View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Fiscal Policy and Regional Inflation in a
Currency Union

WP 03-11

Margarida Duarte
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Alexander L. Wolman
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Fiscal Policy and Regional In‡ation
in a Currency Union¤
Margarida Duartey

Alexander L. Wolmanz

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 03-11
August 2003
JEL Nos. F33, F02, E62
Keywords: currency union, …scal policy, in‡ation di¤erentials

Abstract
This paper investigates the ability of a region participating in a currency union to
a¤ect its in‡ation di¤erential with respect to the union through …scal policy. We study
the interaction between regional …scal policy and in‡ation di¤erentials in a ‡exible­
price, two-region model with both traded and nontraded goods. For symmetric regions,
changes in one region’s tax rule that decrease the volatility of its in‡ation di¤erential
also decrease the volatility of its output. The decrease in the volatility of the in‡ation
di¤erential is brought about by an increase in the volatility of tax rates. The e¤ect
of the tax rule on output volatility – but not in‡ation volatility – depends on country
size. For a small country lower volatility of in‡ation di¤erentials is associated with
higher volatility of output. This relationship results from the fact that small countries
are more open, and hence there is a greater role for traded goods productivity shocks.

¤ We

would like to thank Michael Dotsey, Tommaso Monacelli, Fabio Natalucci, Cedric Tille, and partici­
pants in the 2002 SED meeting in New York, the International Forum on Monetary Policy at the European
Central Bank, the Federal Reserve System Committee on International Economics, the 2003 Midwest Macro
conference, and the 2003 Econometric Society meeting for comments on this and an earlier version, and Elise
Couper for research assistance. This paper does not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve
System or the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
y Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, margarida.duarte@rich.frb.org.
z Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, alexander.wolman@rich.frb.org.

1. Introduction
Regions participating in a currency union delegate monetary policy – the principal
tool for controlling their in‡ation rate – to a central authority. However, a currency
union typically does not involve homogeneous, perfectly integrated regions, and
in‡ation rates therefore vary across regions. The currency union comprising the
United States is homogeneous and integrated enough that no attention is paid
to in‡ation di¤erentials across regions; state-level consumer price index data is
not even collected. The European Monetary Union is another matter. Domestic
in‡ation rates continue to play an important role in discussions of individual
countries’ economic conditions. And at the EU level, Ireland was reprimanded
by the European Union’s …nance ministers in 2001 for pursuing easy …scal policy
in the face of a high in‡ation rate. More recently, Pedro Solbes, the European
Commissioner for Economic and Monetary A¤airs, stated that for Ireland today,
“the in‡ation question, as in Spain, has to be tackled on the national level.”1
Should a region in a currency union wish to exert in‡uence over its own in‡a­
tion rate – or its in‡ation di¤erential relative to the rest of the union – it must
turn to …scal policy. When …scal policy is its only available instrument, several
questions arise. Can the regional …scal authority a¤ect its in‡ation di¤erential?
If so, what types of policies are e¤ective, and what consequences do they have for
real economic activity?
This paper investigates the ability of a region participating in a currency union
to a¤ect its in‡ation di¤erential with respect to the union through …scal policy.
We study the interaction between regional …scal policy and in‡ation di¤erentials
in a ‡exible-price, two-region model with both traded and nontraded goods. In
our framework, price (and in‡ation) di¤erentials arise from both movements in
the relative price of nontraded goods across countries and deviations from the
law of one price for traded goods. There is an exogenous stream of government
expenditures, and the regional …scal authority has access to a labor income tax,
seigniorage revenue, and debt to …nance these expenditures. The model is driven
by shocks to government expenditures and to productivity.
Because regional …scal authorities can issue debt, they have some ‡exibility
as to the pattern of distortionary taxes. We assume that the tax rate is determined by a rule that responds to the level and change in the stock of outstanding
government debt.2 We study the implications of modi…cations to the benchmark
1 Irish
2 This

Times, January 31, 2003, page 51.
type of rule has been commonly used in large, quantitative models (see Johnson, 2001).

tax rule that are aimed at in‡uencing the region’s in‡ation di¤erential. The tax
rate is distortionary, so changes in its cyclical behavior alter the behavior of real
variables, including the price of the home consumption basket relative to the for­
eign consumption basket. Thus, regional …scal authorities do have the ability
to a¤ect the regional in‡ation di¤erential. Speci…cally, by lowering (raising) the
distortionary tax rate in response to positive (negative) in‡ation di¤erentials, a
regional …scal authority can decrease the absolute value of its in‡ation di¤erential
in response to the shocks driving the model.
We …nd that for symmetric regions, changes in one region’s tax rule that
decrease the volatility of its in‡ation di¤erential also decrease the volatility of its
output. The decrease in the volatility of the in‡ation di¤erential is brought about
by an increase in the volatility of tax rates. We also consider the behavior of the
smaller of two regions in an asymmetric currency union. For small countries, the
relationship between the tax rule and volatility of in‡ation di¤erentials is similar
to the symmetric case. Likewise, small countries experience essentially the same
relationship between the tax rule and tax rate volatility. However, the e¤ect of the
tax rule on output volatility depends on country size. For a small country lower
volatility of in‡ation di¤erentials is associated with higher volatility of output.
This relationship results from the fact that small countries are more open, and
hence there is a greater role for traded goods productivity shocks.
Early research on currency unions, dating back to Mundell (1961), concerns the
optimal composition of a currency area. In modern dynamic equilibrium models,
it has been di¢cult to …nd conditions under which it is optimal for a region
to delegate its monetary policy (see, for example, Monacelli, 2001). Given the
existence of a currency union, Benigno (2002) studies optimal monetary policy and
Bergin (2001) shows how non-constant demand elasticities can generate in‡ation
di¤erentials through deviations from the law of one price.
We use a general equilibrium model to study how regional …scal policy a¤ects
regional in‡ation di¤erentials.3 4 Beetsma and Jensen (2002) also study regional
…scal policy in a general equilibrium model of a currency union. They describe
3 An

empirical literature documents regional variation in in‡ation within currency unions.
Cecchetti, Mark, and Sonora (2002), Parsley and Wei (1996), and Rogers (2001) study price
level convergence, and Canova and Pappa (2003) study the e¤ects of …scal shocks on price
dispersion.
4 Bergin (2000) and Sims (1999) consider implications of the …scal theory of the price level
for a monetary union. We focus on monetary and …scal policy regimes in which there is a
unique equilibrium. Nonetheless, the particular form of a region’s …scal policy rule a¤ects the
equilibrium behavior of in‡ation.

2

the optimal coordinated monetary and …scal policies whereas we treat policy as
exogenous. In addition, the models di¤er in their assumptions about the instru­
ments of …scal policy and the role of government spending. Beetsma and Jensen
allow for lump-sum taxes and assume that government spending yields utility to
consumers. We assume that the government must rely on a labor income tax and
debt to fund spending that is a pure resource drain. Furthermore, in Beetsma
and Jensen consumer price levels are identical across countries and in‡ation is
measured by the change in the producer price index.
The paper proceeds as follows. In section 2 we present the model. Section
3 describes the model’s calibration. Section 4 is devoted to developing a basic
understanding of the model; we describe the channels which lead in‡ation to
vary across countries, and discuss the dynamic responses to productivity and
government spending shocks. Section 5 contains our results for symmetric regions
on the implications of using …scal policy to a¤ect the in‡ation di¤erential, and
section 6 is devoted to the small country case. Section 7 concludes.

2. Model
The currency union is composed of two regions, denoted home and foreign, that
share the same currency. A central monetary authority issues the currency and
conducts monetary policy. Each region has a …scal authority, which is responsible
for …scal policy in the region.
The two regions share the same structure but may di¤er in size. Each region
is specialized in the production of a continuum of varieties of a tradable and
nontradable good. Monopolistically competitive …rms produce these goods using
labor, which is immobile across regions. Prices are ‡exible.
The regions are populated by a continuum of households of measure N (home)
and N ¤ (foreign). Households in each region supply labor to domestic …rms and
consume all varieties of both home and foreign tradable goods, as well as all
varieties of the region’s nontradable good. We assume that, in order to consume
a traded good, agents need to combine it with nontraded goods.5 That is, a
consumer must purchase ´ additional units of the local nontraded good in order
to obtain utility from a traded good. Hence nontraded goods are used both for
5 This

assumption re‡ects the need to combine di¤erentiated traded goods with distribution
services (intensive in local nontraded goods) before households can consume the former. This
corresponds to the setup in Corsetti and Dedola (2002), except that for the purpose of our paper,
and without any loss of generality we do not need to model the distribution sector separately.

3

consumption and distribution purposes. Households also demand real balances,
which are an argument in their utility function.
We assume that asset markets are complete. Thus, in every state of the world
the ratio of marginal utilities of per capita consumption across regions is equated
to the ratio of consumption price levels across regions.6
We describe only the home region’s economy. An analogous description applies
to the foreign region. The subscript f (or h) denotes a good’s country of origin,
whereas the superscript ¤ denotes a foreign region variable; for example, PT¤;h is
the price of a traded good produced in the home country and consumed in the
foreign country.
2.1. Households
Households derive utility from consuming a composite good (ct ), leisure time
t
(1 ¡ lt ), and from holding real money balances ( M
). Households maximize the
Pt
expected discounted value of the utility ‡ow,
"1
µ
¶#
X
M
U0 = E0
¯ tu ct ; 1 ¡ lt; t
(2.1)
P
t
t=0

where E0 denotes the mathematical expectation conditional on information available in period t = 0, ¯ 2 (0; 1) is the discount rate, and u is the momentary utility
function, assumed to be concave and twice continuously di¤erentiable.
2.1.1. The Composition of Consumption
The composite consumption good is an aggregate of traded and nontraded goods
(cT;t and cN;t ) as follows:
»
·
¸ »¡1
»¡1
»¡1
»
»
ct = · T cT;t + · N cN;t
:
(2.2)

The elasticity of substitution between the traded and nontraded good is », and
·T and ·N determine the agent’s bias towards the traded good. Consumption of
traded goods is a similar aggregate of home- and foreign- produced traded goods
(cT;h;t and cT;f ;t ):
°
·
¸ °¡1
°¡1
°¡1
°
°
cT;t = ·T;h cT;h;t + ·T ;f cT;f ;t
;
(2.3)
6 See,

for example, Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002).

4

where ° > 0 denotes the elasticity of substitution between the home and foreign
composite traded goods, and the weights ·T;h and · T;f determine the agent’s bias
for the domestic traded good.
Each country produces a continuum of varieties of the traded good, indexed
by i 2 [0; 1] ; and a continuum of varieties of the nontraded good, indexed by
j 2 [0; 1]. The local nontraded good and the local and imported traded goods in
(2.2) and (2.3) are aggregates of these continua of varieties:
cN;t =

µZ

1

cN;t (j)

µ¡1
µ

dj

0

cT;h;t =

µZ

1

cT ;h;t (i)

µ¡1
µ

µ
¶ µ¡1

and
cT ;f;t =

µZ

1

cT ;f;t (i)

0

µ¡1
µ

µ
¶ µ ¡1

;

(2.5)

µ
¶ µ¡1

;

(2.6)

di

0

di

(2.4)

;

where µ > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between any two varieties of the same
good, and the price elasticity of demand for a given variety.
2.1.2. Demands and Price Indices
The numeraire we will work with is the common currency: Let Pt denote the price
of the composite consumption good and PT;t and PN;t denote the prices of the
composite traded and nontraded goods, respectively. And let PT;h;t (i), PT;f ;t (i),
and PN;t (i) denote the prices set by the producers of the home and foreign traded
goods and of the local nontraded good of type i, respectively. Since ´ units of
the nontraded composite good need to be purchased for every unit consumed of
traded good i, the cost to the household to consume one unit of traded good i is
e¤ectively PT;h;t (i) + ´PN;t for the home good and PT;f ;t (i) + ´PN;t for the foreign
good.7
Given the consumer’s demand for the composite consumption good, the de­
mand for each lower level good can be determined by solving a cost minimization
problem. Substituting these demands back into the appropriate consumption ag­
gregator then yields the corresponding price index.
7 More

formally, consumers should be viewed as having Leontief preferences over any individ­
ual traded good and ´ times the composite nontraded good.

5

Composite Goods The price index for the composite consumption good, Pt ,
is
³
´1=(1¡»)
Pt = ·»T (PT;t )1¡» + ·»N (PN;t )1¡»
;
where the price indices for the traded and nontraded goods aggregates are given
by
¡
¢1=(1¡°)
°
PT;t = · °T;h (PT ;h;t )1¡° + · T;f
(PT ;f;t )1¡°
and

µZ

PN;t =

1

PN;t (i)

1¡µ

dj

0

1
¶ 1¡µ

:

In addition, the price indices PT ;h;t and PfT;t for the local and imported composite
traded goods are given by
PT;h;t =

µZ

1

(PT;h;t (i) + ´PN;t )

1¡µ

di

0

and
PT;f ;t =

µZ

1

(PT;f;t (i) + ´PN;t )

1¡µ

di

0

1
¶ 1¡µ

1
¶ 1¡µ

:

These price indices re‡ect the requirement that ´ units of the nontraded composite
good be purchased for every unit consumed of traded good i.
The demand functions for each variety of each good are given by
µ
¶
PN;t (i) ¡µ
cN;t (i) =
cN;t;
(2.7)
PN;t
Ã
!¡µ
PT;h;t (i) + ´PN;t
cT;h;t (i) =
cT;h;t :
(2.8)
T
Ph;t
and
cT;f;t (i) =

Ã

PT;f ;t (i) + ´PN;t
T
Pf;t

!¡µ

cT;f;t :

(2.9)

Naturally, the demands for traded goods depend on the cost to the household of
consuming one unit of the good and therefore re‡ect the price of nontraded goods.
The terms cN;t , cT;h;t , cT ;f;t denote the demand for the relevant composite good
and are derived analogously. For example, cN;t = k»N (PN;t =Pt )¡» ct :
6

2.1.3. The Budget Constraint
The representative consumer in the home region holds currency, Mt , issued by the
central monetary authority and trades a complete set of state contingent nominal
bonds with the consumer in the foreign region. We denote the price at date t
when the state of the world is s t of a bond paying one unit of currency at date
t + 1 if the state of the world is s t+1 by Q (st+1 js t) and we denote the number
of these bonds purchased by the home agent at date t by D (s t+1 ). The home
consumer also holds riskless nominal bonds issued by the home and foreign …scal
authorities, Bh;t and Bf ;t , both paying (1 + Rt ) currency units in period t + 1.8
The agent’s intertemporal budget constraint, expressed in currency units, is
X
Pt ct + Mt + Bh;t + Bf ;t +
Q (st+1 jst ) D (st+1 )
(2.10)
s t+1

· (1 ¡ ¿ t ) Ptwt lt + Mt¡1 + D (st ) + ¦t + (1 + Rt¡1 ) (Bh;t¡1 + Bf ;t¡1 ) ;

where ¦t represents pro…ts of domestic …rms (assumed to be owned by the do­
mestic consumer) and (1 ¡ ¿ t ) Pt wt lt represents nominal labor earnings after tax.
The consumer chooses sequences for consumption, ct , labor, lt , state contingent
bonds, D (s t+1), government bonds, Bh;t and Bf;t , and money holdings, Mt , in
order to maximize the expected discounted utility (2:1) subject to the budget
constraint (2:10).
2.2. The Regional Fiscal Authority
The …scal authority in the home region issues nominal debt, Bt , taxes labor income
at rate ¿ t , and receives seigniorage revenues from the central monetary authority,
Zt . These revenues are spent on public consumption, g t, and interest payments on
the debt. Public consumption does not yield utility to households in our model.
The region’s government budget constraint is given by
Bt + N ¿ t Pt wt lt + Z t = (1 + Rt¡1 ) Bt¡1 + Pt g t :

(2.11)

The government has the same preferences as the consumer for the di¤erent
varieties of the local nontraded good and both traded goods. Therefore, given
8 Because

home and foreign agents can both freely buy and sell home and foreign government
bonds, arbitrage ensures that there is a common nominal interest rate. Our assumption of
complete asset markets independently guarantees that the nominal interest rate is common
across countries.

7

a level of total government consumption gt , government demands for individ­
ual goods are given by expressions analogous to the individual consumption de­
mands (2:7), (2:8), and (2:9) ; for example, gN;t (i) = (PN;t (i) =PN;t )¡µ gN;t =
(PN;t (i) =PN;t )¡µ kN» (PN;t=Pt )¡» gt .
We are interested in studying the roles of both regional …scal policy shocks and
systematic …scal policy in a¤ecting in‡ation di¤erentials across regions. Fiscal
policy shocks can be associated with either taxation or spending, and likewise
systematic …scal policy can be associated with either taxation or spending. We
follow much of the literature in assuming that the ratio of government spending
to output follows an exogenous stochastic process, whereas the labor income tax
rate is determined by a feedback rule that incorporates a response to the stock of
debt.9 This response insures that the government will be able to pay the interest
on its debts.
The share of total public consumption in output, g=y, is given by
µ ¶
µ ¶
g
g
= cg + ½g
+ "g;t ;
(2.12)
y t
y t¡1
¯ ¯
where ¯½g ¯ < 1 and "g;t » N (0; ¾ g ). The tax rate ¿ t on labor income is determined
by a feedback rule that targets the debt/GDP ratio b according to
¡
¢
¡
¢
¿ t = ¿ t¡1 + ®b;¿ b t ¡ b + ®¢b;¿ (b t ¡ bt¡1 ) + ®p;¿ ¼ t ¡ ¼ Ut :
(2.13)
Note that we have allowed for a response of the tax rate to the in‡ation di¤erential
(¼Ut denotes union-wide in‡ation, to be de…ned below). This response is how we
model …scal policy as attempting to a¤ect in‡ation di¤erentials.
2.3. Firms
There are two sectors of production in each region, the traded, T , and nontraded,
N , sector. The production function for each …rm i in each sector is given by
zt lt (i), where lt (i) represents labor input and zt is a sector- and country-speci…c
productivity shock. We denote the real marginal cost by à t = wt =zt . Note that
marginal cost is “country-sector speci…c;” two …rms in the same country in the
same sector have the same level of productivity and hence (since they face the
same wage) the same marginal cost. Firms are monopolistically competitive and
prices are ‡exible.
9 Johnson

(2001) criticizes the arbitrariness of the approach taken by much of the literature
(and by us). See Mitchell, Sault, and Wallis (2000) for a study of di¤erent rules used in the
literature.

8

2.3.1. The Tradable Goods Sector
Firm i chooses PT;h;t (i) and PT¤;h;t (i), the prices to charge in each market for
its good. We assume that home and foreign markets are segmented; thus, the
law of one price need not hold for traded goods. As it will become clear below,
due to the need to use ´ units of the local nontraded good in order to derive
utility from traded goods, …rms producing these goods may …nd it optimal to
price discriminate across the two markets, setting PT ;h;t (i) 6= PT¤;h;t (i).
The pro…t maximization problems for the producer of traded good i are
µ
¶µ
¶¡µ
PT ;h;t (i)
PT;h;t (i) + ´PN;t
max
¡ ÃT ;t
yT ;h;t
(2.14)
PT ;h;t (i)
Pt
PT;h;t
and
max
¤

PT;h;t(i)

µ

PT¤;h;t (i)
¡ Ã T;t
Pt

¶Ã

¤
PT¤;h;t (i) + ´PN;t
PT¤;h;t

!¡µ

y¤T;h;t ;

where yT;h;t = N cT ;h;t + g T;h;t denotes home demand in period t for the composite
home traded good and y¤T;h;t = N ¤c¤T;h;t + gT¤ ;h;t denotes foreign demand. These
problems imply that the price of a domestically produced traded good in the home
and foreign markets is, respectively
µ
¶
PT;h;t (i)
µ
´ PN;t
=
1+
à T;t
(2.15)
Pt
µ¡1
µÃ T;t Pt
and

µ
¶
PT¤;h;t (i)
µ
´ PN¤ ;t
=
1+
ÃT;t :
Pt
µ¡1
µÃT ;t Pt

(2.16)

That is, prices are a markup over the standard measure of marginal cost, where
the markup is increasing in the relative price of nontraded goods. Increases in
the relative price of nontraded goods raise the market power of a traded goods
producer, by decreasing the traded goods producer’s share of the traded goods
consumer price.
As shown in Corsetti and Dedola (2002), with ´ > 0, the elasticity of demand
for home traded goods is not necessarily the same across countries and it will di¤er
if the relative price of nontraded goods di¤ers across countries. The monopolistic
…rm takes this fact into account when choosing its prices and may …nd it optimal
to charge di¤erent prices across markets.
9

The market clearing condition for home traded good i is given by
N cT ;h;t (i) + N ¤ c¤T;h;t (i) + g T;h;t (i) + g ¤T h;t (i) = zT ;t lT ;t (i) ´ yT;t (i) ;

(2.17)

and, similarly, the market clearing condition for foreign traded good i is
¤
N cT ;f;t (i) + N ¤ c¤T;f ;t (i) + gT ;f ;t (i) + gT¤ ;f;t (i) = zT¤ ;t lT¤ ;t (i) ´ yT;t
(i) :

(2.18)

Note that individual household demands are expressed in per capita terms whereas
government demands and …rm-level labor inputs are not.
2.3.2. The Nontraded Goods Sector
The pro…t maximization problem for a producer of nontraded good i is
max

PN;t(i)

µ

PN;t (i)
¡ ÃN;t
Pt

¶µ

PN;t (i)
PN;t

¶¡µ

yN;t ;

where yN;t denotes total demand for the composite nontraded good. This term
has two components since nontraded goods are demanded by households and gov­
ernment for both consumption and distribution purposes. This problem implies
the usual pricing condition
PN;t (i)
µ
=
à :
Pt
µ ¡ 1 N;t

(2.19)

The market clearing condition for nontraded goods is di¤erent from the one
for traded goods, as it re‡ects the quantity of nontraded goods demanded for
“distribution” purposes as well as the quantity demanded for consumption. The
market clearing condition for home nontraded good i is then given by
µ
¶
cT ;h;t (i) + cT;f ;t (i)
(N cN;t (i) + gN;t (i)) 1 + ´
= zN;t lN;t (i) ´ yN;t (i) :
cN;t
It is important to note that the variable cN;t (i) does not include the nontraded
goods purchased for their role in distribution; these goods are accounted for by
the term in ´.

10

2.4. The Central Monetary Authority
The central monetary authority issues non-interest bearing money and allocates
seigniorage revenue to the regions. Let the superscript U denote a union-wide
variable; for example total nominal money balances in the union are MtU = Mt +
Mt¤ .
In period t, the monetary authority earns revenue from printing money equal to
U
U
Mt ¡ Mt¡1
and it distributes this revenue among the regional …scal authorities.10
Recalling that Z denotes seigniorage, we have
U
MtU ¡ Mt¡1
´ ZtU = Zt + Z t¤ :

(2.20)

We have to specify the rule for allocating seigniorage. We will assume that
seigniorage is allocated according to each country’s share of nominal consump­
tion in the stationary steady-state, sc , so that
Z t = sc ZtU :

(2.21)

The monetary authority is assumed to follow an interest rate rule similar to the
rules studied by Taylor (1993) and Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1998). In particular,
the nominal interest rate Rt is set as a function of the lagged nominal rate, next
period’s expected in‡ation rate in the union, and union-wide real output,
£ ¡
¢
¡
¢¤
¹ + ½R Rt¡1 +(1 ¡ ½R ) ®¼ Et ¼Ut+1 ¡ ¼U + ®y ln yU =yU ; (2.22)
Rt = (1 ¡ ½R ) R
t

where a bar over a variable denotes its target value. In order to implement this
rule, the central monetary authority needs a measure both for the price level and
real output in the whole currency union, PtU and yUt , respectively.
We de…ne the “union-wide” price level, PtU , as a weighted average of each
region’s price level, where the weight is determined by the region’s share of nominal
consumption. That is,
PtU = sc;t Pt + (1 ¡ sc;t ) Pt¤ :

10 In the description central monetary authority we abstract, without loss of generality, from
the monetary authority’s balance sheet and from each government’s borrowing from the mon­
etary authority. To solve the model, we need to specify how the revenue from money creation
is allocated across regions. We do this by choosing a rule for the allocation of the change in
the monetary base. This choice eliminates the need to keep track of the central bank’s balance
sheet. If we were, instead, to specify the allocation rule in terms of the central bank’s interest
revenues, we would need to keep track of its balance sheet.

11

In order to de…ne “union-wide” real output, we …rst de…ne union nominal
output as the sum of each region’s nominal output, yUt n = ytn + yt¤n . Union real
output is obtained by de‡ating union nominal output by the union price level,
Un
yUt = yPt U .
t

2.5. Equilibrium and Model Solution
We focus on the symmetric equilibrium of the model in which all …rms in the
same sector choose the same price. An equilibrium for this economy is de…ned as
a collection of allocations for home and foreign consumers, allocations and prices
for home and foreign …rms, composite good prices, real wages, and bond prices that
satisfy the e¢ciency conditions for households and …rms (…rst-order conditions for
the maximization problems stated above) and market clearing conditions, given
the policy rules assumed for the monetary and …scal authorities.11 The remaining
market clearing conditions needed to solve the model are for the labor markets in
the two countries:
T
N lt = lh;t
(i) + ltN (i) :
(2.23)
As before, individual household labor supply in period t, lt , is expressed in per
capita terms, whereas …rm-level labor inputs lTt (i) and lN
t (i) are not. We approx­
imate the equilibrium linearly around its steady-state.

3. Calibration
In this section we report the parameter values used in solving the model. Our
benchmark calibration assumes that the regions in the currency union are symmet­
ric and share the same structure and parameter values. The model is calibrated
using German data, unless otherwise noted, and we assume that a time period in
the model corresponds to one quarter.
3.1. Preferences and Production
We follow Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002) closely in the preference speci…­
cation. The momentary utility function is given by
Ã
µ
¶
µ ¶± ! 1¡¾
±
M
1
M
(1 ¡ l)1¡º
U c; l;
=
ac± + (1 ¡ a)
+Ã
:
P
1¡¾
P
1¡º
11 In

the interest of space we do not present the e¢ciency conditions.

12

We set the curvature parameter, ¾, equal to two. The parameters à and º are set
to 17:4 and 1:5, respectively, so that the fraction of working time in steady-state
is 0:25 and the elasticity of labor supply, with marginal utility of consumption
held constant, is 2.
The parameters a and ± are obtained from estimating the money demand
equation implied by the …rst-order condition for bond holdings. Using the utility
function de…ned above, this equation can be written as
log

Mt
1
a
1
R ¡1
=
log
+ log ct +
log t
:
Pt
±¡1
1¡a
±¡1
Rt

To estimate ± and a we used German quarterly data from 1995:01 to 2000:01
for M1, CPI, real private consumption and the three-month Libor rate. We set
1
±¡1 equal to our estimate of the interest elasticity, ¡0:45, and obtain ± = ¡1:22.
The value for the weight coe¢cient a was set to 0:91 and it was derived from the
estimate for the intercept, ¡1:026. The discount factor, ¯ , is set to 0:99, implying
a 4% annual real rate in the stationary economy.
For the consumption index cT we need to assign values to °, the elasticity of
substitution between domestic and imported traded goods, and to ·T h and ·T f ,
the weights on consumption of home and foreign traded goods. Collard and Dellas
(2002) estimate ° for France and Germany using data from 1975:1 to 1990:4. Their
estimate for France is 1:35 while their point estimate for Germany is substantially
higher (2:33) but also very uncertain. In the benchmark calibration we set ° equal
to 1:5, which is also the standard value used in models calibrated for US data.
The weight ·T h is set equal to 0:63 so that the import share in steady state is
25% of GDP and we use the normalization ·°T h + · T° f = 1 to obtain ·T f .
The consumption index for c depends on », the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods, and on · T and · N , the weights on consump­
tion of traded and nontraded goods. We use Mendoza’s (1995) estimate of the
elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods for industrialized
countries and set » equal to 0:74.12 To set the weight ·T we refer to Stockman and
Tesar (1995) who report that nontraded goods account for about half of output in
OECD countries. We set ·T = 0:86 to match this ratio and use the normalization
·»T + ·»N = 1 to obtain ·N .
Finally, we need to choose the values for the distribution parameter ´ and for µ,
the elasticity of substitution across varieties of goods. Based on Burstein, Neves,
12 This

estimate is bigger than the one found by Stockman and Tesar (1995), who use data
from both developing and industrialized countries.

13

and Rebelo (2000), we set ´ equal to 0:9 so that distribution services represent
45% of the retail price of traded goods in steady state.
The elasticity of substitution between di¤erent varieties of a given good, µ,
is related to the markup chosen when …rms adjust their prices. The markup
for …rms in the nontraded sector is simply µ= (µ ¡ 1). We set µ = 10, which is
a representative value in the literature. It implies a markup of 1:11, which is
consistent with the empirical work of Basu and Fernald (1997) and Basu and
Kimball (1997). For the same elasticity of substitution among varieties of traded
goods, the steady state markup for …rms in the traded goods sector is larger due
to the presence of distribution costs. In steady state, the markup for …rms in
the traded sector is 1:22, about 10% higher than in the nontraded goods sector
because of the added market power generated by the distribution costs.
3.2. Monetary and Fiscal Policy Rules
The parameters of the nominal interest rate rule are taken from the estimates in
Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1998, Table I) for the Bundesbank. We set ½r = 0:91,
®p;r = 1:31, and ®y;r = 0:25=4, where this last term is converted for quarterly
data. The target values for R, ¼ U , and y U are their steady-state values. We
assume that in steady-state prices grow at 2% per year (or 0:5% per quarter).
The parameters for the tax rule are taken from Mitchell, Sault, and Wallis
(2000). We convert their values for quarterly data and set ®b;¿ = 0:04=16 and
®¢b;¿ = 0:3=4.
3.3. Exogenous processes
The technology shocks£are assumed to ¤follow an AR (1) process z t+1 = Az zt + " zt ,
where zt is the vector ztT ; ztN ; zt¤T ; zt¤N and Az is a 4 £ 4 matrix. The vector "zt
represents the innovation to z. Stockman and Tesar (1995) provide estimates for
a joint productivity process such as this one, but that process is annual, and the
home and foreign countries are interpreted as symmetric and together comprising
the entire industrialized world. Our model is quarterly, and the home and foreign
countries are loosely interpreted as Germany and France, which likely experience
higher correlation of productivity shocks. We adjust the Stockman and Tesar

14

process to account for these two di¤erences, and end up with
2
3
0.199 0.249 -0.010 0.094
6 0.176 0.593 0.036 0.044 7
7
Az = 6
4 -0.010 0.094 0.199 0.249 5
0.036 0.044 0.176 0.593
and

2

3 2
²Tt ;h
1 0
N;h 7
6
6
²
t
7 60 1
"zt = 6
4 ²Tt ;f 5 + 4 1 0
0 1
²tN;f

3

7
7
5

·

²Tt ;c
²tN;c

¸

;

with each ² independently distributed across both time and sectors and ¾ 2²T;i =
¾2
0:02422 , ¾ 2²N;i = 0:01232 , and ¾²2c = 0:3636, for i = h; f.13
²i
Shocks to government expenditures in each country are assumed to follow the
same independent AR (1) process gt+1 = c+Ag gt +"gt , where gt represents the share
of government expenditures in GDP. We estimated this process using quarterly
data for Germany from 1991:2 to 2001:3. The estimate for Ag is 0:57 and the
estimate for ¾ 2"g is 0:000166.

4. The Mechanisms Behind Regional Price Di¤erentials
The model contains three distinct mechanisms that can generate price (and in­
‡ation) di¤erentials across regions. Each mechanism works through the presence
of local nontraded goods. First, households consume both traded and nontraded
goods, implying that the consumption price indices in the two countries correspond
to distinct baskets of goods. Even if the law of one price holds for all traded va­
rieties, the consumption price indices di¤er in the two countries in response to
13 We

arrived at this representation for productivity in two steps. First, we computed a
quarterly productivity process that came close to replicating the Stockman-Tesar process when it
was time-aggregated. Next, we imposed the common shock structure of Collard and Dellas, who
estimate a joint AR(1) process for aggregate productivity for Germany and France. We assumed
that the variance ratio of common to idiosyncratic shocks was as they report for Germany. We
chose the levels of idiosyncatic shock variances so that, (i) when combined with our Az matrix,
the ratio of own variances of traded and non-traded productivity was that implied by the original
Stockman and Tesar process, and (ii), the standard deviation of hp-…ltered output relative to its
mean was 1.1%, which is what we estimated for Germany. We intend to estimate this process
directly in future work.

15

movements in the relative price of nontraded goods across countries. Second, due
to the need to use local nontraded goods for the consumption of traded goods,
the consumer price of traded varieties depends on the price of the local nontraded
composite good. Third, movements in the relative price of nontraded goods across
countries will lead traded goods’ producers to price discriminate across markets
(equations (2.15) and (2.16)). For these reasons, the consumer price of traded
goods (and thus the consumption price indices) di¤ers in the two countries in
response to movements in the relative price of nontraded goods across countries.14
Any exogenous shock which a¤ects the relative price of nontraded goods across
regions generates an equilibrium price di¤erential across regions through the mech­
anisms just described. We now look at the equilibrium price di¤erential associated
with permanent shocks to government spending and home nontraded productiv­
ity. In these experiments we assume that countries are equal-sized and monetary
policy is given by a constant money growth rate.15 We consider di¤erent alterna­
tives for the options available to the …scal authority to balance its budget each
period.
Government Expenditure Shock Fiscal policy in each region is summa­
rized by an exogenous process for government expenditures as a share of output
and by a feedback rule for the labor income tax. Here we illustrate the e¤ects of
permanent shocks to government spending on price di¤erentials for di¤erent as­
sumptions on the tools available to the government to …nance its budget. Recall
that in our setup government spending is a pure resource drain on the economy.
Figure 1 displays the response of selected variables to a one percentage point
permanent increase in the share of government spending in output, when govern­
ment spending is …nanced by lump-sum taxes. The shock generates an increase in
government spending of about 5.8%, increasing demand for both home and foreign
traded goods as well as for the local nontraded goods (partly to be used for the
distribution of traded goods). Domestic real output increases by less than 1% and
the transmission of the shock to foreign output is even smaller.16 The shock has
14 In

the presence of nontraded goods, distribution costs are not necessary for generating
relative price changes across countries. However, they do generate deviations from the law of
one price, which have been documented to contribute importantly to the observed movements
in relative prices across countries.
15 The analysis of relative price levels across countries does not require the use of a monetary
model. In a real two-country model of relative national price levels Duarte (2003) …nds results
analogous to those presented in this section.
16 Betts and Devereux (1999) …nd identical responses of home and foreign output to government

16

a negative e¤ect on private consumption, bigger in the home country than in the
foreign country, and it generates a one time permanent positive price di¤erential
with respect to the foreign region of about 0:15 percentage points.17 The real
wage increases in the home country while it decreases in the foreign country.
Since the relative price of home traded goods to foreign traded goods increases,
home and foreign households and governments substitute consumption away from
home traded goods towards foreign traded goods. This substitution e¤ect leads
to the relative expansion of the traded goods sector in the foreign country, while
the nontraded goods sector expands relatively more in the home country.
Figure 2 displays the response to the same shock when the government …­
nances its spending with labor income taxes instead of lump-sum taxes. The
e¤ect on the price di¤erential generated by the shock is now about 0:8 percentage
points, substantially higher than in the previous case. Due to the higher labor
income taxes in the home country (needed to …nance the increased government
spending), the (pre-tax) real wage required by home households to work more and
meet the increased demand for home goods increases more than in the previous
case. In equilibrium, the home household works less and consumes less. Prices of
home goods now increase more relative to the price of foreign goods than before,
implying that agents substitute even more towards foreign goods.
In the benchmark model we allow for the government to …nance its spending
with both labor income taxes and debt. Each period labor income taxes are de­
termined by the tax feedback rule (2.13) that depends on that period’s net change
and level of public debt, as well as the previous period’s tax rate; public debt,
in turn, adjusts to insure that the government’s intertemporal budget constraint
holds. In response to a government spending shock, the regional …scal authority
issues new debt and raises labor income taxes. The tax feedback rule introduces
dynamics to the shock response, absent in the cases where the increase in govern­
ment spending is …nanced period-by-period by either lump-sum or labor income
taxes.18
spending shocks. In our model the response of home and foreign outputs is not identical because
there are nontraded goods.
17 As mentioned above, the assumption of complete asset markets implies that u =P = u¤ =P ¤
c
c
every period. This condition implies that the ratio of price levels moves together with the
ratio of marginal utilities of consumption. Abstracting from the presence of money in the
utility function, this condition implies a negative relationship between price di¤erentials and
consumption di¤erentials.
18 In their analysis of the government’s …nancing decision, Baxter and King (1993) abstract
from government debt, arguing that any path for debt can be replicated with transfers, for a

17

Figure 3 displays the response to the same shock in the benchmark environment
with debt. In the period of the shock, the government issues new public debt and
increases the labor income tax slightly as well. Therefore, the impact e¤ect of the
shock resembles its e¤ect when government expenditure is …nanced with lumpsum taxes (…gure 1). In the following periods, both public debt and labor income
taxes increase; as taxes increase the behavior of the model resembles that in the
case where labor income taxes …nance government spending (…gure 2). After the
public debt returns to its steady-state level, the response of all variables equals
the impact response from …gure 2. The overshooting that occurs in intermediate
periods is generated by the dynamics of the tax rule.
Productivity shock to nontraded goods sector Figure 4 plots the re­
sponse to a 1% permanent increase in productivity in the home nontraded goods
sector when the government balances its budget with lump-sum taxes. This shock
generates a negative price di¤erential, with the home price level decreasing about
0:5% and the foreign price level increasing about 0:15%. With optimal risk shar­
ing, the fall in the home relative price is associated with a fall in the ratio of
marginal utilities of consumption across countries and an increase in home rela­
tive consumption.
In response to this shock, home producers of nontraded goods lower their
prices. Due to the presence of distribution costs, the fall in nontraded goods
prices also reduces the consumer price of home and foreign traded goods in the
home country, but relatively less than the fall in the price of nontraded goods.
Home consumption increases for all goods and real output increases in the home
country; increased home demand for foreign traded goods also raises foreign real
output. The foreign household, whose productivity has not changed, works more
and the home household works less by substituting hours away from the relatively
more productive sector.
The magnitude of the response to this shock changes little when we consider
the alternative options for public revenue, namely distortionary taxes and public
debt. In fact, when labor income taxes are the only source of public revenue
available, the response of these taxes to the shock is small, implying that the
response of all variables is not a¤ected signi…cantly by the revenue sources at the
government’s disposal.
given sequence of distortionary taxes. We are explicitly concerned with the interaction between
debt and tax rates, as parameterized in equation (2.13); debt matters because the tax rate
responds to it.

18

In contrast to a shock to nontraded goods productivity, a permanent produc­
tivity shock to the traded goods sector in one country generates a small price
di¤erential. In fact, for our benchmark calibration, a 1% increase in productivity
in the home traded goods sector generates a negative home price di¤erential of
0:03 percentage points. The sign of this price di¤erential contrasts with the textbook Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect, where, in response to higher productivity in the
traded goods sector, a country experiences an increase in its price level relative to
the foreign country.19 In our model, the sign of the price di¤erential associated
with a shock to productivity in the traded goods sector hinges on the value of the
elasticity of substitution between home and foreign traded goods, °.
A permanent shock to home productivity in the traded goods sector leads a
producer of these goods to lower its price relative to the price of foreign traded
goods. For high values of ° , or high elasticity of substitution between home and
foreign goods, both home and foreign agents substitute more towards the home
traded good and away from the foreign traded good in response to a given decline
in the relative price of home traded goods. Therefore, the higher is °, the bigger is
the response of home traded goods output relative to foreign traded goods output
and the bigger is the increase in home wage relative to foreign wage to induce
the home households to produce relatively more traded goods. That is, for high
values of ° the real wage increases relatively more in the home country and the
home price level increases relative to the foreign price level, a prediction in line
with the textbook Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect. For low values of °, the real wage
increases relatively more in the foreign country because agents do not substitute
as much towards home traded goods, and the price level increases in the foreign
country relative to the home country. We choose a value of ° – 1.5 – that is
standard in the literature. Yet, in our model this implies that the conventional
Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect does not hold.

5. Fiscal Policy and In‡ation Di¤erentials
Because we model the government spending process as exogenous, if a regional
…scal authority wishes to in‡uence the behavior of regional in‡ation relative to
the rest of the monetary union, its sole means for doing so is to move the labor
income tax.20 To study the feasibility and e¤ectiveness of policies aimed at stabi19 See,

for example, Obstfeld and Rogo¤ (1995), page 210.
assume that if a region wishes to a¤ects its in‡ation rate, it recognizes the dominance
of the central bank in determining the overall level of in‡ation, and concentrates on the regional
20 We

19

lizing in‡ation relative to the union, we vary the parameter ®pt; which represents
feedback from the regional in‡ation di¤erential to the tax rate.21 To summarize
the e¤ects of changes in the policy rule, we simulate the model using the shock
processes described above, and illustrate the relationship between the volatility of
the in‡ation di¤erential and that of output, the de…cit/GDP ratio, and the tax
rate.
For our benchmark case of equal sized countries, the results are presented in
…gure 5. Figure 5.b displays the relationship between ®pt and the endogenous
volatility of the in‡ation di¤erential, as measured by its standard deviation in
percentage points.22 Figure 5.b shows that a region within a currency union can
reduce the volatility of its in‡ation di¤erential relative to the rest of the union by
responding to the in‡ation di¤erential with a negative coe¢cient in the tax rule.
In fact, by choosing a strongly negative coe¢cient on the in‡ation di¤erential, a
region can essentially force its in‡ation rate to move with that of the rest of the
union. Furthermore, this nominal stability does not carry with it instability in real
output; …gures 5.A and 5.B together show that as the tax rule coe¢cient on the
in‡ation di¤erential is reduced, both the variance of the in‡ation di¤erential and
the variance of output fall. However, output volatility is an equilibrium response
to given shock processes; decreases in output volatility should not be thought of as
necessarily welfare-enhancing. This idea is reinforced by …gure 5.C, which shows
the locus of tax rate and in‡ation di¤erential variances. Locally, introducing a
negative coe¢cient on in‡ation in the tax rule reduces the variance of the tax rate,
but changes in the tax rule that lead to signi…cant stabilization of the in‡ation
di¤erential also lead to signi…cantly greater volatility of the distortionary tax
rate. Finally, …gure 5.D illustrates the relationship between the volatility of the
in‡ation di¤erential and the frequency with which an arbitrary 3% de…cit to GDP
ratio is exceeded.23 The Stability and Growth Pact imposes a 3% limit on the
de…cit to GDP ratio for member countries of the European Monetary Union. Even
in‡ation di¤erential relative to the unionwide average.
21 In terms of units, ®
pt is the level derivative of the tax rate with respect to the in‡ation
di¤erential. For example, if ®pt = ¡1:0; then an in‡ation di¤erential of one percentage point
would decrease the tax rate by one percentage point compared to a situation with zero in‡ation
di¤erential.
22 We plot this relationship with the in‡ation volatility on the horizontal axis, instead of the tax
rule parameter, because the other panels relate in‡ation volatility to other statistics involving
endogenous variables.
23 The probability that the de…cit exceeds three percent of GDP is a monotonic transformation
of the volatility of the de…cit to gdp ratio.

20

without a tax rule response to in‡ation, the 3% bound is violated quite frequently
– almost 40% of the time – and the frequency increases slightly with policies which
substantially reduce the volatility of the in‡ation di¤erential.
Fundamentally, volatility in any of the endogenous variables is a result of
volatility in productivity and government spending. Thus, the tax rule alters
endogenous volatility by altering the response to productivity shocks and govern­
ment spending shocks. Recall from above that shocks to nontraded productivity
and to government spending, as opposed to traded goods productivity, are pri­
marily responsible for the volatility of price di¤erentials.24 In response to a shock
to home nontraded productivity, we saw that the home country’s output rose and
its relative in‡ation rate fell. This was in response to a simple permanent shock,
as opposed to a shock to the more complicated calibrated process. However, the
same qualitative response occurs to a calibrated shock. When the home …scal
authority responds with a negative coe¢cient on the in‡ation di¤erential, this
tends to raise the home tax rate relative to the benchmark case. The higher tax
rate inhibits labor supply, consumption rises less than in the benchmark case, and
output actually falls. In addition, home relative to foreign consumption rises less
than in the benchmark case. Complete risk sharing implies that the smaller increase in home relative consumption translates into a smaller decrease in the home
relative price level. In response to non-traded goods productivity shocks then, a
regional …scal policy that responds to in‡ation di¤erentials with a negative sign
has the e¤ect of decreasing the variance of in‡ation di¤erentials and output.
In the case of government spending, we saw above that a simple random walk
shock raised home output. Relative to the foreign country, the shock lowered home
consumption and raised the home price level and tax rate. The same qualitative
response occurs with our calibrated shock. When the regional …scal authority
puts a negative coe¢cient on the in‡ation di¤erential, it responds by decreas­
ing the home tax rate. This increases labor supply, amplifying the increase in
output in the home country. But, the tax response also has the e¤ect of decreas­
ing the consumption di¤erential across countries, and with complete risk-sharing
this translates into a decrease in the in‡ation di¤erential. Thus, with respect to
government spending shocks, …scal policy that responds to in‡ation di¤erentials
induces a negative relationship between volatility of output and that of in‡ation
24 It

is worth (foot)noting, however, that this does not imply that volatility of the price dif­
ferential for nontraded goods accounts for the volatility of overall in‡ation di¤erentials. In
fact, most of the volatility of price di¤erentials across countries in the model is attributable to
volatility of the price di¤erential for traded goods.

21

di¤erentials. Because the positive relationship attributable to productivity shocks
is stronger, the overall e¤ect of the …scal response to in‡ation is to a¤ect volatility
of output and the in‡ation di¤erential in the same direction.
Conventional wisdom – associated with a Phillips curve – would say that in
order to decrease the volatility of the in‡ation di¤erential a region’s …scal author­
ity should respond to in‡ation di¤erentials with contractionary policy. Without a
Phillips curve we …nd that in order to decrease the volatility of the in‡ation dif­
ferential, the regional …scal authority lowers the tax rate in response to a positive
in‡ation di¤erential.

6. Country Size and In‡ation Di¤erentials
Within the European Monetary Union, many of the discussions of regional in‡a­
tion di¤erentials have concerned small countries, for example Ireland and Portugal.
To study the role of country size, we vary the home country’s relative population,
N=(N + N ¤ ):
Figure 6 displays the same loci as Figure 5, this time for a country that com­
prises one-third of the union’s population, compared to one-half in the previous
…gures. First, note that in Figure 6.B, changes in the tax feedback rule have
roughly the same e¤ect on the in‡ation di¤erential for the small country as they
do in the symmetric case. And, tax rate volatility has a similar relationship to
in‡ation di¤erential volatility as in the symmetric case. However, for a small coun­
try the relationship between the variances of output and the in‡ation di¤erential
is u-shaped instead of positive; decreasing the standard deviation of the in‡ation
di¤erential by more than about 30% means increasing the variance of output.
To understand the di¤erence between the small and symmetric cases we focus
on the interaction of traded goods productivity shocks with country size. A decrease in relative population raises the country’s level of openness, as measured
by its export share of GDP.25 Greater openness leads to increased importance
of traded goods productivity shocks in accounting for volatility of in‡ation dif­
ferentials. We might then expect that when …scal policy responds to in‡ation
di¤erentials, traded goods productivity shocks drive the relationship between the
25 The

relationship between country size and export share follows from the risk sharing condi­
tion which equates per capita marginal utilities. In the case in which ¾ = a = 1, this condition
equates per capita nominal expenditure across countries. Then, to the extent that per capita
expenditure is equated for each traded good, smaller countries must have higher export shares.
For our calibration, this simple condition does not hold but we …nd the same qualitative result.

22

volatility of in‡ation di¤erentials and the volatility of output. This is indeed the
case. The dashed line in …gure 6 shows that, with only traded goods productivity
shocks, there would be a negative relationship between the volatilities of the in‡a­
tion di¤erential and output. For symmetric countries this relationship would be
positive. For other shocks there are no signi…cant di¤erences between the small
country and symmetric cases.
To understand why the dashed line has a negative slope for a small country
we turn to the response to a traded productivity shock. For a small country, such
a shock causes a positive in‡ation di¤erential, whereas for the symmetric case it
generates a tiny negative in‡ation di¤erential.26 Thus, when we allow the tax rule
to respond to the in‡ation di¤erential with a negative coe¢cient, for the small
country this means the tax rate falls in response to a traded goods productivity
shock. For the large country the tax rate instead rises slightly, and output does
not rise as much as in the small country.

7. Conclusion
This paper investigates the extent to which regional …scal policy can a¤ect the
behavior of regional in‡ation in a general equilibrium model of a two-region cur­
rency union. We …nd that a regional …scal authority can decrease the absolute
value of its in‡ation di¤erential in response to the shocks driving the model by
lowering (raising) the distortionary tax rate in response to positive (negative) in­
‡ation di¤erentials. By simulating the model with calibrated exogenous processes
we …nd that the e¤ect on the volatility of output of …scal policies that lower the
volatility of the in‡ation di¤erential depends critically on the relative size of the
two regions. While for symmetric regions lower volatility of in‡ation di¤erentials
is associated with lower volatility of output, in the case of a small region the
former comes about with an increase in the volatility of output.
An alternative speci…cation of the …scal policy response to in‡ation would
work through government spending. There is a tradition of treating government
spending as exogenous; we followed this tradition and thus it was natural for taxes
to be the instrument of …scal policy. We conjecture that under the alternative
speci…cation, the implications of …scal policy responding to in‡ation di¤erentials
would mirror those described here.27
26 The

small country thus experiences a traditional Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect. It appears that
the value of ° above which there is a Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect is increasing in country size.
27 We have in mind that decreases in government spending would imply decreases in the tax

23

We assumed that prices are ‡exible. Our focus on the behavior of in‡ation
di¤erentials does not require that the model contain any mechanism for monetary
non-neutrality. Flexible prices simplify the model substantially while allowing us
to address our question of interest. Nevertheless, it would be natural to add price
stickiness to the model. Our model predicts too much variability of the in‡ation
di¤erential when compared to the data. Price stickiness might be necessary for
the model to match the observed variability of in‡ation di¤erentials. In addition,
price stickiness would lead to meaningful time-variation in distortions. It would
be interesting to study the e¤ect on these distortions of …scal policies that respond
to in‡ation di¤erentials. We are pursuing these issues in ongoing work (see Duarte
and Wolman [2002] for a preliminary version).
This paper addressed solely positive questions raised by the use of …scal policy
to a¤ect in‡ation di¤erentials in a currency union. Our emphasis on positive ques­
tions was motivated by the attention that has been focused recently on national
in‡ation in EMU member countries. Speci…cally, there have been suggestions
that countries should pursue policies aimed at a¤ecting their national in‡ation
rates. We study the feasibility and e¤ectiveness of such policies. Nonetheless, the
same developments in Europe also naturally motivate studying optimal …scal and
monetary policies in a currency union.

rate. Therefore, responding to in‡ation di¤erentials by decreasing government spending would
be equivalent to responding by decreasing the tax rate directly.

24

References
[1] Basu, S. and J. Fernald (1997), “Returns to Scale in U.S. Production: Esti­
mates and Implications,” Journal of Political Economy 105. 249-283.
[2] Basu, S. and M. Kimball (1997), “Cyclical Productivity and Unobserved
Input Variation,” NBER Working Paper no. 5915.
[3] Baxter, M. and R. King (1993), “Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium,”
American Economic Review 83, 315-334.
[4] Beetsma, R. and H. Jensen (2002), “Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions
in a Micro-Founded Model of a Monetary Union,” European Central Bank
Working Paper no. 166.
[5] Benigno, P. (2002), “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Currency Area,” Journal
of International Economics, forthcoming.
[6] Bergin, P. (2000), “Fiscal Solvency and Price Level Determination in a Mon­
etary Union,” Journal of Monetary Economics 25, 37-53.
[7] Bergin, P. (2001), “One Money One Price? Pricing to Market in a Monetary
Union,” mimeo, Department of Economics, University of California at Davis.
[8] Betts, C. and M. Devereux (1999), “The International E¤ects of Monetary
and Fiscal Policy in a Two-Country Model,” mimeo, Department of Eco­
nomics, University of British Columbia.
[9] Canova, F. and E. Pappa (2003), “Price Dispersions in Monetary Unions:
The Role of Fiscal Shocks,” CEPR Discussion Paper no. 3746.
[10] Cecchetti, S., N. Mark, and R. Sonora (2002), “Price Level Convergence
Among United States Cities: Lessons for the European Central Bank,” In­
ternational Economic Review 43, 1081-1099.
[11] Chari, V. V., P. Kehoe and E. McGrattan (2002), “Can Sticky Prices Models
Generate Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange Rates?,” Review of Economic
Studies 69 (3), 533-563.
[12] Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1998), “Monetary Policy Rules in Prac­
tice: Some International Evidence,” European Economic Review 42 (6), 10331067.
25

[13] Collard, F. and H. Dellas (2002), “Exchange Rate Systems and Macroeco­
nomic Stability,” Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 571-599.
[14] Duarte, M. (2003), “Relative Price Levels in a Simple Two-Country Model,”
mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
[15] Duarte, M. and A. L. Wolman (2002), “Regional In‡ation in a Currency
Union: Fiscal Policy vs. Fundamentals,” European Central Bank Working
Paper No. 180.
[16] Johnson, R. (2001), “Fiscal Reaction Rules in Numerical Macro Models,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper no. 01-01.
[17] Mendoza, E. (1995), “The Terms of Trade, the Real Exchange Rate, and
Economic Fluctuations,” International Economic Review 36 (1), 101-137.
[18] Monacelli, T. (2001), “Relinquishing Monetary Policy Independence,”
mimeo, Department of Economics, Boston College.
[19] Mundell, R. (1961), “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American
Economic Review 51, 657-665.
[20] Mitchell, P., J. Sault, and K. Wallis (2000), “Fiscal Policy Rules in Macroeco­
nomic Models: Principles and Practice,” Economic Modelling 17, 171-193.
[21] Parsley, D. and S.-J. Wei (1996), “Convergence to the Law of One Price
Without Trade Barriers or Currency Fluctuations,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 111, 1211-1236.
[22] Rogers, J. (2001), “Price Level Convergence, Relative Prices, and In‡ation
in Europe,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International
Finance Discussion Paper no. 699.
[23] Sims, C. (1999), “The Precarious Fiscal Foundations of EMU,” mimeo, De­
partment of Economics, Princeton University.
[24] Stockman, A. and L. Tesar (1995), “Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country
Model of the Business Cycle: Explaining International Comovements,” Amer­
ican Economic Review 85 (1), 168-185.
[25] Taylor, J. (1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” CarnegieRochester Conference on Public Policy 39, 195-214.
26

Figure 1. Response to a government
spending shock, with lump sum taxes
(home = solid foreign = dashed)

all variables are measured in percent deviations from steady state

Figure 2. Response to a government
spending shock, with distortionary taxes
(home = solid foreign = dashed)

all variables are measured in percent deviations from steady state

Figure 3. Response to a government spending
shock; distortionary taxes respond to debt
(home = solid foreign = dashed)

all variables are measured in percent deviations from steady state

Figure 4. Response to a nontraded
productivity shock, with lump sum taxes
(home = solid foreign = dashed)

Figure 5. Implications of varying degrees of tax
rule response to the regional inflation differential
(x-axis is standard dev. of inflation differential)

Figure 6. Small country, with tax rule response to inflation differential

(x-axis is standard dev. of inflation differential)

with traded goods
productivity
shocks only