View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 84-2

THE FORMULATION OF MONETARY POLICY

Robert L. Hetzel*

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
May 1984

*The author gratefully acknowledges useful criticism on an earlier
draft from Milton Friedman, Denis S. Karnosky, Richard W. Lang, Robert D.
Laurent, Raymond E. Lombra, Bennett T. McCallum, Thomas Mayer, Allen H.
Meltzer, Roy H. Webb and John T. Woolley. The views in this paper are
solely those of the author and, it must be strongly emphasized, do not
necessarily reflect the views of the foregoing individuals, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond, or the Federal Reserve System.

Abstract
The purpose ,of this paper is to elucidate the way in which current
institutional arrangements shape the character of monetary policy.

It is

emphasized that the Fed, in order to preserve its independence, formulates
. monetary policy in a way that prevents the formation of coalitions within
the government that could threaten its independence. As a consequence, the
Fed, in general, attempts to balance multiple, changing objectives.

This

attempt leads to the demand for "flexibility," an absence of precommitment.
Much of the paper is devoted to a discussion of the way in which the Fed's
/
desire to avoid precommitment influences its use of analytical procedures
for formulating policy and its use of money supply targets.

1.

Introduction
Economists often seem to view the monetary policy of the Federal

Reserve System as formulated independently from the rest of government.
Influencing policy is believed to be a matter of getting the attention of
the chairman of the Fed and convincing him of the cogency of a particular
policy.

It is argued here that monetary policy reflects the nature of the

institutional arrangements that circumscribe it.

Influencing policy is

more aptly viewed as requiring an alteration of institutional arrangements,
than as requiring the persuasion of individual policy makers of the
validity of particular ideas.

The principal participants in the

formulation of monetary policy are introduced briefly in Section 2.

In

Section 3, the theme of the paper is summarized, that is, the primary
importance of institutional arrangements in determining the character of
monetary policy.
2.

The Principal Participants
Constitutionally, the Fed owes its existence to Congress.

An indepen-

dent Fed conforms to Congressional needs in that Congress lacks the incentive to supervise monetary policy closely (Woolley 1984 Chap. 7), but is
unwilling to surrender monetary policy to the Executive Branch.

Congress,

of course, still cares about the effect of monetary policy on the
economy.

The Executive Branch also cares about the effect of monetary

policy upon the economy.

Unlike Congress, it cannot directly threaten the

independence of the Fed.

It can exert influence, however, through the

power to appoint governors. More important, indirect influence derives
from the fact that a good relationship with the Executive Branch can make
the latter a useful ally for the Fed in protecting against encroachments on
its prerogatives by Congress.

[For an extensive list of ways the Executive

-2Branch and Congress can use in order to try

to influence monetary policy,

see Kane (19821.1
The public comprises disparate groups with conflicting objectives.
The relative political influence of these groups, that is, the extent to
which they attempt to influence the political process through voting or
contributions to politicians, depends upon the contemporaneous state of the
economy.

For example, the higher the unemployment rate, the greater is the

pressure on politicians to pursue policies to expand employment.

Accord-

ingly, Congress and the Executive Branch care about the contemporaneous
state of the economy.
The Fed is independent in the sense that no other part of government
dictates monetary policy to it.

The Fed prizes this independence.

The

responsibility to formulate monetary policy makes the Fed into an institution of considerable importance. The resulting access to the public media
and to other policy makers offers a Fed chairman who is publicly and
privately persuasive the opportunity to influence a wide range of governmental economic policies.
3.

Institutional Arrangements and the Character of Monetary Policy
The dominant characteristic of existing institutional arrangements is

the Fed's independence. The sine qua non for the Fed is preservation of
this independence. Preservation of its independence, from the perspective
of the Fed, involves two aspects.

One aspect entails maintaining public

support by encouraging the belief that Fed independence is essential for
the control of inflation.

The aspect emphasized in this paper is that

monetary policy must be formulated in a way that precludes a coalition from
forming, among groups in Congress and the Executive Branch, that is capable
of threatening Fed independence.

It is argued that this latter aspect

-3-

shapes the formulation of monetary policy in three ways.

First, monetary

policy is determined primarily by the contemporaneous state of the economy.
Second, the behavior of the funds rate must accord in a common sense way
with the contemporaneous state of the economy.
Third, preventing the formation of a coalition that can threaten its
independence among groups in Congress and the Executive Branch with
differing objectives appears, in general, to the Fed to require the
balancing of multiple targets, with the relative importance of individual
targets varying over time.

This latter requirement creates the demand by

the Fed for "flexibility," an absence of precommitment. The unwillingness
of the Fed to precommit its actions generates implications for the
formulation of monetary policy of three kinds: 1)
long run and short run in policy; 2)
procedures; and 3)

the relationship of the

the use of analytical operating

the use of money supply targeting. The bulk of this

paper is devoted to discussion of points two and three above.
4.

The Contemporaneous State of the Economy and the Funds Rate
Congress and the Executive Branch are concerned with the contempo-

raneous state of the economy.

A monetary policy guided by the contempo-

raneous state of the economy is, therefore, required in order for the Fed
to maintain its independence. The contention that the dominating influence
on monetary policy is the Federal Reserve's perception of the
contemporaneously most pressing economic problem has been advanced by
students of the Federal Reserve, e.g., Lombra (1980 p. 50) and Pierce (1980
p. 261).
The concern of Congress and the Executive Branch for the behavior of
the economy translates, to a limited extent, into a heedfulness of the

behavior of the money supply because of public association of high rates of
growth of money with high rates of inflation.

Primarily, however, this

concern translates into a heedfulness of the behavior of interest rates.
While the money supply is an intellectual abstraction, interest rates are a
readily observable part of the price system that constrains the availability of resources and affects the distribution of income.
Rep. Paul. A lot of our discussion so far has been on
interest rates, and there is justified reason for this,
because when we go and talk to the people, everything they
see and hear about is in terms of interest-Chairman Volcker. That is right. (U.S. Congress 1982 p. 66)
The Federal Reserve implements monetary policy by varying its policy
instrument in a way that accords with its perception of the contemporaneously most pressing economic problem.

The policy instrument that is

considered relevant for implementing policy, the funds rate or the money
supply, changes in an ad hoc way because of the dual concern of the public
for each of these instruments. The greater importance attached to interest
rates rather than to the money supply by the public implies that generally
it is the behavior of the funds rate that must appear to accord with the
contemporaneous behavior of the economy (Poole 1980 pp. 276-7).

The

attitude of the Fed toward interest rate , as opposed to money supply
targeting, is discussed in Section 6.

For the post-October 1979 period,

the ideas of this section are illustrated in Hetzel (1984).
The political system acts to ensure a monetary policy that is politically acceptable through the selection procedure for the chairman of the
Federal Reserve.

Attributes that promote an individual's candidacy for

chairman include a distinguished career of public service, recognition in
financial markets, recognition by key politicians (especially the chairmen
of the House and Senate Banking Committees), and acceptability to

-5-

presidential political advisors.

In discussing candidates, newspaper

articles stress phrases like "leadership skills," "experience," and "stature."

The economics of serious candidates will be described by words like

"pragmatic" or "eclectic." This recruitment procedure produces chairmen
likely to adopt monetary policies that will elicit broad political support,
specifically, policies guided pragmatically by the contemporaneously most
pressing problem of the economy, rather than by an abstract economic
paradigm.
The hypothesis that monetary policy is shaped by the need to avoid
formation of coalitions that could threaten the Fed's independence implies
that monetary policy should be thought of as being formulated within the
political system rather than as being formulated apart from this process by
philosopher economists.

This implication in turn implies the testable

implication that monetary policy will not be formulated in any way that
removes it from the political decision making process.

The characteristics

of the way in which monetary policy is formulated that are described below
can be viewed as empirical evidence supporting this testable implication.
More generally, the hypothesis of this paper that the character of monetary
policy derives from the institutional arrangements within which it is
formulated requires for testing observation of monetary policy across
different monetary regimes.

The summary of monetary policy for the current

regime offered here is intended as a step in the latter program of
research.
5.

The Time Horizon of Policy and Nonanalytical Decision Making
FOMC discussion, as it evolved in the early 197Os, was in two parts,

with each part organized around a staff presentation. The first of these
presentations, the Greenbook presentation, entailed a detailed forecast of

-6-

the behavior of the economy over a four to six quarter horizon (Lombra and
Moran 1980).

In the subsequent discussion, FOMC members would offer their

views on the current and near-term state of the economy and would ask
'stump the staff' questions about the consistency and validity of the
staff's projections.

Detailed discussion of the state of the economy

dominated at FOMC meetings, with minimal discussion of basic issues of
monetary theory and policy (Mayer 1982a). No explicit numerical specification of ultimate objectives was attempted.
The second presentation, the Bluebook presentation, entailed
explication of three sets of paired values of the federal funds rate and
growth of the money supply, with the values in each pair predicted to be
mutually consistent.

These three sets assumed a slightly lower, unchanged,

and slightly higher value of the funds rate than the currently prevailing
value, and they showed the associated money growth predicted over consistent six, later twelve, and two month paths.

Specification of the pairs of

funds rate and money supply projections started with a staff forecast of
the growth of nominal GNP.

This latter variable was taken as exogenous

over the relevant horizon of policy.

The relationship between the funds

rate and money supply projections was derived on the basis of a Keynesian
liquidity preference effect.

Nominal money growth that was high,

commensurate with, or low in relation to the given value of GNP growth was
assumed, respectively, to depress, leave unchanged, or raise the level of
market rates.
The FOMC in its discussion would select a pair of values for the funds
rate and growth of the money supply, although not necessarily one of the
pairs listed in the Bluebook.

The associated figure for money growth was

viewed as a benchmark, not a target (Hetzel 1981). Over the ensuing

-7-

intermeeting period, the Desk would compare projections of money growth
(revised weekly on the basis of incoming data) with this benchmark as the
criterion for determining whether to change the target for the funds rate.
The relationship between the first and second parts of FOMC meetings
was informal.

For example, when FOMC members were concerned about the real

sector, the detailed discussion of the economy in the first part typically
focused on reasons for not tightening in the money market.

Such concern is

often recorded in the Record of Policy Actions (a summary of FOMC deliberations) by statements like the following:
It was also suggested that a firming of money market conditions. . .
would be premature, given the weakness of recent economic statistics, the still unsettled coal strike, and uncertainty about the
strength of the prospective rebound in economic activity. (Board
1978 p. 150)
If the real sector was the primary concern, the FOMC would choose an "easy"
benchmark for money growth based upon the alternative specified by the
staff in which money growth was high relative to the projected growth of
GNP.

In this way, incoming data on the money supply would be likely to

cause the Desk to lower the funds rate slightly.

If inflation was the

primary concern, the FOMC would choose a "restrictive" benchmark for money
growth, one likely to cause the Desk to raise the funds rate slightly.
(This discussion of operating procedures in the 1970s is continued in
Section 6).
Although the operating procedures of the Fed changed in 1979 (Hetzel
1982 and 1984), the formulation of monetary policy has retained a basic
continuity.

First, monetary policy evolves as a succession of short-run

decisions, as reflected in the assumption of exogeneity of GNP growth over
the relevant policy period.

It is assumed that an optimal long-run policy

will result from a concatenation of policy decisions, each of which is

-8-

optimal in a short-run context, without any systematic procedure whereby
long-run objectives constrain the decision-making process.

The

unwillingness to constrain the behavior of policy variables on the basis of
long-run objectives is one manifestation of avoidance of precommitment.
Second, monetary policy is formulated outside of an analytical framework.

For example, Lombra and Moran (1980 p. 43) comment, ". . .without

the guidance or discipline offered by an analytic model and formal targets
for nonfinancial variables, the formulation of monetary policy often seemed
a seat-of-the pants operation."

(See also Warburton 1952, Friedman and

Schwartz 1963, Brunner and Meltzer 1964, Guttentag 1966, Kane 1980, Pierce
1980, Mayer 1982a and 1982b, and Lombra forthcoming.) The FOMC does not
specify explicit numerical values for ultimate objectives and then employ a
model of the economy in order to derive, from these ultimate objectives,
settings for either its intermediate or operating targets.

Monetary policy

is effected outside of any framework relating policy variables to ultimate
objectives.

Instead, policy variables are moved in a way that conveys a

shading of emphasis among competing qualitative objectives, such as "low"
unemployment and "low" inflation.
There are a variety of reasons why the Fed formulates monetary policy
outside of an analytical framework. Analytical decision making requires
explicit formulation of ultimate objectives.

The Fed believes that explic-

it formulation of objectives would encourage an attack on its independence.
In particular, Congressional review of explicit objectives might allow
Congress to dictate them.

This view is illustrated in testimony by the Fed

on the numerous bills introduced in Congress in 1983 that would require the
Fed to make explicit its ultimate objectives.
introduced by Rep. Fauntroy,

(An example is the bill

The Balanced Full Growth Act of 1983, that

-9-

would require the Federal Reserve to transmit to Congress twice annually an
objective for GNP growth.)
Finally, some proposals could be motivated--whether explicitly
or not- by a desire for the Congress (or an administration) to exert
direct control over setting and implementing monetary policy. That
is not usually a professed objective; but the effect of some proposals would be to facilitate or even encourage such an outcome (p.
618). . .The independent status of the Federal Reserve that makes
a longer-term view possible might well be compromised with GNP
targeting, since the Federal Reserve could be under great pressure
to conform its targets to some immediately attractive number and
then to act to achieve those targets. (Volcker 1983c p. 620)
Indeed, in the end, the pressures might be intense to set the
short-run "objectives" directly in the political process. . . .
(Volcker 1983a p. 607)
More generally, analytical decision-making procedures are unacceptable
to the Fed because they would precommit it to a way of making decisions
incompatible with the formulation of monetary policy in a way that prevents
the formation of political coalitions capable of threatening its
independence. At times, analytical procedures would call for changes in
policy instruments that to the public would appear unjustifiable in light
of the contemporaneously most pressing economic problem, for example,
significant increases in the funds rate when unemployment, rather than
inflation, is the major concern. Also, analytical procedures for decision
making would cause the Fed's preference for moderate, gradual changes in
its operating variables , especially the funds rate, to appear adventitious.
(The existence of this preference is not contradicted by occasional large
changes because it may be the moderate, gradual changes that force
occasional large changes.)

Such behavior of operating variables is valued

because it creates the impression that the Fed is not making a clear choice
between conflicting goals, but rather is only shading the emphasis of
policy.

In this way , monetary policy actions are packaged in order to

avoid serving as a lightning rod for the criticism of potential opposition.

- 10 -

Other problems turn on the fact that policy formulated within an
analytical framework requires numerical specification of ultimate objectives.

Such explicitness is ill adapted to the requirement that priorities

among ultimate objectives be varied over time in an ongoing manner (Kane
1980).

By serving as a focal point for pressure from vocal, well organized

groups, explicit objectives would constrain the ability of the Fed to alter
the priorities assigned to ultimate objectives.

When an objective is

revised in a way that a particular group considers undesirable, the explicitness of past targets would facilitate accusations by this group of a lack
of resolve and consistency on the part of the Fed.
The absence of explicit ultimate objectives aids in fostering a
consensus among competing groups that actual monetary policy is desirable.
The more explicit the monetary authority is about its ultimate objectives,
the harder the task of convincing competing groups that their conflicting
objectives are being pursued.

Vagueness fosters consensus by permitting a

defense of policy as a joint pursuit of all desirable objectives, at least
within some undefined long run.
trade-offs.

Explicitness highlights painful

Explicitness about the relationship between ultimate objec-

tives and operating targets also would increase the ability of groups to
challenge the Fed over whether the actual choice of operating targets would
in fact achieve the stated ultimate objectives.
Perspective on the formulation of monetary policy outside of an
analytical framework can also be gained from the work of political scientists like Lindblom (1959). A variety of entities can potentially combine
in order to threaten Fed independence. These entities include the House
and Senate Banking Committees , each of which possesses majority and
minority camps, and the Executive Branch, which may be divided into

- 11 -

disparate camps comprising the Treasury, the Council of Economic Advisers,
and the Office of Management and Budget.

These camps will have their own

constituencies. The conflicting objectives of these various constituencies
render impossible formulation of a common set of objectives, the pursuit of
which would preserve Fed independence. Analytical decision-making
procedures, consequently, are impractical. Negotiations within the
political system over ultimate objectives are not possible.

Discussions

over ultimate objectives are replaced by more tractable discussions over
moderate changes in operating variables, although in unusual situations of
"crisis," large changes in operating variables become feasible.
6.

Money Supply Targeting
Money supply targeting is only infrequently an acceptable means of

implementing monetary policy.

It generally conflicts with the need for the

behavior of the funds rate to "look right" given the contemporaneous
behavior of the economy.

Also, within the Fed, money supply targeting is

associated with precommitment, that is, a commitment to vary the funds rate
on the basis of the behavior of the money supply, relative to a target set
in the past.

An absence of precommitment, however, is viewed as a prereq-

uisite for balancing multiple, changing targets.

These points are illus-

trated below in the context of a review of the three general ways in which
the Fed has implemented monetary policy in the recent past.
The first general way of implementing monetary policy is termed the
judgmental mode.

It involves straight judgmental variation of the funds

rate (or money market conditions) with no criteria specified in advance for
determining this variation.

This mode characterizes monetary policy from

the post-Accord period through Sept. 1972.

In response to criticism that

it had allowed excessive growth of money in 1968, the FOMC early in 1970

- 12 -

began to make policy choices from alternative pairs of specifications of
conditions in the money market and projections of money growth.

The hope

of the FOMC was that, if it were aware of the implications for growth of
the money supply of its choice of the interest rate target, then interest
rate targets that produced undesirable money growth would be avoided.

This

procedure, of course, did not obviate the need to make hard choices between
interest rate changes and monetary control.

In practice, the increased

awareness of the implications for growth of money of the rate target did
not enhance monetary control.
From the perspective of the Fed, the problem with the judgmental mode
is that it conveys the message to the public that the Fed can control
interest rates.

Pressures then develop for the Fed to control interest

rates in order to achieve allocative, rather than macroeconomic, objectives.

These pressures led to the indirect mode for implementing monetary

policy.

In this mode, used from Oct. 1972 until Oct. 1979 (Hetzel 1981),

the behavior of the money supply triggers changes in the funds rate considered desirable by the Fed.
In the 19709, the prerequisite for significant targeting of the money
supply, that is, operationally-significant targets for the money supply,
did not exist.

Because of the phenomenon known as base drift, the money

supply targets specified by the Fed lacked operational significance.
Targeted growth rates (two quarter before 1975 and four quarter thereafter)
were applied to a base that was changed quarterly.

The result was to

vitiate the significance of the targets by causing them to become a function of the quarterly misses of past targets.
The Desk was not given targets for the money supply, but rather was
given "tolerance ranges."

These tolerance ranges were not intended to

- 13 -

constrain actual money growth; instead, they served as benchmarks which, in
conjunction with projections of near-term growth of the money supply,
indicated to the Desk when to change the funds rate.

Changes in the funds

rate were constrained to be essentially monotonic over particular phases of
the business cycle (Hetzel 1981). In this way, the money supply served as a
triggering mechanism for producing desired changes in the funds rate.
operating procedures of the 1970s were extremely complex.

The

They can,

however, be understood as designed in order to build the politically
advantageous rationale of monetary control into increases in the funds rate
while in fact allowing the Fed to retain the funds rate as its policy
variable.
In the third general way of implementing policy, the monetary aggregates mode, the behavior of the money supply is the criterion for setting
the funds rate.

This mode lacks the precommitment envisaged by proponents

of money supply targeting.

The money supply is retained as a criterion for

setting the funds rate only as long as the behavior of the money supply
captures the Fed's perception of the economy's most pressing problem.

In

contrast with the judgmental and indirect modes discussed above, however,
the monetary aggregates mode does require specifying in advance a criterion
for determining changes in the funds rate.

The relative importance of

precommitting policy with this latter mode makes its use acceptable only
when the Fed possesses a single objective, lowering the rate of inflation.
The monetary aggregates mode was employed from Oct. 1979 to July 1982,
apart from the period of the Special Credit Restraint Program in spring
1980 when credit, rather than money, was targeted. [The formulation and
implementation of monetary policy from Oct. 1979 to Dec. 1983 is described
in detail in Hetzel (1984).] The monetary aggregates mode allows full use

- 14 -

of the language of monetary control as a way of relaxing the political
constraints on raising the funds rate.

The use of this language allows the

Fed to avoid setting an explicit target for the funds rate and to defend
increases in the funds rate as necessary in order to control inflation.
In the summer of 1982, the Fed switched from the monetary aggregates
mode of implementing policy to the judgmental mode.

The prior preoccupa-

tion with the single objective of reducing inflation gave way to the more
typical situation in which the Fed was balancing multiple objectives.

In

particular, policy came to be directed toward sustaining economic recovery
and averting a collapse of the international financial system, while
forestalling a revival of inflation. A policy environment of balancing
multiple objectives rendered even the limited precommitment of the monetary
aggregates mode unacceptable.

This environment made inevitable a return to

the implementation of policy through judgmental variation of the funds
rate.
The money supply plays a role in two of the general ways of implementing monetary policy discussed above, the mode in which it triggers desirable changes in the funds rate and the mode in which it semes
rion for setting the funds rate.

as a crite-

In order to understand this role, it is

important to note that, with both kinds of operating procedures, the Fed
"looks through" the money supply to economic activity in determining the
funds rate.

Specifically, the money supply is regarded as a useful crite-

rion for triggering changes or for setting the funds rate when its behavior
reflects the behavior of contemporaneous economic activity, but is discounted otherwise.

When money is growing rapidly during a recession, for

example, the growth of money will not appear to offer information on the
behavior of economic activity, so it will be discounted.

The lack of

- 15 -

correspondence between the behavior of money and GNP will be interpreted as
reflecting a shift in the demand for money.

In this way, the funds rate

can be moved in a way that appeals to common sense in the light of
contemporaneous economic activity.

These ideas explain the following kind

of quotation.
We recognize the considerable uncertainties surrounding the
shorter-run relationship between growth rates of the monetary
aggregates, on the one hand, and the behavior of output and
prices on the other. The Federal Reserve will continue, therefore, to maintain a vigilant and flexible approach, putting
the long-run performance of the economy above the pursuit of
any fixed monetary growth rates. (Miller 1978 p. 189)
The idea of "looking through" the behavior of money to the economy
explains the importance the Fed attaches to having multiple definitions of
the money supply to choose from as targets.

This multiplicity of defini-

tions and targets and the ability to vary the emphasis placed on particular
definitions and targets increase the probability that at any given time the
Federal Reserve will have available a definition of money whose behavior
captures its perception of the contemporaneous state of economic activity.
.for purposes of conducting monetary policy, it is never
safe to rely on just one concept of money. . . . (Bums 1973
p. 794)
.

.

I believe we need to measure and target a variety of aggregates
because, in a swiftly changing economic environment, any single
target can be misleading. (Volcker 1982 p. 751)
.in the final analysis, reality is too complicated to pick
Au; a single figure at this single point in time that can fully
capture the essence of money and will not behave somewhat differently than the numbers relative to economic activity. (Volcker
1980 p. 8)
.judgment about which target or targets are more significant
it'particular times, provide an element of, to me, appropriate
flexibility in the face of shifts in relationships of the aggregates to the economy. . . . (Volcker 1983b p. 614)

- 16 -

7.

The Role of Money after 1975
In the 197Os, the Fed resisted a direct role for money in monetary

policy.

Discussions within the Fed typically concentrated on why the Ml

demand function might plausibly be considered to be contemporaneously
unstable.

For example, when Ml was below its target range, discussions

usually centered on reasons why financial innovation might cause the Ml
demand function to shift leftward in an erratic fashion.

Such discussions,

by concentrating on the possibility of unpredictable shifts in money demand
and by ignoring the difficulties of associating values of the funds rate
with values of the expenditure of the public, built in the conclusion that
the Federal Reserve should target the funds rate.

The widespread aversion

to money supply targeting probably derives from the tacit assumption that
acceptance of money supply targeting implies acceptance of stability of the
public's money demand function. This stability implies a simple criterion
for assessing monetary policy - high rates of growth of money are inflationary.

Such a simple criterion would curtail the freedom of the Fed to

pursue policies balancing multiple , changing objectives and would, from the
perspective of the Fed , reduce its ability to maintain its independence.
In 1975, Congress, as part of the post-Watergate effort to increase
its influence, required the Fed to report to it on objectives for money
growth.

As the discussion in Woolley (1984 Chapter 7) makes clear, the

primary concern of Congress was over the behavior of interest rates.

Money

supply targeting represented a compromise among other legislative initiatives, probably made necessary by the impossibility of reaching a consensus
over what would constitute a desirable interest rate target.

Woolley (1984

p. 147) concludes, "Mainly, HCR 133 required the appearance of the Federal
Reserve Chairman at hearings at regular intervals.

This was an opportunity

- 17 -

for fruitful exchange; nothing more (italics in original).'

The Fed

opposed publicly-reported money supply targets.
.if the Federal Reserve's policies were to be focused
ioiely on the money supply. . .our financial system would be
placed in jeopardy. . . .Let us not lose sight of the fact that
the public's demand for currency, for demand deposits, for
savings deposits, and for a host of other liquid assets are
constantly changing. (Burns 1975 p. 153)
In order to understand the role played by money supply targets after
1975, it is useful to note that the requirement that the Fed balance
multiple goals creates a demand by the Fed for multiple instruments of
policy.

Typically,'the Fed attempts to implement policy with two kinds of

variables:

one variable directed at influencing directly the spending of

the public, the funds rate, and the other variable(s) directed at
influencing the public's perception of monetary policy, the discount rate,
public announcements, money supply targets, and again the funds rate
(Cukierman and Meltzer 1983).
After April 1975, the Federal Reserve used its money supply targets
primarily as a means of influencing the inflationary expectations of the
public.

The target range for growth of Ml was lowered periodically between

April 1975 and July 1977, despite the fact that over this same period the
actual growth of Ml rose to its cyclical highpoint after the trough of
early 1975. The target range for Ml was lowered in order to convey to the
public the message that the Fed's ultimate objective of price level stability would constrain its policy in a long run context, even though this
objective could not be constraining in a short-run context because of a
concern for the behavior of the real sector.
The formulation of monetary policy has retained a basic continuity
from the post-Accord period through the present.

The level of interest

rates in the money market is varied judgmentally, primarily in response to

- 18 -

the contemporaneous state of the economy.

Starting in 1975, however, the

language of interest rate targeting began to be abandoned in favor of the
language of monetary control. Use of the former language is felt by the
Fed to encourage the political system in the inappropriate belief that
interest rates can be manipulated either to achieve allocative ends or to
substitute for fiscal discipline.
Starting in 1975, the Fed began to use the language of intermediate
targeting, with the funds rate as the instrumental target, the money supply
as the intermediate target, and, say, GNP as the ultimate target.

After

Oct. 1979, in this description of policy, nonborrowed reserves replaced the
funds rate as the instrumental target.

Finally, after Oct. 1982, borrowed

reserves became the instrumental target.

This language allows the Fed to

avoid any reference to interest rate targets.

Unfortunately, it has also

created considerable confusion over the nature of monetary policy because
economists have often inferred the nature of policy from the language used
by the Fed.
8.

Summary and Conclusion
Monetary policy is characterized by

the judgmental variation of

policy variables, especially the funds rate, in response to the behavior of
the contemporaneous state of the economy.

The judgmental character of

' monetary policy is viewed by the Fed as allowing it to pursue desirable
goals while also endowing policy with the latitude necessary in order to
preserve the independence of the Fed.

The need to formulate monetary

policies capable of preserving its independence is believed by the Fed
typically to impose the requirement of balancing multiple goals among which
priorities change.

This requirement creates the demand for flexibility, an

absence of precommitment.

The desire not to specify in advance criteria

- 19 -

for determining the behavior of policy variables limits the willingness of
the Fed to constrain policy by long-run goals, to employ analytical
operating procedures, or to pursue money supply targeting.
Altering the character of monetary policy requires altering
institutional arrangements, rather than convincing the policy maker of the
truth of particular economic theories. The removal of Fed independence and
the assignment of the responsibility for monetary policy to Congress or the
Executive Branch, however, would not necessarily change the basic character
of mpnetary policy.

Monetary policy would probably still be characterized

by the ad hoc juggling of multiple, changing targets. An alteration of the
way in which monetary policy is formulated would require an explicit
mandate from Congress for a change.
The current mandate from Congress to the Fed is too general to possess
any significance.

Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act requires the Fed

"to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and
moderate long-term interest rates."

The "ranges of growth or diminution of

the monetary and credit aggregates" are to be set "taking account of past
and prospective developments in employment, unemployment, production,
investment, real income, productivity, international trade and payments,
and prices."

In the absence of a clearly defined Congressional mandate,

the effective mandate of the Fed is defined in an ongoing way by the
contemporaneous state of the economy.

It is the contemporaneous state of

the economy that determines the relative priorities among the variables the
Fed must juggle in order to preserve its independence.
Economists interested in influencing monetary policy often have
assumed that the character of monetary policy derives from a choice by
policy makers from among the ideas debated by macroeconomists. Influencing

- 20 -

policy becomes then an exercise in convincing policy makers of the cogency
of particular theoretical paradigms.

The political economy of monetary

policy, however, possesses little in common with the ideas constituting
macroeconomic debates.

Economists interested in influencing monetary

policy, it is contended here, need to pay increased attention to the design
of institutional arrangements.

- 21-‘

References
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Wash. DC:
BNnner,

65th Annual Report.

Board of Governors, 1978.

Karl and

Meltzer, Allan H.

the Free Reserve Concept.
--

The Federal Reserve's Attachment -to

House Committee on Banking and Currency,

Subcommittee on Domestic Finance.

Wash. DC:

Government Printing

Office, May 1964.
Burns, Arthur F. "Money Supply in the Conduct of Monetary Policy."
Reserve Bulletin 59 (Nov. 1973):
-.

Federal

791-798.

"Testimony before the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and
Urban Affairs."

Federal Reserve Bulletin 61 (March 1975):

150-155.

Cukierman, Alex and Meltzer, Allan H. "A Positive Theory of Credibility
under Discretionary Policy and Mandatory Announcements of Monetary
Targets."

Mimeographed.

Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon, Dec. 1983.

Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J. AMonetary
States.

History -of the United

Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press, 1963.

Guttentag, Jack M. "The Strategy of Open Market Operations." Q.J.E.

80

(Feb. 1966): l-30.
Hetzel, Robert L. "The Federal Reserve System and Control of the Money
Supply in the 1970s."

J. Money, Credit, and Banking 13 (Feb. 1981):

31-43.
-.

"The October 1979 Regime of Monetary Control and the Behavior of
the Money Supply in 1980." J. Money, Credit, and Banking 14 (May
1982): 234-251.

-.

"Monetary Policy in the Early 1980s." Working Paper.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, April 1984.

Richmond:

- 22 -

Kane, Edward J. "Politics and Fed Policymaking." -J. Monetary Econ. 6
(April 1980): 199-211.
"External Pressure and the Operations of the Fed."

-.

Economy of International andDomestic

In Political

Monetary Relations, edited by R.

Lombra and W. Witte. Ames, IA: Iowa State Univ. Press, 1982.
Lindblom, Charles E. "The Science of Muddling Through." Public
Administration Review 19 (1959): 79-86.
Lombra, Raymond E. and Moran, Michael. "Policy Advice and Policymaking at
the Federal Reserve."

In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series -on

Public Policy, vol. 5, edited by K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1980.
.

"Monetary Policy:

The Rhetoric vs. the Record.'

Business Cycle, edited by T. Willett.

Cambridge, MA:

In The Political
Ballinger,

forthcoming.
Mayer, Thomas.

"A Case Study of Federal Reserve Policymaking." -J. Monetary

Econ. 10 (Nov. 1982a): 259-271.
.

"Federal Reserve Policy in the 1972-1975 Recession: A Case Study of

Fed Behavior in a Quandary." In Crisis -in the Economic and Financial
Structure, edited by Paul Wachtel.

Lexington, MA: Lexington Books,

1982b.
Miller, G. William. "Statement before the House Committee on Banking,
Finance and Urban Affairs."

Federal Reserve Bulletin 64 (March 1978):

185-189.
Pierce, James L. "Making Reserves Targets Work."
Aggregates III.

In Controlling Monetary

Boston, MA: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1980.

Poole, William. "Macroeconomic Policy, 1971-1975: An Appraisal."
Rational Expectations &

In

Economic Policy, edited by Stanley Fischer.

Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press, 1980.

- 23 -

U.S. Congress, House Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs.
Conduct -of Monetary Policy.

Committee Print. Wash. DC:

Government

Printing Office, Feb. 10, 1982.
Volcker, Paul.

"Remarks before the National Press Club. Jan. 2."

Mimeographed.

Wash. DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

System, 1980.
-.

"Statement before the Joint Economic Committee." Federal Reserve
Bulletin 68 (Dec. 1982): 747-753.

-.

"Statement before the House Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban
Affairs."
.

Federal Reserve Bulletin 69 (Aug. 1983a): 601-609.

"Statement before the Subcommittee on Economic Policy of the Senate

Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs."

Federal Reserve

Bulletin 69 (Aug. 1983b): 613-617.
.

"Statement before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of

the House Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs." Federal
Reserve Bulletin 69 (Aug. 1983c): 617-621.
Warburton, Clark. "Monetary Difficulties and the Monetary System." -J.
Finance 7 (1952): 523-545.
Woolley, John T. Monetary Politics:
-of Monetary Policy.

The Federal Reserve -and the Politics

New York: Cambridge Univ. Press, 1984.