View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Income Volatility and
Portfolio Choices

WP 20-01

Yongsung Chang
Seoul National University
Jay H. Hong
Seoul National University
Marios Karabarbounis
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Yicheng Wang
University of Oslo

Income Volatility and Portfolio Choices∗
Yongsung Chang
Seoul National University

Jay H. Hong
Seoul National University

Marios Karabarbounis
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Yicheng Wang
University of Oslo

March 14, 2020

Abstract
Based on administrative data from Statistics Norway, we find economically significant
shifts in households’ financial portfolios around structural breaks in income volatility. When
the standard deviation of labor-income growth doubles, the share of risky assets decreases
by 4 percentage points. We ask whether this estimated marginal effect is consistent with a
standard model of portfolio choice with idiosyncratic volatility shocks. The standard model
generates a much more aggressive portfolio response than we see in the data. We show that
Bayesian learning about the underlying volatility regime can reconcile the gap between the
model and the data.

JEL Classification: E2, G1, J3.
Keywords: Income Volatility, Portfolio Choice, Risky Share, Bayesian Learning
∗

Emails: yongsung.chang@gmail.com, jayhong@snu.ac.kr, marios.karabarbounis@rich.frb.org, and
yicheng.wang@econ.uio.no. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. For helpful comments,
we thank our discussant José Mustre-del-Rı́o, and also Mark Aguiar, Mark Bils, Marcus Hagedorn, Grey
Gordon, Per Krusell, Ben Moll, Luigi Pistaferri, Kjetil Storesletten, Morten Ravn, Alex Wolman and other
participants at U of Oslo, Econometric Society China Meeting 2018 in Shanghai, SED 2018, the 12th Nordic
Summer Symposium in Macroeconomics, EEA/ESEM 2018 in Cologne, AEA 2019, Rochester, Yonsei, Seoul
National U, Pittsburgh, Richmond Fed, SHUFE, Tsinghua PBC and ITAM. Yicheng Wang acknowledges
financial support from the European Research Council ((FP7/2007-2013)/ERC grant n.324085, Principal
investigator: Kjetil Storesletten at the University of Oslo). We also thank the Frisch Center at the University
of Oslo, Andreas Moxnes and Marcus Hagedorn for access to the administrative data of Statistics Norway.

1

Introduction

How do households respond to background risk? A large literature has studied how the
presence of uninsurable labor-income risk affects the patterns of savings, consumption, and
portfolio allocation over the life cycle. Despite the extensive research done, there is still
substantial progress to be made. On one hand, quantitative models analyzing the role of
labor-market risk in the allocation of financial assets often report difficulties in matching
the empirical patterns of portfolio choice, such as the average stock holdings or the risky
share profile across ages (for example, Cocco, Gomes, and Maenhout (2005), Benzoni, CollinDufresne, and Goldstein (2011), Huggett and Kaplan (2016), to name only a few). On the
other hand, empirical studies—which are much fewer in number—have difficulty in finding an
economically sizable effect of labor-income volatility on households’ portfolios (for example,
Guiso, Jappelli, and Terlizzese, 1996; Palia, Qi, and Wu, 2014).
Our paper contributes to this literature both empirically and quantitatively. First,
based on administrative panel data from Statistics Norway, we establish a sizable negative
relationship between income risk and the risky share in financial assets. We overcome two
problems that have led to small estimated responses in the literature: (i) the lack of highquality panel data, and (ii) the measurement of exogenous variations in income volatility.
Second, we build a structural model that successfully reproduces the estimated response of
portfolio to income risk. This is a new attempt because the existing studies have been mostly
interested in matching the average risky share not the marginal effect of income risk. As
our analysis illustrates, the marginal effect is useful to (i) understand the nature of earning
dynamics and (ii) assess the welfare cost of background risk.
Households in Norway are obliged to report detailed information about their income
and wealth to the tax authority every year. As a result, our dataset includes a complete
description of households’ labor income and financial assets as well as their allocation to safe
and risky financial accounts. We merge the households’ income and financial data with other
data regarding labor market status, demographic characteristics, and, more importantly for
our analysis, employer information.
We overcome the challenges in estimating the marginal effect of income risk in two ways.
First, we identify the “structural’’ breaks in income volatility, which are the periods when
an individual worker experiences the largest change in the standard deviation of income
growth. By looking at big events, we can potentially avoid noisy variations unrelated to true
regime changes. Second, since not all the structural breaks are exogenous (or unpredictable)
to households, we use firm-side information as an instrumental variable—an innovative
method pioneered by Fagereng, Guiso, and Pistaferri (2017). Specifically, based on a matched

1

employer-employee register, we use the volatility of firms’ sales as an instrument to isolate an
orthogonal variation in the individual worker’s income volatility.
We find a clear negative relationship between income volatility and risky share. According
to our instrumental variable estimation, when the income volatility doubles, the risky share
decreases by 4 percentage points over a 4-year horizon. This economically sizable estimate
illustrates that our methodology (individual structural breaks combined with a firm-side
instrumental variable) is effective.
We then build a structural model of portfolio choice to reproduce the estimated risky
share response to income volatility. Our benchmark structural model features: (i) a life-cycle
economy with incomplete asset markets, (ii) a portfolio choice between risk-free bonds and
risky equity (e.g., Cocco, Gomes, and Maenhout (2005) and Gomes and Michaelides (2005)),
(iii) an exogenous borrowing limit, (iv) labor earnings that consist of a mix of heterogeneousincome profiles (Guvenen and Smith, 2014) and uninsurable shocks, and finally (iv) our
highlighted new element, idiosyncratic shocks to income volatility.
The structural model is estimated by indirect inference using various moments from the
Norwegian panel including the estimated portfolio response to volatility. To identify the
(hard-to-observe) persistence of the idiosyncratic volatility shock, we exploit the age profile
of the kurtosis of earnings emphasized by Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, and Song (2015): the
age profile of the cross-sectional kurtosis heavily depends on this persistence of the volatility
shocks.1
We show that the standard model cannot replicate the portfolio response in the data. It
predicts that in response to an increase in (uninsurable) income volatility, a typical household
should decrease the risky share much more aggressively than what we find from the Statistics
Norway panel. To fill the gap between the model and the data, we introduce Bayesian learning
about the volatility of underlying income process. While there are other ways to introduce
frictions into the model—e.g., adjustment costs in rebalancing the portfolio, Bayesian learning
has a couple of merits. First, it is a parsimonious way of reconciling the model with the
data—it does not introduce an additional free parameter. Second, adjustment costs are
probably less important for the intensive margin (the adjustment of portfolios for households
that already participated in risky investments) on which our analysis is focused.2
Finally, according to our structural model, the welfare cost of background risk is fairly big
when a worker experiences an increase in income risk in the early stage of life. For example,
1

This identification strategy mirrors that by Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004), who show that the
persistence of labor-income shocks is important for the slope of the life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional
variance of income.
2
Adjustment costs have been found to play an important role at the extensive margin, the decision to
participate in the stock market or not.

2

a three-fold increase in the standard deviation of income growth at age 22 can generate a
welfare cost of 9 percent in consumption-equivalent units. While the majority of welfare losses
come from the volatile consumption (lack of insurance), a half-of-a-percentage point welfare
loss is due to rebalancing the financial portfolio toward safe assets—missing the opportunity
to exploit the profitable but risky investment (the equity premium).
Our contribution to the existing literature on labor-market risk and portfolio choice can
be summarized as follows. Most of the literature (based on cross-sectional data) reports
that an effect of background risk on risky share is qualitatively consistent with economic
theory but quantitatively small. Based on the Italian household survey of expectations about
future income, Guiso, Jappelli, and Terlizzese (1996) find a small effect of risk on portfolio.
Palia, Qi, and Wu (2014) report that the impact of background risk (such as labor income,
house prices, and business income) on the risky share is not sizable: a one standard deviation
increase in the labor-income variance (which amounts to a one-and-half times increase in
the standard deviation of labor-income growth on average) reduces the risky share by 1.9
percentage points, much smaller than our estimates. A notable exception is Angerer and
Lam (2009). Based on the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth for 1979, a 10 percent
increase in the standard deviation of (the permanent component of) labor-income growth
decreases the risky share by 3.7 percentage points, close to an upper bound in the literature
and almost three times larger than our estimates.
We overcome the identification challenges by identifying individual structural breaks
(coupled with a firm-side instrumental variable) from a high-quality administrative panel
data set from Statistics Norway. Our analysis yields a large and precisely estimated response
of risky share to income risk.3 We closely follow the methodology of Fagereng, Guiso, and
Pistaferri (2017), who first used the firm-side information as an instrument to isolate the
orthogonal variations in households’ income risk. We then expand their method by identifying
the individual-specific structural breaks in the underlying income process. Our approach of
using structural breaks has its own merit. By further reducing the influence of frequent noisy
events, it increases the estimated response by 20 percent.
There has been extensive progress in quantitative analysis of portfolio choice and labormarket risk, represented by Heaton and Lucas (2000), Haliassos and Michaelides (2003),
Cocco, Gomes, and Maenhout (2005), Gomes and Michaelides (2005), Benzoni, Collin3
There has been increased use of the administrative data from Statistics Norway. Fagereng, Gottlieb, and
Guiso (2017) analyze the portfolio responses to volatility or portfolio allocation over the life cycle. Fagereng
and Halvorsen (2015) study household debt and heterogeneity in the marginal propensity to consume. Eika,
Mogstad, and Vestad (2017) analyze consumption expenditure using data on income and assets. Fagereng,
Holm, Moll, and Natvik (2019) analyze the saving rate across the wealth distribution and highlight the
importance of capital gains.

3

Dufresne, and Goldstein (2011), Athreya, Ionescu, and Neelakantan (2015), Huggett and
Kaplan (2016), Fagereng, Gottlieb, and Guiso (2017), Chang, Hong, and Karabarbounis
(2018), and Catherine (2019), to name only some. The existing literature has been mostly
interested in matching the average risky share, not the marginal effect of income risk on which
we focus.4 Our analysis differentiates itself from this literature by (i) introducing idiosyncratic
volatility shocks and parsimonious Bayesian learning about the underlying income process
and (ii) by structurally estimating and testing the model.
Our paper also contributes to the literature on the estimation of earnings dynamics.
Structural models of earnings dynamics typically analyze the level of labor earnings in
conjunction with data on consumption choices (for example, Primiceri and van Rens, 2009;
Guvenen and Smith, 2014). In contrast, we build a structural model to analyze the individual
volatility of labor earnings using as information a reliable estimated response of portfolio
choice to income risk. The risky share is a suitable alternative target on which to base our
estimation, especially since quality panel data on consumption choices are hard to obtain
and—as we show in our empirical analysis—households actively use the portfolio margin to
insure against larger income fluctuations.
Similarly, our paper is related to the literature analyzing the dynamic process for
idiosyncratic volatility. Meghir and Pistaferri (2004) model volatility dynamics using an
ARCH specification based on data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics. Guvenen,
Karahan, Ozkan, and Song (2015) use tax-record data to document a series of stylized
facts regarding higher-order moments of the earnings distribution. They estimate a flexible
specification that allows for i.i.d. volatility shocks. We consider a dynamic process for
volatility that we model as an AR(1). We use higher-order moments of labor-income growth
to discipline the size and persistence of the volatility shocks.5
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes our empirical specifications and documents the basic patterns regarding the response of portfolio choice to
income volatility. Section 3 sets up the structural model. Section 4 describes the estimation
results as well as the identification of the structural parameters. Section 5 explores specific
aspects of stochastic volatility, such as the workers’ information set or its persistence, and
also computes welfare losses from volatility fluctuations. Section 6 concludes.
4

There are a few exceptions to this; Gollier and Pratt (1996) develop a model but without endogenous
wealth accumulation. Bertaut and Haliassos (1997) and Viceira (2001) analyze the optimal allocation of
assets under various degrees of labor-income risk.
5
Our paper introduces learning about the volatility of labor income, whereas the existing literature has
focused on learning about the level of income (Pischke, 1995; Guvenen, 2007; Guvenen and Smith, 2014).

4

2

Empirical Analysis

We utilize a wealth of information regarding labor income, asset holdings, and portfolio
composition from Statistics Norway to document two facts:
1. A large fraction of workers experience sharp changes in the volatility of their laborincome growth (measured by the standard deviation).
2. The risky share of financial assets significantly decreases (increases) in response to an
increase (decrease) in labor-income volatility.

2.1

Data

The Norwegian Registry is a set of comprehensive, relatively measurement-error-free data with
detailed information on labor income and household financial assets. Households in Norway
are subject to not only an income tax but also a wealth tax. Thus, they are obliged to report
their complete income and wealth holdings to the tax authority every year. Employers, banks,
brokers, insurance companies, and any other financial intermediaries are also obliged to send
information on the value of personal assets to both the individual and the tax authority.6
The financial accounts in our data include bank deposits, financial securities, shares in
mutual funds, shares in private companies, pension agreements, insurance policies, total debt
(loans, credit purchases, mortgages), and others. We also have information on homeownership
as well as house values.7
We merge our wealth data with other data sets such as: (1) the Income Registry Data,
which have detailed information on earned income including cash salary, taxable benefits and
sickness and maternity benefits each year, capital investment income, entrepreneurial income,
unemployment benefits, and pensions; (2) the Central Population Register, which contains
yearly individual demographic information (e.g., gender, date of birth, marital status, number
of children, to name a few); (3) the National Educational Database, which has the history
and the latest education record for each resident, and finally, (4) the Employer-Employee
Register, which provides annual information on workers’ labor market status (full-/part-time
6

Traded financial securities are reported at market value. The value of shares in private companies is
reported by individuals as well as private companies to the tax authority. The tax authority will then combine
the information from companies’ reports with those from individual households and adjust if necessary.
7
Reliable information on the house value is available only for the period 2010-2014. For earlier years, the
housing value for homeowners reported in the tax registry data may not be the true market values, typically
underreported, due to self-reporting errors and/or treatment policies of wealth tax. This is well-documented
in the literature (see Eika, Mogstad, and Vestad (2017), Fagereng and Halvorsen (2017), among others).
For our definition of the risky share, we focus on financial assets and exclude housing and mortgage debt.
Nonetheless, in the empirical analysis, we include homeownership dummies in the list of control variables in
the regression.

5

employment, employer ID, beginning/ending time of job, total payments from each employer,
industry, occupation, etc.). All data sets are merged using unique personal identifiers assigned
to each individual and firm (similar to social security numbers and employment identification
numbers in the U.S.). For more details on our data, see Appendix A.
The data are uniquely suitable to address many challenges arising in the empirical analysis
of portfolio choices and income volatility. Traditional data sets, which are typically based on
surveys, present at least four issues. First, respondents often misreport their labor income or
wealth intentionally or unintentionally.8 In our data, information is directly collected by third
parties (employers or financial institutions) for tax purposes, which substantially reduces
measurement errors. Second, household surveys are often top-coded. This is problematic when
analyzing higher-order moments of earnings that may be driven by top earners (Guvenen,
Karahan, Ozkan, and Song, 2015).9 Third, traditional data with detailed information on
households’ financial assets (such as the Survey of Consumer Finances) are repeated crosssections. Thanks to the panel dimension of our data, we can eliminate bias stemming from
unobserved fixed heterogeneity (e.g., risk aversion across individuals) in the estimation.
Fourth, there is frequent attrition in traditional data, whereas attrition in our data occurs
only due to migration or death.
From the whole population with income tax registration records in 1993, we first choose
the native Norwegian males, older than 25 in 1993, with no missing records on education and
demographic variables. We then randomly select 10 percent from the above sample (amounting
to 137,776 individuals and 2,880,970 person-year observations). For each individual male in
our sample, we can then obtain his household information (marital status, demographics,
total household income and wealth, and so on). For more details on our sample selection and
construction, see Appendix A.2.

2.2

Risky Share

Following the standard literature, we classify financial assets into two categories: safe and
risky. Safe assets include deposits in Norwegian banks, the cash value of life insurance policies,
and debt securities traded in the financial market (mainly government bonds). Risky assets
include shares in mutual funds, shares in private companies, and financial securities (mainly
stocks and equity certificates traded in financial markets).10 Total financial assets are the
8

For example, see the handbook chapter “Measurement Error in Survey Data,” by Bound, Brown, and
Mathiowetz (2001).
9
This is important for our analysis as the life-cycle profile of the kurtosis of labor-income growth plays a
key role in identifying the persistence of volatility shocks (as we show in Section 4.1).
10
Since we do not have detailed information on the riskiness of the individual’s investment in mutual
funds, we use aggregate statistics from Statistics Norway to split the assets in mutual funds into risky and

6

sum of safe and risky assets at the household level. The risky share of financial assets is the
value of risky assets over the value of total financial assets. In our benchmark definition, we
do not consider debt and focus on gross savings.

2.3

Individual Structural Break in Income Volatility

We measure labor-market risk based on an individual structural break in income volatility.11
The main idea is to identify an episode of a “large” change in labor-income volatility.12 More
specifically, we look for a year when an individual worker experiences the largest change
in terms of the standard deviation in labor-income growth. The algorithm to identify the
structural volatility break is as follows:
1. Compute the residual (net of age and time effects) annual labor earnings of individual i
at time t: yi,t .
2. Construct labor-income growth: ∆yit ≡ yit − yi,t−1 . We focus on the changes in income
growth rather than the level to eliminate potential income variations due to heterogeneity
in income profiles (which is strongly supported by the data).13
3. We then construct the standard deviation before and after τ , SD(∆y)i,t<τ and SD(∆y)i,t≥τ ,
respectively, for all τ . The change in income volatility for a worker i in year τ is
∆SDi,τ = SD(∆y)i,t≥τ − SD(∆y)i,t<τ .
4. Given the sequence of volatility changes for worker i: {∆SDi,τ }, we identify the
structural break period τ ∗ such that τ ∗ = argmaxτ abs(∆SDi ). The corresponding
volatility change in the structural-break year is denoted by ∆SDi,τ ∗ .
Using this methodology we identify the structural break year τ ∗ for each worker. Each
structural break is associated with a positive or a negative change in the standard deviation
of labor-income growth. Since we identify the largest change in the worker’s income history,
each worker has a single structural break.
risk-free components. Our results are quite robust to different splitting rules.
11
For an application of this approach in the context of neighborhood segregation, see Card, Mas, and
Rothstein (2008), and for housing and labor markets, see Charles, Hurst, and Notowidigdo (2018).
12
In our benchmark specification, the unit of our analysis is the individual. Nonetheless, portfolio responses
may be affected by insurance between the primary and the secondary earner. Therefore, we explore in our
robustness section the portfolio responses when we also consider the household as the unit of analysis using
household-level total disposable income.
13
According to the labor-income specification in Section 3, labor income for worker i at age j is yij =
ai + βi × j + xij . Labor-income growth equals ∆yij = yij − yi,j−1 = βi + ∆xij . Therefore, variability over
some periods V ar(∆yij ) will ignore the constant term βi and only consider the variability in the time-varying
component V ar(∆xij ).

7

Figure 1: Construction of Individual-Specific τ ∗
τ∗ τ∗

y

τ∗ τ∗

∆y

0

2000

2002

2004

2006

2000

2008

2002

2004

2006

2008

Notes: The left (right) panel shows hypothetical income paths (growth rates) for two workers. For
each worker we show the year identified as a structural break by our method.

We demonstrate our methodology to identify the individual structural break in Figure 1.
The left panel plots hypothetical labor-income paths, y, for two workers: worker A (solid line)
and worker B (dotted line). The right panel shows the growth rate of income, ∆y. Worker A’s
growth rate fluctuates before 2003, and stabilizes after 2003. The structural break τ ∗ occurs
in 2003 and the volatility of income growth decreases after the structural break. Worker B’s
growth rate is constant up to 2004 and fluctuates thereafter. The structural break τ ∗ occurs
in 2004, and the volatility of income growth increases after the structural break.
For our benchmark, the sample is restricted to workers with at least 18 years of observations of labor earnings. We focus only on employed workers with identified employer IDs, and
we do not include self-employed workers. These restrictions decrease the sample to 48,768
individuals. Moreover, we require at least 16 years of positive risky shares, which decreases
the sample to 18,156 individuals.14 We also require total financial assets to be above 50,000
NOK in 2005 (which decreases the sample further to 16,700 individuals).15 In the robustness
section below, we confirm that our results are robust with different sample-selection criteria
considered.
14

Hence, we are basically looking at the response of risky shares conditional on participation.
This is close to the 10th percentile of the cross-sectional distribution of total financial assets in 2005.
We impose this restriction because the risky share could be very noisy for workers with a small amount of
total financial assets.
15

8

2.4

Response of the Risky Share

We examine the household’s portfolio choice around the individual volatility break τ ∗ . In
particular, we compute the change in the risky shares with a window of k-years before and
after the structural break, RSi,τ ∗ +k − RSi,τ ∗ −k , for k = 1, 2, 3, 4.
We estimate the response of the risky share with the following regression:
RSi,τ ∗ +k − RSi,τ ∗ −k = β∆SDi,τ ∗ + αXi,τ ∗ + δDt + i,τ ∗ .

(1)

Our benchmark specification includes year dummies (Dt ) and a set of individual controls
(denoted by Xi,τ ∗ ). This includes changes (between τ ∗ − k and τ ∗ + k) in log of household’s
disposable income, log of the household’s wealth, total number of children, number of children
younger than 10, and number of children younger than 5. We also include dummies for changes
in marital status and homeownership. Moreover, we include the levels of log household income
and wealth as well as age and education dummies at τ ∗ .
The coefficient β gives the change in the risky share (in percentage points) if the standard
deviation of income growth increases by one unit. For example, the median of the standard
deviation of income growth in our benchmark sample is 0.25 (see Table 9 in Appendix B).
Thus, if income volatility is doubled for the median worker, the impact would be β × 0.25
percentage points on the risky share.
Figure 2 plots a simple scatter-bin plot between the change in income volatility (measured
as the largest change in income growth ∆SDτ ∗ ) and the change in the risky share over an
8-year window (k = 4) without any controls. It shows a clear negative relationship between
changes in labor-income volatility and changes in the risky share. The plot confirms that
around periods of heightened income volatility, households reduce their exposure to risk in
financial investments by decreasing the risky share.
Table 1 reports the estimates of the regression. We show the estimates with and without
any controls Xi,τ ∗ . For all windows, the risky share decreases in response to an increase in
volatility. Without controls, when the standard deviation of income growth increases by one
unit, the risky share decreases by 1.18, 4.36, 5.71, and 7.85 percentage points, for k=1 to 4,
respectively. With controls, the risky share decreases by 0.77, 2.91, 2.37, and 2.91 percentage
points, for k=1 to 4, respectively. Except for k = 1, all estimates are statistically significant
at the 1 percent level. The control variables (most notably the level and the changes in
income and wealth) absorb a lot of the changes in the risky share and decrease the magnitude
of coefficients. Looking at a 4-year window (k = 2), if the standard deviation of income
growth doubles in size for the median worker, the risky share decreases by 0.72 percentage
points (2.91 × 0.25).
9

Figure 2: Risky Share and Income Volatility

Change in Risky Share (percentage points)

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-3.5

-2.5

-1.5

-0.5
0.5
1.5
Change in Income Volatility

2.5

3.5

Notes: The figure is a bin-scatter plot. The y−axis represents the change in the risky share (∆RS)
and the x−axis represents the change in income volatility (∆SD) over an 8-year (k = 4) window
around the individual structural break ∆SDi,τ ∗ .

In our analysis, we have addressed a major challenge highlighted in the literature
estimating the portfolio response to volatility: unobserved heterogeneity. Studies that have
estimated the volatility effect on portfolios typically rely on cross-sectional variation (with the
exception of Fagereng, Guiso, and Pistaferri, 2017). In our regression, we estimate the change
in the risky share to the change in the individual income volatility. Thus, our methodology
eliminates unobserved fixed heterogeneity. Nonetheless, our OLS estimates of the risky share
response are not substantially larger than those in the studies using cross-sectional variation.
Therefore, based on our exercise, unobserved fixed heterogeneity is not necessarily a major
driving force behind the small responses of risky share found in the literature.
A second major concern is the measurement of labor-income risk. Typically, risk is
measured using the observed income volatility. However, risk can be very different from the
observed volatility, especially if households already anticipate the changes in income volatility.
In fact, a recent literature suggests that a substantial portion of the residual variation in
earnings is predictable and reflects individual choices rather than risk (e.g., Primiceri and
van Rens, 2009; Guvenen and Smith, 2014). According to Cunha and Heckman (2007), the
statistical decomposition of earnings cannot distinguish uncertainty from other sources of
income variability. Misinterpretation of labor-income volatility as pure income risk is likely
10

Table 1: Response of Risky Share to Income Volatility

∆SDi,τ ∗ (OLS)

[ i,τ̂ (IV)
∆SD

J test†

Controls

k=1

k=2

k=3

k=4

No

-1.18**
(0.50)

-4.36***
(0.58)

-5.71***
(0.62)

-7.85***
(0.65)

Yes

-0.77
(0.58)

-2.91***
(0.72)

-2.37***
(0.74)

-2.91***
(0.76)

No

-8.45***
(2.09)

-20.70***
(2.49)

-25.67***
(2.63)

-33.67***
(2.84)

Yes

-4.96
(4.12)
0.26

-16.35***
(4.86)
0.67

-20.61***
(5.23)
0.92

-24.80***
(5.43)
0.66

Notes: OLS estimates report the coefficients from regression (1). The IV estimates also use the
first-stage regression (2). The numbers in parentheses are the robust standard errors. The asterisk(s)
denote the statistical significance at three p-values: 10%, 5%, and 1%. † denotes the p-value for the
over-identifying restriction tests (Hansen’s J test). The first-stage F -tests have p-values of 0.00 for
all cases and thus are not reported.

to bias the estimated response of portfolio choice toward zero.
In order to identify the marginal effect on portfolio choice of (uninsurable) income
risk one needs exogenous variation in the latter. To this end, we employ an instrumental
variable estimation based on firm-side variables, a method developed by Fagereng, Guiso, and
Pistaferri (2017). The identifying assumption is that an individual worker cannot influence
the firm’s overall performance. To identify exogenous variations in income volatility, we use
as instruments the volatility of growth rates for sales and value added (both scaled by assets)
of firm f where a worker i is employed.16 Using the exact same steps 1-3 described above,
s
v
we compute the change in the volatility of sales, ∆SDf,t
, and value added, ∆SDf,t
, before
and after period t. Henceforth, to simplify notation, we bundle both instruments in vector
∆SDf,t . As a first-stage regression, we run the following:
∆SDi,t = γ∆SDf,t + Xi,t + ui,t ,

(2)

where Xi,t is the same set of worker characteristics described in Equation (1) at period t. The
coefficient γ can be interpreted as the “pass-through” of firm volatility to workers’ earnings
16

Sales refer to gross revenue minus operating costs, and value added is gross revenue minus operating
costs plus wage bills.

11

[ i,t , an arguably exogenous
volatility.17 By projecting ∆SDi,t on ∆SDf,t , we obtain ∆SD
component of earnings volatility.18
[ i,t ’s, we identify the structural break for each individual.
Based on the time series of ∆SD
We denote the year of the exogenous structural break as τ̂ and the projected volatility change
[ i,τ̂ . Note that in the benchmark IV regression, we also include workers
at that year as ∆SD
who change firms around the structural break. Nonetheless, we estimate, as a robustness
exercise, the portfolio responses for a subsample of workers who always stay with the same
employer (roughly about 80 percent of the total sample) with the empirical estimates being
similar in magnitude.
[ i,τ̂ ’s. Clearly, the
Table 2 compares the summary statistics of ∆SDi,τ ∗ ’s and ∆SD
exogenous variation of income volatility shows a much smaller dispersion, as the standard
deviation of the volatility change decreases from 0.58 to 0.13. This occurs because our
raw measure of volatility ∆SDi,τ ∗ is a mix of predictable and unpredictable episodes, while
[ i,τ̂ isolates episodes that are closer to how we think of background risk.
∆SD
[ i,τ̂
Table 2: Summary Statistics for ∆SDi,τ ∗ and ∆SD
Obs.

Mean

S.D.

10th Percentile

90th Percentile

∆SDi,τ ∗

7,982

-0.04

0.58

-0.65

0.59

[ i,τ̂
∆SD

7,982

-0.02

0.13

-0.16

0.16

Notes: Summary statistics for the change in the standard deviation of labor-income growth ∆SDi,τ ∗
\i,τ̂ .
and the projected change in the standard deviation of labor-income growth ∆SD

The bottom panel of Table 1 reports the IV estimates.19 Without controls, the risky
share decreases by 8.45, 20.70, 25.67, and 33.67 percentage points, for k=1 to 4, respectively.
As with the OLS estimation, the control variables mitigate the responses. In particular, with
controls, the risky share decreases by 4.96, 16.35, 20.61, and 24.80 percentage points, for
k=1 to 4, respectively. Looking at a 4-year window (k = 2), if the standard deviation of
labor-income growth doubles in size for the median worker, the risky share decreases by 4.09
17

To exclude outliers from the estimation, we only keep those between the 1st and 99th percentiles of
∆SDf,t ’s in each cross-section. The estimate of γ in the first-stage regression is around 3 percent for sales and
0.8 percent for value added, both statistically significant at the 1 percent level. According to the standard test
for over-identifying restrictions, both sales and value added are valid instruments. This suggests considerable
insurance on behalf of the firms to the workers (see also Guiso, Pistaferri, and Schivardi, 2005 and Fagereng,
Guiso, and Pistaferri, 2017).
18
We also inspect the correlation between current risky share changes, RSi,t+1 − RSi,t , and future shocks,
\
∆SDi,t+k , k ≥ 2. We find basically that there is no significant correlation. That is, households cannot
anticipate our identified exogenous shocks in the future.
19
The OLS estimation also considers the same sample of workers who can be matched with their employer.

12

Table 3: Using Structural Breaks vs. All Observations
k=1

k=2

k=3

k=4

-4.96
(4.12)
7,851

-16.35***
(4.86)
7,729

-20.61***
(5.23)
7,600

-24.80***
(5.43)
7,440

-7.48***
(1.91)
56,225

-13.63***
(2.25)
55,585

-17.11***
(2.43)
54,775

-22.51***
(2.57)
53,783

Using Structural Breaks
Dependent Variable: RSi,τ̂ +k − RSi,τ̂ −k
[ i,τ̂ (IV)
Coefficient on ∆SD
Obs.
Using All Observations
Dependent Variable: RSi,t+k − RSi,t−k
[ i,t (IV)
Coefficient on ∆SD
Obs.

Notes: Structural breaks are based on the instrumented labor-income growth. When we use all
observations we construct successive windows around period t. The numbers in parentheses are the
robust standard errors. The asterisk(s) denote the statistical significance at three p-values: 10%,
5%, and 1%. We include the same set of controls as in our benchmark regression.

percentage points (16.35× 0.25). This is substantially larger than the corresponding OLS
estimate of 0.72 percentage points.
Finally, Table 3 compares the estimates based on all years—i.e., estimates based on the
[ i,t —to those based on the structural breaks. Naturally, using
volatility changes in every t, ∆SD
more observations improves the statistical significance, especially for short-term responses.
However, our benchmark specification generates larger responses. For example, looking at a
4-year window (k = 2), when the standard deviation of labor-income growth doubles for the
median worker, the risky share decreases by 3.40 percentage points (13.63 × 0.25), for the
case where we use all t, compared with 4.09 percentage points based on the structural breaks
(a 20 percent increase).

2.5

Robustness

We further examine whether our benchmark IV findings are robust with respect to different
specifications and measurements. We discuss briefly the estimates of each robustness check
and report the estimates in Table 10 in Appendix B. By and large, our baseline results are
robust with respect to the following variations: employer changes, exclusion of small firms
and managers from the sample, definitions of risky share, sample-selection criteria, additional
13

control variables (such as high-order polynomials of income and wealth, mortgage debt, and
capital income), alternative measures of income volatility, and different subsamples for those
always being married or being single, households’ disposable income (as opposed to individual
income), and others.
Staying with Same Employer: Switching firms is an endogenous choice, and it might
be influenced by some unobserved factors that also drive portfolio adjustment. Therefore, we
also estimate the portfolio responses for a subsample of workers who always stay with the
same employer (roughly about 80 percent of the total sample). The empirical estimates are
similar in magnitude and in some cases more pronounced relative to the benchmark.
One concern about the instrument’s
Excluding Small Firms and Managers:
validity is that (i) in smaller firms individual workers can have some impact on the firm’s
performance, and (ii) some workers may have managerial positions that allow them to directly
influence firms’ decisions. Thus, as a robustness check, we exclude from our sample first,
firms in the bottom quartile of the employment distribution and second, workers who are
managers. The IV estimates retain their size and significance and in some cases become even
more pronounced.
Alternative Measures of Firm Volatility: We also consider using value added/assets
or sales/assets separately as instrumental variables. For both specifications we have negative
estimates in the same range as in the benchmark specification, but the estimates are more
noisy. We also experiment with alternative ways to measure volatility at the firm level (such
as growth rate for net sales but not scaled by firm assets). The results are still consistent.
Alternative Control Variables for Nonlinear Wealth Effects: We also consider
using high-order polynomials in income and wealth and their changes to possibly control
some nonlinear wealth effects.
Industry/Occupation Controls: Also, as pointed our in the literature (e.g., Heaton
and Lucas, 2000; Campbell, Cocco, Gomes, and Maenhout, 2001; Angerer and Lam, 2009),
individual income (labor income or total income) may be correlated with aggregate stock
returns, and this correlation may be different across industries and/or occupations. To see
whether this has a big impact on our estimated response of risky share to income volatility,
we additionally include two-digit industry and/or occupation dummies in our benchmark
regression.
Further Sample Restrictions Another concern is that the responses may be driven
by workers who have too little assets (or risky assets) or who experience a temporary
unemployment spell. In the next robustness check, we exclude workers (i) who collect
unemployment benefits, (ii) with financial assets in the bottom quintile, or (iii) with a risky
share of less than 0.05. All of the restricted samples generate coefficients of similar magnitude
14

and statistical significance as in the benchmark specification.
[ i,t ,
Alternative Definition for τ̂ : In the benchmark specification, we constructed ∆SD
[ i,t ’s,
an arguably exogenous variation of earnings volatility. Based on the time series of ∆SD
we identified the structural break for each individual, τ̂ , and denoted the projected volatility
[ i,τ̂ . It is worth analyzing the empirical responses if we still use
change around τ̂ as ∆SD
the firm’s volatility as an instrument but look around the original worker’s structural break
[ i,τ ∗ instead of ∆SD
[ i,τ̂ . In this case, the
τ ∗ . Therefore, in this specification we use ∆SD
coefficients are even more pronounced than in the benchmark, but more noisy for shorter
horizons (k < 3).
Household Disposable Income: In our benchmark specification, we constructed
income volatility using the individual’s earnings growth. However, the decision to hold risky
assets may be influenced by the volatility of household income, not only individual income.
For example, if there is intra-household insurance, individual income volatility may not
necessarily affect household savings. Therefore, we apply the structural-break approach based
on total household-level disposable income instead of individual labor earnings. Once more,
the estimates become more pronounced relative to the benchmark specification.
Marriage and Disposable Income: We also separately look at those individuals
who are always married (from −k to +k) and those who are always single to control for
some potential influence from marital status. Results are robust for married workers but less
statistically significant for singles.

2.6

Heterogeneity across Groups

We examine the response of the risky share to income volatility (IV estimation) across different
groups (by age, education, and income growth). The results are collected in Table 11 in
Appendix B.
By Age: Given that individual earnings and risky share exhibit clear life-cycle patterns
(Guvenen, 2007 and Chang, Hong, and Karabarbounis, 2018), we ask whether our main
finding is distinctive for a particular age group. The sample is classified into three groups:
the young (younger than 40 years old), middle-aged (40 to 55), and old (older than 55) based
on a worker’s age in 2005. This splits the sample into 18 percent, 56 percent, and 26 percent,
respectively.20 Table 11 shows that for most horizons the young and the middle-aged exhibit
the most significant and distinctive responses.
By Education: Workers with different levels of education may face different labor
markets—e.g., stability of jobs, career paths, etc. Table 11 shows the estimated response
20
In our sample for the benchmark regression, the mean age for the young group (middle-aged, old group)
is about 36 (47, 58).

15

of the risky share separately for college graduates and high-school only graduates. While
both groups show statistically significant responses, the college graduates exhibit sharper
responses. We also examine whether knowledge about financial markets matters (Lusardi
and Mitchell, 2007). Based on the Norwegian Education Registry, we classify the college
graduates into those who majored in “Econ/Finance’’ (economics, business, and other related
business/management majors) and the rest. Those who majored in economics/finance-related
subjects do show stronger responses.
By Income Growth: We estimate the responses for different groups based on average
income growth during the period (from −k to +k). Based on income growth before and
after the individual structural break year τ ∗ for a given time horizon, we classify workers
into three groups: low growth (bottom 25 percent), high growth (top 25 percent) and the
rest. In Table 11 we confirm that different groups show similar responses of the risky share
to changes in income volatility.

3

Life-Cycle Model

3.1

Economic Environment

Demographics The economy is populated by a continuum of workers with total measure of
one. A worker enters the labor market at age j = 1, retires at age jR , and lives until age
J. The decision to retire is exogenous. During each period the worker faces a probability of
surviving sj .
Preferences

Each worker maximizes the time-separable discounted lifetime utility:

U =E

J
X

δ j−1 (Πjt=1 st )

j=1

cj 1−γ
,
1−γ

(3)

where δ is the discount factor, cj is consumption in period j, and γ is the relative risk
aversion.21 For simplicity, we abstract from the labor effort choice and assume that labor
supply is exogenous.
Labor-Income Profile

We assume that the log earnings of a worker i with age j, log Yij , is:
log Yij = zj + yij

with yij = ai + βi × j + xij .

21

(4)

Alternative preferences have also been proposed in the literature analyzing portfolio choice. For example,
Gomes and Michaelides (2005) use Epstein-Zin preferences with heterogeneity in both risk aversion and
inter-temporal elasticity of substitution. Wachter and Yogo (2010) use non-homothetic preferences.

16

Log earnings consist of common (zj ) and individual-specific (yij ) components. The common
component, zj , represents the average age-earnings profile, which is assumed to be the same
across workers. The idiosyncratic component, yij , consists of an individual-specific profile,
ai + βi × j, which is constant along the life cycle, and stochastic shocks, xij , which follow an
AR(1) process:
xij = ρx xi,j−1 + νij ,

with νij ∼ i.i.d. N (0, σij2 ).

(5)

Note that the volatility of income shocks, σij2 , is also idiosyncratic, and its stochastic process
is described below.
Variance of Labor Income
AR(1) process:

The idiosyncratic labor-income volatility is assumed to follow an

2
log(σij2 ) = (1 − ρσ ) log(σν2 ) + ρσ log(σi,j−1
) + ζij ,

with ζij ∼ i.i.d. N (0, σζ2 ).

(6)

We use a log specification to ensure that income volatility is positive. Three parameters
govern its dynamics: (i) σν2 , which is the average variance of x, (ii) σζ2 , which is the variance
of the volatility shocks, and (iii) ρσ , which governs their persistence. We approximate the
autoregressive process for the volatility shock using a Markov chain. In particular, we assume
2
that the labor-income volatility takes N possible values (regimes): σ 2 = {σ12 , ..., σN
}. The
2 2
Markov chain is defined as Γ(σj |σj−1 ).
Savings
There are two types of assets for savings: a risk-free bond, b, (paying a gross
return of R in consumption units) and a stock, s, (paying Rs = R + µ + η), where µ (> 0)
represents the risk premium and η is the stochastic rate of return.22 We denote the probability distribution of the stock realization by χ(η). Workers save for insuring themselves
against labor-income volatility (precautionary savings) as well as for retirement (life-cycle savings). We allow workers to borrow using the risk-free bond (b0 ≥ b), where b is the credit limit.
Tax System and Social Security
The government performs two functions in the model.
First, it taxes individual earnings Yij using the tax function T (Yij ). We specify a flexible tax
function based on Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante (2014) that allows for transfers (see
Section 4.1). Second, it runs a social security system. When a worker retires from the labor
market at age jR , the worker receives a social security benefit. To avoid the computational
22

For simplicity, we abstract from the general equilibrium aspect by assuming exogenous average rates of
return to both stocks and bonds.

17

complexity of tracking one more state variable (history of earnings), we make the social
security benefit dependent on earnings received in the last working year before the exogenous
retirement (Guvenen, 2007). The social security benefit of worker i is denoted by ss(YJR −1 ),
which is financed by the social security tax rate τss .
Matrix for Income Process We define the matrices Mj−1 and Hj that allow us to define
the recursive problem in terms of income y, as follows:


Mj−1


a


= β
,
ρx xj−1




1
 
Hj =  j  .
1

(7)

The following period’s Mj is:


Mj





0

 

= R Mj−1 +  0  (yj − H0j Mj−1 )
1

(8)

with R denoting a (3 × 3) matrix whose diagonal elements are (1, 1, ρx ). Note that, H0j Mj−1
is the conditional expectation of period j’s labor income as of age j − 1. Moreover,
yj − H0j Mj−1 = xj − ρx xj−1 = νj , is the innovation of the shock to x. When the worker enters
period j, log labor earnings yj are drawn from a normal distribution F with mean H0j Mj−1
and variance σj2 (denoted as F (yj | H0j Mj−1 , σj2 )).
Benchmark: Perfect Information about Volatility Shocks In the benchmark model, workers
have perfect information about their individual labor-income volatility (perfect information
model or PIM, henceforth). In particular, workers enter age j observing volatility σj2 and
2
forming expectations about the next period’s volatility based on the law of motion Γ(σj+1
|σj2 ).
Imperfect Information about Volatility Shocks The second case is one where workers have
imperfect information about their individual income volatility (imperfect information model or
g
IIM, henceforth). In this case, workers enter age j with a prior probability πj|j−1 = {πj|j−1
}N
g=1
P g
for each possible regime g with g πj|j−1 = 1 (in the PIM, the prior is a just degenerate
g
at the true regime). They form a posterior belief for each regime πj|j = {πj|j
}N
g=1 based on
the Bayes rule. In particular, workers compute the probability that a particular regime g is
currently active given the available information {y, Mj−1 }. As a result, the posterior beliefs

18

are given by:
πj|j (σg2

yj , H0j Mj−1 )

|

g
F (yj | H0j Mj−1 , σg2 ) × πj|j−1
(σg2 )

= PN

0
2
h
2
h=1 F (yj | Hj Mj−1 , σh ) × πj|j−1 (σh )

,

(9)

where F (yj | H0j Mj−1 , σg2 ) is the probability that labor-income realization, yj , is observed
given that the last year’s labor income is H0j Mj−1 and that the current volatility regime is σg2 .
If the absolute value of yj − H0j Mj−1 (the innovation νj ) is small, the worker places a larger
probability on the low-volatility regimes and vice versa. Given the posterior probabilities,
the worker forms the next period priors:
πj+1 (σg2 )

=

N
X

Γ(σg2 | σh2 ) × πj|j (σh2 ).

(10)

h=1

Note that in both perfect and imperfect information models, workers know the law of
motion (transition probability) for the volatility regime, Γ. What is different in the two
cases is the initial regime. Under perfect information, workers know the true regime, while
under imperfect information, workers have a probability distribution over the possible regimes.
Value Functions We collapse financial wealth into one variable, “total financial wealth,”
W = bR + sRs . Then, the state variables include workers’ wealth (W ), current income (yj ),
the expected income (Mj−1 ), and the prior probability about the current volatility regime,
πj|j−1 . The value function of a worker at age j is:
(
Vj (W, yj , Mj−1 , πj|j−1 ) = max
0 0
c,s ,b

+ δsj

XZ Z
g

η0

c1−γ
j
1−γ
)

πj+1 (σg2 )Vj+1 (W 0 , yj+1 , Mj , πj+1|j )dF (yj+1 |H0j+1 Mj , σg2 )dχ(η 0 )

yj+1

s.t. c + s0 + b0 = [(1 − τss )Yj − T (Yj )] × 1{j < jR } + ss(YJR −1 ) × 1{j ≥ jR } + W
PIM: πj+1 (σg2 ) is based on law of motion Γ(σg2 |σj2 )
IIM: πj+1 (σg2 ) is given by Equations (9) and (10)
Mj is given by Equation (8)
F (yj+1 |H0j+1 Mj , σg2 ) is the prob. distribution for the next period income given Mj , σg2
b0 ≥ b and s0 ≥ 0,

19

where 1{·} is an indicator function and total labor income is Yj = ezj +yj .

4

Estimation

There are several sets of parameters to pin down: (i) life-cycle parameters {jR , J, sj }, (ii)
preferences {γ, δ}, (iii) asset-market parameters {R, µ, ση2 , b}, (iv) labor-income process
{zj , σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , ρσ , σν2 , σζ2 }, and (v) tax and transfers {τ1 , τ2 , τ ∗ , τss , ss}. One set of parameters
is calibrated directly from the data or the existing literature. The remaining parameters are
estimated using indirect inference.

4.1

Calibrated Parameters

Table 4 gives the list of calibrated parameters. The model period is a year. Workers are
born and enter the labor market at j = 1 and live for 80 periods, J = 80. This life cycle
corresponds to ages 21 to 100. Workers retire at jR = 45 (age 65) when they start receiving
the social security benefit. We estimate the survival probability {sj } at each age using the
data on mortality rates from Statistics Norway.
Table 4: Calibrated Parameters
Parameter
Life Cycle
Retirement Age
Risk-free Rate
Equity-Risk Premium
Stock-Return Volatility
Social Security Benefit
Tax Function
Tax Function
Tax Function
Tax Function
Survival Probability
Common Age-Earnings Profile
Number of Volatility Regimes

Variable

Value

Target / Source

J
jR
R−1
µ
ση
ss
τ1
τ2
τ∗
Y∗
{sj }
{zj }
N

80
45
1.43%
3.14%
23.8%
–
0.73
0.16
0.85
1.7
–
–
7

–
–
Klovland (2004)
Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2008)
Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2008)
Statistics Norway
Statistics Norway
Statistics Norway
Statistics Norway
Statistics Norway
Statistics Norway
OECD
–

According to Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2008), the annualized real returns to equity
for Norway from 1900-2005 were 4.28 percent. We follow Fagereng, Gottlieb, and Guiso
(2017) and adjust the returns to reflect an 80 percent bias of Norwegian investors toward
domestic over foreign stocks. Since the world average returns were 5.75 percent, according
20

to Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2008) for the same period, we set the rate of returns to
equity at 4.57 percent. Using the estimates from Klovland (2004), we calibrate a real return
for the risk-free rate to 1.43 percent. Therefore, the equity premium in our model µ is 3.14
percent. The standard deviation of the innovations to the rate of return to stocks, ση , is 23.8
percent, also computed using a weighted average of the standard deviation of Norwegian
stocks and of foreign stocks, which are 26 percent and 17 percent, respectively, based on
Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2008). We assume that the stock returns are orthogonal to
labor-income risks.23
To compute the amount of tax and transfers, we use the following specification:
T (Y ) = Y − τ1 Y 1−τ2 + 1{Y ∗ >Y } τ ∗ (Y − Y ∗ ).
A version of this type of tax function has recently been used to analyze tax and transfers in
the U.S. (Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante, 2017). In particular, parameter τ1 captures
the average tax rate in the economy and parameter τ2 the degree of progressivity of the
schedule. As seen in the left panel of Figure 3, the tax system in Norway becomes very
progressive for income levels around twice the average labor income. To capture the high
progressivity of the Norwegian tax system, we add the term 1{Y ∗ >Y } τ ∗ (Y − Y ∗ ). With our
detailed administrative data, we can calibrate all parameters using information on beforeand after-tax labor earnings. The before-tax earnings are cash salary, while after-tax earnings
are before-tax earnings net of taxes and transfers. Transfers include unemployment benefits,
sickness benefits, money received in government activity programs, and disability benefits.
The left panel of Figure 3 shows that our model matches well the relationship between beforeand after-tax individual labor income.
The social security benefit is calibrated to replicate the average benefit for each laborincome decile we observe in the data (right panel of Figure 3). As mentioned, in the model
we condition the social security benefit on the earnings received in the last working year
before retirement. For consistency, in the data we find the relationship between social security
benefits and labor income during ages 60 to 65. We find that a worker with the mean labor
income during ages 60 to 65 receives a benefit equal to 36 percent of his/her pre-retirement
labor income. A worker with twice the mean labor income during ages 60 to 65 receives
around 55 percent of pre-retirement labor income.
We calibrate the common age profile of income (zj ) based on the age profile of real wages
23

In our data, the correlation between stock market return and average real wage (using aggregate data
from national accounts) is small and equal to -0.08 with a standard deviation of 0.16. These numbers are
similar to the numbers reported in Heaton and Lucas (2000) for the U.S. In other studies that have used
U.S. data, Davis and Willen (2000) find a small, positive correlation, while Campbell, Cocco, Gomes, and
Maenhout (2001) find a positive correlation only for specific population groups.

21

in Norway from the OECD. The real wages for 30-, 40-, and 50-year old workers are on
average approximately 5, 15, and 20 percent higher, respectively, than those of 25-year-old
workers. Finally, we assume that there are 7 regimes for income volatility: N = 7.
Figure 3: Tax and Social Security System: Model vs. Data
0.7

2

Data (Statistics Norway)
Model

1.8

0.6

Social Security Income

1.6

After-tax Income

Data (Statistics Norway)
Model

0.65

1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6

0.55
0.5
0.45
0.4
0.35

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.25

0

0.2

0

0.5

1

1.5
2
Before-tax Income

2.5

3

0.4

0.6

0.8

1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
Before-tax Income (ages 60-65)

2

2.2

Notes: The left panel shows the relationship between before- and after-tax labor income for the
model and the data. The right panel shows the relationship between before-tax labor income
for ages 60 to 65 and the social security benefit in the model and in the data. We normalize
labor-income data by the average earnings, 553,414 NOK. Data are from Statistics Norway and
authors’ calculations.

4.2

Structural Estimation

We use indirect inference to estimate the remaining parameters by minimizing the distance
between the model statistics and their empirical counterparts.24 We need to estimate a total
of 9 parameters represented by the vector:
Θ = [δ, γ, b, σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , ρσ , σν2 , σζ2 ].
Let M m (Θ) denote the set of model-generated moments and M d their empirical counterparts.
The moments used in the estimation are
1. Average assets-income ratio.
2. Average risky assets-total assets ratio.
24

According to Guvenen and Smith (2014), when the estimation uses any type of statistical association
as information, even if that requires specifying an auxiliary model (as the IV estimation in our case), the
estimation falls under the classification of indirect inference. In contrast, with simulated method of moments,
the statistics used in the estimation are directly computed from the data.

22

3. Average consumer debt-income ratio.
4. Variance-covariance matrix of log labor income across ages (a total of 441 moments).
5. Life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth.
[
6. Dispersion of volatility change (projected): ∆SD.
7. Life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional variance of log consumption.25
8. Response of risky share to volatility (IV estimate for k = 2 in Table 1).
In total we have 511 moments. The estimator minimizes the loss function:
min LΘ = [M d − M m (Θ)]0 W [M d − M m (Θ)].

(11)

We pick a weighting matrix W (freely) to focus on some specific dimensions of the data
we view as more important to match. In particular, we place more weight on the two moments
that describe the portfolio behavior: the average risky share and the response of the risky
share to volatility. We also place more weight on moments that describe the dynamics of
labor income, such as the cross-sectional variance of log labor income over the life cycle and
the dispersion in volatility changes. Appendix D provides the weights used in the estimation.
It is useful to connect some parameters with the moments that are the most informative
about their values. For example, the discount factor δ is identified primarily through the
average financial assets to income ratio. In our data, the average financial assets for ages 25
to 60 are 1,212,000 NOK, and the average household income is 553,414 NOK. Therefore, we
estimate the discount factor δ to match an asset-to-income ratio of 2.19. The risk aversion γ
is identified primarily through the risky to total assets ratio. Since the average financial assets
in risky accounts are 690,830 NOK, we target an aggregate risky share of 0.57.26 According
to the data from the Bank of Norway, the credit card debt accounts for 3 percent of total
debt (which averages at 908,587 NOK). Therefore, the average credit card debt to income
ratio is 3% × 908, 587/553, 414 = 4.9%. The debt-to-income ratio is crucial to the value of
borrowing constraint b.
25

We thank Martin Holm from the University of Oslo for providing statistics for this moment. In our data
set, we could not have reliable estimates on individual consumption since we do not have access to those data
required for constructing consumption (transaction data on housing prices; housing physical characteristics;
detailed information on capital gains; and so on). See Eika, Mogstad, and Vestad (2017) among others.
26
The average risky share in the Norwegian panel is a much lower value of 0.31. As is well-known, it is
hard to match such low values of the average risky share unless we resort to unrealistically high degrees of
risk aversion or highly risky events such as a stock market crash or long-term unemployment spell. Instead,
we base our estimation on a more feasible target, the aggregate risky share.

23

For the estimation of parameters {σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , σν2 } that govern the income process, we use
the variance-covariance matrix of log labor earnings similar to Guvenen (2009). For the
estimation of the stochastic process of volatility, {ρσ , σζ2 }, we use the life-cycle profile of the
[
cross-sectional kurtosis of income growth and the dispersion of the volatility change ∆SD.
(See Appendix C for the construction of the life-cycle profile of kurtosis.) We discuss the
identification of all income parameters in more detail in Section 4.4, below.
Our estimation takes into account important economic choices. The first regards the
variance of log consumption along the life cycle. According to Guvenen and Smith (2014),
consumption inequality is informative about (i) the presence of borrowing constraints and (ii)
the lack of prior information about the income profile. Here, for simplicity, we choose not
to assume imperfect information about the level component of the income profile because
(i) it simplifies our analysis, which is mainly focused on learning about the volatility shock,
and (ii) the imperfect information on the growth component does not necessarily improve
the empirical fit of the model.27 This is in contrast to the imperfect information about the
volatility, which, as we show below, is necessary to match the data better.
Second, the response of portfolio choice to income volatility is a key moment. More
specifically, the response coefficient β in Equation (1) is a part of our target moments (the
IV estimates in Table 1). Obviously, the portfolio response depends on several parameters,
such as risk aversion (γ), the borrowing constraints (b), and the persistence of the volatility
shocks (ρσ ). More importantly, we show that portfolio choice is useful to sharply discriminate
between alternative models of information about the income volatility (PIM and IIM).

4.3

Estimation Results and Model Fit

We estimate two versions of the model: the benchmark case of perfect information about the
volatility regime (PIM) and imperfect information (IIM). We also estimate the parameters
of the income process separately using income moments only (in which case the distinction
between PIM and IIM does not matter). Table 5 shows the estimation results, while Figure 4
and Table 6 show the models’ fit to the empirical targets.
For PIM, the variance of the fixed effect component is σa2 = 0.050, the variance of the
slope σβ2 = 0.0089%, and the average variance of the idiosyncratic shocks σν2 = 0.026. The
27

Guvenen and Smith (2014) estimate the amount of prior information about the growth component of
the income profile on labor market entry using the dispersion of labor income and consumption based on U.S
data. The imperfect information about the level component helps the model to match the fast-increasing
variance of (log) consumption over the life cycle in the U.S. data (10 log points). But in the Norwegian panel,
the profile of the variance of consumption is much flatter (an increase of 4 log points). As a result, imperfect
information about the level component is not crucial for matching the data. Moreover, introducing imperfect
information on both components of the income profile makes the model highly complicated.

24

Table 5: Parameter Estimates
Moments Used in Estimation

All Moments

Model Specification

PIM

Variance of Fixed Component

σa2

0.050
(0.003)
2
Variance of Growth Component σβ × 100 0.0089
(0.0005)
Persistence of Level Shocks
ρx
0.783
(0.012)
Variance of Level Shocks
σν2
0.026
(0.002)
Persistence of Volatility Shocks
ρσ
0.936
(0.006)
Variance of Volatility Shocks
σζ2
0.071
(0.011)
Discount Factor
δ
0.919
(0.033)
Risk Aversion
γ
5.44
(1.21)
-0.144
Credit Limit
b
(0.052)

Income Only

IIM

–

0.054
(0.004)
0.0085
(0.0006)
0.788
(0.016)
0.023
(0.003)
0.931
(0.006)
0.071
(0.010)
0.923
(0.025)
4.86
(1.15)
-0.114
(0.039)

0.053
(0.004)
0.0081
(0.0005)
0.783
(0.015)
0.023
(0.003)
0.933
(0.005)
0.070
(0.010)

Notes: Estimation results for model parameters. “All Moments” uses all available moments (income,
financial wealth, consumption, and portfolio). “Income Only” uses income moments only. The
standard errors for each parameter are reported in parentheses.

persistence of the idiosyncratic shocks is ρx = 0.783.
The upper left panel of Figure 4 plots the cross-sectional variance of log earnings across
ages net of cohort effects. In the data, the variance of income initially decreases during ages
25 to 30, a pattern we cannot generate from the model. After age 30, we see a familiar
increasing variance—also well documented in the U.S. data (see, for example, Storesletten,
Telmer, and Yaron, 2004; Guvenen and Smith, 2014; Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante,
2014). In Norway, it increases by about 10 log points over ages 30 to 55, while in the U.S.
the increase is about 20-25 log points. The PIM captures this increasing profile fairly well
after age 30.
In both our estimation and Guvenen and Smith (2014), who estimated these parameters
using the U.S. data, the idiosyncratic growth component is fairly large, implying a mildly

25

Figure 4: Model Fit: Income, Consumption and Portfolio Response
0.35

12
Variance of log-income (Data)
Variance of log-income (PIM)
Variance of log-income (IIM)

10

Cross-sectional kurtosis

0.3

Kurtosis of income growth (Data)
Kurtosis of income growth (PIM)
Kurtosis of income growth (IIM)

11

0.25

0.2

0.15

9
8
7
6
5
4
3

0.1

2
25

30

35

40
Age

45

50

55

0.12

20

25

30

35

40
Age

45

50

55

60

10
Variance of log-consumption (Data)
Variance of log-consumption (PIM)
Variance of log-consumption (IIM)

0.1

Portfolio response β (in percentage points), Data
Portfolio response β (in percentage points), PIM
Portfolio response β (in percentage points), IIM

0

0.08

-10

0.06

-20

0.04

-30

0.02

-40

0

-50
25

30

35

40
Age

45

50

55

1

2
3
Window around structural break (k)

4

Notes: Upper-left panel shows the variance of log earnings over the life cycle. Upper-right panel is
the cross-sectional kurtosis of income growth. Lower-left panel is the variance of log consumption.
Lower-right panel shows the regression coefficients of response of the risky share in Equation (1) for
k = 1 to 4.

persistent process for the shock to the income level. In particular, we find an almost identical
value for ρx (0.783 versus 0.789 in the U.S. data). One difference is that in our Norwegian
data, the variance of the σν2 is half of what Guvenen and Smith (2014) estimate for the U.S.
data, which reflects the sharper increase in the variance of log labor income over the life cycle,
in the U.S. relative to Norway.
We next turn to the estimated parameters that govern the process of income volatility.
For PIM, the estimated variance is σζ2 = 0.071. This parameter is identified mainly by the
cross-sectional dispersion of changes in income volatility ∆SD. The estimated volatility

26

shocks are highly persistent: ρσ = 0.936.28 The highly persistent process reflects the life-cycle
profile of kurtosis in the data. Looking at the upper-right panel of Figure 4, the model
captures the increasing (and slightly concave) shape of kurtosis over the life cycle. Both the
size and the persistence of the volatility shocks are precisely estimated with t-statistics higher
than 10. This suggests that the moments we picked to identify the volatility process are very
informative. We give more details about the link between the empirical moments and the
parameters of the volatility process in Section 4.4.
The IIM generates broadly similar estimates for the income parameters. This occurs
because income parameters are primarily identified from the income data (the variancecovariance matrix of realized incomes, the cross-sectional kurtosis, etc.) and are not heavily
influenced by economic choices (financial wealth, consumption inequality, portfolio, etc.). We
verify this by estimating the parameters of income process using the income-related moments
only (the last column of Table 5). The estimated parameters are fairly similar to the case
where we use all moments.
Table 6: Model Fit: Selected Statistics
Data

PIM

IIM

Financial Assets / Income
Risky Assets / Financial Assets
Credit Card Debt / Income
Standard Deviation of ∆SD

2.19
0.57
4.9%
0.13

2.21
0.57
6.2%
0.12

2.22
0.56
5.4%
0.12

Response of Risky Share β̂ (k = 2)

-16.3

-22.3

-16.8

Notes: We report selected statistics based on two models (PIM and IIM) and corresponding empirical
targets based on Statistics Norway.

The discount factor in the PIM is δ = 0.919, while in the IIM, it is 0.923. The estimated
credit limit (b) is -14.4 percent and -11.4 percent of annual income, in PIM and IIM,
respectively. The estimate of credit limits is influenced by two sets of statistics from the data.
First, the average debt-to-income ratio. Second, the increase in the cross-sectional variance
of log consumption. Intuitively, if borrowing constraints are tight, consumption inequality
increases in parallel to income inequality. In the data, the variance of log consumption
increases by about 4 log-points (from ages 25 to 50), which is matched fairly well by both
models (lower-left panel of Figure 4).
28

The average number of volatility changes implied by our estimated values for ρσ and σζ2 (and given that
we set N = 7 grid points) is 7.8 in our simulation.

27

Where the two models (PIM and IIM) diverge substantially is with respect to the estimate
of risk aversion (5.44 versus 4.86 in PIM and IIM, respectively) as well as their implications
for portfolio choice. The lower-right panel of Figure 4 plots the regression coefficients of the
risky share to volatility in Equation (1) using model-generated data.29 The model with perfect
information generates responses much larger (in absolute terms) than those we find in the
data. For example, if the standard deviation of labor-income growth increases by one unit, the
risky share decreases by 22 and 34 percentage points, for k = 2 and k = 4, respectively. The
corresponding estimates in the data are 16 and 24 percentage points, respectively. Therefore,
even though parameter estimation in PIM can match well most of the income and financial
moments (see Table 6), it fails to match the marginal response of the portfolio to income
volatility.
On the other hand, parameter estimation in IIM can naturally deliver the marginal
response of the portfolio while still matching the other moments. When the standard
deviation of income growth increases by one unit, the risky share decreases by 12 and 26
percentage points, for k = 2 and k = 4, respectively, which aligns well with the data. The
key mechanism is a gradual learning about the change in volatility regime that mitigates the
response of portfolio choice. The discrepancy is more visible at shorter time horizons because
workers gradually learn about the change in the volatility regime. To confirm that imperfect
information can naturally match the portfolio response, we also consider an estimation where
the marginal response is not targeted. Even in this case, the model matches the portfolio
response very closely, suggesting that the improvement in the fit does not come at the expense
of other moments. One might think that a low value of risk aversion in IIM is crucial for
the different estimated response of the risky share. To explore this possibility, we simulate
PIM under the same risk aversion as the estimate from IIM (γ = 4.86). See Appendix E for
the estimated responses. The response of the risky share in PIM continues to substantially
overpredict the response in the data.

4.4

Identification of the Income Process

We discuss the estimation of the stochastic process of labor income in detail. The discussion
is concentrated on the parameters regarding the volatility (i.e., the second moment) shocks
{σζ2 , ρσ }. The other parameters are discussed briefly because their estimation has been
extensively analyzed in the literature (e.g., Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron, 2004; Guvenen,
29

Similar to the empirical analysis, the regression includes a set of individual controls, namely, changes
(between τ ∗ − k and τ ∗ + k) in income and wealth, as well as the levels of income, wealth, and age at τ ∗ . We
exclude outliers by keeping observations between the 1st and 99th percentiles of the distribution of the risky
share.

28

Figure 5: Identification: Variance of Volatility Shocks σζ2
0.2

Cross-sectional Dispersion in ∆SD

0.18

0.16

0.14

0.12

0.1

0.08

0.06
0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

0.14

Variance of volatility shocks (σ 2ζ )

Notes: The x-axis is the variance of volatility shocks (σζ2 ), and the y-axis is the cross-sectional
standard deviation of the volatility changes ∆SD from the model-generated data.

2009; Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, and Song, 2015).
Variance of Volatility Shocks σζ2
The variance of the volatility shocks is identified
mainly by the cross-sectional dispersion of exogenous changes in volatility (i.e., instrumented
∆SD). When σζ2 increases, the dispersion of ∆SD increases as more workers draw income
shocks from a wider distribution. Figure 5 plots the model-generated dispersion of ∆SD for
a wide range of σζ2 . The model produces a monotonically increasing relationship between
σζ2 and ∆SD. Our estimation exploits this relationship to identify the variance of volatility
shocks σζ2 .
Persistence of Volatility Shocks ρσ The persistence of volatility shocks is identified
by the life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional kurtosis of earnings growth. The transitory
process of volatility implies that the kurtosis quickly approaches its long-run value (thus a
flat life-cycle profile except for the beginning), whereas highly persistent shocks to volatility
imply that the kurtosis gradually converges to its long-run value over time (an increasing
profile).
We explain the identification of ρσ by setting up a simple example. We assume there is
no profile heterogeneity (σa2 = 0, σβ2 = 0). Therefore, labor-income variations are associated
with the stochastic component x only. We further assume that income volatility can take
29

Figure 6: Identification: Persistence in Volatility Shocks: ρσ
0.4

0.4

0.4
Worker 2 (i.i.d. shocks)
0.3

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.1

0
-0.1

Log-income

0.3

0
-0.1

0
-0.1

-0.2

-0.2

-0.2

-0.3

-0.3

-0.3

-0.4

-0.4
25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

-0.4
25

30

35

40

Age

45

50

55

60

65

25

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.1

-0.1

Log-income

0.2

Log-income

0.3

0

0
-0.1
-0.2

-0.2

-0.3

-0.3

-0.4
45

50

55

60

65

30

35

40

Cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth

Cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth

Cross-sectional Kurtosis (i.i.d. shocks)
5.5
5
4.5
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
35

45

50

55

60

65

25

30

35

Age

6

30

40

45

50

60

65

50

55

60

65

-0.4
25

Age

25

55

-0.1

-0.3

40

50

0

-0.2

-0.4

45

Worker 3 (Persistent Shocks)

0.3

35

40

0.4
Worker 2 (Persistent Shocks)

0.3

30

35

Age

0.4
Worker 1 (Persistent Shocks)

25

30

Age

0.4

Log-income

Worker 3 (i.i.d. shocks)

0.3

Log-income

Log-income

Worker 1 (i.i.d. shocks)

55

60

65

Age

40

45

Age

6
Cross-sectional Kurtosis (Persistent Shocks)
5.5
5
4.5
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

Age

Notes: The upper and middle panels show the evolution of log labor income for three workers
from the model-generated data. The upper panels correspond to i.i.d. shocks to income volatility,
whereas the middle panels correspond to persistent volatility shocks. The bottom panels show the
life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional kurtosis of income growth when shocks are i.i.d (left panel)
and persistent (right panel), respectively.

30

three values σζ2 = {0.1%, 5%, 10%}. Let’s compare two extreme cases: (i) an i.i.d. volatility
regime where the transition matrix Γij = 1/3, ∀i, j and (ii) a highly persistent stochastic
process of volatility where Γij = 0.98 if i = j, and Γij = 0.01 otherwise.
The upper panels of Figure 6 show the log labor income (as well as the volatility bands)
for three workers with i.i.d. volatility shocks. In each period, workers receive a shock that is
drawn from a distribution whose variance is independent of the last period’s volatility. As a
result, starting from the beginning of the life cycle, workers jump around the distributions.
The middle panels of Figure 6 show log labor income for three workers when the volatility
follows a highly persistent stochastic process described above. At the beginning of the life
cycle, workers draw shocks from the same middle distribution (σζ2 = 5%). As the life cycle
advances, the volatility of income decreases for worker 1 at age 30. Consequently, labor
income becomes almost constant after the break. For workers 2 and 3, the volatility increases
at ages 40 and 55, respectively, resulting in a more volatile labor-income path.
The bottom panels of Figure 6 show the cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth
for both cases of the stochastic regime changes: (i) i.i.d. in the left panel and (ii) persistent
regime changes in the right panel. In both cases, the average kurtosis is higher than 3 (which
is the value of kurtosis if the distribution is normal) implying a leptokurtic cross-sectional
distribution of income growth. Indeed, Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, and Song (2015) show
that the labor-income process with volatility shocks gives rise to a leptokurtic distribution.
Intuitively speaking, earnings are not drawn from a single normal distribution. Instead
earnings are drawn from a mixture of normals generating a cross-sectional distribution that
looks leptokurtic. We argue that it is not only the average kurtosis but also the life-cycle
profile of kurtosis that conveys useful information about the stochastic process of the income’s
volatility regime—especially with respect to its persistence.
When volatility shocks are i.i.d., workers are distributed across the different normal
distributions from the beginning of the life cycle. Although workers jump around distributions
every period, the measure of workers allocated to each distribution remains invariant. As a
result, the life-cycle profile of the cross-sectional kurtosis in labor-income growth is constant
(left panel of Figure 6). When volatility shocks are persistent, kurtosis experiences a gradual
and linear increase over time (right panel of Figure 6). Workers start their life cycle drawing
shocks from the median distribution. As the life cycle advances, some workers draw from a
narrower distribution (decrease in volatility) and some draw from a wider distribution (increase
in volatility). Due to these transitions, income growth becomes increasingly leptokurtic. The
increasing (and slightly concave) age profile of kurtosis in the data results in a persistent
process of volatility.
Note that our identification strategy for the persistence of volatility, ρσ , mirrors the
31

identification strategy for the persistence of labor-income shocks, ρx . As Storesletten, Telmer,
and Yaron (2004) show, higher ρx leads to a linearly increasing profile in the second moment
of labor income. In our case, higher persistence in the volatility shocks ρσ generates a linearly
increasing profile in the fourth moment of labor income, e.g. the kurtosis.
Remaining Parameters for the Income Process {σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , σν2 } The identification
of the remaining parameters for the income process is similar to that in Guvenen (2009). We
discriminate between the heterogeneous income profile (σβ2 > 0) and the homogeneous income
profile (σβ2 = 0). In the latter case, the age profile of income inequality should be accounted
for by the stochastic shocks only; thus the estimation yields a substantially more persistent
stochastic process of x.
Just for the purposes of presentation, we assume that there is no stochastic volatility. As
outlined in Section 3, the (log) earnings of worker i with age j is:
yij = ai + βi × j + xij ,
where ai is the fixed effect, βi is the individual-specific slope, and xij = ρx xi,j−1 + νij is the
stochastic component that follows an AR(1) process with νj ∼ N (0, σ 2 ). For a worker who is
h years older:
yi,j+h = ai + βi (j + h) + xi,j+h .
The variance and covariance of earnings across ages help us to uncover the underlying
process. Specifically,
Cov(yj , yj ) = σa2 + 2σaβ j + σβ2 j 2 + V (xj )
Cov(yj , yj+h ) = σa2 + 2σaβ [2j + h] + σβ2 j(j + h) + ρhx V (xj )
with

(
V (xj ) =

0,
j=1
Pj−1 2h 2
h=0 ρx σν , j > 1.

The variance of earnings at age j is driven by two components: (i) σβ2 j 2 , which is convex
P
2h
in age j, and (ii) V (xj ) = σν2 j−1
h=0 ρ , which is concave in age j (as long as ρ < 1). The
shape of the cross-sectional variance along the life cycle is informative about which component
is stronger. The autocovariance of labor income at age j also depends on two components:
(i) σβ2 j(j + h) is increasing in the time horizon h, and (ii) the autocovariance should decay
monotonically at rate ρx due to component ρhx V (xj ). Absent the profile heterogeneity, the
autocovariances should decay monotonically from age j onward. In sum, the variance-

32

covariance matrix of labor income from our administrative data identifies {σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , σν2 }.
Note that a common challenge in this identification method is the lack of a long panel, a
challenge we do not face because we have about 20 years of observations.

5

Discussion on Stochastic Volatility

In this section, we illustrate how the marginal response of the risky share to income volatility
is useful to understand: (i) the role of imperfect information, (ii) the welfare cost of income
volatility, (iii) the persistence of the volatility shocks, and (iv) to distinguish our benchmark model from other well-known models of stochastic volatility such as ARCH and GARCH.
Role of Imperfect Information Our structural model exhibits significantly different
portfolio responses between PIM and IIM. To illustrate the importance of imperfect information, we consider a simple example. Suppose that in our model economy all workers start
with the median volatility and experience a single structural change in the volatility regime
at age 43 (i.e., τ ∗ = 43). For one-half of the workers, the volatility increases; for the rest of
the workers, the volatility decreases. The volatility change is assumed to be unexpected and
permanent (until the workers retire from the labor market).
Based on our simulated data, we run the following regression (used in our empirical
analysis) for t = {τ ∗ − 3, .., τ ∗ + 4}:
RSi,t − RSi,τ ∗ −4 = a + βt ∆SDi,τ ∗ + Xi,t + i,t ,

(12)

where Xi,t is a list of control variables (age, wealth, etc.). We plot the marginal responses
(coefficients βt ) in Figure 7. Before the structural break, the risky share differs only due to
time-varying worker characteristics. Therefore, controlling for characteristics, the marginal
responses are approximately equal to zero. The marginal responses turn negative upon
the structural break, reflecting a decrease in the risky share for workers who experience an
increase in income volatility. The negative relationship between the risky share and income
volatility confirms the standard intuition that labor-income risk crowds out financial risk.
With imperfect information, the marginal responses are also negative. But the magnitude is
smaller and slowly increases as workers gradually learn about the shift in the regime.
Welfare Cost of Income Volatility One advantage of the structural model is that it
allows us to examine the welfare cost of background income risk. Here, we study two types
of welfare cost of volatile income. First, consumption becomes more volatile because of the

33

Figure 7: Response of Risky Share: Perfect vs. Imperfect Information

Portfolio response β t (in percentage points)

0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50
-60

Perfect Information Model
Imperfect Information Model

-70
39

40

41

42

43
Age

44

45

46

47

Notes: The figure shows the estimated response—the regression coefficients from (12)—based on
a simple example where one half of workers experience an increase in income volatility at age 43,
while the other half experiences a decrease.

inability to insure against fluctuations in income streams (referred to as the “volatility effect”).
Second, faced with higher risk in the labor market, households would like to reduce their
exposure to risky investment in the financial market and, as a result, forgo the opportunity
to exploit the risk premium (the “portfolio effect”).
Suppose that some workers are exogenously switched to a high-volatility income regime
in the early stage of the life cycle. More specifically, at age 22 (τ ∗ = 22), one year after
the labor-market entry in our model, these workers experience a sharp increase in income
volatility from the middle to the highest volatility regimes (σζ = 2.5% to 20%). This increase
in income volatility is equivalent to the three-fold increase in the standard deviation of income
growth: 0.24 to 0.74. We denote these workers as “H” (high volatility). This change in
income volatility is assumed to be unexpected and permanent. We compare their welfare to
that of those who remain in the middle volatility regime, denoted by “M ” (middle volatility).
Table 7 reports the volatility of consumption and the average rate of return from
investment (during the working period, ages 21 to 65) for both groups. The workers in
the H regime experience 18 percent more volatile consumption (the standard deviation of
log consumption of 0.40 versus 0.34 in M ). This results in a welfare cost of 8.4 percent in
consumption-equivalent units. At the same time, they receive a lower average rate of return
34

of 3.0 percent (compared with 3.3 percent in the M group) as they invest their savings in a
more conservative way. This results in a welfare cost of 0.5 percent in consumption-equivalent
units. (See Appendix F for the details of computing the two types of welfare cost.)
Table 7: Welfare Costs of Volatile Income
Volatility Regime

“M”

“H”

Welfare Cost

SD of Log Consumption 0.34
Average Rate of Return 3.3%

0.40
3.0%

Volatility Effect 8.4%
Portfolio Effect 0.5%

Persistence of Volatility Shocks The indirect inference requires a highly persistent
volatility process in order to match the increasing age profile of kurtosis in the data. We
examine the role of the persistence of volatility shocks on portfolio choice. Specifically, we
vary the persistence and estimate the marginal effect of income volatility on the risky share
(i.e., β̂ in Equation (1), for k = 4, using model-simulated data). In each case, we adjust (i)
σζ2 to match the same standard deviation of ∆SD as in the benchmark and (ii) the discount
factor, δ, to match the same assets-income ratio as in the benchmark. Figure 8 plots the
marginal effect (regression coefficients) separately for the PIM and IIM models.
As the volatility shocks become more persistent, the response of the risky share (β̂)
becomes larger: workers adjust the risky share aggressively when the volatility change is
long-lived. For small values of ρσ , the responses are similar between PIM and IIM. When
the shocks are transitory, the realized income is not so informative about the regime. As the
volatility shocks become persistent, the response of the risky share diverges between PIM
and IIM since the current outcome is more informative about the future regime.
Alternative Models of Stochastic Volatility We next examine the portfolio choices
from the models under the alternative specification of stochastic volatility such as ARCH/GARCH
(which are commonly used in the empirical analysis, e.g., Engle, 1982).
First, suppose that the income process follows an ARCH (which is also used in Meghir
and Pistaferri (2004)). The individual variance of labor-income growth is:
2
σi,j+1
= σν2 + φ(yj − H0j Mj−1 )2 .

Now, the variance of income growth is a constant term (the median variance σν2 ) plus a term
that depends on the squared innovation νj (= yj − H0j Mj−1 ). In this specification, future
variations in income volatility are linked to realizations of innovations in earnings.

35

Figure 8: Persistence of Volatility Shocks and Response of Risky Share

Portfolio response β (in percentage points)

0
Perfect Information Model
Imperfect Information Model

-10

-20

-30

-40

-50

-60
0

0.1

0.2

0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Persistence of volatility shocks (ρσ )

0.9

1

Notes: The x-axis is the persistence of volatility shocks, ρσ , and the y-axis is the estimated response
of the risky share, β̂, with k = 4, for PIM and IIM.

Under GARCH, the variance of income growth can be written as:
2
2
σi,j+1
= (1 − ρσ )σν2 + ρσ σi,j
+ φ(yj − H0j Mj−1 )2 .

This explicitly allows for persistence in the volatility regime. However, note that none of these
specifications can accommodate imperfect information about the regime. In ARCH/GARCH,
the next period’s (expected) volatility depends on the innovation of the current labor income,
which is assumed to be perfectly observed.
For both ARCH and GARCH, we calibrate the parameters of the model in a similar
way to our benchmark. Specifically, φ is calibrated to match the cross-sectional dispersion of
[ For GARCH, the persistence, ρσ , is
the projected (instrumented) change in volatility, ∆SD.
calibrated to match the average kurtosis over the life cycle. We calibrate the discount factor,
the risk aversion, and the credit limit to match the same financial moments. Finally, we keep
the other labor-income parameters (including σν ) equal to the values estimated from the
benchmark case. Figure 9 illustrates the implications of each stochastic volatility model for
(a) the variance of log income, (b) the kurtosis of labor-income growth, (c) the variance of
log consumption, and (d) the estimated portfolio response—the regression coefficient β̂.
While the ARCH specification generates a realistic variance of labor income along the life
36

Figure 9: Alternative Models: Evaluation
0.45

8
Variance of log-income (Data)
Variance of log-income (ARCH)
Variance of log-income (GARCH)

0.4

Kurtosis of income growth (Data)
Kurtosis of income growth (ARCH)
Kurtosis of income growth (GARCH)

7.5
7

0.35

6.5

0.3

6
0.25
5.5
0.2
5
0.15

4.5

0.1

4

0.05

3.5

0

3
25

30

35

40
Age

45

50

55

0.12

25

30

35

40

45
Age

50

55

60

65

10
Variance of log-consumption (Data)
Variance of log-consumption (ARCH)
Variance of log-consumption (GARCH)

0.1

0

0.08

-10

0.06

-20

0.04

-30

0.02

-40

0

Portfolio response β (in percentage points), Data
Portfolio response β (in percentage points), ARCH
Portfolio response β (in percentage points), GARCH

-50
25

30

35

40
Age

45

50

55

1

2
3
Window around structural break (k)

4

Notes: Model fit for ARCH and GARCH. Upper-left panel shows the variance of log labor income.
Upper-right panel shows the cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth. Lower-left panel shows
the increase in the variance of log consumption along the life cycle starting from age 25. Lower-right
panel shows the coefficients from a model-generated regression of risky share on volatility, for every
horizon.

cycle, it fails to generate an increasing kurtosis profile as there is no built-in persistence in the
volatility process (as we explained in Section 4.4). Moreover, ARCH fails to generate a realistic
profile for consumption inequality because the process is characterized by a strong mean
reversion. A high income today increases the next period’s volatility, inducing high-income
workers to save more for precautionary reasons. A low income today also increases the next
period’s income volatility, inducing low-income workers to borrow because escaping from
the low-income state is more likely when the income process is highly volatile. As a result,
the ARCH model generates a large inequality in wealth that leads to a larger inequality in
consumption. Finally, the ARCH model generates portfolio responses smaller than what we
37

find in the data because there is no persistence in the volatility.
One characteristic of GARCH is the lack of symmetry in the evolution of income volatility.
On average, volatility increases for most workers along the life cycle as the income process is
persistent. This is not the case in our our benchmark model because workers can experience
both increases and decreases in income volatility, which lead to a nearly constant average
profile over the life cycle. As a result, the GARCH specification overestimates—by a wide
margin—the income inequality along the life cycle. Consumption inequality rises even faster
relative to ARCH because of the rapidly increasing income inequality. The GARCH can
deliver an increasing kurtosis profile, which confirms that persistence in income volatility is a
key element for the realistic age profile of kurtosis. However, we could not find a combination
of parameters (φ, ρσ ) to match both the dispersion of ∆SD and the average kurtosis. Finally,
GARCH cannot deliver a realistic response of portfolio choices due to a lack of symmetry in
the changes in volatility.
Overall, judging from the joint dynamics of labor income and portfolio choices (as well
as consumption), we argue that our model of persistent stochastic volatility is the best
representation of the data.

6

Conclusion

Households’ portfolio decisions depend on the background risk in the labor market. Based
on detailed administrative panel data from Statistics Norway, we find a statistically and
economically significant shift in the risky share around the structural break in income volatility:
if the standard deviation of labor-income growth doubles in size, the worker decreases the risky
share by 4 percentage points on average. We find substantially larger estimates compared to
many previous studies due to our identification strategy: individual-specific structural breaks
of income volatility combined with a firm-side instrumental variable.
We then ask whether our estimated marginal effect is consistent with a standard model
of portfolio choice with idiosyncratic shocks to income volatility. We structurally estimate
the model using various moments on income, consumption, and financial portfolio choices
from the Norwegian panel. The standard model fails to replicate the portfolio choice we see
in the data. It predicts that in response to a sudden change in income volatility, a typical
household should decrease the risky share much more aggressively than we see in the data.
We show that imperfect information (Bayesian learning) about the income volatility can
fill the gap between the model and the data by mitigating the response of the household’s
portfolio choice to the changes in income volatility. We also show that the structural model is
useful for identifying the higher moments of earning dynamics as well as assessing the welfare
38

cost of background risk.

39

References
Angerer, Z. and P.S. Lam. 2009. “Income risk and portfolio choice.” Journal of Finance 64 (2):1037–
1055.
Athreya, K., F. Ionescu, and U. Neelakantan. 2015. “Stock market participation: the role of human
capital.” Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Benzoni, L., P. Collin-Dufresne, and S. R. Goldstein. 2011. “Portfolio choice over the life-cycle when
the stock and labor markets are cointegrated.” Journal of Finance 62 (5):2123–2167.
Bertaut, C.C. and M. Haliassos. 1997. “Precautionary portfolio behavior from a life-cycle perspective.”
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21 (8-9):1511–1542.
Bound, J., C. Brown, and N. Mathiowetz. 2001. “Measurement error in survey data.” Handbook of
Econometrics 5:3705–3843.
Campbell, J., J. Cocco, F. Gomes, and P. Maenhout. 2001. “Investing retirement wealth: a life-cycle
model.” In Risk Aspects of Investment-Based Social Security Reform, edited by M. Feldstein and
J. Campbell. NBER.
Card, D., A. Mas, and J. Rothstein. 2008. “Tipping and the dynamics of segregation.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 123 (1):177–218.
Catherine, S. 2019. “Countercyclical labor income risk and portfolio choices over the life cycle.”
Working paper, University of Pennsylvania.
Chang, Y., J. Hong, and M. Karabarbounis. 2018. “Labor-market uncertainty and portfolio choice
puzzles.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10 (2):222–262.
Charles, K.K., E. Hurst, and M.J. Notowidigdo. 2018. “Housing booms and busts, labor market
opportunities, and college attendance.” American Economic Review 10 (108):2947–2994.
Cocco, F. J., J. F. Gomes, and J. P. Maenhout. 2005. “Consumption and portfolio choice over the
life-cycle.” Review of Financial Studies 18 (2):491–533.
Cunha, F. and J. J. Heckman. 2007. “The evolution of inequality, heterogeneity and uncertainty in
labor earnings in the US economy.” Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Davis, S. J. and P. Willen. 2000. “Occupation-level income shocks and asset returns: their covariance
and implications for portfolio choice.” Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Deaton, A. and C. Paxson. 1994. “Intertemporal choice and inequality.” Journal of Political
Economy 102 (3):437–467.
Dimson, E., P. Marsh, and M. Staunton. 2008. “The worldwide equity premium: A smaller puzzle.”
In Handbook of the Equity Risk Premium, edited by Rajnish Mehra. Elsevier.
Eika, L., M. Mogstad, and O. L. Vestad. 2017. “What can we learn about household consumption
expenditure from data on income and assets?” Working paper, University of Chicago.
Engle, F.R. 1982. “Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of
United Kingdom inflation.” Econometrica 50 (4):987–1008.
Fagereng, A., C. Gottlieb, and L. Guiso. 2017. “Asset market participation and portfolio choice
over the life-cycle.” Journal of Finance 72 (2):705–750.

40

Fagereng, A., L. Guiso, and L. Pistaferri. 2017. “Portfolio choices, firm shocks, and uninsurable
wage risk.” Review of Economic Studies 85 (1):437–474.
Fagereng, A. and E. Halvorsen. 2015. “Debt and household level responses.” Working paper, Norges
Bank.
———. 2017. “Imputing consumption from Norwegian income and wealth registry data.” Journal
of Economic and Social Measurement 42 (1):67–100.
Fagereng, A., M.B. Holm, B. Moll, and G. Natvik. 2019. “Saving behavior across the wealth
distribution: The importance of capital gains.” Working paper, National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Floden, M. 2001. “The effectiveness of government debt and transfers as insurance.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 48 (1):81–108.
Gollier, C. and J. W. Pratt. 1996. “Risk vulnerability and tempering effect of background risk.”
Econometrica 64 (5):1109–1123.
Gomes, J. F. and A. Michaelides. 2005. “Optimal life-cycle asset allocation: Understanding the
empirical evidence.” Journal of Finance 60 (2):869–904.
Guiso, L., T. Jappelli, and D. Terlizzese. 1996. “Income risk, borrowing constraints and portfolio
choice.” American Economic Review 86 (1):158–172.
Guiso, L., L. Pistaferri, and F. Schivardi. 2005. “Insurance within the firm.” Journal of Political
Economy 113 (5):1054–1087.
Guvenen, F. 2007. “Learning your earning: Are labor income shocks really very persistent?”
American Economic Review 97 (3):687–712.
———. 2009. “An empirical investigation of labor income processes.” Review of Economic Dynamics
12 (1):58–79.
Guvenen, F., F. Karahan, S. Ozkan, and J. Song. 2015. “What do data on millions of U.S. workers
reveal about life-cycle earnings risk.” Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Guvenen, F. and T. Smith. 2014. “Inferring labor income risk and partial insurance from economic
choices.” Econometrica 82 (6):2085–2129.
Haliassos, M. and A. Michaelides. 2003. “Portfolio choice and liquidity constraints.” International
Economic Review 44 (1):143–177.
Heathcote, J., K. Storesletten, and G.L. Violante. 2014. “Consumption and labor supply with
partial insurance: An analytical framework.” American Economic Review 104 (7):2075–2126.
———. 2017. “Optimal tax progressivity: An analytical framework.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 132 (4):1693–1754.
Heaton, J. and D. Lucas. 2000. “Portfolio choice in the presence of background risk.” Economic
Journal 110 (460):1–26.
Huggett, M. and G. Kaplan. 2016. “How large is the stock component of human capital?” Review
of Economic Dynamics 22:21–51.
Klovland, J.T. 2004. “Bond markets and bond yields in Norway 1819-2003.” In Historical Monetary

41

Statistics for Norway 1819-2003, edited by Oyvind Eitrheim, J.T. Klovland, and J.F. Qvigstad.
Norges Bank.
Lusardi, A. and O.S. Mitchell. 2007. “Baby boomer retirement security: The roles of planning,
financial literacy, and housing wealth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 72 (1):1–32.
Meghir, C. and L. Pistaferri. 2004. “Income variance dynamics and heterogeneity.” Econometrica
72 (1):1–32.
Palia, D., Y. Qi, and Y. Wu. 2014. “Heterogeneous background risks and portfolio choice: Evidence
from micro-level data.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 8 (46):1687–1720.
Pischke, J. 1995. “Individual income, incomplete information, and aggregate consumption.” Econometrica 63 (4):805–840.
Primiceri, G. and T. van Rens. 2009. “Heterogeneous life-cycle profiles, income risk and consumption
inequality.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (1):20–39.
Storesletten, K., I. C. Telmer, and A. Yaron. 2004. “Consumption and risk sharing over the life
cycle.” Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (3):609–633.
Viceira, L. M. 2001. “Optimal portfolio choice for long-horizon investors with non-tradable labor
income.” Journal of Finance 56 (2):433–470.
Wachter, A. J. and M. Yogo. 2010. “Why do household portfolio shares rise in wealth?” Review of
Financial Studies 23 (11):3929–3965.

42

Appendix
A

Data

A.1

Data Sources

Based on Statistics Norway, we combined the several data sets using the unique personal identifiers.
The details of the data are as follows.
Central Population Register: The data contain individual demographic information for all
Norwegian residents from 1992 to 2014. This includes personal variables (country of birth, first
stay date, immigration category, country background, gender, date of birth) as well as time-varying
characteristics (marital status, spouse’s ID if married). The family identifiers can be used to link
spouses and cohabiting couples with common children. Family structure and family types variables
are also available: total number of persons in the family, the age of youngest child, the age of
youngest and oldest person in the family, the number of children under the ages of 18, 16, 11, and 6,
family type, father ID and mother ID at the time of birth.) Some of these variables are missing for
several years (e.g., family type).
National Educational Database: All individual statistics on education have been gathered in
the National Education Database (NUDB) since 1970. Educational attainment is reported by the
educational establishment directly to Statistics Norway. By October 1 of each year, the completed
education from the previous school/academic year is updated and the information about the highest
attained level of education for the whole population is updated as well.
Administrative Tax and Income Records: All households in Norway are subject to an income
tax and a wealth tax, and they are obliged to report their complete income and wealth holdings to
the tax authority every year. Also, employers, banks, brokers, insurance companies and any other
financial intermediaries are obliged to send the information on the value of the assets owned by
the individual to the individual and to the tax authority as well. Traded financial securities are
reported at market value; value of shares in private companies is reported by individuals as well
as private companies to the tax authority. The tax authority will combine the information from
companies’ reports on net worth with individuals’, and adjust if necessary. For more details, see
annual reports from the tax authority (http://www.skatteetaten.no) as well as other literature (e.g.,
Fagereng and Halvorsen (2017))
Income Registry: From the income registry data, we gathered the following items:
• Earned income includes cash salary, taxable benefits and sickness and maternity benefits
during the calendar year.
• Net entrepreneurial income includes the income from land and forestry, fishing and hunting,
income from other business activities and sickness benefits in employment during the calendar
year.

43

• Capital investment income includes interest income, dividends, realized gains and other
investment income:
– Interest income (from bank deposits and accounts receivable during the calendar year)
– Dividends received during the calendar year
– Realization gains: Taxable gains on the sale of real estate and financial securities during
the calendar year.
– Deductible losses on the sale of real estate and financial securities during the calendar
year.
– Other income: Net income from the rental of real property outside the industry, return
on “spare part” of life insurance, income from abroad and other unspecified investment
income during the calendar year.
• Unemployment benefits paid to wage earners and self-employed.
• Pensions:
– Pensions from the scheme (ftryg): includes own pensions and national insurance, including a spouse’s allowance and child benefit for children aged 16 or younger.
– Own pensions: Occupational pensions include the payment to working conditions
including contractual pension (AFP). It also includes payments from individual pension
agreements (IPA), annuities and maternity council benefits in agriculture and forestry.
• Transfers:
– Tax-free transfers include child allowance, housing allowance, study grants, social
assistance, basic and auxiliary disability compensations.
– Taxable transfers include pensions from the National Insurance, pension, unemployment
benefit and received contributions, as well as other taxable transfers.
• Miscellaneous items in the income tax record:
– Alimony and annuities outside employment
– Sum of income and wealth taxes and negative transfers
– Sum of interest payments (interest on debt to Norwegian and foreign creditors) and
residential income (imputed residential income and leisure property and shareholder’s
share of income from housing companies).

Wealth Registry Record: For persons who are older than 17 years, we can obtain the wealth data
from the tax authority every year. Here are the descriptions quoted from the tax administration.30
30

For detailed information, see the corresponding 2015 tax form from the Norwegian Tax Administration: http://www.skatteetaten.no/en/person/Tax-Return/Find-item/#&del1=1&del2=1&del3=
1&del4=1&del5=1.

44

• Bank Deposits Deposits in Norwegian banks (entry 4.1.1 in the 2015 tax form)
“This item shows what deposits you and your children who are under 17 years of age at the
end of the income year have in Norwegian banks as of 31 December. Deposits belonging to
children under 17 will be split with half being assigned to each of the parents if they live
together. The amount will normally be pre-filled with the amount that has been reported.”
• Value of Shares in Mutual Funds (entry 4.1.4)
“The item is pre-filled with information concerning capital in Norwegian unit trusts and certain
foreign unit trusts which the Tax Administration has received information about from the
management companies concerned.”
• Value of Financial Securities (entry 4.1.7)
“This item shows the value of bonds and shares in the Norwegian Central Securities Depository
(VPS) as of 31 December. The amount will normally be pre-filled with what has been
reported.”
• Value of Shares in Private Companies (entry 4.1.8)
“This item shows the capital value of shares and other securities not registered with VPS.”
• Tax Value of Housing and Other Real Property (entry 4.3)
Capital such as dwellings, holiday homes, forest property, farms, agricultural property, plots
and commercial property, etc.
• Value of Home Owned (entry 4.3.2)
“If you own a home as of 31 December, the tax value must be entered under this item. The
tax value is determined on the basis of factors such as location, size and year of construction.
If the tax value exceeds 30 percent of the home’s market value, you can change the value if
you are able to document the market value. This concerns your primary home.”
• Premium Funds, Individual Pension Agreements (entry 4.5.1)
“This item shows your capital in the form of premium funds as of 31 December. The amount
will normally be pre-completed with the amount that has been reported by the company you
have entered into a pension agreement (IPA) with.”
• Value of Life Insurance Policies (entry 4.5.2)
“This item shows the surrender value of your annuities as of 31 December. The amount
will normally be pre-filled with the amount that has been reported by the insurance company/companies or employer who has made deposits on your behalf.”
• Other Capital (entry 4.5.4)
“If you have other taxable capital as of 31 December, the value must be entered under this
item. ‘Other taxable capital’ means for example assets in the form of capitalised ground rent,
rights linked to forest/uncultivated land, share of company assessed as partnerships (RF-1221)
and/or NOKUS (RF-1246).”

45

• Total Debt (entry 4.8)
“The items under ‘4.8 Debt’ concern negative capital such as loans, credit purchases, underpaid
tax, private loans, debts in housing cooperatives/jointly owned properties, debts abroad and
deductions for leasehold land, etc.”
• Total Net Worth (entry 4.9)
“Amounts specified under this item form the basis for the calculation of wealth tax payable to
municipalities and the state. The basis for this is the sum of your wealth with a reduction for
any debt.”

Employer-Employee Register: Statistics Norway combines the required report from each firm
that hires workers and the tax record from individuals. The data include detailed labor market
information for every worker each year (worker ID, employers’ ID, job starting date with each
employer, job ending date with each employer, total payments to workers from each employer,
industry, occupation, actual and expected working hours, total number of days worked, indicator
for full-time/part-time employment, etc.).
Register of Social Assistance Received: For each person from 1992, the register records
monthly the details of social assistance received. This includes any unemployment benefit, rehabilitation/medical rehabilitation, maternity, temporary disability insurance as well as the benefit for
sickness.

46

A.2

Sample Selection and Variable Definitions

Sample Selection Criteria
1. From the whole population with income tax registration records in 1993 (who are older than
17 years old), we choose male, Norwegian native, older than 25 in 1993, with no missing
records on education and other demographic variables.
2. We randomly select 10 percent and construct a panel for the period of 1993-2014.
3. Starting in 1994 and onward, for each year, we add a random sample of 10 percent who
became 25 years old to the panel data.
4. Using a unique person ID, we link the labor market information (industry, sector, occupation,
working days, and so on) with income tax record and wealth tax record. The occupation data
are only available starting in 2003.
5. Using a unique person ID, we link the social assistance (including unemployment benefits,
number of months being paid).
Linking Household Information
1. From the Central Population Register data, we obtain marital status and link to his spouse’s
ID.
2. From the Central Population Register data, we obtain the person’s father’s ID and mother’s
ID at the time of his/her birth; we can also link to each of his children’s ID. This provides
the information on family size, number of children, and number of young children.
3. Based on the person ID, spouse ID, father ID, mother ID, and children’s IDs’, we construct
information on the spouse’s income and wealth, father’s income and wealth, and each child’s
income and wealth if older than 17. This yields household-level income and wealth. (The
administration registry does not keep track of household-level income and wealth.)

Multiple Jobs and Main Job: In our benchmark sample, approximately 10 percent of workers
have multiple jobs within a year. Some of them are associated with multiple employers (different
establishment ID). Also, some workers with the same employer (establishment ID) have records
of earnings with different starting and/or ending dates. The latter cases reflect, for most workers,
changes in titles, job requirements, or new contracts with the same employer. Thus, we simply add
up the earnings under the same establishment within a year. Following the literature, we define the
main job, possibly among different employers, as the one with the largest earnings within a year. As
a result, this will reduce the person-year observations of earnings slightly, from 2,880,970 to 2,864,084.
Labor Market Status: Since the respondent does not report labor market status, we classify
them as follows:

47

• Employed: those with positive earnings and non-missing establishment ID.
• Unemployed: those with positive unemployment benefit during the year and the received
unemployment benefit greater than received earnings (if any), and not receiving pensions
(either from own pensions or other pension plans).
• Self-employed: those not associated with any employers, not receiving any unemployment
benefits during the year, and with positive reported business income.
• Retired: those not associated with any employers, not receiving any unemployment benefits
during the year, and with positive pensions (either from own pensions or other pensions plans)
Homeownership: In the wealth registry, we observe the reported value of home. One natural way
to define homeowners is just to find those with a positive value of home. However, according to this
definition, it turns out the homeownership rate is very low and not consistent with the report from
Statistics Norway (e.g., see the link “https://www.ssb.no/en/bo/”). Since some households may
have positive value of other real estate—which is either occupied by themselves or rented out—we
prefer to add up those values with the value of home. As a result, the homeownership rate is close
to 80 percent in the sample, very close to the official statistics.
Financial Assets and Risky Shares:
• Total Financial Assets: Value of life insurance + Value of Shares in mutual funds + Bank
Deposits + Value of Shares in private companies + Value of Financial Securities + Value in
premium fund (mostly pension funds)
• Risky Assets: Value of Shares in mutual funds + Value of Shares in private companies +
Value of Financial Securities
Same Employer Dummy: If the worker works with the same establishment ID this period and
last period—we require both establishment IDs and earnings records to not be missing.
Tenure for Current Job: This is calculated from the job starting date, which is reported in the
Employer-Employee Register. Note that for each worker and each year, if he has multiple job
records within the same establishment (e.g., someone works based on monthly contracts), we
use the summation of all earnings as the earnings record and use the earliest date as the job
starting date. If he has several records across different establishments, we then select the one
with the largest earnings.
Number of Job Changes: Total number of times changing employers in his history (in our
sample period) up to date.
Industry Stayer Dummy: If the worker works in the same industry (at the 2-digit level) in year
t − 1 and t.
Number of Industry Changes: The total number of times of changing industries up to date.
Occupation Stayer Dummy: If the worker works at the same occupation (at the 2-digit level)
in t − 1 and t.

48

Number of Occupation Changes: The number of times changing occupations up to date.
Number of Occupations Experienced: The number of different occupations up to date.
Years of Experience in Occupation: The total years of experience with the current occupation
up to date.

49

B

Summary Statistics and Robustness
Table 8: Sample Selection

10% of registered Norwegian males
+ Earnings ≥ 18 years
+ Positive RS ≥16 years
+ Financial Assets ≥ 50K NOK
+ Identified Structural Breaks

Number of Individuals

Person-Year Obs.

%

137,776
48,768
18,156
16,700
16,041

2,880,970
1,014,882
379,204
348,918
337,899

100.0
35.4
13.1
12.1
11.6

Notes: Earnings are deflated by the CPI. “10% of registered men” includes 10% random sample of
registered Norwegian males, older than 25, with no missing records on birth year, education, and
income and wealth tax.

Table 9: Summary Statistics for Income Growth and Changes in Volatility
Mean

S.D.

Percentiles

5%
10%
25%
yi 0.096 0.369 -0.492 -0.316 -0.105
∆yi,t -0.002 0.398 -0.499 -0.240 -0.065
SDi [∆yit ] 0.319 0.260 0.056 0.075 0.136
∆SDi,τ ∗ [∆yit ] -0.098 0.583 -1.031 -0.722 -0.352

50

50%
0.097
0.004
0.247
-0.072

75% 90% 95%
0.308 0.527 0.678
0.069 0.230 0.476
0.419 0.659 0.831
0.193 0.498 0.775

Table 10: Robustness for IV Estimates

Dependent Variable: RSi,τ̂ +k − RSi,τ̂ −k

k=1

k=2

k=3

k=4

-13.68*

-32.95***

-24.79**

-21.57**

Excluding managers within HHs

-4.85

-21.82***

-24.20***

-30.75***

Using value added/assets only

13.46

-23.24*

-38.11***

-27.36*

Using net sales/assets only

-4.46

-10.95

-4.88

-28.78

Excluding HHs with unemp. spells

-7.11

-25.36***

-23.15***

-25.23***

Financial assets > 20 p.p.

-8.41

-31.44***

-30.17***

-28.32***

Risky share > 5 p.p.

-7.27

-23.12***

-26.11***

-28.90***

Using τ ∗ defined from workers’ ∆SD

-14.45

-13.86

-32.61**

-36.15***

With higher-order income & wealth

-5.12

-16.98***

-20.02***

-24.92***

With industry dummies

-3.00

-15.37***

-18.94***

-23.00***

With industry & occ. dummies

-3.19

-21.28***

-27.02***

-28.68***

Staying with the same employer

-4.50

-22.67***

-22.44***

-23.07***

Always married from −k to +k

-3.85

-15.61***

-20.14***

-24.64***

Always single from −k to +k

-20.26

-29.20*

-14.08

-45.41**

Using volatility of disposable income

-14.81**

-34.53***

-39.31***

-39.88***

Controlling mortgage debt & housing

-4.281

-16.37***

-20.08***

-24.16***

Excluding firms < 25 pct.

51

Table 11: Responses by Group: IV Estimates

Age
Young (age < 40 in 2005)
∆SDi,τ ? (i)
Middle (40 ≤ age ≤ 55)
∆SDi,τ ? (i)
Old (age > 55 in 2005)
∆SDi,τ ? (i)
Education
College
High School
Financial Knowledge
Econ/Finance Major
Other Majors
Income Growth
Top 25%
Middle
Bottom 25%

k=1

k=2

k=3

k=4

-5.30
(10.71)

-27.02**
(13.50)

-26.22*
(14.76)

-25.28
(15.85)

-8.46
(5.800)

-16.83**
(6.610)

-13.55*
(7.041)

-22.02***
(7.329)

-3.45
(9.144)

-8.813
(12.54)

-29.48**
(12.14)

-15.19
(12.70)

8.49
(7.131)
-11.21*
(5.936)

-23.77***
(8.664)
-17.79**
(7.089)

-29.25*** -36.66***
(9.146)
(10.08)
-20.88*** -25.26***
(7.505)
(7.661)

-3.11*
(1.761)
-6.34
(4.455)

-4.10*
(2.376)
-17.94***
(5.267)

-6.64***
(2.221)
-24.93***
(5.656)

-10.03
(8.371)
-1.87
(6.48)
-5.64
(6.98)

-18.25*
(9.76)
-13.30*
(7.53)
-20.86**
(8.49)

-23.80** -30.69***
(10.47)
(10.98)
-23.61*** -23.56***
(7.93)
(8.03)
-14.30
-25.52**
(9.34)
(9.98)

52

-5.71**
(2.450)
-28.32***
(5.862)

C

Life-Cycle Kurtosis

We construct the life-cycle profile of kurtosis controlling for cohort effects. Following the methodology
of Deaton and Paxson (1994) we first compute kurtosis in labor income growth by age and cohort
group and second, regress the computed kurtosis on cohort and age dummies. The left panel of
Figure 10 shows the kurtosis profile for selected cohorts, while the right panel plots the age dummies.
The labor income growth of Norwegian workers exhibits substantial kurtosis. The average kurtosis
is 8.3, which suggests considerable deviations from a normal distribution that has a kurtosis equal
to 3.
The high average kurtosis reflects the large dispersion in volatility breaks, ∆SD. As mentioned,
we have filtered these changes to capture plausibly exogenous variations in volatility using firm-side
volatility. It is thus more appropriate to estimate our model based on a scaled kurtosis profile that
\ To construct the scaled profile we apply
is closer to the instrumented worker volatility change ∆SD.
the following process. First, we fit a linear trend to the profile of kurtosis and generate the trend
coefficients {tj } and the deviations from the linear trend {aj } where j stands for age. Second, we
construct a scaled version of the linear trend {sj } by setting s1 = t1 (both profiles start at the same
point at age 25) and s60 = xt60 (where x is the scale factor).
\ = 0.55, e.g., the raw
Our motivation for the scaled kurtosis profile is that it reflects sd(∆SD)
\ = 0.128, e.g., the exogenous measure by which we
measure of volatility breaks, and not sd(∆SD)
discipline the model. To calculate x we construct a relationship between the standard deviation of
\ and kurtosis. We use model-simulated data from a process without persistence to capture
∆SD
\ We find that
only the relationship between average kurtosis and the standard deviation of ∆SD.
if the standard deviation of ∆SD decreases by 0.1, the average kurtosis decreases by 1.25. Since
we adjusted downward the dispersion of ∆SD by 0.43 (0.55-0.12), we need to re-scale (decrease)
kurtosis by 0.43 × 1.25/0.1 =5.37, which implies that x = 0.55. Finally, we add the deviations {aj }
to the scaled linear trend to obtain the scaled kurtosis profile (right panel of Figure 10).

15

15

14

14

Cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth

Cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth

Figure 10: Cross-Sectional Kurtosis across Age Groups

13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6

Cohort 1950
Cohort 1955
Cohort 1960
Cohort 1965
Cohort 1970

5
4
3
2

13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4

Kurtosis, age dummies
Kurtosis, scaled

3
2

25

30

35

40

45
Age

50

55

60

65

25

30

35

40

45
Age

50

55

60

65

Notes: The left panel plots cross-sectional kurtosis of labor income growth by age for selected cohort
groups. The left panel plots the cross-sectional kurtosis of labor income growth net of cohort effects
and the scaled profile that takes into account the firm-induced variability.

53

D

Indirect inference

We estimate the model using indirect inference. We need to estimate a total of P = 9 parameters
represented by the vector
Θ = [δ, γ, b, σa2 , σβ2 , ρx , ρσ , σν2 , σζ2 ].
We estimate the parameters by minimizing the distance between a set of model-generated moments
M m (Θ) and their empirical counterpart M d (Θ). As explained in the main text, the moments used
in the estimation are
1. The average assets-income ratio.
2. The average risky assets-total assets ratio.
3. The average consumer debt-income ratio.
4. The variance-covariance matrix of log labor income across ages (a total of 441 moments).
\
5. The dispersion in the firm-induced volatility change ∆SD.
6. The life-cycle profile in the cross-sectional kurtosis of labor-income growth.
7. The life-cycle profile in the cross-sectional variance of log-consumption.
8. The response of the risky share to volatility (over a 4-year horizon).
In total we have M = 511 moments. The estimator minimizes the loss function
min LΘ = [M d − M m (Θ)]0 W [M d − M m (Θ)].

(D.1)

W denotes the weighting matrix of the moments. We first re-normalize the units by setting
weight on the diagonal element i equal to Wi = 1/Mid , e.g., the inverse of the empirical moment
we target. We then distribute more weights on moments we think are important to match closely
in our estimation. In particular, we multiply 500 times the weight associated with the average
assets-income ratio, 50 times for both the weights associated with the average risky share and
the response of the risky share to volatility, 500 times the weight associated with the variance of
log-earnings at three stages of the life cycle (ages 25, 45, 60). Finally, we multiply by 7,000 the
weight associated with the dispersion in volatility. Θ∗ is the parameter vector that minimizes the
distance between the model and empirical moments given our choice of the weighting matrix. We
compute the standard errors as follows.
1. Given Θ∗ we generate N = 100 different draws of shocks. For each n = {1, .., N } we compute
the model-generated moments Mnm (Θ∗ ).
2. We compute the variance-covariance matrix of the moments Cov(Mnm ), which is an M × M
matrix. We construct the M × M matrix S, which includes only the diagonal elements of
S = diag(Cov(Mnm )).

54

3. For each parameter θ = {1, .., P } we compute the numerical derivative with respect to each
moment m. We do so by altering slightly the value of the parameter relative to its estimated
value and computing the difference in the resulting value of the model-generated moment.
n
We end up with a P × M matrix ∆m
∆θ .
4. We compute the standard errors using the diagonal elements of the inverse of the following
matrix
1 ∆mn −1 ∆mn 0
).
V = (
S
N ∆θ
∆θ

E

Robustness: Small Risk Aversion

According to our model, the risky share overshoots in PIM because workers immediately realize the
regime change. The estimated relative risk aversion is 5.4 in PIM and 4.8 in IIM. One might be
concerned that the smaller risk aversion may drive this different response between PIM and IIM. To
explore this possibility, we solve the PIM with the risk aversion of 4.8 the estimate in the IIM (i.e.,
4.86). The responses are reported in Figure 11. Even with a smaller risk aversion, the response
of the risky share in PIM substantially over-predicts the response of the risky share. Notably, the
discrepancy is more visible at shorter time horizons. Workers gradually learn about the regime
change so the difference between PIM and IIM remains substantial for shorter time horizons.

Figure 11: Portfolio Response in PIM with Smaller Risk Aversion
10
Portfolio response, Data
Portfolio response, PIM (RA=5.4)
Portfolio response, PIM (RA=4.8)
Portfolio response, IIM (RA=4.8)

0

-10

-20

-30

-40

-50
1

2
3
Window around structural break (k)

55

4

F

Calculation of Welfare Costs

To isolate each channel of welfare loss we adopt the decomposition proposed by Floden (2001). The
life-time utility of each group p = {H, M } is given by:
Vp =

J X
X

δ j−1 (Πjt=1 st )

j=1 i∈p

cij 1−γ
.
1−γ

If for each age, each worker had consumption equal to the average consumption within each age
group, then welfare is:
V̄p =

J
X

δ j−1 (Πjt=1 st )

j=1

cpj

cpj

1−γ

1−γ

,

p
i cij /N

P

and N is the total number of workers.
where =
To find the volatility effect, we first compute the compensating differential (xp ) for no dispersion
in consumption for each group:
J
X
j=1

δ

j−1

1−γ
cpj
j
(Πt=1 st )

1−γ

=

J X
X
j=1 i∈p

V̄

δ j−1 (Πjt=1 st )

(1 + xp )cij 1−γ
.
1−γ

1
1−γ

This equals V̄p = (1 + xp )1−γ Vp and xp = ( Vpp )
− 1. According to our calibrated model, workers
in the M group are willing to give up 16 percent of annual consumption to be in an economy with
equal consumption within age group, while workers in the H group are willing to give up 26 percent
of their consumption. The welfare loss due to an increased volatility in H relative to that in M is
1+xH
ω v = 1+x
− 1.
M
Finally, in response to an increased background risk, workers move their portfolio toward safer
assets, missing out on the equity premium. To estimate the portfolio effect, we compute life-time
utility for each group in a counterfactual economy, where H workers experience on average the same
financial returns as the M group in the benchmark example. We find that the equity premium has
to increase to µ = 3.94 relative to µ = 3.14 for the H group to receive on average return of 3.3%. We
then compute the welfare from being in the counterfactual economy (high volatility and high returns)
VHµH .

µ

The welfare loss from missing on the equity premium in H group is

56

ωµ

=

V H
( VHH

)

1
1−γ

− 1.