View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Home Production

WP 06-04

Yongsung Chang
Seoul National University
Andreas Hornstein
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Home Production∗
Yongsung Chang

Andreas Hornstein

Seoul National University

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 06-04
May 31, 2006

Abstract
Studying the incentives and constraints in the non-market sector–that is, home
production–enhances our understanding of economic behavior in the market. In particular, it helps us to understand (1) small variations of labor supply over the life cycle,
(2) large variations of employment relative to wages over the business cycle, and (3)
large income differences across countries.
Keywords: Home Production, Time Allocation, Labor Supply
JEL Classifications: E3, J2, O4

∗

This note is prepared for the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd edition (New York, NY:
Palgrave McMillan). Any opinions expressed in this note are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
Chang: Associate Professor, School of Economics, Seoul National University, Seoul Korea 151-742.
Hornstein: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Richmond, VA 23261 USA.
Our e-mail addresses are yohg@snu.ac.kr and andreas.hornstein@rich.frb.org.

Studies such as the Michigan Time Use Survey (Hill, 1984; Juster and Stafford, 1991)
indicate that a typical married couple allocates only about one-third of its discretionary
time working for paid compensation in the market. The allocation of time for non-market
activities, such as home production or leisure, may be as important for economic welfare as
is the time spent working. Starting with Becker (1965) and Mincer (1962), the value of nonmarket activity has been explicitly incorporated into economic analysis in terms of forgone
earnings. Since household decisions on the allocation of time to market and non-market
activities are undertaken jointly, studying the incentives and constraints in the non-market
sector–home production–enhances our understanding of economic behavior in the market
sector. We discuss three examples where the inclusion of home production has improved
our understanding of macroeconomic issues: (1) low estimates of the labor supply elasticity
from panel data; (2) low correlation between return to working and hours worked over the
business cycle; and (3) large differences in measured output across countries.
In a standard neoclassical growth model with home production, a household derives
utility not only from the consumption of market goods, but also from the consumption
of non-market goods. Non-market goods are produced in a home production sector using
work effort and capital. The household’s utility also depends on the consumption of leisure,
which is the household’s time endowment less work effort supplied to the market and the
home production sector. One usually assumes that the economy’s technology is such that
investment goods that can be used to augment the capital stock in the market and nonmarket sectors are produced only in the market sector of the economy. Important factors in
the determination of the dynamics of a neoclassical growth model with home production are
the substitution elasticity between the consumption of market and non-market goods, the
substitution elasticity between capital and labor in market and home production, the relative
capital intensity of production in market and home production sector, and the correlation
of total factor productivity in the two sectors. Examples of the neoclassical growth model
augmented with home production are Benhabib, Rogerson and Wright (1991) and Greenwood
and Hercowitz (1991).

1

1. Business cycle analysis
The allocation of hours worked–employment–is at the heart of business cycle analysis.
Table 1 shows the standard deviations and correlation of the cyclical components of total
hours worked and returns to work for the U.S. economy, 1964—2003.

Table 1. Business Cycle Statistics of the Labor Market:
σ n /σ w

σ n /σ y/n

1.51

1.72

cor(n, w) cor(n, y/n)
.38

.01

Note: All variables are logged and de-trended with the Hodrick-Prescott
filter. Hours worked (n) represents the total hours employed in the nonagricultural business sector. Wages (w) are the real hourly earnings of production and non-supervisory workers. Labor productivity (y/n) is output
divided by hours worked. The period covered is from 1964:I—2003:II

Source: DRI-WEFA Basic Economics Database, Global Insight.

Two features are of great interest to macroeconomists. First, hours worked is substantially more volatile than the return to working. Second, hours worked is not highly correlated
with the return to working. Employment in other countries also exhibits similar features
(for example, Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, 1992). These facts present a serious challenge to
modern business cycle theory that builds on the idea of inter-temporal substitution of work
effort. This theory assumes that people work relatively more hours in some years than in
others because the return from working in the market is unusually high in these years [for
example, Lucas and Rapping (1969)]. According to Table 1, on the one hand it appears as if
employment would have to be very elastic in its response to changes in the return to work,
but on the other hand, the returns to work appear to be only weakly correlated with the
supply of work time.

2

1.1. Estimates of the labor supply elasticity
Business cycle theory that builds on the stochastic growth model, for example, Kydland and
Prescott (1982), indeed requires a large inter-temporal elasticity of substitution in order to
account for the relatively large fluctuations of hours worked. Yet a substantial empirical
literature based on micro data finds that households’ willingness to substitute hours is quite
low – less than 0.5 (for example, MaCurdy, 1981; Altonji 1986). Home production provides
a potential resolution of this problem.
Most micro estimates of the inter-temporal substitution elasticity rely on the variation
of hours worked and wages over the life cycle of households. Rupert, Rogerson and Wright
(2000) show that these estimates may underestimate the true willingness to substitute hours
across time if one does not take into account the fact that households simultaneously decide on the supply of hours for market and non-market activities. Essentially, conventional
estimates of labor supply elasticities suffer from an omitted variable bias: home work is positively correlated with market work and should be included in the estimation. For simplicity
assume that households’ preferences are log-linear in a consumption aggregator of market,
cmt , and home-produced consumption, cht , and work time, be it in the market, nmt , or at
home, nht :
u(cmt , cht , nmt , nht ) = log c(cmt , cht ) − B

(nmt + nht )1+1/γ
.
1 + 1/γ

Then the optimal labor supply of a household that is t years old can be written as
log wt = (1/γ) log(nmt + nht ) + At ,
where wt denotes the market wage rate, and At represents other terms that may depend
on age. The parameter γ denotes the willingness to substitute total hours over time–
intertemporal substitution elasticity. For conventional estimates of the labor supply elasticity, which ignore home production, time spent for home production activities represents an
unobserved supply shifter for market-labor.
A typical worker faces a hump-shaped wage profile in his life: wage rates rise, reach a peak
at age 45-55, and decline from then on. It is not unreasonable to assume that the consumption

3

of non-market goods, and therefore hours worked in home production, is correlated with the
market wage profile over the life cycle. For example, high earning years tend to be around
the years in which one buys a house or has children, both of which call for more time spent
in home production. The fact that home work and market work are positively correlated
over the life cycle, but home work is omitted from the estimation equation, implies that the
estimated inverse labor supply elasticity 1/γ̂ will be biased upward.
1.2. Wage-employment correlations
One of the primary empirical patterns that has puzzled many business cycle theorists is
the lack of a systematic relationship between employment and wages. On the one hand,
Keynesian IS-LM models assume that real wages and hours worked lie on a stable, downwardsloped marginal product of labor schedule and predict a strong negative correlation between
real wages and hours worked (for example, Dunlop, 1938). On the other hand, real-businesscycle models, such as that of Kydland and Prescott (1982), where productivity shocks shift
the labor demand schedule along a relatively stable positively sloped market labor supply
curve, tend to predict a strong positive correlation between wages and employment. Incorporating home production into the neoclassical growth model helps account for the low
correlation between market work and wages as well as the large variation of employment.
Technical progress not only augments the marginal product of labor in the market sector,
but it also affects the marginal product of labor in the home production sector. Consider, for
example, technical progress that is embodied in consumer durables, such as vacuum cleaners,
washers, etc. This kind of technological progress often reduces the required work effort in
the home sector for household chores, and thereby shifts the supply curve of market work
outward along a negatively sloped market demand for labor curve. Thus, while technical
progress in the market sector causes a positive correlation between market hours and wages,
technical progress in the non-market sector can cause a negative correlation between market
hours and wages. If technical progress in the market is positively correlated with that in the
non-market sector, then market hours may fluctuate substantially without any accompanying
changes in real wages.
In general, the allocation of hours between the market and home depends on (i) the
4

covariance structure of productivity in the market and home, (ii) the substitution elasticity
between market goods and home-produced goods, and (iii) the substitution elasticity between
capital and labor in the home production function–in particular, if the purchase of home
capital (for example, a home theater system) requires or saves hours in home production.
Recently, rich structures between the market and home production have been introduced to
study the various features of business cycles–for example, McGrattan, Rogerson and Wright
(1997), Hornstein and Praschnik (1997), Fisher (1997), Einarsson and Marquis (1997), Ingram, Kocherlakota and Savin (1997), Perli (1998), Chang (2000), Gomme, Kydland, and
Rupert (2001).

2. Cross-country income differences
There are enormous income differences across countries, and such disparity has persisted
over time. According to Heston, Summers, and Aten (2002), the ratio of the average per
capita GDP (based on Purchasing Power Parity Price) of the richest fifth of all countries to
that of the poorest fifth of all countries was about 12 in 1960 and had doubled to almost
25 by 2000. In the standard neoclassical growth model, distortions to capital accumulation
contribute to income differences. For a reasonably calibrated neoclassical growth model, the
distortions that are required to account for the observed income differences are, however,
unreasonably large. Parente, Rogerson and Wright (2000) show that the required distortions
are substantially reduced once we distinguish between an economy’s market sector whose
output is measured in the National Income Accounts and a home-production sector whose
output is not measured. With home production, distortions to capital accumulation not only
reduce the capital stock but also can reallocate economic activity from the market sector
to the non-market sector. Moreover, the measured income differences overstate the true
differences in welfare, and the unmeasured consumption from home production may explain
how individuals in some countries can survive on the very low levels of reported income.
Consider the neoclassical growth model with log preferences in consumption, cm , and
leisure, l. Output, ym , is produced using capital, km , and labor, nh , as inputs to a constant
αm
returns to scale Cobb-Douglas production function, ym = km
(zm nm )1−αm . Output can

5

be used for consumption and investment, xm , to increase the capital stock: km,t+1 = (1 −
δ)kmt + xmt /π, where δ is the depreciation rate. With capital accumulation distortions,
investment increases the capital stock less than one for one: π ≥ 1 (for example, Parente
and Prescott, 1994). It is easily conceivable that there are substantial inefficiencies in capital
accumulation in less-developed economies (for example, inefficient governments, ill-protected
property rights). Given commonly assumed preferences and technology, the investment rate
and work effort on the balanced growth path will be independent of the magnitude of capital
distortions, but the capital stock and output will decline with the capital distortion. Two
countries that look alike in terms of the investment rates may nevertheless have very different
output levels. Conditional on a reasonable parameterization of the economy, we would,
however, have to assume capital distortions, π ≥ 100, in order to account for observed
output differences of a factor of at least 10 (for example, Parente, Rogerson and Wright,
2000).
A straightforward extension of the neoclassical growth model that includes home production assumes that preferences are defined over a consumption aggregator that includes
market consumption and non-market consumption, ch , from the home-production sector.
The home production sector also uses capital, kh , and work effort, nh , as inputs to a CobbDouglas production function. The household’s time endowment can now be used in the
market and the non-market sector, and market production can be used for investment in the
market and the non-market sectors. If home production is less capital-intensive than market
production and market and non-market goods are sufficiently close substitutes, a higher capital distortion not only reduces total capital accumulation, but also leads to a reallocation
of the available capital and work effort from the market sector to the non-market sector.
Parente, Rogerson and Wright (2000) argue that, for reasonable substitution elasticities between market and home-production consumption and capital shares in the home-production
sector, capital distortions as low as π = 15 can account for income differences in the market
sector of a factor of 10.

6

References
[1] Altonji, J., “Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Supply: Evidence from Micro Data,”
Journal of Political Economy 94 (1986), s176-s215.
[2] Backus, D., Kehoe, P., and F. Kydland, “International Real Business Cycles,” Journal
of Political Economy, 100 (1992), 745-775.
[3] Becker, G., “A Theory of the Allocation of Time,” Economic Journal 75 (1965), 493-517.
[4] Benhabib, J., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright, “Homework in Macroeconomics: Household
Production and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Journal of Political Economy 99 (1991), 11661187.
[5] Chang, Y., “Comovement, Excess Volatility, and Home Production,” Journal of Monetary Economics 46 (2000), 385-396.
[6] Dunlop, John T., “The Movement of Real and Money Wage Rates,” Economic Journal
48 (1938), 413-434.
[7] Einarsson, T., and M. Marquis, “Home Production with Endogenous Growth,” Journal
of Monetary Economics 39 (1997), 551-569.
[8] Fisher, J., “Relative Prices, Complementarities and Comovement among Components
of Aggregate Expenditures,” Journal of Monetary Economics 39 (1997), 449-474.
[9] Gomme, P., Kydland F., and P. Rupert, “Home Production Meets Time-to-Build,”
Journal of Political Economy 109 (5), 1115-1131.
[10] Greenwood, J., and Z. Hercowitz, “The Allocation of Capital and Time over the Business
Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy 99 (1991), 1188-1214.
[11] Heston, A., Summers R., and B. Aten, Penn World Table Version 6.1, Center for
International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP), October 2002.
[12] Hill, M. S. “Pattern of Time Use.” In Time, Goods and Well-Being. Ed. F. Thomas
Juster and Frank P. Stafford. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press (1984).
7

[13] Hornstein, A., and J. Praschnik, “Intermediate Inputs and Sectoral Comovement in the
Business Cycle,” Journal of Monetary Economics 40 (1997), 573-595.
[14] Ingram, B., Kocherlakota, N., and N. E. Savin, “Using Theory for Measurement: An
Analysis of the Cyclical Behavior of Home Production,” Journal of Monetary Economics
40 (1997), 435-456.
[15] Juster, F. T., and F. P. Stafford, “The Allocation of Time: Empirical Findings, Behavior
Models, and Problems of Measurement.” Journal of Economic Literature 29 (1991),
471-522.
[16] Kydland, F., and E.C. Prescott, “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica 50 (1982), 1345-1370.
[17] Lucas, R. E. Jr., and L. Rapping, “Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation,” Journal
of Political Economy 77 (1969), 721-754.
[18] MaCurdy, T., “An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life-Cycle Setting,” Journal
of Political Economy 88 (1981), 1059-1085.
[19] McGrattan, E., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright, “An Equilibrium Model of the Business
Cycle with Household Production and Fiscal Policy,” International Economic Review
38 (1997), 267-290.
[20] Mincer, “On the Job-Training: Costs, Returns and its Implications” Journal of Political
Economy, 70 (1962) 50-79.
[21] Parente, S., and E. C. Prescott, “Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development,"
Journal of Political Economy, 102 (1994), 298-321.
[22] Parente, S.L., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright, “Homework in Development Economics:
Household Production and the Wealth of Nations,” Journal of Political Economy 108
(2000), 680-687.
[23] Perli, R., “Indeterminacy, Home Production, and the Business Cycle: A Calibrated
Analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 41 (1998), 105-125.
8

[24] Rupert, P., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright, “Homework in Labor Economics: Household
Production and Intertemporal Substitution,” Journal of Monetary Economics 46 (2000),
557-579.

9