View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Misallocation and Credit Market
Constraints: the Role of Long-Term
Financing

WP 19-01

Marios Karabarbounis
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Patrick Macnamara
University of Manchester

Misallocation and Credit Market Constraints:
the Role of Long-Term Financing∗
Marios Karabarbounis
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Patrick Macnamara
University of Manchester

January 2019
Working Paper No. 19-01
Abstract
We measure aggregate productivity loss due to credit market constraints in a model with
endogenous borrowing constraints, long-duration bonds, and costly equity payouts. Due to
long-duration bonds, the model generates a realistic distribution of credit spreads. We structurally estimate our model using firm-level data on credit spreads from Thomson Reuters
Bond Security Data and balance sheet data from Compustat. Credit market constraints increase aggregate productivity by 0.4% through their effect on the credit spread distribution.
However, credit market constraints also interact with costly equity payouts, resulting in an
overall productivity loss equal to 1.6%.

Keywords: misallocation, endogenous borrowing constraints, long-duration bonds
JEL Classification Numbers: E23, E44, G32, O47

∗

Emails:
Marios Karabarbounis:
marios.karabarbounis@rich.frb.org;
Patrick Macnamara:
patrick.macnamara@manchester.ac.uk. For useful suggestions we thank Andrea Caggese, Huberto Ennis, Nobu Kiyotaki, Leonardo Melosi, Raffaele Rossi, Alex Wolman and seminar participants at Madrid
Macro Workshop 2017, SED 2017, Midwest Macro 2018, Manchester Economic Theory Workshop 2018.
The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.21144/wp19-01

1

Introduction

The basic idea behind the large literature on misallocation is that distortions at the firm
level show up as a reduction in total factor productivity (TFP) at the aggregate level. According to Restuccia and Rogerson (2013), one of the main approaches used in the literature
to measure misallocation is to pick one or more frictions thought to be important and then
build a dynamic model where these frictions are explicitly specified.1 If the model can be
disciplined with direct measures of the relevant frictions, this approach can yield convincing
estimates of the magnitude and sources of misallocation.
Credit market constraints are perhaps the single most studied channel generating misallocation of capital.2 The literature typically models credit market constraints using an
exogenous collateral constraint. With such a constraint, the underlying distortion manifests
itself through a shadow price (i.e., Lagrange multiplier), which has no direct empirical counterpart. Although it is possible to identify credit market constraints using broad statistics
related to financing (e.g., leverage), the resulting multipliers cannot be externally validated
in the data. Furthermore, the literature has typically abstracted from how credit market
constraints interact with other features in the economy. Credit market constraints may affect
misallocation not only by influencing borrowing costs, but also by altering the effect of other
frictions or technological constraints. Therefore, modeling firms’ investment decisions within
a realistic environment is crucial in order to identify the transmission mechanism of credit
market constraints on misallocation.
In this paper, we measure the misallocation of capital using a model where credit market
constraints can be directly disciplined using micro data and at the same time propagate or
mitigate other existing frictions or technological constraints. There are three distinct features
in our model. First, firms issue bonds balancing the tax advantage of debt with bankruptcy
costs in case of default (Hennessy and Whited, 2007; Gourio, 2013). Lenders charge a credit
spread to firms that have a higher probability of default. As a result, firms are endogenously
constrained due to their inability to attract funds at a relatively low cost. Second, firms issue
long-duration bonds (Hatchondo and Martinez, 2009; Chatterjee and Eyigungor, 2012). With
long-term financing, lenders take into account the whole sequence of default probabilities
until the bond matures. The combination of endogenous borrowing constraints and longduration bonds allows us to generate a realistic distribution of credit spreads. Third, firms
1
Restuccia and Rogerson (2013) call this the direct approach to measure misallocation. Examples of this
approach include Restuccia and Rogerson (2008), Guner, Ventura, and Xu (2008), Caggese and Cuñat (2013),
Khan and Thomas (2013), Midrigan and Xu (2014), Moll (2014), and Gourio and Roys (2014). On the other
hand, the indirect approach is to infer reduced-form wedges directly from static first-order conditions. Following this approach, Hsieh and Klenow (2009) find very large TFP differences between countries. Correcting for
additive measurement error, Bils, Klenow, and Ruane (2017) obtain smaller but still sizable TFP losses.
2
For example, see Khan and Thomas (2013), Midrigan and Xu (2014), and Moll (2014).

2

face capital adjustment costs and costly equity payouts (Hennessy and Whited, 2007; Jermann
and Quadrini, 2012). The four model elements (credit market constraints, capital adjustment
costs, equity payout costs, and taxes) introduce a wedge between the firm’s expected marginal
product of capital and the user cost of capital.3
The key advantage of our approach is that we can directly map the wedge to statistics we
can measure in the data. For example, credit market constraints can be directly disciplined
based on credit spreads. We structurally estimate our model using the Simulated Method of
Moments (SMM). We obtain information on firm-level credit spreads from Thomson Reuters
Bond Security Master Data and combine it with income and balance sheet data from Compustat. To our knowledge, this is the first paper that reproduces firm-level patterns regarding
credit spreads, investment rates, and leverage using a structural estimation.4
Credit market constraints have two effects in our model. First, they affect the distribution
of credit spreads, and this generates variation in the wedge across firms. We call this the
direct effect of credit market constraints on misallocation. Second, by affecting investment
rates and dividend issuance, credit market constraints also influence the effect that capital
adjustment costs, costly equity payouts, and taxes have on aggregate TFP. We call this the
indirect effect of credit market constraints on misallocation.
We find a new and surprising result. The direct effect of credit market constraints increases
aggregate TFP by 0.4%. Credit market constraints generate dispersion in credit spreads. If
we did not have any other frictions or technological constraints, this would lead to TFP loss,
similar to the findings in the literature (e.g., see Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajšek, 2013). However,
consistent with the data, the model generates a negative covariance between credit spreads
and firm-level productivity. In contrast, capital adjustment costs, equity payout costs, and
taxes collectively have a relatively larger effect on high-productivity firms. As a result, credit
market constraints (through credit spread variation) also tend to offset the productivity losses
induced by the existing model environment.
Our second result is that the indirect effect of credit market constraints decreases aggregate TFP by 2.0%. Nevertheless, individual frictions or technological constraints respond
differently to the introduction of credit market constraints. First, credit market constraints
decrease the dispersion in investment rates across firms. As a result, there is less dispersion in
3
The reason we use expected and not realized marginal product of capital is that in our model firms choose
capital one period in advance. As a result, the marginal product of capital could differ substantially across
firms due to the ex-post realization of productivity (e.g., see Asker, Collard-Wexler, and De Loecker, 2014).
We do not view such variation as interesting since it does not arise from an underlying distortion and it does
not interact with credit market constraints.
4
Bai, Lu, and Tian (2018) estimate a model of firm financing using balance sheet data from Chinese
firms. The authors calculate a firm-specific interest rate as the ratio of total interest payments to total debt.
In general, interest expenses reflect the accumulation of multiple bond issuances over the previous years. In
contrast, we use the credit spreads of current bond issuances that are more informative about financial distress.

3

the portion of the wedge that can be attributed to capital adjustment costs. The interaction
of credit market constraints with capital adjustment costs increases aggregate TFP by 0.6%.
Second, credit market constraints inhibit firms from smoothing dividend issuance across time.
As a result, there is more dispersion in the portion of the wedge that can be attributed to
equity payout costs. The interaction between credit market constraints and equity payout
costs decreases aggregate TFP by 2.0%. Finally, the interaction of credit market constraints
with taxes also decreases aggregate TFP by 0.6%.
The overall (direct and indirect) effect of credit market constraints is to decrease aggregate
TFP by 1.6%. The effect on aggregate TFP is small because credit market constraints affect
the wedge in multiple, and at times contradictory, ways. The transmission mechanism of
credit market constraints on misallocation occurs through the indirect effect, a point missed
by models where credit market constraints are analyzed in isolation.
Our exercise offers two lessons for policymakers. First, any policy that targets misallocation
by affecting the distribution of credit spreads needs to take into account not only the dispersion
of credit spreads, but also which types of firms have lower borrowing costs. Second, an effective
way to insulate the economy from a financial shock is to create an environment with low taxes
and where firms can adjust intertemporally dividend payouts without substantial cost. We
do not explicitly evaluate such policies but simply highlight the mechanisms that are relevant
for policy design.
Our paper differentiates itself from the large literature analyzing credit market constraints
and misallocation. Midrigan and Xu (2014) and Moll (2014) analyze misallocation in a model
with an exogenous collateral constraint. Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajšek (2013) discipline a
static model to the observed distribution of credit spreads and find modest TFP losses from
misallocation. We analyze misallocation in a dynamic model with endogenous borrowing
constraints, long-duration bonds, capital adjustment costs, and costly equity payouts. As a
result, our model has two contributions. First, credit market constraints show up through
credit spreads that can be externally validated in the data. Second, credit market constraints
affect misallocation through credit spread variation, but also through their interaction with
other frictions or technological constraints. While the overall effect of credit market constraints
is modest (as in the literature), we identify a new transmission mechanism through the indirect
effect.
We are not the first to study the effect of credit market constraints within a rich model
environment. Khan and Thomas (2013) model collateral constraints and capital adjustment
costs jointly. In their paper, capital adjustment costs propagate financial shocks in the economy and reduce aggregate TFP. In contrast, we find that credit market constraints mitigate
the TFP losses induced by capital adjustment costs. In Khan and Thomas (2013), the fi-

4

nancial shock generates misallocation by preventing young firms from quickly reaching their
optimal scale. In our model, we abstract from firm entry and exit due to the nature of our
data (large, publicly listed firms).
Our paper is also related to the growing literature on long-term financing. Our results
regarding the shape of bond-price schedules are based on Hatchondo and Martinez (2009) and
Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012), who were the first papers to introduce long-term borrowing
in a tractable model of sovereign default. We introduce long-term financing in a model with
endogenous investment, and we structurally estimate the model using firm-level data. A paper
closer to ours is Gordon and Guerron-Quintana (2018), who introduce capital in a sovereign
default model with long-duration bonds and calibrate the model to cross-country moments.
Gomes, Jermann, and Schmid (2016) focus on the role of monetary policy and inflation in a
model with long-duration bonds and endogenous investment. Their model emphasizes the role
of debt overhang due to long-duration bonds, while our model emphasizes the implications
of long-duration bonds for credit spread variation, and thus misallocation. Finally, Crouzet
(2017) and Sánchez, Sapriza, and Yurdagul (2018) use models with an endogenous maturity
choice. In our paper, bonds mature probabilistically, which makes our model tractable enough
to estimate using SMM.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 characterizes
the model and analyzes how the wedge affects the firms’ investment decisions. Section 4
describes the empirical analysis, and Section 5 describes the structural estimation exercise.
Section 6 reports the main results regarding misallocation. Section 7 explores how each of the
key features of our model contribute to our main findings. Finally, Section 8 concludes.

2

Model

Our model combines the firm financing structure of Hennessy and Whited (2007) with
long-duration bonds (Hatchondo and Martinez, 2009; Chatterjee and Eyigungor, 2012). Firms
borrow for two reasons. First, internal funds may be insufficient to reach the desired level
of investment. Second, there is a tax benefit associated with debt that encourages all firms
(even those that are unconstrained) to seek debt financing. On the other hand, firms face an
endogenous limit on the amount they can borrow. The main friction that generates endogenous
borrowing constraints is limited commitment. In particular, firms cannot commit to repaying
their debt in the future, nor can they commit to future actions (such as the issuance of new
debt), which also increase the probability of default. And since defaults incur deadweight
losses, firms with less-healthy balance sheets face stricter borrowing limits.

5

2.1

Technology and Productivity

Firms are perfectly competitive and produce a single homogeneous good. The firm’s proγ
duction function is f (z, k, n) = z [k α n1−α ] , where z is total factor productivity, k is the capital
input, and n is the labor input. The production function exhibits decreasing returns to scale
(i.e., we assume γ ∈ (0, 1)). According to the “span of control” models of Lucas (1978) and
Rosen (1982), diminishing returns to scale can be interpreted as a consequence of the diminishing returns to entrepreneurs in managing larger operations. Firms hire labor in a perfectly
competitive labor market, so that profits are given by π(z, k) = maxn {f (z, k, n) − wn}, where
w is the wage.
Idiosyncratic productivity z follows an AR(1) process:
ln z 0 = ρz ln z + ε
2
). We denote by H(z 0 |z) and h(z 0 |z) the cumulawhere ε is an i.i.d. shock drawn from N (0, σεz
tive distribution and probability density functions, respectively, for next period’s productivity
z 0 , conditional on the current productivity z.
The realization of next period’s productivity z 0 is not known when the investment decision
takes place. Therefore, our model departs from Buera and Shin (2011), Moll (2014), and
Midrigan and Xu (2014) where firms rent current capital after observing the realization of
current productivity.

2.2

Long-Duration Bonds

In our model, a firm issues debt for two reasons. First, internal funds may be insufficient to
reach the desired level of investment. Second, debt payments reduce a firm’s taxable income,
which generates an additional incentive for firms to borrow, even if they have sufficient internal
funds. As we discuss later, the firm has the option to default on its debt payments. In the
case of default, there are deadweight losses that are reflected in the firm’s borrowing costs.
Following Hatchondo and Martinez (2009) and Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012), we assume that a constant fraction θ of all bonds will mature each period. This implies that
tomorrow’s stock of bonds b0 must satisfy
b0 = (1 − θ)b + ib
where b is today’s stock of bonds and ib is the number of bonds issued today. Bonds are
assumed to be infinitesimally small. Therefore, while bonds mature probabilistically, there is
no uncertainty about the number of bonds that will be outstanding next period.
6

Each bond will pay a coupon rate of c. For the θb bonds that mature, the firm pays back
the principal plus interest, so that the total payment today is (1 + c)θb. For the (1 − θ)b bonds
that do not mature, the firm only pays the coupon, so that the total payment today is c(1−θ)b.
In total, the firm will make a payment of (θ + c)b on both maturing and non-maturing bonds.
If the firm issues b0 − (1 − θ)b bonds today, it will receive q(z, k 0 , b0 ) [b0 − (1 − θ)b], where
q(z, k 0 , b0 ) is the bond price (in Section 2.7 we explain how the bond price is determined).
This price depends on today’s productivity z, capital k 0 , and the total number of bonds b0 .5
A larger amount of bonds b0 increases the probability of default, which is reflected in a higher
credit spread (i.e., a lower q(z, k 0 , b0 )). When θ < 1, firms have an incentive to dilute existing
debt. More debt issuance today lowers q(z, k 0 , b0 ) and reduces the value of outstanding bonds
(i.e., q(1 − θ)b). In Section 3.1, we discuss in more detail the incentives of firms to issue debt.
Our model does not allow for an endogenous maturity choice. The maturity parameter, θ,
is fixed and firms do not have the ability to issue short-term debt. While this assumption is
restrictive, it makes our model tractable enough to structurally estimate based on micro-level
data. Nevertheless, long-duration bonds are actually preferable to short-duration bonds in
Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012) when their baseline model is extended to allow for a small
probability of a rollover crisis.
For convenience, we assume that bonds issued in different periods are of equal seniority.
We also assume that lenders impose no debt covenant restrictions. In principle, lenders could
impose restrictions on firms regarding future debt issuance or the payment of dividends to
shareholders.6 Our model does put restrictions on capital investment and equity payouts (see
the next two sections) but these are not explicitly related to b0 .

2.3

Capital Adjustment Costs

According to Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006), there are large periods of investment inaction
at the plant level, which are complemented by periods of intensive adjustment of the capital
stock. Moreover, during periods of adjustment, investment does not appear to be excessively
volatile but relatively smooth. There are two standard assumptions that together can generate
such investment patterns. First, there is a fixed cost to undertake investment, and second,
investment is associated with quadratic adjustment costs.
Intuitively, investors are more reluctant to buy long-duration bonds if firms’ investment is
too volatile. As a result, we focus only on the second type of costs, which seem more relevant
5
Since the default decision depends on the total number of outstanding bonds tomorrow, b0 , q(z, k 0 , b0 )
depends on b0 rather than the amount of debt issued today (i.e., b0 − (1 − θ)b).
6
Debt covenant restrictions are relatively uncommon in the investment grade bond market. For example,
in Reisel (2014), only 5.92% of investment-grade bonds include restrictions on the additional payouts and
additional debt (see Table 4 in their paper).

7

for our model. In particular, we assume that capital investment is subject to adjustment costs
g(k, k 0 ), which take the following form:


0

g(k, k ) = φk

k 0 − (1 − δ)k
k

2
k.

The parameter φk controls the cost of adjusting investment each period. Adjustment costs
are symmetric to positive or negative investment adjustments.

2.4

Equity Payout Costs

Each period, firms choose the level of dividends d. To control the substitution between
debt and equity, we assume that shareholders incur a cost whenever the firm issues dividends
(i.e., d > 0). Our modeling assumption for equity payout costs hinders an investment strategy
whereby firms sell all their capital and subsequently distribute large payouts to shareholders
shortly before defaulting. We view such sudden dividend payouts as unrealistic.
In principle, we could also assume that shareholders pay a cost when the firm is raising
external equity (i.e., d < 0). However, costs to distribute funds to shareholders in the future
are implicitly a cost to raise funds from shareholders today. Therefore, since equity payout
costs also affect equity issuance, we economize on parameters by modeling costs only when
d > 0.7
We summarize the costs paid by shareholders with the following function:
(
Λ(d) =

0
Cd (d)

if d < 0
if d ≥ 0

Rd
where Cd (d) = 0 cd (x)dx is the total equity payout cost and cd (d) = 1 − exp(−φd d) is the
marginal equity payout cost. The parameter φd controls the speed to which marginal payout
costs increase with the level of dividends.
Equity payout costs are modeled, in a reduced-form way, to capture both pecuniary and
non-pecuniary costs. For example, they can be interpreted to include dividend taxes or costs
associated with share repurchases. But they can also capture the preferences of managers
to smooth dividends. Lintner (1956) documents the tendency of firms to smooth dividends.
While such smoothing behavior could arise from an agency friction, we do not model these
frictions directly. With a similar motivation, Hennessy and Whited (2007) assume a progressive dividend tax, while Jermann and Quadrini (2012) assume a quadratic equity payout
7
Indeed, when we explicitly added equity issuance costs, our results regarding leverage, credit spreads,
and misallocation did not change.

8

cost.

2.5

Taxes

We incorporate a realistic tax structure. Investors must pay a constant tax rate, τi , on
interest income. Meanwhile, firms pay a tax on their corporate income. The firm’s taxable
income, x, is assumed to be profits minus economic depreciation and interest expense:
x = π(z, k) − δk − cb
where δ is the depreciation rate of capital and cb is the interest expense. As in Hennessy and
Whited (2007), the corporate tax rate is assumed to be τc+ when taxable income is positive,
and τc− when taxable income is negative. Therefore, the firm’s total corporate tax bill is given
by
(
τc+ x if x ≥ 0
Tc (x) =
τc− x if x < 0.
In order to capture loss limitations in the U.S. corporate tax code, we will assume that
τc− < τc+ .

2.6

Value Functions and Default Decision

A firm that does not default today chooses dividends d, capital k 0 , and debt b0 according
to the following program:
V (z, k, b) = max
{d − Λ(d) + βE [max(V (z 0 , k 0 , b0 ), 0)|z]}
0 0
d,k ,b

(1)

subject to
d + k 0 = e(z, k, b) + q(z, k 0 , b0 ) [b0 − (1 − θ)b] − g(k, k 0 )
e(z, k, b) = π(z, k) − Tc [π(z, k) − δk − cb] + (1 − δ)k − (θ + c)b.

(2)
(3)

Today the firm’s shareholders receive dividends, d, minus the equity payout cost, Λ(d). Future
dividends are discounted with β = η/(1 + r(1 − τi )), where the parameter η ∈ (0, 1] reflects
the extra impatience of the firm. This parameter will help generate default in equilibrium.
Nevertheless, due to long-duration bonds, we can generate a realistic level of default without
resorting to unrealistically low values of η. The risk-free interest rate r is exogenous in our
analysis. We define internal equity, e(z, k, b), as the sum of after-tax profits and undepreciated
capital minus current payments to bondholders. According to the firm’s budget constraint,
9

the firm has access to three sources of funding for capital. First, the firm can issue new debt
(e.g., q(b0 − (1 − θ)b)). Second, the firm can utilize internal equity (e.g., e). Third, the firm
can resort to external equity (e.g., by choosing d < 0).
Next period, after the realization of z 0 , the firm chooses whether to default. If the firm
defaults, its continuation value is zero. However, defaulting firms go through bankruptcy
reorganization. In particular, lenders recover (a fraction of) the firm’s value as a compensation
for default. The firm continues operating with the same productivity z 0 and capital level k 0
as if there was no default. The only difference is that firms do not have any debt obligations
anymore (b0 = 0). Since z 0 and k 0 retain their values, there is no misallocation in our model
due to the extensive margin (entry and exit of firms).
We can define a threshold, zd0 (k 0 , b0 ), such that the firm will default next period only
for realizations of productivity z 0 < zd0 (k 0 , b0 ). This threshold is defined to be the value of
idiosyncratic productivity, zd0 , such that the firm is just indifferent between defaulting and not
defaulting:
V (zd0 (k 0 , b0 ), k 0 , b0 ) = 0.
The value of not defaulting (i.e., V (z 0 , k 0 , b0 )) may be strictly positive for any value of z 0 . In
this case, the firm will not default next period and the default threshold is zd0 = 0.

2.7

Determination of Bond Price

Bonds are purchased by risk-neutral lenders. In the case of default, the firm continues
operating but it goes through bankruptcy reorganization. This assumption reflects common
practices under bankruptcy laws in which the owners’ rights and interests are ended and the
company’s creditors are given ownership of the newly reorganized company.8
In default, lenders receive equity in the reorganized firm but pay a bankruptcy cost. If the
firm defaults tomorrow, lenders will recover (1 − ξ)V (z 0 , k 0 , 0), where ξ is the bankruptcy cost
parameter and V (z 0 , k 0 , 0) is the value of the firm with no debt. As a result, the price of the
bond, q(z, k 0 , b0 ), is set to guarantee lenders an expected pre-tax return equal to the risk-free
rate:

1  d
R (z, k 0 , b0 ) + Rnd (z, k 0 , b0 )
(4)
q(z, k 0 , b0 ) =
1+r

8
An alternative would be to follow Hennessy and Whited (2007) and assume that debt is renegotiated to
the point where the firm is just indifferent between defaulting and not defaulting. However, in our model with
long-duration bonds, this assumption would imply that the defaulting firm would renegotiate to a relatively
high level of debt. which it would immediately dilute by issuing even higher debt next period and then
defaulting again.

10

where
Z 0 0 0
1 zd (k ,b )
R (z, k , b ) ≡ 0
(1 − ξ)V (z 0 , k 0 , 0)h(z 0 |z)dz 0
b 0
Z ∞
nd
0 0
R (z, k , b ) ≡
[θ + c + (1 − θ)q(z 0 , k 0 (z 0 , k 0 , b0 ), b0 (z 0 , k 0 , b0 ))] h(z 0 |z)dz 0 .
d

0

0

zd0 (k0 ,b0 )

There are two components that determine the bond price. The first component, Rd (z, k 0 , b0 ),
reflects payments lenders will receive in default states (i.e., when z 0 < zd0 (k 0 , b0 )). In this case,
lenders receive equity in the reorganized firm and pay the bankruptcy cost. The second
component, Rnd (z, k 0 , b0 ), reflects payments lenders receive in non-default states (i.e., when
z 0 ≥ zd0 (k 0 , b0 )). In this case, lenders receive a payment (θ + c) on all maturing and nonmaturing bonds today. For the outstanding bonds that do not mature, the lender can expect
to receive more payments in the future. The value of these claims is (1 − θ)q(z 0 , k 00 , b00 ), where
q(z 0 , k 00 , b00 ) is the price of the unmatured bonds tomorrow. Notice that the price tomorrow
depends not only on the realized productivity tomorrow, z 0 , but also on k 00 = k 0 (z 0 , k 0 , b0 ) and
b00 = b0 (z 0 , k 0 , b0 ), which are the firm’s choices for capital and debt tomorrow.
In one-period bond models (i.e., θ = 1), the bond price depends only on the probability
the firm will default next period. The probability of defaulting in two periods or more has
no effect on today’s price. In contrast, in models with long-duration bonds, today’s price is
affected by the possibility of default in each future state of the world until the bond matures.
For example, if the firm is expected to issue a high level of debt next period (i.e., high b00 ), then
the probability of default after two periods increases and next period’s bond price q(z 0 , k 00 , b00 )
decreases. This will be reflected in the price of bonds today, q(z, k 0 , b0 ).
To make the above discussion more transparent, we plot in Figure 1 the cumulative probability of default over various horizons and the bond price. In our framework, we can distinguish
between the probability of default in the short-run (the next couple of periods, for example)
from the probability of default over a longer horizon (10 years ahead). We make this distinction by showing in the left panel of Figure 1 how the cumulative probability of default (after
one period, two periods, etc.) depends on today’s choice of b0 . The right panel of Figure 1
plots the bond price q as a function of b0 . Both figures have been plotted for a given z and k 0 .
In all horizons the default probability increases with a higher debt issuance b0 . A highly
indebted firm will have smaller value and hence will find default more attractive. What’s
noteworthy is how, as b0 increases, default over longer horizons becomes likely before default
over shorter horizons does. In Figure 1, if the firm issues very little b0 , then it is likely that
the firm will neither default over a long horizon (i.e., within 10 years) nor over a short horizon
(i.e., within three years). As b0 increases, it may then become likely that the firm will default

11

1

1

0.8

0.8

Bond Price

Default probability

Figure 1: Probability of Default by Horizon (Left Panel) and Bond Price Schedule (Right
Panel)

0.6
0.4
1 period
2 periods
3 periods
10 periods

0.2
0
0

50

0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0

100

b’

50

100

b’

Note: The left panel plots how the cumulative probability of default (for selected time horizons) depends on
today’s choice of b0 . The right panel plots the bond price, q, as a function of today’s b0 . Both figures have
been plotted for a given z and k 0 . Note that the model has been calibrated so that the risk-free price of the
bond is 1.

over a 10-year horizon, but is still unlikely to default within three years. As b0 increases even
more, the firm is certain to default within three years as well. The firm has to issue a large
amount of debt to make it likely that the firm will default next period.
The link between the cumulative probability of default and b0 explains the shape of the
bond price schedule. Even as b0 → 0, the bond price is strictly less than the risk-free bond
price (normalized to 1). Lenders fear that, over a long horizon, the firm might be in a position
to default on this debt. As b0 gradually increases – and as default on shorter horizons becomes
even more relevant – the bond price gradually decreases. The probability of default over longer
horizons (due to long-term financing) is key to generating a smoothly decreasing bond price
schedule. This will help us match the credit spread distribution. With one-period bonds,
the only relevant default probability is the default probability after one period. As a result,
firms can issue a relatively large amount of debt at the risk-free rate and the cross-sectional
distribution of credit spreads will be degenerate (at zero). We show this in Section 7.2.
Therefore, the main friction that limits the ability of firms to borrow is limited commitment. The firm cannot commit to repaying its debt tomorrow nor at any time in the future.
Furthermore, the firm cannot commit to not taking any actions regarding future choices of
(d, k 0 , b0 ), which may result in losses for current debtholders. Due to lack of commitment (and
also bankruptcy costs), bondholders demand a higher credit spread to supply funds to the

12

firm. As a result, the overall amount that firms are able to borrow is reduced.

3

Model Analysis

In this section, first, we analyze the optimal debt issuance policy with a particular focus
on the effect of long-duration bonds. Second, we analyze the optimal capital policy. In
the presence of frictions or technological constraints, the firm does not equate the expected
marginal product of capital with the user cost of capital. We show how each friction and
technological constraint contributes to a wedge in the firm’s optimality condition. Third, we
explain how we measure aggregate productivity and misallocation of capital across firms.

3.1

Optimal Financing Policy

We describe how the optimal choice for next period’s debt b0 is determined for a given
choice of next period’s capital k 0 . Optimizing Equation (1) with respect to b0 gives


∂q 0
[1 − Λ (d)] q + 0 [b − (1 − θ)b] = E [(1 − χ0 )(1 − Λ0 (d0 )) {θ + c + (1 − θ)q 0 − cτc0 }], (5)
{z
}
|
∂b
|
{z
}
MC
0

MB

where χ0 = 1 {z 0 < zd0 (k 0 , b0 )} is an indicator for whether the firm defaults tomorrow, q 0 is
tomorrow’s bond price, and τc0 is tomorrow’s marginal corporate income tax rate. The lefthand side of Equation (5) represents the marginal benefit of an additional unit of debt issuance,
holding fixed k 0 . If the firm issues one more unit of debt, it is able to increase dividends by
q + (∂q/∂b0 ) [b0 − (1 − θ)b]. The marginal value of these additional dividends depends on
whether the firm is issuing equity (d < 0) or issuing dividends (d > 0). If the firm is issuing
equity, then term Λ0 (d) is equal to zero. If the firm is issuing dividends, then term 1 − Λ0 (d)
is equal to 1 − cd (d). Therefore, equity payout costs reduce the marginal benefit of additional
debt issuance.
Looking at the left-hand side of Equation (5), we can see that existing debt b increases the
marginal benefit of debt issuance (since ∂q/∂b0 < 0). The firm benefits from issuing more debt
since additional debt issuance reduces the price the firm receives on debt issued today, but
not debt issued in previous periods. The more indebted a firm is (i.e., higher b), the stronger
is its incentive to issue more debt to dilute existing claims. This incentive to overborrow is
a notable feature of models with long-duration bonds. If θ = 1, then the current stock of
outstanding bonds does not affect the incentives to issue new debt.
The right-hand side of Equation (5) represents the marginal cost of servicing the additional
debt, holding fixed k 0 . Tomorrow, the firm will make an additional payment of (θ + c) on the
13

maturing and non-maturing debt. The firm will be obligated to make additional payments
in the future on the non-maturing debt. The marginal increase in these future payments is
captured by the (1 − θ)q 0 term. Moreover, since debt is tax deductible, debt issuance reduces
the corporate income tax paid by the firm. This provides an incentive for the firm to issue
more debt.

3.2

Optimal Investment Policy

Using the optimality condition for capital k 0 , we describe how various frictions/technological
constraints affect the first-best level of investment. Holding fixed the firm’s choice for b0 , the
first-order condition for k 0 is


∂π(z 0 , k 0 )
E
+ 1 − δ = W edge,
(6)
∂k 0
where


∂q 0
∂g(k, k 0 )
1 − Λ0 (d)
1 − 0 (b − (1 − θ)b) +
W edge ≡
β
∂k
∂k 0



∂π(z 0 , k 0 )
0 0
0
0 0
+1−δ
+ E {Λ (d ) + χ (1 − Λ (d ))}
∂k 0

 0

∂Tc ∂g(k 0 , k 00 )
0
0 0
+ E (1 − χ )(1 − Λ (d ))
+
.
∂k 0
∂k 0


(7)

According to Equation (6), firms invest until the expected marginal product of capital
(EMPK) plus 1 − δ is equal to the capital wedge, denoted by W edge.9 Our model economy
features four elements that affect aggregate productivity through the wedge: credit market
constraints (CMC), capital adjustment costs (CAC), equity payout costs (EPC), and taxes
(T). Without these features, W edge = 1+r and thus EMPK equals the user cost of capital (r+
δ). In this case, the EMPK is equated across firms. In our benchmark economy, however, each
of the four features generates variation in W edge across firms and thus generates dispersion
in the cross-sectional distribution of EMPK.
To understand the transmission mechanism of credit market constraints, we now define
four individual wedges that correspond to the four model elements in our economy. Each
individual wedge, W edgej , isolates the effect of feature j ∈ {CM C, CAC, EP C, T } in Equation (7).

9
In our model, credit market constraints generate a wedge in the first-order condition for capital. However,
in other classes of models, it is possible for borrowing constraints to generate a wedge in the first order condition
for labor (e.g., see Jermann and Quadrini, 2012).

14

Wedge due to Credit Market Constraints To isolate the effect of credit market constraints, we re-compute the wedge assuming that only credit market constraints are present.
As a result, we set g(k, k 0 ) = 0, Λ(d) = 0 and Tc (x) = 0 in Equation (7). This yields the
credit market constraints wedge:
W edgeCM C



  0

∂q(z, k 0 , b0 ) 0
∂π
1
0
1−
≡
(b − (1 − θ)b) + E χ
+1−δ .
β
∂k 0
∂k 0

(8)

The larger the variation in credit spreads and default probabilities across firms, the larger the
variation in the wedge due to credit market constraints. In our quantitative analysis, we discipline our model based on the empirical distribution of credit spreads and default probabilities.
This mapping of the wedge to direct empirical counterparts is a key part of our contribution.
Wedge due to Capital Adjustment Costs To isolate the effect of capital adjustment
costs, we assume ∂q/∂k 0 = 0, χ0 = 0, Λ(d) = 0 and Tc (x) = 0 in Equation (7). This yields the
capital adjustment cost wedge:
W edgeCAC


k 0 − (1 − δ)k
k
" 
 00
2
#
1 k 00 − (1 − δ)k 0
k − (1 − δ)k 0
− 2φk E
+ (1 − δ)
.
2
k0
k0

1 2φk
= +
β
β



(9)

The wedge depends on the investment rate [k 0 − (1 − δ)k]/k as well as the correlation between
investment rates across periods. The wedge is largest when high (low) investment rates in the
current period tend to be associated with low (high) investment rates in the future. In the
case of capital adjustment costs, the relevant empirical moments are the standard deviation
of investment rates and the autocorrelation of investment rates.
Although W edgeCAC is directly affected by capital adjustment costs (through the presence
of φk ) it is also indirectly affected by credit market constraints. Credit market constraints
change the firms’ investment rates and hence the cross-sectional distribution of [k 0 −(1−δ)k]/k.
As a result, credit market constraints affect misallocation of capital through the presence of
capital adjustment costs.
Wedge due to Equity Payout Costs
To isolate the effect of equity payout costs, we
assume that ∂q/∂k 0 = 0, χ0 = 0, g(k, k 0 ) = 0 and Tc (x) = 0 in Equation (7). This yields the
equity payout cost wedge:
W edgeEP C


 0

∂π
Λ0 (d)
1
0 0
+
1
−
δ
−
.
≡ + E Λ (d )
β
∂k 0
β
15

(10)

Equity payout costs affect the wedge through variation in dividend issuance across time.
Notice that the wedge is largest when dividend issuance today is low relative to tomorrow.
In contrast, if marginal equity payout costs are constant over time (i.e., Λ0 (d) = Λ0 (d0 ) =
constant), then the wedge disappears and equity payout costs would have no effect on misallocation.
Similar to the case of capital adjustment costs, W edgeEP C is also affected by the presence
of credit market constraints. In particular, credit market constraints affect the incentive of
firms to smooth dividends across time. A borrowing constrained firm would like to reduce
dividends d today and increase future dividends d0 . Without credit market constraints, firms
would be free to use debt to smooth dividend issuance. As a result, credit market constraints
have an effect on the firm’s EMPK through the presence of equity payout costs.
Wedge due to Taxes Finally, to isolate the effect of corporate income taxes, we assume
that ∂q/∂k 0 = 0, χ0 = 0, g(k, k 0 ) = 0 and Λ(d) = 0 in Equation (7). This yields the tax wedge:
 0
∂Tc
1
.
W edgeT ≡ + E
β
∂k 0

(11)

Variation in expected marginal tax rates across firms generates misallocation. Once more,
credit market constraints have an effect on W edgeT by affecting firms’ decisions and ultimately the distribution of marginal tax rates.
The distinction between the direct and indirect effects of credit market constraints is a key
part of our analysis. Credit market constraints have a direct effect on investment through the
credit market constraints wedge (i.e., W edgeCM C ). However, credit market constraints also
interact with the other three wedges (W edgeCAC , W edgeEP C , W edgeT ). Therefore, to study
the overall effect of credit market constraints, it is crucial to consider their effect jointly in a
realistic model environment.

3.3

Aggregate Productivity and the Wedge

We now show how the wedge is related to aggregate TFP. To do so, we first derive an
expression for TFP in our benchmark economy. Namely, we can derive the following aggregate
relationship (see Appendix A.3 for details):

γ
Y = A K α N 1−α

16

where Y is aggregate output, K is aggregate capital, N is aggregate labor, and A is TFP.
Credit market constraints can reduce output in two ways. First, they reduce the overall level
of K. Second, they increase misallocation of capital across firms, which results in a lower A.
To understand the second channel, we derive the following expression for TFP (again, see
Appendix A.3 for details):



E

P
 i
A=

1/(1−(1−α)γ)
|zi
zi0

( )

 ! 1−(1−α)γ
1−γ




(wik )αγ/(1−(1−α)γ)




E

P
 i

1/(1−(1−α)γ)
|zi
zi0

( )

1−(1−α)γ

 ! 1−(1−α)γ
1−γ

(12)

αγ



wik

where zi is the productivity of firm i and wik is the gross deviation of firm i’s expected marginal
product of capital (EMPK) from the economy-wide average. The firm-specific wedges (derived
in the previous section) thus affect TFP. To gauge the extent to which TFP is affected, we
first define a benchmark level of TFP. Specifically, we re-allocate capital and labor across firms
to maximize total output subject to the constraints that aggregate capital is equal to K and
aggregate labor is equal to N . In this case, EMPK is equated across all firms and wik = 1 for
all firms. Therefore, the benchmark level of TFP is
"
Ā =

X

h

E (zi0 )

1/(1−(1−α)γ)

zi

i 1−(1−α)γ
1−γ

#1−γ
.

i

TFP loss is the percentage difference between Ā and A:
TFP loss =

Ā
− 1.
A

(13)

Two important statistics that determine the TFP loss are the variance of the wedge
Var(wik ) and the covariance of the wedge with productivity Cov(wik , ln zi ). Namely, higher
cross-sectional dispersion in EMPK (i.e., higher Var(wik )) is associated with higher TFP
losses.10 While Var(wik ) is informative about the magnitude of TFP loss, Cov(wik , ln zi ) is
informative about the direction of TFP losses. When Cov(wik , ln zi ) > 0, high-productivity
firms are under-investing and have too little capital. TFP could be increased by transferring
resources to more productive units. In contrast, high-productivity firms have too much capital
if Cov(wik , ln zi ) < 0, and TFP would increase by allocating more resources to less-productive
10

If wik is log-normally distributed, TFP loss is directly proportional to Var(wik ).

17

units.
Finally, since in our model firms choose next period’s capital stock before they learn next
period’s productivity, it is possible for aggregate productivity to decrease due to firms underor over-investing prior to their productivity being realized. We do not view these losses to be
interesting, as they reflect underlying uncertainty over productivity (e.g., see Asker, CollardWexler, and De Loecker, 2014) and do not interact in any way with credit market constraints.
As a result, we net out such effects by considering TFP loss to be zero when the expected
MPK is equated across firms.

4

Empirical Analysis

In this section, we conduct our empirical analysis. First, we start with a description of our
data. Second, we report some summary statistics. Third, we analyze the relationship between
firm-level TFP and firm characteristics (such as credit spreads).

4.1

Description of Datasets

Our analysis is based on two firm-level datasets: Standard and Poor’s Compustat industrial
files and Thomson Reuters Bond Security Master Data (henceforth, TR). Compustat includes
detailed income statement, balance-sheet, and cash flow data of publicly listed companies. We
use annual fundamental data from 1984-2015. We impose selection criteria common in the
literature.11 First, we exclude financial firms (SIC 6000–6999) and utilities (SIC 4900–4999).
Second, we drop any firm-year observations without information on assets, capital stock, debt,
or equity. Third, we drop observations that violate the accounting identity of assets equal to
equity plus debt (normalized by assets) by more than 10%. Fourth, we drop firms affected
by the 1988 accounting change (GM, GE, Ford, Chrysler) and include only firms reporting
in USD. And finally, we keep companies that appear more than 10 consecutive years in the
sample. This leaves us with a total of 7,632 firms and 113,389 observations.
Our second dataset, Thomson Reuters Bond Security Master Data, provides information
on primary issuances of corporate bonds between 1980-2015. There are a total of 18,480 bond
deals in our data.12 Available information includes the name of the company issuing the bond,
the market value of the issue, the issue date, the type and purpose of the bond issuance, the
maturity of the bond, and the credit spread paid by the issuer (defined as the interest rate

11
These criteria are common in studies employing Compustat data. See Bernanke, Campbell, and Whited
(1990) for details.
12
We find that around 70% of bond deals took place after the year 2000.

18

Table 1: Compustat vs. NIPA
Sales Share
Employment Share
Investment Share
Correlation of Sales Growth
Correlation of Employment Growth
Correlation of Investment Growth

Compustat/NIPA
0.49
0.58
0.30
0.80
0.61
0.91

Bond-issuing firms/NIPA
0.19
0.20
0.10
0.88
0.57
0.94

Note: This table uses time series from the national income accounts (NIPA), Compustat firms, and a subset of
Compustat firms that have issued at least one bond in our sample (denoted “bond-issuing firms”). We focus
on two set of statistics: (a) the share of sales, employment, and investment in Compustat or bond-issuing firms
in Compustat relative to the aggregate and (b) the correlation between sales, employment, and investment
growth between NIPA, Compustat, and bond-issuing firms in Compustat.

paid over a Treasury bill of similar maturity).13 We drop bond issuances (1) below 1 million
dollars, (2) with a maturity larger than 40 years, and (3) with a credit spread less than 5 basis
points. These restrictions leave us with 18,369 deals. When we merge Compustat with TR
data, we are left with 4,372 bond deals.
In Table 1, we compare statistics regarding sales, employment and investment between
aggregate national income accounts (NIPA), Compustat firms, and Compustat firms that have
issued bonds in our data (merged sample). Compustat firms represent a fairly large share of
the aggregate economy: 49% of aggregate sales, 58% of aggregate employment, and 30% of
aggregate investment. Bond-issuing Compustat firms represent a smaller but still sizable share
of the aggregate economy: 19% of aggregate sales, 20% of aggregate employment, and 10%
of aggregate investment. The correlation between sales and investment growth across time
is high when comparing both Compustat and NIPA and bond-issuing Compustat firms and
NIPA. On the other hand, the correlation of employment growth in NIPA and Compustat
is low, around 0.6, as most of the employment growth usually comes from small firms. In
Table 2 we describe the construction of variables in our empirical analysis. For most of the
variables, there is a direct model counterpart.

4.2

Summary Statistics

Table 3 reports summary statistics for Compustat and TR data, respectively. In Compustat, the mean leverage ratio is 0.29 while the mean assets/sales ratio is 2.56. These estimates
are close to estimates using aggregate data. We define the investment rate as investment-to13
In our data there is also similar information on bank loans. Bank loans are typically of shorter maturity
relative to bonds. Modeling bank loan issuance alongside bond issuance would require us to include an
endogenous portfolio debt choice. Therefore, to keep the model tractable, we exclude bank loan financing
from the analysis.

19

Table 2: Definition of Variables: Model vs. Data
Variable
Capital

Notation
k

Investment

i

Depreciation
Dividends

δ
d

Employees
Leverage

n
qb0 /k 0

Sales
Value added
Materials

y
–
–

Credit spread
Productivity

(θ + c)/q − θ − r
z

Definition
Gross value of property, plant,
and equipment (PPENT, data item #8)
Capital expenditures on property, plant,
and equipment (CAPXV, #30)
minus sales of capital stock (SPPE, #107).
Current depreciation (DP, #14)
Common dividends (DVC, #268)
plus preferred dividends (DVP, #270)
minus stock repurchases (PRSTKC, #115)
Stock of employees (EMP, #29)
Debt in current liabilities (DLC, #34)
plus long-term debt (DLTT, #9)
divided by book value of assets (AT, #6)
Total Sales (SALE, #12)
Sales minus materials
Total Expenses [(SALE, #12) - (OIBDP, #13)]
- Labor Expenses [ (EMP, #29) × Wages]
Interest rate paid over a similar maturity Treasury bill
See main text

Note: We describe the empirical counterpart of model variables. For variables computed using Compustat
data we include the definition and data item in parentheses.

capital ratio. The mean investment rate in Compustat is 0.16, and the standard deviation is
0.26. Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) analyze data from the Longitudinal Research Database
and find an investment rate around 0.12 and a standard deviation of 0.33. Due to their size
and access to equity markets, Compustat firms are naturally less volatile in their investment
decisions. Around 6% of firms do not adjust their investment and 21% of firms change their
investment by more than 20%. These results are in accord with the large literature on investment dynamics suggesting the presence of costs to adjust capital. The corresponding numbers
in Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) are 8% and 18%, respectively.
In our data, 9.8% of Compustat firms issue a bond. The median number of bond issuances
by a single firm in all years is four while the maximum is 88. In some cases, firms issue multiple
bonds of different amounts and maturities during the same time period. Moreover, firms raise
funds through the bond market at a relatively high frequency. A firm issuing a bond in year
t re-issues a bond with probability 45% between years [t, t + 2] and with probability 57%
between years [t, t + 4]. The average amount raised in a deal is around $365 million. The
distribution is highly skewed: the maximum amount issued is $2 billion. Most of the issues in
our data involve long-term financing. The average bond matures in 11.6 years.

20

Table 3: Summary Statistics
Variable

#Obs.

Mean

Compustat
Leverage
Assets/Sales
Investment rate
Inaction rate (|< 1%|)
Spike rate (> 20%)
Autocorrelation
Dividends/profits
Autocorrelation

(Firms)
133,786
129,730
119,991
119,991
119,991
119,991
94,861
94,861

0.29
2.55
0.16
0.06
0.21
0.41
0.21
0.17

SD

Min p(10) p(25) p(50) p(75) p(90)

Max

0.42 0.00 0.00
7.29 0.20 0.43
0.22 -0.05 0.01

0.03
0.63
0.04

0.20
0.96
0.08

0.38
1.68
0.17

0.60
3.53
0.36

3.23
61.6
1.82

0.43

0.0

0.05

0.23

0.55

3.06

0.0

Thomson Reuters
(Bond deals)
Mkt. val. of issue ($mil.)
18,369
365.5 364.6 3.5
Maturity (years)
18,369
11.6 8.59
1
Credit spread (p.p.)
18,369
2.32 2.16 0.05

0.0

28.3 126.6 268.6 475.1 795.8 2000.0
5
6
10
11
30
40
0.60 0.90 1.55 3.00 5.37 9.59

Note: We report statistics from the cross-sectional distribution over the entire period sample. All variables
are winsorised at the 1%. The inaction rate and the spike rate are the fraction of firms with investment rates
less than 1% (in absolute value) and more than 20%, respectively. For Compustat, the different number of
observations across variables is due to missing values.

The main focus of the analysis is on the distribution of credit spreads. On average, firms
pay a spread of 2.3% over a T-Bill of similar maturity. The standard deviation is 2.0%.
Figure 2 shows the cross-sectional distribution of credit spreads in the data. The sizable
dispersion reflects a wide variety of bond qualities in our data. Our findings are very close
to Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012). The authors use secondary market prices of outstanding
securities between 1973-2010 to construct bond yields. They find a credit spread mean of
2.0% with a slightly larger standard deviation of 2.8%.14
In Table 3 we used all bond deals. When we examine bond deals issued only by Compustat
firms (around 4,129 deals) the results remain largely intact. The average maturity is 11 years,
the average credit spread is 2.10 p.p., and the standard deviation decreases slightly to 2.0 p.p.
(see Appendix Section A.2). Hence, credit quality can vary substantially in our data even if
we restrict the sample to bond-issuing Compustat firms.

14
When we look at time variation in credit spreads, we document a countercyclical pattern similar to the
findings of Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012). In addition, during the Great Recession, bond issuance increased.
Issuance of new bonds totaled around $80 billion in 2007 and increased to $130 billion during the crisis. This
was the result of more firms choosing bond issuance as a means of financing. The annual number of bond
deals increased from around 200 to 400 per year. In contrast, given bond issuance, the average amount of
issuance decreased. The average amount per bond deal decreased from around $350 million to around $300
million. The increase in the number of issuances occurred because firms substituted bank loan financing with
corporate debt issuance. For a more detailed analysis of the time-series variation in bank loans and bond
issuance see Adrian, Colla, and Shin (2012) and Karabarbounis (2015).

21

Figure 2: Credit Spread Distribution (in p.p.)

0

1

2

3

4
5
6
7
Credit Spreads, in p.p.

8

9

10

Note: Credit spread distribution in percentage points over the period 1980-2015. We winsorize the distribution
at 1%. Source: Thomson Reuters Bond Security Master Data and authors’ calculations.

4.3

Productivity and Firm Characteristics

A key part of our analysis is the relationship between firm-level total factor productivity
(TFP) and firm characteristics. To estimate firm-level TFP we use the following specification:
yit = β0 + βk kit + βl lit + zit + εit ,
where all variables are in logs. yit is value added by firm i in year t, and kit and lit are the
capital and labor inputs, respectively, by firm i in year t. zit is the TFP of firm i in year t,
which is observed by the firm but unobserved by the econometrician. Finally, εit represents
either shocks unobserved to both the econometrician and the firm (and hence, not influencing
labor inputs) or measurement error.
We translate nominal variables such as value added or total value of capital into physical
units using the GDP price deflator and the price index for private fixed investment, both
available from the Bureau of Economic Analysis). To transform the capital stock into physical
units, we take into account that capital stock is shaped based on investment that occurred in
different time periods. Following the method by Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2003), we calculate
the average capital age as accumulated depreciation divided by current depreciation.15 As a
result, we deflate capital by the investment deflator of the respective year.
15
As suggested by İmrohoroğlu and Tüzel (2014), we smooth further capital age by taking a three-year
moving average.

22

Table 4: Relationship between TFP and Firm Characteristics
TFP Decile
Leverage
Assets/Sales
Investment Rate
Dividends/Profits

1st
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00

2nd
1.06
0.66
0.76
0.68

3rd
1.04
0.58
0.86
0.53

4th
0.97
0.56
0.99
0.51

5th
0.92
0.55
1.15
0.50

6th
0.90
0.60
1.29
0.51

7th
0.85
0.64
1.52
0.52

8th
0.82
0.68
1.73
0.57

9th
0.73
0.77
2.15
0.61

10th
0.71
1.03
2.93
0.59

10th-1st
-0.29
+0.03
+1.93
-0.64

Note: We divide firms based on their TFP into 10 bins. For each bin, we calculate the average leverage,
assets-sales ratio, investment rate, and dividends-profits ratio. For each variable we normalize the series based
on the value in the first bin. We summarize the relationships using the difference between the 10th to first
decile.

There are several challenges to estimate firm-level total factor productivity. First, there is
a simultaneity problem between the firm’s choices and the firm’s productivity. For example, if
a firm hires more workers because it is more productive, then coefficient βl might be upward
biased and productivity zit might be downward biased. Moreover, there is a selection problem.
The most productive firms are more likely to issue equity for a longer time and thus stay in the
sample longer. To deal with these shortcomings, we employ the approach developed by Olley
and Pakes (1996). We leave a description of this technique to Section A.1 in the appendix.
Second, our measure of productivity is revenue-based (revenue total factor productivity
or TFPR), so it is jointly affected by true, physical productivity (TFPQ) as well as changes
in prices (Foster, Haltiwanger, and Syverson, 2008). Moreover, firm value added is likely to
be measured with error. We address – to some extent – these concerns using a fixed effects
estimator when analyzing the effect of TFP on credit spreads (Equation (14) below). It is
less likely that measurement error would change over time for the same firm (see for example,
Bils, Klenow, and Ruane, 2017). Moreover, as Kaplan and Menzio (2015) show, variation in
good prices is very prevalent across stores but small for the same store across time. Therefore,
although we do recognize that our productivity measure partially captures price variation, we
mitigate this concern by using a fixed effects estimator.16
Table 4 explores the relationship between firm-level TFP and firm-level leverage, assetsto-sales ratio, investment rate, and the dividends-profits ratio. In particular, we sort firms
into 10 bins based on their TFP level. For each bin, we report the average leverage ratio,
assets-to-sales ratio, investment rate, and dividends-profits ratio. We have around 9,000 firmyear observations per bin. For each statistic, we normalize bins by the value of the first decile.
16
Note that our approach is also susceptible to an input price bias as we deflate capital using aggregate
deflators. For this case, we explicitly check the magnitude of the bias by using not aggregate but industryspecific deflators available by the NBER-CES database. The deflators are available at the six-digit NAICS
level but only for a subset of industries that reduces substantially the number of our observations. We compare
our estimates for productivity and its relation to credit spreads (to be discussed in Table 5 below) when we
deflate by the mean investment deflator and by industry-specific deflators. We present results in Table 13 in
Appendix A.2. Our estimates are not substantially affected by using the industry-specific deflators.

23

Table 5: Determinants of Credit Spreads
Dependent
Variable
Specification
zit (Productivity)

Sijt (Credit Spreads)
(1)

(2)

(3)

-0.06*** -0.37***
(0.02)
(0.05)

[b0 /k 0 ]it (Leverage)
St. Deviation of
Equity Returns
# Observations
R-squared
# Firms
Year/Bond F.E.
Firm F.E.

4,151
0.38
724
Yes
No

4,151
0.47
724
Yes
Yes

(4)

(5)

-0.01
(0.01)
0.27*** 0.27*** 0.28***
(0.03) (0.05) (0.03)
1.04*** 0.41*** 1.04***
(0.05) (0.05) (0.05)
3,780
0.57
625
Yes
No

3,780
0.48
625
Yes
Yes

3,644
0.57
608
Yes
No

(6)
-0.33***
(0.05)
0.26***
(0.04)
0.39***
(0.05)
3,644
0.54
608
Yes
Yes

Note: This table reports estimates from the regression in Equation (14). Sijt is the log credit spread paid by
firm i associated with bond j issued in year t, zit is TFP (in logs) of firm i in period t, [b0 /k 0 ]it is log-leverage,
and we also include the logged standard deviation of yearly equity returns for firm i as calculated from CRSP.
One, two, and three stars denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

Firms at the 10th decile have around 70% of the leverage and almost twice the investment
rate of firms in the first decile. The relationship between TFP and the assets-to-sales ratio is
non-monotonic. Our results are consistent with the findings in İmrohoroğlu and Tüzel (2014).
In Section 3.2, we have shown that the credit market constraints wedge depends on the
credit spread. Moreover, the sign and magnitude of the covariance between the wedge and
productivity is crucial for our results regarding the direct effect of misallocation (see Section 6). We analyze this covariance by exploring the empirical relationship between firm-level
productivity and credit spreads. In particular, we run the following regression:
Sijt = β0 + β1 zit + β2 [b0 /k 0 ]it + β3 [Sd Dev. Equity Returns]it + αt + ηi + Xj + εijt .

(14)

The dependent variable Sijt is the log credit spread paid by firm i associated with bond
j issued in year t. We regress the spread to firm-level TFP zit and log leverage [b0 /k 0 ]it . We
also include the standard deviation of yearly equity returns for firm i. Equity volatility is
estimated using data from the CRSP daily stock files during the period of our analysis. We
capture time-varying common factors using a time dummy αt . Moreover, we include a firm
fixed effect ηi . Finally, we include bond characteristics Xj such as the value of the issue (in
logs) and the maturity of the bond.
24

Table 5 shows the results of our regression. All specifications use time fixed effects and
bond characteristics. We first regress spreads on firm-level TFP without and with fixed effects
(specifications (1) and (2)). The fixed effect differences out time-invariant cross-sectional
variation in firm characteristics and turns out to be very important. Without fixed effects, a
1% increase in TFP decreases credit spreads by 0.06%. When we include firm fixed effects, a
1% increase in TFP decreases credit spreads by 0.37%. We view the discrepancy to be related
with our discussion on revenue-based productivity versus physical productivity. If productive
firms charge lower prices, then a revenue-based measure of productivity will be biased toward
zero. Since price variation is likely to be more prevalent in the cross-section (Kaplan and
Menzio, 2015), the fixed effects estimator increases the coefficient.
Specifications (3) and (4) run separately credit spreads on leverage and the volatility of firm
equity returns. This is motivated by the extensive literature trying to identify the determinants
of credit spreads (Duffee, 1998; Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin, 2001; Driessen, 2005;
Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajšek, 2014). Leverage and equity volatility are identified as important
determinants of the probability of default on debt obligations. A 1% increase in leverage
increases credit spreads by 0.27%. This is unaffected by the inclusion of fixed effects. Moreover,
a 1% increase in the volatility of equity increases credit spreads by 1.04% without fixed effects
and 0.41% with fixed effects. Specifications (5) and (6) include all regressors – namely, TFP,
leverage and equity volatility. Compared to specifications (1)-(2), the coefficient of TFP
becomes less negative, which can be explained by the inclusion of the other regressors. Once
more, the inclusion of fixed effects turns out to be very important. With fixed effects, we find
that a 1% increase in TFP decreases credit spreads by 0.33%.
Although not reported in Table 5, credit spreads increase with the amount issued from
a bond. Moreover, conditional on the amount issued and year, longer maturity is associated
with higher credit spreads. The relationship between maturity and spreads is affected by the
fact that better firms issue bonds of longer duration (Helwege and Turner, 1999). In our
specification, we can overcome this challenge by looking at the term structure paid by the
same firm.
Our regression explains around 50% of the variation in credit spreads. The challenge to
capture the determinants of credit spreads is well known in the literature as the credit spread
puzzle. Driessen (2005) analyzes the determinants of credit spreads, taking into account most
of the variables proposed by the literature. He finds that only two-thirds of the variation
is explained by his specification. Our explanatory power is somewhat lower but within the
ranges found in the literature.

25

5

Model Estimation

In this section, we discuss our structural estimation technique, the estimated parameters,
and assess the model’s fit with the data.

5.1

Estimation Strategy

One set of parameters is set outside of the model (literature or data), and the remaining
parameters are estimated using Simulated Method of Moments (SMM). With SMM, we solve
for the unknown parameters by minimizing the weighted sum of squared errors between model
and data moments.17 We select moments in the data that are particularly informative (based
on our theory) for the wedge and misallocation.
Table 6 lists the calibrated parameters. The model is computed at an annual frequency.
We normalize the wage rate to 1 and set the annual risk-free rate r equal to 4%. The returns
to scale parameter, γ, is set to 0.85, which is in the middle of the estimates of Burnside,
Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995). We set the capital share parameter equal to α = 0.35 and
the tax parameters to be τi = 0.296, τc− = 0.2, and τc+ = 0.35, which are typical values in the
literature (e.g., Katagiri (2014)). We set the coupon rate, c, to be equal to the risk-free rate.
This is just a normalization that ensures the risk-free bond price is equal to 1. The expected
P
t−1
= 1/θ. Since the average maturity in
maturity of a bond in our model is ∞
t=1 tθ(1 − θ)
our data is 11.8 years, we set θ = 1/11.8 ≈ 0.085. The depreciation rate is set to δ = 0.08 to
match the median investment rate in our data.
Table 6: Calibrated Parameters
Parameter
Wage
Risk-free rate
Coupon
Capital share
Returns to scale
Min. corporate tax rate
Max. corporate tax rate
Interest income tax rate
Bond maturity
Depreciation rate

Notation
w
r
c
α
γ
τc−
τc+
τi
θ
δ

Value
1
0.04
0.04
0.35
0.85
0.2
0.35
0.296
0.085
0.08

Target / Source
Normalization
Typical in literature
Normalization
Capital-income share
Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995)
Katagiri (2014)
Katagiri (2014)
Katagiri (2014)
TR Bond Security Data
Median investment rate

The remaining parameters are estimated via SMM to match moments computed from our
data. We estimate six parameters: the productivity parameters (ρz , σεz ), the discount factor
17

For a review of SMM, see Strebulaev and Whited (2012).

26

η, the bankruptcy cost ξ, the equity payout cost parameter φd , and the capital adjustment
cost parameter φk .
The six parameters are estimated using a total of nine moments. The moments are reported
in Panel A of Table 7. We choose moments that are informative about the parameters we seek
to estimate. To pin down the parameters of the productivity process (ρz , σεz ), we estimate a
first-order autoregressive process in log-sales, controlling for firm fixed effects, and we target
the persistence and the standard deviation of the residual.
The average firm-level assets-to-sales ratio is informative for the discount factor (η). If firms
discount the future more, then a higher fraction of profits will be distributed to shareholders
and a lower fraction will be re-invested. Hence the assets-to-sales ratio will be lower. The
median leverage ratio is informative for several parameters, including the discount factor η,
the bankruptcy cost ξ, and the equity payout cost parameter φd . With a lower discount factor,
firms choose higher leverage ratios, making default more likely. With a higher bankruptcy
cost ξ, lenders charge higher credit premiums for a given leverage ratio, which discourages
firms from borrowing. The equity payout cost parameter φd affects the firm’s incentive to
distribute dividends and ultimately how much debt to issue.
To inform our estimation, we also use the median credit spread and the mean default
rate.18 The expected default rate on corporate bonds is constructed using Moody’s estimates
on default probabilities on different classes of bonds. In our sample, for example, 20% of
bond deals are rated as A1, 15% as Baa1, 12% as Baa2, and 10% as A3.19 The average
default rate is calculated by combining the distribution of bonds over categories and the
default probability for each class. The average default rate of bonds turns out to be 1.56%.
The median credit spread and the average default rate are informative about the bankruptcy
cost ξ and the discount factor η. Lenders charge higher credit spreads if bankruptcy costs
are higher. Moreover, when the discount factor is lower, firms default at a higher frequency,
generating higher credit spreads.
We also target the elasticity of credit spread with respect to productivity. In the data, there
is a negative relationship between credit spreads and firm-level TFP. As mentioned before, the
bankruptcy cost ξ and the discount factor η affect the credit spread distribution and hence
the elasticity with respect to productivity. Moreover, the elasticity depends on the equity
payout cost parameter φd . The equity payout cost hinders an investment strategy whereby
firms sell all their capital and subsequently distribute large payouts to shareholders shortly
before defaulting. When we allowed such strategies to take place (by setting φd = 0), the
18
In the model, the firm’s credit spread is r∗ − r, where r is the risk-free rate and r∗ = (θ + c)/q − θ is the
yield-to-maturity on the promised sequence of payments.
19
More than half of our firms in the sample are rated by Moody’s. Since every maturity has a different
default probability, we choose the probability of defaulting after 12 years. This is the average maturity we
observe in our sample.

27

Table 7: Model Fit and Estimated Parameters
Panel A: Moments

Model

Data

Autocorrelation of log sales
Standard deviation of innovation to log sales
Mean capital/sales ratio
Median credit spread
Mean default rate
Std dev. of investment rates
Median leverage ratio
Credit spread-TFP elasticity
Autocorrelation of dividends/profits

0.78
0.48
2.48
1.22%
1.63%
0.24
0.34
-0.53
0.18

0.75
0.50
2.55
1.55%
1.56%
0.22
0.20
-0.33
0.17

Notation

Value

Productivity persistence

ρz

Std dev. of productivity innovation

σεz

0.670
(0.006)
0.210
(0.002)
0.972
(0.001)
0.100
(0.005)
0.045
(0.001)
0.500
(0.018)

Panel B: Parameters

Discount factor

η

Bankruptcy cost

ξ

Capital adjustment cost

φk

Equity payout cost

φd

Note: Panel A reports the targeted moments in the model and the data. Panel B reports the resulting
parameters, estimated via Simulated Method of Moments (SMM). Standard errors are reported in parentheses.

elasticity turned from negative to positive as it was the most productive firms that defaulted.
The standard deviation of investment rates is informative for the capital adjustment cost
wedge. In particular, the standard deviation of investment rates is lower when φk is higher.
And finally, the autocorrelation of dividends/profits is informative for the equity cost parameter, φd . The equity cost parameter affects the incentives of firms to smooth dividends over
time.

5.2

Estimation Results and Model Fit

Although we use six parameters, our model overall does a good job matching our nine
empirical moments (see Panel A of Table 7). In particular, the model matches very closely
the median credit spread, the standard deviation of investment rates, the mean assets/sales
28

-4.7

Credit Spreads (in logs)
-4.5
-4.3
-4.1

-3.9

Figure 3: Credit Spreads and Productivity: Model vs. Data

Data
Model
-.8

-.6

-.4

-.2
0
.2
Firm-level Productivity

.4

.6

.8

Note: This figure plots the relationship between credit spreads and firm-level TFP in the model and the data.
The data source is Compustat and Thomson Reuters Bond Security Master Data. Each point in the scatter
plot represents a bin of firms (total of 80 bins).

ratio, the average default ratio, and the autocorrelation of dividends/profits.
The model also matches well the negative cross-sectional relationship between credit spreads
and productivity. This is shown in Figure 3. Highly productive firms are able to attract financing at a lower cost since (a) their incentive to default is lower and (b) the lenders can
recover a highly valued firm in the case of default. The negative covariance between credit
spreads and productivity turns out to be critical for our results regarding the effect of credit
market constraints on misallocation (see Section 6.2).
We now evaluate our model’s fit with respect to untargeted moments (see Table 8). For
example, in our estimation, we targeted the median credit spread but not other moments of
the credit spread distribution. Figure 4 shows the distribution of credit spreads in the data
(left panel) and the distribution generated in the model (right panel). Dispersion of credit
spreads in the data is substantial. The bottom 10%, median, and top 10% pay less than
0.5, 1.5 and more than 5 percentage points, respectively. The model generates a dispersed
distribution of credit spreads close to what we observe in the data. The standard deviation
of credit spreads in the model is 0.9 percentage points versus 2.0 in the data.
Our model also replicates the positive relationship between leverage and credit spreads. In
the model, highly leveraged firms have a larger incentive to default and so they are charged

29

Figure 4: Credit Spread Distribution: Data (Left Panel) and Model (Right Panel)

Data

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

Model

10

0

Credit Spreads, in p.p.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Credit Spreads, in p.p.

Note: Left panel shows the credit spread distribution in percentage points from Thomson Reuters Bond
Security Master Data (authors’ calculations). The right panel shows the credit spread distribution from the
simulated data.

Table 8: Untargeted Moments: Model vs. Data
Moments
Model Data
St. dev. of credit spreads
0.92% 2.03%
Investment rate |i/k |
< 1% (Inaction)
7.19% 6.97%
> 20% (Spike)
34.3% 17.7%
Autocorrelation
0.16
0.41
10th - 1st TFP decile
Assets/Sales
-4.44
0.03
Investment/Capital
0.44
1.93
Leverage
-0.20 -0.29
Dividend/profits
-2.02 -0.64
Elasticity of credit spreads wrt Leverage
0.63
0.26
Mean dividends/profits
0.61
0.21
Std. dev. of dividends/profits
0.73
0.43
Note: This table reports untargeted moments from our benchmark model and in the data.

a higher credit spread. The leverage coefficient that comes out of the regression (see Equation (14)) when we use the model-generated data is 0.63. This is somewhat higher than the
coefficient of 0.26 in the data.
In addition, the model matches well the relationship between firm-level TFP and leverage.
The model reproduces qualitatively the relationship between investment rate and firm-level
TFP, but investment rates are less responsive than in the data. Similarly, the model reproduces
30

qualitatively the relationship between the dividends/profits ratio and firm-level TFP, but in
this case, the model is more responsive than what the data suggest. The model is not successful
capturing the relationship between TFP and assets/sales ratio. In the data, the relationship
is non-monotonic, while in the model it is monotonically decreasing.
Table 8 also reports untargeted moments regarding the investment rates. The inaction
rate (investment rate in absolute terms less than 1%) is 7.1% which is close to the empirical
counterpart of 6.9%. However, the model over-predicts the fraction of firms undertaking a
large investment relative to their capital (34% versus 17% in the data). Moreover, the model
underpredicts the autocorrelation of investment rates (0.16 versus 0.41 in the data). Finally,
the model cannot match well untargeted statistics regarding dividend issuance. In the model,
firms issue three times more dividends (relative to their profits) than in the data. Moreover,
the dispersion in the model is also higher than in the data (0.73 versus 0.43, respectively).

6

Quantitative Results

In this section, we present our main findings. We show how credit market constraints
affect TFP directly, but also indirectly through their interaction with other frictions and
technological constraints.

6.1

Overall Effect of Credit Market Constraints

Table 9 analyzes the overall effect of credit market constraints on misallocation. We
report the results for our benchmark economy as well as an economy without credit market
constraints. In the economy without credit market constraints, we eliminate bankruptcy costs
and limited commitment.20 For each model, we compute various aggregate statistics, including
TFP loss. Note that for the case without credit market constraints, we compute the wage at
which the aggregate level of labor is the same as our benchmark economy.
When we add credit market constraints, the variance of the overall wedge increases and
TFP loss increases by 1.6%. Small TFP losses are a relatively common finding in the literature
analyzing credit market constraints. For example, Midrigan and Xu (2014) and Moll (2014)
find small effects of financial frictions due to persistent productivity shocks and self-financing.21
Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajšek (2013) find that dispersion in credit spreads is not large enough
to generate a significant amount of misallocation. In our case, the effect of credit market
20
We model commitment by requiring that firms buy back existing debt at the risk-free price before issuing
new debt or before dis-investing.
21
Midrigan and Xu (2014) do find substantial losses from misallocation due to entry and exit of firms. We
do not consider the extensive margin in our model since our data includes only publicly listed firms and not
newly formed establishments.

31

constraints on misallocation is small because they affect the wedge in multiple, and at times
contradictory, ways. We illustrate this point in Section 6.2 by decomposing the overall effect
into a direct and an indirect effect.
Table 9: Overall Effect of Credit Market Constraints

Wage
N
K/N
Y /N
Median EMPK
TFP loss

Model w/o
CMC

Benchmark
Model

1.12
0.40
4.32
2.03
0.12
2.6%

1.00
0.40
3.10
1.81
0.15
4.2%

Note: The model without credit market constraints (CMC) eliminates bankruptcy costs and limited commitment. TFP loss is computed according to Equation (13).

In addition, when we add credit market constraints, the capital-labor ratio decreases by
28%, and the median EMPK increases by about 0.03. Therefore, while credit market constraints have a modest effect on misallocation and the dispersion of EMPK, they have a large
effect on the average level of EMPK and aggregate capital. To the extent that all firms are
affected by credit market constraints, this shows up in the level of EMPK. To the extent that
firms are affected in different ways (e.g., low- versus high-productivity firms), this shows up
in the dispersion of EMPK.

6.2

Decomposing the Transmission of Credit Market Constraints

We have shown that the overall effect of credit market constraints is to generate more misallocation. However, the overall effect is the combination of the direct effect, which originates
from cross-sectional variation in credit spreads, and the indirect effect between credit market
constraints and other frictions and technological constraints.
When we move from a model with no credit market constraints to our benchmark economy,
aggregate TFP decreases because the variance of the overall wedge increases. As discussed in
Section 3.2, the overall wedge can be decomposed into four individual wedges: (1) the credit
market constraints wedge (W edgeCM C ), (2) the capital adjustment cost wedge (W edgeCAC ),
(3) the equity payout cost wedge (W edgeEP C ), and (4) the tax wedge (W edgeT ). To distinguish between the direct and indirect effects of credit market constraints, we investigate
how the introduction of credit market constraints affects the variance of the overall wedge
through each individual wedge. Specifically, for both the model with and without credit market constraints, we compute the TFP loss attributable to feature i ∈ {CM C, CAC, EP C, T }
32

Table 10: The Direct and Indirect Effects of Credit Market Constraints on TFP
TFP loss
Transmission
Mechanism

Model w/o
CMC

Credit Market Const. Direct Effect
Capital Adj. Costs
Indirect Effect
Equity Payout Costs Indirect Effect
Taxes
Indirect Effect
All
Direct+Indirect Effect

0.0%
1.5%
0.4%
0.7%
2.6%

Benchmark
Model
Change
-0.4%
0.9%
2.4%
1.3%
4.2%

-0.4%
-0.6%
2.0%
0.6%
1.6%

Note: To decompose total TFP loss into direct and indirect effects, we decompose the wedge into four individual
wedges that separately isolate the effect of credit market constraints, capital adjustment costs, equity payout
costs, and taxes. Then we construct the marginal contribution of each wedge to the overall TFP loss by
decomposing the variance of the overall wedge using Equation (15).

as follows:

P
Var(W edgei ) + j6=i Cov(W edgei , W edgej )
.

P
TFP lossi = TFP loss 
Var
j W edgej


(15)

With this approach, the marginal contribution of feature i to TFP loss depends not only on
the variance of W edgei , but also on the covariance of W edgei with the other wedges. W edgei
has a larger effect on the overall variance when it covaries positively with the other wedges.
The direct effect of credit market constraints is the change in TFP lossCM C when we move
from a model without credit market constraints to a model with credit market constraints.
Similarly, the indirect effect is the change in TFP lossi for i ∈ {CAC, EP C, T } between
the model with and without credit market constraints. For example, for the case of capital
adjustment costs, the indirect effect of credit market constraints is captured by the change in
TFP lossCAC .
In Table 10, we report TFP loss for each wedge and for each model (with and without
credit market constraints). TFP loss due to the credit market constraints wedge (W edgeCM C )
is naturally zero. When we add credit market constraints, TFP loss due to the credit market
constraints wedge decreases by 0.4%. Therefore, our first finding is that the direct effect of
credit market constraints reduces misallocation. TFP loss due to all the other features in the
economy increases by a total of 2.0%. Therefore, the overall increase in TFP loss by 1.6%
arises due to the indirect effects. In the following, we explain in more detail what is driving
the direct and indirect effects of credit market constraints.
Direct Effect of Credit Market Constraints

33

When we introduce credit market con-

straints, TFP lossCM C decreases. Looking at Equation (15), we can see that TFP lossCM C
P
depends on Var(W edgeCM C ) and j6=CM C Cov(W edgeCM C , W edgej ). As we highlighted in
Figure 4, credit market constraints generate dispersion in credit spreads and this increases
Var(W edgeCM C ) and thus generates misallocation. If our model had a single distortion, then
the direct effect would generate TFP loss. This is exactly what Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajšek
(2013) find since they omit any other frictions or technological constraints from the analysis.
However, in our model, TFP lossCM C also depends on the covariance between the credit marP
ket constraints wedge with the other individual wedges ( j6=CM C Cov(W edgeCM C , W edgej )).
The direct effect can decrease TFP lossCM C as long as the sum of the covariances between the
individual wedges is negative and also larger in magnitude than the variance of W edgeCM C .
Figure 5 shows the covariance between each wedge and productivity. The middle left panel
of Figure 5 shows that when we eliminate credit market constraints, there is no dispersion in
the credit market constraints wedge across firms (W edgeCM C ). In this economy, there is no
variation in credit spreads and the probability of default is zero for all firms. When we add
credit market constraints, as mentioned above, Var(W edgeCM C ) increases due to the higher
dispersion in credit spreads and default probabilities.
However, Cov(W edgeCM C , ln z) turns negative. The negative covariance between the credit
market constraints wedge and productivity stems from the negative relationship between credit
spreads and productivity. In the model, more productive firms can borrow at a lower cost for
two reasons. First, due to higher productivity, the firm has less incentive to default and lose
part of its future value. As a result, lenders are willing to supply more funds to the firm at a
low cost. Second, even if default takes place, the high recovery value of a high-productivity
firm allows lenders to charge a smaller credit spread. As shown in Section 5.2, our model
replicates the empirical relationship between credit spreads and productivity very closely.
Although Cov(W edgeCM C , ln z) turns negative, the covariance of all other wedges with
productivity turns positive (middle right panel and lower panels of Figure 5). As a result,
P
j6=CM C Cov(W edgeCM C , W edgej ) < 0, which explains why the direct effect reduces misallocation. Credit market constraints affect mostly low-productivity firms. Other frictions
or technological constraints affect mostly high-productivity firms. Therefore, credit market
constraints reduce misallocation directly through credit spreads, because they offset the productivity losses induced by the existing model environment.
Our results indicate that variation in credit spreads might be desirable as long as it affects
mostly low-productivity firms. While such variation increases the dispersion in the credit market constraints wedge, it also decreases the covariance between the credit market constraints
wedge and the other wedges. Therefore, any policy that targets misallocation by affecting
the distribution of credit spreads needs to take into account not only the dispersion of credit

34

Figure 5: Effect of Credit Market Constraints on Individual Wedges

Note: Bottom four panels show a scatter plot of four individual wedges (credit market constraints, capital
adjustment costs, equity payout costs, and taxes) and productivity. We plot the wedges for our benchmark
model with credit market constraints and a model without credit market constraints. Top panel shows the
scatter plot between the overall wedge (all frictions and technological constraints) and productivity.

35

spreads but also which type of firms have lower borrowing costs.
Indirect Effect of Credit Market Constraints Since the overall effect of credit market
constraints is to decrease aggregate TFP, the main transmission mechanism occurs through
the indirect effect. However, the individual frictions and technological constraints respond
very differently when we eliminate credit market constraints.
When we add credit market constraints, TFP loss due to capital adjustment costs decreases
(Table 10). This is because dispersion in the capital adjustment cost wedge decreases (see the
middle-right panel of Figure 5). To gain intuition for this result, we repeat the expression for
the capital adjustment cost wedge (see Equation (9)):
W edgeCAC


k 0 − (1 − δ)k
k
" 
2
 00
#
1 k 00 − (1 − δ)k 0
k − (1 − δ)k 0
− 2φk E
+ (1 − δ)
.
2
k0
k0

1 2φk
= +
β
β



The variance of this wedge is largest when the dispersion in investment rates is high and when
investment rates across periods are volatile. When we introduce credit market constraints,
dispersion and volatility of investment rates decrease and thus aggregate productivity losses
associated with capital adjustment costs decrease as well.
Similar to our exercise, Khan and Thomas (2013) jointly model credit market constraints
and capital adjustment costs. In their paper, capital adjustment costs interact with collateral
constraints, propagate shocks in the economy, and decrease aggregate TFP. In contrast, we find
that credit market constraints mitigate the productivity losses induced by capital adjustment
costs. In Khan and Thomas (2013), the financial shock generates misallocation by preventing
young firms from quickly reaching their optimal scale. In our model, we abstract from firm
entry and exit due to the nature of our data (large, publicly listed firms).
While credit market constraints decrease TFP loss directly and indirectly through capital
adjustment costs, they increase TFP loss through equity payout costs and taxes. Quantitatively, the strongest indirect effect comes from the equity payout cost wedge. To understand
the mechanism, we repeat the definition of the equity cost wedge (Equation 10):
W edgeEP C


 0

∂π
Λ0 (d)
1
0 0
+1−δ
−
.
≡ + E Λ (d )
β
∂k 0
β

Equity payout costs create an incentive for firms to smooth dividend issuance across time.
Notice that the wedge is largest when dividend issuance today is low relative to tomorrow.
Credit market constraints affect the incentives of firms to smooth dividends. Consider the

36

firm’s budget constraint (see Equation (2)), which we repeat here:
d + k 0 = e(z, k, b) + q(z, k 0 , b0 ) [b0 − (1 − θ)b] − g(k, k 0 ).
A firm with low equity e is more likely to be borrowing constrained. Such a firm, in order
to finance capital k 0 , would like to reduce dividends d today (maybe even making d negative)
and increase future dividends d0 . Without credit market constraints, this firm would be free
to use debt to smooth dividend issuance. With credit market constraints, the ability of the
firm to issue debt is limited and misallocation arises because of the presence of equity payout
costs.
Our results suggest that an effective way to mitigate credit market constraints is to design
policies that target equity payout costs. For example, by making it easier for firms to adjust
dividends, misallocation from credit market constraints may be reduced. We do not explicitly
evaluate such policies, but our exercise highlights the mechanisms that are relevant for policy
design.

7

Inspecting the Mechanism

In this section, we explore which model element is responsible for our findings. First,
we shut down endogenous default and consider an economy with an exogenous collateral
constraint. Second, we discuss the role of long-term financing. Third, we consider the role of
productivity persistence for TFP loss.

7.1

The Role of Endogenous Default

In our benchmark model, firms are endogenously constrained due to limited commitment.
We now study a version of our model with an exogenous collateral constraint. Instead of
assuming long-duration bonds with limited commitment, we assume firms issue one-period
bonds subject to the following constraint:
b0 ≤ ψk 0 .

(16)

As there is no default in this version of the model, firms are able to issue bonds at the
price (1 + c)/(1 + r). Parameter ψ governs the magnitude of borrowing constraints. We set
ψ = 0.34 to match the leverage ratio in our benchmark model. All other parameters are the
same as in our benchmark parameterization.22 We compare this economy to one in which the
22

One exception is that there are no bankruptcy costs in our exogenous collateral constraint model (as

37

Table 11: Credit Market Constraints and TFP: Exogenous Collateral Constraint
TFP loss
Transmission
Mechanism

Model w/o
CMC

Credit Market Const. Direct Effect
Capital Adj. Costs
Indirect Effect
Equity Payout Costs Indirect Effect
Taxes
Indirect Effect
All
Direct+Indirect Effect

0.4%
1.5%
0.1%
0.7%
2.7%

Benchmark
Model
Change
-0.7%
1.0%
2.5%
1.3%
4.1%

-1.1%
-0.5%
2.4%
0.6%
1.4%

Note: TFP loss decomposition for the model with an exogenous collateral constraint. To decompose total
TFP loss into direct and indirect effects, we decompose the wedge into four individual wedges that separately
isolate the effect of credit market constraints, capital adjustment costs, equity payout costs, and taxes. Then
we construct the marginal contribution of each wedge to the overall TFP loss by decomposing the variance of
the overall wedge using Equation (15).

exogenous collateral constraint is relaxed to ψ = 1.23
Table 11 reports the result of this exercise. The introduction of an exogenous credit market
friction increases overall TFP loss by 1.4%. In our benchmark economy, the effect of credit
market constraints on TFP loss is 1.6%. Therefore, the exogenous collateral constraint has a
similar effect on misallocation as an endogenous borrowing constraint.
As in the benchmark economy, we decompose the overall wedge into individual wedges.
The only difference is that the credit market constraints wedge is now given by
W edgeCM C =

1
(1 − ψµ) ,
β

(17)

where µ is the Lagrange multiplier on the collateral constraint. Because an increase in capital
k 0 relaxes the borrowing constraint, the direct effect of a more binding collateral constraint
is to reduce the (exogenous) credit market constraints wedge.24 The direct effect of credit
market constraints reduces misallocation as in the benchmark model. Moreover, overall,
credit market constraints generate more misallocation, which implies that the transmission
mechanism occurs through the indirect effect.
Therefore, there is no qualitative difference between our model with endogenous default
and a model with an exogenous collateral constraint. Endogenous default is not necessary
there is now no default).
23
When η < 1, a value of ψ = 1 guarantees that E[M P K] = r + δ when there are no other distortions. We
get similar results when we set η = 1 and ψ to a very large number.
24
In our model, if g(k, k 0 ) = 0 and d = 0, then the budget constraint is k 0 = e+b0 (using (1+c)/(1+r) = 1).
Using the firm’s budget constraint, we can re-write the exogenous borrowing constraint (b0 ≤ ψk 0 ) as k 0 ≤
e/(1 − ψ). In this case, an increase in k 0 pushes the firm closer to the constraint. However, this transformation
depends crucially on the restriction that d = 0.

38

for our results. But then what is the added value of incorporating an endogenous borrowing
constraint? With exogenous collateral constraints, the underlying distortion manifests itself
through a shadow price (i.e., Lagrange multiplier), which has no direct empirical counterpart.
In contrast, in our benchmark model with endogenous borrowing constraints, the distortion
shows up through credit spreads that can be externally validated in the data. This allows us to
verify empirically the covariance between the credit market constraint wedge and productivity.
In both models, the covariance is negative. However, with endogenous default, this covariance
takes the form of a relationship between credit spreads and firm productivity that we can
empirically verify.

7.2

The Role of Long-Term Financing

In this section, we analyze how long-duration bonds affect our results. In particular, we
consider an economy with endogenous default but where bonds mature after one year (θ = 1).
As mentioned in Section 2.7, long-term financing allows us to generate a realistic distribution
of credit spreads. What matters with long-term financing is the whole sequence of default
probabilities until the bond matures. As a result, lenders charge a premium based on the
long-run probability of default.
With one-period bonds, what matters for firms is the one-period default probability. It
turns out that with one-period bonds, larger issuances increase the credit spreads very steeply.
As a result, all firms prefer to pay the risk-free rate. In contrast, with long-term financing,
credit spreads increase more gradually since they reflect the whole path of future default
probabilities, not just next period’s default probability.25 Figure 6 (right panel) shows that
the credit spread distribution is degenerate at the risk-free rate when θ = 1. In contrast, in
our benchmark model (θ = 0.085), the credit spread distribution has sizable dispersion, closer
to what we observe in the data.
In Table 12, we compare a model without credit market constraints to a model with credit
market constraints. Since with a one-period bond there is no effect on credit spreads, the
direct and the indirect effects of credit market constraints are zero. Therefore, long-term
financing is necessary for our findings.

25
The shape of bond-price schedules with long-term financing was first analyzed by Hatchondo and Martinez
(2009) and Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012) in the context of a sovereign default model without capital. Our
paper uses the insights developed in these papers to analyze how long-term financing affects misallocation of
capital.

39

Figure 6: Credit Spread Distribution: Benchmark and One-Period Bond Model

Benchmark

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

One-period Bond Model

10

0

1

2

3

Credit Spreads, in p.p.

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Credit Spreads, in p.p.

Note: The left panel shows the credit spread distribution in the benchmark model (θ = 0.085), and the right
panel shows credit spread distribution in a one-period bond model (θ = 1). Credit spreads are reported in
percentage points.

Table 12: Credit Market Constraints and TFP: One-Period Bond Model
TFP loss
Transmission
Mechanism

Model w/o
CMC

Credit Market Const. Direct Effect
Capital Adj. Costs
Indirect Effect
Equity Payout Costs Indirect Effect
Taxes
Indirect Effect
All
Direct+Indirect Effect

0.0%
1.3%
0.7%
0.6%
2.6%

Benchmark
Model
Change
0.0%
1.3%
0.7%
0.6%
2.6%

0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%

Note: TFP loss decomposition for the model with a one-period bond. To decompose total TFP loss into direct
and indirect effects, we decompose the wedge into four individual wedges that separately isolate the effect of
credit market constraints, capital adjustment costs, equity payout costs, and taxes. Then we construct the
marginal contribution of each wedge to the overall TFP loss by decomposing the variance of the overall wedge
using Equation (15).

40

Figure 7: Persistence and Misallocation
Overall TFP Loss

5

Change in TFP loss (p.p.)

without Cr. Mkt. Const.
with Cr. Mkt. Const.

4

TFP loss (p.p.)

5

3
2
1
0

Effect of Credit Market Constraints

4
3
2
1
0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

0.2

Persistence, z

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Persistence, z

Note: The left panel plots shows the relationship between the persistence of productivity (ρz ) and TFP loss.
We show the relationship in a model without credit market constraints and our benchmark model with credit
market constraints. The right panel shows the effect of credit market constraints on TFP loss. In each case,
the standard
deviation of the innovation to productivity (σεz ) is adjusted so that the unconditional variance
p
2
/ 1 − ρ2z ) is the same as our benchmark economy. All other parameters are the same.
(σεz

7.3

The Role of Persistence

A standard result in the literature is that steady-state productivity losses due to financial frictions are smaller when productivity is more persistent (Buera and Shin, 2011; Moll,
2014; Midrigan and Xu, 2014). With a higher persistence, high-productivity firms accumulate
internal funds quickly and thus they can reach their optimal scale faster. We now evaluate
how the persistence in productivity affects misallocation by varying the parameter, ρz , in our
2
so that the
benchmark economy. For each value of ρz , we adjust the conditional variance σεz
2
2
unconditional variance σεz /(1 − ρz ) remains the same as in our benchmark parameterization.
All other parameters are held fixed at their benchmark values.
Figure 7 shows the relationship between productivity persistence and TFP loss in our
model. The left panel plots TFP loss in our benchmark economy and in our model without
credit market constraints. The right panel plots the difference in TFP loss between the two
economies. The effect of persistence in our model is non-monotonic. Misallocation increases
up to ρz = 0.7 and then decreases. The decreasing part of the schedule is based on the
standard intuition provided in the literature. With higher persistence, high-productivity firms
accumulate much more internal equity and can reach their optimal scale through self-financing.
However, we find that for ρz < 0.7, persistence results in a smaller effect of credit market
constraints on misallocation. The reason is that we have a dynamic investment decision that is
different from the aforementioned literature. In particular, we assume firms make investment
decisions one period in advance, before they learn tomorrow’s productivity. In contrast, the
41

literature often models a static problem whereby firms choose the current level of capital given
current productivity. In our economy, when shocks are i.i.d. (ρz = 0), all firms choose the
same capital stock k 0 . As a result, there is no dispersion in the expected marginal product of
capital and there is no misallocation. This explains the non-monotonic relationship. If the
model was static, and firms rented capital based on their current productivity, misallocation
would be positive even with i.i.d. shocks.
In sum, our model confirms the intuition mentioned in the literature that if shocks become
very persistent, misallocation would be eliminated. But at the same time, our model highlights
a different channel that is based on the timing of investment and the realization of productivity.

8

Conclusion

Our paper evaluates the contribution of credit market constraints to misallocation in a
model with endogenous borrowing constraints, long-duration bonds, capital adjustment costs,
costly equity payouts, and taxes. Due to long-duration bonds, the model generates a realistic
distribution of credit spreads. We distinguish between the direct and indirect effects of credit
market constraints on misallocation of capital. The direct effect captures the effect of credit
market constraints on the cross-sectional variation in credit spreads. The indirect effect corresponds to how credit market constraints propagate or mitigate the effect of other frictions
or technological constraints on aggregate productivity.
The direct effect of credit market constraints increases aggregate TFP by 0.4%. This
happens because more productive firms face lower credit spreads, a relationship we confirm
in the data. In contrast, other frictions and technological constraints collectively affect highproductivity firms. As a result, credit spread variation offsets the productivity losses induced
by the existing model environment. We find that the overall effect of credit market constraints
is to decrease aggregate TFP by 1.6%, which means that the main transmission mechanism
occurs through the indirect effect.
Our exercise provides guidance for policymakers regarding the appropriate mix of policies
to reduce misallocation. First, policies that directly target credit spread variation, without
taking into account which firms have lower borrowing costs, may actually be ineffective at
reducing misallocation. Second, the bulk of misallocation occurs through the indirect effect
of credit market constraints. As a result, an effective way to reduce misallocation is to design
policies that target other frictions or technological constraints. One example is to make it
easier for firms to adjust dividends. Our paper does not explicitly evaluate such policies, but
it does highlight the transmission mechanisms that are relevant for policy design. We leave a
complete quantitative evaluation of such policies for future research.

42

References
Adrian, Tobias, Paolo Colla, and Hyun Song Shin. 2012. “Which Financial Frictions? Parsing
the Evidence from the Financial Crisis of 2007 to 2009.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual
2012, Volume 27, edited by Daron Acemoglu, Jonathan Parker, and Michael Woodford.
University of Chicago Press, 159–214.
Asker, John, Allan Collard-Wexler, and Jan De Loecker. 2014. “Dynamic Inputs and Resource
(Mis)Allocation.” Journal of Political Economy 122 (5):1013–1063.
Bai, Yan, Dan Lu, and Xu Tian. 2018. “Do Financial Frictions Explain Chinese Firms’ Saving
and Misallocation?” Working Paper.
Bernanke, Ben S., John Y. Campbell, and Toni M. Whited. 1990. “U.S. Corporate Leverage:
Developments in 1987 and 1988.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 21 (1):255–286.
Bils, Mark, Peter J. Klenow, and Cian Ruane. 2017. “Misallocation or Mismeasurement?”
Working Paper.
Brynjolfsson, Erik and Lorin M. Hitt. 2003. “Computing Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence.”
Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (4):793–808.
Buera, Francisco J. and Yongseok Shin. 2011. “Self-Insurance vs. Self-Financing: A Welfare
Analysis of the Persistence of Shocks.” Journal of Economic Theory 146:845–862.
Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 1995. “Capital Utilization and
Returns to Scale.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1995, Volume 10, edited by Ben S.
Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg. MIT Press, 67–110.
Caggese, Andrea and Vicente Cuñat. 2013. “Financing Constraints, Firm Dynamics, Export
Decisions, and Aggregate Productivity.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (1):177–193.
Chatterjee, Satyajit and Burcu Eyigungor. 2012. “Maturity, Indebtedness, and Default Risk.”
American Economic Review 102 (6):2674–2699.
Collin-Dufresne, Pierre, Robert S. Goldstein, and J. Spencer Martin. 2001. “The Determinants
of Credit Spread Changes.” Journal of Finance 56 (6):2177–2207.
Cooper, Russell and John Haltiwanger. 2006. “On the Nature of Capital Adjustment Costs.”
Review of Economic Studies 73:611–633.
Crouzet, Nicolas. 2017. “Default, Debt Maturity and Investment Dynamics.” Working Paper.
43

Driessen, Joost. 2005. “Is Default Risk Priced in Corporate Bonds?” Review of Financial
Studies 18 (1):165–195.
Duffee, Gregory R. 1998. “The Relation Between Treasury Yields and Corporate Bond Yields
Spreads.” Journal of Finance 53 (6):2225–2241.
Foster, Lucia, John Haltiwanger, and Chad Syverson. 2008. “Reallocation, Firm Turnover,
and Efficiency: Selection on Productivity or Profitability.” American Economic Review
98 (1):394–425.
Gilchrist, Simon, Jae W. Sim, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2013. “Misallocation and Financial Market
Frictions: Some Direct Evidence from the Dispersion in Borrowing Costs.” Review of
Economic Dynamics 16 (1):159–176.
———. 2014. “Uncertainty, Financial Frictions, and Investment Dynamics.” Working Paper.
Gilchrist, Simon and Egon Zakrajšek. 2012. “Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations.” American Economic Review 102 (4):1692–1720.
Gomes, Joao, Urban Jermann, and Lukas Schmid. 2016. “Sticky Leverage.” American Economic Review 106 (12):3800–3828.
Gordon, Grey and Pablo Guerron-Quintana. 2018. “Dynamics of Investment, Debt, and
Default.” Review of Economic Dynamics 28:71–95.
Gourio, François. 2013. “Credit Risk and Disaster Risk.” American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 5 (3):1–34.
Gourio, François and Nicolas Roys. 2014. “Size-Dependent Regulations, Firm Size Distribution, and Reallocation.” Quantitative Economics 5 (2):377–416.
Guner, Nezih, Gustavo Ventura, and Yi Xu. 2008. “Macroeconomic Implications of SizeDependent Policies.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4):721–744.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos and Leonardo Martinez. 2009. “Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign
Defaults.” Journal of International Economics 79 (1):117–125.
Helwege, Jean and Christopher M. Turner. 1999. “The Slope of the Credit Yield Curve for
Speculative-Grade Issuers.” Journal of Finance 54 (5):1869–1884.
Hennessy, Christopher A. and Toni M. Whited. 2007. “How Costly Is External Financing?
Evidence from a Structural Estimation.” Journal of Finance 62 (4):1705–1745.

44

Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in
China and India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4):1403–1448.
İmrohoroğlu, Ayşe and Şelale Tüzel. 2014. “Firm-Level Productivity, Risk, and Return.”
Management Science 60 (8):2073–2090.
Jermann, Urban and Vincenzo Quadrini. 2012. “Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks.”
American Economic Review 102 (1):238–271.
Kaplan, Greg and Guido Menzio. 2015. “The Morphology of Price Dispersion.” International
Economic Review 56 (4):1165–1206.
Karabarbounis, Marios. 2015. “Does Bank Lending Matter for Large Firms’ Investment?”
Economic Quarterly 101 (4):303–317.
Katagiri, Mitsuru. 2014. “A Macroeconomic Approach to Corporate Capital Structure.” Journal of Monetary Economics 66:79–94.
Khan, Aubhik and Julia K. Thomas. 2013. “Credit Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations in an
Economy with Production Heterogeneity.” Journal of Political Economy 121 (6):1055–1107.
Lintner, John. 1956. “Distribution of Incomes of Corporations Among Dividends, Retained
Earnings, and Taxes.” American Economic Review 46 (2):97–113.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1978. “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms.” The Bell Journal
of Economics 9 (2):508–523.
Midrigan, Virgiliu and Daniel Yi Xu. 2014. “Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from
Plant-Level Data.” American Economic Review 104 (2):422–458.
Moll, Benjamin. 2014. “Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-Financing
Undo Capital Misallocation?” American Economic Review 104 (10):3186–3221.
Olley, G. Steven and Ariel Pakes. 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry.” Econometrica 64 (6):1263–1297.
Reisel, Natalia. 2014. “On the Value of Restrictive Covenants: Empirical Investigation of
Public Bond Issues.” Journal of Corporate Finance 27:251–268.
Restuccia, Diego and Richard Rogerson. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity
with Heterogeneous Establishments.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4):707–720.
———. 2013. “Misallocation and Productivity.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (1):1–10.
45

Rosen, Sherwin. 1982. “Authority, Control, and the Distribution of Earnings.” The Bell
Journal of Economics 13 (2):311–323.
Sánchez, Juan M., Horacio Sapriza, and Emircan Yurdagul. 2018. “Sovereign Default and
Maturity Choice.” Journal of Monetary Economics 95:72–85.
Strebulaev, Ilya A. and Toni M. Whited. 2012. “Dynamic Models and Structural Estimation
in Corporate Finance.” Foundations and Trends in Finance 6 (1-2):1–163.

46

A

Appendix

A.1

Estimation of TFP

We estimate TFP of firm i at time t using the following specification
yit = β0 + βk kit + βl lit + zit + εit

(A.1)

To deal with issues of endogeneity and selection we employ the approach of Olley and
Pakes (1996). Their method relies on the following assumptions.
1. Labor lit is chosen at time t based on a static decision problem.
2. Capital at t + 1 depends on investment at period t: kit+1 = (1 − δ)kit + it .
3. Firm i makes the investment decision at time t based on the observed productivity
zit and the current stock of capital kit . Hence the investment policy rule is given by
iit = f (zit , kit ).
4. f is strictly monotonic in zit so that the policy rule can be inverted to obtain zit =
f −1 (iit , kit )
We assume that f −1 is a third order polynomial in iit and kit and their interaction iit kit .
Substituting into Equation (A.1) we get
yit = β0 + βk kit + βl lit + γ1 iit + γ2 i2it + γ3 i3it +
γ4 kit + γ5 kit2 + γ6 kit3 + γ7 iit kit + γ8 iit kit2 + γ9 iit kit3 + εit
(A.2)
From this regression we cannot separately identify βk from the γ’s. But given that we
have eliminated the unobserved component we can consistently estimate coefficient βl as well
as Φ̂it defined as
Φ̂it = β̂0 + βˆk kit + γˆ1 iit + γˆ2 i2it + γ̂3 i3it + γ̂4 kit + γ̂5 kit2 + γ̂6 kit3 + γ̂7 iit kit + γ̂8 iit kit2 + γ̂9 iit kit3
Given our estimates we can take the expectation of Equation (A.1)
E[yit − βl lit | χit = 1] = β0 + βk kit + E[zit | zi,t−1 χit = 1]
where χit is an indicator that the firm survived. Let E[zit | zi,t−1 χit = 1] be a function of
lagged productivity and the survival probability: g(zt−1 , P̂t ) where P̂t is the probability of
47

Table 13: Robustness

Benchmark

Leverage
Assets/Sales
Investment rate
Inaction rate (| < 1%|)
Spike rate (> 20%)
Bond amount ($million)
Maturity (years)
Mean credit spread (p.p.)
St. dev. of credit spread (p.p.)
Elasticity of credit spreads
wrt TFP
W/o controls, no FE
W/o controls, FE
W/ controls, no FE
W/ controls, FE

Merged Compustat/TR

Industry-Level Deflators

# Obs.

Mean

# Obs.

Mean

# Obs.

Mean

133,786
129,730
119,991
119,991
119,991
18,369
18,369
18,369
18,369

0.29
2.55
0.16
0.06
0.21
365.5
11.6
2.32
2.16

16,526
16,504
15,641
15,641
15,641
4,326
4,326
4,326
4,326

0.31
1.39
0.11
0.02
0.12
421.0
11.0
2.12
2.05

55,580
54,100
50,789
50,789
50,789
18,369
18,369
18,369
18,369

0.26
2.98
0.16
0.06
0.20
365.5
11.6
2.32
2.16

4,129
4,129
4,127
4,127

-0.06***
-0.37***
-0.01
-0.33***

4,129
4,129
4,127
4,127

-0.06***
-0.37***
-0.01
-0.33***

1,399
1,399
1,399
1,399

-0.42***
-0.60***
-0.40***
-0.54***

Note: This table reports a collection of statistics for three specifications: “Benchmark,” bond issuing firms in
Compustat (denoted “Merged Compustat/TR”) and a specification using industry-level deflators. One, two,
and three stars denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

survival. Olley and Pakes (1996) suggest modeling the first using Φit−1 − βk kit−1 and for the
second using the predicted probability from a probit on survival indicator on a polynomial
including capital and investment. As a result we run the following regression
yit − β̂l lit = β0 + βk kit + δ1 [Φit−1 − βk kit−1 ] + δ2 [Φit−1 − βk kit−1 ]2
We estimate Equation (A.1) using a non-linear OLS estimator and derive estimates for βk .

A.2

Robustness

We explore how our main findings vary for different sample or for different specifications.
In Table 13 we report the benchmark values which is a combination of statistics reported
in Tables 3 and 5. Column “Merged Compustat/TR” considers firms that appear in both
samples (i.e., Compustat firms that have issued at least one bond). Naturally, the number of
observations drops significantly. The most notable discrepancy occurs for the assets-to-sales
ratio which drops from 2.55 to 1.39.
However, statistics associated with bond issuance remain largely intact (with the exception

48

of average bond issuance). In particular, bonds for both publicly listed and non-publicly listed
firms have similar average maturity and average credit spread. Note that to compute the
elasticity of credit spreads to TFP we used the merged sample so by construction the first
and the second column are identical.
Finally, we check if the elasticity of credit spreads changes significantly when we us
industry-specific deflators to deflate capital. The industry-specific deflators available by the
NBER-CES database and are available at the 6-digit NAICS level but only for a subset of
industries which reduces substantially the number of our observations. There are two differences relative to our Benchmark estimates. First, even without fixed effects the elasticity of
credit spreads with respect to productivity is negative and statistically significant. Second,
the estimates with fixed effects also increase to a range closer to what our model predicts.

A.3

TFP Loss

P
To compute TFP losses, we take as given the aggregate stock of capital K = i ki0 and
P
labor N = i E[n0i (zi0 )|zi ] from the original economy and solve the following problem:
max
0 0 0

ki ,ni (zi )

X



E zi0 (ki0 )αγ (n0i (zi0 ))(1−α)γ zi

i

subject to
X

ki0 = K

i

X

E

[n0i (zi0 )|zi ]

=N

i

We are using the fact that aggregate capital and labor are constant in a stationary steady
state (i.e., K 0 = K and N 0 = N ). The solution to this problem takes into account the fact
that firms choose capital one period in advance, before they learn tomorrow’s productivity.
To maximize total expected output, we choose ki0 for each firm i and a rule for tomorrow’s
labor n0i (zi0 ) as a function of tomorrow’s realized productivity, subject to the constraint that
the total capital stock tomorrow is K and the total labor stock tomorrow is N .
Let α̂ = αγ and β̂ = (1 − α)γ. The Lagrangian for this problem is given by:

L=

XX
i

h

i

"

π(zi0 |zi ) zi0 (ki0 )α̂ (n0i (zi0 ))β̂ + λk K −

zi0

#
X
i





ki0 + λn N −

XX
i

π(zi0 |zi )n0i (zi0 )

zi0

where π(zi0 |zi ) is the probability of transitioning to zi0 , given that current productivity is zi .
49

The first order conditions are then
λk = E

h

α̂zi0 (ki0 )α̂−1 n0i (zi0 )β̂

zi

i

(A.3)

λn = β̂zi0 (ki0 )α̂ n0i (zi0 )β̂−1

(A.4)

where λk and λn are the Lagrange multipliers. The solution to this problem requires that the
expected marginal product of capital (EMPK) and the marginal product of labor (MPL) are
both equated across firms.
Solving Equations A.3 and A.4 for ki0 and n0i (zi0 ), we obtain:

ki0


=

n0i (zi0 ) =



α̂
λk
α̂
λk

β̂
 1−
1−γ

β̂
λn

α̂
 1−γ

β̂
λn

β̂
! 1−γ

E
α̂
! 1−
1−γ

h

(zi0 )1/(1−β̂)

zi

β̂
i 1−
1−γ

(A.5)

α̂
h
i 1−γ
(zi0 )1/(1−β̂) E (zi0 )1/(1−β̂) zi

(A.6)

Take expectations to get the expected value of n0i (zi0 ) tomorrow:

E

[n0i (zi0 )|zi ]


=

α̂
λk

α̂
 1−γ

Substituting Equations A.5 and A.7 into
obtain




α̂
λk
α̂
λk

β̂
λn

P

β̂
 1−
1−γ

α̂
 1−γ

i

α̂
! 1−
1−γ

E

h

(zi0 )1/(1−β̂)

ki0 = K and

β̂
λn
β̂
λn

P

i

zi

β̂
i 1−
1−γ

(A.7)

E[n0i (zi0 )] = N , respectively, we

β̂
! 1−γ

Γ=K

(A.8)

Γ=N

(A.9)

α̂
! 1−
1−γ

where
Γ≡

X

β̂
h
i 1−
1−γ
E (zi0 )1/(1−β̂) zi

i

Solving Equations A.8 and A.9 for λk and λn , we obtain
λk = α̂K α̂−1 N β̂ Γ1−γ

(A.10)

λn = β̂K α̂ N β̂−1 Γ1−γ

(A.11)

50

Substituting for λk and λn in Equation (A.5), we obtain
ki0


=

K
Γ



β̂
h
i 1−
1−γ
E (zi0 )1/(1−β̂) |zi

(A.12)

This is the capital choice which maximizes output. Similarly, we can use Equation (A.9) to
substitute for λk and λn in Equation (A.6). We then obtain an expression for labor n0i (zi0 ):
n0i (zi0 ) =

α̂
N 0 1/(1−β̂) h 0 1/(1−β̂) i 1−γ
zi
E (zi )
(zi )
Γ

(A.13)

This is the rule for labor tomorrow which maximizes output.
Given the new level of capital ki0 in Equation (A.12) and the rule for labor tomorrow n0i (zi0 )
in Equation (A.13), we can then compute TFP losses as the percentage difference between
output (with inputs allocated according to Equations A.12 and A.13) and the original level
of output.
We now derive an expression for TFP. In our benchmark economy, the optimal labor, n0i (zi0 ),
and capital policies, ki0 , for firm i are chosen to satisfy the following first order conditions:
h
i
E α̂zi0 (ki0 )α̂−1 (n0i )β̂ = r̄wik
β̂zi0 (ki0 )α̂ (n0i )β̂−1 = w̄

(A.14)
(A.15)

where w̄ is the average MPL and r̄ is the average EMPK across all firms. We impose that the
MPL will be equated across all firms, which is true in our benchmark economy. However, the
EMPK, in general, will not be equated across firms. This is represented by the firm-specific
wedge, wik , which is now the gross deviation of the firm’s EMPK from the economy-wide
average. When the EMPK is equated across all firms, wik = 1 for all i.
Equations A.14 and A.15 imply the following optimal demands for capital and labor:

ki0 =
n0i (zi0 ) =





α̂
r̄wik
α̂
r̄wik

β̂
 1−
1−γ

α̂
 1−γ

β̂
w̄
β̂
w̄

β̂
! 1−γ

β̂
h
i 1−
1−γ
1/(1−β̂)
E (zi0 )
zi

α̂
! 1−
1−γ

(zi0 )

1/(1−β̂)

α̂
h
i 1−γ
1/(1−β̂)
E (zi0 )
zi

(A.16)

(A.17)

Taking expectations of the optimal labor demand in Equation (A.17) yields

E[n0i (zi0 )|zi ] =



α̂
r̄wik

α̂
 1−γ

β̂
w̄

51

α̂
! 1−
1−γ

β̂
h
i 1−
1−γ
1/(1−β̂)
E (zi0 )
zi

(A.18)

P 0
Let K =
i ki denote the aggregate capital stock. Substituting for the optimal capital
demand from Equation (A.16) yields
β̂
  1−
α̂ 1−γ
K=
r̄

β̂
w̄

β̂
! 1−γ

ΓK

(A.19)

where
β̂
h
i  1−
1−γ
0 1/(1−β̂)
E
(z
)
|z
X
i
i


ΓK =
k
w
i
i



(A.20)

P
0 0
Similarly, let N =
i E[ni (zi )|zi ] denote the aggregate labor stock. Substituting for the
optimal expected labor demand from Equation (A.18) yields
α̂
  1−γ
α̂
N=
r̄

β̂
w̄

α̂
! 1−
1−γ

ΓN

(A.21)

where
β̂
h
i  1−
1−γ
0 1/(1−β̂)
E
(z
)
|z
X
i
i


ΓN =
k α̂/(1−β̂)
(w
)
i
i



(A.22)

Using Equations A.19 and A.21 to substitute for w̄ and r̄ in Equations A.16 and A.17, we get
i (1−β̂)/(1−γ)
h
0 1/(1−β̂)
)
|z
E
(z
i
i
K 

ki0 =
ΓK
wik
 h 1/(1−β̂) i α̂/(1−γ)
0
|zi
N 0 1/(1−β̂)  E (zi )
0 0

(zi )
ni (zi ) =
ΓN
wik


Taking expectations of n0i (zi0 ):
h
i (1−β̂)/(1−γ)
0 1/(1−β̂)
E
(z
)
|z
i
i
N 

E[n0i (zi0 )|zi ] =
ΓN
(wik )α̂/(1−β̂)


Substituting for the optimal ki0 and n0i (zi0 ) in the production function, yi0 = zi0 (ki0 )α̂ (n0i )β̂ , we

52

obtain output for each firm tomorrow:
α̂
h
i  1−γ

α̂  β̂
0 1/(1−β̂)
E (zi )
|zi
K
N
0 1/(1−β̂) 
0

yi = (zi )
k
ΓK
ΓN
wi



Taking expectations, we obtain:

E[yi0 |zi ]

E

h

=

(zi0 )1/(1−β̂)

|zi

(wik )α̂/(1−β̂)

β̂
i  1−
1−γ





K
ΓK

α̂ 

N
ΓN

β̂

Aggregating across all firms, we get
Y = AK α̂ N β̂
where A is TFP:
1−β̂ 
−α̂
β̂
β̂
i  1−
i  1−
h
h

1−γ
1−γ
0 1/(1−β̂)
0 1/(1−β̂)
|zi
|zi
X E (zi )

X E (zi )


 


 
=
k




w
(wk )α̂/(1−β̂)


A=

β̂
Γ1−
N
Γα̂K



i

i

i

i

We can compare this level of TFP to a benchmark level of TFP, in which we remove all
distortions and technological constraints are removed. In this case, wik = 1, and TFP becomes:
"
Ā =

X

E

h

1/(1−β̂)
(zi0 )

zi

β̂
i 1−
1−γ

#1−γ

i

We can then define the TFP loss as the percentage difference between Ā and A.




E

P
 i

"
#1−γ
β̂
i 1−
X h
Ā
1−γ
1/(1−
β̂)
TFP loss = − 1 =
E (zi0 )
zi

A
i
P
 i

53

1/(1−β̂)
zi0
|zi

( )

 ! 1−β̂
1−γ




wik


E

1/(1−β̂)

(zi0 )

α̂

|zi

(wik )α̂/(1−β̂)

 ! 1−β̂
1−γ

1−β̂ − 1

