View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 85-3
THE RECENT FINANCIAL DEREGULATION AND THE
INTEREST ELASTICITY OF THE SIMPLE MI DEMAND
AJN EMPIRICAL NOTE
FUNCTION:

by
Yash Mehra*

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

November 1985

*I wish to thank Michael Dotsev7, Marvin Goodfriend, Robert L. Hetzel and
Thomas D. Simpson for many helpful comments. The views expressed in this
paper are solely those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

ABSTRACT

The main objective of this note is to examine whether the interest
elasticity of money demand has increased during the last few vears.
simple money demand regression that includes additional intercept

and

A
slope

dummv variables defined over the interval 1981.01 to 1985.03 is estimated
for the whole sample period 1961.01-1985.03.

The regression results show

that the elasticity of money demand with respect to market interest rates
has for now increased.
elasticities.

No shifts are detected in income and time trend

The in-sample predictions of the more interest-sensitive

monev demand regression are broadly consistent with the actual behavior of
Ml observed so far in the 1980s.

The residuals also suggest that the MI

demand function has been subject to transitory shocks over the same period.

Introduction
An important issue in the discussion of the effects of financial
innovations on the money demand function has been the stability of the
marginal relationship between real money balances and interest rates.

The

recent round of financial deregulation which occurred with the introduction
of NOWS, Super-NOWS and Money Market Deposit Accounts has raised the possibility that the interest elasticity of money demand might have increased
during the last few years.

Two interrelated reasons have been advanced for

this potential rise in interest elasticity. 2

First, with Ml now containing

assets potentially suitable for savings, it is possible that the public's
demand for it is more sensitive to market yields than it was in the past,
when it was closer to a pure transaction aggregate.

This is so because the

own rate of return on some assets like NOWS is still regulated and is set at
levels below the open market rates.

Second, since NOW accounts pay explicit

interest but demand deposits do not, a given change in market interest rates
causes a larger proportional change in the opportunity cost of holding NOWS
than of demand deposits.

As a result, changes in market rates might cause

larger changes in NOWS than in demand deposits, thereby increasing the
responsiveness of Ml as a whole to interest rate swings as NOWS become a
larger fraction of Ml.
Another implication of the above hypothesis, if it is valid, is
that the potential rise in the interest elasticity of money demand may not
be permanent.

Since Ml now contains Super-NOWS whose own explicit return is

1Cagan and Schwartz (1975), Simpson and Porter (1980), Hafer and
Hein (1984), and Roley (1985).
2

Brayton, Farr and Porter (1983) and Simpson (1984).

- 2-

unregulated, the opportunity cost of holding Super-NOWS is lower relative
that for NOWS.

Therefore, as the proportion of Ml that is subject to

unregulated own return (like Super-NOWS in the current period and NOWS in
the near future) grows, the market rate elasticity is likely to decrease.3
The main objective of this note is to examine whether the interest
elasticity of money demand has changed during the period 1981-1985.

The

empirical results presented here do seem consistent with the view that the
public's Ml demand function has become more interest sensitive during this
period.

Furthermore, the increased interest-sensitivity of money demand is

due to an increase in the interest-sensitivitv of the 'other checkable
deposits' component of Ml.

Therefore, the various episodes of unusual

strength in Ml growth which have occurred during this period are essentially
predictable and consistent with a money demand regression exhibiting relatively a higher interest elasticity with respect to the market interest
rate.
2.

Estimation Methodology and the Empirical Results
A money demand regression that is estimated including some addi-

tional intercept and slope dummy variables is used to examine whether
financial innovations and deregulation have changed the parameters of the
standard money demand function.
A ln(M/P)t = a

The estimated money demand regression is

+ b(L) A lnyt + c(L) A lnRt + d(L) A lnPt

+ A Dl + A D2 + b(L) Dl*Alny + c(L) D1*AlnR +
1
2
t
t

b(L) D2 * Alnyt + c(L) D2*AlnR

3

+

Ut

For more details see Simpson (1984).

(1)

- 3 -

where M is nominal money balances (currency plus total checkable deposits),
y measures the real income, R is the nominal interest rate and P is the
price level.

D1 and D2 are the zero/one dummy variables, taking values 1

respectively in the periods 1974-1980 and 1981-1985 and zero otherwise.
b(L), c(L), and d(L) are polynomials in the lag operator, L and L is defined
by f

t

. The real income-and interest rate-interaction variables (like

Dl*AlnX) are formed by taking products of the interest rate, real income,
and the zero/one dummy variables.

The statistical significance and the

signs of the estimated coefficients on the interest rate-interaction dummy
variables in the money demand regression (1) can be used to examine whether
the interest rate elasticity has changed over time.
Though the focus of the present note is on the potential behavior
of interest elasticity in the 1980s, the money demand regression (1) also
permits the time trend and income elasticities to vary over this period.
Therefore, the zero/one dummy variable D2 enters individually as well as in
an interactive form with real income and the interest rate.

Furthermore,

several analysts have already documented considerable evidence that is
consistent with the view that the parameters of the money demand regression
had not been stable even over the late 1970s.4

Additional zero/one dummy

variables, defined over the interval 1974 to 1980, are also included in
order to control for the effect that financial innovations might have had on
the parameters of the money demand function in the 1970s.
The money demand regression (1) is standard in the sense that real
money demand depends only upon real income and a nominal interest rate.

4

See, for example, Goldfeld (1976), Simpson and Porter (1980),
Judd and Scadding (1982), and Dotsey (1983).

- 4 -

However, it differs in several ways from the form in which money demand
regressions are usually estimated.

First, the money demand regression (1)

is estimated by simple distributed lags.

This is to be contrasted with the

more popular Koyck-lag specification in which geometric lag shapes are
imposed on the distributed-lag coefficients of the independent variables.
Since the point-estimates of long-term income and interest elasticities
could be sensitive to the restrictions imposed on the lag shapes, the
distributed-lag coefficients in the money demand regression (1) were freely
estimated.

Second, the price level enters the money demand regression (1)

in a distributed lag form.

The standard theoretical models of transaction

demand for money typically assume that the price level elasticity of the
demand for real money balances is zero.

If this assumption is correct, the

distributed-lag coefficients on the price level in the money demand regression (1) should add up to zero.

However, the standard money demand

theory does not say much about the speed with which real money demand
adjusts over time.

If changes in the price level affect the demand for

money with a lag, the individual distributed-lag coefficients on the price
level in (1) would be different from zero.
Including the price level in the money demand regression (1) thus
enables one to test directly whether lags exists in the response of real
money demand to changes in the price level and whether the price level
elasticity of demand for real money balances is zero.

This is to be con-

trasted with the standard money demand regressions based on the real-partial

Goodfriend (1983) has argued that the lags found in the estimated
money demand regressions could arise from the presence of measurement errors
in the relevant independent variables.
5

- 5 adjustment hypothesis, in which the assumption about the absence of lags in
the effect of the price level on real money demand is simply imposed on the
data.

Third, the money demand regression here is estimated in the first

difference form.

The general use of differencing has been suggested to

reduce the possibility of spurious regression results.

In fact, a recent

study by Layson and Seaks (1984) indicated that the first-difference version
of the money demand specification is statistically preferable to its level
form.
In order to test whether interest elasticity has changed in the
early 1980s, the money demand regression (1) is estimated using the monthly
data that span the period 1959-1985.8

The sum of coefficients on the

interest rate (real income) variable provides an estimate of the long-term
interest (income) elasticity over the earlier period 1959-1973.

The sum of

coefficients on the interest-interaction (income-interaction) dummy variable
can then be used to test whether or not the interest rate (the income)
coefficient in the relevant subperiod differ from the one in the earlier
period 1959-1973.

If the sum of coefficients on the interaction variable is

statistically significant, it implies that a shift in the long-run value of
the regression coefficient has occurred over the relevant subperiod.

The

sign and size of this sum would then indicate the nature and the magnitude

6Spencer (1985) presents the empirical evidence that strongly
rejects the assumption that the price level affects the demand for real
money without lag. See also Gordon (1984).
7 Granger and Newbold (1974), Plosser and Schwert (1978),
and
Plosser, Schwert and White (1982).

I get similar results from the quarterly money demand
regressions.
8

- 6 -

of the presumed shift in the parameter.

In addition to the sum of coeffi-

cients on the interaction variables we have also presented F statistics that
test the null hypothesis that each one - not the sum - of the coefficients
on the interaction variables in the money demand regression (1) is zero.

It

is plausible that the t value on the sum of the estimated coefficients on
the interaction variable is very small, indicating no shift in the long-run
value of the relevant regression parameter and yet the F statistic is
significant, the latter implying a shift in some of the coefficients on the
relevant variable.

An outcome like this simply means that the shape of the

lag structure on the relevant independent variable is not stable over the
subperiod, even though the magnitude of the long-run response of. real demand
to that variable is.
Two regression equations are reported in Table 1.

Equation (1) is

the money demand regression that includes all the intercept and slope dummy
variables.

Equation (2) is the money demand regression that retains only

those dummy variables which are statistically significant.

These

9 The money demand regressions always included the current and the
lagged values of changes in the price level. The sum of the estimated
distributed-lag coefficients on the price level was not significantly
different from zero, implying that the price level elasticity of demand for
real money balances is zero. However, several individual distributed-lag
coefficients on the price level were significant, suggesting lags in the
effect of the price level on money demand. These results are in line with
the findings reported in Spencer (1985).

l The constant term in the money demand regressions estimated here
was generally significant and therefore was not suppressed to zero. The
inclusion of the constant term in the first difference version of the money
demand function amounts to permitting the influence of time trend on the
holdings of real money balances. The time trend variable is a proxy for
technological progress in the financial system and captures, though
imperfectly, the influence of changes in the cash management techniques and
other financial innovations on money demand. See Lieberman (1977, 1979).

- 7 -

regression results suggest two major inferences.

First, the interest

elasticity of money demand has increased during the last few years.

The sum

of distributed-lag coefficients on the interest rate-interaction dummy
variables is negative and statistically significant (see the t values on
this sum in equations (1) and (2), Table l).

For the period 1981-1985 these

money demand regressions yield a long-term interest elasticity of - .16,
which is substantially higher than the one (- .07) obtained from the earlier
part of the sample period.

Second, no significant shifts appear to have

occurred in the long-term income elasticity of money demand.

In fact, these

money demand regressions provide point estimates of the long-term income
elasticity which are closer to unity for most of the period studied here.
Third, except for a shift that occurred in the constant term, these regressions imply that other long-run parameters of the MI demand function did
not change during the 1970s.
If the public's MI demand function has become more interest
sensitive during the 1980s, is this new money demand regression consistent
with the actual pattern of money growth observed over the period
1981.01-1985.03? The within-sample prediction errors that are presented in
Table 2 suggest this to be the case.

Two sets of errors that occur in

predicting the quarterly levels and growth rates of nominal money balances
are presented.

One set assumes that the interest elasticity of money demand

has not increased during the 1980s.

The money demand regression that omits

the pertinent dummy variables is estimated over the entire sample period,
and the estimated coefficients are used to generate the errors in predicting
nominal money balances (see errors in Columns Al and A2, Table 2).

The

other set of errors is generated under the assumption that the interest
elasticity of money demand had been higher during the 1980s.

The money

- 8 -

demand regression that includes the relevant dummy variables is estimated,
and the estimated coefficients are used to generate the sample errors (see
errors in columns BI and B2 Table 2).

A comparative analysis of the mean

and the RMSE statistics clearly suggests the inference that the pattern of
money growth that is predicted by this more interest-sensitive money demand
regression is not at all inconsistent with the actual behavior of money
growth over the interval 1981.01 to 1985.03.
Source of the Shift in the Interest Elasticity
In order to identify the source of the increased interest-sensitivity of the MI demand function, the money demand regression
reported in Table 1 (equation 2) was reestimated for the transactions
deposit component of Ml, with and without including 'the other checkable
deposits'.

For the money demand regression that excludes other checkable

deposits from the transaction deposits, the shift variables on the
interest-elasticity parameters are not statistically significant (the t
value is -.5 and the F2 R value, .89; see Equation 2.1, Table 3).

When other

checkable deposits are included in the transaction deposits, the same shift
variables on the interest-elasticity parameters turn out to be statistically
significant (the t value is -3.1 and the F2R value, 3.8; see Equation 2.2,
Table 3).

This suggests that it is the recent nationwide authorization of

NOWS and Super-NOWS which is at the source of the increased
interest-sensitivity of the Ml demand function.
The other checkable deposits pay an explicit rate of return, so
that the explicit yield on money is no longer zero.

The money demand

regressions reported here do not include the variable measuring the own
yield on money.

This omission of the own yield variable from the money

- 9 -

demand regressions can, in general, affect the estimates of the remaining
parameters.
In order to investigate the above issue, the money demand
regression is reestimated by including a different proxy for the opportunity
cost variable.

Following Cagan (1983) a simple proxy for the explicit yield

on money is calculated as the share of other checkable deposits in MI
multiplied by the yield on these deposits, 5-1/4 percent; the assumption
being that the regulatory restrictions on the payment of an explicit rate on
demand deposits are not circumvented.

This measure of the explicit yield

on money is then subtracted out from the commercial paper rate, and the
money demand regressions that include this redefined opportunity cost
variable (R) are reported in table 4.

The sum of the distributed-lag

coefficients on this opportunity cost-interaction dummy variables are still
negative and statistically significant (see the t and F values, Equations
4.1 and 4.2, Table 4).

This suggests the inference that the increased

interest-sensitivity of the money demand function probably does reflect the
increase sensitivity of money demand to the opportunity cost variable.12

This assumption is questionable. Klein (1974) has argued that
the depository institutions have implcitly paid a competitive return on
demand deposits, whereas Starz (1979) has noted that the implicit rate that
is paid on demand deposits appears to be about one half of the competitive
rate. Carlson and Frew (1980) however have raised some econometric issues
and have argued that the statistical performance of Klein's measure of the
yield on money in the money demand regression might be spurious.
1 1

12 The results of this regression must be interpreted cautiously,
as there are some problems with the approach taken here. Two potential
problems are noteworthy. First, to be extent that some implicit return,
though not necessarily at the competitive rate, is earned by the holders of
demand deposits, the approach used here to calculate the own yield on money
overstates the effect that the other checkable deposits have on the own
yield. Second, some of the econometric issues raised by Carlson and Frew
(Footnote Continued)

-

10

-

Comparison with Some Existing Studies
The empirical results here partially support the general nature of
findings reported in Brayton, Farr and Porter (1983) and Simpson (1984).
These analysts have argued that the introduction of NOWS, Super-NOWs and
Money Market Deposit Accounts has altered the interest sensitivity of the Ml
money demand function.

Thus, the period of strength in Ml demand in 1982

and 1983 could in part be explained in terms of an increase in interest
elasticity in combination with a significant drop in short-term interest
rates which occurred during that period.
Our results also imply that the financial innovations that occurred in the 1970s did not raise the interest elasticity of the Ml demand
function during that period, a result that is consistent with the findings
reported in Hafer and Hein (1984).
For the period 1961-1980 the monthly money demand regressions
reported here imply that the point estimate of the long-term interest
elasticity is -.07, which appears quite low when compared with the ones
obtained from some standard money demand regressions. 3

As stated before,

the standard money demand regressions are estimated in the level form and
include the lagged dependent variable, the latter amounts to imposing a
geometric shape on the distributed-lag coefficients of the independent
variables.

(Footnote Continued)
(1980) may be applicable to this regression. Stochastic shifts in money
demand could generate contemporaneous correlation between the error term and
the opportunity cost variable, thereby biasing the estimated coefficients.
13For example, for almost similar sample periods the long-term
interest elasticity is estimated to be -.13 in Judd and Motley (1984) and
-.16 in Hafer and Hein (1984).

-

11

-

Since the money demand regressions reported here are estimated in
the first difference form it will be-interesting to examine whether the
first-difference estimation of the standard money demand regressions still
provides high estimates of the interest elasticity of money demand.

Ignor-

ing for the moment the dummy variables the standard lagged-dependent variable versions of the money demand regression can be derived from the
equation (1) by imposing the following restrictions on lag structures
b(L) = b

Xs (1-,)s
s=o

1
c(L) = c1

X

(i-X)5

= (b1

A)/(1-(1-A)L)

(2a)

Xs = (C1

A)/(1-(1-A)L)

(2b)

X

1s=o
d(L) = 0.0

(2c)

d(L) = (y-1) + y " (1-X)
s=1

L

=

[(y-1) + (1-y)L]/[1-(1-X)LI

ao = 0.0

(2d)

(2e)

The restrictions expressed as in (2a) and (2b) impose geometrically declining lag structures on income and interest rate variables.
on d(L) as expressed in (2c) implies two assumptions. 4

The restriction
The first is that

the price level elasticity of the demand for real money balances is zero,
i.e., the sum of distributed lag coefficients on the price level is zero.
The second is that the demand for real money balances adjusts to the price
level with no lags, i.e., each of the distributed lag coefficients on the
price level is zero.

The restriction (2e) amounts to assuming that time

trend has no influence on the holdings of real money balances.

Substituting

(2a), (2b), (2c) and (2e) into (1) and ignoring dummy variables yield the
money demand regression (3a)

14 Mehra (1978) and Spencer (1983).

-

12 -

Aln (M/P) = (b1 X)/(1-(I-X)L) Alnyt +

(C1 X)/(l-(1-X)L)AlnR

(3a)

Alternatively, (3a) could be expressed as follows:

Aln (M/P)

=

bIX A ln yt + C1 X AlnRt + (I-X)Aln (M/P)ti

(3b)

The money demand regression (3b), popularly known as the real-partial
adjustment model of money demand, is one of the lagged dependent variable
versions of the standard money demand function.

Another version, known as

the nominal partial adjustment model of money demand, is obtained if we
assume that lags do exist in the adjustment of real money balances with
respect to changes in the price level.

But we retain the assumptions that

the long-run price level elasticity of the demand for real money balances is
zero and that the lag shape on the price level variable is geometric.

These

assumptions imply that d(L) follows the restrictions expressed as in (2d).
Substituting (2a), (2b), (2d) and (2e) into (1) yields the following:
Aln (M/P) = b X Alny + c1 X AlnR + (1-X) ln (Mt1/P)

(4)

The money demand regressions (3b) and (4) and their level versions
were estimated over the sample period 1961-1980.

Presented in Table 5 are

the estimates of the long-term interest elasticity of money demand.

These

regression results show that the estimates of the long-term interest
elasticity that are obtained from the level versions of the standard money
demand regression are substantially higher than the ones obtained from the
relevant first-difference versions.

This suggests that high estimates of

the long-term interest elasticity derived from the level versions of the
standard money demand regression are not robust.

3.

Concluding Remarks
The evidence presented here suggests that the interest elasticity

of money demand has increased during the most recent period.

If we take

- 13 into account the impact of falling nominal interest rates on the behavior of
money demand, we could easily explain a significant fraction of the surge in
MI growth that has occurred at various times during the early 1980s. The
empirical work also shows that the income and time trend elasticities of
money demand have not so far changed during the last few years.
The evidence presented here do suggest that the recent round of
financial deregulation which occurred with the nationwide introduction of
NOWS, Super-NOWS and Money Market Deposit Accounts has been instrumental in
raising the interest elasticity of money demand.

If this explanation is

correct, we may be heading towards a period during which there would remain
some uncertainty about the magnitude of the interest elasticity parameter.
As the fraction of assets in MI which is deregulated grows overtime and as
the own rates of return on these deregulated assets move with the market
interest rates, it is quite plausible that the increase observed in the
interest elasticity of money demand might fade away.
The finding that the interest elasticity of money demand has
increased during the early 1980s does not by itself invalidate monetary
targeting, nor does it reduce the usefulness of MI as a guide to the
long-run formulation of monetary policy.

It does imply, however, that in

the short run we could observe large swings in the growth rate of MI following large, exogenous changes in nominal interest rates.

In case we observe

large, policy induced or exogenous breaks in the long-run behavior of
nominal interest rates, changes in money growth which are induced by such
changes in nominal interest rates need to be accommodated by a revision of
the short-term monetary targets.

-

14 -

REFERENCES

Brayton, Flint, Terry Farr and Richard Porter, "Alternative Money Demand
Specifications and Recent Growth in Ml," Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, May 23, 1983, 1-19.
Cagan, Philip, "Monetary Policy and Subduing Inflation", in Contemporary
Economic Problems, American Enterprise Institute, 1983, 21-53.
Cagan, Philip, and Anna J. Schwartz, "Has the Growth of Money Substitutes
Hindered Monetary Policy," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, May
1975, 137-59.
Carlson, John A. and James R. Frew, "Money Demand Responsiveness to the
Rate of Return on Money: A Methodological Critique," Journal of
Political Economy, 3, 1980, 598-607.
Dotsey, Michael, "The Effects of Cash Management Practices on the Demand for
Demand Deposits", Working Paper 1983-2, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond.
Goldfed, Stephen M., "The Case of the Missing Money" Brookings Paper on
Economic Activity, 3, 1976, 683-73.
Goodfriend, Marvin, "Reinterpreting Money Demand Regressions")
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 22, 1985,
207-242.
Granger, Clive W.M. and Paul Newbold, "Spurious Regressions in Econometrics,
Journal of Econometrics, July 1974, 111-20.
Hafer, R.W. and Scott E. Hein, "Financial Innovations and the Interest
Elasticity of Money Demand: Some Historical Evidence," Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, May 1984, 247-51.

- 15 -

Klein, Benjamin, "Competitive Interest Payments on Bank Deposits and the
Long-Run Demand for Money," American Economic Review, December 1974,
931-49.
Judd, John P. and Brian Motely, "The Great Velocity Decline of 1982-83: A
Comparative Analysis of MI and M2," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, Summer 1984, 56-74.
Judd, John P., and John L. Scadding, "The Search for a Stable Money Demand
Function: A Survey of the Post-1973 Literature," Journal of Economic
Literature, September 1982, 993-1023.
Layson, Stephen K. and Terry G. Seaks.

"Estimation and Testing for

Functional Form in First Difference Model", The Review of Economics and
Statistics, Mav 1984, 339-343.
Lieberman, Charles, "Structural and Technological Change in Money Demand,"
American Economic Review, May 1979, 324-29.
"The Transactions Demand for Money and Technological Changes,"
Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1977, 307-317.
Mehra, Yash, "Is Money Exogenous in Money Demand Equations," Journal of
Political Economy, Part 1, April 1978, 211-28.
Plosser, Charles I. and C. William Schwert, "Money, Income and Sunspots:
Measuring Economic Relationships and the Effects of Differencing,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, November 1978, 637-60.
Plosser, Charles I., G. William Schwert and Halbert White, "Differencing as
a Test of Specification", International Economic Review, October 1982,
535-52.
Roley, V. Vance, "Money Demand Predictability" Working Paper 84-12, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, December 1984.

- 16 Simpson, Thomas D. and Richard D. Porter, "Some Issues Involving the Definition and Interpretation of Monetary Aggregates," In Controlling Monetary Aggregates III, Proceedings of a Conference, Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, 1980, 161-234.
.

"Changes in the Financial System:

Implications for Monetary

Policy," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1984, 249-65.
Spencer, David E.

"Money Demand and the Price Level," The Review of Econom-

ics and Statistics, August 1985, 3, 490-96.
Startz, Richard, "Implicit Interest on demand deposits," Journal of Monetary
Economics, October 1979, 515-34.

-

17 -

Table 1

Formal Tests of a Change in Money Demand
Parameters, Monthly Money Demand Regressions

Equation 1
Aln(M/P) = -.002 + .87 Alny - .07 AlnR
(-1.6) (3.5)
(-4.4)

-

.002 Dl + .40 DI * Alny + .01 DI *
(-1.8)
(1.2)
(.02)

AlnR - .000 D2 + .16 D2 * Alny - .09 D2 *AlnR
(-.05)
(.35)
(-2.2)
Sample-Period = 1961.01-1985.03

DW = 2.0

F1

R

= 2.1
FlR = 2.3*
(9,232)
y (8,232)

=

SER = .00358

.449

F2y = 1.0
(8,232)

F2R

ROW = .1
(1.7)

2.6*
(9,232)

=

Equation 2
Aln (M/P) = -.002 + 1.0 Alny - .07 AlnR - .001 DI
(-1.9)
(-6.4)
(-3.0) (6.5)
Sample-Period = 1961.01-1985.03

Notes:

R

= .413

SER

-

=

.09 D2 * LlnR
(-3.3)
.00369

ROW = .1 DW = 2.1
(1.7)

1n is the natural logarithm, A the first difference operator, M the Ml,
R the commercial paper rate, y the real personal income, and P the
personal consumption expenditure deflator. DI and D2 are the zero/one
dummy variables, taking values 1 respectively in the periods 1974-1980
and 1981-1985 and zero otherwise. D * Aln X is formed simply by taking
the product of the zero/one dummy variable D and the X variable. The
estimated coefficients on the income and interest rate variables are the
sum of the coefficients that are estimated with a simple distributed lag
and therefore provide estimates of the relevant long-term elasticities.
1ny includes 8 contemporaneous and lagged terms; lnR, 9 such terms. The
money demand regressions always included current and lagged values of
the price level, the sum of distributed-lag coefficients on the price
level constrained to zero. The regressions were estimated by the
Hildreth-Lu estimation procedure. Fly (F2y) is the F test of the null
hypothesis that each one of the coefficients on the income-interaction
dummy variables is zero in the relevant subperiod. A similar
interpretation applies to F1 R and F2 R.

- 18 -

Table 2
Within-Sample Simulation Results, 1981Q1-1985Q1:
Percentage Error in Predicting Nominal Money Balances

No Change in the
Interest Elasticity of
Money Demand during the 1980s

A Higher Interest Elasticity
of Money Demand during the 1980s

Year/Quarter

Al
Quarterly
Levels

A2
Quarterly
Changes

Bi
Quarterly
Levels

B2
Quarterly
Changes

1981Q1
1981Q2
1981Q3
198104

.42
.97
-.28
-1.04

1.69
2.23
-5.09
-3.07

-.21
.06
-1.08
-1.97

-.84
1.10
-4.66
-3.67

1982Q1
1982Q2
1982Q3
1982Q4

-.69
-.84
-.53
1.36

1.42
.59
1.27
7.76

-1.82
-2.36
-1.94
-1.30

.64
-2.26
1.73
2.71

1983Q1
1983Q2
1983Q3
1983Q4

2.14
3.54
5.11
5.33

3.15
5.55
6.11
.89

-1.64
-.94
.98
1.42

-1.43
2.93
7.83
1.78

1984Q1
1984Q2
1984Q3
1984Q4

4.99
5.06
5.06
4.31

-1.31
.24
- . 00
-2.91

1.53
2.50
1.77

.40
1.51
2.45
-3.01

1985Q1

4.89

2.27

1.67

- .34

Mean Error

2.34

1.15

- .08

.40

RMS E

3.39

3.44

1.62

2.93

Notes:

-

1.90

Errors in the columns labeled 'Quarterly Levels' are calculated as
the difference between the actual and predicted level, divided by the
predicted level of nominal money balances. Errors in the columns
labeled 'Quarterly Changes' are calculated as the difference between
the actual and predicted quarterly growth rates, divided by the
predicted growth rates of nominal money balances. The predicted
values used in calculating these errors were generated in two ways.
For the errors in columns BI and B2 the predicted values used are
from the money demand regression 2 summarized in Table 1. For the
errors in columns Al and A2 the predicted values used are from the
money demand regression 2 that was reestimated omitting all the
interest rate-interaction dummv variables; this amounts to assuming
no change in the interest elasticity of money demand over the 1980s.
RMSE is the root mean squared error.

-

19 -

Table 3

Disaggregated Money Demand Regressions: Explaining
The Source of the Shift in Interest Elasticity

Equation 3.1

Demand Deposits

Aln (DD/P) = -.003 + 1.2 Alny (-2.4) (4.4)
- .027 D2 * AlnR
(-.5)

.10 AlnR - .003 DI - .006 D2
(-5.3)
(-2.3)
(-4.5)

Sample-Period = 1961.01-1985.03 R2
.38 SER = .00369
F2R = .89
(9,257)

ROW

=

.3

DW

1.94

Equation 3-2 :Demand deposits and Other Checkable Deposits
Aln (DD +OCD/P) = -.003 + 1.1 Alny - .08 AlnR
(-3.6)
(6.3)
(-6.2)
+ .001 D2 - .11 D2 * AlnR
(.71)
(-3.1)

-

.001 DI
(-2.0)

-2
Sample Period = 1961.01-1985.03 R =.38 SER = .0047 ROW = 0.0
F2R = 3.8
(9,257)

Notes:

DW = 1.94

DD is demand deposits and OCD is the other checkable deposits. See
Notes in Table 1 for an explanation of the remaining variables.

- 20 -

Table 4
Money Demand Regressions that Include the Own Rate,

Equation 4.1 : Transaction deposits
Aln (DD + OCD/P) = -.003 + 1.1 Alny -

(-3.6)
+ .0004 D2 -

(.5)

(6.4)

.08 AlnR -

.001 DI

(-6.3)

(-2.0)

.08 D2 * AlnR

(-2.1)
-2

Sample-Period = 1961.01-1985.03 R = .38 SER = .005
F2- = 3.4

ROW = 0.0

DW = 1.95

R (9,257)

Equation 4.2 : Currency and Transaction Deposits (M)
Aln (M/P) = -.002 + 1.0 Alny - .07 AlnR -.001 D1
(3.4)
(7.2)
(-6.9)
(-1.8)
+ .0004 D2 -

(.6)

.07 D2* AlnR

(-2.7)

Sample-Period = 1961.01-1985.03 R

= .412 SER = .0037

ROW = 0.0

DW = 1.92

F2- = 3.05

(9,257)

Notes:

R is the commercial paper rate minus the own vield on money. The own
yield on money is measured as the share of other checkable deposits in
MI multiplied by the yield on these deposits, 5-1/4 percent. For other
variables see notes in Table 1.

- 21 -

Table 5

Interest Elasticities of the Standard Monthlv
Money Demand Equations, 1961-1980

Level Form

Long-Run Elasticity

Real-Partial Adjustment Equation

-.23

Nominal-Partial Adjustment Equation

-.21

First Difference Form
Real-Partial Adjustment Equation

-.03

Nominal-Partial Adjustment Equation

-. 03

Notes:

The estimates of the long-run interest elasticity are from the
following money demand regressions.
Level Form
In (M/P) = a + b lny + c 1nR + d in (M/P)-1

+ gD1

In (M/P) = a + b 1ny + c 1nR + d In (M 1/P) + gD1

First Difference Form
A In (M/P) = bAlny + cAlnR + dAln (M/P)

1

+ eD1

A In (M/P) = bAlny + cAlnR + dAln (M_1 /P) + eD1

The regressions are estimated by the Hildreth -Lu estimation
procedure. For an explanation of the variables see the note in
Table 1.