View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Loan Loss Reserves, Accounting
Constraints, and Bank Ownership
Structure

WP 11-09

Eliana Balla
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Morgan J. Rose
University of Maryland, Baltimore
County

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Loan Loss Reserves, Accounting Constraints, and Bank Ownership Structure
This version: November 17, 2011
Eliana Balla1
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Morgan J. Rose
University of Maryland, Baltimore County
Working Paper No. 11-09

Abstract
This paper examines how the tightening of accounting constraints associated with the SunTrust
bank decision in 1998 impacted the loan loss reserve policies of banks differently based on
ownership structure. The SunTrust case, the result of an SEC inquiry over possible overstating
of loan loss reserves, represented a strengthening of accounting priorities, which stress the
importance of the reserve account for financial statement objectivity and comparability, relative
to supervisory priorities, which emphasize the role of reserves for bank solvency through
changing economic environments. The evidence presented indicates that publicly held banks,
which fall directly under the SECs purview, reduced their loan loss reserve and provisions
relative to privately held banks. Evidence also indicates that the positive relationship between
bank earnings and provisions weakened, consistent with a reduction in either earnings
management or early recognition of losses.

JEL classification: G21; G28; G32; E65
Keywords: Loan loss provisioning; Earnings management; Income smoothing; Ownership
structure; Financial institutions; Banking regulation.

1

We thank seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and participants at the Federal Reserve
System Committee on Financial Structure and Regulation conference for comments and Susan Maxey for excellent
research assistance. Please contact Eliana Balla at Eliana.Balla@rich.frb.org with any comments. The views
expressed belong to the authors and do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the
Federal Reserve System.

1

Section I - Introduction
A bank‟s loan loss reserve (LLR) account, also known as the allowance for loans and
leases losses (ALLL), is a contra-asset account used to reduce the value of total loans and leases
on the bank‟s balance sheet by the amount of losses that bank managers anticipate in the most
likely future state of the world.2 Provisioning is the act of building the LLR account through a
provision expense item on the income statement.3 As a relatively large accrual for commercial
banks, loan loss provisions have a significant effect on earnings and regulatory capital. 4 With
respect to LLR policy, there is a tension between what might be termed accounting priorities and
supervisory priorities.5 Accounting priorities emphasize the objectivity and comparability of
financial statements to facilitate bank monitoring. As reflected under accounting standards set
by the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB)6, an inherent credit loss should be
recognized only upon the occurrence of an event indicating that a loss is probable and if the
amount of the loss can be reasonably estimated.7 Supervisory priorities emphasize the ability of
banks to maintain solvency through changing business environments. The evaluation of the
adequacy of LLR is one of the most important functions of bank examinations.8 From the
perspective of bank supervisors, an adequate LLR is a safety and soundness issue because a
deficit in LLR implies that the bank‟s capital ratios overstate its ability to absorb unexpected
2

Economists generally view LLR as intended to capture expected future losses that will occur if a borrower does not
repay in accordance with the loan contract, a view most helpful for the pricing of loans in the secondary market.
Benston and Wall (2005) point out that if loans could be reported reliably at fair value, where fair value is value in
use, there would be no need for a loan loss provision or reserves. A market for the full transfer of credit risk does
not exist and loans cannot be reported reliably at fair value.
3
During 1992–2010, the median and mean ratios of loan loss provisions to earnings before provisions and taxes for
all U.S commercial banks (winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles) were 6.7 and 13.0 percent, respectively. During
2007-2010, those ratios were 9.4 and 22.5 percent.
4
See Ahmed et al. (1999).
5
See Wall and Koch (2000) for an extensive summary of the theoretical and empirical evidence on bank loan loss
accounting and LLR philosophies.
6
Financial Accounting Standards Board and the International Accounting Standards Board. Information for
Observers. March 2009 Meeting. Project: Loan Loss Provisioning.
7
Section II of this paper discusses regulatory and accounting standards concerning LLR policy in greater detail.
8
See Gunther and Moore (2003a and b) for a discussion of the role of bank exams for bank LLR.

2

losses.9 For the supervisory priorities to hold in practice, bank managers must incorporate into
their loan loss provisioning expectations about future losses due to changes in economic
conditions that affect credit defaults for loan losses, even if no event has yet occurred to indicate
specific estimable losses.10 The tension between objective but backward-looking historical data
on the one hand and subjective but forward-looking expectations on the other reflects a trade-off
between two laudable goals, transparency and safety and soundness.
The “incurred loss model” reflected in current LLR policy has been criticized in the
context of the recent financial crisis as contributing to the procyclicality of LLR. As with bank
regulatory capital more broadly, the concern is that with a reserving approach in which banks
have to rapidly raise reserves during bad times, the bad times could become prolonged. Laeven
and Majnoni (2003) and Bouvatier and Lepetit (2008) discuss the procyclicality of loan loss
provisions with cross-country data. They argue that banks delay provisioning for bad loans until
economic downturns have already begun, amplifying the impact of the economic cycle on banks‟
income and capital.
If loan losses are not recognized until the occurrence of specific events, then during good
economic times when fewer such events occur, LLR will be relatively low. An event-driven
approach to LLR also does not reflect the relaxation of underwriting standards and greater risktaking that often occurs in banks during a booming economy, given that most of the resulting bad
loans will only reveal themselves in a recession.11 Once adverse economic conditions arise and

9

The view that loan loss reserves serve to cover expected credit losses and capital unexpected losses is reflected in
the Basel II (2006) and Basel III(2011) capital frameworks. See Laeven and Majnoni (2003), Appendix A for a
detailed description of the conceptual relationship between loan loss reserves, provisions, capital, and earnings.
10
One way to separate the current accounting perspective from an expected loss perspective is by stating that no
expected economic impacts are taken into account in current LLR methodology. A bank manager cannot, for
example, consider the increases in default risk due to future increases in unemployment.
11
Independent of any LLR effects, stylized facts and a burgeoning literature suggest that bank lending behavior is
highly procyclical. Many explanations have been presented. The classical principal-agent problem between
shareholders and managers may lead to procyclical banking if managers‟ objectives are related to credit growth.

3

more credit impairment and default events occur, banks must quickly increase their provisioning
to raise their LLR. Requiring banks to build up reserves during an economic downturn, when
bank funds may already be otherwise strained, can compel banks to reduce lending activities,
potentially magnifying the downturn by exacerbating a credit crunch. A less procyclical LLR
policy, in which banks are able to build a buffer of loan loss reserves during boom times, could
position banks to better weather bust times, but accounting guidelines pose a constraint. Many
banks entered the financial crisis of 2007-2009 with low loan loss reserves, then had to sharply
increase provisions in recognition of pending losses, which for many banks more than offset
earnings and reduced capital. (See Figure 1.) In this manner, the banking sector may have
magnified the cycle.
In a speech in March 2009, Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve, stated that there is “considerable uncertainty regarding the appropriate levels of
loan loss reserves over the cycle. As a result, further review of accounting standards
governing…loan loss provisioning would be useful, and might result in modifications to the
accounting rules that reduce their procyclical effects without compromising the goals of
disclosure and transparency.”12 In the aftermath of the 2007-2009 experience, the Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision formally encouraged accounting regulatory bodies to pursue
a forward looking loan loss provisioning regime in the Basel III (2011) framework.13 As of the

Rajan (1994) suggests that credit mistakes are judged more leniently if they are common to the whole industry.
Berger and Udell (2003) suggest that, as the time between the current period and the last crisis increases,
experienced loan officers retire or genuinely forget about the lending errors of the last crisis and become more likely
to make “bad” loans. LLR effects may exacerbate this otherwise present procyclicality of bank lending.
12
Bernanke, Ben. Financial Reforms to Address Systemic Risk. Remarks at the Council on Foreign Relations.
Washington, D.C. March 10, 2009.
13
While Basel III (2011) explicitly builds in countercyclical capital requirements, no countercyclical provisioning
requirements are specified. Spain‟s experience with the use of loan loss provisions as a macroprudential tool
garnered attention in the policy debates of 2007-2009. See Balla and McKenna (2009) for a discussion of the
differences between the U.S. incurred loss approach and Spain‟s dynamic provisioning approach.

4

time of this writing, FASB is reconsidering its policy to potentially allow for more forwardlooking loan loss provisions.14
This paper contributes to the renewed interest in LLR policies by presenting evidence on
bank-level changes in LLR account levels and provisioning in response to a shift in the
regulatory environment. Specifically, the 1998 SunTrust decision (described below) by the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) indicated stricter enforcement of accounting
priorities relative to supervisory priorities in LLR policy, but directly affected only publicly held
banks that fall under the SEC‟s purview. By exploiting both temporal variation in regulatory
emphasis and cross-sectional variation in bank ownership structure, we can identify the effect of
the strengthening of the accounting constraint on LLR and provisioning.
Increasing reserves when earnings are high could reflect bank managers building up
reserves as a precaution against economic downturns as supervisory priorities suggest. It could
also reflect managing earnings (or “smoothing income”) across the business cycle to portray
greater earnings stability than is really the case, which is viewed as undesirable by the
accounting profession. Wall and Koch (2000) offer a review of the theoretical and empirical
evidence on earnings management via loan loss accounting. The evidence they summarize
suggests that banks have an incentive to manage reported earnings and that, while the empirical
evidence is not conclusive, several papers find that banks use loan loss accounting to manage
reported earnings.15

14

Financial Accounting Standards Board. May 26, 2010. Proposed Accounting Standards Update—―Accounting
for Financial Instruments and Revisions to the Accounting for Derivative Instruments and Hedging Activities”
15
Also see Greenwald and Sinkey (1988) and Wahlen (1994).

5

The existing literature has typically focused on publicly held banks.16 In publicly held
firms, managers may have incentives to manage earnings to maximize compensation tied to
meeting specific earnings thresholds. In addition, earnings reports provide signals to investors
and analysts and managing earnings allows managers to control the signals. It is unclear whether
privately held firms manage earnings more or less than publicly held firms. Because outside
investors have relatively less information on privately held firms, reported earnings from
privately held firms may have relatively more importance in terms of signaling, possibly giving
privately held firms greater incentives to manage earnings than publicly held firms.17 On the
other hand, assuming that equity-based compensation is less relevant for privately held firms,
managers at privately held firms will have less incentive to manage earnings in order to influence
equity value. Beatty et al. (2002) find that both public and private banks manage earnings, but
public banks manage earnings more.18 Fonseca and González (2008) provide a panel study of 40
countries (excluding the United States) and find that neither the amount of income smoothing
using loan loss provisions nor the difference in income smoothing using loan loss provisions
between public and private banks is stable across countries.19

Section II – Background on Loan Loss Reserves
Bankers desire flexibility in determining appropriate reserves in recognition of subjective
assessments of future losses. Bank regulators desire flexibility in recognition of the importance

16

See Kwan (2004) for a general discussion of differences in performance and risk taking behavior of publicly
traded vs. privately held U.S. bank holding companies.
17
See Adams (2009) on earnings management with respect to thrift IPOs.
18
Beatty et al. (2002) define “managed earnings” as more frequent announcements of small increases in earnings
than small decreases, reflecting managers‟ incentives to avoid the reporting of negative earnings when possible.
Accounting researchers define different aspects of the use of discretion in bank accounting. For another example in
differences between publicly held and privately owned banks see Nichols et al. (2009).
19
None of the above studies use samples that extend past 2002, while our sample includes the years leading up to
the financial crisis of 2007-2009.

6

of LLR for bank safety and soundness. Accounting standard setters stress the need for
transparency and comparability across banks‟ financial statements. In this section, we describe
the accounting and bank regulation policies for LLR, both in terms of specific characteristics and
the history behind these policies.
Provisioning for loan losses in the United States is accounted for under FAS Statement 5,
Accounting for Contingencies (issued in March 1973), and FAS 114, Accounting by Creditors
for Impairment of a Loan – an amendment of FASB Statements 5 and 15 (issued in May 1993).
Impaired loans evaluated under FAS 114, which provides guidance on estimating losses on loans
evaluated individually, must be valued based on the present value of cash flows discounted at the
loan‟s effective interest rate, the loan‟s observable market price, or the fair value of the loan‟s
collateral if they are collateral dependent. Loans individually evaluated under FAS 114 that are
not found to be impaired are transferred to homogenous groups of loans that share common risk
characteristics, which are evaluated under standard FAS 5. FAS 5 provides for accrual of losses
by a charge to the income statement based on estimated losses if two conditions are met:
(1) information available prior to the issuance of the financial statements indicates that it is
probable that an asset has been impaired or a liability has been incurred at the date of the
financial statement, and
(2) the amount of the loss can be reasonably estimated.20
Both FAS 114 and 5 allow banks to include environmental or qualitative factors in
consideration of loan impairment analysis. Examples of these factors include, but are not limited
to, underwriting standards, credit concentration, staff experience, local and national economic
business conditions. In addition, FAS 5 allows for the use of loss history in impairment

20

Financial Accounting Standards Board, Summary of Statement No. 5: Accounting for Contingencies, March
1973.

7

analysis.21 These elements provide bankers with flexibility in determining the level of provisions
taken against incurred losses when they are well substantiated by relevant data or documentation
required by supervisors and accountants. Banks identify losses by categorizing loans based on
their payment status (i.e. current, 30 days past due, 60 days past due, etc.) and the severity of
delinquency (which can vary by asset class) and assess whether a provision should be taken on
loans they expect to experience a loss, if the loss is probable and estimable.22
The Basel Accord of 1988 set current rules for bank capital regulation and the role of
LLR in capital regulation. In 1991, FDICIA enacted these changes into law. LLR were no
longer counted as a component of Tier 1 capital but were counted toward Tier 2 capital, up to
1.25 percent of the bank‟s risk-weighted assets. So if a bank increases its LLR, the effect is to
increase Tier 2 capital while reducing retained earnings and Tier 1 capital.23 If, as a result of this
transfer, Tier 1 regulatory thresholds become binding, (usually in bad economic times), bank
supervisors would require the bank to issue more capital or reduce its measured risk. Laeven and
Majnoni (2003) have argued that since 1991 “…from the perspective of compliance with
regulatory capital requirements, it became much more effective for U.S. banks to allocate income
to retained earnings (entirely included in Tier 1 capital) than to loan loss reserves (only partially
included in Tier 2 capital).”24
The SEC‟s ruling on the earnings restatement for SunTrust bank in 1998 reflected
increased concerns at this organization that publicly traded U.S. bank holding companies were
using loan loss provisions to manage reported earnings. The SEC and bank regulators entered a
21

SR 06-17: Interagency Policy Statement on the ALLL, December 13, 2006. SR 01-17: Policy Statement on ALLL
Methodologies and Documentation for Banks and Savings Institutions, July 2, 2001. SR 99-22: Joint Interagency
Letter on the Loan Loss Allowance, July 26, 1999.
22
See Walter (1991) for an explanation of how banks identify and categorize defaults.
23
Ahmed et al. (1999) provide evidence that, in line with reduced incentives in the new regulatory regime of risk
based capital, banks engaged in less capital management through loan loss provisions in 1991-1995 compared to
1985-1990.
24
Laeven and Majnoni (2003), p. 194.

8

period of dialogue reflected in interagency letters to banks in November 1998, March 1999, and
July 1999.25 The stance of the interagency communications is one of “prudent, conservative, but
not excessive” LLR.
Throughout the sample period we study, banking regulators have remained concerned
with the role that loan losses and banks‟ reserves for losses play in insolvency risk. Banking
regulator comments following the SunTrust ruling continued to emphasize the importance of
building a LLR cushion during good economic times. Former Comptroller of the Currency John
Dugan reiterated that same point in 2009 stating that
…banking supervisors love the loan loss reserve. When used as intended, it
allows banks to recognize an estimated loss on a loan or portfolio of loans when
the loss becomes likely, well before the amount of the loss can be determined
with precision and is actually charged off. That means banks can be realistic about
recognizing and dealing with credit problems early, when times are good, by
building up a large „war chest‟ of loan loss reserves. Later, when the loan losses
crystallize, the fortified reserve can absorb the losses without impairing capital,
keeping the bank safe, sound, and able to continue extending credit.26
But accounting guidelines, as enforced subsequent to the SunTrust decision, may have limited
the ability of loan loss reserves to function in the way summarized by Comptroller Dugan.

Section III – Hypotheses

25

The full text of these interagency letters can be found at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/bankinforeg/srletters/srletters.htm
26
Dugan, John. Loan Loss Provisioning and Procyclicality. Remarks before the Institute of International Bankers.
March 2, 2009.

9

Based on the preceding discussion, in this paper we empirically test the following
hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1a: Following the SunTrust decision, the level of loan loss reserves of
publicly held banks declined relative to that of privately held banks.
Hypothesis 1b: The level of loan loss reserves of privately held banks was unaffected by
the SunTrust decision.
By requiring a stricter adherence to accounting rules on the part of banks subject to SEC
oversight, the SunTrust decision constrained the ability of publicly held banks to use loan loss
management during times of positive earnings to either smooth income or prudentially increase
loan loss reserves as a precaution against future downturns. Privately held banks are not subject
to SEC oversight, and so their loan loss management need not have been affected. However, if
bank supervisors incorporated the requirements of the SunTrust decision into the rules applicable
to all banks, then privately held banks may also have been forced to reduce their levels of
reserves following the decision. Hypothesis 1a implies that the SunTrust decision placed more
binding constraints on publicly held banks than on privately held banks, but allows for
constraints of at least some degree on privately held banks. Hypothesis 1b implies that the
SunTrust decision did not impose binding constraints on privately held banks.
Hypothesis 2a: Following the SunTrust decision, provisioning for loan losses by publicly
held banks declined relative to that of privately held banks.
Hypothesis 2b: Provisioning for loan losses of privately held banks was unaffected by
the SunTrust decision.
Hypotheses 2a and 2b are based on the same rationale as Hypotheses 1a and 1b, only
applied to banks‟ provisions for loan losses rather than their overall levels of loan loss reserves.

10

Hypothesis 3a: Following the SunTrust decision, the relationship between pre-provision
earnings and loan loss provisions for publicly held banks weakened relative to that for privately
held banks.
Hypothesis 3b: The relationship between pre-provision earnings and loan loss
provisions for privately held banks was unaffected by the SunTrust decision.
If banks increase loan loss provisioning when earnings are high, as a means to either
maximize executive compensation or increase loan loss reserves as a buffer against future loan
losses, our empirical analysis should find a positive relationship between pre-provision earnings
and loan loss provisions. If the stricter adherence to accounting rules associated with the
SunTrust decision constrained the ability of banks to engage in such loan loss management, then
that positive relationship will be weaker following the decision. Publicly held banks are directly
subject to SEC oversight, suggesting that the relationship between earning and provisions should
weaken more dramatically for publicly held banks than for privately held banks, as stated in
Hypothesis 3a. Hypothesis 3b implies that the SunTrust decision did not impose binding
constraints on the ability of privately held banks to manage earnings via loan loss accounting.
Note that based on the discussion in the previous sections, there is reason to think that the
relationship between earnings and provisions should weaken more for privately held banks than
for publicly held banks, in contradiction to Hypotheses 3a and 3b. If prior to the SunTrust
decision privately held banks had greater incentives to engage in loan loss management due to
their greater asymmetric information, and if bank supervisors incorporated the requirements of
the SunTrust decision into the rules applicable to all banks, then the constraints imposed after the
SunTrust decision would be more binding for privately held banks than for publicly held banks.
Stated differently, if prior to the SunTrust decision SEC oversight and market analyst coverage

11

already constrained publicly held banks from loan loss management, then the additional
constraints that followed the SunTrust decision would primarily affect the behavior of privately
held banks.

Section IV– Data and Methodology
The data for this paper come primarily from banking regulatory databases. Our first task
was to identify publicly traded banking institutions. Using a mapping maintained by the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York (the mapping is valid from January 1990 to December 2007), we
identify supervised banking institutions that are listed on the NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ.27
Because we are interested in all banking companies that file with the SEC, and not just the ones
traded in the three largest exchanges, we use SNL Financial to identify additional publicly traded
banking institutions.
While equity offerings are made at the holding company level, reserving policies are
generally set at the bank level. Both because managerial decisions on LLR are made at the bank
level and for data completeness (small bank holding companies report less frequently and not on
a consolidated basis), we use bank-level financial data from regulatory filings (Call Reports).
We obtain structure data on relationships between holding companies and banks, as well as data
on firm age, bank mergers and acquisitions, and failures, from Federal Reserve databases. If the
bank holding company or the top holding company (one layer removed from the bank) were
traded publicly, we consider the bank publicly held.
Our sample period begins in the first quarter of 1992, when the current rules for how
loan loss reserves enter into bank capital first went into effect, and ends in the second quarter of

27

The mapping is available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/banking_research/datasets.html.

12

2007.28 Both loan loss reserves and provisions increased dramatically during the recent financial
crisis (see Figure 1), which could skew our results if included in the sample. From this initial
sample, we drop banks located outside of the continental United States and banks that are not
active lenders, which we define as banks for which total loans never exceeds 5 percent of total
assets. We remove outliers by dropping observations for which the value of any of the ratio
variables defined below is beyond four standard deviations from that variable‟s mean value.29
Taken together, these sample criteria eliminate approximately 1.4 percent of the original
observations. The final dataset includes over 500,000 bank-quarter observations from 13,317
banks. As consolidation in the banking industry progressed through our sample period, the
number of banks declined from 11,400 in 1992 to 6,889 in 2007. Approximately 73 percent of
our sample banks are privately held throughout the sample period and 16 percent are publicly
held throughout the sample period. The remainder switch ownership structure, with the vast
majority switching from private to public.
Table 1 presents summary statistics for the variables used in the empirical analysis. The
dependent variables are loan loss reserves (LLR) and provisions for loan losses (PLL). Two of
the key explanatory variables for testing our hypotheses are an indicator equaling one in quarters
following the SunTrust decision (AfterST) and an indicator equaling one for publicly traded
banks or banks owned by publicly traded holding companies (Public). As the mean value of
0.49 shows, AfterST splits the dataset into almost equally sized subsamples. The percentage of
banks that were publicly held at the start of our sample was 18 percent, reached a high of 20
percent in 1994, and then declined steadily to a low of 11 percent in 2007. Figure 2 provides

28

Both the tax and capital regulatory regimes are constant throughout this sample. The last change to tax treatment
for loan loss provisions occurred in 1986. Note that some financial data from 1990 and 1991 are used to construct
lagged variables.
29
See Holod and Peek (2007).

13

greater detail on the distribution of Public over our sample, for all sample banks and for banks
divided by size at $1 billion and $10 billion in total assets.
Other explanatory variables include controls for bank balance sheet and income statement
variables relevant to loan losses, as well as controls for broader bank characteristics and
macroeconomic activity. Non-performing loans (NPTL)30 is a proxy for poor asset quality, and
is expected to be positively associated with LLR and PLL. The change in total loans (ΔLoans)
could be negatively associated with LLR and PLL if loan growth indicates an expansion of
profitable investment opportunities due to expected economic growth, or it could be positively
associated with LLR and PLL if loan growth indicates deteriorating underwriting quality.31 A
positive relationship between earnings before provisioning (EBP) and PLL would indicate that
banks on average increase their loan loss provisioning and reserves when earnings are higher,
consistent with both income smoothing and precautionary loan loss management. Shareholder
equity (EQ) captures firm capital structure, and could be positively or negatively related to LLR
depending on whether capital management is a complement or a substitute for loan loss
management. EQ should be negatively related to PLL as provisions directly influence total
equity by reducing net income. Balance sheet variables (LLR, NPTL, ΔLoans, and EQ) are
expressed as percentages of total assets from the previous quarter. Income statement variables
(PLL and EBP) are expressed as percentages of average assets from the previous quarter.
Average net charge-offs as a percentage of average assets over the previous eight quarters (NCO)
reflects bank use of historical loan losses in assessing future loan losses, and it is expected to be
positively associated with LLR and PLL.

30
31

Non-performing loans refers to the sum of loans 90+ days past due and those in a nonaccrual status.
See Keeton (1999) and Foos et al. (2010).

14

Bank size (Size) is measured as the natural log of bank total assets (in thousands) from
the previous quarter. The percentage change in real GDP over the previous quarter (ΔGDP),
obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis, proxies for economic growth. Three
indicator variables capture events in the life cycle of a bank that may be associated with atypical
loan loss reserves and provisioning. DeNovo equals one in the first five years of a bank‟s life.
Fail equals one in the final quarter of a bank‟s existence and the previous three quarters. Merger
equals one if the bank merged with another firm during the current quarter. All specifications
also include quarter indicator variables to control for seasonality, a quadratic time trend, and a
constant term.
To conduct the empirical analysis we use panel estimation with random effects at the
bank level. Laeven and Majnoni (2003) and Fonseca and González (2008) both use the GMM
estimation technique developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) to examine dynamic models of
loan loss provisioning, but the large number of instruments required combined with the size of
our dataset (two orders of magnitude greater than those authors‟ datasets) makes that technique
computationally intractable here. Laeven and Majnoni (2003) present results from both panel
estimation with random effects and Arellano-Bond estimation, with similar results across the two
models.32 They also find evidence of second-order correlation in the first-differenced errors for
their U.S. bank sample, suggesting that Arellano-Bond estimates for that sample may be biased.
Due to computing constraints we were unable to employ Arellano-Bond estimation for our full
dataset, but when we did for randomly selected subsets of our dataset we also consistently found
evidence of second-order correlation. For comparability with the previous literature we use

32

Specifically, in their pooled international sample, all of their explanatory variables have the same signs and levels
of significance across the two models. In their sample of U.S. banks only, their coefficient estimate for loan growth
changes sign across models, but all other explanatory variables retain their signs and levels of significance. Our
sample contains only U.S. banks.

15

panel estimation with random effects rather than fixed effects. As discussed in the next section,
in unreported work we repeated all of our analyses using fixed effects and find similar results
throughout.

Section V – Empirical Analysis
Section V.1 – Univariate Analysis
Table 2 presents results of univariate analyses of the means of LLR (Panel A) and PLL
(Panel B) for publicly held and privately held banks before and after the SunTrust decision. The
first row of Panel A shows that prior to the SunTrust decision, the level of loan loss reserves for
publicly held banks was on average 0.192 percent of assets higher than the level for privately
held banks. That difference in means is statistically significant, and is economically substantial
given the overall sample mean LLR of 0.933 percent of assets. Hypothesis 1a predicts that this
difference should decrease following the SunTrust decision, and that prediction is borne out in
the second row. The post-SunTrust difference in means is less than half the size of pre-SunTrust
difference, and the magnitude of the drop is more than 30 times the standard error of either
difference. Hypothesis 1b predicts that mean LLR for privately held banks should be the same
before and after the SunTrust decision, but the second column of Panel B indicates a significant
decline in mean LLR across periods.
Panel B of Table 2 shows the same analysis for PLL, with similar results. The difference
in means in the first row is 0.093 percent of assets, quite substantial relative to the overall sample
mean PLL of 0.215. The difference in means in the second row of Panel B is smaller than that in
the first row, with the magnitude of the drop being about seven times greater than either standard
error. This is consistent with Hypothesis 2a. The second column of Panel B indicates that mean

16

PLL for privately held banks increased following the SunTrust decision, which is inconsistent
with Hypothesis 2b and with our larger supposition that if the SunTrust decision had any effect
on the provisioning of privately held banks it should have decreased mean PLL. This
inconsistency with expectations emphasizes the need for multivariate analysis.

Section V.2 – Multivariate Analysis
Table 3 presents results from panel estimations using LLR as the dependent variable. The
key variables of interest are Public, AfterST, and their interaction. Models 1 and 2 employ
sample periods before and after the SunTrust decision, respectively. Hypothesis 1 predicts that
the coefficient estimate for Public is smaller in the post-SunTrust period than in the pre-SunTrust
period. The coefficient estimate for Public in model 1 indicates that prior to the SunTrust
decision the level of loan loss reserves of publicly held banks was greater than that of privately
held banks by 0.136 percent of assets. This is an economically substantial difference across
ownership structures, equal to 16 percent of the sample median LRR (0.136 / 0.848). In model 2,
the coefficient estimate drops nearly in half to 0.072 percent of assets (8.5 percent of the sample
median), consistent with Hypothesis 1a. The signs of the estimates for the other explanatory
variables here and in subsequent tables are consistent with expectations. The positive
coefficients for ΔLoans suggest that loan growth is associated with declining credit quality.
Models 3 and 4 separate the sample into publicly held and privately held banks. The
coefficient estimates for AfterST indicate that both publicly held and privately held banks on
average had lower levels of loan loss reserves in the period following the SunTrust decision.
The point estimate for publicly held banks is twice as large (in absolute value) as the one for

17

privately held banks, consistent with Hypothesis 1a, while the negative and significant result for
privately held banks is inconsistent with Hypothesis 1b.
The explanatory variables in models 3 and 4 exhibit a pattern that persists in all of the
remaining analyses in the paper. NCO is positive and significant in both models, but the point
estimate for privately held banks is substantially greater than that for publicly held banks. NPTL
is also positive in both models, but the point estimate is greater for publicly held banks. These
results suggest that loan loss reserves at privately held banks are relatively more responsive to
trends in historical loan losses (a more backward-looking metric), while reserves at publicly held
banks are relatively more responsive to current changes in non-performing loans (a metric for
expected future loan losses).
Models 5 through 8 use the full sample for more direct estimates of the effect of the
SunTrust decision on loan loss reserves across ownership structures. Public remains positive,
with magnitudes ranging between 10.7 percent and 13.6 percent of the sample median LLR. The
estimates for AfterST in models 5 and 7 indicate that on average, reserves were lower by about
0.015 percent of assets in the post-SunTrust period. While highly statistically significant, the
economic significance is more modest, equaling 1.7 percent of the sample median LLR. Model
8, which includes the interaction of Public and AfterST, directly tests Hypotheses 1a and 1b.
Public*AfterST is negative and significant, consistent with the level of loan loss reserves for
publicly held banks declining relative to loan loss reserves for privately held banks following the
SunTrust decision as predicted by Hypothesis 1a. AfterST is no longer significant at
conventional levels, suggesting that for privately held banks, the SunTrust decision had no effect
on loan loss reserves, as predicted by Hypothesis 1b. The reduction in LLR associated with
AfterST in models 5 and 7 appears to be concentrated exclusively among publicly held banks.

18

Based on the coefficient estimate for Public*AfterST, publicly held banks lowered their loan loss
reserves by an amount equal to 6 percent of the sample median LLR in the wake of the SunTrust
decision.
One concern with the findings in Table 3 is that, given our lengthy sample period,
AfterST could reflect changes to loan loss reserves other than those related to the SunTrust
decision. Lingering effects of the savings and loan crisis and the recession in the early 1990s,
the 2001 recession, the 2001 SR letter (which was the end point for the dialogue between the
SEC and banking regulators initiated with the 1998 and 1999 interagency letters – see Section
II), or other phenomena could all affect the pattern of loan loss reserves (or provisioning,
discussed below) over time and so be captured by AfterST. To address this concern, we
performed the analyses of Table 3 again using a much narrower sample period, including just
eight quarters before and after the SunTrust decision. Results from these specifications are
presented in Table 4. The pattern of results is extremely similar to those in Table 3. The
coefficient estimate for Public again declines by just under half from model 1 to model 2,
consistent with Hypothesis 1a. The absolute value of the point estimate for AfterST is again
nearly twice as large in model 3 as in model 4, although neither is statistically significant.
Public*AfterST is negative and significant in model 8, consistent with Hypothesis 1a. The
absolute value of the point estimate for Public*AfterST is lower in Table 4, but still implies a
reduction in loan loss reserves of publicly held banks equal to 4.4 percent of the sample median
following the SunTrust decision. AfterST is not significant in model 4 or 8, consistent with
Hypothesis 1b. Results for the explanatory variables are also similar, although in Table 4 several
drop in significance, plausibly due to the reduction in both the number of observations and the
variation in some variables over the shorter time horizon.

19

Table 5 presents specifications similar to those of Table 3 using the full sample period,
but with PLL as the dependent variable in order to test Hypotheses 2a and 2b. Hypothesis 2a
predicts that the coefficient estimate for Public should decrease from model 1 (the pre-SunTrust
period) to model 2 (the post-SunTrust period), and this prediction is confirmed. There was no
statistically significant difference in provisioning across ownership structure in the pre-SunTrust
period, but in the post-SunTrust period provisioning by publicly held banks was 0.0202 percent
of assets lower than provisioning by privately held banks. This difference is economically
substantial, equaling 17 percent of the sample median PLL (0.0202 / 0.119). Models 3 through 7
indicate that, on average, provisioning was higher after the SunTrust decision than before, and
over the entire sample period publicly held banks had lower provisioning than privately held
banks. Model 8 includes the interaction term Public*AfterST, which is negative and significant
and therefore is consistent with Hypothesis 2a. The coefficient estimate on AfterST is positive
and significant in models 4 and 8, which is consistent with Table 2 but contradicts the prediction
of Hypothesis 2b that provisioning by privately held banks was unaffected by the SunTrust
decision.
The coefficient estimate for Public*AfterST in model 8 indicates that following the
SunTrust decision, loan loss provisions of publicly held banks were on average 0.0483 percent of
average assets lower than those of privately held banks each quarter. While this difference
appears quite small as a percentage of assets, its magnitude is equal to 40.6 percent of the sample
median PLL, nearly a full standard deviation, clearly an economically significant adjustment of
provisioning policy. If publicly held banks had not reduced their provisioning relative to
privately held banks following the SunTrust decision, they would likely have had substantially
higher reserves to better absorb the impact of the recent financial crisis.

20

Table 6 repeats the analyses of Table 5 using the narrower sample period of eight
quarters before and after the SunTrust decision. A few differences between Tables 5 and 6 are
noteworthy. The point estimates for Public drop from model 1 to model 2 in Table 6, but in
neither specification is the estimate significant. The estimate for Public*After in model 8
remains negative, consistent with the prediction of Hypothesis 2a. AfterST switches from
positive in Table 5 to negative in most models of Table 6, suggesting that an increase in
provisioning associated with the 2001 recession may explain the positive coefficients found
using the full sample period. AfterST is not significant for privately held banks in model 4,
consistent with Hypothesis 2b; however, it is negative in model 6, which is inconsistent with
Hypothesis 2b and suggests that provisioning by privately held banks decreased after the
SunTrust decision, possibly influenced by their supervisory agencies.
With only one exception, the coefficient estimates for EBP are positive and significant
across all models in Tables 5 and 6, indicating that banks increase their provisions for loan losses
as their pre-provisioning income increases. As described above, this could indicate the use of
provisioning to either smooth income or create an additional cushion in loan loss reserves against
future losses. The exception, an insignificant result in model 3 of Table 6, suggests that publicly
held banks may not have managed earnings via provisioning as described above, at least during
the narrow sample period around the SunTrust decision.
Tables 7 and 8 include interactions of EBP with Public and AfterST to examine further
how the relationship between earnings and provisions for loan losses differed across ownership
structures and periods. In models 1 and 2 of Table 7, the estimates for EBP*Public indicate no
significant differences in earnings management via provisioning across ownership structures in
either the pre- or post-SunTrust period. Models 3 and 4 indicate that following the SunTrust

21

decision, the relationship between provisions and earnings weakened for privately held banks but
not for publicly held banks, contradicting Hypotheses 3a and 3b. A plausible explanation is that
even prior to the SunTrust decision, SEC oversight, disclosure requirements, and market analyst
coverage limited the potential usefulness of earnings management for publicly held banks, so the
stricter accounting rules following the SunTrust decision may not have been binding. Privately
held banks, with relatively more asymmetric information between insiders and outsiders and
therefore more ability to influence investor perceptions through signaling, may have stronger
incentives to manage earnings. Such firms may have been influenced to reduce earnings
management via loan loss provisioning in the wake of the SunTrust decision.
Models 5 through 8 use the full sample, exploiting variation in both ownership structure
and sample period. EBP*Public is consistently negative, indicating that earnings management
via provisioning is more prevalent among privately held banks than publicly held banks. This
suggests that the greater scope for asymmetric information among privately held firms, which
can increase the potency of signals from earnings reports, provides greater incentives for
earnings management relative to the incentives of publicly held firms. EBP*AfterST is also
consistently negative, suggesting that the stricter adherence to accounting rules following the
SunTrust decision was effective at reducing the extent of earnings management via loan loss
provisioning. Comparing the coefficient estimates for EBP and EBP*AfterST from model 6
implies that the average amount of provisioning associated with one extra dollar of pre-provision
income dropped by 45 percent (-0.0201 / 0.0446) after the SunTrust decision. A Wald test
rejects the hypothesis that the sum of those two coefficient estimates equals zero, suggesting that
although the relationship between earnings and provisioning weakened after the SunTrust
decision, it was not eliminated entirely. The coefficient estimates for EBP and EBP*AfterST

22

from models 7 and 8 show similar drops in earnings management following the SunTrust
decision. In model 8, EBP*Public*AfterST is not significant, suggesting that the weakening of
the relationship between earnings and provisions following the SunTrust decision was not
concentrated among firms of one ownership structure or the other, contradicting Hypothesis 3a.
Table 8 uses the same specifications as Table 7 for the narrower sample period. The
pattern of results is similar to that found in Table 7, except that several coefficient estimates drop
in significance. Public*AfterST remains significant in some models, but other variables that
relate to AfterST are not significant in any model. The lack of significance for EBP*AfterST in
models 4 and 8 is consistent with Hypothesis 3b, but in light of most variables involving AfterST
being insignificant, the results may be more reflective of the limited sample period than of the
hypothesis.
Overall, Tables 3-8 provide strong support for Hypotheses 1a and 2a. The SunTrust
decision is associated with statistically and economically significant reductions in loan loss
reserves and provisioning among publicly held banks relative to privately held banks. The
evidence regarding Hypotheses 1b and 2b are more mixed. From some specifications, privately
held banks do not appear to have experienced significant reductions in loan loss reserves or
provisioning following the SunTrust decision, but other specifications indicate reductions in
both. Neither Hypothesis 3a nor 3b are supported by the evidence. The relationship between
bank earnings and provisioning does appear to have weakened following the SunTrust decision,
but if anything the weakening was concentrated among privately held banks, not publicly held
ones.

Section V.3 – Robustness Checks

23

We performed several additional analyses to check the robustness of our findings. (These
results are all available upon request.) As noted above, the reported results are based on panel
regressions with random effects for consistency with previous literature. When we use fixed
effects instead, the results are very similar. The main variable of interest that changes is Public.
It loses significance in model 2 of Table 3 and all models of Table 5. In Tables 6 and 8, Public is
positive in all models except model 2. Public also becomes positive in model 8 of Table 7. In
addition, AfterST becomes negative in model 4 of Tables 4 and 6, Public*AfterST becomes
negative in model 6 of Table 8, and EBP loses significance in the first two models of Table 8.
Because our hypotheses rest on comparisons across sample periods, it is possible that the
quadratic time trend included in all specifications could influence our findings. To address this
concern, we performed the analyses without the time trend variables. As might be expected,
AfterST is the key variable that is most affected. AfterST becomes positive and significant in
most models in Table 3, in models 4 and 8 of Table 4, and in models 5 through 7 in Table 8. It
loses significance in models 5 and 7 of Table 4, models 3 and 4 of Table 5, all models in Table 6,
and model 3 of Table 7. In addition, Public loses significance in Table 5, becomes positive in
model 8 of Table 7, and Public*AfterST loses significance in model 8 of Table 7. We also
repeated the analyses for Tables 3, 5, and 7 after omitting the observations for 1999, on the
premise that banks may have required multiple quarters to fully adjust their provisioning policies
following the SunTrust decision.33 AfterST is no longer significant in Table 3, Public is no
longer significant in model 2 of Table 5, and Public and EBP*Public are no longer significant in
models 5 and 7 of Table 7.

33

We do not perform this robustness check for Tables 4, 6 and 8 because doing so would entail dropping a quarter
of the total observations.

24

The level of loan loss reserves could plausibly affect the subsequent magnitudes of loan
loss provisions, but including a lagged value of LLR as an explanatory variable in Tables 5 and 6
does not alter the results. Including lagged LLR causes Public to lose significance in Table 7,
and Public*After to lose significance in model 7 of Table 8. In recognition that banks may
consider more than two years of historical loan losses when determining current provisions, we
altered NCO to equal average net charge-offs over the previous 12 quarters instead of eight. In
Table 3 this results in AfterST losing significance in models 3 through 7 and becoming positive
in model 6. In Table 4, AfterST loses significance in model 4. Changing NCO did not affect
Tables 5 or 6. Public lost significance in Table 7, while Public*After became negative in model
6 of Table 8.
The analyses were repeated using only banks with assets under $10 billion to determine
whether the paper‟s results are driven by a small number of banks whose scale and scope of
operations may be qualitatively different from those of smaller banks. Dropping the largest
banks causes only limited changes to the variables of interest. AfterST becomes negative in
model 8 of Table 3 and loses significance in model 8 of Table 6. Public becomes positive in
model 8 of both Tables 7 and 8. Public*AfterST loses significance in model 8 of Table 7 and
becomes negative in model 6 of Table 8, and EBP*Public becomes negative in model 8 of Table
8. It is also possible that the approximately 3 percent of publicly traded banks that are not on any
of the three largest exchanges (NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ) are not representative of the 97
percent that are. Dropping the observations for publicly traded banks not on one of the major
exchanges caused no changes in Tables 3 through 5. AfterST loses significance in model 8 of
Table 6. Public is no longer significant in Table 7, and EBP*Public loses significance in model
8 of Table 7. In Table 8, Public*AfterST becomes negative in model 6.

25

Our provisioning results could be influenced by a quarterly pattern in the percentage of
observations with loan loss provisioning equal to zero. Nearly 29 percent of first-quarter
observations show a provision of zero, and that percentage declines steadily to around 15 percent
of fourth-quarter observations. Zero could be the most appropriate provision value for a given
bank in a given quarter, but a zero provision could also indicate a bank that as a matter of policy
provisions less frequently than quarterly. To try to minimize the effect of zero provisioning as a
matter of policy without dropping all zero provisioning observations, we repeated the analyses
using only fourth-quarter observations, the rationale being that if a bank provisions only in one
quarter during the year, anecdotal evidence and the sample characteristics just described suggest
that it is likeliest to provision in the fourth quarter. AfterST is not significant in model 7 of Table
3, is positive in most models of Tables 4 and 6, and is negative in model 5 of Table 8. Public
loses significance in model 2 of Table 5 and throughout Table 8. It becomes positive throughout
Table 6, and becomes negative in models 1 and 8 of Table 5, and in model 6 of Table 7.
Public*After loses significance in most models of Tables 7 and 8. EBP*Public loses
significance in model 5 of Table 7 and throughout Table 8.
Summarizing the robustness checks with respect to our main hypotheses, the results for
the variable with which we test Hypotheses 1a and 2a, Public*AfterST, do not change in Tables 3
through 6 in any of the robustness checks described above, consistently supporting both
hypotheses. The variable‟s results do change in Tables 7 and 8, sometimes losing significance
(weakening support for Hypothesis 2a) and sometimes becoming negative and significant
(strengthening support for Hypothesis 2a). EBP*Public*AfterST remains insignificant in all of
our robustness checks, consistently contradicting Hypothesis 3a.

26

Section VI – Conclusion
This paper examines how the tightening of accounting constraints associated with the
SunTrust decision impacted the loan loss reserve policies of banks differently based on
ownership structure. The SunTrust decision, being the result of an SEC inquiry, placed more
binding constraints on publicly held bank than on privately held banks. The evidence presented
here indicates that, all else equal, publicly held banks held higher levels of loan loss reserves as a
percentage of assets relative to privately held banks, but the difference across ownership
structures significantly narrowed following the SunTrust decision. Publicly held banks lowered
both their levels of loan loss reserves and their provisioning for loan losses relative to privately
held banks. Evidence also indicates that the positive relationship between bank earnings and
loan loss provisioning weakened in the wake of the SunTrust decision, consistent with a
reduction in either income smoothing or early recognition of loan losses during good economic
times. That weakening appears concentrated among privately held banks, potentially due to
privately held banks having relatively greater incentive to manage earnings, and so constraints on
earnings management are more binding for privately held banks than publicly held banks.
Together, these findings suggest that the stricter accounting constraints associated with the
SunTrust decision contributed to an overall lowering of loan loss reserves in the years leading up
to the recent financial crisis. In the aftermath of the 2007-2009 experience, the Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision has incorporated countercyclical tools, including strong
recommendations for forward-looking loan loss provisions, in the new Basel III capital
framework. The experience of the 1990s described in this paper suggests that banker incentives
may well be aligned for a move to a more forward-looking loan loss provisioning approach.

27

References
Adams, B., Carow, K.A., Perry, T., 2009. Earnings management and initial public offerings:
The case of the depository institution. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 2363-2372.
Ahmed, A.S., Takeda, C., Thomas, S., 1999. Bank loan loss provisions: A reexamination of
capital management, earnings management, and signaling effects. Journal of Accounting and
Economics 28, 1-25.
Arrellano, M., Bond S. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence
and an application to employment equation. Review of Economic Studies, 58. 277-297.
Balla, E. McKenna, A. 2009. Dynamic Provisioning: A Countercyclical tool for loan loss
reserves. Economic Quarterly Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Fall, 383-418.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2011. Basel III: a Global Regulatory Framework for
More Resilient Banks and Banking Systems.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2006. Basel II: International convergence of capital
measurement and capital standards: A revised framework - comprehensive version.
Beatty, A.L., Ke, B., Petroni, K.R., 2002. Earnings management to avoid earnings declines
across publicly and privately held banks. The Accounting Review 77, 547-570.
Benston, G.J., Wall, L.D., 2005. How should banks account for loan losses? Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, Fourth Quarter, 19-38.
Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 2003. The institutional memory hypothesis and the procyclicality of
bank lending behavior. Journal of Financial Intermediation 13, 458-495.
Bernanke, Ben. Financial reforms to address systemic risk. Remarks before the Council on
Foreign Relations, Washington, D.C., March 10, 2009.
Bouvatier, V., Lepetit, L., 2008. Banks‟ procyclical behavior: Does provisioning matter?
Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money 18, 513-526.
Dugan, J. Loan loss provisioning and procyclicality. Remarks before the Institute of
International Bankers, Washington, D.C., March 2, 2009.
Financial Accounting Standards Board, March 1973. Summary of Statement No. 5: Accounting
for contingencies.
Financial Accounting Standards Board, May 1993. Statement of Financial Accounting
Standards No. 114: Accounting by Creditors for Impairment of a Loan – an amendment of
FASB Statements No. 5 and 15.

28

Financial Accounting Standards Board. May 26, 2010. Proposed Accounting Standards
Update—―Accounting for Financial Instruments and Revisions to the Accounting for Derivative
Instruments and Hedging Activities.”
Fonseca, A.R., Gonzalez, F., 2008. Cross-country determinants of bank income smoothing by
managing loan-loss provisions. Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 217-228.
Foos, D., Norden, L., Weber, M., 2010. Loan growth and riskiness of banks. Journal of Banking
and Finance 34, 2929-2940.
Greenwald, M.B., Sinkey Jr. J. F., 1988. Bank loan loss provisions and the income smoothing
hypothesis: an empirical analysis, 1976-1984. Journal of Financial Services Research, 1, 301318.
Gunther, J.W., Moore, R.R., 2003a. Early warning models in real time. Journal of Banking and
Finance 27, 1979-2001.
Gunther, J.W., Moore, R.R., 2003b. Loss underreporting and the auditing role of bank exams.
Journal of Financial Intermediation 12, 153-177.
Holod, D., Peek, J., 2007. Asymmetric information and liquidity constraints. Journal of
Banking and Finance 31, 2415-2451.
Keeton, W., 1999. Does faster loan growth lead to higher loan losses? The Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, Second Quarter, 57-75.
Kwan, S.H., 2004. Risk and return of publicly held versus privately owned banks. The Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, September, 97-107.
Laeven, L., Majnoni, G., 2003. Loan loss provisioning and economic slowdowns: Too much,
too late? Journal of Financial Intermediation 12, 178-197.
Nichols, D.C., Wahlen, J.M., Wieland, M.M., 2009. Publicly traded versus privately held:
Implications for conditional conservatism in bank accounting. Review of Accounting Studies
14, 88-122.
Rajan, R., 1994. Why bank credit policies fluctuate: A theory and some evidence. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 399-441.
Supervision and Regulation Letter 06-17: Interagency Policy Statement on the ALLL, Board of
Governors, Federal Reserve System, December 13, 2006.
Supervision and Regulation Letter 01-17: Policy Statement on ALLL Methodologies and
Documentation for Banks and Savings Institutions, Board of Governors, Federal Reserve
System, July 2, 2001.

29

Supervision and Regulation Letter 99-22: Joint Interagency Letter on the Loan Loss Allowance,
Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System, July 26, 1999.
Wall, L.D., Koch, T.W., 2000. Bank loan loss accounting: A review of theoretical and empirical
evidence. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, Second Quarter, 1-19.
Wahlen, J. (1994). The nature of information in commercial bank loan loss disclosures. The
Accounting Review 69, 455-478.
Walter, J., 1991. Loan loss reserves. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond‟s Economic Review
77, 20-30.

30

Figure 1
Loan loss provisions as a percentage of pre-provision, pre-tax earnings. This figure indicates the
quarterly sample average of loan loss provisions as a percentage of pre-provision earnings. Loan
loss provision and pre-provision earnings data are from Call Reports. Percentages are
winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles to avoid distortions due to extreme values.

31

Figure 2
Distribution of Public. This figure shows the percentage of banks that were publicly held in the
fourth quarter of each indicated year, for the full sample and for banks divided by size at $1
billion and $10 billion in total assets.

32

Table 1
Summary statistics. LLR is loan loss reserves. PLL is provision for loan losses. AfterST equals 1 after
1998Q4, 0 otherwise. Public equals 1 if the firm is publicly traded or if the bank-holding company or
financial-holding company owning the firm are publicly traded, 0 otherwise. NCO is the average value
over the previous eight quarters of net charge-offs as a percentage of average assets from the previous
quarter. NPTL is non-performing loans. ΔLoans is change in total loans. EBP is earnings before
provisions and taxes. EQ is shareholder equity. Size is the natural log of total assets (in thousands) in the
previous quarter. ΔGDP is percentage change in real GDP in the previous quarter. DeNovo equals 1 in
the first five years of the firm‟s life, 0 otherwise. Fail equals 1 in the final quarter of the firm‟s existence
and the previous three quarters, 0 otherwise. Merger equals 1 if the firm merged with another firm during
the current quarter, 0 otherwise. LLR, NPTL, ΔLoans, and EQ are expressed as percentages of total assets
from the previous quarter. PLL and EBP are expressed as percentages of average assets from the previous
quarter.
Variable Mean Std. Dev. 25th percentile Median 75th percentile
LLR
0.933
0.508
0.648
0.848
1.093
PLL
0.215
0.467
0.003
0.119
0.261
AfterST
0.487
0.500
0
0
1
Public
0.160
0.367
0
0
0
NCO
0.166
0.431
0.012
0.070
0.192
NPTL
0.671
0.856
0.129
0.400
0.882
ΔLoans
1.590
6.225
-0.385
1.091
2.851
EBP
1.871
1.358
1.351
1.818
2.291
EQ
10.371
4.062
8.099
9.439
11.516
Size
11.363
1.302
10.517 11.215
11.993
ΔGDP
0.795
0.475
0.500
0.769
1.063
DeNovo
0.052
0.222
0
0
0
Fail
0.001
0.027
0
0
0
Merger
0.010
0.101
0
0
0
Number of institutions
13,317
Number of observations
517,822

33

Table 2
Differences of means of LLR and PLL by bank type and sample period. LLR is loan loss reserves as a
percentage of total assets from the previous quarter. PLL is provision for loan losses as a percentage of
average assets from the previous quarter. The pre-SunTrust and post-SunTrust sample periods are
1992Q1-1998Q3 and 1999Q1-2007Q2, respectively. Significance levels and t-statistics in brackets are
from t-tests of differences in means. All differences of means are significant at the 1 percent level.
Panel A: Means of LLR
Public banks Private banks Difference in means
Pre-SunTrust
1.111
0.919
0.192***
[71.089]
Post-SunTrust
0.984
0.899
0.085***
[31.460]
Difference in means 0.127***
0.020***
[29.212]
[13.815]
Panel B: Means of PLL
Public banks Private banks Difference in means
Pre-SunTrust
0.290
0.198
0.093***
[37.467]
Post-SunTrust
0.279
0.206
0.072***
[28.592]
Difference in means 0.011***
-0.009***
[2.786]
[-6.611]

34

Table 3
Panel regressions of loan loss reserves (LLR) using the full sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1992Q1-1998Q3 and 1999Q1-2007Q2,
respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1992Q1-2007Q2, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded. Variables are
as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a constant
term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Pre-SunTrust Post-SunTrust Public banks Private banks All observations All observations All observations All observations
Public
0.136***
0.0718***
0.0912***
0.0910***
0.115***
[10.88]
[3.861]
[7.950]
[7.940]
[9.210]
AfterST
-0.0285**
-0.0134***
-0.0148***
-0.0145***
-0.00644
[-2.329]
[-3.176]
[-3.447]
[-3.389]
[-1.401]
Public*AfterST
-0.0508***
[-4.058]
EBP
0.00611
0.0123***
0.00654
0.00958***
0.00911***
0.00965***
0.00954***
0.00969***
[1.193]
[4.022]
[0.963]
[2.866]
[2.790]
[2.944]
[2.914]
[2.965]
NCO
0.156***
0.0982***
0.0860**
0.193***
0.156***
0.156***
0.156***
0.156***
[5.346]
[3.052]
[2.361]
[10.83]
[5.555]
[5.563]
[5.556]
[5.552]
NPTL
0.119***
0.120***
0.240***
0.121***
0.139***
0.139***
0.139***
0.139***
[27.56]
[28.53]
[20.26]
[37.15]
[36.13]
[36.15]
[36.20]
[36.26]
ΔLoans
0.00903***
0.00623***
0.0109***
0.00480***
0.00779***
0.00779***
0.00779***
0.00777***
[18.92]
[11.29]
[19.44]
[10.57]
[19.71]
[19.74]
[19.75]
[19.71]
EQ
0.00188
0.00300*
-0.000697
0.00258
0.00186
0.00147
0.00138
0.00158
[1.415]
[1.815]
[-0.277]
[1.590]
[1.402]
[1.105]
[1.034]
[1.188]
Size
-0.0781***
-0.0593***
-0.0334*
-0.0486***
-0.0442***
-0.0521***
-0.0517***
-0.0478***
[-8.607]
[-8.497]
[-1.843]
[-5.576]
[-5.829]
[-6.667]
[-6.620]
[-6.118]
ΔGDP
-0.0031***
0.0038***
-0.00806*** -0.00151*
-0.0028***
-0.0026***
-0.0029***
-0.0028***
[-3.134]
[3.444]
[-3.020]
[-1.664]
[-3.167]
[-2.859]
[-3.346]
[-3.181]
DeNovo
-0.0109
-0.0319***
-0.0288
-0.0259***
-0.0303***
-0.0284***
-0.0267***
-0.0271***
[-0.806]
[-3.638]
[-1.266]
[-2.710]
[-3.314]
[-3.119]
[-2.913]
[-2.968]
Fail
0.383***
0.248***
0.638**
0.306***
0.352***
0.354***
0.354***
0.356***
[3.826]
[2.718]
[2.116]
[3.816]
[4.208]
[4.223]
[4.224]
[4.220]
Merger
0.131***
0.144***
0.0586***
0.214***
0.141***
0.139***
0.139***
0.139***
[12.08]
[12.05]
[5.374]
[18.24]
[15.30]
[15.16]
[15.19]
[15.17]
Observations
265,500
252,322
82,983
434,839
517,822
517,822
517,822
517,822
Banks
11,927
9,441
3,865
10,989
13,317
13,317
13,317
13,317
R2
0.187
0.16
0.268
0.194
0.195
0.208
0.209
0.214

35

Table 4
Panel regressions of loan loss reserves (LLR) using a narrow sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1996Q4-1998Q3 and 1999Q1-2000Q4,
respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1996Q4-2000Q4, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded. Variables are
as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a constant
term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Pre-SunTrust Post-SunTrust Public banks Private banks All observations All observations All observations All observations
Public
0.178***
0.0926***
0.128***
0.128***
0.148***
[6.729]
[5.253]
[7.608]
[7.627]
[8.464]
AfterST
-0.0107
-0.00581
-0.0097***
-0.0105***
-0.00425
[-1.385]
[-1.499]
[-2.745]
[-2.976]
[-1.135]
Public*AfterST
-0.0371***
[-3.902]
EBP
0.015
0.00734*
0.00551
0.0133**
0.00990*
0.0106*
0.0105*
0.0106*
[1.407]
[1.905]
[0.445]
[2.306]
[1.793]
[1.904]
[1.884]
[1.918]
NCO
0.117***
0.0399*
0.0420*
0.154***
0.0809***
0.0808***
0.0808***
0.0804***
[6.955]
[1.901]
[1.805]
[5.545]
[2.812]
[2.806]
[2.807]
[2.808]
NPTL
0.0847***
0.0804***
0.173***
0.0873***
0.0988***
0.0988***
0.0989***
0.0987***
[13.64]
[15.76]
[9.243]
[17.47]
[19.17]
[19.23]
[19.23]
[19.22]
ΔLoans
0.00943***
0.00796***
0.0102***
0.00625***
0.00847***
0.00848***
0.00849***
0.00848***
[12.24]
[12.31]
[11.90]
[8.307]
[13.83]
[13.82]
[13.84]
[13.83]
EQ
0.00910***
0.0141***
0.0104***
0.00791***
0.00898***
0.00821***
0.00812***
0.00824***
[4.536]
[6.080]
[2.735]
[3.889]
[5.062]
[4.616]
[4.553]
[4.631]
Size
-0.0235**
-0.0163**
0.00793
-0.0354***
-0.00554
-0.0219**
-0.0219**
-0.0200**
[-2.469]
[-2.041]
[0.459]
[-2.718]
[-0.619]
[-2.248]
[-2.254]
[-2.041]
ΔGDP
-0.00419
0.000543
-0.00304
0.00033
-0.000403
-0.00192**
-0.000371
-0.000374
[-1.538]
[0.513]
[-1.283]
[0.331]
[-0.430]
[-2.018]
[-0.396]
[-0.399]
DeNovo
-0.0122
0.00138
-0.0683*
-0.00489
-0.0204
-0.021
-0.0208
-0.0203
[-0.611]
[0.0548]
[-1.682]
[-0.227]
[-1.044]
[-1.076]
[-1.068]
[-1.039]
Fail
0.102
0.303**
0.800
0.137
0.221*
0.216*
0.216*
0.215*
[0.928]
[2.300]
[0.929]
[1.141]
[1.744]
[1.700]
[1.699]
[1.689]
Merger
0.0999***
0.101***
0.0332*
0.205***
0.117***
0.116***
0.116***
0.115***
[4.658]
[6.070]
[1.938]
[8.649]
[7.483]
[7.394]
[7.394]
[7.361]
Observations
69,401
63,145
21,821
110,725
132,546
132,546
132,546
132,546
Banks
9,303
8,459
2,230
7,977
9,723
9,723
9,723
9,723
R2
0.185
0.145
0.202
0.177
0.179
0.183
0.183
0.184

36

Table 5
Panel regressions of provisions for loan losses (PLL) using the full sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1992Q1-1998Q3 and 1999Q12007Q2, respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1992Q1-2007Q2, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded.
Variables are as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a
constant term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Pre-SunTrust Post-SunTrust Public banks Private banks All observations All observations All observations All observations
Public
-7.31E-05
-0.0202*
-0.0195**
-0.0191**
0.00163
[-0.00665]
[-1.932]
[-2.406]
[-2.350]
[0.180]
AfterST
0.0711***
0.0370***
0.0459***
0.0458***
0.0536***
[5.711]
[8.009]
[10.21]
[10.19]
[11.44]
Public*AfterST
-0.0483***
[-5.623]
EBP
0.0348***
0.0352***
0.0270***
0.0382***
0.0336***
0.0331***
0.0335***
0.0336***
[5.707]
[6.886]
[4.081]
[7.785]
[8.187]
[8.109]
[8.166]
[8.186]
NCO
0.164***
0.122***
0.0915***
0.219***
0.174***
0.176***
0.174***
0.174***
[6.954]
[4.172]
[3.214]
[10.88]
[6.497]
[6.528]
[6.496]
[6.496]
NPTL
0.119***
0.122***
0.195***
0.111***
0.124***
0.125***
0.124***
0.124***
[24.46]
[26.00]
[17.22]
[30.62]
[31.54]
[31.47]
[31.51]
[31.53]
ΔLoans
0.00175***
0.00216***
0.00202*** 0.00207***
0.00227***
0.00228***
0.00227***
0.00225***
[4.212]
[5.568]
[4.364]
[4.975]
[7.401]
[7.456]
[7.401]
[7.336]
EQ
-0.0160***
-0.00931***
-0.00911*** -0.0154***
-0.0136***
-0.0138***
-0.0135***
-0.0134***
[-8.723]
[-6.673]
[-4.005]
[-9.615]
[-10.28]
[-10.42]
[-10.18]
[-10.04]
Size
0.0492***
0.0389***
0.0533***
0.0661***
0.0502***
0.0529***
0.0522***
0.0548***
[9.201]
[8.379]
[4.123]
[10.45]
[10.46]
[10.43]
[10.26]
[10.62]
ΔGDP
0.0041**
-0.0104***
-0.00896*** -0.00640*** -0.0069***
-0.0080***
-0.0069***
-0.0067***
[2.174]
[-7.231]
[-2.848]
[-4.923]
[-5.747]
[-6.604]
[-5.719]
[-5.598]
DeNovo
0.148***
0.161***
0.134***
0.189***
0.178***
0.182***
0.177***
0.177***
[9.402]
[18.35]
[4.737]
[17.57]
[17.93]
[18.57]
[17.88]
[17.84]
Fail
0.346**
0.401***
0.347
0.426***
0.427***
0.427***
0.426***
0.428***
[2.238]
[3.076]
[1.382]
[3.498]
[3.755]
[3.760]
[3.750]
[3.765]
Merger
0.00902
-0.0143
-0.0152
-0.0102
-0.0111
-0.00994
-0.0107
-0.0111
[0.816]
[-1.181]
[-1.499]
[-0.789]
[-1.305]
[-1.166]
[-1.262]
[-1.304]
Observations
265,500
252,322
82,983
434,839
517,822
517,822
517,822
517,822
Banks
11,927
9,441
3,865
10,989
13,317
13,317
13,317
13,317
R2
0.216
0.213
0.218
0.204
0.216
0.215
0.216
0.214

37

Table 6
Panel regressions of provisions for loan losses (PLL) using a narrow sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1996Q4-1998Q3 and 1999Q12000Q4, respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1996Q4-2000Q4, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded.
Variables are as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a
constant term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Pre-SunTrust Post-SunTrust Public banks Private banks All observations All observations All observations All observations
Public
0.0221
-0.00712
-0.0011
-0.00086
0.00917
[1.536]
[-0.523]
[-0.0873]
[-0.0680]
[0.684]
AfterST
-0.0289**
-0.0059
-0.0146**
-0.0145**
-0.0110*
[-2.199]
[-0.821]
[-2.309]
[-2.309]
[-1.672]
Public*AfterST
-0.0213**
[-2.280]
EBP
0.0433***
0.0233***
0.00389
0.0429***
0.0294***
0.0296***
0.0294***
0.0295***
[3.141]
[2.895]
[0.434]
[4.165]
[3.755]
[3.773]
[3.758]
[3.765]
NCO
0.300***
0.0805**
0.0658**
0.281***
0.130***
0.130***
0.130***
0.130***
[4.993]
[2.294]
[2.315]
[7.091]
[2.721]
[2.720]
[2.721]
[2.723]
NPTL
0.111***
0.103***
0.177***
0.116***
0.128***
0.128***
0.128***
0.128***
[12.09]
[10.89]
[8.171]
[14.64]
[16.09]
[16.09]
[16.09]
[16.09]
ΔLoans
0.00145**
0.00139*
0.00275*** 0.000769
0.00162***
0.00160***
0.00162***
0.00161***
[2.221]
[1.820]
[3.693]
[0.916]
[2.934]
[2.909]
[2.934]
[2.924]
EQ
-0.0101***
-0.00963***
-0.0102***
-0.0150***
-0.0130***
-0.0129***
-0.0130***
-0.0129***
[-3.970]
[-5.110]
[-3.496]
[-6.256]
[-6.288]
[-6.272]
[-6.299]
[-6.286]
Size
0.0234***
0.0377***
0.0561***
0.0464***
0.0446***
0.0448***
0.0447***
0.0450***
[4.173]
[5.593]
[3.737]
[5.860]
[7.181]
[6.392]
[6.390]
[6.424]
ΔGDP
-0.00608
-0.00117
0.00154
-0.00215
-0.00167
-0.00383**
-0.00167
-0.00167
[-1.007]
[-0.903]
[0.443]
[-1.130]
[-0.984]
[-2.070]
[-0.985]
[-0.986]
DeNovo
0.238***
0.276***
0.338**
0.249***
0.260***
0.260***
0.260***
0.260***
[6.607]
[9.076]
[2.445]
[9.346]
[8.767]
[8.757]
[8.761]
[8.770]
Fail
0.129
0.452***
0.219
0.25
0.232
0.233
0.232
0.232
[0.447]
[2.764]
[0.626]
[0.902]
[0.951]
[0.952]
[0.952]
[0.950]
Merger
0.00186
0.0296
-0.00848
0.0392
0.0149
0.015
0.0149
0.0145
[0.0969]
[1.470]
[-0.604]
[1.406]
[0.958]
[0.967]
[0.959]
[0.931]
Observations
69,401
63,145
21,821
110,725
132,546
132,546
132,546
132,546
Banks
9,303
8,459
2,230
7,977
9,723
9,723
9,723
9,723
R2
0.295
0.187
0.178
0.246
0.205
0.205
0.205
0.205

38

Table 7
Panel regressions of provisions for loan losses (PLL) using the full sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1992Q1-1998Q3 and 1999Q12007Q2, respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1992Q1-2007Q2, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded.
Variables are as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a
constant term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Public

(1)
Pre-SunTrust
0.0257
[0.982]

(2)
Post-SunTrust
-0.00537
[-0.266]

AfterST

(3)
Public banks

(4)
Private banks

0.107***
[3.070]

0.0827***
[4.659]

0.0348***
[2.706]

0.0517***
[6.720]

-0.0152
[-0.941]

-0.0235**
[-2.549]

0.0919***
[3.222]
0.195***
[17.19]
0.00194***
[4.020]
-0.00893***
[-3.857]
0.0538***
[4.161]
-0.00900***
[-2.870]
0.133***
[4.747]
0.35
[1.391]
-0.0154
[-1.525]
82,983
3,865
0.219

0.221***
[11.09]
0.111***
[30.62]
0.00200***
[4.892]
-0.0150***
[-9.627]
0.0679***
[10.85]
-0.00623***
[-4.779]
0.186***
[17.63]
0.436***
[3.585]
-0.0107
[-0.830]
434,839
10,989
0.205

Public*AfterST
EBP
EBP* Public

0.0392***
[5.533]
-0.014
[-1.135]

0.0371***
[6.021]
-0.00767
[-0.789]

EBP*AfterST

(5)
All observations
0.0329*
[1.885]
0.0539***
[11.47]
-0.0480***
[-5.563]
0.0382***
[7.821]
-0.0170**
[-2.143]

(6)
All observations
-0.00174
[-0.192]
0.0927***
[6.041]
-0.0416***
[-4.891]
0.0446***
[6.710]

-0.0201**
[-2.536]

(7)
All observations
0.0318*
[1.756]
0.0940***
[6.219]
-0.0411***
[-4.804]
0.0498***
[7.211]
-0.0183**
[-2.195]
-0.0206***
[-2.634]

0.175***
[6.521]
0.124***
[31.49]
0.00216***
[7.116]
-0.0131***
[-10.03]
0.0559***
[10.86]
-0.00659***
[-5.473]
0.175***
[17.98]
0.436***
[3.838]
-0.0115
[-1.357]
517,822
13,317
0.215

0.175***
[6.543]
0.124***
[31.53]
0.00227***
[7.306]
-0.0132***
[-10.11]
0.0556***
[10.77]
-0.00661***
[-5.486]
0.175***
[18.04]
0.440***
[3.888]
-0.0107
[-1.265]
517,822
13,317
0.214

EBP* Public*AfterST
NCO
NPTL
ΔLoans
EQ
Size
ΔGDP
DeNovo
Fail
Merger
Observations
Banks
R2

0.165***
[6.970]
0.119***
[24.45]
0.00184***
[4.328]
-0.0160***
[-8.765]
0.0491***
[9.266]
0.00411**
[2.198]
0.148***
[9.446]
0.351**
[2.274]
0.00954
[0.862]
265,500
11,927
0.216

0.122***
[4.178]
0.122***
[26.02]
0.00220***
[5.626]
-0.00939***
[-6.732]
0.0389***
[8.352]
-0.0105***
[-7.251]
0.162***
[18.39]
0.402***
[3.083]
-0.0141
[-1.164]
252,322
9,441
0.211

0.174***
[6.517]
0.124***
[31.56]
0.00235***
[7.544]
-0.0135***
[-10.13]
0.0544***
[10.53]
-0.00673***
[-5.613]
0.177***
[17.92]
0.432***
[3.810]
-0.0103
[-1.218]
517,822
13,317
0.213

(8)
All observations
0.044
[1.594]
0.0993***
[5.722]
-0.0654*
[-1.936]
0.0514***
[6.802]
-0.0241*
[-1.760]
-0.0234**
[-2.561]
0.0114
[0.660]
0.175***
[6.536]
0.124***
[31.52]
0.00228***
[7.328]
-0.0132***
[-10.12]
0.0556***
[10.79]
-0.00659***
[-5.481]
0.175***
[17.97]
0.441***
[3.897]
-0.0107
[-1.265]
517,822
13,317
0.214

39

Table 8
Panel regressions of provisions for loan losses (PLL) using a narrow sample period. The sample periods for models 1 and 2 are 1996Q4-1998Q3 and 1999Q12000Q4, respectively. The sample period for models 3-8 is 1996Q4-2000Q4, with 1998Q4 (the quarter in which the SunTrust decision occurred) excluded.
Variables are as defined in Table 1. Specifications include random effects by bank, robust standard errors, quarter dummies, quadratic time trend variables, and a
constant term. T-statistics appear in brackets. Levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** for 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Public

(1)
Pre-SunTrust
0.064
[1.182]

(2)
Post-SunTrust
0.021
[0.690]

AfterST

(3)
Public banks

(4)
Private banks

0.029
[0.641]

0.0152
[0.607]

0.0196
[1.031]

0.0488***
[3.428]

-0.0243
[-1.262]

-0.0111
[-0.878]

0.0657**
[2.336]
0.177***
[8.268]
0.00249***
[3.143]
-0.00905***
[-3.103]
0.0560***
[3.758]
0.00196
[0.552]
0.332**
[2.436]
0.22
[0.621]
-0.00925
[-0.647]
21,821
2,230
0.184

0.283***
[7.078]
0.117***
[14.66]
0.000772
[0.922]
-0.0149***
[-6.196]
0.0460***
[5.881]
-0.00196
[-1.013]
0.246***
[9.727]
0.242
[0.877]
0.0383
[1.384]
110,725
7,977
0.248

Public*AfterST
EBP
EBP* Public

0.0493***
[2.859]
-0.0201
[-0.822]

0.0287**
[2.490]
-0.0137
[-0.943]

EBP*AfterST

(5)
All observations
0.0825***
[2.665]
-0.00851
[-1.272]
-0.0237**
[-2.571]
0.0418***
[4.026]
-0.0353***
[-2.660]

(6)
All observations
0.00665
[0.495]
0.019
[0.880]
-0.0151
[-1.549]
0.0382***
[3.317]

-0.0157
[-1.464]

(7)
All observations
0.0774**
[2.453]
0.019
[0.908]
-0.0179*
[-1.853]
0.0493***
[3.771]
-0.0340**
[-2.484]
-0.0145
[-1.392]

0.131***
[2.736]
0.128***
[16.12]
0.00156***
[2.814]
-0.0127***
[-6.144]
0.0449***
[6.443]
-0.00142
[-0.822]
0.256***
[8.949]
0.222
[0.909]
0.0139
[0.901]
132,546
9,723
0.206

0.133***
[2.770]
0.128***
[16.18]
0.00176***
[3.029]
-0.0130***
[-6.225]
0.0443***
[6.351]
-0.00171
[-0.985]
0.256***
[9.033]
0.229
[0.938]
0.0147
[0.945]
132,546
9,723
0.206

EBP* Public*AfterST
NCO
NPTL
ΔLoans
EQ
Size
ΔGDP
DeNovo
Fail
Merger
Observations
Banks
R2

0.302***
[5.020]
0.112***
[12.12]
0.00160**
[2.213]
-0.0104***
[-3.929]
0.0234***
[4.215]
-0.00596
[-0.987]
0.238***
[6.628]
0.124
[0.428]
0.00281
[0.149]
69,401
9,303
0.296

0.0817**
[2.298]
0.103***
[10.92]
0.00147*
[1.895]
-0.00984***
[-5.097]
0.0371***
[5.533]
-0.00116
[-0.901]
0.276***
[9.121]
0.458***
[2.812]
0.0297
[1.456]
63,145
8,459
0.187

0.133***
[2.759]
0.128***
[16.15]
0.00182***
[3.153]
-0.0132***
[-6.370]
0.0444***
[6.329]
-0.00195
[-1.146]
0.260***
[8.865]
0.239
[0.976]
0.0153
[0.975]
132,546
9,723
0.204

(8)
All observations
0.0657
[1.373]
0.0144
[0.577]
0.00195
[0.0418]
0.0481***
[3.414]
-0.0287
[-1.314]
-0.012
[-0.942]
-0.009
[-0.404]
0.134***
[2.773]
0.128***
[16.17]
0.00174***
[2.978]
-0.0129***
[-6.210]
0.0442***
[6.347]
-0.00173
[-0.995]
0.257***
[9.109]
0.232
[0.950]
0.0146
[0.932]
132,546
9,723
0.206

40