View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Forecasts of Inflation From Var Models

WP 94-08

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Roy H. Webb
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Working Paper 94-8

FORECASTS OF INFLATION FROM VAR MODELS
Roy H. Webb*

Federal

Research Department
Reserve Bank of Richmond
July 1994

This is a preprint of an article published in the Journal of Forecasting , vol. 14, May 1995, pp. 267-85.

*The author

is grateful

to James Lothian, Stephen McNees, Yash Mehra, Radha
referees for helpful comments.
The views and
opinions expressed
in this paper are solely those of the author and should
be attributed
to any other person or the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

Murthy, and two anonymous

not

FORECASTS

OF INFLATION

FROM

VAR MODELS

ABSTRACT
Why are forecasts of inflation from VAR models
forecasts

of

performance,

real

variables?

This

paper

Accounting

actions,

two

changes

of

that

relatively

a VAR model

poor

fitted to U.S.

Statistical work by other authors has found

that coefficients in such price equations
monetary

documents

and finds that the price equation

postwar data is poorly specified.

so much worse than their

in

may

not be constant.

monetary

policy

for those two shift5 yields significantly

more

Based on specific

regimes

are

proposed.

accurate forecasts and

lessens the evidence of misspecification.

Key words:
regimes.

Inflation forecasts, vector autoregressive

models, monetary policy

FORECASTS

OF INFLATION

Forecasts of real macroeconomic

FROM

VAR

MODELS

statistics for the United State5 have

been successfully produced by vector autoregressive

(VAR) models.

McNees

(1986), for example, compared a series of published forecasts produced in the
early 1980s by Robert Litterman's VAR model with forecasts made by conventional macroeconomic

forecasters.

McNees’s

comparisons showed Litterman's

forecasts to be more accurate than six competitors for real GNP growth and the
unemployment
ahead.

rate for forecasts varying in length from one to eight quarters

In addition, Webb (1991) compared simulated forecasts of business

cycle turning points generated by a VAR model adjusted by individually set lag
lengths (AVAR) with actual forecasts from three large forecasting services.
That study found little difference for one-quarter-ahead
superior performance

by the AVAR for four-quarter-ahead

forecasts but
forecasts.

VAR forecasts of inflation have been less successful relative to other
forecasts.

McNees's data shows that the average error of the series of

Litterman's

inflation forecasts was typically the worst of several that were

compared, with his errors often double those of the best forecaster.

Zarno-

wit2 and Braun (1991) also simulated VAR forecasts from a model with restrictions similar to Litterman's, which is often referred to as a BVAR model.

In

comparison with actual forecasts included in the National Bureau of Economic
Research-American

Statistical Association survey, they found "The BVAR

forecasts of [real GNP] perform relatively well . . . . but the BVAR forecasts of
... [the GNP implicit price deflator) are apparently much weaker."
fOreCaSt

Simulated

of inflation from models that are presented below are often less

accurate than simply predicting no change.
This paper attempts to diagnose the source of inaccurate inflation
forecasts and to suggest a direction for improvement.
performance of several models is first documented.
evidence of misspecification
from two models.

The relatively poor

In the next section

is presented for representative

Possible sources of misspecification

price equations

are next examined;

2
evidence is presented that the price equations' coefficient5
to two monetary policy

regime

changes.

are unstable due

A possible remedy is evaluated by

means of simulated forecasts.

RELATIVELY

POOR PERFORMANCE OF VAR INFLATION FORECASTS

VAR MODELS

A VAR model uses historical data to predict future values.
unrestricted

X=

VAR (WAR)

p + p(L)X+

where

X

is a

terms,

f3(L)

a

vector

kxl

An

model can be written

e

(1)
vector of variables,

kxl

u

is a

vector of constant

kxl

is a polynomial of degree m in the lag operator
of

error

terms.

(L), and

e

is

In practice, a k-variable model is often

simply k separate equations for which the coefficients can be estimated by
ordinary

least squares.

pt = PLp+ gg

P&L-,

The price equation in the WAR

considered below is

+ et

(2)

where p is the inflation rate, t indexes time, v indexes the particular
variable,

j indexes the lag number, and

pI, and the

fl,,@ are coefficients.

Note that even for a relatively small VAR model such as the one used in
this paper, with the number of variables k=5 and the lag length m=6, the price
equation contains 31 coefficients to be estimated.

It is often believed

desirable to limit the number of estimated coefficients.

As Doan put it,

"Forecasts made using unrestricted vector autoregressions

often suffer from

the overparameterization
forecast

errors.

n’

of the models ... [which] causes large out-of-sample

In addition, Hafet and Sheehan (1989) presented evidence

that led them to conclude that "relatively short-lagged
be

more

[VAR] models

accurate, on average, than longer-lagged specifications."

typically,
performance

[tend] to

More

Engle and Yoo (1987) have simply asserted that "The forecasting
of unrestricted

VARs has not been particularly good . ..."

3

In order to limit the number of estimated parameters, this paper's
strategy is to reduce many lag lengths in an adjusted VAP (AVAP) model.

For

each equation, set two lag lengths -- one for the dependent variable and
another for all independent variables -- in order to optimize
criterion.
Criterion

some

statistical

The particular criterion used in this paper is the Schwarz
(SC), which typically gives a parsimonious specification.'

It is

defined as

SC = T In a2 + Nln

T

(3)

where T is the number of observations, N is the number of estimated coefficients, and

a2

is the estimated residual variance.

By minimizing

the

Schwarz Criterion one is trading off the lower residual variance from adding
an additional coefficient against a penalty term that rises with the number of
estimated coefficients.

The strategy for selecting lag lengths in this paper

is to (1) specify a maximum lag length; (2) assume that all independent
variables

in each equation have the same lag length; and (3) compute the

Schwarz value for all possible lag length combinations.
lengths for several variants of
the Appendix.

a

basic

five

variable

The resulting lag

model are presented in

Of special interest is the price equation for the AVAP model,

which is

PC=Pp+g bP% +c, g b,J”,t-j + Et

(4)

where the number of lags m, of the dependent variable is three and the number
of lags q of each independent variable is one.
Forecast error statistics from representative VAR models are presented
in Tables 1 and 2; a detailed account of the models' construction
used is given in the Appendix.
five U.S.

time

series:

base, the manufacturing
bill

rate.

real

and the data

Unless otherwise noted, each model contains

GNP, the GNP implicit price deflator, the monetary

capacity utilization rate, and the go-day Treasury-

Two models illustrate the basic result of relatively poor infla-

4
tion forecasts.

The model labeled AVAB is identical to one described in Webb

(19851, except that the lag lengths are set by the simpler procedure described
above.

The model labeled BVAB uses Bayesian "priors" that have been advocated

by Litterman

(1984) to effectively

limit the model's number of parameters that

need to be estimated.

FORECASTING

PROCEDURE

A rolling regression procedure was used to simulate forecasts to compare
with data actually observed through 1990 Q4.

Coefficients

in each model were

first estimated based on actual data from 1952 Q2 to 1977 Ql; one-quarterahead forecasts were made for each variable, which were then used to prepare
forecasts for the next quarter, and

50

forth up to eight quarters ahead.3

Each model's coefficients were then reestimated based on data from 1952 Q2 to
1977 Q2, and forecasts were again produced for each variable up to eight
quarters ahead.
accordingly

The procedure was repeated through 1990 Q3.

100 observations

quarter-ahead

There were

on which the first estimate was based, 55 one-

forecasts, and 48 eight-quarter-ahead

forecasts.

Each forecast

was compared with actual values and error statistics were calculated.
error is simply the actual value minus the predicted value.

An

The square root

of the mean squared error (RMSE) was then calculated for all available
forecasts.
Exhibit 1 {place here} contains BMSE values for the levels of the
interest rate and percentage changes of real GNP and the implicit deflator.
For the latter two variables the columns labeled "Single Quarter
were derived from percentage

Forecasts”

changes from the preceding quarter stated as a

compound annual rate; the column labeled "Cumulative Forecasts" was derived
from the percentage

change over four quarters.

The forecast horizon is the

number of quarters beyond the latest data that were used to estimate the
coefficients

for the model.

Thus for a one-quarter-ahead

forecast for 1977

Q2, only data referring to 1977 Ql and previous quarters would be used; that

5

same data would also produce a two-quarter-ahead

forecast for 1977 Q3, and so

forth.
RMSEs are useful for giving a quick view of model accuracy.

Another way

to view the same data is presented with Theil U statistics in Exhibit 2.
{Place here} Those values simply represent the ratio of the RMSE described
above to the RMSE of a forecast of no change from the previous period.
with RMSEs,

smaller

U values represent

more

As

accurate forecasts; in addition,

values greater than 1.0 indicate a forecast of little value under most loss
functions.

BASIC

RESULTS

The U Statistics in Exhibit 2 confirm that the inflation forecasts from
the AVAR model are relatively inaccurate.

While forecast5 of the T-bill rate

are similar or slightly worse than a no-change forecast, real GNP forecasts
are substantially better.
worse.

Inflation forecasts, however, are substantially

The BVAR model embodies a substantially different strategy for

reducing a VAR model's parameterization.

While its inflation forecasts are

more accurate than the AVAP model, its single-quarter inflation forecasts are
either worse than or not significantly better than a no-change forecast at
each horizon.4
change forecast.

Its cumulative inflation forecast is much better than a noThe BVAR is less accurate than the AVAR, however, for GNP

and interest rate forecasts.5
A more formal comparison of model and no-change forecasts can

be

made by

testing the hypothesis that a series of forecast errors from a model is not
significantly different from the series of errors that would result from a nochange forecast.

Diebold and Mariano

(1991) have proposed such a test that

has several desirable properties; perhaps
valid even if the two

series

most

important for this paper, it is

of forecast errors are contemporaneously

lated or if either series has significant autocorrelation.

corre-

The DM test

statistic is calculated from autocovariances of the difference in squared
errors6 from two forecasts, and is asymptotically normally distributed.

6
For

each model listed in Exhibits 1 and 2, the inflation forecasts at

each horizon were compared with no-change forecasts.

DM statistics were

calculated and are presented in Exhibit 3 {place here}; negative values
indicate that the average squared error from the model was larger than the
squared error of a no-change ,forecast.

For the AVAE model, inflation fore-

casts at each horizon were significantly worse than the no-change forecasts.
For the BVAE, forecasts one quarter ahead were also significantly worse than
the no-change

forecast, but were not significantly different at two, three,

and four quarter horizons. The four-quarter cumulative forecast was significantly more accurate than the no-change comparison.
There are many possible explanations
few can be examined in a single article.

for the poor performance;
Any small macroeconomic

only a

model omits

variables that could be important, and there is certainly a long list of
omitted variables that might affect prices.

While examination of potential

additions will be left for future research, poor choices may have been made in
choosing the five variables included in the model.

To examine that possibili-

ty, two additional models were used to produce simulated fOreCastS.
labeled AVAB-M2,
The rationale

substitutes the M2 monetary aggregate for the monetary base.

is that many researchers have documented a relationship

M2 and prices.'

One,

Another,

between

labeled AVAR-CPI, substitutes the Consumer Price

Index for the GNP implicit price deflator, on the grounds that movements

in

the deflator reflect not only price changes but also changes in the relative
quantities of goods produced.
lengthy intervals and is a

ClOBer

In contrast, the CPI has fixed weights for
approximation to the type of price index

most analysts would prefer.
As indicated in Exhibit 1, substituting M2 for the monetary base failed
to

improve inflation forecasts and also produced less accurate forecasts for

other variables.
significantly

At each forecasting horizon the inflation forecasts were

worse than the no-change comparison.

The results from substituting the CPI for the implicit deflator are
slightly better.

The U statistic for the inflation term fell below unity at

7
the shorter horizons in the table, as well as for the four-quarter
forecast.

cumulative

The GNP and interest rate forecasts were slightly worse than in the

original model.
A final variation is to simulate forecasts from a six-lag WAR

as a

check on the conventional wisdom that substantially reducing the number of
estimated coefficients will normally improve the accuracy of VAR forecasts.
The results for prices were surprisingly accurate (to the author, at least);
these results should not have been too surprising, however, in light of
Lupoletti and Webb (1986), who found simulated WAR

inflation forecasts at all

but a one-quarter horizon to be competitive with those from major forecasting
services.
Attempting to isolate the reason for the WAR
a hybrid model was simulated.
rates are highly persistent,

model's greater accuracy,

The intuition here is that since inflation
long lags might be especially useful.

The AVAR

specification was adopted for every equation except the price equation, and
the Unrestricted

six-lag version was used for prices.

roughly between the AVAR and WAR

in forecast accuracy.

was then simulated, using unrestricted
the monetary base.

The results were
Another hybrid model

lags in the equations for prices and

The results are shown in the table, labeled A/WAR.

This

model produced the most accurate longer-term inflation forecasts, with little
penalty for other variables.
The main result of this section is that the VAR models generated price
forecasts that, for most horizons, were significantly worse than simply
predicting no change.

In order to isolate potential problems, the price

equation from the AVAR and A/WAR

models is examined more closely below.

SPECIFICATION TESTS FOR PRICE EQUATIONS
The price equations from two VAR models will be examined more closely in
this section.

Equation

(5) is from the AVAR model with shorter lag lengths,

and the other is equation
reprinted below.

(6) with longer lag lengths.

Both equations are

8

Pt = b + k$
v-1

01

Pj,GG,,-j + et

Residuals

from both equations were first tested for serial correlation.

The specific test' is a Lagrange multiplier test that takes into account the
presence of lagged values of the dependent variable and little prior knowledge
of the exact form of serial correlation.

The procedure is to first estimate

the price equation and its residuals and then add
residuals to the equation before reestimating

it.

m

lagged values of the
An F test on the signifi-

cance of the lagged values is asymptotically valid for a null hypothesis of no
serial correlation

and an alternative hypothesis of either

AR(m)

or

MA(m)

errors.

As the first line in Exhibit 4 {place here) indicates, the null hypothesis of no serial correlation
For equation

is rejected for equation

(6) with unrestricted

when the alternative

(5) with short lags.

lags, the null hypothesis

is not rejected

is first order correlation, an unsurprising

six lagged values included in the equation.
fifth order autocorrelation,

With an alternative hypothesis of

however, the null hypothesis can be rejected.

The next test, for autoregressive

conditional hetereoskedasticity

(ARCH) I is also a two-step procedure; the first step
price equation and its residuals.

is

also to estimate the

The second step is to regress the squared

residual on a constant term and m lags of the squared residual.
observations

times

the R2

statistic

is chi-squared with

under the null hypothesis of no ARCH.
equation

(5) with

m=l,

log-level price
was accepted.

series,

m

The number of

degrees of freedom

The null hypothesis is rejected for

and is also rejected for equation

A final test is whether it is appropriate
in first differences.

result with

to

estimate

(6) with

m=5.

the price equation

A standard Dickey-Fuller test was used to examine the
and the null hypothesis of the presence of a unit root

Similar test results for the series of first differences were

9

ambiguous, however.

shown in Exhibit 4, either acceptance or rejection of

As

the null hypothesis could occur, depending on the lag length of the differenced inflation rates.g

Since there is no conclusive reason a priori to

prefer one lag length to another, the choice of working with first or second
differences of the price data is a close call.

Since overdifferencing

risks

losing information that could be useful in forecasting, the basic models in
this paper use the first difference of the implicit deflator.

FORECAST PERFORMANCE WITH MODIFIED MODELS
STATIONARITY

AND POSSIBLE

COINTEGRATION

The VAR models discussed above contained three variables in differences:
the price level, the monetary base, and real GNP.

Formal tests for stationar-

ity have already been discussed for the price series.

Dickey-Fuller

also failed to reject the null hypothesis of nonstationarity

tests

for the monetary

base, real GNP, and the interest rate, but did reject the null when data were
differenced one time.

The capacity utilization rate, which is stationary by

construction, was not tested.
ARE THE VARIABLES COINTEGRATED?

It is also possible that the

equations in differences may be misspecified
of those variables that is stationary.
the variables

if there is a linear combination

It is especially important to check

in this model since (1) other authors, for example Mehra (1991),

have found that closely related series are cointegrated, and (2) theory
suggests that the variables could be related by the quantity equation with
interest-sensitive

velocity and a money-multiplier

monetary base and the money supply.

relation between the

If cointegration were to be found, then

the use of an error correcting model might well improve forecast accuracy.
A cointegrating

equation was therefore used to estimate the parameters

of such a linear combination.
found to be nonstationary,
A cointegrating

If the residuals from that equation are not

the hypothesis of cointegration

can be accepted."

equation for the four nonstationary variables was therefore

estimated, and the results are displayed in Exhibit 4.

An augmented Dickey-

10

Fuller test was used to test the null hypothesis that the residuals were
nonstationary,

which would imply that the series are not cointegrated.

While

the test result could possibly be affected by the lag length m, the value
shown in the table is the one that maximizes the

?

statistic, and is also

the shortest lag length for which the Ljung-Box Q statistic does not indicate
significant

serial correlation.

The failure to reject the null hypothesis is

consistent with no cointegration.
SHOULD_THE?

At this point it is useful

to question the economic significance of the finding that the interest rate is
nonstationary.

It is well known that the Dickey-Fuller

test is not powerful

against a highly persistent alternative, such as a root of 0.98.

And there is

a reason that one would expect the interest rate series to be highly persistent.

Goodfriend

(1991) discusses theoretical and empirical work on central

bank smoothing of nominal interest rates -- that is, daily changes in reserve
supply that keep the federal funds rate within a narrow band that is only
changed infrequently.

Such smoothing could impart a high degree of persis-

tence to even a quarterly average of a daily rate, as is used in this paper.
It may therefore be appropriate to treat the interest rate as stationary, as was done in the models presented earlier.

A regression with the

interest rate in levels would not be spurious, and differencing
valuable information.

could lose

But if that assumption were wrong and the interest rate

were actually a random walk, the regression in levels would be spurious and
differencing

would be appropriate.

In order to empirically examine which specification
lag lengths were reset

in the A/WAR

is more appropriate,

model with the interest rates in differ-

ences; series of forecasts were then generated.

The somewhat ambiguous

results are shown in Exhibit 5 for the model labeled A/WAF+l?D.

The interest

rate forecasts from the latter model were slightly more accurate, but forecasts of GNP growth and inflation were less accurate.

Those results are

consistent with the notion that the information 1055 from differencing may be
large enough to justify entering the interest rate in level form.

11
ANOTHER POSSIBILITY OF COINTEGRATION:

Admitting the possibility

the interest rate and inflation series are nonstationary,

that

could there be a

stable "real" rate, that is, the nominal rate minus the quarterly inflation
rate?ll

To test this possibility,

it is not necessary to estimate a cointe-

grating equation since the coefficients are known to be one and minus one.
real rate series was therefore constructed; a Dickey-Fuller

A

test, presented in

Exhibit 4, rejects the null hypothesis of the presence of a unit root.
Given the stationary combination of two arguably nonstationary

series,

the next step is to construct a vector error correcting version of the A/WAR
model (VECM).

The strategy used here was to difference the nominal rate and

inflation series, and add the first lag of the constructed real rate series to
each equation.

Aapt = IQ, +

kg
v=l

The resulting price equation is

Pj,A,t-j

+ y==t-1

+

‘lt

(7)

=l

where p is the log of the implicit deflator, rr is the error correcting

term,

that is the nominal rate minus the inflation rate, and the variables in X are
altered to include the first differences of the interest rate and inflation
rate.

Lag lengths were reset to minimize the Schwarz Criterion.

were then generated, with summary statistics given in Exhibit 5.
tion values indicate that the VECM
A/WAR

model.

Forecasts
The infla-

forecasts are much worse than the standard

It appears that the information lost from differencing the

inflation series was substantial, while the value of including the level of
the real rate was not large.
One final check of possible cointegration was made using the multivariate test proposed by Watson

(1992).

In this test the null hypothesis is the

existence of one cointegrating vector, the real interest rate; the alternative
is the existence of an additional cointegrating vector.
\

The test is a

likelihood ratio, and in this case involves comparing the largest eigenvalue
of a matrix computed from the appropriate VECM with critical values that were

12
computed from the statistics' asymptotic chi-squared distributions.

In this

case, the largest eigenvalue was 9.7, well below the critical value of 20.4
that would indicate rejection of the null hypothesis at the 10% level.

This

failure to reject the null is consistent with the results of the univariate
tests above, and does not indicate that further analysis of possible cointegration would prove useful.
In short, reconsidering
cointegration

the stationarity of the variables and possible

did not indicate a direction for improving the accuracy of

inflation forecasts from the VAB models examined here.
POSSIBLE

REGIME

CHANGES

It is common to think of nonstationary behavior of an economic variable
by analogy to a random walk with frequent small, permanent disturbances.
Indeed, widely used statistical tests for nonstationarity

are derived under

the assumption of such a random walk as the null hypothesis.
nonstationarity

are also possible, however.

Other types of

An alternative that is pursued in

this section involves large, infrequent shocks.

Several authors have found

that U.S. postwar inflation data appear to have been generated by a process
with one or more discrete shifts.
Evans and Wachtel

(1993) proposed a two-state Markov switching process

for the CPI, and found that it explained

some of the puzzles that are raised

by the ex post bias often found in series of inflationary anticipations.
Boschen and Talbot

(1991) found evidence of unstable coefficients

in regres-

sions of inflation on several variables, notably including the growth of the
monetary base, growth of real GNP, and the differenced T-bill rate.

Balke and

Fomby (1991) studied the GNP deflator from 1870 to 1988 and found four "level
shifts" to the inflation rate; the two in postwar data were in 1968 and in
1983.12
The last finding provides statistical evidence that something important
that affects inflation changed around the mid 1960s and early 1980s.

An

obvious possibility

I find

is that something about monetary policy changed.

it plausible that (1) the President and Congress chose to tolerate higher

13
inflation during the Viet Nam buildup for a variety of reasons, including
raising revenues via 'bracket creep' and the personal income tax;13 (2) as
long as this consensus held, monetary policy had an inflationary bias;14 (3)
this consensus was destroyed by the early 1980s;15 and (4) monetary policy
then included low inflation as an important goal.

It is therefore possible to

view monetary policy as making a discrete move toward more inflation at some
point in the middle of the 19605, with the monetary effects on prices becoming
apparent by 1968; a discrete move toward disinflation occurred somewhat later
and the inflation effects became apparent by 1983.
DATING REGIME CHANGES:
moves?

What were the exact dates of these discrete

The strategy here will be to look for specific actions that do not fit

the pattern of the Fed's usual behavior.

It is possible to loosely character-

ize monetary policy since the Federal Reserve - Treasury Accord in 1951 as
"leaning against the wind.'

That is, the Fed's day-to-day actions involved

open market operations that varied the quantity of bank reserves in'order to
keep the federal funds rate within a narrow band.

The funds rate band, in

turn, was set in order to respond to pressing economic conditions.

This often

involved raising the funds rate when inflation was rising and unemployment
relatively

low, and lowering the funds rate when inflation was low and real

growth weak.
slow

In addition, there were times during which unusually rapid or

money growth would bolster the case for changing the funds rate target.
The Fed departed from that strategy in the 1960s; the background account

in this paragraph
substantially

is taken from Kettl (1986).

In 1965 President Johnson

increased military action in Viet Nam, proposed domestic social

legislation requiring increased spending, but resisted increasing nominal
interest rates.

In June 1965 the Fed's chairman William McChesney Martin

learned that the Viet Nam buildup was larger than the administration
publicly admitting.

was

In October Martin wrote to the President arguing for an

immediate increase in interest rates.

On December 5 the Fed raised the

discount rate by 50 basis points, and 'Johnson was furious.
advisers believed that the decision was precipitous

. ...

He and his

The President saw

14

The President

the discount rate increase as a personally vindictive act."16

and the Chairman met at the President's ranch in Texas later that month.
In 1966 real growth was a rapid 6.0 percent, the unemployment

rate was a

very low 3.7 percent, and the inflation rate (the change in the annual average
CPI) rose from 1.6 in 1965 to 2.9 percent.

A consistent application of

leaning against the wind would have required increasing the funds rate until
inflation was clearly checked.

Although interest rates rose during the first

part of the year, in the fourth quarter "Monetary policy promptly moved to
relax the degree of reserve restraint.""

The inflation rate was 3.1 percent

in 1967, 4.2 percent in 1968, and 5.5 percent in 1969.
departure

Here is a clear

from the previous leaning against the wind strategy, namely lowering

interest rates, beginning in the fourth quarter of 1966, while inflation was
rising and unemployment

low.

The fourth quarter of 1966 was therefore the end of a low inflation
period.
enemy

By the end of the 1970s inflation was being described as "public

number

one."

That sentiment did not translate immediately into presi-

dential support for a substantial change in monetary policy.

In the lead

paragraph of his 1980 Economic Report to Congress, President Carter asserted
that higher oil prices were the

major

reason for rising inflation in 1979. In

that twelve page statement, there are only two sentences that mention monetary
policy.

The most relevant is, "Monetary policy will have to continue

in support of the same anti-inflationary

goals.111E [Emphasis mine]

firmly
In

January 1981 the political party controlling the Presidency and the Senate
changed.

The discussion of monetary policy also changed substantially.

example, in the first annual report of the Reagan Administration's
Economic Advisers
essentially

(1982), one encounters the following phrases:

Council of
"Inflation is

a monetary phenomenon." p.75; "The appropriate policy for reducing

the inflation rate is a decrease in the rate of money growth." p.76; "The
Administration
reduction

For

expects that the Federal Reserve will achieve an orderly

in the trend of money growth to a noninflationary

[Emphasis mine].

rate." p.64

15
Monetary growth was high and
example,

Ml

variable

in the 1970s and also in 1980; for

grew at a 16 percent annual rate between May and November of 1980.

In 1981, however, "growth in Ml-B adjusted for shifts into NOW accounts was
about 2 l/4 percent -- 1 l/4 percentage points below the lower end of its
targeted range.""

That behavior of the main intermediate target of Fed

policy, shift-adjusted Ml-B, was substantially different from what had been
seen in the past decade.
Turning to specific actions, in the first quarter of 1981 the unemployment rate was 7.4 percent, compared to an average 7.0 percent in 1980 and 5.8
percent in 1979.

The trend in real activity was difficult to interpret in

light of the monetary volatility in the last year as well as the imposition
and removal of credit controls in 1980.
shift-adjusted

During the second quarter of 1981

Ml-B was at or below the lower bound of the target range that

the Fed had announced in February.

Yet the federal funds rate rose by five

full percentage points from April 1 to July 8.20 Here is an extraordinary
departure from previous behavior; the second quarter of 1981

is

therefore the

last of the inflationary period.21
ECONOMETRIC

RESULTS:

Based on the evidence discussed above, three

periods are studied: an early low inflation period from 1952 Q2 to 1966 44; a
middle inflationary period from 1967 Ql to 1981 42; and a disinflationary
period from 1981 Q3 to 1990 44.

Separate regressions were run for each

subperiod and the entire sample; the results are displayed in Exhibit 6.
Perhaps most striking is the complete failure of the restricted equation
for the early period, with essentially no explanatory power from its regressors.

Regressions

for the middle and late periods appear to work somewhat

better, at least as indicated by the usual summary statistics.

For the whole

period the sum of the coefficients on nominal variables, that is lagged
prices, the interest rate, and the monetary base, is approximately unity.
the middle period, however, it

is

In

1.26 while in the late period it is 0.80.

The sum of coefficients on lagged prices rises substantially

in the two later

periods; the strong persistence of inflation is not evident in the early

16
period.

The coefficient on the monetary base is significantly different from

zero only in the middle period.
These statistical results are consistent with the story of monetary
regime changes.22
regimes.

There are several options when forecasting under changing

Perhaps the simplest is to use a few dummy variables to allow some

coefficients to abruptly shift.
O-l dummies were constructed
Dl, respectively.

Based on the results summarized in Exhibit 6,

for the middle and late periods, labeled Dm and

In addition, the product of Dm and the monetary base is

labeled Db, and the product of the implicit deflator and sum of Dm and Dl is
labeled Dp.
equation

Dm, Dl, and one lagged value each of Db and Dp were added to

(5), with the results also displayed in Exhibit 6. {place here) As

might be expected, the apparent fit of the equation improved and the four
dummy variables were each significant at conventional
Diagnostic

levels.

tests were again repeated and are displayed in Exhibit 6.

The F test for serial correlation was repeated on the price equation for the
entire sample.

In contrast to the results presented in Exhibit 4, the null

hypothesis of no serial correlation is not rejected at conventional

levels.

The test statistic for ARCH is also presented, and the hypothesis of no ARCH
is again rejected at the one percent level.
statistics

were

constructed

Finally, Dickey-Fuller

test

for the inflation rate over the three intervals.

In the early and middle periods the null hypothesis of a unit root is rejected
at the one percent level.

For the late period, the null is rejected at either

the five or ten percent level, again depending on a lag length used in the
test.

Adding the dummy variables to the price equation of the AVAB model
substantially

improved its forecasting performance,

The modified AVAB model has by far the

most

as shown in Exhibit 5.

accurate inflation forecasts at

each horizon of any of the models considered in the paper, with the GNP
forecasts remaining as accurate as any of the models considered.
same dummy variables to the A/WAR

Adding the

model slightly improved its inflation

17
forecasts, although the AVAR-D model remained significantly

more

accurate.

Neither model forecasts the interest rate well.
To put these figures in perspective, consider the root-mean-square
errors of the ASA-NBER inflation forecasts from 1968 to 1990, taken from
Zarnowitz and Braun, Table 5.
forecasts for the same period.

The AVAR-D model was used to produce simulated
One-quarter-ahead

forecasts from the VAR model

were less accurate, with an RMSE of 1.48 percent versus 1.00 percent.

Four-

quarter cumulative forecasts from the VAR model were much more accurate, with
an RMSE of 0.88 percent versus 1.92 percent.
VAR's performance

If taken at face value, the

is competitive with actual forecasters of inflation over

that interval. The major reason not to take the results at face value is the
amount of experimentation

that was used to construct the AVAR-D model.

In

addition, the model had the benefit of using revisions of GNP and implicit
deflator data that were unavailable to the real-time forecasters.

CONCLUSION
Several small VAR models have been examined in this paper, with particular emphasis on inflation forecasts and the inflation equation of the models.
Two models are of particular interest.
stricted lags in two equations.

One has unfashionably

long, unre-

The other uses dummy variables to represent

the political decision made in the 1960s to allow higher rates of inflation
and the subsequent decision made in the early 1980s to lower the inflation
rate.
The latter model produced the most accurate inflation forecasts of the
models examined while its GNP forecasts retained their accuracy.

That result

suggests a resolution to the puzzle of relatively inaccurate inflation
forecasts from VAR models; two monetary policy regime changes led to inaccurate inflation forecasts from models with constant coefficients.

Moreover,

either adding dummy variables or dividing the entire sample into three
subperiods also removed serial correlation from the residuals of the price
equation.

18
These results may be of interest to several groups.

To anyone inter-

ested in price behavior, the improved performance of the price equation after
an adjustment for temporal instability points out a danger of using constant
coefficients

over most of the postwar period.

the finding that long, unrestricted

To users of small macro models,

lags led to an equation that worked well

relative to a highly restricted equation

suggests that long, unrestricted

lengths should not be rejected out of hand.

Students of monetary policy may

find the dating of regime changes of interest.
nonstationarity

lag

The finding that possible

of the inflation rate over the postwar period is not apparent

in the three subperiods of consistent monetary policy may be of interest to
empirical macroeconomists
contexts.

concerned about potential nonstationarity

in other

Finally, if one wishes to forecast inflation, using the admittedly

ad hoc dummy variables may be preferable to ignoring the monetary regime
changes altogether.
Several directions

for future research are also evident.

First, do the

results that are presented above overstate the probable accuracy of current
inflation forecasts, due to too much experimentation?

Of course, new data

over time will reveal whether the post-sample performance of these models is
in line with those results.

Also, despite the experimentation

a basic stability in the model structure.

there has been

Since 1984 the author has published

results from VAR models with the same variables, with the same starting date
for regressions,

and with the same choices for differencing.23

Changes have

been limited to different lag lengths and the addition of the dummy variables
for the two shifts in monetary policy.
This paper views monetary policy changes as being responsible
persistent
fied.

shifts in the inflation process that several authors have identi-

Are there other candidates such as energy

plausible?

for large,

prices that are equally

And if the monetary policy explanation

suggested dates of regime change robust?

is accepted, are the

One approach would be to estimate a

structural relation between instruments and goals of monetary policy and

19
examine its stability in the neighborhood of the dates of the suggested
changes.
Residuals

from the best performing price equation still displayed ARCH,

and that specification

failed to explain inflation during the early subperiod.

It is therefore apparent that this model, like many other small

macro

models,

might benefit from additional variables that help predict inflation rates.
The challenge will be to narrow the field, given the large number of variables
that analysts have used with apparent success in price equations in the past.

20

APPENDIX:

TEE DATA AND MODELS

The following data series, with
used in this paper:

Citibase

mnemonic in parentheses,

were

P, the implicit price deflator for gross national product

(GD); Y, real gross national product (GNP82); M, the monetary base as estimated by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (FMBASE); CU, the capacity
utilization

rate in manufacturing

three month treasury bills (FYGM3);
urban consumers

(IPXMCA); R, the secondary market yield on
CPI, the consumer price index for all

(PUNEW), and the M2 monetary aggregate after 1959 (FM2).

All

except the interest rate were seasonally adjusted by the agency compiling the
data.

Natural logarithms were taken of each data series except the interest

rate and the capacity utilization rate.
maintained

by Citibase on July 19, 1991.

Robert Hetzel; see Hetzel
The table
collection

below

Data were the latest revisions
Pre-1959

M2

data were obtained from

(1989) for further information on its construction.

describes each model in the paper.

of equations that are individually described.

DEP VAR contains the dependent variable for each eguation.

Each model is a
The column labeled
The column labeled

DIFF? contains a Y for differenced series, N for levels, and 2 for a series
differenced

twice.

The number of lagged terms for the dependent variable and

the common lag length for all the independent variables are given in the next
two columns.
as described

The final column notes if an equation contained dummy variables
in the final section, or RR, the difference between the nominal

interest rate and the inflation rate; a constant term was also included in
each equation.

21
Model Descriptions
MODEL

DEP VAR

DIFF?

# OWN LAGS

# LAGS OF IND VARS

A/WAR

P
Y
t4
C
R

A/WAR-D

P
Y

6

6

1

1

M

6
2
6

6

C
R
A/WAR-RD

P
Y
M
C
R

AVAR

P
Y
M
C
R

AVAR-CPI

OTHER TERMS

Y
Y
Y
N
N

4. 4 d, %

CPI
Y
M

C
R
AVAR-D

P
Y

d, d, d, 4

M

C
R
AVAR-M2

P
Y
M2

C
R
BVAR"

P
Y
M

C
R
VECM

P
Y
M

C
R

RR
RR
RR
RR
RR

22
EXHIBIT 1
Forecast Error Statistics from Several VAR Models
Root Mean Square Errors

Model

Variable

Single Quarter Forecasts
Horizon: IQ
4Q
x2

Cumulative Forecasts
As2

AVAR
IPD
GNP
RTB

1.57
3.40
1.20

1.92
3.07
1.95

2.62
3.50
2.44

1.84
1.58

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.58
3.81
1.24

1.59
3.75
2.03

1.79
4.21
2.69

1.11
1.92

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.86
3.75
1.26

2.32
3.41
2.05

3.17
3.84
2.60

2.30
2.15

CPI
GNP
RTB

1.91
3.40
1.24

2.56
3.24
2.04

3.22
3.58
2.60

2.16
1.80

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.69
3.40
1.20

1.64
3.09
1.97

1.73
3.60
2.50

1.11
1.60

BVAR

AVAR-M2

AVAR-CPI

A/WAR

Note : Model construction and data sources are described in detail in the
Appendix.
Variable abbreviations'include the quarterly average level of RTB,
the go-day Treasury-bill rate, and annualized rates of change from the
previous quarter of GNP, real gross national product; IPD, the GNP implicit
price deflator; and CPI, the consumer price index. The numerical entries are
root-mean-squared error statistics described in the text, covering synthetic
forecasts from 1977 Q2 to 1990 43.

23
EXHIBIT 2
Forecast Error Statistics from Several VAR Models
Theil U Statistics
Model

Variable

Single Quarter Forecasts
Horizon: u
22

Cumulative Forecasts
AC2

AVAR
IPD
GNP
RTB

1.05
0.75
1.00

1.22
0.63
1.08

1.44
0.66
1.04

1.40
0.47

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.06
0.84
1.03

1.01
0.77
1.12

0.98
0.80
1.15

0.85
0.58

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.25
0.83
1.05

1.46
0.70
1.13

1.74
0.73
1.11

1.74
0.65

CPI
GNP
RTB

0.85
0.75
1.03

0.92
0.66
1.13

1.02
0.68
1.11

0.96
0.54

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.13
0.75
1.00

1.04
0.63
1.09

0.95
0.68
1.06

0.84
0.48

BVAR

AVAR-M2

AVAR-CPI

A/WAR

Note: Model construction and data sources are described in detail in the
Appendix.
Variable abbreviations include the quarterly average level of RTB,
the go-day Treasury-bill rate, and annualized rates of change from the
previous quarter of GNP, real gross national product; IPD, the GNP implicit
price deflator; and CPI, the consumer price index. The numerical entries are
Theil U statistics described in the text, covering synthetic forecasts from
1977 Q2 to 1990 43.

24
EXHIBIT 3
VAR Inflation Forecasts Compared to No-Change Forecasts

Model

Variable

Single Quarter Forecasts
Horizon: u
2sL

!?Q

Cumulative Forecasts
!a

AVAR
U Statistic
DM Statistic
Significance,

%

1.05
-3.7
eo.1

1.22
-11.7
CO.1

1.44
-11.6
co.1

1.40
-5.2
co.1

%

1.06
-3.2
0.1

1.01
-0.2
>lO

0.98
0.63
>lO

0.85
2.4
1.7

%

1.25
-12.8
co.1

1.46
-18.0
<O.l

1.74
-10.0
co.1

1.74
-4.9
CO.1

%

0.85
14.5
co.1

0.92
7.3
<O.l

1.02
-1.0
>lO

0.96
0.9
>lO

1.13
-6.1
co.1

1.04
-1.2
>lO

0.95
1.6
>lO

0.84
2.2
2.9

BVAR
U Statistic
DM Statistic
Significance,
AVAR-M2
U Statistic
DM Statistic
Significance,
AVAR-CPI
U Statistic
DM Statistic
Significance,
A/WAR

U Statistic
DM Statistic
Significance,

%

:
Model construction and data sources are described in detail in the
Appendix.
Synthetic forecasts inflation from 1977 42 to 1990 44 are compared
with no-change forecasts.
The U Statistic ie the ratio the root-mean-squared
The DM statistic
error of the model forecast to that of a no-change forecast.
tests the null hypothesis that the model and no-change forecast have equal
accuracy; negative values indicate that the sum of squared forecast errors is
larger for the model forecast.
Note

25
EXHIBIT 4
Specification Tests for Price Equations

Equation

(5)

pc = pP +

Serial correlation test:
ARCH test:

Equation

x2 (1)

F(1,145) = 3.93;

Serial correlation test:
ARCH test:

Dickey-Fuller

x2(5)

level = .049.

= 5.13; Significance level = .024.

pt = cr,+ ej?
GL-j
v-1 -1

(6)

Significance

+ et

F(5,114) = 2.48;

Significance

level = .036.

= 14.64; Significance level = .012.

test for a unit root

Z, = p + m P,A= t-j; P&-l + et
F-1
e,tp=11 = 0.80; 10% sig. level = -2.58;

Price Level

( Z, = P, ): m=2;

Differences

( Z, = AP, ): m=l;

9,(p=l) = -3.42; 5% sig. level = -2.89;

Differences

( Z, = AP, ): m=5;

$,(p=l) = -2.06.

"Real" Rate ( Z, = Rt- (pt-ptel) ): m=2 ;

Cointegrating

equation

Q,(p=l)

=

14.1.

P, = 1.29 + .83&l,- .15Y, + .016R, + I?,

Augmented Dickey-Fuller

test on residuals from cointegrating

AQ, = -XI?,-,
+ * PjAQt-j
F-1
t

(x=0)

= 3.12;

Note: This significance

10% level = 3.89
level is from Engle and Yoo (1987).

equation:

26
EXHIBIT 5
Forecast Error Statistics from Several Models
Theil U Statistics
Model

Variable

Single Quarter Forecasts
Horizon: lJJ
!T!Q
22

Cumulative Forecasts
22

A/WAR
IPD
GNP
RTB

1.13
0.75
1.00

0.95
0.68
1.06

1.06
0.65
1.03

0.84
0.48

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.19
0.81
0.98

1.02
0.75
0.98

0.98
0.61
1.03

0.94
0.69

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.30
0.80
0.95

1.55
0.73
1.08

2.09
0.61
1.20

1.49
0.71

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.16
0.75
1.00

0.69
0.68
1.05

0.65
0.65
1.02

0.65
0.48

IPD
GNP
RTB

1.05
0.75
1.00

1.44
0.66
1.04

1.54
0.64
1.00

1.40
0.47

IPD
GNP
RTB

0.83
0.75
1.00

0.67
0.66
1.04

0.56
0.64
1.00

0.58
0.47

A/WAR-RD

VBCM

A/WAR-D

AVAR

AVAR-D

Note: Model construction and data sources are described in detail in the
Appendix.
Variables include the quarterly average level of RTB, the go-day
Treasury-bill rate, and annualized rates of change from the previous quarter
of GNP, real gross national product; and IPD, the GNP implicit price deflator.
The numerical entries are Theil U statistics described in the text, covering
synthetic forecasts from 1977 Q2 to 1990 Q3.

27
EXHIBIT 6
Regression Results for Several Time Periods

1952 Q2 to 1966 Q4
fit= 0.28 - 0.08~~~, + O.OBp,-, + O.llp,-, + 0.07r,-, + O.O2c,-, - o.Olm,-, + O.OSy,-,
(0.76)
(-0.01)
(0.51)
(0.72)
(0.28)
(0.24)
(0.06) (-0.54)
2

= -0.08

8 =1.85
F(1,149) = 0.17
Q, = -7.90' (m=O)

x2 (1) = 3.48"'

1967 Ql to 1981 Q2
$, = -2.78 + 0.30&s, - o.o4p,-, + o.o4p,-, + 0.33r,,, + 0.02~~~, + 0.6Om,-, - 0.08~~~,
(-1.52)
(4.87)
(-0.54) (2.30)
(-0.28)
(0.27)
(0.26)
(2.56)

Rz = 0.57

a = 1.59

F(1,148) = 2.42

x2(1)=2.31

Q, = -3.64' (m=O)

1981 43 to 1990 44
8t = -8.87 + 0.21P,-, + O.O9p,-, + 0.20~~~, + 0.20r,-, + O.lOc,-, + O.lOm,-, - 0.15~~~~
(-0.21)
(0.53)
(1.02)
(-1.54) (1.16)
(1.15)
(1.07)
(1.68)

Ra = 0.51

6 = 1.06

9, = -2.63

9, = -2.63"'

(m=l)

(m=l)

F(1,28) = 0.45

9, = -2.95"

x2(1) = 0.46

(m-2)

1952 Q2 to 1990 44
rr,= -3.84 + 0.3Op,-, + 0.23~~~~ + 0.22p,+ + o.o05r,-, + o.o5c,-, + 0.17m,-, - 0.22~~~
(-0.59)
(-1.42) (6.38)
(2.89)
(2.71)
(0.07)
(2.95)
(1.54)

R1 = 0.59

8 = 1.75

F(1,145)

= 3.93"

x2(1) = 5.13.'

28
EXHIBIT 6
(Continued)

1952 Q2 to 1990 44 with Dummies
3, = -1.29 - 0.05pcw1 + 0.02~~-~ + O.O6p,-, + 0,2lr,-, + 0.04~~~, + O.O2m,-, - O.O2y,-,
(-0.51) (-0.45)
(0.29)
(0.30)
(-0.44)
(0.82)
(2.34)
.(1.16)
- 2.11d, - 1.32d, + o.38dD + 0.42d,
(-2.66)
(-2.00) (2.53)
(3.61)

R'"= 0.68

Significance

levels:

6 = 1.56

l%, *;

F(1,141)

5%, *;

= 0.25

X2(l) = 23.4'

lO%, -

Note:
For each equation t-statistics are in parentheses.
Symbol definitions
are as follows: p is the inflation rate, t is a time subscript, r is the level
of the 3-month T-bill rate, c is the manufacturing capacity utilization rate,
m is the percentage change of the quarterly average monetary base, y is the
percentage change of real GNP, dm is a dummy variable that is unity from 1967
Ql to 1981 42 and zero otherwise, dl is a dummy variable that is unity from
1981 Q3 to 1990 44 and zero otherwise, dp is the product of p and dm+dl, and
db is the product of dm and m.

The

9,

statistic allows a Dickey-Fuller

test

The F statistic
of the hypothesis of a unit root in the dependent variable.
allows a test of the null hypothesis that serial correlation is zero. The
chi-squared statistic allows a test of the null hypothesis of no ARCH.

29

REFERENCES
Balke, Nathan S. and Thomas B. Fomby. 1991. Shifting Trends, Segmented Trends,
and Infrequent Permanent Shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics 28: 6185.

"Comparing Predictive Accuracy 1:
Diebold, Francis X. and Roberto S. Mariano.
An Asymptotic Test." Discussion Paper 52, Institute for Empirical
Macroeconomice, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Doan, Thomas A. 1990. Users Manual:
Evanston, Illinois.

RATS,

Version

3.10.

VAR Econometrics,

Economic Report of the President. Transmitted to the Congress, Together with
the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. 1980, 1982.
United States Government Printing Office, Washington.
Engle, Robert F. and C. W. J. Granger. 1987. Co-integration and Error Correc
tion: Representation, Estimation, and Testing. Econometrica
55 no. 2
(March): 251-276.
and Byung Sam Yoo. 1987. Forecasting and Testing in Co-integrated
Systems. Journal of Econometrics
35 no. 1 (May): 143-159.
Godfrey, L.G. 1988.
Multiplier

Misspecification
Principle
and Other

Tests in Econometrics:
The Lagrange
Approaches.
Cambridge University Press,

New York.
Goodfriend,

Marvin. 1991. Interest Rates and the Conduct of Monetary Policy.

Carnegie-Rochester

Conference

Series

on Public

Policy

34,

7-30.

Hafer, R. W. and Richard G. Sheehan. 1989. The Sensitivity of VAR Forecast5
to
Alternative Lag Structures. International Journal of Forecasting
5: 399408.

Hallman, Jeffrey J., Richard D. Porter, and David H. Small. 1991. 15 the Price
Level Tied to the M2 Monetary Aggregate in the Long Run? American
Economic Review 81 (September): 841-858.
Hetzel, Robert L. 1989. M2 and Monetary Policy. Economic Review
ber/October) Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond: 14-29.
. 1990. A Mandate for Price Stability. Economic Review
(March/April) Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond: 47-52.

Kettl, Donald F.

Leadership

at the Fed.

75/S (Septem-

76/2

Yale University Press, New Haven.

Litterman, Robert B. 1984. Specifying Vector Autoregressions for Macroeconomic
Forecasting.
Staff Report 92, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

30

Lupoletti, William M. and Roy H. Webb. 1986. Defining and Improving the
Accuracy of Macroeconomic Forecasts: Contributions from a VAR Model.
Journal of Business vol. 59 #2 pt. 1 (April): 263-286.
Martin, William. 1967. Statement to the Congressional Joint Economic Commit
tee, February 9. Reprinted in Federal Reserve Bulletin
(February 1967):
211-216.
McNees , Stephen K. 1986. The Accuracy of Two Forecasting
Techniques: Some
Evidence and an Interpretation.
New England Economic Review (March-

April) Federal Reserve Bank of Boston: 20-31.
Mehra, Yash P. 1991. An Error-Correction Model of U.S. M2 Demand. Economic
Review 77/3 (May-June) Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond: 3-12.
Steurle, C. Eugene. 1991. The Tax Decade: How Taxes Came to Dominate
Public Agenda. The Urban Institute Press, Washington, p. 43.
Volker, Paul. 1982. Monetary Policy Report to Congress.
Bulletin
(March): 125-134.
Webb, Roy H. 1984.
Economic

Federal

the

Reserve

Vector Autoregressions a5 a Tool for Forecast Evaluation.
70/l (January-February) Federal Reserve Bank of Rich-

Review

mond: 3-11.
.

.

1985. Toward More Accurate Macroeconomic Forecasts for Vector Autoregressions.
Economic Review 71/4 (July-August) Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond: 3-11.
1988. Commodity Prices as Predictors of Aggregate Price Change.
Review 74/6 (November-December) Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond: 3-11.

Economic

-.

1991. On Predicting the Stage of the Business Cycle. In Kajal
Lahiri and
Geoffery H. Moore
(eds.), Leading Economic Indicators:
New Approaches
and Forecasting
Records.
New York: Cambridge University Press.

Yi, Chang and George Judge. 1988. Statistical Model Selection Criteria.
Economic Letters 28: 47-51.
Zarnowitz, Victor and Phillip Braun. 1991. Twenty-Two Years of the NBER-ASA
Quarterly Economic Outlook Surveys: Aspects and Comparisons of Forecasting Performance. Working Paper 3965, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

-

31

ENDNOTES

1.

Doan

(1990). p. 8-16.

One
2. Why was the Schwarz Criterion used instead of some other statistic?
reason, which is only applicable for this paper, is simply to have a sharp
difference between the restricted and unrestricted models. More generally, Yi
and Judge (1988) studied the asymptotic performance of three widely used
statistics for model selection. Only the Schwarz Criterion excluded irrelevant
variables with a probability approaching one as the sample size increased.
3. These would be referred to as early quarter forecasts, since they assume
knowledge of the previous quarter's implicit deflator and GNP values, which are
now first released near the end of the first month of a quarter. In real time,
a forecaster would also have other valuable information by the time those values
are released, such as some values in the current quarter for interest rates and
the monetary base.
4. Forecasts from one to eight quarters ahead were examined, although only a few
horizons are shown in the table.
The discussion in the text refers to all
periods, whether or not included in the table.
5. These BVAR model results are based on a model in which real GNP, the implicit
price deflator, and the monetary base are differenced.
Many users of BVAEs,
however, prefer to use levels and trend terms. In other words, they prefer to
assume trend stationarity rather than difference stationarity. To see if these
results are sensitive to that assumption, the BVAR model was also simulated with
all variables in levels and with a time
trend in the equations. The results of
simulated forecasts were generally worse, especially for the inflation rate.
6. While this paper uses squared errors, other functions of the error series
would also be valid.
7.

A particularly

8.

For a discussion of this particular test see Godfrey

well-known example is Hallman, Porter, and Small

(1989).

(19881, section 4.4.

The shorter lag length was chosen to minimize the Schwarz Criterion.
A
longer lag was also examined to check the robustness of the test to the lag
length.
This was particularly important for prices since earlier work, Webb
(1988), had found that the results of Dickey-Fuller tests for unit roots in the
CPI series were also dependent on the lag length.
9.

10.

Engle and Granger

(1987) is the classic reference on the subject.

11.
For a proper ex post real rate, the 3-month nominal rate R would be the
value at the beginning of the quarter, the log price level P would be the value
at the end of the quarter, and the real rate would be R, - (P,-P,.,).The measures
for the nominal rate and the price level that are actually used in this paper are

32
quarterly averages.
would be preferable.

Of course, one could also argue that an ex ante real rate

12. It is interesting to note that they also applied their procedure to real GNP
growth over the same period and did not find any level shift.
13. See, for example,
and a nonindexed tax
inflation rate raised
falling real personal

Hetzel (19901, who emphasizes the interaction of inflation
code.
In 1974 alone he estimates
that.aneleven
percent
the growth in tax revenues to seventeen percent despite
income.

14. While the Federal Reserve has considerable independence in its day to day
operations, if it were to pursue goals outside a political consensus for very
long, legislation putting permanent restrictions on the Fed could be enacted.
Since officials would most likely not wish to see such legislation enacted, as
a practical matter one would not expect to see the Fed continue to pursue goals
that the President and Congress opposed.
15. The Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 included substantial indexing of the
personal income tax for inflation, thereby reducing the government's revenue
gains from inflation. According to Steurle (19911, "The major individual reform
instituted in 1981 was not the direct reduction in tax rates, but the establishment of indexing of tax brackets .... Eventually, indexing will dominate all
other provisions of the 1981 Act."
16.

Kettl, p. 104.

17.
Martin
(19671, p. 215.
The phrase "lowering the degree
restraint" can be translated as lowering the fed funds rate.

of

reserve

18. The other is "The October actions of the Federal Reserve Board to change the
techniques of monetary policy helpedmoderate inflationary expectations whichhad
been partly responsible for the pressure on the [foreign exchange value of the1
dollar."
19.

Volker

(1982) P. 129.

20.

For an account of specific Fed actions during this period see Cook (1989).

21. Some analysts prefer to date the monetary regime change as October 6, 1979,
the time of a Fed announcement of a major change in operating procedures.
Arguing against that date are (1) at the time, the President did not publicly
support a strong, disinflationary monetary policy, preferring instead to focus
on wage-price guidelines, energy conservation, and the risks of monetary policy
being too tight; (2) an important political incentive for inflation, the lack of
indexing of the personal income tax, was not removed until 1981; and (31 monetary
growth in 1980 was not consistent with a shift to a disinflationary monetary
policy.
22.
The statistical hypothesis of structural stability could of course be
formally tested with a standard Chow test. That test, however, is invalid when
the full-sample regression has residuals that display ARCH, as in this case. It

33
is however possible to construct a likelihood ratio test of the joint hypothesis
of constant coefficients and constant residual variance against the alternative
of changing coefficients and/or changing residual variance. The LR statistic in
this case has a chi-squared (18) distribution; the calculated LR value, 43.45,
indicates the null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% level.
23.

See Webb

(1984, 1985, 1991) and Lupoletti and Webb

(1986).

An important part of the BVAR specification procedure is to set "hyperzirameters" that could in principle be used to impose prior beliefs on the data.
Here these parameters were chosen to minimize the log-determinant of the
variance-covariancematrixconstructedfromone-quarter-aheadforecasterrors
for
the model.
The resulting choices are summarized in the RATS statement
SPECIFY(type=symmetric,decay=.5,tight=,6)
.9
(see Doan, ch. 8.8 for further details).