View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Interest Rate Rules and Nominal
Determinacy

WP 90-01

John H. Boyd, III
University of Rochester
Michael Dotsey
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Working Paper 90-l

INTEREST RATE RULES AND NOMINAL
DETERMINACY

John H. Boyd, III*
and
Michael Dotsey

University of Rochester
and
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
February 1990

*John H. Boyd, III is an Assistant Professor at the University of Rochester.
The authors wish to thank Marvin Goodfriend, Bennett McCallum, and Alan
Stockman for their helpful comments. The views expressed in this paper are
solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
University of Rochester, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, or the Federal
Reserve System.

Abstract
Monetary economists have recently begun a serious study of money supply rules that
allow the Fed to adjustably peg the nominal interest rate under rational expectations.
These rules vary from procedures that produce stationary nominal magnitudes to those
that generate nonstationarities in nominal variables. Our paper investigates the determinacy properties of three representative interest rate rules.
We use Blanchard and Kahn’s solution technique as a starting point.
rectly apply, so we first modify their procedure.

It doesn’t di-

We then narrow the range of solutions

by considering the ARMA solutions of Evans and Honkapohja and the global minimum
state variable solution of McCallum.

We then examine these solutions in light of the

expectational stability notions emplayed by DeCanio, Bray and Evans.
Two of the three classes of rules yield a unique admissible solution. The exclusion of
bubbles usually rules out the general ARMA solutions present in Evans and Honkapohja
and leads to unique solutions via a saddlepoint property. Nonetheless, the nonstationary
money supply rules we examine do not generally yield a well determined system over all
parameter values.

We employ the global minimum state variable methodology

Callum and Evans’ expectational stability in an effort to insure uniqueness.

of Mc-

Although

these methods are usually in agreement, one of the nonstationary rules yields a global
minimum state variable solution that is expectationally
is sensitive to interest rate deviations.
(non-global)

unstable when the central bank

Moreover, under these conditions, an alternative

minimum state variable solution is expectationally

the applicability of McCallum’s global procedure in thii context.

stable, casting doubt on

1. Introduction
Beginning with McCallum’s

(1981) article, monetary economists have been able to

seriously study the use of an interest rate instrument in an economic environment that incorporates rational expectations. Dotsey and King (1983,1986) and Canzoneri, Henderson
and Rogoff (1983) have examined a variety of money supply specifications that allow the
central bank to target or adjustably peg the nominal interest rate. Barro (1989), building
on the work of Goodfriend (1987) and McCallum (1986), has used the concept of interest
rate smoothing in an attempt to generate nominal variables that have statistical properties
that resemble actual time series.
The literature has produced a number of money supply rules that allow the Fed to
adjustably peg the nominal interest rate. The rules vary from procedures that produce
stationary nominal magnitudes to those that generate nonstationarities in nominal variables. Although determinacy issues are central to much of McCallum’s work, the various
types of rules have not been subjected to a systematic investigation. Our paper carries out
that investigation.
We use Blanchard and Kahn’s (1980) procedure as a starting point for studying three
representative forms of interest rate rules. Since their procedure doesn’t directly apply
to our problems, the first order of business is to modify it so that it does apply.

We

then narrow the range of solutions using the methods of Evans and Honkapohja (1986)
and of McCallum (1983). Finally, we examine these solutions in light of the expectational
stability notions employed by DeCanio (1979), Bray (1982) and Evans (1985, 1986).’
By focusing on solutions that meet the nonexplosiveness criteria of Blanchard and Kahn
(1980) we find that two of the three classes of rules yield a unique admissible solution. The
exclusion of bubbles usually rules out the general ARMA solutions present in Evans and
Honkapohja and leads to unique solutions via a saddlepoint property similar to that used
in Blanchard and Kahn (1980).
Nonetheless, the nonstationary money supply rules which are employed in McCallum
(1986) and extended by Barro (1989) d o not generally yield a well determined system over
all parameter values -

there are an infinity of solutions. Focusing on solutions involving

a minimal set of state variables helps somewhat, but uniqueness may still be a problem.
In an effort to insure uniqueness, McCallum (1983) has proposed a subsidary principle,
further refining the set of admissible solutions to those minimum state variable solutions
’ General discussions of expectational stability may be found in Blume, Bray and Easley
(1982) and Frydman and Phelps (1983).

2
that hold globally -

for all values of the parameters. Both McCallum and Barro appeal

to the global minimum state variable methodology of McCallum (1986).
However, our methodology indicates that only Barro’s model has a unique nonexplosive
solution when the interest rate is pegged. This occurs because, in his model, the central
bank is concerned about the variance of price level surprises.

Thii concern leads to a

restriction of the admissible parameter values that the coefficients on the interest rate
feedback terms are allowed to have.
When it comes to interest rate rules, we are not as optimistic as they are in applying
McCallum’s

technique.

Although Evans (1986) finds that expectational

stability often

provides support for the subsidiary principle, that is not always the case here. In fact,
under one of the nonstationary rules, we find that the global miniium
solution is expectationally

state variable

unstable when the central bank is sensitive to interest rate

deviations. Moreover, under these conditions, an alternative (non-global) minimum state
variable solution is expectationally stable, casting doubt on the applicability of McCallum’s
subsidiary principle in this context.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section Two gives three variants of the basic model,
differing only in the interest rate rule. Section Three contains our modification of Blanchard
and Kahn’s eigenvalue counting rules. In Section Four, we examine the solutions to our
systems and investigate their nominal determinacy properties. Section Five analyzes their
expectational stability, while Section Six discusses Barro’s model. Section Seven contains
concluding remarks.

2. The Model
The basic economic structure is similar to McCallum (1981, 1986), and Goodfriend
(1987).

The real side of the economy is depicted by a Fisher relationship between the

nominal rate of interest, the stochastic real rate of interest, and the expected rate of
inflation. Thus
&=

=+&I%+1

-Pt

+ rt

(1)

where & is the nominal rate of interest, a + tt is the real rate of interest, a serially
independent stochastic process with mean a, pt is the logarithm of the current price level,
and Etpt+r is the expectation of the log of next period’s price level, conditional on current
information.

The current information set includes observations on all current and past

values of the endogenous variables and the stochastic disturbances. The demand for money
is given by

3
where mt is the logarithm of nominal money balances and vt is a mean zero white noise
disturbance term. The initial money supply m. is given. The disturbance term includes
the effects of changes in income on the demand for money as well as shifts in taste and
transactions technology.
The model is closed by specifying the money supply process. Here we choose to examine
three different candidates.
mi=b+X(&-R*).
rni = rnt-l + A(& - A!‘),

(34
m0 given

m,d = w-1 + A(& - G-I&),

(3b)

m0 given.

(34

Equations (3a) and (3b) are in the spirit of McCallum (1986)’ while (3~) is somewhat representative of the specification used in Goodfriend (1987)) Dotsey and King (1983,1986),
and Canzoneri, Henderson, and Rogoff (1983). The parameter X determines how much the
monetary authority reacts to changes in the interest rate. In all three specifications we
approximate the behavior of a peg by letting X + 00.
Equation (3a) implies a stationary money supply, while (3b) and (3~) yield nonstationary movements in money. As will be shown below, equation (3b) produces determinacy
problems not found in the other two systems.

3. Root Counting Rules
In order to analyze the determinancy properties of our interest rate rules we need a
methodology.

The methodology

that we find most appealing is that of Blanchard and

Kahn (1980)) since it rules out explosive solutions and is carefully based on a general
theory of uniqueness for a system of linear difference equations.
conditional expections of future x do not explode.

They require that the

Specificially, &zt+i is polynomially

bounded in the sense that for all t there exist random variables Z, and integers w with
IE,z,*I 5 (1 + i)“‘Zt for all i. The nonexplosiveness criteria seems sensible to us since it
mimics the role of transversality conditions in well specified optimization models. Also, as
an empirical matter, analyzing explosive bubbles does not seem particularly relevant.
To facilitate comparison with Blanchard and Kahn (1980)’ we refer to variables with
&6+1

= zt+r as predetermined and those with E,z,+r # zt+l as non-predetermined.

course, Etzt = xt for all x.

Of

Blanchard and Kahn assume that the initial values of the

predetermined variables are given, while the initial values of non-predetermined variables
are not given. We break camp with them here. Our analysis in this section shows that it
is not the stochastic properties of the variables which matter, but rather the presence or
absence of initial conditions.

4
Blanchard and Kahn’s formulation is not immediately applicable to our set of problems
since systems involving (3b) or (3~) fall under their example C due to the presence of terms
containing E tP t+s. As they point out, problems in thii category can not be addressed by the
counting rules in their theorem. We are, therefore, required to modify their methodology.
Our method will prove useful for a wide class of models that include past expectations of
current and future variables and is of interest in and of itself. Although our method is
applicable to a much wider variety of systems, the theorem we present is optimized for the
systems set forth in section 2. In addition to meriting investigation in their own right, the
interest rate rules we analyze in sections 4 and 5 serve double duty as interesting examples
of our methods.
Our starting point is the solution procedure of Blanchard and Kahn (1980).

The

matrix multiplying the current variables is put into Jordan form J, with the eigenvalues
listed in order of increasing modulus.

The matrix that performs the diagonaliiation

is

denoted S. Blanchard and Kahn’s procedure is to partition J into blocks corresponding
to the ni, eigenvalues inside or on the unit circle, and the noa eigenvalues outside the
unit circle. The vector of variables gives the nwe p redetermined variables first, followed
by the nnonnon-predetermined

variables. Partition S accordingly.

It is crucial that the

nd x nm matrix Ss2 be of full rank. Blanchard and Kahn then restrict their attention
to the polynomially

bounded solutions of the system.

They find that there is a unique

solution when nM = nnon, there is an inEnity of solutions when nd

< nnon, and, for

almost all initial conditions, there is no solution when nd > nm.
The importance of their rank condition cannot be underestimated.

When the rank

condition fails, the ill-behaved parts of the solution cannot be ruled out through polynomial boundedness.

The root counting procedure fails. The following simple example

illustrates this. Consider the system zt+r = 2xt and Etpt+r = pt/2 where zt is predetermined and pt is non-predetermined.

Since nd = nnon= 1, root counting would yield a

unique polynomially bounded solution for all initial conditions. However, for zs # 0, there
is no polynomially bounded solution since zt = 2%s. When z,-, = 0, there are many polynomially bounded solutions. To see the indeterminacy, let wt be an arbitrary martingale,
so Ecwt+1 = wt. Consider pt = c~(1/2)~wtand Z~ = 0 for CYarbitrary. This is a solution
she

&pt+l

= pt/2, and is clearly polynomially bounded.2

Our problems appear to be only slightly different from Blanchard and Kahn%. Nonetheless, their results do not directly apply to our problems due to the presence of future
2 Martingale solutions are considered in Pesaran (1981) and Gourieroux,
Monfort (1982). See Pesaran’s (1987) book for a complete exposition.

Laffont and

5
expectations.

Fortunately, similar results do apply. ’

Let Pt be the m-vector
m+-vector,

of variables, n, an m-vector

of disturbance terms, F an

Q an m* x 2m matrix and let A, 23, C and D be m

x

m matrices.

The

equations we are interested in will have the form
P:+I = Apt + BW’t+l

+

CM’t+2

s.t.

+ %+l,

+ D&+&+2

Q

[

PO
Eopl

I

= F

(4)

where Xc = EoPl. All three of our cases fit into this format, as does Blanchard and Kahn’s
second example C, Pt+l = CU(E~P,+~
- E,P,+,) + ct. The initial condition on mt can be
written in terms of PO and EoPl by using (1) and (2). This yields the initial condition
(1 + c)po - cEopl = m + ca + cro - vo.
Start by applying Et to (4). Thii yields
E*fi+l = APt + BE&+1 + (C + D)Et(Et+lPt+2) + Etilt+l.

(5)

Provided C + D is invertible, the substitution Xt = EtPt+l puts this into the Blanchard
and Kahn format

E*[$]=[

-(C +‘D)-‘A

(C + D&(1

- B) ] [z]

+

[dt,,]’

To study uniqueness, we consider the case with fit = 0 and F = 0. Equation (4)
becomes

[A-D]
[2l]=[AJl
[z]+!WlE:
[zl]

while equation (5) becomes
-(C +‘D)-‘A

(C + D+(I

-B)

pt
X,
I[
I.

(7)

If there are two solutions to (4)’ their difference must solve (6).
We cannot blindly apply the Blanchard and Kahn results to equation (7). Some of its
solutions may not satisfy (6). Our method is to first solve (7), and then substitute into
(6) to see if it imposes any additional restrictions.
Let
K=

-(C +‘D)-‘A

(C + D)“(I

- B)

1.

Let J be its Jordan form with eigenvalues arranged in order of increasing modulus and let
S satisfy SJ = KS. Partition both J and S into four blocks each so that Jll and Srr are
m,, x ~YQ,and 522 and Ss2 are rnd x mat.
’ Our technique also applies to the recalcitrant example C of Blanchard and Kahn.

6
THEOREM. Suppose that K is invertible and QS has full rank. Lf m,, > m’, there
are infinitelymany polynomially bounded solutions, if mi, < m’ most initialconditions do
not admit any polynomially bounded solutions, while if q,

= m* < m with Sll - D&

invertible, all initial conditions yield a uniquepolynomially bounded solution.
First consider the case m,, c m*. Take the expectation

PROOF.

equation (4) and multiply by S-l.
EoS-’

Setting & = S-r

[1
it

with initial condition QSRc = F.

polynomially bounded and deterministic.

[ 1
Eopt
Eopt+l

at time zero in

, thii yields &+r = J& +

If there is a solution to (4)’ & will be

By subtracting a particular solution, we may

assume fit = 0 without loss of generality. Then & = J*&, and polynomial boundedness
requires that the last m d entries in & be 0. The inital condition QS&

= F then gives us

m* equations in min unknowns. Since QS has full rank, it will usually have no solutions.
It follows that (4) will usually have no solutions.
Now suppose mi, > m*. It is tedious but straightforward to use Blanchard and Kahn’s
procedure to show that at least one solution to (4) exists. Again consider the homogeneous
equation obtained by taking expectations

at time zero and multiplying by S-l.

polynomially bounded solution to thii with initial condition QS&

Any

= 0 can be added to

a solution to (4) to obtain another solution. As long as the last moutentries in & are 0,
& will be polynomially

bounded.

Since there are m* < mi, equations in mi,, unknowns,

there are many such Rc, and the solution is not unique.
Finally, suppose mi,, = m* 5 m. Again, there is at least one solution.

We restrict

our attention to the associated homogeneous stochastic difference equation (6). Pesaran
(1987) shows that the general solution to (6) is
= SJ*Mt = K’SMt
where M* is an arbitrary martingale. It is easily verified that [I, -D]K
Substituting in (6) we obtain [I, -D]S J*+l(Mt-Mt+l)

= [A, B] + [0, C]K.

= 0.

Again, the last rnoG entries of M* must be zero in view of polynomial boundedness.
Since rni, 6 m, we have [I, -D]S J*+l(W-Mt+~) = (%I - DS21)~;I-1(M~,t+~
--Ml,:) = 0.
Then the invertibility of Srr - D&l and Jll implies Mrt =Mr,*+r. Finally, plugging in the
initial conditions, we see that M* = 0, and the solution is unique.

QED

One interesting aspect of this type of equation is that the distinction between predetermined and non-predetermined variables is unimportant in the solution procedure.

We can

only discover which variables are which type by solving the equations. What was important
was the presence or absence of intitial conditions. The predetermined/non-predetermined

7
distinction is important to Blanchard and Kahn only through the initial conditions.

If

there are predetermined variable without initial conditions, trying to use the distinction
causes problems.
A one-sector deterministic optimal growth problem illustrates thii problem. Lmearizing the Euler equations, we obtain a second-order difference equation in the capital stock
kt. Introducing zt = Ict+r as a variable gives a first-order system of the type considered
by Blanchard and Kahn. Th e saddlepoint property will typically hold, and there will be
one root inside the unit circle and one root outside it. However, since everything is deterministic, all variables are predetermined and root-counting implies that there are (usually)
no polynomially bounded solutions since there are two predetermined variables, kt and zt.
Yet it is well-known that the linearized system will have a unique polynomially bounded
solution. The problem is that the Blanchard and Kahn framework requires us to impose an
initial condition on the future capital stock x t. Of course, only one such initial condition
is consistent with optimality.

Any other initial condition will not yield a solution.

Our

framework handles the optimal growth problem correctly by only specifying one initial
condition, for current capital. Our root counting implies that there is a unique solution the correct result.

4. The Solutions
Now that we are armed with an appropriately modified Blanchard-Kahn result, we are
ready to investigate the relations between the three types of solutions to our systems -

the

Blanchard-Kahn type, the Evans-Honkapohja ARMA solutions and McCallum’s minimum
state variable solutions.
(a) The stationary

money supply

rule

Equations (l), (2), and (3a) yield a reduced form expression for prices of
l
[b-XR*+(X+c)Etpt+l+(X+c)(a++ut].
I%= 1+x+c
This expression is easily put in the framework above, yielding
Em+1

= &(1+

(8)

x + C>Pt - WI

where wt = b - AR’ + (A + c)(a + rt) - ut.
The root of thii equation is (1 + X + c)/(A + c). For large X, this root is outside the
unit circle. Since there is precisely one non-predetermined endogenous variable at time t,
there is a unique nonexplosive solution. It is
pt = (A + c)a + b - AR* + (Xl++c~+;vf.

8
Thii is also the global minimum state variable solution derived in McCallum (1983,1986).
When R* = a, this solution will approach a limit as X + 00. This limit apprmcimates the
solution for large X. It is not to be confused with the solution to the lit
(8), which is without obvious economic meaning.
directly incorporate

of equation

The money supply rule (3a) does not

a trend rate of money growth.

It makes intuitive sense that the

nominal interest rate target is the expected real rate of interest. In this case the nominal
interest rate is & = R* + (rt +ut)/(l

+X +c) and will fluctuate randomly around its target.

Even though b is not its target, the money stock m = b + X(rt + ut)/(l + X + c) likewise
fluctuates randomly about b.
The limiting value of the price level as X + 00, pt(oo), is well-defined for R’ = a and
equal to
Ptb)

= ac -I- b+

rt.

As in other interest rate pegging literature, the price level is unaffected by the money
demand disturbance.

The limiting behavior of the price level is also seen to be equal to

the price level of a money supply rule in which the central bank buys and sells bonds at
a nominal interest rate that is expected to produce a money supply of b. That is, if the
monetary authority chooses to buy and sell bonds at a nominal interest given by
Rt = +t-lpt

- b),

the price level pt (00) and interest rate a = R’ emerge as the unique polynomially bounded
solution when c > 0. The interpretation of the limiting value of (9) as a peg is thus well
motivated.
While (9) represents the unique nonexplosive solution to (8), there are infinitely many
explosive solutions.

The class of these with finite degree ARMA representations can be

found by employing the method used in Evans and Honkapohja (1986).

First eliminate

the constant term with the transformation qt = pt - (UC+ b). The finite degree ARMA
solutions are then found by substituting qt = CfE,~qt,i + Cf=,(biut-~+ cirt+). The general
ARMA solution is given by

Pt = &(I+

A + +t-1

- (b - AR’) + w-l] - (a + w-l) + bout + car:

where &, and COare arbitrary. The nonexplosive solution (9) solves this for bo = -l/(1
X + c) and co = (X + c)/(l

00)
+

+ X + c). In o th er cases, it is easy to see that the difference

equation for pt is explosive for positive X. Arbitarily limiting the solution to bounded price
levels, one could solve (8) forward as in Sargent (1979) and end up with equation (9).

9

Alternatively, restricting the solutions to be expectationally stable in the sense of EWIU
(1985) rules out solutions other than (9).
(b) Nonstationary

money

supply rules

We next analyze rule (3b). The reduced form equation for prices derived from (1)) (2))
and (3b) is
pt=

’
1+x+c

[Ata - R*) + (I+ c)pt-1 - c&-a
- crt-1+

ut-1+

(X +

c)rt

-

+ (A + c)Etpt+l
ut].

01)

In this case, it’s simpler to walk through the steps of the theorem rather than invoke it
directly.
Update, take expectations conditional on date t information, substitute zt = Etpt+l,
and rearrange to obtain the matrix form

[~~]=i%[

-(IO+ c)

1+ x+c
x + 2c ] [:I

+&

[A(R’-.P+.rt-Vr]

This new system is in our framework and has eigenvalues p=

02)

1 and Y = (1 + c) / (X + c).

Since at most one eigenvalue will be outside the unit circle, there is a temptation to use
Blanchard and Kahn’s proposition

3 to conclude there are an infinity of nonexplosive

solution. This would be an error. The transition from (11) to (12) has introduced some
extraneous solutions which solve (12) but not (11).
Let pt be any solution to (12) which also solves (11). As before, any other solution to
(12) can be obtained by adding #rnlt+vtrn2t

where mlt and rnzt are martingales and p and

v are the eigenvalues. Consider first the case when 1~1> 1. The polynomial boundedness
requirement implies m2t = 0. Now substitute in (11), and use the fact that pt solves (11)
to obtain ml,t+r = mlt. It follows that (11) has a unique solution, provided we know the
initial price level. Provided we know the initial price level, the extra constraint imposed
by (11) has the same effect on determinacy as reducing the number of non-predetermined
variables by one. Roughly speaking, (11) turns pt into a predetermined variable.
Now consider the case where 1~1< 1. Again substituting in (11), and using the fact
that Y = (1 + c)/(X + c), we obtain Xvt+1m2,t+l+ml,t+l = Xvt+1m2t+mlt. Even given an
initial price level, there are an infinity of solutions to (11). In particular, taking the lit
as A 3

00 will not produce a unique solution. The solution to an interest rate peg with

this underlying money supply rule will suffer from nominal indeterminacy.
The myriad of nonexplosive finite-degree ARMA solutions can be found by extending
the methodology of Evans and Honkapohja (1986) so that it encompasses equation (11).

10
First remove the constant term with the transformation qt = pt - X(R’ - @/(A

- 1) (the

time dependence arises from the unit root). Then set qt = Cfzlqqt-i + C~=,(biut-i+ cirt-i)a
It is easily verified that there are at most two non-zero lags. There are three solutions,
dependingonwhetheral

= (l+X+2c)/(A+c)
oral solves (X+c)af-(l+X+b)u~+l+c = 0.

The first is the most general form and is given by
Qt = &[(I

+ X + 2C)qt-1- (I+ c)qt-2 + crt-2 - ut-f + ut-1 - (A + c)r+l]
+ h&h - cut-l/(X + c)] + c0[rt - cc-l/(X

+ c)]

(13)

where b and co are arbitrary. The roots of this difference equation are 1 and (1+c)/(X+c).
When I1+ cl < I;\+ cl, this solution is nonexplosive.
The other two solutions are actually specializations of (13).The second solution has
= 1,and is the solution picked by McCallum. Thii solution obeys

a1

Qt = !?t-1

+

Thiisolutionoccurswhenbo

&--[(A

-

l)vt

+

(A +

c)rt + vt-1

-

crt-l].

(14

= (A-l)/(l+c)
andco = (X+c)/(l+c).
Choosing thesevalues

implies that (13) can be obtained from (14)by multiplying (14)by I - (1+ c)L/(X+ c),
where I and L are the identity and lag operators, respectively.’
The third solution has al = (1+ c)/(X+ c)and obeys
Qt=

1+c
x+t-1+

L[ut-l
x+c

- crt--l]+ rt.

When II+ cl< IX+cI, th is is also a minimum state variable solution. However, since it
fails to be admissible for some parameter values (X < 1),it is not the global minimum
state variable solution of McCallum.

Similarly, choosing be = 0 and CO= 1 implies that

(13)can be obtained from (15) by multiplying it by (I - L). Note that adding a constant
term to (15) also gives an equation that solves (l3), since the constant disappears upon
application of I - L. Further note that this would fail for (15’) since the constant term in
(13’) is zero.
Transforming back to pt yields, respectively
Pt

= $-[X(R’

- a)+ (1+ X + 2c)pt-1 - (1+ c)pt-2 + a-t-2 - ut-2 + q-1 - (A + c)rt-I]

’ To further see that McCallum’s solution is not the unique nonexplosive solution when
X < 1, one can add the linear combination of martingales #mu

+ ytrnzt to equation (14)

where mrt = Cf,lari and m2t = Cf,rflvj with ar and P arbitrary. Since 1~1, 1~15 1, this is
also a nonexplosive solution. Also, a little algebra confirms that the solution with arbitrary
martingales can be transformed into equation (13).

11

+ bo[vt- cut-l/(X+ c)] + c0[rt - m-l/(X + c)].
Pt =-

*-

$--[(A

a) + Pt-1+

AR

pt = $---[&-(I

(13’)

- 1)ut + (A + c)rt + ut-1 - crt-11.

(14’)

+ c)(R* - a) + (1 + c)pt-1 + ut-1 - crt-11+ rt.

(15’)

Perhaps a more intuitive way of seeing the underlying indeterminacy is to iterate (12
forward n periods and to examine the system. Let nt =

[

crt _ ut
’
]D”dz=[A(Rp-.)l

for notational simplicity. Then (12) becomes

Et [ -]

= S-lJ”S [E] + $-[s-@)sz

+ s-‘J”-‘sflt]

(16)

where J is the diagonal matrix composed of the eigenvalues of (12) and S-l represents the
matrix of corresponding eigenvectors. They are given by

s-1
=[

Xfc
l’tc

1
1

1.

Examining the tist row of (16) yields
GPt+n

= (A + C)(a=

-

l)&pt+1+

[(I + c) -

(A + +qPt

+A[=-n](R*-a)+(#-‘-l)(crt-ut)

(17)

where (Y = (1 + c)/(X + c) and we have substituted zt = Etpt+l. Since c > 0, we observe
that larj> 1 for -1 - 2c < X < 1. Dividing (17) by cr” and letting n + 00, we obtain
Etn+l

=pt+&R*-u)+‘;;cVf’

which is the global minimum state variable solution in equation (14’).
The other case of interest is when X < -1 - 2c or A > 1, which implies Ial < 1.
Requiring R* = a and letting n + co, equation (17) becomes
Em+1

= +-[(I

+ c)pt - (crt - ut) + (A - l)Etz-+)].

Recalling that R* = a, we see that this agrees with (15’) when &p(co) = 0. However,
there exists an infinity of solutions for Etpt+l,

one for each arbitrary choice of Etp(co).

Interestingly, if one constrains oneself to the choice Etp(oo) = Etp:+l, the global miniium
state variable solution (14’) is obtained.
this solution.

Essentially, McCallum’s (1983) procedure picks

12
The global minimum state variable procedure for the above model works in the following manner. The procedure works by perturbing the model and examining a more general
specification of the money supply rule
rnf = hmt-l + X(& - R’).
The procedure then picks the solution associated with the eigenvalue that does not go to
zero when h is zero.

When h = 0, we know the nonexplosive solution is unique.

The

procedure indicates that the solution associated with the positive root of the difference
equation for the price level is the correct one and implies that the coefficient on pt-1 in
the solution for pt is one. As mentioned, this means that Etpt+i = Etpt for all j and hence
J-G(=)

= Etn+r.

In many instances the global miniium

state variable methodology has intuitive appeal.

A casual look out the window doesn’t seem to indicate that indeterminacy is an important
aspect of the economic environment. Adopting a solution that is robust for various values
of preference or technology parameters seems sensible since unique solutions often characterize well-defined optimization problems.

In the case of interest rate (money supply)

rules the parameters in question, h and X, are just arbitrarily chosen by the modeler or
policymaker.

In a standard optimizing model with money in the utility function choosing

h = 1 does not violate any transversality conditions, yet leads to a nominal indeterminacy.
An alternative interpretation to McCallum (1986) is that a money supply rule given by
(3b) is not well specified, rather than hi interpretation that hi particular solution should
be chosen.

Inferences drawn from the solution when h = 0 may not be relevant for a

solution when h = 1 as economic systems that are stationary are quite different from those
that are not.
(c) An alternative

nonstationary

money supply

rule

If instead of (3b) we close our economic system with equation (3c), the results are
strikingly different. The reduced form becomes
pt = [(I + c)pt-I

+ (A + c)&pt+l

- XEt-lpt+l - q-1

+ (A - c)Et-IP~

+ ut-1 + (A + c)rt - ut]/(l+

Updating puts this in our form with A = (1 + c)/(l
C=

-X/(l+X+c)

and D = (X+c)/(l+X+c).

[2$]=:[

x + c)*

+ x + c), B = (A - c)/(l

(18)
+ A + c),

Taking expectations and using zt s Etpt+l

-(1"+c) 1;2c ] [ft]+

[rt_o,/c].

13
The eigenvectors for this system are ~1= 1 and Y = (1 + c)/c.

As both are non-zero,

the matrix K is non-singular. It is easily verified that

transforms K into Jordan form.

Since c > 0, we have one eigenvector outside the unit

circle. Since S - DS = l/(1+ X + c)# 0 and the first column of QS is 1 + c - c = 1,the
hypotheses of the theorem hold. Since we have one initial condition and one root outside
the unit circle, there is a unique polynomially bounded solution from a given initial money
stock.

(This could also be easily verified by looking for additional solutions of the form

pt + ptmlt + vtmzt where pt is a solution to (18). The polynomial boundedness implies
m2t = 0. Substituting in (18)shows that ml,t+l =mLt.]
An extension of the Evans and Honkapohja (1986)technique yields the following
second-order solution
pt = [(1+ 2c)pt-1 - (1+ c)pt-2 - ut-2]/c + ut4/(X + c) + rt-2 - rt-1
+ b0[vt - (A + Xc + c2)vt-l/c(X + c)] + c0[rt - (A + Xc + c’)rt-l/c(X

+ c)] (19)

where b. and c,-,are arbitrary.
As in the previous section, there are two first-order equations solving (18).The 6rst
is the global minimum state variable solution of McCallum,
Pt = Pt-1+

$--[(A

- 1)~~+ (A + +t

+ vt-I - crt-11

(20)

and the second is the explosive solution

1+c

Pt =

cpt-1

ut-1
- vt + c
- rt.

(21)

As before, (19) may be obtained from (20) by setting b = (A - l)/(l+ c) and CO =
c 1 an d multiplying (20) by I - (1 + c)L/ c, while (19) is obtained from (21)
0 +M1+
by setting &, = -1 and co = 0 and multiplying by I - L. However, unlike the previous
section, (21)always yields an explosive solution.
Although (20) is a well-defined nonexplosive solution for finite but arbitrarily large X,
the variance of the price level goes to infinity as X --) 00. As McCallum (1986) notes,
this result is model specific. An augmented model that includes an aggregate supply term
containing pt - Et-Ipt would yield a price level with finite variance no matter how large X
became. As before, letting X + 00 can be interpreted as having the central bank buy and

14
sell bonds at a nominal interest rate that will yield a money supply equal to last period’s
money supply. When the aggregate supply term is included, buying and selling bonds at
& =

$Lpt
C

- m-l]

yields an equation similar to (20)as the liiiting
(d) A comparison

solution of this augmented model.

of all three rules

From an intuitive standpoint our results are a little puzzling. Responding to interest
rate deviations from a preset value is a well-defined procedure when the underlying money
supply rule is stationary, yet yields indeterminacy when the money supply is nonstationary.
This indeterminacy occurs even when R’ = a the expected real interest rate. Yet a nonstationary money supply rule that responds to deviations of the nominal interest rates from
last period’s expectation of the current nominal interest rate yields unique nonexplosive
solutions with the property that Et-l& = a in equilibrium.
With respect to the latter puzzle our conjecture is that specifying the nominal interest
rate target at Et-l& places restrictions on beliefs that are not present with money supply
rule (3b). For example today’s expectations of future money supplies, mt+l, are equal to
m with money supply rule (3~).
With specification (3b), Etmt+n = mt + XC~=~(Et&+j - a). Deviations of Et&+j from
a cumulate in expectations of future money. With X > 1 thiileads to an entire family of

pricelevel
pathsthatareconsistent
withvarious
departure
ofE&+i

from a. Essentially,

money supply rule (3b) d oes not pin down the future and hence does not uniquely define
current nominal quantities when X > 1.
This inability to uniquely define expectations of future money is potentially a problem
for money supply rule (3a). However, deviations of Et&+j from R’ = a, do not cumulate.
That is, it is impossible for E tm t+j to stray too far from the value b. Apparently this is
sufficient to guarantee uniqueness and that Et-l&

= a (when R* = u).

An alternative way of examining the difference between rules (3b)and (3~)would be
to posit a hybrid money supply rule

mi = m-1 + @t

- Et-&) + b(&-&

- a),

mo given.

With this rule the eigenvalues are (1 + c)/(X, + c) and 1 implying that -1 - 2c < X2 < 1
is needed for uniqueness of the nonexplosive solution. Considering only positive values of
X2, deviations of Et& +n from a can potentially accumulate in the expectations of mt+,.
However with X2 < 1 these deviations are insufficient to generate nonuniqueness.
with X2 < 1,Et&+n = a.

Hence

15
From our discussion one might also draw the conclusion that observing nonstationary
money is inconsistent with the central bank responding to nominal interest rate deviations
around some arbitrary value. This is not the case, since one could append a nonstationary
money control error, xt = xt-1 + et, to equation (3a) without influencing the discussion
concerning uniqueness. Interestingly, the rule (3a) with a random control error is identical
to
rn5= w-1 + A(& - R*) - A(&-1 - R’) + et, mo

given.

The eigenvalues when thii rule is used are (1 + X + c)/(X + c) and 1, which implies a unique
nonexplosive solution.

5. Barro’s Model
In a recent article, Barro (1989) builds on the work of Goodfriend (1987) and McCallum
(1986) in an attempt to generate a money supply rule that produces time series properties of nominal variables that are consistent with actual observations.

He also employs

McCallum’s (1983) procedure to isolate a unique global minimum state variable solution.
We have seen that this procedure can not always be relied upon to guarantee a unique
nonexplosive solution and, as we will show in the next section, does not always produce
expectationally stable solutions. It is, therefore, worth investigating Barro’s extension with
our methodology.
For our purposes, a simplified version of Barro’s money supply rule can be written as
m,b= mt-l + X1(& - R’) - As(&-1 - R*),

mo given

where we have altered the model by holding the interest rate target constant. The eigenvalues for the system using this money supply rule and (1) and (2) are (1 +X3 +c)/(&

+c)

and 1. Clearly not all values of AS and X1 will produce a unique nonexplosive solution.
In Barro’s model, however, the central bank is concerned about two objectives.

One

is to smooth nominal interest rates by minimizing E(& - R*)2. The other is to miniize
the variance of unexpected price level movements, i.e., E(pt - Et-1pt)2. The first concern
implies the As should be set arbitrarily large, while the second implies that Xr = (1 +
Xa)B - c(1 - 8) with 8 = ~:/(a:
of Xl/h

+ a:).

As X3 gets arbitrarily large, the limiting value

= 8. The restriction placed on parameter values by a concern for price level

surprises guarantees uniqueness for thii model. Hence, in searching for money supply rules
that yield nominal determinacy, one can employ reasonable loss functions that generate
the appropriate parameter restrictions.

16

6. Expectational Stability
Evans (1985) proposes an alternative to McCallum’s
particular solution from a class of solutions.

(1983) procedure for choosing a

He requires that any solution be expecta-

tionally stable. Take a small deviation from a rational expectations solution. Use this to
solve your system, and then update expectations. This process must converge to the same
rational expectations solution. The time t expectation of pt+l

at the N-th

stage will be

denoted Ef’pt+l. We will restrict our attention to linear expectations functions having the
form
E:pt+l

=

aN

+ PNPt

-t vNet

+ 6Nut

where et = [(A + c)rt - vt]/(l + X + c) and ut = (ut - crt)/(l

(22)

+ X + c). Updating, taking

expectations at time t, and substituting in (22), we obtain

(a) Trend

stationary

money

supply

Equation (8) with R’ = a can be written as
Pt = AI + Al&t+1
where & = (b+cu)/(l+X+c)
is expectationally
the

qC?CtatiOIlS

and Al = (X+c)/(l+X+c).

+ et

(24)
We can easily check to see if (10)

stable as X + 00. Since ut does not appear in (24), we may omit it from
fUIlCtiOIlwithout

1oSSOf generality,

leaving

Eypt+l = (YN+ @Nptf yNet.

Update (24), take expectations at time t and use (23) with 6~ = 0 to get Efv+lpt+l. This
yields the recursive relationships
aN+l

= &

pN+l

= Al&

-I-

Ar(l + /?N)QN

(25)

7N+l = &PN~N-

Thii system has two types of steady state solution.

The frrst is a = b + cu, p = 0 and

7 = 0. Obviously, this is implied by equation (10). The second has a = -&/Al,

/3 = l/Al

and 7 arbitrary. Linearizing (25), we see that the three roots for the first steady state are
Al, 0 and 0. Thus for IAll < 1, aN, /?N and 7~ converge to their steady state values as
N -+ 00. Since IAll < 1 for arbitrarily large A, the interest rate rule (3a) is expectationally
stable. Similarly, linearizing about the second steady state yields roots 1 + Al, 2 and 1.
This second steady state is unstable since one of the roots is larger than 1.

17
(b) Non-stationary

money supply

We next check to see if the minimal state variable solution of (11)is expectationally
stable. When R* = a, (11)has the form
Pt

= &%lpt

+ &Etpt+l

+ &a-l

+ w-l

+ et

(26)

where B1 = -c/(1+X + c),B2 = (A+ c)/(l
+ X + c),BS = (1+ c)/(l+ X + c),and et ad
ut are as before. Updating (26), taking the expectation at time t and using (22) and (23)
yields the recursive relationships
aN+l

=

[Bl + B2(1+

pN+l=

pN)]aN

&~N+Bz&+&

7N+l

=

(Bl

+ &PN)~N

6 N+l

=

(Bl

+ B~BN)~N

+ 1.

This iterative system has two types of stationary solutions:
P = I,7

The first has Q = 0,

= 0 and 6 = (1+ X + c)/(l+ c) (giving (14’)); the second has CYarbitrary,

@ = (1 + c)/(X + c), 7 = 0 and 6 = (1 + X + c)/(X + c) (giving (15’)). Linearizing around
the first steady state we obtain eigenvalues B1 + 2B2 (twice) and B1 + B2 (twice). These
eigenvalues are (2X + c)/(l+ X + c ) and X/(1+ A + c). When -(1 + c)/2< X < 1,this
solution is expectationally stable while for X > 1 or X < -(1 + c)/2, it is expectationally
unstable.
The second type of solution is not unique, but rather a continuum. Because of t&ii,
we only ask for stability in the sense that small deviations from a member of the solution
set lead to convergence to another member of that set. These solutions have eigenvalues
1, (2 + c)/(l

+ A + c) and l/(1 + X + c) (t wice). This system is expectationally unstable

for -(2 + c) < X < 1. When X < -(2 + c) or X > 1,three of the eigenvalues have modulus
less than 1. Only stability of aN is still in doubt because of the unit eigenvalue.5 However,
given initial CQwe find that
N-l
aN = m

n

[BI + &(I

+ Pi)].

i=O

Thus
lo&N/~]

=

Nflo$%

+

Bz(l

+bi)].

i=O

’ It pays to be careful here. Evans (1985) claims stability with a unit root in hi Proposition 2, part II. However, actual calculation of the solution reveals that the equilibrium
set is not stable. Rather, his system converges to the other steady stateifa isbelowits
steady state value, while his system blows up if a is above its steady state value.

18
We now apply the ratio test to the sum. Since fii+r = B1/3i+ B#
is (log[Bl + I&(1+ B&i + B&

+ Bs)])/(log[Bl+

Bt(l +&)I).

+ Bs, the relevant ratio

Using L’H6pital’s rule and

the facts that pi + p = (1 + c)/(X + c) and fl = B1/3 + B2P2 + Bs allows us to obtain the
limit Bl+ 2B2p = (2 + c)/(l+

X + c). Since thii has modulus less than one when X > 1,

the series, and hence the product, converges. It follows that the solution set is stable. In
particular, (15’) gives the expectationally stable solution for large X, while the miniium
state variable solution (14’) is expectationally unstable.
(c) Alternative

non-stationary

money

supply

Using (3~) implies a different outcome. Equation (18)can be written as
Pt = GE,-,p,

+ C2E t-1 pt+l + C&n+1

cl = (A - c)/(l + X + c), Cz = -X/(1
(1 + c)/(l

+ Cot-1

+ w-l

+ X + c), C, = (X + c)/(l

+ et,

+ X + c) and C4 =

+ X + c) with ut-1 and et as before. The presence of the constant term creates

additional difficulties since this equation has a unit root. To handle it, we include a trend
term in the expectation function. Thus EFp t+l = ~N+PNpt+rNet+SNut+tlNt. Proceeding
as before, we obtain the following recursive relationships:
aN+l

=

[cl

P N+l

=

cl@,

+

+

7N+l = [Cl +
6N+1

=

tl~+l=

(c2

+
(c2

&)(I
+

+ fh)]aN

c2)&

(c2

+

cS)/&V]7IV
cS)@N]bN

+

+

+

VN

c,

[cl

+

(c2

+

1

[Cl

+

(C2

+ Cs)(l + PN)]~N.

Again, there are two steady state solutions corresponding to (20) and (21). The first
has a! = 0, p = 1, 7 = 0, 6 = l/C 4 and q = 0 while the second has a arbitrary,
p = (1 + c)/c, 7 = 0, 6 = (1 + X + c)/c and q = 0. Linearizing around the minimum state
variable solutions in (20), the conditions for expectational stability are ]Cr + Z(C2 + C3) 1=
1(X + c)/(l

+ X + c)I < 1 and ]Ci + C, + C3] = IX/(1 + X + c)] < 1. These conditions

are satisfied for positive values of X. The solution corresponding to (21) requires that
](X + c)/(l

+X + c)] < 1 and I(2 + X + c)/(l+

X + c)] < 1. These cannot be simultaneously

satisfied.

7. Summary and Conclusions
This paper provides a detailed examination of the nominal determinacy properties of
various interest rate rules. The class of rules examined is broad enough to essentially span

19
most of the literature on this subject.

Our analysis indicates that care should be taken

when specifying policies in which the central bank responds to nominal interest rates. This
is especially true when the underlying money supply rule displays nonstationarity, since
determinacy issues are sensitive to specification of the interest rate feedback term. In thii
case the preferred model includes responses to deviations from last periods expectation of
the current nominal interest rate rather than responses to some arbitrary target. If for
other reasons, as in Barre (1989), it is desirable to explore how monetary responses to an
exogenous interest rate target affect economic outcomes then the investigator should be
careful to restrict the admissable parameter values that are assigned to feedback coefficients.
In examining this class of policies we have drawn from a wide range of literature that
deals with the solutions to rational expectations models. This literature ranges from the
undetermined coefficient approach of Lucas to the martingale method of Pesaran (1987)
and the general ARMA solutions of Evans and Honkapohja (1986). We have also looked
at the expectational stability properties of the models and find that there is a one to one
correspondence

between unique nonexplosive solutions and expectationally

stable solu-

tions. When uniqueness is a problem we find that under a peg the general class of ARMA
solutions are expectationally stable, but that McCallum’s solution is not.
To rigorously examine the question of uniqueness we have extended the counting rule
methodology of Blanchard and Kahn (1980) to models that include past expectations of
current and future variables.

Since rational expectations models with this attribute are

fairly common, our methods used to establish our theorem should be useful in a variety of
other contexts.

Appendix: Blanchard and Kahn Revisited
Although Blanchard and Kahn’s result is not implied by our result, or vice-versa, our
method does apply to their system. A close reading of the Blanchard and Kahn paper
reveals that the predetermined/non-predetermined

distinction is only required when the

number of predetermined variables is equal to the number of roots inside the unit circle.
However, our method shows that predeterminedness is not required here either.
Suppose there are wz’variables Xt with initial conditions and m variables without initial
conditions Pt. These correspond to the predetermined and non-predetermined variables,
respectively. The system considered by Blanchard and Kahn is

20
For uniqueness, we may consider the homogeneous case (f2t = 0) without loss of generality.
$i to obtain EtQt+1 = At& The Jordan form of A is .7 = S’lAS
[
I
and the general solution to the homogeneous equation is Qt = SJtMt where Mt is an
Apply Et and set Qt =

arbitrary martingale. If md = m, the last m entries of Mt are zero. Substituting back in
the original equation, we obtain SrrJ’+lMr,t+r = [ASJ'Mlt]l= SrrP’Mrt.
invertible, this implies Mr,t+r =Mrt.
the m’-vector Mlo.

When Srr is

The solution is deterministic and is determined by

The m’ initial conditions imply Mlt =Mrc = 0. It follows that the

inhomogeneous system has a unique solution.
Our method also applies to their first example C. It is Yt = uEt-lYt - &. For simplicity,
suppose the forcing process 2, obeys Et-l& = 0. There are no initial conditions. Applying
Et-1 to the equation yields 0 = (1 - a)Et-lYt. Unless a = 1, Et-lYt = 0. Substituting
back in the homogeneous equation yields Yt = -&

as the unique solution.

The second example C, P t+r = a(E&+2 - E&+1) + et doesn’t quite fit the statement
of our theorem since zero is a root of K. Nonetheless, the same techniques apply and yield
a unique solution provided Pc is given.

References
Robert J. Barre (1989),
Interest Rate Targeting, J. Mon. Econ. 23, 3-30.
Olivier J. Blanchard and Charles M. Kahn, The solution of linear difference models under
rational expectations, Econometrica
48 (1980),
1305-1311.
Lawrence E. Blume, David Easley and Margaret Bray, Introduction to the stability of
rational expectations equilibrium, .I. Econ. Theory 26 (1982),
313-317.
Margaret Bray, Learning, estimation, and the stability of rational expectations,
Theory 26 (1982),
318-339.

J. Econ.

Matthew Canzoneri, Dale Henderson and Kenneth S. Rogoff, The information content of
the interest rate and optimal monetary policy, Quart. J. Econ. 98 (1983),
546566.
Stephen J. DeCanio, Rational expectations and learning from experience, Quart. .7. Econ.

93 (1979),
47-57.
MichaelDotsey and Robert King, Monetary instruments and policy rules in a rational
expectations environment, J. Mon. Econ. 12 (1983),
357-382.
Michael Dotsey and Robert King, Informational implication of interest rate rules, Amer.
Econ. Rev. 76 (1986),
33-42.
George W. Evans, Expectational stability and the multiple equilibria problem in linear
rational expectations models, Quart. J. Econ. 100 (1985),
1217-1233.

21
Geor e W. Evans, Selection criteria for models with non-uniqueness, J. Mon. Econ. 18

(198&147-157.
George W. Evans and Seppo Honkapohja, A complete characterization of ARMA solutions
to linear rational expectations models, Rev. Econ. Stu$. 53 (1986), 227-239.
R. Frydman and E. S. Phelps, “Individual expectations and aggregate outcomes: An introduction to the problem,” in IndividualForecastingand Aggregate Outcomes (R. Frydman
and E. S. Phelps, eds.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1983.
Marvin Goodfriend, Interest rate smoothing and price level trend stationarity, J. Mon.
Econ. 19 (1987), 335-348.
C. Gourieroux, Jean-Jaques Laffont and A. Monfort, Rational expectations in dynamic
linear models: Analysis of the solutions, Econometrica50 (1982),
409-425.
Bennett T. McCallum, Price level determinacy with an interest rate policy rule and rational
expectations, J. Mon. Econ. 8 (1981),
319-329.
Bennett T. McCallum, On non-uniqueness in rational expectations models: An attempt at
perspective, J. Mon. Econ. 11 (1983),
134168.
Bennett T. McCallum, Some issues concerning interest rate pegging, price level determinacy, and the real bills doctrine, J. Mon. Econ. 17 (1986),
135-160.
lK~~g%saran,

Identification of rational expectations models, J. Econometrics 16 (1981),

.
M. H. Pesaran (1987), The Limits to Rational Expectations, Basil Blackwell, New York
Thomas Sargent (1979), Macroeconomic

Theory, Academic Press, New York.