View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Early Development

WP 94-02

Marvin Goodfriend
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
John McDermott
University of South Carolina

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Early Development*
Marvin Goodfriend and John McDermott**

January 1994

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 94-2
ABSTRACT: Long-term economic development involves four fundamental processes:
the exploitation of increasing returns to specialization, the transition from household to market
production, knowledge and human capital accumulation, and industrialization. In this paper, we
integrate these processes into a coherent framework for thinking about economic history. Preindustrial development is driven by increasing returns to specialization made possible by a
growing population. Increasing specialization eventually activates a learning technology and
initiates industrial growth, which carries the economy to a fully market-based balanced-growth
path. Among other things, we attribute a role to population and market size that is consistent
with the evidence.
JEL Nos. N1, 011
Keywords: growth, development, technology, population, familiarity, human capital

*

This paper appears in the March 1995 American Economic Review. It was begun while both authors were
visiting the Graduate School of Business of the University of Chicago. The work has benefited greatly from
presentations at the American Economic Association Meetings, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, James
Madison University, the Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank Conference On Growth and Development,
Northwestern University, Ohio State University, Rutgers University, the Stanford NBER Growth Conference,
the University of British Columbia, the University of Chicago, the University of Kentucky, the University of
Rochester, the University of South Carolina, the University of Virginia, Virginia Polytechnic University, and
the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania.
**

Goodfriend: Research Dept, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, P.O. Box 27622, Richmond, VA, 23261.
McDermott: Economics Dept, University of South Carolina, Columbia, SC, 29208.

Economic growth since the Industrial Revolution has been truly remarkable. Angus
Maddison (1982) estimated, for a sample of sixteen industrialized countries, that total product
increased sixty-fold and per capita product rose thirteen-fold since 1820.1 This extraordinary
performance is even better appreciated by contrasting it with prior historical experience. Table 1,
also from Maddison, presents population and per capita product growth rates since 500 AD.
Although the numbers are highly aggregated both across countries and over time, and are
obviously imprecise, they tell a dramatic story.
For the thousand years following the fall of Rome, there was little net progress in
population and none in per capita product. From 1500 to 1700, progress was also very poor,
although population growth doubled and per capita product began to grow slightly.2 The period
from 1700 to 1820 was marked by a doubling of both population and per capita product growth
compared to the preceding two hundred years, although per capita growth was still very poor by
today's standards.3
Improvement in transportation, particularly during the latter period, helped break down the
isolation of self-sufficient villages and greatly increased the scope for economies of scale and
specialization. Such progress prompted Adam Smith (1776) to observe that productivity gains
were made possible by the division of labor, which in turn was limited by the extent of the market.
In his day, markets grew not only because of rising population, but also because improved
transportation greatly enlarged regional markets for many goods and services.
From 1820 to 1980 population growth again more than doubled compared to the previous
hundred and twenty years. This time, however, growth in per capita product increased eight-fold,
reflecting the startling jump in technological improvement and productivity growth associated with
industrialization.
The rise of urban population in Europe indicates the extent to which specialization
associated with the division of labor accompanied economic development. For towns of five
thousand or more, Paul Bairoch (1988) estimates urban population in 1000 AD. at about 10% of
the total, rising only slightly to 12% by 1700. Urbanization quickened over the next hundred and
1

Table 1 — Performance Characteristics of Four Eras
Average Annual Compound Growth Rates
Era

Population

Per Capita GDP

500-1500

0.1

0.0

1500-1700

0.2

0.1

1700-1820

0.4

0.2

1820-1980

0.9

1.6

Source: Maddison (1982), Table 1.2, p.6. The sample includes sixteen countries, twelve
from Europe, plus Australia, Canada, Japan, and the U.S.A.

fifty years with urban population rising to 19% of the total by 1850. But the pace exploded after
that, bringing urban population to 67% of the total by 1980.4 The trend in city dwelling thus
mirrors the growth in population and per capita product over the same long history.
In the late 1700s and early 1800s there occurred the great break with the past that we call
the Industrial Revolution. The Industrial Revolution was marked by a widespread systematic
application of empirical knowledge and methods to the production of goods and services.
Attempting to understand the onset of industrialization, David Landes (1969) pointed out that
many technical improvements became feasible only after advances in associated fields. The steam
engine is the classic example of this. In the 1800s, know-how associated with the division of labor
had progressed sufficiently that the search for technological improvements became routine and
productive. Widespread innovation, in turn, created more specialized knowledge which further
raised the productivity of time devoted to innovation. In this way, the Industrial Revolution
initiated the cumulative, self-sustaining, technical improvements that give rise to modern economic
growth.
Our paper presents a model motivated by the broad picture of early development described
above. The history of our model economy spans three epochs separated by two great transitions:
a pre-market period prior to the appearance of cities, pre-industrial market development prior to
the Industrial Revolution, and industrial growth since. Population is initially too small to support a
market sector. But if the population continues to grow, the market sector eventually opens. This
first transition corresponds to the initial formation of cities, perhaps five or six thousand years ago
[Bairoch (1988), Part 1]. The model then generates a long pre-industrial period in which growth in
per capita product is tied to population growth. This is followed by an Industrial Revolution, after
which productivity grows endogenously regardless of the growth of population.5
In the model, per capita product grows as production shifts from primitive processes to
market-based specialized techniques. The model economy is slow to specialize in the preindustrial period if the population grows slowly, reflecting the relatively slow pace of urbanization
prior to the Industrial Revolution. But thereafter, the pace of modernization quickens, reflecting
2

the rapid urbanization that accompanied industrialization.
Each household in our model is endowed with a primitive, diminishing-returns technology
allowing it to produce its own consumption goods. A purely primitive economy is one in which all
goods production is carried out by each household independently using this technology. There is
also a market technology that exhibits increasing returns due to specialization along the lines of
Paul Romer (1987, 1990).6
Once the market sector has opened, continuing population growth enables the economy to
benefit more fully from increasing returns. The growing population raises market sector wages
and lowers the primitive sector marginal product, thereby causing the market sector to expand at
the expense of the primitive sector. Our model thus reproduces the stylized fact emphasized by
Luis Locay (1990) that production shifts from households to firms as the economy develops. It
also embodies Smith's (1776) idea that the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market.
Population is the scale factor governing the size of the market in the pre-industrial period,
although we recognize that other factors, such as transportation costs, also help determine market
size.
Productivity gains during the pre-industrial period arise primarily from an ever-finer
division of labor without much improvement in fundamental productive techniques themselves.
The pre-industrial period in our model economy is one in which households choose to remain in a
"no-learning corner" in the sense that they devote no time to devising fundamental improvements
in technology. They choose not to innovate because learning productivity depends on the
economy-wide degree of specialization, and initially the specialized market sector is too small to
make learning productive. The idea is that innovation involves problem solving which, in turn, is
facilitated by access to specialized tools and techniques.
An Industrial Revolution occurs in our model when the growing population expands the
specialized market sector to the point where households finally choose to leave the no-learning
corner. Thus, we associate industrialization with learning that yields fundamental improvements in
technology.7 We do not have physical capital in our model. Instead we index the state of
3

technological know-how by the stock of human capital. The accumulation of human capital
initiated by the Industrial Revolution enables endogenous per capita productivity growth to take
place independently of the population growth rate, and greatly speeds the transition from primitive
to market-based production techniques.
When the transition is complete the economy attains a path, consistent with the stylized
facts of modern growth [see Nicholas Kaldor (1961) and Romer (1989)], along which time
allocations are constant and per capita product grows at a constant rate. This is more familiar
territory, given the work of Hirofumi Uzawa (1965), Robert E. Lucas (1988), and Sergio Rebelo
(1991) among others, though the engine of endogenous growth in our model closely resembles
that in Romer (1987).
Conditions for industrialization have recently been studied in three important papers.
Kevin Murphy, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny (1989) show how a backward economy could
raise per capita product by coordinating investment in a big push. Gary S. Becker, Murphy, and
Robert Tamura (1990) produce a model with two kinds of equilibria: a "Malthusian" one with
large families, little human capital, and no growth, and a "Development" equilibrium with small
families and rising living standards. A development trap is also present in the paper by Costas
Azariadis and Allan Drazen (1990). All three papers are primarily concerned with the possibility
of multiple steady states and how this might account for observed differences across countries.
We, however, focus on explaining how a long period of slow pre-industrial development
eventually triggers an Industrial Revolution that leads to modern balanced growth.
We recognize that a population-driven model of development such as ours must confront a
puzzle. How can a model that relies on increasing returns to labor be consistent with the lack of
evidence that per capita product rises with population? And how can such a model explain why
some of the world's most populous countries have such low per capita income?
Two features of our model allow us to address this population puzzle. First, scale in the
sense of a sufficiently large population (or market size) is a necessary pre-condition for industrial
growth. But human capital, not more bodies, is the decisive scale factor during industrial growth.
4

Second, per capita product can differ enormously among countries depending on the relative sizes
of their primitive and market sectors. Since the timing of the Industrial Revolution does not
depend entirely on population, but also involves the three technologies — primitive, market, and
learning — more heavily populated countries need not pass through the transition most quickly.
To sum up, ours is a model in which population growth is advantageous primarily because
of its effect on the timing of the switch to industrial growth, not because of its direct effect on per
capita product growth. Think of a race in which participants must first crawl 1,000 meters and then
get into race cars. A racer who is 1% faster at crawling will be about 1% farther ahead in the first
phase of the race (pre-industrial growth). Once at least one racer has begun to drive (industrialize),
however, small differences in the rates of crawl will lead to huge differences in relative positions.
The plan of the paper is as follows. The market-based production function is derived in
Section I. The technology for accumulating human capital is motivated and described in Section
II; and Section III presents the primitive technology. We then study early development, first
without human capital accumulation in Section IV, and then with learning in Section V, where we
discuss the timing of the Industrial Revolution. The population puzzle is discussed in Section VI,
and a brief summary concludes the paper.

I. Market Production With Specialized Inputs
Market-based final good production uses labor and intermediate goods as follows:
(1)

Y = (e Y hN)

1−α

∫

M
0

[x (i)]

α

di ,

where 0 < α < 1. There are N workers in the economy each of whom possesses human capital h
and devotes a fraction of time eY to the production of final goods. Total effective work effort
engaged in final goods production is thus eY h N. The x (i) are the quantities of distinct
intermediate inputs indexed by i and arranged on a continuum of measure M. Thus, M denotes the
range of intermediate inputs. Our final-good technology is a straightforward extension of that in
Wilfred Ethier (1982) and Romer (1987) to incorporate human capital.
We model the production of intermediate goods as in Romer (1987), except that effective
5

labor is the primary factor instead of capital. The effective-labor cost of producing the quantity x
of any intermediate good is b (x) / h. Therefore, the cost in terms of workers with the minimum
human capital (h = 1) is just b (x). We assume that b ( 0 ) = 0, b (ε) > 0 for ε > 0, b´(x) > 0, and
b´´(x) > 0.
The market sector must satisfy two labor-market clearing conditions. First, total work
effort involved in producing intermediate goods must equal its supply:
(2)

M

b(x)
=e I N .
h

Here eI is the fraction of time an individual devotes to intermediate-good production. Second,
individual effort utilized by both final and intermediate-good firms must equal total work effort,
eM, supplied to the market sector :
(3)

eY + eI = eM .

At this stage, we take eM as given, and let firm demands allocate the total between intermediate and
final-good firms.
Each final-good firm chooses labor hours and intermediate inputs to maximize profit,
taking the final-good wage, w, and the final-good prices of the intermediate inputs, pi , as given.
Setting marginal products equal to relative prices and exploiting the symmetry in (1) yields:
−α

(4)

w = (1−α ) (e Y hN)

(5)

p i = p = α (e YhN)

hMx α ,

1−α

xα−1 .

The wage, w, is the competitively determined compensation per hour in units of the final good paid
to a worker with human capital of h. Symmetry implies that the price of each intermediate good
will be the same in equilibrium.
Each intermediate-good firm behaves like a monopolist, since it is aware that the demand
for its product is given implicitly from (5). Taking the wage, w, as given, each firm maximizes
profit,
(6)

Π = px − w
6

b (x)
,
h

by choosing x, substituting from (5) for p before undertaking the maximization.
Although each intermediate firm is a monopolist, each must earn zero profit in equilibrium.
If intermediate-firm profits were positive, new firms would arise to produce additional specialized
inputs: M would increase, eliminating the original profit. Setting (6) to zero, and using conditions
(2) – (5), results in:
(7)

e Y = (1−α ) e M ,

(8)

e I = αe M .
Using (2), (7), and (8), profit maximization and zero-profit yield:

(9)

x

b′(x)
=α ,
b(x)

which implicitly defines a constant equilibrium output level, ~
x , for each intermediate firm.
Conditions (2) and (8) yield the following expression for M, the range of intermediate
inputs or the degree of specialization:
M= α

(10)

e M hN
.
b(x)

Aggregate effective labor (eMh N) is the primary determinant of M. As the market sector grows, in
terms of the fraction of time worked (eM), human capital per person (h), or the labor force (N), it
becomes more and more specialized as the range of inputs that complement labor expands.
Our reduced-form production function, obtained by substituting (10) and (7)) into (1), is:
Y = A (e M hN)

(11)

2−α

,

~ ). The function exhibits increasing
where the productivity coefficient A ≡ α (1– α)1-α ~x α / b(x
returns to effective labor, eMh N.8
Substituting (7) and (10) into (4) yields a reduced-form expression for the wage:9
(12)

w = Ah 2−α (e M N)

1−α

.

An important feature of the model is that w rises with population and work effort. There is, at
bottom, only one factor of production, labor augmented with human capital. All output is

7

exhausted in compensating that factor, since w eM N = Y.

II. Human Capital Accumulation
Individuals can accumulate human capital by allocating current time to learning. Family
production of human capital depends, in part, on effective learning time, eLh n, where eL is time
spent learning, h is human capital per person, and n is the number of family members. The
productivity of learning time is enhanced by the economy-wide degree of specialization, M.
Learning does not use up intermediate inputs, but it is made more productive by access to
knowledge associated with the production and use of specialized inputs.10 For this reason, we
assume that the quantity of each intermediate input does not matter, but the range of such inputs
does.
Household acquisition of human capital is governed by the following:
˙
H

(13)

=

e L H1−γ M γ .

where H ≡ h n is the household's stock of human capital and 0 < γ < 1. The technology exhibits
diminishing returns to the family's stock of human capital and the range of intermediate inputs
separately.11
Equation (13) captures the idea that holding specialization, M, constant a household’s
learning time is more productive the greater its human capital. Conversely, holding household
human capital constant, learning time is more productive the greater the economy-wide degree of
specialization. We assume decreasing returns to the household's stock of human capital, H,
because limited human capabilities make it increasingly difficult for a household to increase its
knowledge. Development, however, raises the degree of specialization and offsets the decreasing
returns to accumulation, making balanced growth with human capital accumulation feasible.
Using (10) to eliminate M, we can write (13) as:
(14)

( )

˙ = e hn
H
L

γ
h a nf 
γ
 α ˜  e Ma ,
 b x 


1−γ 

()

8

where f is the constant number of households in the economy, and ha and eMa are, respectively,
economy-wide per capita averages of human capital and hours worked in the market sector. An
individual household takes ha and eMa as given when choosing its own time allocations.
If new family members are born with the average stock of household human capital,
without a family’s having to incur any (time) costs of education,12 we may write a per capita
accumulation equation of the following form:
γ
˙
h = δ e L h1−γ h a ,

(15)
where:

γ
δ≡ α f
e Ma γ .
b(x)

(16)

Our accumulation technology is similar to Lucas's (1988, eq. 13), but differs from his in
two important respects. Ours recognizes an external effect of the economy-wide average per capita
human capital, ha, on the productivity of an individual's learning time. And our δ depends on the
economy-wide average time devoted to market production, eMa. Both externalities enter through
the degree of specialization, M.13
Industrial development in our model relies on the notion that per capita human capital can
grow without bound. Thus, our human capital partly represents scientific knowledge that exists
outside of any individual. More than that, ours is a generalized sort of human capital that indexes
the economy-wide state of practical know-how.

III. Primitive Production
Each household has a primitive technology that allows it independently to produce a final
good. We assume that this output is a perfect substitute for the good produced with specialized
inputs in the market sector. A household’s primitive production function is:
(17)

YP = Bln (1 +e P n) ,

where YP is total household primitive production of final goods, eP is the fraction of time that each
household member works in the primitive sector, and B is the productivity coefficient. The product
9

ePn is the total household time allocated to primitive production. We choose this technology
because it exhibits diminishing returns to the labor input, and because the marginal product
reaches an upper bound at eP = 0. The latter property is not necessary for what follows, but is
convenient since it means that the primitive sector will be abandoned in finite time.
We conceive of primitive production as applying to virtually all household activities since,
at least until recently, home production utilized relatively simple and traditional techniques. For
those goods produced both at home and in the market, such as agricultural products, we regard as
primitive only that portion produced at home for domestic use with traditional techniques.
Three characteristics distinguish the primitive technology from the market production
process. First, each household operates its own primitive process independently, whereas market
processes employ workers from all households. Second, individual households are too small to
use specialized inputs economically with the primitive technology. Third, human capital does not
enhance labor productivity in the primitive production of goods. Only innate human capital (h = 1)
is relevant in the primitive sector.

IV. Pre-Industrial Market Development
In this section we analyze how an economy using the primitive household technology of
Section III transforms itself into a market economy using specialized intermediate inputs as
described in Section I. Exogenous population growth drives the development process. Initially,
population is too small to support the use of specialized intermediate inputs. Eventually, however,
rising population pushes the scale of operation to a critical point, at which time the market sector
becomes viable and specialized market processes come into use alongside the primitive sector.
This event corresponds to the formation of cities, perhaps five to six thousand years ago. We
show how ongoing population growth after that expands the market and shrinks the primitive
sector until the latter is shut down altogether.
To best illustrate the role of population growth in pre-industrial development, we assume
for now that conditions are such that there is no human capital accumulation (eL = 0). We analyze
10

accumulation in Section V.
The bottom curve in Figure 1 shows how, according to (12), the market sector wage
depends on per capita hours worked there, eM. The wage rises with eM because the market sector
is characterized by increasing returns to labor. Differentiating (12) shows this curve to be concave
to the horizontal axis. Moreover, as population, N, grows this curve rotates upwards around the
left-hand origin.
The top curve shows how, according to (17), the primitive-technology marginal product
per man-hour of labor, ∂ yP/ ∂ eP = B / (ePn + 1), depends on per capita hours allocated to that sector,
eP (measured from the right-hand origin). The right-hand intercept is the maximum marginal
product per man / hour, B, which is independent of household size. If the market sector wage rises
to B, it is optimal to shut down the primitive technology (set eP = 0). It is straightforward to verify
that this curve is convex to the horizontal axis. Because of diminishing returns to labor, the curve
rotates down over time as the population grows.
The width of the box, eP + e M, represents an individual’s allocation of work effort. Under
the assumption that eL = 0, this exhausts his total endowment of time, which we take to be 1.
Equilibrium requires that two conditions be satisfied. First, the market sector wage must
equal the primitive sector marginal product if both eP and eM are positive. Second, an (eP, eM)
allocation is an equilibrium only if an individual household has no incentive to deviate from it
when taking other households' allocations as given.
Figure 1 illustrates the case where population is small enough that the primitive-sector
marginal product curve lies everywhere above the market sector wage curve. When this is the case,
no equilibrium exists with eP and eM both positive, since there is no way for the market wage to
equal the primitive marginal product while eP and eM sum to unity.
This leaves either corner, point C or D, as a possible equilibrium. The second condition,
however, is not satisfied at point D, because if all households chose eM = 1 and eP = 0, then the
marginal product of work in the primitive sector would exceed the market-sector wage at D.
Hence, an individual household, taking everyone else's allocation (and, therefore, the market wage)
11

Marginal
Compensation
w

B
Marginal Product in the
Primitive Sector

Market

E
Primitive
Production C
Only

F

eM
Effort Devoted to
Market Work

D Production
Only

Market Sector Wage

eP
Effort Devoted to
Primitive Sector Work

Figure 1. The Purely Primitive Economy

as given would be better off shifting work effort to its own primitive technology up to point E. If
everyone did so, however, the market-sector wage would fall to point F. Repeating the argument, it
is clear that point C is the only equilibrium in Figure 1. So eP = 1 is the only equilibrium and the
economy remains purely primitive for a sufficiently small population.
Now let population grow. This drives the upper curve down and the lower curve up until,
eventually, a critical size is reached at which the two touch at a point like Z in Figure 2. This
tangency point satisfies both conditions mentioned above, so it represents a second equilibrium in
addition to the one at the eP = 1 corner. Importantly, the new equilibrium at point Z can support a
market sector.
Per capita consumption is higher in the interior equilibrium Z than at the corner
equilibrium. To see this, note that market-sector product per person is w eM, while primitive-sector
per capita product is the area under the upper curve, measured from the right to the equilibrium
eM. Therefore, an economy-wide move from eM = 0 to eM = eMz results in a net increase in
product per person.
When the tangency appears at Z, however, the economy is at the eP = 1 corner. The
equilibrium will remain there if individual households believe that everyone else will not move. On
the other hand, if each believes that everyone else will switch to eMz, then the equilibrium will jump
to Z. Which equilibrium will be selected is indeterminate. Given the potential gains in current and
future consumption, however, there is reason to believe that the jump would be made shortly after
it became feasible. We shall, at any rate, assume that market sector springs into existence as soon
as possible.14
Before proceeding further, note the nature of our theory of the appearance of cities. Cities
are not sustainable until population rises sufficiently, because primitive technology is simply too
productive relative to specialized market techniques when population is very small. Our theory is
consistent with the views of Ester Boserup (1965, 1981) who argues that population pressure in
early times, combined with the diminishing returns of primitive technologies, induced
technological improvements associated with the establishment of cities.
12

Marginal
Compensation
w

B
Marginal Product in the
Primitive Sector

U

Market
Sector
Wage

Z
V

eMZ
Optimal Effort Allocation
at the Opening of the
Market Sector

eMU
Optimal Effort Allocation
With a Larger Population

Figure 2. The Pre-Industrial Market Economy

The dashed lines in Figure 2 locate the primitive marginal product and the market wage
curves for a population that has grown beyond the critical level. As one can see, the Z allocation is
no longer an equilibrium with the larger population. Equilibrium is now at point U.15 Moreover, if
population continued to grow, the interior equilibrium would move to the northeast until it
eventually reached B, at which time the primitive technology would be abandoned completely.
Early development — the transition from a primitive economy to a fully specialized, market
economy — would then be complete.

V. Industrial Development and the Transition to
Modern Balanced Growth
In the previous section, development proceeded solely on the strength of increasing returns
to specialization made possible by a growing population. This reflects pre-industrial growth, in
which productivity gains arise from an ever-finer division of labor without much improvement in
fundamental productive techniques themselves. Industrialization, on the other hand, occurs when
fundamental improvements in technology come about following investment in human capital. In
our model, industrialization corresponds to learning which raises the rate of technological knowhow, allowing per capita product to grow without population growth. By raising the market sector
wage curve in Figure 2, human capital growth speeds the transition from the primitive to the
market economy. Thus, the model explains why early industrialization was associated with an
acceleration of the pace of urbanization.
We pointed out in the previous section that the primitive technology would be abandoned
once the rising market wage reached B. It is straightforward to show, once that happens, that the
fully market economy will follow a balanced growth path along which effort allocations are
constant and per capita product grows endogenously at a constant rate.16
Figure 3 illustrates the process by which the primitive economy attains modern balanced
growth. The upper panel shows the progress of per capita product; the lower panel shows how
effort is allocated between the three competing uses as development proceeds. As long as the
13

Log of
Per
Capita
Product

ln y

Time

Effort
Allocations
1
eP

eM
eL
Time

Purely
Primitive
Economy.

Pre-Industrial Market
Development. Scale
Rising Due To N
Growth.

Industrial
Development.
Scale Rising Due
To h and N
Growth.

Figure 3. Time Line

Fully
Market
Economy.

economy is purely primitive, per capita product falls as the population grows.17 There is an
immediate increase in living standards at the opening of the market, i.e. urban, sector. Thereafter,
effort shifts gradually from the primitive to the market sector as population continues to grow.
Even as the market sector expands, however, per capita product continues to fall before it begins to
rise (more on this in Section VI).
This economy will undergo an Industrial Revolution at some point prior to attaining fully
modern balanced growth, if and only if:
δ (1) > ρ − η ,

(18)

where ρ is the rate of time preference, η is the rate of population growth, and δ (1) refers to the
value of the learning productivity coefficient in (16) when eMa = 1. In other words, this economy
will industrialize if, at a position of no learning in modern balanced growth, the rate at which a
household can transform per capita consumption intertemporally by accumulating human capital
exceeds ρ - η, its net utility rate of time discount.
The Timing of the Industrial Revolution
In order to solve a forward-looking model such as this, one must always work backwards
from some kind of terminal condition. As mentioned above, instead of a terminal steady state, our
model has a terminal pattern of modern balanced growth. Assuming (18) is satisfied, to achieve
the optimal plan households must decide when to industrialize, i.e. initiate learning, with a view to
attaining the unique balanced growth path the instant the primitive technology is abandoned and
the economy becomes fully modern. Because development involves the gradual transition from a
diminishing returns primitive technology to an increasing returns market technology, its dynamics
are fundamentally non-autonomous in population and consequently are too complex to discuss
fully here. Goodfriend and McDermott (1992) contains a phase plane analysis of this economy’s
entire development path.
Industrialization is not an accident of history in our model; rather, it is a deliberate choice
made by forward-looking, decentralized household decision makers. Households in our economy
14

choose to fundamentally improve technology when it becomes efficient to do so. The timing of
this watershed event turns on the interaction of the primitive technology, market production
processes, the learning technology, population scale, and preferences.
By (16) it is feasible for households to begin to accumulate human capital through
learning once the market sector opens, but they will not do so. Human capital benefits individuals
in our model by raising the wage that they earn in the market sector. The wage can be expressed
as the product of an individual’s human capital and a base wage, i.e. w = wb h, where the base
wage,
w b = A (e Mah aN)

(19)

1−α

,

is the wage an individual would command if he had only 1 unit of human capital, given that the
economy average is ha ≥ 1 and average hours worked in the market sector is eMa. Since the base
wage is beyond the individual’s control, accumulating an additional unit of human capital raises
his wage in direct proportion.18
A marginal increase in human capital raises an individual’s market sector earnings by the
present discounted value of future increments, wb eM. In the early market period, few hours are
worked in the market sector, per capita human capital is unity, and population is small. Hence the
base wage is very low and the marginal consumption benefit to human capital is also low.
An individual's consumption opportunity cost of accumulating a unit of human capital is
the time cost, 1 / h δ (eMa), multiplied by the wage, wb h; i. e., wb / δ (eMa). Thus, both the benefit and
the cost of learning depend positively on the base wage and, as a first approximation, we can
ignore the marginal effect of wb on the benefit net of cost. In the early market period, however, we
are left with a benefit that is low relative to the cost because few hours are worked in the market
sector, and because the small size of the market sector restricts specialization, keeping learning
productivity δ (eMa) down.
In an equilibrium with representative agents, an individual’s work effort, eM, equals the
average value, eMa. A sufficiently small eM = eMa makes it inefficient to accumulate from the start.

15

Accumulation becomes efficient only when market work effort becomes large enough that the
present discounted value of the increments to future earnings exceeds the opportunity cost of the
learning time needed to accumulate human capital.
Several factors govern the timing of the Industrial Revolution and the speed with which a
society makes its transition from a primitive to a market economy. Using Figure 2 to analyze the
pre-industrial period, we see that faster population growth causes the market sector to open sooner
and speeds development thereafter. It is also apparent that the market sector opens later, the more
productive the primitive technology (the higher is B) and the less productive the market sector (the
lower is A). Likewise, development proceeds more slowly when the primitive technology exhibits
smaller diminishing returns and the market sector is characterized by smaller increasing returns.
The slower development of the market sector, in turn, limits learning productivity δ (eMa) and
delays industrialization.
These factors are not necessarily independent. For example, rapid population growth early
on may be associated with a highly productive primitive technology, a high B. If population
growth depends on the technology in this manner, there is little reason to expect a heavily
populated region to have developed rapidly, since its highly productive primitive technology would
have discouraged development of a market sector.
Our model suggests that different development experiences may be due to different
geographical initial conditions. To interpret different experiences in terms of our model, we would
need to understand how geographical factors account for differences in population growth,
primitive technologies, early market techniques, and learning productivities. We believe that the
primitive technology is critical in this, since it provides the foundation for population growth and
the specialized goods that arise initially.

VI. The Population Puzzle
Population plays a central role in our model of early development. It must grow to a
threshold level before the economy can support an urban-market sector, and must attain a second

16

critical level before industrialization can begin. If population were to stop growing prior to
triggering industrialization, development would cease.
Yet empirically, the relationship between population and per capita product appears weak.
Consider, for example, Kuznets's (1973, pp. 41 - 48) post-War cross-country evidence from a
sample of 63 developed and less-developed countries. He finds a statistically significant negative
correlation between population growth and growth in per capita product. But this negative
correlation is due entirely to the differences between the two groups of countries. Disaggregating,
he finds that the correlation becomes insignificant both for the developed group by itself and the
less-developed countries taken by themselves.
The negative correlation between groups arises because all high income countries have
gone through a transition from high fertility and mortality rates to low rates, due to improved
health care and the higher opportunity cost of having children.19 Thus, the higher income growth
appears to be the result of a high level of economic development, rather than a lower population
growth rate. Controlling for the level of economic development, Kuznets finds little correlation
between growth in population and growth in per capita product.
Since our model relies on increasing returns to population in the market sector, it would
seem to imply that the most populous countries should have the highest per capita product. Yet
this does not appear to be the case. Moreover, we must reconcile the central role of population in
our model with evidence that finds little correlation between population growth and per capita
output growth for either developed or less-developed countries.
Developed Countries
The increasing importance of human capital following the Industrial Revolution provides
some resolution of the population puzzle. The accumulation of human capital means that
population eventually becomes relatively unimportant for per capita product in fully developed
economies. To see this, use (11) to express per capita product in a fully market economy as:
(20)

y = A (e Mh)

2−α

17

N1−α .

Our model of increasing returns to specialization requires that 1– α > 0, no matter how
small. In fact, a small value for 1 – α is reasonable, since it makes for a longer transition to modern
balanced growth. If so, then (20) shows that we would not expect per capita product in a fully
market economy to be very sensitive to population. In contrast, per capita output would be
approximately proportional to both eM and h if 1 – α were near zero. The fraction of time spent
working is constant in balanced growth and one would not expect it to be a major source of
differences among national product levels. But the stock of human capital is unbounded, and can
potentially account for large discrepancies across countries. Hence, our model implies that human
capital per capita, rather than population, accounts for the diversity of per capita product across
developed nations. The model attributes differences in levels of h, in turn, to the fact that countries
have industrialized at different times, for reasons outlined in the last section.
As it stands, the model implies a positive but weak relationship between population growth
and per capita product growth. The direction of effect becomes ambiguous if the model is
modified to require a time cost to educate the newly born by subtracting the rate of population
growth, η, from the right-hand side of (15). In that case, as in Rebelo (1992), there would be a
negative effect on endogenous growth due to the fact that a higher rate of population growth
requires a higher saving (learning) rate to maintain a given growth rate of per capita product.
Less-Developed Countries
The continuing widespread use of primitive production processes alongside relatively
modern techniques is the most striking feature of less-developed countries (LDCs).20 In Figure 4
we see that the effect of population on per capita product is ambiguous for an economy that is still
largely primitive. The dark curves there determine an equilibrium at point G, so that per capita
output is the area under HGB. The dashed curves depict the situation after a period of population
growth. The equilibrium has moved to point I, where per capita product is now the area under JIB.
The net change in per capita output is JKGH less KBI. As drawn, per capita product falls slightly;
although it could have risen starting from a different (eM, eP) allocation.
18

Marginal
Compensation
B

w
Per Capita
Product Loss
Per Capita
Product Gain

K

J
H

I

G

eM
Effort Devoted to
Market Work

eP
Effort Devoted to
Primitive Sector Work

Figure 4. Per Capita Product During the Transition

Population growth can reduce the standard of living in LDCs because per capita product is
the average of output from a diminishing returns primitive technology and an increasing returns
market sector. Rising population forces down per capita product in the primitive sector. Although
per capita product in the market sector rises with population, N, the increase is slight if 1 – α is
near zero. Effort shifts to the market sector in response to the higher population, but the returns to
eM there may not be high enough to offset the diminishing returns in the primitive sector. The
effect of a population increase on per capita product is more likely to be negative the larger the
primitive sector, the larger the diminishing returns in the primitive sector, and the smaller the
increasing returns in the market sector.
Even though population growth may reduce per capita product temporarily in our model,
the cumulative effect of population during the entire transition to a fully market economy must be
positive. A related point is that per capita product may be considerably higher for countries at or
near the end of the transition, than for countries whose primitive sectors are still relatively large.
Countries that continue to produce a relatively large share of output with primitive techniques will
have low per capita product regardless of population size.
Our model reconciles two apparently contradictory notions about the influence of
population in LDCs. It emphasizes the role of population in driving the transition from a primitive
society to a market economy. But it also allows for the possibility that population growth could
actually reduce per capita product during the transition. Thus, our model explains how population
growth might appear detrimental to LDC development over some periods. The link between
population and per capita product is, of course, weakened further by industrialization. An increase
in human capital raises per capita product in LDCs because it raises the market wage without
shifting the primitive sector marginal product curve.
Taking a long, historical perspective, there is a U-shaped curve for per capita product as a
function of population (or time, assuming population is growing steadily) in the pre-industrial era.
This is shown in the time line of Figure 3. The U-shaped path for per capita product has two
important implications. First, the path could conceivably dip below a minimum subsistence level,
19

precluding further population growth. A binding subsistence constraint in the pre-industrial period
would leave the economy in a Malthusian trap in which development would cease. Second, the
effect on per capita product of an exogenous population shock due to war or plague, for example,
would depend on the society's position along this curve when the shock occurred. The model
implies that a plague in a relatively primitive society would raise output per person, even though it
would reduce it in a largely urbanized economy. The pre-industrial data summarized in the
introduction suggests that population raised per capita product after 1500 but had little effect prior
to that date.

VII. Conclusion
Long-term economic development involves four fundamental processes: the exploitation of
increasing returns to specialization, the transition from household to market production,
knowledge and human capital accumulation, and industrialization. In this paper, we integrated
these processes into a coherent framework for thinking about economic history.
The main propositions found in our paper are these:
(1) Population must grow to a threshold before our economy can support an urbanmarket sector. After this sector appears, rising population continues to shift effort
from the household to the market sector because the latter is more efficient at larger
scales of operation. The pace of urbanization is dictated by the rate of population
growth in the pre-industrial economy.
(2) Population must attain a second critical level to get industrial growth going. The
human capital or knowledge accumulation that characterizes modern industrial growth
does not begin until market size has expanded the range of specialized goods
sufficiently to make routine innovation worthwhile. Market size, perhaps through
trade, is a necessary precondition for industrialization.
(3) Two recently proposed “growth engines” – human capital and increasing returns to
specialization – are compatible so that human capital, not more bodies, is the decisive

20

factor during industrial growth. Increasing returns to scale in pre-industrial
development are consistent with the achievement of a fully modern balanced growth
path along which per capita product grows at a constant endogenous rate, regardless
of population growth.
(4) Population may increase or decrease per capita product in our model, depending on
the relative size of the primitive and market sectors. The reason is that per capita
product is an average of output from a diminishing returns primitive technology and
an increasing returns market technology. This insight helps explain how population
growth can be viewed as good for per capita product in some contexts, for example,
18th century Great Britain and 19th century United States, and bad in others, such as
modern-day China and India.
(5) Ours is a model in which population growth is advantageous primarily because of its
effect on the timing of the switch to industrial growth, not because of its direct effect
on per capita product growth. Faster population growth makes industrialization begin
sooner by speeding the transition from household to specialized market production
processes. A more productive primitive technology slows the transition and delays
industrialization. When faster population growth is associated with a more productive
primitive technology, however, the net effect on the timing of the switch to industrial
growth is uncertain.
(6) The hallmark of first-generation endogenous growth models is their ability to generate
perpetual growth in per capita product. The level of the output path, however, is
largely determined by initial conditions for the relevant capital stock variables.
Focusing on modern economic growth, rather than on long-term economic
development, as they do, first-generation models have been silent on initial conditions.
Our model, in contrast, focuses on the historical preconditions that give rise to fully
modern growth. It shows that different levels of per capita product in fully modern
economies are due, in part, to primitive geographical initial conditions, since these help
21

determine the timing of the switch to industrial growth and, thereby, the per capita
human capital that a country inherits from its past.
Our closed-economy model necessarily identifies pre-industrial market size with
population. In subsequent research [Goodfriend and McDermott (1993)], we analyze trade by
building regional labor market segmentation and transport costs into the model. Trade allows even
a relatively small country with access to a large world market to industrialize, although sufficient
local population is still necessary to support a market sector that can take advantage of trade. In
the open-economy model, regions may industrialize at different times because of variations in
local market size or varying proximity to world markets. However, population still determines
global market size and world population must still reach a critical scale before industrialization
occurs somewhere in the world.

22

Appendix: Household Maximization and Modern Balanced Growth
A household maximizes:

∫

(A1)

∞
0

n (t ) lnc (t ) e −ρt dt ,

where c is per capita consumption and family size n grows at rate η, by choosing effort allocations
eM(t) and eL(t), subject to the time constraint:
(A2)

e M +e L =1 ,

and the budget constraint,
(A3)

c =w b he M .
The household takes as given the path of the base wage, wb as expressed in (19) in the

text, but the wage that each member earns, w = wb h, depends on his own human capital.
A household saves by allocating time to learning. Human capital accumulation is governed
by (15) and (16). The productivity of learning time, eL, depends on the economy-wide averages ha
and eMa, whose paths the household also takes as given.
Two first-order conditions are necessary for a household optimum with learning. First, the
marginal utility value of eM and eL must be equal:
w bh
= q δh1−γ ha γ ,
c

(A4)

where q is the shadow utility value of human capital per capita. Second, q must evolve through
time according to:
(A5)

˙
γ
w e
q
= ρ − η − 1 − γ δ e L h−γ ha − b M ,
q
qc

( )

so that the utility capital gain on human capital, plus the marginal productive value of h in learning
and in enhancing wages, equals the net rate of discount. There is also a transversality condition:
(A6)

lim e−ρ t q (t ) h (t ) n (t ) = 0 .

t→ ∞

The learning technology (15) and (16) and the pricing equation (A5) govern the motion of
h and q that a household optimum plan must follow. Restricting household optimum choices to
23

equal economy-wide averages (so that eM = eMa and h = ha), we can use (A2), (A3), and (A4) to
eliminate eM and eL from the dynamic equations for h and q. The system can then be expressed in
terms of a single dynamic equation in q h that satisfies aggregate consistency.
The stationary value of q h uniquely satisfies transversality (A6) and yields constant
equilibrium effort allocations that generate balanced growth without transition dynamics. The
equilibrium eM allocation supporting modern balanced growth with learning is given implicitly by:
1 
ρ−η 
eM * =
γ+
< 1 ,
1+ γ  δ (e M *)

(A7)

where δ (eM) is expression (16) with aggregate consistency (eM = eMa) imposed. The balanced rate
of growth with learning is:
(A8)

˙
y
=
y

(2 − α ) δ (e M *) e L

24

(

)

+ 1− α η .

References
Azariadis, Costas and Drazen, Allan, “Threshold Externalities in Economic Development,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics , May 1990, 105, 501 - 526.
Bairoch, Paul, Cities and Economic Development, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.
Barro, Robert J. and Becker, Gary S., “A Reformulation of the Economic Theory of Fertility,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1988, 103, 1 - 25.
Becker, Gary S., Murphy, Kevin and Tamura, Robert, “Human Capital, Fertility, and Economic
Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, October 1990 (Part 2), 98, S12–S37.
Boserup, Ester, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agricultural Change
Under Population Pressure, Chicago: Aldine, 1965.
____________, Population and Technological Change: A Study of Long-Term Trends, Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1981.
Cairncross, A. K., Factors in Economic Development, New York: Praeger, 1962.
Cipolla, Carlo M., Before the Industrial Revolution: European Society and Economy, 1000-1700
(Second Edition), New York: Norton and Company, 1980.
Ethier, Wilfred J., “National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of
International Trade,” American Economic Review, June 1982, 72, 389-405.
Goodfriend, Marvin, and McDermott, John, “Early Development: Technical Analysis,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper, November 1992.
___________, “A Theory of Convergence, Divergence, and Overtaking,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Working Paper, September 1993.
Harris, Marvin, Cannibals and Kings: The Origins of Cultures, New York: Random House, 1977.
Kaldor, Nicholas, “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth”, in Lutz and Hague, eds., The
Theory of Capital, New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1961.
Kuznets, Simon, Population, Capital and Growth, New York: Norton, 1973.
Landes, David, The Unbound Prometheus, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.
Locay, Luis, “Economic Development and the Division of Production Between Households and
25

Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, October 1990, 98, 965 - 82.
Lucas, Robert E., “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 1988, 22, 3-42.
Maddison, Angus, Phases of Capitalist Development, New York: Oxford University Press, 1982.
McNeill, William H., Plagues and Peoples, New York: Doubleday, 1976.
Murphy, Kevin, Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert, “Industrialization and the Big Push,”
Journal of Political Economy, October 1989, 97, 1003-26.
Rebelo, Sergio, “Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political
Economy, June 1991, 99, 500-21.
_________, “Growth in Open Economies.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy (Allan H. Meltzer and Charles I. Plosser, eds.), July 1992, 36, 5 – 46. .
Reynolds, Lloyd, Economic Growth in the Third World, 1850 – 1980, New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1985.
Romer, Paul, “Growth Based on Increasing Returns Due to Specialization,” American Economic
Review, May 1987, 77, 56-62.
________, “Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long-Run Growth,” in R. Barro, Editor,
Modern Business Cycle Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989.
________, “Endogenous Technological Change,” Journal of Political Economy, October 1990,
98, S71 - S102.
Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations, New York: Modern Library, 1965. (Original 1776.)
Sokoloff, Kenneth, “Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence From Patent
Records, 1790 - 1846,” The Journal of Economic History, December 1988, 48, 813 - 47.
Stigler, George, “The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market.” Journal of
Political Economy, June 1951, 59, 185 - 93.
Uzawa, Hirofumi, “Optimum Technical Change in an Aggregative Model of Economic Growth,”
International Economic Review, January 1965, 6, 18-31.
Young, Allyn, “Increasing Returns and Economic Progress,” Economic Journal, December 1928,
26

38, 527-42.

27

Footnotes

1

Maddison (1982), p. 4.

2

Maddison notes that his estimates are below those of Simon Kuznets and David Landes, but

above those of Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie and Wilhelm Abel (Maddison, 1982, p. 7).
3

The flat population profile before 1700 was marked by two major declines due to epidemic

disease. The first occurred in the sixth and seventh centuries, the second in the fourteenth century.
Such devastating epidemics had tapered off by 1700, helping to make possible the sustained
growth in population that was to follow. See William McNeill (1976).
4

Bairoch (1988), Table 13.3, p. 219.

5

The switch from pre- to post-industrial growth in our model closely corresponds to the change

from “extensive” to “intensive” growth characterized by Lloyd Reynolds (1985).
6

Well-known discussions of specialization and the division of labor appear in George Stigler

(1951) and Allyn Young (1928).
7

Kenneth Sokoloff's (1988) analysis of patent records in early industrial America (1790 - 1846)

provides evidence that the onset of industrialization was characterized by a surge in the
commitment of resources to the search for advances in technology. While technological progress
did not begin with industrialization (see, for example, Carlo M. Cipolla (1980)), early innovations
arrived sporadically and slowly, whereas modern invention and innovation is routine and
widespread.
8

The source of increasing returns to effective labor is easily seen by rewriting (1) as
Y = [ (1 – α ) e h N]1 - α M ~x α. By (10), e h N has a unit elastic effect on Y through M. Holding
M

M

M constant, the elasticity of Y with respect to eM h N is 1 – α; so the total elasticity is 2 – α.
9

The wage cannot be found by differentiating (11), since it is determined by small firms who do

not benefit from the external effect of labor in increasing the degree of specialization.
10

Our intermediate goods, to use Romer's (1990) terminology, are both excludable and rivalrous

in final good production, but they are neither in the learning technology.
28

11

We follow Uzawa (1965), Lucas (1988) and Becker, Murphy and Tamura (1990) in assuming

constant returns to eL because it simplifies the solution for time allocations in balanced growth.
12

This assumption corresponds to adding the term ηH to (13), where η is the growth rate of

family size, n.
13

Strictly speaking, one can imagine a model in which learning involves intermediate goods but

there are no external effects on learning productivity. As long as there are uncompensated learning
productivity benefits associated with specialization, however, there will be external effects on
learning operating through M. Since the mere exposure and routine access to specialized goods
generates ideas that cannot be compensated, we think that as a practical matter the favorable effects
of specialization on learning involve important external effects.
14

Early empires appear to have used coercion and religion as coordinating devices to ensure the

movement to urban areas in order to realize gains from specialization. Although important and
interesting, a more complete treatment of government policy to foster urbanization, or to encourage
learning, is beyond the scope of this paper.
15

For a given population size, a point like V is also an equilibrium. We ignore such equilibria,

however, since they are not stable.
16

The effort allocations that support modern balanced growth are derived in the appendix.

17

Anthropologists generally agree that mankind enjoyed a sort of golden age in the Upper

Paleolithic period (35,000 to 10,000 BC) before the introduction of agriculture. With the
extinction of certain animals after the last ice age, however, living standards fell secularly as
population rose, and mankind domesticated plants and animals in an effort to restore its earlier
prosperity. For an analysis along these lines, see Marvin Harris (1977) as well as Boserup (1965,
1981).
18

The wage that an individual commands in the labor market can be written as the marginal

product of effective labor in final-goods production given M, ∂Y /∂ (eY h N), times the units of

29

effective labor that each hour of his time is worth, h. An individual with only the minimum human
capital (h = 1) just earns ∂Y /∂ (eY h N), the base wage, wb . Therefore, dividing (12) by h yields the
base wage.
19

On this point, see Barro and Becker (1988) and Becker, Murphy, and Tamura (1990).

20

See Cairncross (1962), p. 21.

30