View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Real Rates and Consumption Smoothing
in a Low Interest Rate Environment: The
Case of Japan

WP 17-08

Jonathan Lecznar
Boston University
Thomas A. Lubik
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Real Rates and Consumption Smoothing in a Low Interest
Rate Environment: The Case of Japan∗
Jonathon Lecznar
Boston University†

Thomas A. Lubik
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond‡
May 2017

Working Paper No. 17-08

Abstract
We study the dynamics of consumption, the real interest rate and measures of labor
input in Japan over the period from 1985-2014. We identify structural breaks in macroeconomic aggregates during the 1990s and associate them with the zero interest rate
policy pursued by the Bank of Japan and the surprise increase in the consumption tax
rate in April 1997. Formal estimation using the Generalized Methods of Moments shows
that the mid-1990s are characterized by breaks in the structural parameters governing
household consumption and labor supply decisions. Specifically, following the tax hike
and during the low nominal rate period, Japanese households became less risk averse
and exhibited a higher degree of habit formation.
JEL Classification: C26; E21; E43
Key Words: Euler equation; GMM; nominal interest rate, labor supply

∗

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be interpreted as those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
†
Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, MA 02215. Email: jlecznar@bu.edu.
‡
Research Department, P.O. Box 27622, Richmond, VA 23261. Email: thomas.lubik@rich.frb.org.

1

1

Introduction

In this paper, we show that the behavior of aggregate consumption changed considerably
in Japan in early 1997. Evidence from raw comovement patterns, structural break tests,
and more formal GMM-based estimation on structural Euler-equations for consumption
growth all indicate that the behavior of aggregate consumption suffered a break during
that time period. Based on the historical record, we can in principle correlate this finding
with two dramatic policy actions: the Bank of Japan’s (BoJ) implementation of a highly
accommodative low-interest policy in mid-to-late 1995 and a 2 percentage point rise in the
consumption tax rate to 5% in April 1997.1 We argue that the results in our paper show
fairly conclusively that the tax change led to a break in the aggregate consumption series
to the effect that it became more serially correlated afterward. This can be explained in
terms of a simple consumption-choice model whereby Japanese households formed stronger
habit preferences toward their purchases following the tax increase.
The economy of Japan is a congenital environment to study the behavior of aggregate
consumption. The period from the mid-1980s through early 2010s in Japan can be tersely
described as a boom, then bust, followed by a long period of primarily stagnation and
intermittent deflation. Throughout this period there were marked changes in multiple facets
of governmental policy. With regards to monetary policy, the BoJ lowered rates to hitherto
historic lows in 1995, only to eventually go further in 1999 by introducing the zero interest
rate policy (ZIRP). The BoJ’s policy rate has not deviated very far from zero ever since.
On the fiscal policy side, numerous rounds of fiscal stimulus were passed beginning in 1992,
labor laws on temporary employment were relaxed in 1998, and a tax on consumption was
initially introduced in 1989 then subsequently raised in 1997.
We first assess whether key macroeconomic time series exhibit changes in behavior over
the period from 1985 through 2014. In particular, we consider measures of consumption,
the real interest rate, and the extensive and intensive margins of employment. A simple
ocular inspection of the data suggests that they do, as both consumption growth and the
real rate of interest appear to begin behaving differently in the mid-1990s. Using a bevy of
structural break tests, we identify the second quarter of 1995 as a break in the real interest
rate series, which coincides with the onset of a period when the BoJ held the policy rate
fixed at 50 basis points. We also find a break in consumption growth in the second quarter
of 1997, which coincides with the hike in the consumption tax rate that is often regarded
1
Initially announced in November 1994, the tax rise was associated with an anticipatory spike in consumption followed by a sharp drop, then protracted stagnation.

2

as the starting point of the lost decade. Moreover, we find evidence of a structural break
in the behavior of employment and hours worked that started earlier in the 1990s. The
picture that emerges of Japan’s economy during the 1990s is one of considerable change in
the macroeconomic environment.
Given the dramatic changes in the economic and policy environments during this time,
we ask whether the standard consumption Euler-equation is a good and consistent descriptor
of consumption growth throughout such an environment. Economic theory suggests that the
key explanatory variable for consumption growth is the real rate of interest. A convenient
way of thinking about this relationship can be found in the optimal savings decisions of
households. More specifically, we consider the canonical consumption Euler-equation arising
from constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) preferences with risk aversion parameter . It
describes how consumption  , a (gross) nominal interest rate  , and (gross) inflation  
are related to each other:
−
− =   +1

1

 +1

  0

(1)

 is a parameter that discounts future consumption, and  is a rational expectations
operator. This relationship can also be expressed in a more compact form by rewriting it
in terms of a log-linear approximation:
´ 1
³
e+1 = 1 
e −  
e+1 = e 
 ∆



(2)

where tilde ‘~’ denotes logarithmic deviations from the steady state. The real interest rate,
e , is defined as the log-difference of the nominal rate and expected inflation.

The Euler-equation (2), and its variants discussed below, provide testable implications

for how consumption and real rates comove under the assumption of underlying optimizing
behavior.2 This relationship also implies that the strength of the responsiveness of consumption growth to changes in the real rate is dictated by the degree of risk aversion.3
However, underlying this time-series relationship is the assumption of structural stability
which requires both that  and the theoretical framework that gave rise to this conjectured relationship remain constant over the period considered. The statistical tests on the
Japanese macroeconomic time series described above give us strong reason to believe that
the assumption of structural stability is violated during this period.
2

A rise in the real rate increases current savings and thus lowers current consumption. Consumption
is therefore expected to increase from the current period to the next, which induces positive comovement
between the two variables. In the data, this simple relationship is violated since it leaves out additional
conditioning variables as we document in the main part of thepaper.
3
For example, increased risk aversion, signified by an increase in , implies that increases in the real rate
result in a weaker rise in consumption.

3

We therefore develop a baseline specification that generalizes the basic relationship conjectured in equation (2) to incorporate external habit formation. Using the Generalized
Method of Moments (GMM) to estimate this relationship, we find that a standard specification with habits in consumption fits the data over the full sample reasonably well, with
structural parameter estimates in line with previous results in the literature. We cannot,
however, accept the null hypothesis of structural stability of the estimating equation, which
leads us to consider subsamples. From our estimation, we find evidence suggesting that the
1997 consumption tax rate hike changed the nature of consumer behavior. In particular,
following the tax increase, we find that consumers became less risk averse, thus responding
more to real rate changes, while exhibiting stronger habit preferences. Additionally, we test
alternative specifications incorporating the extensive and intensive margins of employment.
We conclude that the inclusion of employment in the utility function is not necessary for
capturing consumption dynamics in Japan. This is similar to findings reported by Kiley
(2010) who, for the US during 1960Q1-2004Q4, also finds evidence for habit persistence but
against nonseparability in consumption and leisure. Overall, we provide evidence supporting the predictive power and structural stability of the habits-based estimating equation,
although not in its constituent parameters.
The plan for our investigation is as follows. In the next section, we provide an overview
of the macroeconomic and monetary history of Japan with a focus on the period since
the 1980s as a background for the formal empirical analysis. We derive the consumption
Euler equation we intend to estimate in Section 3. We discuss the general specification
and highlight specific and nested parameterizations. Section 4 contains the main body of
results, while section 5 considers some alternative approaches and robustness analyses. We
conclude in section 6.

2

A Short Macroeconomic History of Japan over the Lost
Decades

In this section, we provide some background on the development of the Japanese economy
from the beginning of our sample period in the mid-1980s through the lost decades of the
1990s and 2000s. The first half of our sample was characterized by fast growth and a
run-up in asset prices, whereas the latter half of this period saw a dramatic decline of the
economy, followed by a sluggish and incomplete recovery that has often been referred to
as stagnation. As background for our empirical analysis with its focus on the relationship
between aggregate consumption and the real interest rate, we start out with a brief narrative
4

of the key episodes over this period. We then provide a more detailed statistical analysis
with the aim of establishing some key facts.

2.1

A Brief Narrative4

The 1980s were a period of relative calm in the Japanese economy as it emerged from the
decades-long rebuilding process after the end of World War II. Especially the mid-to-late
1980s were a time of strong growth, as GDP growth rose from 3.3% on average over 1980Q11987Q2 to 5.7% in 1987Q3-1990Q2. At the same time, it was a period of aggregate price
stability since from 1982-1989 inflation remained well contained between 0-3%. However,
primary stock and land price indices rose 300% in 1983-1989. This era has come to be
known as the bubble period that laid the foundation for Japan’s lost decades. In hindsight,
there were many events potentially contributing to this boom-bust cycle. The significant
appreciation in the Yen during this period5 induced the BoJ to lower the three-month
Gensaki rate6 from 7% to 3.75% in 1985Q4-1987Q3. Substantial money growth ensued,
with broad money growing at greater than 9% annually between 1986-1988 and peaking at
11% in 1989. The higher money growth rate initially stimulated real variables and asset
prices, as the Japanese public had come to expect price stability.
Eventually, as inflation picked up — from 1% in 1985Q1-1989Q1 to 2.8% in 1989Q21991Q4 — and asset prices reached staggering heights, the BoJ responded by pushing interest
rates sharply higher: the Gensaki three-month rate rose from 4.3% to 7.6% between 1989Q2
and 1990Q4. During this same period, a 3% consumption tax, the first of its kind in Japan,
was enacted in April 1989. In response to these contractionary policies, real GDP barely
grew over 1992Q2-1995Q1, despite the passing of an initial round of fiscal stimulus in 1992.
At the same time, asset prices in general began to fall, punctuated by an approximately
60% drop in the Nikkei stock index between 1990 and 1992. Land prices also exhibited a
marked decline beginning in 1991 and continuing into the 2000s. The asset price collapse
and prevalence of nonperforming loans resulted in a largely insolvent financial sector and
the failure of many smaller institutions, primarily between 1992-1995.7 Commensurate with
these events, broad money growth slowed to a 3.8% annual rate.
4

This section draws heavily on Hetzel (1999), Ono and Rebick (2003), Ito and Mishkin (2004), and Fortin
and Sicsic (2009).
5
From February 1985 to November 1985 alone, the dollar fell by 20% against the Yen.
6
The Gensaki rate pertains to bond repurchase agreements. The one- and three-month Gensaki rates
were the relevant policy rates at this time, as short-term government bonds were first available in 1986.
7
In order to stem this tide of failing financial institutions, the Japanese government switched from guaranteeing individual deposits up to U10 million to a complete guarantee.

5

The BoJ responded to the sharp economic downtown by progressively lowering the
overnight rate, eventually hitting a hitherto historical low of 0.5% in September 1995. After
the BoJ was granted formal independence in April 1998, the rate was further lowered to 25
basis points in September 1998. It was over this period that inflation began its inexorable
decline toward deflationary territory. In line with the overall drop in asset prices and
money growth, the GDP deflator began falling in 1991 from 2.6% annually to -0.7% in 1995
and -0.6% in 1996. At the same time, GDP growth stabilized at a low but positive level,
despite numerous adverse factors: real wages continued to rise in the 1990s, depressing
employment growth; and the yen nearly doubled in value relative to the dollar between
1990 and 1995. Coinciding with the economic slowdown in the 1990s, the weakening of the
social compact of life-long employment began to occur. This is evidenced by a fall in the
percentage of employed workers considered regular-employees from 80% in 1994 to 66% in
2008. Additionally, the likelihood of being employed by the same employer for at least a
decade declined between 1992 and 2002 from 63% to 49%.8
Arguably the most consequential policy change was initiated in November 1994, when
the Diet passed a bill to raise the consumption tax rate from 3% to 5%, effective in April
1997. The anticipated rise in the consumption tax rate contributed positively to a fleeting
recovery via the acceleration of big-ticket purchases. However, the decline soon after was
sharp: 1997Q2 GDP fell by an annualized rate of 3.9%; consumption growth dropped to
an annualized -10% between 1997Q1 and Q2. The effects were also protracted: despite a
brief uptick in the CPI to 2.5% annual growth in the middle of 1998, by 2003 it was 3
percentage points below its 1997 level. Nominal GDP fell by 4% between 1997 and 2002.
To add to the economic headwinds fomented by the consumption tax rise, 1997 coincided
with the expiration of temporary income tax cuts and the onset of the Asian Financial
Crisis. While very far from a causal relationship, as numerous other events were occurring
contemporaneously, both the 1989 and 1997 consumption tax raises were soon followed by
abrupt economic slowdowns.
The BoJ initiated the original near-ZIRP in February 1999, under the promise of maintaining it until deflationary concerns were dispelled. By 1999Q4, house and stock prices
neared their early 1980s levels. Although amid deflation, an effectively contractionary monetary policy,9 and governmental pressure, the BoJ abandoned the ZIRP in August 2000 by
8

A revision to the Labor Standard Law in 1998 is often cited as a key contributing factor in this change.
The revision increased the maximum length of fixed-term contracts from one to three, then eventually five
years.
9
Hetzel (1999) argues, “[t]he combination of zero, or negative, expected inflation with an equilibrium
real rate near zero means that even the low market rates currently observed in Japan are consistent with

6

raising its target rate to 25 basis points. This decision would come to be seen as a policy
mistake, with negative growth subsequently returning. Amid an economic slowdown and
continued deflation, the ZIRP was reinstated in March 2001, coupled with the promise of
being instituted until the inflation rate remains steadily above zero. In addition to returning to the ZIRP, the BoJ simultaneously instituted a two-fold “quantitative easing policy”:
first, it switched the policy target from short-term interest rates to the BoJ’s net current
account position; and second, it started a program of purchasing long-term government
bonds. The scope of these policies, along with the institution of further measures,10 continued to expand markedly through March 2003. Despite these efforts, economic growth
was muted and deflation remained present through the 2000s. Real GDP per capita rose
by only 2.1%, and the GDP deflator fell 10.4% between 2000-2009.

2.2

Data, Preliminary Results, and Some Stylized Facts

We now want to establish some stylized facts to inform the empirical analysis to be conducted later. We focus on the period shortly before the asset price run-up in the mid-1980s
through the Great Recession and its aftermath. To this end, we collect quarterly data
from 1985Q3 through 2013Q4, published by the Statistics Division of the Cabinet Office of
Japan and available via the Haver database. All quantity variables are normalized by total
population and are seasonally adjusted. We compute annualized growth rates as 400 times
the quarter-over-quarter log-difference. We follow Kiley (2010) and measure consumption
as nondurable goods and services. The series is converted into real values using the consumer price index (CPI) with 2010 as the base year. We compute the real interest rate
as the difference between a short-term nominal interest rate and a measure of expected
inflation. For the former, we choose the uncollateralized overnight call rate, which is the
BoJ’s policy rate. We measure it as the effective, end of period, annual rate. Expected
inflation is approximated by the annualized growth rate in the CPI between the subsequent
and the current quarters. Our maintained assumption is that the realized one-period-ahead
inflation rate is a good proxy for its one-step-ahead forecast. Similarly, current inflation
is computed as the annualized growth rate in the CPI between the current and previous
quarter. We use two measures of labor supply, namely total employment from the Japanese
Labor Force Survey, which captures the extensive margin of labor adjustment. Alternacontractionary monetary policy.”
10
In the fall of 2002, the BoJ began buying stocks from banks. Additionally, over the course of 2003, the
BoJ adds bank bills and commercial paper, along with asset-backed securities and commercial papers to its
portfolio. The goal of these policies was to remove risky assets from bank’s balance sheets.

7

tively, an intensive measure is given by aggregate weekly hours worked in nonagricultural
industries.
Figure 1 illustrates the primary relationship we investigate in our empirical exercise.
We plot the growth rate of nondurables consumption, ∆, against the nominal,  ,
and the real rate of interest,  , where each series is constructed as described above. The
graph conveys the impression that there are three distinct episodes of post-1985 Japanese
macroeconomic history. From the start of our sample through the rise and collapse of
Japanese asset prices and the accompanying recession up until the mid-1990s, consumption
growth is volatile, with highs of close to 15% almost matched by lows of close to -10%.
Over the course of this period the nominal rate declines from 8.5% in the early 1990s to
a level of just above zero in 1998. This trend behavior of the nominal rate is matched by
the real rate, although the latter appears more volatile.11 The policy rate hits zero in early
1999, which coincides with the second episode we can identify in Figure 1. From then on,
consumption growth is less volatile and remains at a lower level, as does the real rate of
interest. Since the nominal rate is at the zero lower bound, any movement in the real rate
is thus driven by changes in expected inflation in the way we constructed the real rate.
The picture changes again with the onset of the Great Recession when consumption and
real rate volatility rise again, whereas the nominal rate remains at zero. This sequence of
episodes indicates that the relationship between consumption growth and the real rate may
have undergone changes that are related to the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates.
This is one of the questions that we take up in our paper.
In order to establish a baseline for the changes in these relationships, we compute simple
correlations that are reported in Table 1. We split the sample in 1997Q2, which we visually
identify as a likely break date. Using more sophisticated statistical methods, we confirm
below that this date is, in fact, consistent with a break in the consumption series. Over
the full sample period, consumption and the real rate are positively correlated as measured
by a correlation coefficient of 0.39. This correlation declines between the two subsamples
from a value of 0.38 to 0.25. We provide further evidence of the changing nature of this
relationship in Figure 2, where we report five-year rolling window correlations between
consumption growth and the real rate. While the correlation is positive over the full sample
and the subsamples, the size of the correlation varies in line with the three episodes we
11

It is, of course, a central empirical question which direction the cause-and-effect relationship runs. Does
the policy rate follow the real rate down in the worldwide decline of interest rates? Or is policy such that
it is accommodative and working through an expected inflation channel. More discussion and some recent
evidence is provided by Laubach and Williams (2015) and Lubik and Matthes (2015a).

8

identified in the previous paragraph. The first period exhibits a correlation of around 0.35,
which at the onset of the zero interest rate policy rises to well above 0.5. The correlation
comes down sharply in 2008 when the rolling window starts to include data points from
the Great Recession. Throughout this period the correlation remains below 0.3 and is thus
lower than the correlation at the beginning of our sample.12
We also look at the behavior of measures of labor input over the sample period. As we
will show below, economic theory allows us to link the behavior of consumption growth and
the real rate to changes in employment via the intertemporal Euler-equation. Focusing only
on the consumption-real rate relationship may run danger to an omitted variable bias in
how consumption growth is determined. For a first assessment of the potential importance
of labor, we plot the growth rate of total employment, ∆ , our extensive margin, against
consumption growth and the real rate in Figure 3. Employment is noticeably less volatile
than the other two series. Moreover, the contemporaneous correlation coefficients in Table
1 suggest that employment growth is only weakly correlated with consumption, if at all,
and only mildly stronger with the real rate. Noticeably, the correlation is strongest in the
second half of the sample, albeit negative with respect to both consumption and the interest
rate. While the latter may not be surprising since higher rates tend to be contractionary
and thereby reduce employment, the former fact may be unexpected. We assess this finding
more formally when we estimate a theoretical relationship between these variables below.
Finally, Figure 4 depicts five-year rolling window correlations. The relationship between
consumption and employment does not appear to change as markedly as that with the real
rate. Toward the end of the sample, the relationship turns decidedly negative, while there
is a period in the mid-1990s whereby this relationship is noticeably positive.
In the next step, we assess the possibility of breaks in the time series of interest more
formally. Table 2 reports results from various structural break tests on the series for nondurable goods and services consumption, the real interest rate, and two labor market variables: total employment and average hours worked. Overall, the results confirm what the
more casual eyeballing tests above suggested. We find robust evidence of structural breaks
in all variables throughout the 1990s and around the time of the onset of the BoJ’s zero
interest rate policy. There are, however, some interesting differences among the series.
The tests clearly identify 1997Q2 as the break period in our consumption series. The
12

Lubik and Matthes (2015b) highlight the importance of modeling time variation explicitly in aggregate
time series. They advocate the use of time-varying parameter VARs with stochastic volatility to delineate
different sources of time variation and apparent breaks in data. Applying this methodology to our question
at hand goes beyond the scope of the paper but is a topic for future research.

9

date of this break aligns ominously with the April 1, 1997, increase in the consumption tax,
indicating the possibility that a policy change coincided with or induced the break. Turning
to the specific test results, the sequential Bai and Perron (2003) test for the number of
breaks in a series indicates a single break over the full sample period. The onset of the
Great Recession, on the other hand, seems not to line up with a break, as none of the
tests indicate a break around the 2007-2008 period.13 We take this as supportive of our
focus on changes in the policy environment, be it a shift in the BoJ’s policy stance or
changes in consumption-relevant tax rates as a driver of changes in the macroeconomic
environment. Continuing with the evidence for consumption, the Andrews (1993) test for a
single unknown breakpoint also picks 1997Q2. To assess the robustness of this finding, we
performed standard Chow-tests for a range of known break dates around this period. Again,
1997Q2 emerges as a break date. At the same time, there is some uncertainty over the exact
break date, as we can reject the null hypothesis of no break in the period 1996Q2-1997Q4
for typical significance levels.
This uncertainty over the break date is echoed in our results for the real interest rate.14
We find strong evidence for the existence of a single break in 1995Q2. As before, a simple
Chow test indicates that we can reject the null of no break for a wide range of break dates
around this time. We note that the second quarter of 1995 coincides with the date when the
call rate settled on 50 basis points for an extended period after coming down substantially in
the wake of the collapse of the asset price bubble. This date also coincides with the period
when the correlation between consumption growth and the real rate changes substantially.
A key hypothesis we investigate in our paper is whether the behavior of consumption
growth is partially explained by the behavior of employment due to nonseparabilities in
the utility function. We consider total employment as a measure of the extensive margin
of labor input and average hours worked for the intensive margin. While the Bai-Perron
test and the Andrews test for an unknown break both point toward 1992Q2 for the total
employment series, a break in average hours worked can be rejected.15 This suggests that the
13

We should note, however, that the length of the Great Recession subsample is short enough to raise
small-sample concerns for these break tests, especially since the onset of the Great Recession is close to the
15% trimming of the overall sample as recommended in the literature. Nevertheless, we will take a separate
look at the Great Recession period in our robustness section.
14
We choose to focus on the real rate since it is the key variable for understanding consumption growth.
Moreover, the fact that the nominal rate was subject to the zero lower bound can be considered as independent evidence of a break in the nominal rate as the economy changes its underlying dynamics in this case.
The question thus remains whether a commensurate break in the behavior of expected inflation offsets the
break in the nominal rate or not.
15
The Bai-Perron test finds evidence for one break in 1990Q1 that is just about significant at the 5% level
and close to the start-point of the 15% trimming range. Given the evidence from the other tests we discount

10

economic upheaval in the 1990s that culminated in the ZIRP and a lost decade started with
a structural break in the behavior of the extensive margin of employment. The obvious
corollary is that the Japanese model of lifetime employment suffered its demise with a
downward adjustment in employment growth.
We can now summarize our preliminary empirical findings as follows. We find substantial
evidence of a structural break in the behavior of several aggregate time series in the 1990s.
The behavior of employment, particularly along the extensive margin, changed in the early
1990s. Interestingly, this timing roughly coincides with the loosening of the “job for life”
model that is considered to have begun in the mid-1990s (see Fortin and Sicsic, 2009). This
was followed by a break in the behavior of the real rate around 1995 when the BoJ began a
policy of very low interest rates reaching zero in 1998. Lastly, the consumption growth series
experienced a structural break in 1997Q2. This date is ominous because of the change in the
consumption tax from 3% to 5% on April 1, 1997, which is widely credited as the starting
point for deflation in Japan and pushing the economy into a long recession. The next step
in our study is to analyze the behavior of consumption growth and its determinants in light
of the consumption Euler-equation.

3

A Consumption Euler-Equation: Theory and Empirics

The key theoretical building block for our analysis is the consumption Euler-equation that is
derived from a household’s utility-maximization problem. Assuming risk aversion, a household and its members desire to smooth consumption over time. This can be accomplished,
for instance, by holding and investing in interest-bearing assets, such as nominal bonds.
These assets deliver payoffs to sustain consumption when other sources of income decline;
they provide a vehicle for savings and transfer income over time when there is a temporary
windfall. The optimal intertemporal consumption choice depends on the effective real rate
of return of the asset portfolio. As is well known, the generic optimality condition for such
an optimization problem is:
 =  +1   +1

(3)

where  is the marginal utility of wealth,  is the (gross) nominal return, and   =  −1
is the (gross) inflation rate.  is an aggregate price index. 0    1 is the household’s
discount factor.
However, the marginal utility of wealth  is generally unobservable. In order to derive
this finding.

11

testable implications from this relationship, we need to link it to observable variables. Since
 is also the Lagrange-multiplier on the household’s budget constraint, we can connect it
to the marginal utility of consumption:  =   (·). Depending on the specification of
the utility function, namely its parametric form and the type of its arguments, we can then
estimate the resulting Euler-equation using limited-information methods. We follow Kiley
(2010) in choosing a broad set of specifications for the utility function.
Our first specification, which we use to establish a baseline for the parameter estimates,
allows for habit formation in consumption. We assume that a household’s utility depends
on current consumption as well as the previous period’s consumption level. Formally, we
can capture this by the utility function  (C ) =

C1−
1− ,

where C =  − −1 is effective

consumption under habit formation, and 0 ≤   1 is the habit parameter. Furthermore,
we allow for curvature in the utility function, where   0 is the intertemporal substitution

elasticity. Assuming that agents have external habits,16 that is, that they do not take into
account that today’s consumption choice affects tomorrow’s habit stock, the optimality
condition is:
 = ( − −1 )− 

(4)

Substituting into the generic Euler-equation and computing a log-linear approximation results in:

³
´
e+1 = ∆
e + 1 −  
e −  
 ∆
e+1 


(5)

We note that for  = 0, the expression reduces to the standard case without habits as in
equation (2). Habit formation simply redistributes the consumption adjustment mechanism
away from rapid interest rate movements toward slower intrinsic consumption movements.
Conditional on the current level of consumption, increases in the real rate imply higher
expected consumption growth. However, depending on the underlying factors, the relationship could turn on its head such that real rate increases are associated with lower expected
consumption growth, which in turn would require lower current consumption growth.
The second specification we consider allows for an additional variable in marginal utility,
namely labor input  . We assume the preference formulation,  (C  1 −  ) =

1−
1
(1−
1− C

 ), where C =  − −1 is effective consumption and (·) is utility derived from leisure
1 −  . This specification implies the Euler-equation:

16

³
´
e+1 = ∆
e +  1 −    ∆
e+1 + 1 −  
e −  
 ∆
e+1 
 1−


(6)

With internal habits, agents do internalize this feedback effect. This makes the analytics more cumbersome, since it introduces additional leads and lags in the consumption Euler-equation.

12

where  = −0 (·)(1 −  )(·)  0 is the labor supply elasticity and  is the steady-state

value of the labor input. When  = 0, the specification reduces to the non-habits case,
but it still allows for expected employment growth to enter the Euler-equation. We note
that this specification does not alter how current consumption growth and the real rate
affect expected consumption, that is, the respective coefficients on these terms remain the
same. In that sense, expected employment growth simply enters as an additional regressor.
However, the coefficients on these variables are connected via cross-coefficient restrictions
imposed by theory (and the specific form of the utility function). This specific functional
form allows us to separate identification of the parameters of interest. The habit parameter
 is identified off the first term in (6), while the substitution elasticity  can be identified
off the last term from the movements of the real rate. Given a calibrated level of long-run
employment, we can then identify the labor supply elasticity  from the movements of the
labor variable.
We estimate the Euler-equations detailed above using GMM. It is well known that a
GMM approach is quite sensitive to the instrument set being used and the method utilized to compute the weighting matrix in small samples, especially with respect to the
heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation (HAC) robust estimation of the variance-covariance
matrix. Moreover, we are mindful of weak instrument problems, which we address separately in our robustness section. In order to maintain consistency across the different
specifications, we use as our baseline method the Newey-West HAC estimator with fixed
bandwidth. The estimator is evaluated in a feasible manner by iterating to convergence.
Experimenting with different specifications, we found that this baseline method provided
overall quite satisfactory results. We will point out deviations from this baseline using
different methods where appropriate.17

4

Empirical Results

We present the key results in two steps. We first estimate a baseline specification that omits
the role of additional covariates in the Euler-equation. Based on the initial results, we then
augment this version by the inclusion of employment as prescribed in the previous section.
17

Hall (2005) has an extensive discussion of the care that needs to be taken when interpreting the results
from different empirical GMM methods when the underlying theoretical model is misspecified.

13

4.1

A Baseline Consumption Euler-Equation

We first estimate a specification that only includes habits in consumption, namely equation
(5), which establishes a baseline for the extended version of the Euler-equation. This is
a standard specification in the empirical consumption-based asset pricing literature and
in macroeconomic models, which has proved to deliver reasonable performance. The key
aspect is that habit formation introduces a lagged term in the estimating equation, which
is designed to capture the serial correlation in consumption growth data. We estimate two
structural parameters, the intertemporal substitution elasticity  and the habit parameter
. The results are reported in Table 3.
We first consider estimates from a baseline instrument set that includes the second
through fourth lags of nondurables and services expenditures growth, CPI inflation and the
overnight call rate. The results from the full sample estimation, from 1986Q4 - 2014Q4, are
representative of the literature and are in line with our prior expectations. The intertemporal substitution elasticity  is estimated at 1.44 with a standard error of 0.26, while the
estimate of the habit parameter  at 0.17 is not significantly different from zero. The Jstatistic for a test of the overidentifying restrictions indicates that the moment conditions
are valid at a p-value of 0.58, which is par for the course in consumption Euler-estimations.
Alternative empirical specifications, including more lags and alternative weighting matrix
estimators result in estimates of these parameters in the same ballpark. In particular, a
statistically significant substitution elasticity ranging between 1 and 2 and a small habit coefficient that is often not statistically distinguishable from zero. However, closer inspection
of the empirical results reveals what may have been apparent from the discussion of the raw
data above. The behavior of Japanese aggregate time series has changed in the mid-to-late
1990s as the BoJ entered its period of pursuing the ZIRP. When we plot the residuals from
the baseline consumption-Euler specification (see Figure 5) we note a sizeable drop in their
volatility around 1997 and an increase in volatility, albeit less pronounced, around 2007,
the start of the Great Recession. This clearly suggest that the baseline specification misses
out on key aspects of the data.
In the next step, we estimate the consumption Euler-equation over sub-periods. As
our analysis of the raw data has shown, a break in the real interest rate likely occurred
in 1995Q2. This coincided with the nominal rate reaching a level of 50 basis points for
an extended period, before being lowered further. At the same time, we also identified a
break in consumption growth in 1997Q2, the timing of which corresponded with a hike in
the consumption tax. Visual inspection of the graph of residuals in Figure 5 shows that
14

the break seems closer to the middle of 1997. Formally, we can assess whether the sample
period has experienced a structural break in terms of the consumption Euler-equation by
performing the Andrews-Fair Wald test for the null hypothesis of structural stability.18 The
sup Wald-statistic (not reported, but available on request) points toward a structural break
in 1996Q4 at a p-value of 0.42, whereby the p-value for 1997Q1 is 0.40. Given our evidence
from the raw data, we therefore decide to split the sample into two, starting the second
period from 1997Q1 onward.19
The results from the subsample estimation using the same instrument set as before are
reported in Table 3. In the first sample period, the substitution elasticity rises to 2, whereas
the habit parameter estimate is negative and insignificant.20 The p-value of this specification
is 0.65. The results for the second subsample are quite different, however. With a p-value
of 0.70,  now falls to a (still significant) 0.42, whereas the estimate of  is 0.52 with a
standard error of 0.12. We obtain the same pattern for all empirical specifications and
weighting matrix choices. Specifically, the full sample parameter values are an “average” of
the subsample estimates, whereby Japanese consumers became less risk averse but allowed
for more habits in consumption at the turn of the ZIRP period.
We can also interpret these findings in terms of the properties of the data. As the Eulerequation (5) indicates, the introduction of habits adds lagged consumption growth to the
specification. The habit parameter  is therefore identified from the degree of persistence
in consumption. In the first subsample, this parameter is indistinguishable from zero, while
in the second sample period it rises to around 0.5. In other words, the ZIRP and the
consumption tax hike made consumption growth more persistent when compared to the
preceding period.21 The substitution elasticity  is then identified from the responsiveness
of consumption growth to real rate movements given . The elasticity (1 − ) in the first
18
We include the Great Recession period as part of the second sample since the zero-lower-bound issue was
present during that time span as well. Moreover, the shorter sample period for this episode raises concerns
about the power of these tests.
19
Following the recommendation of Hall and Sen (1999) to identify the source of instability we also perform
their O-test. Since the Wald test indicates structural instability, this can stem from parameter instability
or instability in the instrument set. We find that the O-test statistic is highly insignificant with values at
0.99 for a wide range of possible break dates. This suggests a broader source of instability than just changes
in the parameters. One likely candidate is explicit stochastic volatility, which also seems indicated by the
behavior of the residuals in the baseline regression. However, analyzing this aspect further goes beyond the
scope of our paper.
20
The results remain the same when we fix  = 0 for this period.
21
There is a potential fallacy here in that it is well known that it is difficult to disentangle intrinsic (via
habits) from extrinsic (via exogenous shocks) sources of persistence in rational expectations models (see
Nason and Smith, 2008, for further discussion and examples). That is, the source of increased persistence
in consumption growth is not an increase in habit formation but via a more persistent real rate. The use of
a structural model and the embedded cross-coefficient restrictions only guards partially against this.

15

period is 0.55, then rises to 1.15 in the ZIRP period. Less volatile real rate movements —
which stem almost exclusively from changes in expected inflation — now have a larger effect
on consumption growth.
The findings from the baseline structural estimation therefore lend support to the view
that the rise in the consumption tax rate changed the nature of Japanese consumer behavior,
in that both attitudes toward risk and assessment of relative consumption choices were
affected. An alternative interpretation, however, is that the baseline model is misspecified
due to the omission of an explanatory variable. That is, what appears as a structural break
in the estimating equation simply reflects the changing nature of an omitted variable. We
now assess this hypothesis by turning to an alternative specification of the consumption
Euler-equation.

4.2

An Euler-Equation with Employment

Intertemporal consumer choice implies that the change in the marginal utility of consumption is driven by the real interest rate. In the simple model, where utility depends on consumption only, this translates into a direct relationship between consumption growth and
the real rate. However, the macroeconomic literature abounds with alternative specifications for consumer utility that allow for additional arguments interacting with consumption
choice. The margin we consider is the labor-leisure trade-off as derived in Section 3. We
therefore estimate equation (6) with GMM as an alternative to the benchmark specification.
This leaves us with an additional parameter to estimate, namely the labor supply elasticity
 ≥ 0. Moreover, the derivation of equation (6) shows that the coefficient on expected em-

ployment growth also depends on the steady-state value of employment. We set  = 23
in all of our estimation exercises based on the sample mean in the total employment series
when normalized by population. One aspect of the exercise that we focus on is to what
extent the additional variable can capture the unexplained residuality in the baseline, and
more specifically, whether there are still apparent breaks in the residual series. In this section, we use total employment, that is, the extensive margin of labor adjustment, as our
observable variable for labor input. We present results for the intensive margin, namely
hours worked, as a robustness check in the following section. The estimation results are
reported in Table 3.
The estimates of the structural parameters go qualitatively in the same direction as those
for the specification with only habits. For the full sample period from 1986Q4 - 2014Q4,
the substitution elasticity  = 090, which is halfway between the two subsample estimates

16

of 171 and 035. We also note that the subsample estimates are very close to those of the
habits-only specification, whereas the full sample estimates differ significantly. The habit
parameter  rises from zero to 0.53 over the subsample, which is the same estimate as in
the baseline. Interestingly, the full sample estimate is  = 053 and therefore identical to
the second subsample estimate, albeit with a higher standard error. These results confirm
our previous findings: the tax hike apparently instigated a break in household preferences.
As in the benchmark specification, a higher degree of habit formation may pick up stronger
serial correlation in consumption growth.
The specification with employment allows us to estimate the aggregate labor supply
elasticity  in addition to the other preference parameters. For the full sample, we find
that  = −031 (with a standard error of 024), which is an inadmissible value given the
specification of utility. However, the P-value of this specification is considerably higher than

that of the baseline specification, which suggests that the estimation algorithm attempts
to compensate for underlying behavior in the time series that a theoretically consistent
specification over the full sample cannot fully accommodate. When we restrict estimates of 
to be non-negative, the estimated value is zero (reported in Table 3). For the two subsamples
the estimates of  are 081 and 011, respectively, whereby the latter is not statistically
significant at conventional values. Moreover, the p-values are essentially the same as in the
habits-only specification. When we look at the time series of the estimated residuals from
this specification (not reported, but available upon request), we find a more or less identical
pattern as in the benchmark. Prior to the break in 1997Q1, the residuals are considerably
more volatile than in the second half of the sample, but the overall degree of variation in
the residuals appears very similar to those in the benchmark without employment in the
regression.
Finally, we also perform structural break tests on the GMM estimating equation (results
not reported). The Hall-Sen test for structural instability finds strong evidence for overall
instability throughout the middle of the full sample period (which is the period we are
focusing on), similar to our benchmark findings. We also cannot reject the null hypothesis
of stability based on the Andrews-Fair Wald test. However, the highest p-value of 0.31 is
reached in 1996Q2, which is almost a year earlier than in the benchmark and not obviously
related to any policy decisions that may have led to this break. This finding could be
explained with reference to the breaks in the behavior of employment that we found in the
raw data. As Table 2 shows, there is a likely break in the employment series in 1992Q2.
Given the excess volatility of the residuals in the first half of the sample, the effects of a

17

break in one series may have taken time to affect other series as well. Incidentally, this break
date is also close to the break in the real rate series in 1995Q2. However, we are discounting
this finding to the extent that we have to restrict the estimate of the labor supply estimate in
order to get valid results. We therefore conclude that allowing for substitutability between
consumption and labor, as measured by total employment, is not necessary for capturing
consumption dynamics in Japan. The dominant factor appears to be the break in the
consumption series.

5

Robustness and Further Empirical Results

We consider a few additional empirical exercises to further substantiate our findings for the
benchmark specification. First, we re-estimate the Euler-equation with labor input using
data on hours worked to assess whether changes in the behavior of the intensive margin are
important. Second, we look at the issue of the robustness of the estimates given that GMM
often has to contend with problems of weak or invalid instruments. In the third exercise,
we consider the behavior of our variables of interest before and after the Great Recession
which arguably is another period of potential structural change.

5.1

The Intensive Margin of Labor Adjustment

The specification of the Euler-equation (6) includes a term for labor input but is in principle
silent on what the variable  measures. In the benchmark, we used total employment as the
observable series. An arguably more relevant series is the number of hours worked, which
is a broader measure of labor input since it also captures the intensive margin. In order
to assess the robustness of our benchmark results, we therefore redo the previous analysis
with this alternative labor supply measure. The standard break tests conducted on the raw
data in Table 2 suggest that we can date one structural break in 1990Q1. However, the
evidence is less statistically robust than for the other series, especially since the break date
is close to the start of the effective sample period. In economic terms, it may very well
be that Japanese employers adapted to a break in total employment caused, for instance,
by changes in employment or retirement law, by adjusting on the intensive margin. As a
result, the path of overall labor input would remain largely unaffected.
When we reestimate the Euler-equation (6) with the alternative series we find that the
results hew closely to those for the benchmark (see Table 4). Overall, using hours worked
data results in a more elastic labor supply, presumably on account of higher variations in the
hours margin. As before, the second subsample implies a much higher estimate for the habit
18

parameter, which picks up the higher degree of serial correlation in consumption growth
following the sales-tax hike in early 1997. Moreover, the residuals from this regression
depict the same pattern as evident before. We therefore conclude that our initial findings
are robust to the use of alternative labor supply data, specifically with respect to the
importance of habit persistence after the tax hike and the relative unimportance of the
labor-leisure trade-off in explaining consumption growth.

5.2

Weak Instruments

A general concern in GMM estimation is that the instruments may be weak in the sense that
they are not correlated strongly enough with the endogenous variable or that the correlation
patterns among the instruments are such that the parameter estimates and their standard
errors are not reliable. In this case any hypothesis tests based on a specific instrument
should be regarded with caution. To assess this possibility for our benchmark specification
we therefore conduct two sets of weak instrument diagnostics. First, we perform the Cragg
and Donald (1993) test, which is the multivariate analog of a standard F-test.22 We perform
the test for our baseline instrument set, which includes lags of consumption growth, CPI
inflation, and the call rate, but also for variations of the instrument set in terms of additional
variables and combinations of various lags. We apply this test for the models with habits
only and also for the extended specification using employment data. We find across the
board that we cannot reject the null hypothesis of the presence of weak instruments. The
values of the test statistics never quite reach 2 in the full sample and in the subsamples,
whereas the critical values from Stock and Yogo (2005) are around 10 for a significance level
of 10%. This leaves us with the impression that the results above need to be interpreted with
caution as they possibly reflect distortions to inference from weak instruments. However,
since the results of the various specification point in the same direction, these concerns
should also not be overinterpreted.

5.3

The Great Recession

In the final exercise, we look specifically at the behavior of aggregate consumption during
the Great Recession. A priori, we might expect that the onset of the Great Recession in
2008-2009 could possibly change the behavior of the consumption equation. This seems not
to be the case. When we estimate the Euler-equation in its various forms over the Great
Recession sample we do not find significant differences from the second subsample period
22
The Cragg-Donald test cannot be performed on a nonlinear equation. We therefore replace all composite
nonlinear parameters with new coefficients, following the same procedure as Kiley (2010).

19

estimates, which began in 1997Q2. This is also evident when we look at the pattern of
residuals in Figure 5, where the recession is noticeable but not to the same degree as in the
first subsample. More formally, we conduct our usual set of break tests, which find support
for a break in either 2009Q1 or 2009Q4 depending on the specific benchmark model, but
only at low levels of significance with p-values around 0.30. We can therefore conclude that
the findings from our benchmark specifications are robust.

6

Conclusion

We show in this paper that the behavior of aggregate consumption in Japan changed considerably in early 1997. Evidence from raw comovement patterns, structural break tests,
and more formal GMM-based estimation on structural Euler-equations for consumption
growth indicates that the behavior of aggregate consumption suffered a break during that
time period. We can in principle correlate this finding with two dramatic policy actions.
First, the BoJ implemented a highly accommodative low-interest policy in mid-to-late 1995,
which was accompanied by deflation and a strong appreciation of the yen. In fact, the data
show a break in the behavior of the real rate of interest during that period. Second, an illtimed move by the Japanese government to raise consumption taxes in April 1997 resulted
in an anticipatory spike in consumption. This was followed by a sharp drop in economic
activity and protracted stagnation. This date directly coincides with a break in the consumption series. We argue that the results in our paper show fairly conclusively that the
tax change led to a break in the aggregate consumption series to the effect that it became
more serially correlated afterward. This can be explained in terms of a simple consumptionchoice model whereby Japanese households formed stronger habit preferences toward their
purchases following the tax increase.
A byproduct of our analysis is to show that a consumption Euler-equation with habits in
preferences can fit the consumption behavior well in terms of its relationship with the real
rate of interest. Despite formal evidence of a break in the real rate series and the fact that
the BoJ’s monetary policy was subject to the zero lower bound - which could have arguably
interfered with the consumption-real rate relationship - we do not find any indication that
this is the case during the ZIRP from the late 1990s through the 2000s. Finally, we do
not find any evidence that the labor-leisure trade-off plays a significant role in explaining
consumption growth beyond the real-rate channel. Our results make arguably a strong case
that tax policy is at the core of the economic slump that Japan suffered in the 1990s and
further out. Yet, this insight is particularly timely because of the enactment of two recent
20

consumption tax rate increases: in April 2014 and 2017, the rate rose from 5% to 8% and
then 10%, respectively. The imposition of these additional tax hikes, upon the backdrop
of our results, argues for further investigation into the relationship between tax policy and
consumer behavior in the aggregate.
Our work can be extended in several additional directions. First, there are some remaining concerns as to the validity of the results because of the low power of structural break
tests and the presence of weak instruments. Second, the analysis should be broadened to
consider alternative specifications of the Euler-equation, especially in regards to preferences.
Third, and assuming that the results hold true, the analysis should be expanded to include
other intertemporal relationships such as asset pricing or investment equations. Lastly, this
analysis could also be utilized to inform models that explicitly model structural breaks as
an equilibrium phenomenon.

References
[1] Andrews, Donald W.K. (1993): “Tests for Parameter Instability and Structural Change
with Unknown Change Point”. Econometrica, 61, 821-856.
[2] Bai, Jushan, and Pierre Perron (2003): “Computation and Analysis of Multiple Structural Change Models”. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(1), 1-22.
[3] Cragg, John G., and Stephen G. Donald (1993): “Testing Identifiability and Specification in Instrumental Variable Models”. Econometric Theory, 9, 222—240.
[4] Fortin, Aurélien, and Michaël Sicsic (2009): “Japan’s changing labour market and how
its affecting its growth models ”. Trésor-Economics, 65, 1—8.
[5] Hall, Alastair R. (2005): Generalized Method of Moments. Oxford University Press.
Oxford.
[6] Hall, Alastair R. and Amit Sen (1999): “Structural Stability Testing in Models Estimated by Generalized Methods of Moments”. Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics, 17, 335-348.
[7] Hetzel, Robert L. (1999): “Japanese Monetary Policy: A Quantity Theory Perspective”. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 85(1), 1-25.
[8] Ito, Takatoshi and Frederic S. Mishkin (2004): “Two Decades of Japanese Monetary
Policy and the Deflation Problem ”. NBER Working Paper, 10878.
21

[9] Kiley, Michael T. (2010): “Habit Persistence, Nonseparability between Consumption
and Leisure, or Rule-of-Thumb Consumers: Which Accounts for the Predictability of
Consumption Growth?” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(3), 679-683.
[10] Laubach, Thomas, and John C. Williams (2015): “Measuring the Natural Rate of
Interest Redux”. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2015-16.
[11] Lubik, Thomas A., and Christian Matthes (2015a): “Calculating the Natural Rate
of Interest: A Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches”. Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Brief, 15-10.
[12] Lubik, Thomas A., and Christian Matthes (2015b): “Time-Varying Parameter Vector
Autoregressions: Specification, Estimation, and an Application”. Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 101(4), 323-352.
[13] Nason, James M. and Gregor W. Smith (2008): “The Phillips Curve: Lessons from
Single-Equation Estimation”. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
94, 361-395.
[14] Ono, Hiroshi, and Marcus E. Rebick (2003): “Constraints on the Level of Efficient Use
of Labor in Japan ”. NBER Working Paper, 9484.
[15] Stock, James, and Motohiro Yogo (2005): “Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV
Regression”. In: James Stock and D.W.K. Andrews (Eds.): Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas J. Rothenberg. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, MA.

22

Table 1: Sample Correlations
Correlation Coefficients: 1985Q3 - 1997Q1

Consumption
Employment
Real Rate

Consumption
-0.03
0.38

Employment
-0.03
0.08

Real Rate
0.38
0.08
-

Correlation Coefficients: 1997Q2 - 2013Q4

Consumption
Employment
Real Rate

Consumption
-0.14
0.25

Employment
-0.14
-0.165

Real Rate
0.25
-0.165
-

Correlation Coefficients: 1985Q3 - 2013Q4

Consumption
Employment
Real Rate

Consumption
-0.04
0.39

Employment
-0.04
-0.26

Real Rate
0.39
-0.26
-

Notes: We report contemporaneous sample correlations for the 1985Q3 2013Q4 period and two subsamples. Consumption is measured as the growth
rate of nondurables goods and services per capita; the real rate is measured
as the overnight call rate less the one-step-ahead CPI inflation rate.

23

Table 2: Structural Break Tests
Break Tests
Date

Consumption

Real Rate

Employment

Hours

1997Q2

1995Q2

1992Q2

1990Q1

16.95*
5.19

68.37**
0.74

57.72**
5.19

8.87*
0.48

7.78 (0.07)
2.32 (0.04)
3.94 (0.02)

124.10 (0.00)
58.15 (0.00)
48.89 (0.00)

41.24 (0.00)
16.98 (0.00)
16.35 (0.00)

2.03 (0.78)
0.31 (0.63)
0.55 (0.60)

41.24 (0.00)

2.03 (0.16)

Bai-Perron
0 vs. 1 break
1 vs. 2 break
Andrews
Max LR
Exp LR
Ave LR
Chow
7.78 (0.01)

Notes: We report structural break tests for the sample period 1985Q3-2014Q1. For unknown break dates, we trim
the data equally by 15%. The effective sample period is thus 1990Q1-2009Q4. Consumption is measured as the
growth rate of nondurables goods and services per capita; the real rate is measured as the overnight call rate less the
one-step-ahead CPI inflation rate; employment and hours worked are in growth rates. The table reports F-Statistics
and, where appropriate, p-values. Bai and Perron (2003) sequentially tests the null hypothesis of L against L+1
breaks. We choose Lmax =5, and trim the sample by 15%. The 5% critical value is 8.58. Andrews (1993) tests the
null hypothesis of no break against the general alternative. We report several versions of the likelihood-ratio test.
The Chow-test tests the null hypothesis of no break at a given date.

24

Table 3: GMM Estimation: Benchmark
Habit Specification

Full Sample

J-Stat
9.46

P-Value
0.58


1.44

S.E.
0.26


0.17

S.E.
0.16

8.65

0.65

2.00

0.43

0.00

0.11

8.20

0.70

0.42

0.17

0.52

0.12

1986Q4-2014Q4

Sub-Sample 1
1986Q4-1997Q1

Sub-Sample 2
1997Q2-2014Q4

Habits & Labor Specification

Full Sample

J-Stat
6.80

P-Value
0.74


0.90

S.E.
0.33


0.53

S.E.
0.22


0.00

S.E.
0.24

7.44

0.68

1.71

0.36

0.00

0.10

0.81

0.41

7.15

0.71

0.35

0.13

0.53

0.12

0.11

0.13

1986Q4-2014Q4

Sub-Sample 1
1986Q4-1997Q1

Sub-Sample 2
1997Q2-2014Q4

Table 4: GMM Estimation: Robustness
Alternative Labor Data: Hours Worked

Full Sample

J-Stat
2.41

P-Value
0.99


0.99

S.E.
0.15


0.61

S.E.
0.07


0.00

S.E.
0.06

8.91

0.54

1.65

0.35

0.00

0.14

0.31

0.17

4.41

0.93

0.49

0.38

0.62

0.22

0.90

0.06

1986Q4-2014Q4

Sub-Sample 1
1986Q4-1997Q1

Sub-Sample 2
1997Q2-2014Q4

25

Consumption Growth and Interest Rates
1985.Q3 ‐ 2013.Q4
15%

10%

5%

0%
1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

‐5%

‐10%
Growth Rate of Non‐Durables & Services Consumption (SAAR)

Real Interest Rate

Nominal Interest Rate

Figure 1: Consumption Growth and Interest Rates

Consumption Growth and Real Interest Rate: Five‐Year Rolling Correlation
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
‐0.10

1990

1995

2000
2005
Consumption Growth & Real Interest Rate Five‐Year Rolling Correlation

Figure 2: 5-Year Rolling Window Correlations

26

2010

Consumption Growth, Employment Rate Change and the Real Interest Rate
15%

10%

5%

0%
1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

‐5%

‐10%
Growth Rate of Non‐Durables & Services Consumption (SAAR)

Real Interest Rate

Growth of Employment Rate (SAAR)

Figure 3: Employment and Consumption Growth

Employment Growth, Consumption Growth and Real Interest Rate Five‐Year: Rolling Correlations
0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

‐0.20
‐0.40
‐0.60
Emp. Rate Change & Consumption Growth

Consumption Growth & Real Interest Rate

Figure 4: 5-Year Rolling Window Correlations

27

Emp. Rate Change & Real Interest Rate

Figure 5: GMM Residuals: Baseline Specification

28