aw (or both) must be caused by lagged
levels of the variables. The intuition behind this result is that if there is

- 5 -

a long-run relationship between p and w, then there must be causation between
them to provide necessary dynamics.
II
This section presents empirical results.
quarterly and cover the period 1959Q1 to 1988Q4.

The data used are
I have examined the dynamic

interactions between wages and prices in a tri-variable system consisting of
the general price level, productivity-adjusted wage and a demand pressure
variable.

The general price level (p) is measured by the log of the fixed-

weight GNP deflator; productivity-adjustedwage (w), by the log of the index
of unit labor costs of the non-farm business sector; and the demand pressure
variable, by the log of real GNP over potential (denoted as g).

The potential

real output series used is from the Board of Governors.

Test Results for Unit Roots and Cointegration
The test used to detect a unit root in a given time series yt is the
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test (ADF) and is performed estimating the following
regression

Ayt = a

n

+

bT + 2
=1

Cs Ayt-. + d yt-1 + et

(6)

where et is the i.i.d. disturbance. n is the number of lagged values of
first-differenced y that are included to allow for serial correlation in the
residuals.

If there is a unit root in y, then the estimated coefficient d in

(6) should be zero.

The results of estimating (6) for levels as well as for

first differences of price, wage and output-gap regressors are presented in
Table 1.

These test results are consistent with the presence of two unit

-6 -

roots in each price and wage regressors (pt and wj) and a single unit root in
the output gap variable (gt).

They suggest that variables measuring the rate

of growth in wages and prices (Aw and Ap) have each a stochastic trend.
Table 2 presents estimates of the cointegrating regressions using
levels as well as growth rates of prices and wages.

In addition, the results

of applying the ADF test for detecting a unit root in the residuals of the
cointegrating regressions are also reported there.

These unit root tests

results are consistent with the inference that while levels of wage and price
variables are not cointegrated,3 first differences are.

Hence, long-run

movements in the growth rates of wages and prices appear to be correlated.
Test Results for Granger-Causality
Table 3 presents results of testing for the presence of Grangercausality between wages and prices.

The recent work by several analysts4

shows that the asymptotic distributions of causality tests are sensitive to
the presence of unit roots and time trends in the time series.

In many such

cases it might be necessary to conduct causality tests using appropriately
differenced variables. The unit root test results presented in Table 1 would
suggest that wage and price data need to be differenced twice.

However, the

existence of cointegration between wage growth and the rate of inflation
implies that Granger-causality tests should be done using first differences of
wage and price regressors. To illustrate, the results presented here so far

Engle and Granger (1987) also find that levels of wage and price
variables are not cointegrated. They however did not examine the possibility
that first differences of wages and prices could contain stochastic trends and
be cointegrated.
3

4

Sims, Slock and Watson (1986), Phillip (1987), and Ohanian (1988).

- 7-

imply that wage and price variables satisfy an error-correction model of the
form
ni

A2 p = a + E b. A2 pt_
S-1

a + 2 6S

n2
&2Pt_

5=1

n3

CF A2 Wt_3 + a d4 Agut-

S=1

n1.

A2Wt =

n2

+

S-1

(7)

n3

+2 E, A2Wt-S+ 2 ds
S=1

+ X, Vt-1 + elt

Agtos + ) 2 Vt-1 + C2 t (8)

=

where all variables are as defined before and where Vt l is the lagged value
of the residual from the 'cointegrating regression' of the form5
Apt = do + d, Awt + d2

gt + Vt

(9)

The presence of cointegration between Ap and Aw implies that at
least one of A), i=I, 2, is different from zero.

So, even if second

differences of price and wage regressors do not enter (7) and (8), first
differences might through the residual and hence Granger-cause prices and/or
wages.
The test results of Granger-causality are reported in Table 3.

In

panel A of Table 3, the price and wage regressors are in second differences
and the demand pressure regressor as measured by the output gap in first
differences.

In panel B of Table 3, wage and price regressors enter also in

first difference form satisfying the error-correction mechanism described in
(7) and (8).

In panel C, wage and price regressors are in first differences

and the output gap regressor in levels, a specification similar to the one
reported in Gordon (1988).

It is also known that Granger test results are

sensitive to the selection of lag lengths on the regressor. Hence, in

5 Equivalently, one could use the residual
from the 'cointegrating
regression' with Awt as the dependent variable.

- 8 -

addition to the results for the lag length selected by the final prediction
error criterion, I also present results for some arbitrarily selected lag
lengths.
The Fl- and tl-values, reported in panels A, B, and C of Table 3,
test for the presence of Granger-causality from wage growth to the rate of
inflation.6

These values are not statistically significant and thus

consistent with the inference that the rate of wage growth has no incremental
predictive content for the rate of inflation. The F2-values (also reported in
Table 3) test for the presence of Granger-causality from the output gap
regressor to the rate of inflation. Here, the F2-values provide mixed
results.

These values imply that inflation depends upon past output gap when

the output gap regressor is in levels, but not when the output gap regressor
is in first differences. Since level of the output gap regressor does have a
unit root, the F2-values for this regressor are however suspect.7
The F3- and t2-values, reported in panels A, B, and C of Table 3,
test for the presence of Granger-causality from inflation to wage growth.
These values are statistically significant and thus consistent with the
inference that inflation does have an incremental predictive content for wage
growth.

The F4-values (also reported in Table 3) test for Granger-causality

from the output gap regressor to wage growth.

These values are generally

6 Alternatively, we could interpret the tI statistic
as testing whether
the long-run relationship found between the rates of change in wages and
prices constraints the short-run behavior of the rate of inflation.

That is so because the restrictions being tested involve coefficients
that appear on levels of the output gap regressor, which is not stationary.
Hence, the F2-value might not have the usual F distribution (Sims, Stock and
Watson (1986)).
7

- 9 -

statistically significant and imply that output gap does contribute to the
explanation of wage growth.8
III
Concluding Observations
A central proposition in the expectations-augmented Phillips curve
model of the inflation process is that prices are marked up over productivityadjusted labor costs.

If that is true, then long-run movements in prices and

labor costs must be correlated.

If the long-run component in a time series is

modeled as a stochastic trend, then the above noted implication of the 'price
markup' view is related to the concept of cointegration discussed in Granger
(1986).

The evidence reported here shows that long-run movements in the rate

of growth in prices and labor costs are correlated over time.

But the

presence of this correlation appears to be due to Granger-causality running
from inflation to wage growth, not from wage growth to the rate of inflation.
These results thus do not support the 'price markup' view of the inflation
process.

As for monetary policy, these results imply that anti-inflationary

policy need not respond to labor cost data because such data contain no
additional information about the future rate of inflation.

8 The kind of caution noted in footnote 8 applies to the F4-values
reported in panel C of Table 3.

-

10

-

References
Akaike, H. "Fitting autoregressive models for Prediction." Annals of
International Statistics and Mathematics, 1969, 21, 243-247.
Barth, James R. and James T. Bennett. "Cost-push versus Demand-pull
Inflation: Some Empirical Evidence." Journal of Money. Credit, and
Banking, August 1975, 391-97.
Engle, Robert F. and Byung Sam Yoo. "Forecasting and Testing in a CoIntegrated Systems." Journal of Econometrics, 35, 1987, 143-159.
Engle, Robert F. and C.W.J. Granger. "Cointegration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation, and Testing." Econometrica, Vol. 55, No. 2,
March 1987, 251-276.
Fuller, W.A.

Introduction to Statistical Time Series, 1976, Wiley, New York.

Godfrey, L.G. "Testing For Higher Order Serial Correlation in Regression
Equations When the Regressors Include Lagged Dependent Variables."
Econometrica, November 1978, 1303-10.
Gordon, Robert J. "Price Inertia and Policy Ineffectiveness in the United
States, 1890-1980." Journal of Political Economy, 90, December 1982,
1087-1117.
. "The Role of Wages in the Inflation Process." The American
Economic Review, May 1988, 276-83.
. "Understanding Inflation in the 1980s."
on Economic Activity, 1985:1, 263-99.

Brookings Papers

Granger, C.W.J. "Developments in the Study of Cointegrated Economic
Variables". Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 48, 3, 1986,
213-228.

"Some Recent Developments in a Concept of Causality."
Journal of Econometrics, 39, 1988, 199-211.
_

Mehra, Yash P. "Money, Wages, Prices, and Causality." Journal of Political
Economy, 85, No. 6, December 1977, 1227-44.
Ohania, Lee E. "The Spurious Effects of Unit Roots on Vector Autoregressions
A Monte Carlo Study." Journal of Econometrics 39, 1988, 251-66.
Phillips, P.C.B. "Understanding Spurious Regressions in Econometrics."
Journal of Econometrics, 33, 1986, 311-340.
Sims, Christopher A., and James H. stock, and Mark W. Watson. "Inference in
Linear Time Series Models with Some Unit Roots." Manuscript, Stanford
University, 1986.

-

11

-

Stockton, David J., and James E. Glassman. "An Evaluation of the Forecast
Performance of Alternative Models of Inflation." The Review of Economics
and Statistics, February 1987, 108-17.

Table 1
Unit Root Test Statistics

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Equation Ayt = a + b T

n

+

2
s-1

y

Lag Length (1)

d

p

7

-.01

w

3

9

t value (d=0)

Cr A Yt-s + d yt- 1

U(sl)

T.R2 (1)

T.R2 (2)

-2.41

.39

.61

.83

35.5(.22)

-.02

-2.28

.77

1.84

3.46

20.9(.89)

2

-.08

-2.90

.03

.47

1.37

23.7(.78)

Ap

6

-.14

-2.40

.16

.17

.58

36.1(.20)

Aw

2

-.31

-3.24

.08

.57

2.01

19.4(.93)

Ag

1

-.60

-5.23*

.29

.30

1.53

22.3(.84)

Notes:

T.R2 (4)

All data is quarterly and covers the period 1959Q1 to 1988Q4. p is the
log of the fixed-weight gnp deflator; w, the log of unit labor cost; and
g, the log of real output minus potential real output. A is the first
difference operator. The number of own lags (n) included in the Augmented
Dickey-Fuller Equation was chosen by the 'final prediction error'
criterion due to Akaike (1969). Q(sl) is the Ljung-Box Q-statistic based
on 30 autocorrelations of the residuals and sl is the significance level.
T.R2 (1), T.R2 (2) and T.R2 (4) are Godfrey test statistics for first-,
second-, and fourth- order serial correlation and are distributed Chi
Square x2 with one, two and four degrees of freedom, respectively. The 5%
critical values for t (d=o) is 3.45 (Fuller (1976), Table 8.5.2). The 5%
critical values for x2 (1), x2 (2) and x2 (4) are 3.84, 5.99 and 9.49,
respectively.

Table 2
Test Statistics for Cointegration between Wages and Prices; 1959Q1-1988Q4

1.

Cointegrating Regression: pt = .14 + .89 wt + .004 g + Vt
n

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Regression: Avt = b vt1 + X C. Avt 5
5-1

Lag length n:2

Estimated 6 = -. 03 Test Statistic For b = 0:-1.31

Q(sl) = 15.06(.98)

2.

T.R 2 (1) = 1.3

T.R2 (2) = 1.9

T.R2 (4) = 2.1

Cointegrating Regression: wt = -. 14 + 1.1 Pt - .001g + Vt
Augmented Dickey Fuller Regression: A vt = b vt

n

X Cs AvtS

1 +

s-i

Lag length n:2

Estimated b = -.03

Q(sl) = 15.17(.98)
3.

T.R2 (1)

Test Statistics For b
=

=

0:-1.5

1.74 T.R2 (2) = 2.6 T.R2 (4) = 2.8

Cointegrating Regression: Ap = 2.1 + .43 Aw - .16 g + vt
n

Augmented Dickey Fuller Regression: A Vt = b v~.1 + 2 Cs Avt 5
s-i

Lag length n:1

Estimated

Q(sl) = 32.4
4.

S=

Test Statistics For b = 0:-4.96*

-.55

T.R2 (1)

=

1.6

T.R2 (2) = 2.0 T.R2 (4) = 2.3

Cointegrating Regression: Aw = -4.7 + 1.2 Ap - .20 g +
n

Augmented Dickey Fuller Regression: A v~t = b vt 1 + 2 Cs Avt

5

s=l

Lag length n:l

Estimated b

Q(sl) = 28.8(.52)

=

Test Statistics For b = 0:-7.25*

-.96

T.R2 (1)

=

.11 T.R2 (2) = 1.9 T.R2 (4) = 6.6

Notes: All variables are defined as in Table 1. Godfrey test
statistics (T.R2 (i) =, 1, 2, 4) test for the presence of serial
correlation in the residual from the relevant Augmented DickeyFuller Regression. 5% critical value of the test statistics for
b=0 is 3.62 (Engle and Yoo (1987), Table 3)

CD rhtD

o~o o
I-

-

-

(A

U,'^
-C%

I

LA)
r_

'a

0I.

r_co
1
C. .

.

5

CD)

0
-ow
0)

V U
'v 0)

'-

aW

C%,J -%

CQ

-4eLO

*

CNJ CQ

w

.9-

.n

Le CM
0
0%LA 0d
I

CWj

a)$.- L.O
c

I-

1.4,

a

4-3

-4

C

;N

C.4'; .'

+ 43
0.

.gc

r

-4

+

CJNDV-c
CWi O

+

C)
C,,

tv

a)

CY
Li.
l'o40
N

CD

r-. eV
1 o~ cn o

'A

r

"t

.4,

.

Na
08 CO

U'
0)

+

OLJ.

co
m.

-

ID

(A
o

aO

Cn~
4-)
00
-v' to CL0.

.j

0
.0
0

o

0

a4-3

-4
ur
00

(A0)0

co
C;
Un
a-

o0 0

-

0

C 0% V

-4
I-

+
i.
40
'I

S..
4',
C 09

-Ul -c
"r

.

oCD
(DLr
*

U'

qw 00

.4

az l_¢Cs

0--> S< *-

.3

-4
I"I
CD..

3l

4'4'
CO tD08
u9.-.

-4

._-

0

I
t_

lqdli
.~

,to

c
to-

C

cn
4-3

°C

L-S

J

4

.0

r.
.0 C)
4'
O4) q 00
_

_
O*bO*O

-4
LA)

__F-

4
0
4.)

cni

a

.0

C4N

(A)
If4U4-3

V~

A-

0

4-U'
004-

00C)00
CD Cv m

I_ Nq "c to

U'

IV4..)

_4

0

0C'..' C,
r

Lr- m CY

m- C,.
en.%
C- . d-

C

a.

-a)S- -}

kV4C

4-3 4-3

=
4^.- E
V
C'
0 a- 440)

5-_

C-

5- -3 C s
P-S

-S

o

-S

.- S

0
S-

-- 4

C
0

0a

4-3

U
CW CV
M-S~Or

m 4-4-4r

a CO
a -Ia
-@

-e

a)
S-.

cq

+

0)^0C_

^

0..4
.0

C-c
-4

-4-4-4

C_

CO
-S

P)L 0

d

OD

9-4

-4

aW 4,

3

CLa

+

0,-0
0'0
__iCl
ll

Cm

_

N

NL

_5-

C'; -

*M 5- LA
*1
C; e

S-

*-C 0

a)
C) CD

4--- 4)
-4

0 >).-0
4 0.

-

0) C
CD

0

> .0
C
1-D

.-OmOv

.0 r4Ud

4

4

0

-0.

N

00

-4

C;0;es:

-4

0

-4

Os es

C O

-0.

C-

V

*D
C
0o
4-*
0) *- Cj0a-0
S-_00..
-LA

0OD -

i-s CV) LA)

co
-4-4-4

04
_

co

' - Lr ll
C0
e'..-

a a

ll

+

coen
.. co* e'

to

" C
-W 4 -_
OC
*C
~)
C (v4~~~~3
*_ v

D
--*4

0.
.0

'A

v.-

a

a}

aW.4,

10
-0
CO "-

t,

a

S- at

C%j
S.---4

0

S.-

0.

>

0

.M

LaU-

0 4

.d.

9

.0
.0
co
(n

+
Ca '

N

4

--

I- C') LA

0)01

+

aW
C-L
C)LA LAO

...

-4

cn

I'- en LO 0
0%

-

r W "A

4>

0

4- 40-

m0

3c
0%

N

.03

I

-4

.4,

N

I

I

+

_
0

0

4,

4-3

V=

0)sA

-S

n

i-4

*e-t-O~LA')

__~
eu
¢5X0_.

e

C

coCC
M
9 -.

..'u

0> O0C

_*)0

C

as

0n 0

*00
0) *9

C