View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Sectoral vs. Aggregate Shocks: A
Structural Factor Analysis of Industrial
Production

WP 08-07

Andrew T. Foerster
Duke University
Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Mark W. Watson
Princeton University

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Sectoral vs. Aggregate Shocks: A Structural Factor
Analysis of Industrial Production∗
Andrew T. Foerster
Department of Economics, Duke University
Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Mark W. Watson
Department of Economics, Princeton University
Working Paper No. 08-07

Abstract
This paper uses factor analytic methods to decompose industrial production (IP)
into components arising from aggregate shocks and idiosyncratic sector-specific shocks.
An approximate factor model finds that nearly all (90%) of the variability of quarterly
growth rates in IP are associated with common factors. Because common factors may
reflect sectoral shocks that have propagated by way of input-output linkages, we then
use a multisector growth model to adjust for the effects of these linkages. In particular,
we show that neoclassical multisector models, of the type first introduced by Long and
Plosser (1983), produce an approximate factor model as a reduced form. A structural
factor analysis then indicates that aggregate shocks continue to be the dominant source
of variation in IP, but the importance of sectoral shocks more than doubles after the
Great Moderation (to 30%). The increase in the relative importance of these shocks
follows from a fall in the contribution of aggregate shocks to IP movements after 1984.
JEL classification: E32, E23, C32
Keywords: Input-Output Matrix, Great Moderation, Approximate Factor Model
∗

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. We thank Andreas Hornstein, Ray Owens,
and Roy Webb for helpful conversations. We also thank participants at the 2008 Midwest Macro and SED
meetings for their comments. Support was provided by the National Science Foundation through grant SES0617811. Data and replication files for this research can be found at http://www.princeton.edu/~mwatson.

1

1

Introduction

The Federal Reserve Board’s Index of Industrial Production (IP) is an important indicator
of aggregate economy activity in the United States. Month-to-month and quarter-to-quarter
variations in the index are large. Monthly and quarterly growth rates for the seasonally
adjusted IP index over 1972-2007 are plotted in Figure 1. Over this sample period, the
standard deviation of monthly growth rates was over eight percentage points (at an annual
rate), and quarterly growth rates had a standard deviation of nearly six percentage points.
Also evident in the figure is the large fall in volatility associated with the Great Moderation;
the standard deviation in the post-84 period is roughly half its pre-84 value for both the
monthly and quarterly series.
Because the IP index is constructed as a weighted average of production indices for a large
number of sectors, the large volatility in the IP index is somewhat puzzling. Simply put,
while production in an individual sector (e.g. “Motor Vehicle Parts”) may vary substantially
from month-to-month or quarter-to-quarter, apparently much of this variability does not
“average out” in the index of economy-wide production. There are three leading explanations
for this observation. The first relies on aggregate shocks that affect all industrial sectors.
Since these shocks are common across sectors, they do not average out and become the
dominant source of variation in aggregate economic activity. The two other explanations
rely on uncorrelated sector-specific shocks. First, Gabaix (2005) notes that sector-specific
shocks may not necessarily average out when some of these sectors have large weights in the
aggregate index. Second, complementarities in production such as input-output linkages may
propagate sector-specific shocks throughout the economy in a way that generates substantial
aggregate variability.
The literature analyzing sector-specific versus aggregate sources of variations in the business cycle has followed two main approaches. Long and Plosser (1987), Forni and Reichlin
(1998), and Shea (2002) among others rely on factor analytic methods, coupled with broad
identifying restrictions, to assess the relative contributions of aggregate and sector-specific
shocks to aggregate variability. These papers generally find that sector-specific shocks contribute a non-trivial fraction of aggregate fluctuations (e.g. approximately 50 percent in
Long and Plosser (1987)). A second strand of literature is rooted in more structural calibrated multisector models, such as Long and Plosser (1983) or Horvath (1998, 2000), that
explicitly take into account input-output linkages across sectors. In these models, whether
input-output linkages are sufficiently strong to generate substantial aggregate variability

2

from sector-specific shocks depends on the exact structure of the input-output matrix.1
This paper bridges these two approaches and sorts through the leading explanations
underlying both the volatility of IP and its decline in the post-1984 period. In particular,
it describes conditions under which neoclassical multisector models that explicitly consider
input-output linkages, such as those of Long and Plosser (1983) or Horvath (1998), produce
an approximate factor model as a reduced form. Aggregate shocks to sectoral productivity
emerge as the common output factors in the approximate factor model. The “uniquenesses”
in the factor model are associated with sector-specific shocks. However, because input-output
linkages induce some correlation across the “uniquenesses”, the estimated factors may be
biased and reflect not only aggregate shocks but also idiosyncratic shocks that propagate
across sectors by way of these input-output linkages.
Ultimately, our analysis suggests that sectoral weights play little role in explaining the
variability of the aggregate IP index. As in Shea (2002), aggregate variability is driven mainly
by covariability across sectors and not sector-specific variability. In addition, consistent with
Quah and Sargent (1993), who study comovement in employment across 60 industries, and
Forni and Reichlin (1998), who study annual U.S. output and productivity data over 19581986, we find that much of the covariability in sectoral production can be explained by a
small number of common factors. These common factors are the leading source of variation
in the IP index, and a decrease in the variability of these common factors drives the post-1984
decline in aggregate volatility.
Because common factors may reflect not only aggregate shocks but also the propagation
of sectoral shocks by way of input-output linkages, we draw on a generalized version of the
multisector growth model introduced in Horvath (1998) to filter out the effects of those
linkages. Using input-output matrices calibrated to the U.S. production sector, we find that
sectoral shocks generally play a modest role in the variability of aggregate IP. That said, the
relative importance of these shocks more than doubles in the post-1984 period. Specifically,
while sectoral shocks account for roughly 12 percent of the volatility of aggregate IP prior
to 1984, they account for about 30 percent of IP fluctuations after the onset of the Great
Moderation. Moreover, our analysis suggests that changes in the structure of the U.S. inputoutput matrix have not lead to greater propagation of sector-specific shocks in the post-1984
period. Rather, given that the magnitude of sectoral shocks is roughly unchanged before and
after 1984, the increase in the relative importance of these shocks follows from a decrease in
the contribution of aggregate shocks to the variability of aggregate IP.
1

See Dupor (1999), and more generally Carvalho (2007).

3

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the sectoral data, and studies
the role of sectoral weights and sector-specific variation in explaining the variability of the
aggregate IP index. Section 3 asks whether the covariability across sectors can be explained
by a small number of common factors, and quantifies the role that these common shocks
play in the variability of the IP index. In section 4, we show that a generalized version of
the multisector growth model introduced by Horvath (1998) admits an approximate factor
model as a reduced form. We then calibrate the model using input-output matrices for the
U.S. production sector to construct a model-based filter that eliminates the effects of inputoutput linkages. This allows us to isolate the effects of aggregate productivity shocks from
the common factors estimated in section 3. Section 5 offers concluding remarks.

2

A First Look at the Sectoral Data

2.1

Overview of the Data

The analysis uses data on Industrial Production over the period 1972-2007 obtained from
the Board of Governors, and Benchmark Input-Output tables provided by the Bureau of
Economic Analysis (BEA). Benchmark input-output tables are available only every five
years, but provide a greater level of disaggregation relative to tables that are available in
non-benchmark years. For most of the paper, IP data is disaggregated by sectors according
to the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS). The raw data are indices of
real output, from which we compute sectoral growth rates as well as the relative importance
(or shares) of industries in aggregate IP. The “Use Table” measures the value of inputs in
producer prices, given by commodity codes, used by each industry, given by industry codes,
as well as payments to labor and capital. To account for possible low frequency changes
in the structure of input-output linkages across sectors, we consider two benchmark years,
1977 and 1997. Because NAICS definitions are relatively recent and cannot be matched
to input-output tables prior to 1997, we also make use of vintage IP data covering the
period 1967-2002. The vintage IP data are disaggregated according to Standard Industry
Classification (SIC) codes, and discontinued after 2002. A detailed description of the data
is provided in Appendix A, and their main properties are described in Table A1.
Let IPt denote the value of the aggregate IP index at date t, and IPit the index for the i0 th
sector. These indices are available monthly. Quarterly values of the indices are constructed
as averages of the months in the quarter. Growth rates (in percentage points) are denoted
by gt for aggregate IP and xit for sectoral IP. We compute gt as 1200 × ln(IPt /IPt−1 ) and
4

400 × ln(IPt /IPt−1 ) for monthly and quarterly frequencies respectively, and compute xit
similarly.

2.2

Sectoral Summary statistics

Figure 2 shows the distributions of standard deviations of both monthly and quarterly sectoral growth rates over the sample periods 1972-1983 and 1984-2007. In computing these
distributions, IP is broken down into 117 sectors that correspond roughly to a four digit
level of disaggregation. Monthly growth rates are volatile and fell only slightly during the
second period (the median standard deviation fell from 30 percent in the first period to 25
percent in the second period). Quarterly averaging reduces the volatility of sectoral output
growth, and a fall in the volatility of sectoral quarterly growth rates is evident after 1984.
Table 1 summarizes the contemporaneous cross-correlation of the sectoral growth rates. Average pairwise correlations are positive, lower for the monthly data than the quarterly data,
and lower in the second sample period than in the first. Looking at the extremes in the
table, quarterly growth rates were relatively highly correlated in the first period (the average correlation was 0.27 over 1972-1983), while monthly growth rates were relatively weakly
correlated over the second period (the average correlation was 0.05 over 1984-2007).
Let wit denote the share (or weight) of sector’s i production in the aggregate index.
P
Growth in aggregate IP can then be written as gt = i wit xit . Table 2 follows Shea (2002)

and studies two sources of variation in the aggregate IP index: (i) time variation in the
sectoral shares, wit , used as weights in combining sectoral growth rates to produce aggregate

growth rates, and (ii) the covariance of sectoral growth rates.
Panel (a) of Table 2 shows the standard deviation of gt , the standard deviation of

P

i

wi xit ,

where wi denotes the sample average of wit over the sample period, and the standard deP
viation of N −1 i xit , where N is the number of sectors. It is apparent that the standard
P
deviations of gt and i wi xit are nearly identical, indicating that time variation in wit is
not an important source of variability in aggregate IP. Moreover, these values are close to
the standard deviation of IP computed using equal share weights, so that the distribution
of shares across sectors is relatively unimportant in this calculation as well. Moreover, because the variability when using equal weights is somewhat larger than when using wi , larger
sectors have less volatile output growth rates than smaller sectors on average.
Panel (b) considers estimates of the standard deviation of gt that ignore the covariance of
sectoral growth rates. Letting σ
b2i denote the sample variance in xit , the first entry in panel (b)
P 2 −1 P 2 1/2
P 2 2 1/2
shows [ i σ
bi (T
, the second entry shows [ i σ
bi wi ] , and the last entry shows
t wit )]
5

P 2 −2 1/2
[ iσ
bi N ] . Again all values are similar, suggesting that neither time variation in wit nor

distributional concerns are important in these calculations. More importantly, the entries in
panel (b) are markedly smaller than those in panel (a). Evidently, as stressed by Shea (2002),

most of the variance in aggregate output growth is associated with the covariance of sectoral
growth rates. If one were to assume that the comovement in sectoral growth rates is driven
by aggregate shocks that are common to all sectors, it would immediately follow from Table
2 that these shocks represent the overriding source of variation in aggregate IP. For example,
using quarterly growth rates and constant mean shares over the sample period 1984-2007,
the fraction of IP growth variability explained by aggregate shocks would be approximately
1 − (1.5/3.6)2 or 0.83. Note, however, that this calculation is only approximate since the

diagonal elements of the covariance matrix used in panel (b) would themselves reflect, in
part, the effects of aggregate shocks. Finally, panels (a) and (b) of Table 2 suggest that the
fall in the volatility of aggregate IP in the post-1984 period is associated mainly with a fall
in the covariability of sectoral growth rates rather than a decline in the variability of output
growth in individual sectors.
To sum up, the results in Table 2 allow us to discount the “large shocks in sectors with
large shares” explanation for the variability of aggregate output. If anything, we find that
on average, larger sectors are associated with lower output growth volatility. In addition,
the variability in aggregate IP is associated with shocks that lead to covariability in sectoral
output, not shocks that lead to large idiosyncratic sectoral variability. The remaining challenge is to measure and understand the shocks that lead to covariability, and this challenge
is taken up in the next two sections. Throughout the remainder of the paper, the analysis
is carried out using constant mean shares, wi .

3

Statistical Factor Analysis

As discussed in Forni and Reichlin (1998), the approximate factor model is one natural way
to model the covariance matrix of sectoral production.

Letting Xt represent the N × 1

vector of sectoral growth rates, this model represents Xt as
Xt = ΛFt + ut

(1)

where Ft is a k × 1 vector of latent factors, Λ is an N × k matrix of coefficients called

factor loadings, and ut is an N × 1 vector of sector-specific idiosyncratic disturbances. We

denote the number of time series observations by T . In classical factor analysis (Anderson
6

(1984)), Ft and ut are mutually uncorrelated i.i.d. sequences of random variables, and ut
has a diagonal covariance matrix. Thus, Xt is an i.i.d. sequence of random variables with
covariance matrix ΣXX = ΛΣF F Λ0 + Σuu , where ΣF F and Σuu are the covariance matrices of
Ft and ut respectively. Because Σuu is diagonal, any covariance between the elements of Xt
arises from the common factors Ft .
Approximate factor models (e.g. Chamberlain and Rothschild (1983), Connor and Korackzyk (1986), Forni, Halli, Lippi, and Reichlin (2000), and Stock and Watson (2000)),
weaken these assumptions by (essentially) requiring that key sample moments involving Ft
and ut mimic the behavior of sample moments in classical factor analysis. This allows for
weak cross sectional and temporal dependence in the series, subject to the constraint that
sample averages satisfy laws of large numbers with the same limits as those that would obtain
in classical factor analysis. When N and T are large, as they are in this paper’s application,
the approximate factor model has proved useful because relatively simple methods can be
used for estimation and inference. For example, penalized least squares criteria can be used
to consistently estimate the number of factors (Bai and Ng (2002)), principal components
can be used to consistently estimate factors (Stock and Watson (2000)), and the estimation
error in the estimated factors is sufficiently small that it can be ignored when estimating
variance decompositions or conducting inference about Λ (Stock and Watson (2000), Bai
(2003)).
Tables 3 through 5, as well as Figures 3 and 4, summarize the results from applying
these methods to the data on sectoral IP growth rates. To begin, we estimated the number
of factors using the Bai and Ng (2002) ICP1 and ICP2 estimators. These estimators yielded
2 factors in the full sample period (1972-2007), and first sample period (1972-1983). They
yielded 1 factor in the second sample period (1984-2007)2 . The findings shown in Tables 3
through 5 and Figures 3 and 4 are based on estimated 2-factor models. For robustness, we
also carried out our analysis using 1- and 3-factor models. The results (not shown) were
similar to those we report for the 2-factor model.
Given equation (1), we can gauge the importance of common shocks, Ft , relative to the
“uniquenesses,” ut , in two ways. First, we compute the fraction of aggregate IP variability
explained by common shocks, which we denote by R2 (F ). In particular, letting w denote the
N × 1 vector of constant mean shares, gt = w0 ΛFt + w0 ut so that R2 (F ) = w0 ΛΣF F Λ0 w/σ 2g ,

where σ 2g is the variance of IP growth rates. Second, we can also assess the extent to which
2

The estimators are based on the eigenvalues of the sample correlation matrix of the data. These are

presented and discussed in Section 4.

7

the common factors explain output growth variability in individual sectors. That is, we can
also compute the distribution of R2 statistics obtained by regressing xit on Ft , which we
denote by Ri2 (F ).
Table 3 shows the 2-factor model’s implied standard deviation of aggregate IP computed
using constant shares, as well as the fraction of aggregate IP variability explained by the
common factors, R2 (F ). The factor model implies an aggregate IP index with volatility that
is essentially identical to that found in the data. Furthermore, the common factors explain
nearly all of the variability in quarterly growth rates of the aggregate IP index over both
sample periods. Common shocks also explain the bulk of the variability in monthly growth
rates over the 1972-1983 period, but only half of the variance of monthly growth rates over
the 1984-2007 period. Figure 3 illustrates aggregate IP growth rates as well as the model’s
fitted values of the factor component. Consistent with the variance decomposition in Table
3, the series track one another closely for the quarterly data. The series also track each other
closely for the monthly data in the early sample period, but less so over the period 19842007. While the factor component tracks low-frequency movements in monthly growth rates
relatively well over this second period, several of the high frequency spikes in the monthly
series are associated with sector-specific shocks.
Because the common factors explain roughly 90 percent of the variability in quarterly
growth rates over both sample periods, they are responsible for 90 percent of the decrease
in aggregate volatility across the two time periods. Similarly, common shocks explain 85
and 50 percent of the variability in monthly growth rates over 1972-1983 and 1984-2007
respectively, and a decrease in the magnitude of these shocks fully explains the decrease in
variability of the monthly series after 1984. Taken together, these findings suggest that the
Great Moderation is explained by a decrease in the variance of the common components of
IP.
At a more disaggregated level, Figure 4 shows the fraction of output growth variability
in individual IP sectors explained by the common factors. Regarding individual monthly
sectoral growth rates, these factors account for only a small fraction of their variability both
before and after 1984. (the median value is 18 percent in the 1972-1983 period and 10 percent
in the 1984-2007 period). In contrast, common shocks play a non-trivial role in driving the
movements of sectoral quarterly growth rates prior to 1984. Specifically, over the first sample
period, common factors explain at least 41 percent of output growth volatility in half of the
sectors, and are the main source of variability in 25 percent of the sectors. Interestingly, the
relative importance of common shocks for the variability of sectoral quarterly growth rates

8

falls considerably after the onset of the great moderation. After 1984, the median Ri2 (F )
statistic is only 19 percent, so that idiosyncratic shocks take on a more prominent role at
the sectoral level over the second sample period.
Surprisingly, while the importance of common shocks for the variability of sectoral quarterly growth rates declines after 1984, observe in Figure 4 that these shocks nevertheless
explain a very large fraction of output growth volatility in several individual series in both
sample periods. Table 4 lists the ten sectors with the largest fraction of variability accounted
for by common shocks. Prior to 1984, for example, idiosyncratic shocks played virtually no
role in the variability of output growth in the sectors related to “Fabricated Metals: Forging
and Stamping,” or “Other Fabricated Metal Products”. Furthermore, because the sectors
in Table 4 move mainly with common shocks, and as we have just seen movements in the
aggregate IP index are associated with these shocks, the sectors listed in Table 4 turn out
to be particularly informative about the IP index.
Consider, for instance, the problem of tracking movements in IP in real time using only a
et represent
subset M of the IP sectors, say the five highest ranked sectors in Table 5.3 Let X
et = sXt ,
the vector of output growth rates associated with these M sectors such that X

where s is a corresponding M × N selection matrix. To assess the information content of IP

embodied in those M sectors, weights are simply determined by the orthogonal projection
et , E(w0 Xt |X
et ) = X
et ψ. Specifically, the M × 1 vector of weights ψ is given by
of gt on X
et ψ computed with only the
ψ = (sΣXX s0 )−1 sΣXX w. Table 5 then shows that estimates of X

five highest ranked sectors in Table 4 are enough to explain the bulk of the variation in IP.

Prior to 1984, these five sectors alone account for 85 percent of the variation in the growth

rate of the aggregate index. In addition, 99 percent of the variability in IP growth rates
is captured by considering only the thirty highest ranked sectors (out of 117) over 19721983. This fraction is somewhat smaller at 90 percent over the Great Moderation period.
In either case, however, it is apparent that information about movements in IP turns out
to be concentrated in a small number of sectors. Contrary to conventional wisdom, these
3

IP numbers are typically released with a one month lag, revised up to three months after their initial

release, and further subject to an annual revision. Both to confirm initial releases and to independently track
economic activity, the Institute for Supply Management constructs an index of manufacturing production
based on nationwide surveys. In addition, several Federal Reserve Banks including Dallas, Kansas City, New
York, Philadelphia, and Richmond, produce similar indices that are meant to capture real time changes in
activity at a more regional level. Of course, a central issue pertaining to these surveys is that gathering
information on a large number of sectors in a timely fashion is costly, so that the scope of the surveys is
generally limited.

9

sectors are not necessarily those with the largest weights, the most volatile output growth,
nor the most links to other sectors (e.g. Electric Power Generation”). Since aggregate IP is
driven mainly by common shocks, what matters is that those sectors also move with common
shocks. We return to this point in the next section.
What do we learn from these results about the variability of aggregate IP growth rates?
Common shocks largely explain changes in aggregate IP, and a decrease in the volatility of
these shocks explains why aggregate IP is considerably less variable after 1984. In addition,
information about changes in the aggregate IP index is condensed in a small number of
sectors.

4

Structural Factor Analysis

An important assumption underlying the consistent estimation of factors in the previous
section was that the covariance matrix of the uniquenesses, ut , in equation (1) satisfy weak
cross sectional dependence. However, as discussed in Long and Plosser (1983), Horvath
(1998), Carvalho (2007), and elsewhere, input-output linkages between the industrial sectors
may lead to the propagation of sector-specific shocks throughout the economy in a way
that generates comovement across sectors. In other words, these input-output linkages may,
effectively, transform shocks that are specific to particular sectors into common shocks, and
thereby explain in part the variability of aggregate output. As discussed in Horvath (1998)
and Dupor (1999), the strength of this amplification mechanism depends importantly on the
structure of the input-output matrix governing linkages between sectors.
In this section, we use BEA estimates of the input-output matrix linking production
sectors in the U.S. to quantify the effects of shock propagation on the volatility of the aggregate IP index. Because this calculation requires a model that incorporates linkages between
sectors, the first subsection describes a generalization of the framework first introduced in
Horvath (1998) that will be used. This framework extends that used by Long and Plosser
(1983) by considering capital along with non-storable intermediate inputs, and is effectively
a multisector version of the original Brock-Mirman (1972) one sector growth model. The
key feature of interest is that production in each sector uses materials produced in the other
sectors. Therefore, shocks to an individual sector may be disseminated to other sectors and
over time in a way that potentially contributes to aggregate fluctuations. This subsection
then describes conditions under which the factor model in (1) may, in fact, be interpreted
as a reduced form of the structural model with input-output linkages. It also illustrates how

10

the structural model may be used to filter out the effects of these linkages. The following
subsection presents the quantitative results.

4.1

A Canonical Model with Input-Output Linkages

Consider an economy comprised of N distinct sectors of production indexed by j = 1, ..., N.
Each sector produces a quantity Yjt of good j at date t using sector-specific capital, Kjt ,
labor, Ljt , and materials produced in the other sectors, Mijt , according to the technology
Yjt =

α
Ajt Kjtj

N
Y
i=1

S
γ ij 1−αj − N
i=1 γ ij
Mijt Ljt
,

(2)

where Ajt is a productivity index for sector j.
The fact that each sector uses materials from other sectors represents the source of
interconnectedness in the model. An input-output matrix for this economy is an N × N

matrix Γ with typical element γ ij . The column sums of Γ give the degree of returns to scale
in materials in each sector. The row sums of Γ measure the importance of each sector’s
output as materials to all other sectors. Put simply, we can think of the rows and columns
of Γ as “sell to” and “buy from” respectively for each sector. We denote the vector of capital
shares by αd = (α1 , α2 , ..., αN )0 .
We let At = (A1t , A2t , · · · , ANt )0 denote the vector of productivity indices, and assume

that ln(At ) follows the random walk,

ln(At ) = ln(At−1 ) + εt ,

(3)

where εt = (ε1t , ε2t , ..., εNt )0 is a vector-valued martingale difference process with covariance
matrix Σεε . The degree to which sectoral productivity is influenced by aggregate shocks will
be reflected in the matrix Σεε . When Σεε is diagonal, sectoral productivity is affected only
by idiosyncratic shocks.
A representative agent derives utility from the consumption of these N goods according
to

Et

∞
X
t=0

β

t

N
X
j=1

Ã

!
1−σ
−1
Cjt
− ψLjt ,
1−σ

(4)

where the labor specification follows Hansen’s (1985) indivisible labor model. In addition,
each sector is subject to the following resource constraint,
Cjt +

N
X
i=1

Mjit + Kjt+1 − (1 − δ)Kjt = Yjt , j = 1, ..., N.
11

(5)

This model is essentially that introduced by Horvath (1998) extended to allow for elastic
labor supply, less than full capital depreciation, and non-log preferences.
Details of the model solution to the planner’s problem are available in a separate technical appendix [Foerster, Sarte, and Watson (2008)]. While the model in Horvath (1998)
admits an analytical solution, that model’s assumption of full capital depreciation within
the quarter, in particular, makes it somewhat unsuitable for the purposes of an empirical investigation. The companion appendix shows that in the generalized version adopted
here, the deterministic steady state of the model continues to be analytically tractable.4
Furthermore, using a linear approximation of the model’s first-order conditions and resource
constraints around that steady state, one can show that the vector of sectoral output growth,
Xt = (∆ ln(Y1t ), ∆ ln(Y2t ), ..., ∆ ln(YNt ))0 evolves according to
Xt = ΦXt−1 + Πεt + Ξεt−1 ,

(6)

where Φ, Π, and Ξ are N × N matrices that depend only on the model parameters, αd , Γ,
β, σ, ψ, and δ.

Suppose that innovations to sectoral productivity, εjt , reflect both aggregate shocks, St ,
and idiosyncratic shocks, vjt , such that
εt = Λs St + vt .

(7)

The matrix Λs governs the degree to which aggregate disturbances affect productivity in
individual sectors; when there are k aggregate factors in St , Λs is N × k. The vector

of disturbances, vt = (v1t , v2t , ..., vnt )0 , captures idiosyncratic shocks that are uncorrelated
across sectors and has diagonal covariance matrix Σvv .
Given equations (6) and (7), and denoting the lag operator by L, the evolution of sectoral
output growth can be written as
Xt = ΛFt + ut ,

(8)

where Λ(L) = (I − ΦL)−1 (Π + ΞL)Λs , Ft = St , and ut = (I − ΦL)−1 (Π + ΞL)vt . In other

words, the vector of sectoral output growth rates in this multisector extension of the standard
growth model produces an approximate factor model as a reduced form. The common factors
in this reduced form are associated with aggregate shocks to sectoral productivity while the
“uniquenesses” reflect linear combinations of the underlying structural sector-specific shocks.

In particular, the key issue is that input output linkages between sectors will induce some
4

This feature is helpful since, in simulations of the model, it avoids having to solve for a large set of

non-linear equations involving 117 sectors (e.g. there are 13,689 steady state Mij allocations).

12

cross-sectional dependence among the “uniquenesses” that may cause the statistical factor
model to overestimate the importance of aggregate shocks. This is most transparent in the
special case initially studied by Horvath (1998) with no labor, full depreciation, and log
preferences. In that case, the model’s exact solution is given by (6) with Φ = (I − Γ0 )−1 αd ,
Ξ = 0, and Π = (I − Γ0 )−1 , so that

0

ut = (I − (I − Γ )−1 αd L)−1 (I − Γ0 )−1 vt .

(9)

Therefore, while sector specific shocks vt in the equation above have a diagonal covariance
matrix Σvv , the “uniquenesses,” ut , will exhibit some degree of cross-sectional dependence
induced by the input-output matrix Γ. Furthermore, by ignoring the comovement in “uniquenesses,” the factor model would incorrectly attribute any resulting comovement in sectoral
output growth to aggregate shocks.
To eliminate the propagation effects of sector specific shocks induced by input-output
linkages, we filter the vector of data on sectoral output growth to construct εt where, from
equation (6),
εt = (Π + ΞL)−1 (I − ΦL)Xt .

(10)

We can then apply factor analytic methods to the constructed series for εt to recover the
relative contribution of aggregate shocks, St , and sector specific shocks, vt , to the variability
of aggregate output.

4.2

Calibrating the Model Parameters

We shall interpret the model as describing the sectoral production indices analyzed in sections
2 and 3. Thus, we abstract from output of the service and public sectors. In addition, because
the model does not take into account delivery lags that would undoubtedly be relevant at
the monthly frequency, this section focuses on quarterly data.
In order to construct the filtered series described in equation (10), we must first calibrate
the model’s parameters. A subset of these parameters is standard and chosen in accordance
with previous work on business cycles. Thus, given our focus on quarterly data, we set
β = 0.99 and δ = 0.025. We further set σ = 1 and ψ = 1 as a benchmark. While we treat
these parameters as constant through time, the choice of input-output matrix, Γ, requires
more caution. In particular, we wish to capture the model’s implications for the filtered
series, εt , in equation (10) arising from potential low frequency changes in the structure of
U.S. production.

13

The calibration of the parameters describing technology (γ ij and αj ) derives from estimates of input-output tables supplied by the BEA. We use 117 sectors (i.e. N = 117)
which corresponds roughly to a four-digit level of disaggregation. The BEA “Input Use”
tables measure the value of inputs in producer prices, given by commodity codes, used by
each industry, described by industry codes. By matching commodity and industry codes,
we obtain the value of inputs from each industry used by every other industry. Moreover,
the input-output tables include compensation of employees (wages) and other value added
(rents on capital). We abstract from non-IP sectors, which include agriculture, services,
and government. A column sum in the input-output table represents total payments from
a given sector to all other sectors (i.e. material inputs, labor, and capital) and defines the
value of output in that sector. A row sum in the input-output table gives the importance
of a given sector as an input supplier to all other sectors, measured as the value of inputs
in other sectors’ production. Hence, input shares, γ ij , are calibrated as dollar payments
from industry j to industry i expressed as a fraction of the value of production in sector j.
Similarly, capital shares for the j-th industry reflect dollar payments to capital as a fraction
of the value of output in sector j.
To account for changes in the structure of U.S. input-output linkages before and after the
Great Moderation, we consider two BEA benchmark years, 1977 and 1998. BEA benchmark
tables are available only every five years but disaggregated more finely than tables available
in non-benchmark years. Unfortunately, as discussed in Section 2, the input-output tables for
the years prior to 1997 are not updated by the BEA to reflect the reclassification of industries
by NAICS definitions, and are broken down instead according to SIC codes. For consistency,
therefore, we include in our analysis vintage IP data provided by the Board of Governors
where sectors are disaggregated by SIC codes, and which cover the period 1967-2002. We
use these two data sources, and contrast the results associated with each, throughout the
remainder of the paper. Finally, the remaining set of parameters that need to be estimated
are those making up Σεε , the covariance matrix of the structural productivity shocks, εt .
We choose two calibrations for Σεε that help highlight the degree to which the model is
able propagate purely idiosyncratic shocks, and thus effectively transform these shocks into
common shocks. In the first calibration, Σεε is a diagonal matrix with entries given by the
sample variance of εt in the different IP sectors, where εt is computed from equation (10)
using quarterly sectoral production data on Xt . The sample variance of εt is computed over
different sample periods and using different data vintages (e.g. 1972-1983, 1984-2007 using
IP data defined by NAICS codes) to account for heteroskedasticity that may be important for

14

the Great Moderation. Because this calibration uses uncorrelated sectoral shocks, it allows
us to determine whether input-output linkages per se can explain the strong covariance in
sectoral production that is necessary to generate the variability in aggregate output.
In the second calibration, we use a factor model to represent Σεε . That is, we model εt
as shown in equation (7) where, as in the last section, St is a k × 1 vector of common factors

and vt is an N × 1 vector of mutually uncorrelated sector-specific idiosyncratic shocks. In
this model, Σεε = Λs ΣSS Λ0s + Σvv , where Λs , and the covariance matrices ΣSS and Σvv ,

are estimated using the principal components estimator of St constructed from the sample
values of εt . This second calibration allows two sources of covariance in sectoral output: a
structural component arising from input-output linkages and a statistical component arising
from aggregate shocks affecting sectoral productivity.

4.3
4.3.1

Results From the Structural Analysis
Comovement from Input-Output Linkages

Table 6 summarizes key results for the model when sectoral shocks are driven only by idiosyncratic shocks that are cross-sectionally uncorrelated (i.e., Σεε is diagonal). The table
compares average pairwise correlations of sectoral output growth rates implied by the model
with those calculated in the data. It also contrasts the standard deviation of aggregate IP
implied by the model with that in the data. The matrix Σεε is calibrated over the samples
before and after the Great Moderation, and using both 1977 and 1998 input-output matrices
corresponding to SIC and NAICS sectoral decompositions respectively.
Table 6 makes several observations apparent. First, the data vintage is immaterial for
the calculations of average pairwise correlations despite the fact the vintages span different
pre- and post-Great Moderation sample periods. Irrespective of the vintage, one observes
a notable fall in the average pairwise correlation, and thus comovement, of sectoral growth
rates from roughly 0.27 in the first sample period to 0.11 after 1984. Second, the model
with input-output linkages and uncorrelated sector-specific shocks implies significantly less
comovement across sectors than in U.S. data. The model, therefore, falls considerably short
of matching the variability of aggregate IP growth rates. To get a sense of the quantitative
contribution of input-output linkages to aggregate IP variability, consider, for instance, the
data broken down by NAICS definitions. Over the 1972-1983 period, the model explains 17
percent of the variance in aggregate IP growth rates (0.17 = (3.7/8.9)2 ). In contrast, Table
2 indicates that the diagonal elements of the covariance matrix of sectoral IP growth rates

15

account for roughly 7 percent of aggregate IP variance (0.07 = (2.4/8.9)2 ). The difference
(0.17 − 0.07) represents the contribution of input-output linkages to aggregate variability.

Similarly, over the 1984-2007 period, Table 6, panel (a), shows that the model explains
37 percent of the variance in aggregate IP growth rates. The diagonal elements of the
covariance matrix used in Table 2, in contrast, account for 17 percent of the variability in
aggregate IP. It appears, therefore, that the model with uncorrelated idiosyncratic shocks
explains a somewhat larger fraction of aggregate variability after the Great Moderation. As
a mechanical matter, because the same input-output matrix is used for the calculations in
both sample periods, the increased relative importance of sector-specific shocks does not
arise from changes in input-output linkages. Rather, they reflect a fall in the variability of
aggregate shocks after 1984.
Table 7, panels (a) and (b), present an alternative way of assessing the comovement
implied by the structural model with uncorrelated sector-specific shocks. In particular, the
table compares the eigenvalues of the correlation matrix of sectoral growth rates in the data
with selected percentiles of the distribution of eigenvalues obtained from sample correlation
matrices computed from model-simulated data.5 The data indicate one or two dominant
eigenvalues followed by eigenvalues of similar magnitudes. This pattern is consistent with
a factor model characterized by one or two common factors. Indeed, the Bai-Ng estimator
of the number of common factors is based on these eigenvalues, and the results in Table 7
explain why the Bai-Ng estimator finds two factors in the first sample period and one factor
in the second. In contrast, as the percentiles suggest, data generated from model simulations
using a diagonal covariance matrix, Σεε , are very unlikely to exhibit this pattern. Although
associated with some limited comovement, the eigenvalues of the sample correlation matrices
are generally of similar magnitude both across sample periods and across input-output matrix
definitions. Interestingly, therefore, changes in the structure of input-output relationships
between 1977 and 1998 have not lead to greater propagation of idiosyncratic shocks. This is
also consistent with the fact that in Table 6, average pairwise correlations of sectoral growth
rates from the model are similar both across sample periods and across input-output matrix
definitions.
Table 8 presents the same results as those shown in Table 6, but for the case where Σεε
is constructed from a specification with two common factors, so that Σεε = Λs ΣSS Λ0s + Σvv
from equation (7). The factors are estimated using the same method as in section 3 applied
5

The percentiles were computed by Monte Carlo methods from the model with Gaussian errors and using

5000 draws. Results using the empirical distribution of errors computed from the U.S. data via equation
(10) yielded similar results.

16

to the filtered series εt from equation (10). In contrast to the results shown in Table 6,
allowing aggregate shocks to affect sectoral productivity enables the model to capture the
average pairwise cross-correlation in sectoral growth rates found in the data, and produces
an aggregate IP index that is as volatile as in the U.S. data. In addition, Table 9 indicates
that the structural model now generates sample correlation matrices with eigenvalues much
like those found in the U.S. data.
4.3.2

Idiosyncratic vs. Aggregate Shocks

What then are the implications of the structural model for the relative importance of aggregate and sector-specific shocks? Table 10 compares the fractions of IP variance explained by
aggregate shocks, St , in the structural model with those explained by common shocks, Ft , in
the statistical model of section 2. Three key results stand out. First, because the comovement in sectoral growth rates is in part generated by way of input-output linkages, aggregate
shocks explain a somewhat lower fraction aggregate IP variability in the structural model
than in the statistical model. The difference, however, is small prior to the Great Moderation
although somewhat more pronounced after 1984. On the whole, the statistical factor model
represents a relatively robust way of capturing aggregate shocks. Second, aggregate productivity shocks explain the bulk of fluctuations in aggregate IP, although less so after the Great
Moderation. Interestingly, the fraction of aggregate IP variance explained by sector-specific
shocks nearly doubles, to approximately 30 percent, in the second sample period. This result
is driven mainly by a fall in the variability of aggregate shocks, St , over this second period.
Finally, the fall in the variability of St also explains nearly all of the decline in the post-1984
variance of aggregate IP growth rates.
Given the increase in the relative importance of sector specific shocks over the Great
Moderation period, Table 11 lists the sectors whose idiosyncratic shocks (vt in the structural
model above) explain the highest fraction of aggregate IP variability. To account for changes
in the structure of U.S. production, idiosyncratic shocks are constructed using the 1977
input-output matrix for the period 1967-1983 and the 1998 input-output matrix over 19842007. The table highlights several facts. First, the highest ranked sectors tend to be those
that serve as inputs to many other sectors. This is the case, for example, of “Basic Steel
and Mill Products” in the pre-1984 period (6.4 percent), which corresponds to “Iron and
Steel Products” after 1984 (4.2 percent). It is also true of “Utilities” prior to 1984, which
corresponds approximately to “Electric Power Generation and Distribution” in the second
sample period. Second, because of the reduced variability of aggregate shocks in the post17

1984 period, individual sectors can play a measurable role in IP fluctuations after 1984.
Prior to 1984, there were only two sectors whose idiosyncratic shocks alone explained more
than 1 percent of the variation in aggregate IP growth rates. In contrast, all sectors in
Table 11, panel (b), now have idiosyncratic shocks that independently explain more than
1 percent of aggregate IP fluctuations. Finally, Table 11 points to some changes in the
structure of U.S. production. For example, “Coal Mining”, a traditional industry ranked
second prior to 1984 (at 3.4 percent), is no longer among the highest ten ranked sectors
in the second sample period. Similarly, “Electronic Components” moved up in the ranking
(from 0.2 percent to 2.6 percent) and “Aerospace Products and Parts”, becomes one of the
sectors whose idiosyncratic behavior matters most (1.5 percent) in the post-1984 period.
4.3.3

Additional Considerations

Although sector-specific shocks have played a relatively greater role in driving aggregate
IP movements since 1984, it remains that the principal source of variation in IP stems
from aggregate shocks. This is why the sectors listed in Table 4 ultimately do a better job of
tracking IP movements than those listed in Table 11. The result concerning aggregate shocks
as a dominant source of variation in IP is in part related to the structure of the input-output
matrix for U.S. production, but it also reflects the way in which this matrix interacts with
other parameters of the structural model. For example, assuming that capital depreciates
fully within the period (i.e. δ = 1), Horvath (1998) finds that independent sector-specific
shocks contribute an important fraction of aggregate volatility. For comparison, therefore,
Table 12, panels (a) and (b), contrasts the findings under our benchmark calibration, δ =
0.025, with those that obtain with full depreciation, δ = 1. As expected, setting δ = 1
noticeably increases the fraction of variability in IP growth rates explained by idiosyncratic
shocks, especially in the second sample period. Consistent with this finding, the average
pairwise correlation of output growth across sectors generated by purely idiosyncratic shocks
(i.e. 0 factors), essentially doubles when δ = 1. To see why this is the case, recall equation
(5) and move the undepreciated capital to the other side of the equation to define a broad
notion of technology,
α
Yejt = Ajt Kjtj

N
Y
i=1

γ

S
1−αj − N
i=1 γ ij

Mijtij Ljt

+ (1 − δ)Kjt .

(11)

When δ is small, as in our benchmark calibration, a considerable part of a given sector’s
production does not respond contemporaneously to its own idiosyncratic shocks. This is also
true of aggregate shocks but these affect all sectors in the same way. In contrast, when δ = 1,
18

the second term in (11) vanishes and idiosyncratic shocks have a more direct effect on Yejt .

In the filtering process, therefore, a greater portion of fluctuations in sectoral output growth
is attributed to idiosyncratic shocks, which are then propagated by way of input-output

linkages. This will then be reflected in an increase of pairwise correlations of output growth
rates across sectors.
Finally, Table 13 shows how our findings for the benchmark model change with the level of
data disaggregation. In this exercise, we use the 1998 input-output matrix and corresponding
IP data since they provide the highest degree of disaggregation. As the data become less
disaggregated, average pairwise correlations of sectoral IP growth rates increase both in the
data and in the structural model.6 As a result, the fraction of variability in aggregate IP
growth rates explained by aggregate shocks remains essentially unchanged across levels of
disaggregation.

5

Concluding Remarks

In this paper, we explore various leading explanations underlying the volatility of industrial
production and its decline since 1984. We find that neither time variation in the sectoral
shares of IP nor their distribution are important factors in determining the variability of
the aggregate IP index. Instead, the analysis reveals that aggregate shocks largely explain
changes in aggregate IP, and a decrease in the volatility of these shocks explains why aggregate IP is considerably less variable after 1984. Because of this decline in the variability of
aggregate shocks, the relative importance of sector-specific shocks has more than doubled
over the Great Moderation period. Specifically, while sector-specific shocks explain approximately 12 percent of the variation in IP growth prior to 1984, they account for about 30
percent of IP fluctuations after the onset of the Great Moderation. We have also shown that
changes in the structure of the input-output matrix between 1977 and 1998 have not lead to
a more pronounced propagation of sectoral shocks.
The analysis also highlights the conditions under which neoclassical multisector growth
models of the type first studied by Long and Plosser (1983) admit an approximate factor
model as a reduced form. In doing so, it bridges two literatures, one that has relied on factor
analytic methods to assess the relative importance of aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks, and
the other rooted in more structural calibrated models that explicitly take into account input6

This is not surprising since movements in output growth across more broadly defined sectors will reflect

common shocks to their constituent sectors.

19

output linkages across sectors. In the reduced form factor model, aggregate shocks emerge
as the common output factors. The “uniquenesses” are associated with sector specific shocks
but, because of input-output linkages, these can be cross sectionally correlated. A generalized
version of the model studied by Horvath (1998), however, suggests that the degree of sectoral
comovement generated by input-output linkages is limited.

20

References
[1] Anderson, T. W. (1984), “An Introduction to Multivariate Statistical Analysis,” Second
Edition (Wiley, New York).
[2] Brock W. and L. Mirman (1972), “Optimal economic growth and uncertainty: The
discounted case,” Journal of Economic Theory, 4:479-513.
[3] Carvalho, V. M. (2007), “Aggregate fluctuations and the network structure of intersectoral trade,” manuscript, University of Chicago.
[4] Bai, J. (2003), “Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions,” Econometrica,
71:135-171.
[5] Bai, J., and S. Ng (2002), “Determining the number of factors in approximate factor
models,” Econometrica, 70:191-221.
[6] Chamberlain, G., and M. Rothschild (1983), “Arbitrage factor structure, and meanvariance analysis of large asset markets,” Econometrica, 52:1281-1304.
[7] Connor, G., and R. A. Korajczyk (1986), “Performance measurement with the arbitrage
pricing theory,” Journal of Financial Economics, 15:373-394.
[8] Connor, G., and R. A. Korajczyk (1988), “Risk and return in an equilibrium APT:
application of a new test methodology,” Journal of Financial Economics, 21:255-289.
[9] Dupor, B. (1999), “Aggregation and irrelevance in multi-sector models,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 43:391-409.
[10] Foerster, A., Sarte, P-D., and M. W. Watson (2008), “Supplementary material for:
Sectoral vs. aggregate shocks: A structural factor analysis of industrial production,”
available at http://www.princeton.edu/~mwatson.
[11] Forni, M., and L. Reichlin (1998), “Let’s get real: a dynamic factor analytical approach
to disaggregated business cycle,” Review of Economic Studies, 65:453-474.
[12] Forni, M., and L. Reichlin (2000), “The generalized factor model: identification and
estimation,” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82:540-554.
[13] Gabaix, X. (2005), “The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations,” manuscript, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
21

[14] Hansen, G. (1985), “‘Indivisible labor and the business cycle,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 16:309-337.
[15] Horvath, M. (1998) “Cyclicality and sectoral linkages: aggregate fluctuations from independent sectoral shocks,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 1:781-808.
[16] Horvath, M. (2000), “Sectoral shocks and aggregate fluctuations,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 45:69-106.
[17] Long JR, J. and C. I. Plosser (1983), “Real business cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, 91:39-69.
[18] Long JR, J. and C. I. Plosser (1987), “Sectoral vs. aggregate Shocks in the business
cycle,” American Economic Review, 77:333-336.
[19] Quah, D., and T. J. Sargent (1993), “A dynamic index model for large cross sections,”
in: J. H. Stock and M. W. Watson, eds., Business Cycles, Indicators, and Forecasting,
(University of Chicago Press for the NBER, Chicago), Ch. 7.
[20] Shea, J. (2002) “Complementarities and Comovements,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 34:412-433.
[21] Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (2000), “Forecasting using principal components from a
large number of predictors,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 97: 11671179.

22

Appendix A
Data on Industrial Production is obtained from the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System and disaggregated according to the North American Industry Classification
System (NAICS). The raw data are indices of real output, from which we compute sectoral
growth rates and sectoral shares in aggregate IP. While data on the vast majority of sectors
is directly available from the Board of Governors, growth rates for any missing sectors are
approximated using the Board’s recommended methodology. For example, if industry C is
composed of industry A and industry B, then the growth rate of C’s output is approximated
by

where Wit−1

At
Bt
+ WBt−1 IPIPBt−1
WAt−1 IPIPAt−1
IPCt
=
IPCt−1
WAt−1 + WBt−1
is the share of industry i at date t − 1, and WCt−1 = WAt−1 + WBt−1 . Alterna-

tively, if industry C is made up of industry A less industry B, then
At
Bt
WAt−1 IPIPAt−1
− WBt−1 IPIPBt−1
IPCt
=
,
IPCt−1
WAt−1 − WBt−1

and WCt−1 = WAt−1 −WBt−1 . As mentioned in the text, we also make use of vintage IP data,

provided by the Board of Governors, which are disaggregated according to Standard Industry
Classification (SIC) codes. Growth rates and shares for missing sectors are computed in the
manner we have just described. A basic summary of the IP data is provided in Table A1.
Benchmark Input-Output tables, available every five years, are obtained from the Bureau
of Economic Analysis. The “Use Table” measures the value of inputs in producer prices, given
by commodity codes, used by each industry, given by industry codes, as well as payments
to other factors such as labor and capital. The original data are in the most disaggregated
format, and we aggregate industries by adding dollar values for these industries. We consider
benchmark tables for 1977 and 1997 which are broken down according SIC and NAICS
industry definitions respectively.
In order to match the input-output matrices with IP data, we aggregate or disaggregate
the two data types until the smallest industry level for which both data sources are available
is found. Put another way, we find the smallest set of common industries for which we can
match both IP and input-output data. Because the two data sources are originally disaggregated to different levels, the sectoral breakdown we end up using represents collections
of either NAICS or SIC industry levels (depending on whether we are using current or vintage IP data). The approach is as follows: taking the finest available partition of industries
from the benchmark input-output tables, we match up as many industries as possible; the
23

remaining industries with no matches are aggregated until a match is found. The result are
collections of industries whose level of disaggregation ranges from 2-digit to 5-digit levels.
Results reported in the text are for the highest level of disaggregation available, the 5-digit
level, unless otherwise stated.
Data from the 1997 input-output table are matched with IP data disaggregated using
NAICS definitions over the period 1972Q1-2007Q4. Similarly, data from the 1977 inputoutput Table are matched with IP data broken down by SIC code from 1967Q1-2002Q3.
The reclassification of industries from the SIC system to the NAICS system, and the fact
that older input-output tables are not updated according to NAICS definitions, makes the use
of vintage IP data necessary since there is no easy mapping from SIC to NAICS definitions.

24

Figure 1
Growth Rates of Industrial Production
(Percentage points at an annual rate)

A. Monthly Data

B. Quarterly Data

25

Figure 2
Standard Deviation of Sectoral IP Growth Rates
(Percentage points at an annual rate)

A. Monthly Growth Rates

B. Quarterly Growth Rates

26

Figure 3
Factor Decomposition of Industrial Production
(Percentage points at an annual rate)

A. Monthly Data

B. Quarterly Data

27

Figure 4
Distribution of

Ri2 (F )

of Sectoral Growth Rates

A. Monthly Growth Rates

B. Quarterly Growth Rates

28

Table 1
Average Pairwise Correlation of Sectoral IP Growth Rates
Monthly Growth Rates

Quarterly Growth Rates

1972-2007 1972-1983 1984-2007

1972-2007 1972-1983 1984-2007

0.08

0.13

0.05

0.19

0.27

0.11

Table 2
Standard Deviation of IP Growth Rates
(Percentage points at annual rate)
Share Weights Used to

Monthly Growth Rates

Quarterly Growth Rates

Aggregate Sectoral IP

1972- 1972-

1984-

1972- 1972- 1984-

2007

2007

2007

1983

1983

2007

a. Full Covariance Matrix of Sectoral Growth Rates
Time Varying (wit )

8.3

11.6

6.2

5.8

8.7

3.6

Constant (μw )

8.4

11.7

6.2

5.8

8.9

3.6

Equal (1/N)

10.4

14.4

7.6

6.9

10.5

4.2

b. Diagonal Covariance Matrix of Sectoral Growth Rates
Time Varying (wit )

4.3

4.9

4.1

1.9

2.6

1.6

Constant (μw )

4.2

4.6

4.0

1.9

2.4

1.5

Equal (1/N)

4.6

5.6

4.0

1.8

2.5

1.4

Table 3
Decomposition of Variance from Statistical 2-Factor Model
Monthly Growth Rates

Quarterly Growth Rates

1972-1983

1984-2007

1972-1983

1984-2007

11.7

6.2

8.9

3.6

0.86

0.49

0.89

0.87

Std. Deviation of IP Growth Rates
Implied by Factor Model
(with Constant Share Weights)
R2 (F )

29

Table 4
Fraction of Variability in Sectoral Growth Rates Explained by Common Factors
(Quarterly Data)
1972-1983
Sector

Ri2 (F )

Other Fabricated Metal Products

0.86

Fabricated Metals: Forging and Stamping

0.85

Machine Shops: Turned Products and Screws

0.83

Commercial and Service Industry Machinery/Other General Purpose Machinery 0.83
Foundries

0.80

Other Electrical Equipment

0.79

Metal Working Machinery

0.78

Fabricated Metals: Cutlery and Handtools

0.76

Electrical Equipment

0.73

Architectural and Structural Metal Products

0.72

1984-2007
Sector

Ri2 (F )

Coating, Engraving, Heat Treating, and Allied Activities

0.68

Plastic Products

0.67

Commercial and Service Industry Machinery/Other General Purpose Machinery 0.65
Fabricated Metals: Forging and Stamping

0.65

Household and Institutional Furniture and Kitchen Cabinets

0.59

Veneer, Plywood, and Engineered Wood Products

0.59

Metal Working Machinery

0.52

Foundries

0.52

Millwork

0.51

Other Fabricated Metal Products

0.50

30

Table 5
Information Content of IP Contained in Individual Sectors
Selected Sectors Ranked Fraction of IP Explained
by Ri2 (F )

Fraction of IP Explained

by Selected Sectors: 1972-1983 by Selected Sectors: 1972-1983

Top 5 Sectors

85.0

75.4

Top 10 Sectors

90.3

80.4

Top 20 Sectors

97.9

86.4

Top 30 Sectors

98.8

90.3

Table 6
Sectoral Correlations and Volatility of IP Growth Rates
Quarterly U.S. Data and Values Implied by Model with Uncorrelated Sector-Specific Shocks
NAICS (1998 IO Matrix)
1972-1983

1984-2007

SIC (1977 IO Matrix)
1967-1983

1984-2002

Data Model Data Model

Data Model Data Model

0.27

0.04

0.11

0.03

0.23

0.05

0.12

0.04

8.9

3.7

3.6

2.2

8.5

4.0

3.9

2.4

Average Pairwise
Correlation of Sectoral
Growth Rates
Standard Deviation of
IP Growth Rate

31

Table 7
Largest Eigenvalues of Sample Correlation Matrix
IO Model with Uncorrelated Sector-Specific Shocks
a. NAICS (1998 IO Matrix)
1972-1983

1984-2007

Model %-tiles
Eigenvalue Rank Data

1

50

99

Model %-tiles
Data

1

50

99

1

39.4

6.6 8.0 10.1

18.5

4.7 5.5

6.7

2

11.0

5.8 6.4

7.3

6.7

4.1 4.5

5.0

3

5.9

5.3 5.8

6.3

5.1

3.8 4.1

4.5

4

4.8

5.0 5.4

5.8

4.4

3.6 3.8

4.1

5

4.6

4.7 5.0

5.4

4.1

3.5 3.7

3.9

6

4.1

4.5 4.8

5.1

3.6

3.3 3.5

3.7

7

3.5

4.2 4.5

4.8

3.4

3.2 3.4

3.5

b. SIC (1977 IO Matrix)
1967-1983

1984-2002

Model %-tiles
Eigenvalue Rank Data

1

Model %-tiles

50

99

Data

1

50

99

1

30.8

5.9 7.4

9.2

16.9

5.2 6.2

7.7

2

9.1

4.6 5.1

5.8

6.0

4.3 4.8

5.5

3

4.6

4.3 4.6

5.1

4.7

4.0 4.4

4.8

4

4.2

4.0 4.3

4.7

4.3

3.8 4.1

4.4

5

3.6

3.8 4.1

4.4

4.0

3.6 3.9

4.1

6

3.4

3.6 3.8

4.1

3.9

3.5 3.7

3.9

7

3.1

3.4 3.7

3.9

3.6

3.3 3.5

3.7

32

Table 8
Sectoral Correlations and Volatility of IP Growth Rates
Quarterly U.S. Data and Values Implied by 2-factor Model for Sector-Specific Shocks
NAICS (1998 IO Matrix)
1972-1983

1984-2007

SIC (1977 IO Matrix)
1967-1983

1984-2002

Data Model Data Model

Data Model Data Model

0.27

0.27

0.11

0.11

0.23

0.23

0.12

0.12

8.9

9.1

3.6

3.7

8.5

8.8

3.9

4.2

Average Pairwise
Correlation of Sectoral
Growth Rates
Standard Deviation of
IP Growth Rate

33

Table 9
Largest Eigenvalues of Sample Correlation Matrix
IO Model with 2 Factors for Sector-Specific Shocks
a. NAICS (1998 IO Matrix)
1972-1983

1984-2007

Model %-tiles
Eigenvalue Rank Data

1

50

99

Model %-tiles
Data

1

50

99

1

39.4

30.1 39.7 48.4

18.5

14.9 19.2 23.6

2

11.0

8.4

12.2 16.9

6.7

6.3

8.3

10.6

3

5.9

3.6

4.2

5.0

5.1

3.4

3.8

4.4

4

4.8

3.3

3.7

4.3

4.4

3.2

3.5

3.8

5

4.6

3.0

3.5

3.9

4.1

3.0

3.2

3.5

6

4.1

2.8

3.2

3.7

3.6

2.8

3.1

3.3

7

3.5

2.7

3.0

3.4

3.4

2.7

2.9

3.1

b. SIC (1977 IO Matrix)
1967-1983

1984-2002

Model %-tiles
Eigenvalue Rank Data

1

50

99

Model %-tiles
Data

1

50

99

1

30.8

25.0 32.0 39.0

16.9

13.8 18.3 23.0

2

9.1

6.3

8.6

11.3

6.0

5.4

7.2

9.4

3

4.6

3.3

3.8

4.6

4.7

3.6

4.0

4.7

4

4.2

3.0

3.3

3.8

4.3

3.4

3.7

4.1

5

3.6

2.8

3.1

3.5

4.0

3.2

3.4

3.8

6

3.4

2.6

2.9

3.2

3.9

3.0

3.3

3.5

7

3.1

2.5

2.7

3.0

3.6

2.9

3.1

3.4

34

Table 10
Decomposition of Variance from Statistical and Structural 2-Factor Models
NAICS Definitions

SIC Definitions

1972-1983 1984-2007

1967-1983 1984-2002

Std. Deviation of IP Growth Rates

8.9

3.6

8.5

3.9

R2 (F ) - Statistical Model

0.89

0.87

0.85

0.94

0.88

0.69

0.83

0.72

2

R (S) - Structural Model

35

Table 11
Fraction of Aggregate IP Explained by Sector-Specific Shocks
2-Factor Model, 10 Largest Values
a. 1967-1983 (SIC)
Sector

Fraction

Basic Steel and Mill Products

0.064

Coal Mining

0.034

Motor Vehicles, Trucks, and Buses

0.008

Utilities

0.007

Oil and Gas Extraction

0.005

Copper Ores

0.004

Iron and Other Ores

0.003

Petroleum Refining and Miscellaneous

0.003

Motor Vehicle Parts

0.003

Electronic Components

0.002

b. 1984-2007 (NAICS)
Iron and Steel Products

0.042

Electric Power Generation and Distribution

0.036

Semiconductors and Other Electronic Components

0.026

Oil and Gas Extraction

0.017

Automobiles and Light Duty Motor Vehicles

0.017

Organic Chemicals

0.017

Aerospace Products and Parts

0.015

Motor Vehicle Parts

0.013

Natural Gas Distributions

0.012

Support Activity for Mining

0.011

36

Table 12
Sectoral Correlations and Fraction of IP Variance
Explained by Aggregate Shocks
Capital Depreciation Rate

δ = 0.025

δ=1

a. NAICS (1998 IO Matrix)
1972-1983 1984-2007

1972-1983 1984-2007

Fraction of Aggregate IP Variance
Explained by Aggregate Shocks, R2 (S)

0.88

0.69

0.74

0.30

0.04

0.03

0.09

0.07

Average Pairwise Correlation of
Sectoral IP Growth Rates (0 factors)

b. SIC (1977 IO Matrix)
1972-1983 1984-2007

1972-1983 1984-2007

Fraction of Aggregate IP Variance
Explained by Aggregate Shocks, R2 (S)

0.83

0.72

0.61

0.39

0.05

0.04

0.10

0.08

Average Pairwise Correlation of
Sectoral IP Growth Rates (0 factors)

Table 13
Sectoral Correlations and Fraction of IP Variance Explained
by Aggregate Shocks Across Levels of Disaggregation
1972-1983

1984-2007

a. Average Pairwise Correlation of Sectoral Growth Rates
Model Data

Model Data

2-Digit Level, 26 Sectors

0.12

0.43

0.11

0.28

3-Digit Level, 88 Sectors

0.05

0.31

0.04

0.15

4-Digit Level, 117 Sectors

0.04

0.27

0.03

0.11

b. Fraction of IP Variance Explained by Aggregate Shocks
2-Digit Level, 26 Sectors

0.87

0.70

3-Digit Level, 88 Sectors

0.88

0.70

4-Digit Level, 117 Sectors

0.88

0.69

37