View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 81-2

DISCOUNT WINDOW BORROWING, MONETARY POLICY,
AND THE POST-OCTOBER 6, 1979 FEDERAL
RESERVE OPERATING PROCEDURE*

Marvin Goodfriend

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Revised September 1, 1981

*The author is Research Officer and Economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond. Discussions with Tim Cook have been particularly
valuable. Thanks are also due to John Boschen, Bob Ring, Rich Lang,
Ben McCallum, John McDermott, Tom Mead, and Jerome Stein. The views
here are solely those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.

Introduction
This paper is intended to be an analysis of discount
window borrowing as it relates to 'more general issues of monetary
control.

The topic deserves a new look because of the central

role of discount window borrowing under the post-October 6, 1979
"reserve targeting" operating strategy.
The analytical core of the paper is the derivation of
a demand for borrowing function based on profit-maximizing
behavior.

bank

It is shown that a basic feature of the nonprice

rationing mechanism at the discount window causes the banks
to solve a dynamic optimization problem in deciding on optimal
current discount window borrowing.

The solution of this problem

for the structure of the borrowing demand function has
implications for the conduct of monetary policy.

These are

brought out in the latter sections of the paper.
Nonprice Rationing at the Discount Window
If there were no nonprice rationing at the discount
window, the Federal funds rate would never rise above the
discount rate, because a bank would never pay more for reserves
than it would have to pay at the discount window.

Since 1965,

the Federal funds rate has, on numerous occasions, risen above
the discount rate.

On two occasions it has remained above the

discount rate for roughly two years running.
-l-

This indicates

.-2that an effective form of nonprice rationing is xbeing administered
at the discount window.
The basis for this nonprice rationing is spelled out
in Regulation A.

The condition under which a bank is entitled

to "adjustment credit" at the discount window is stated in
Regulation A as follows:
Federal Reserve credit is available on a short-term
basis to a depository institution under such rules as
may be prescribed to assist the institution, to the
extent appropriate, in meeting temporary requirements
for funds, or to cushion more persistent outflows of
funds pending an orderly adjustment of the institution's
assets and liabilities.'
The sense of this statement of privilege is that
The intention is

appropriate borrowing should be temporary.

clearly that discount officers and committees should use
duration as a fair objective measure of appropria.teness, with
appropriateness negatively related to duration.

This intention

is also clearly expressed in the Report of the System Committee
on the Discount and Discount Rate Mechanism
suggested that "the duration of borrowing
establish a rebuttable presumption

(1954), where it is

[is] to be used to

that borrowing

[is] for an

2

inappropriate purpose."
Reserve Banks have set up rules for administering their
discount windows based on duration as a measure of appropriateness.
A common feature of these rules is a set of restrictions on the
number of weeks a bank can be "in the window" during a specified
period.

Such "frequency" restrictions exist for 13-, 26-, and

52-week periods.3 In general, the rules seem to be designed to

-3apply progressively heavier pressure to banks the more lengthy a
given "stay in the window."
From the point of view.of modeling borrowing behavior,
there are many unsatisfactory

features of the nonprice rationing

mechanism in force at the Reserve Banks.
on banks are difficult to identify.

The nonprice costs imposed

-The frequency guidelines are

difficult to incorporate in an operational empirical model of the
demand for borrowing.

And the lack of uniformity in.discount

window administration

across Reserve Banks contributes to the

difficulty in modeling aggregate borrowing.

However, these problems

are ignored in this paper in order to fully concentrate on the
effect of "progressive pressure" in influencing the structure of
the bank borrowing function.
4

A Model of the Bank Borrowing Decision
Major aspects of the bank borrowing decision are
described in this section.
and to maximize profits.

Banks are assumed to behave rationally
Because of the mechanism of nonprice

rationing at the discount window, banks turn out to care about
the past and

future

in deciding how much to currently borrow.

In other words, they face a "dynamic optimization problem."

In

the following two sections, a simple formal solution to this
optimization problem is derived and some characteristics of the
bank borrowing function are discussed.
Even a simple version of this dynamic optimization
problem is fairly complex.

Consequently, a simple form of

discount window nonprice rationing mechanism is assumed for

-4this disc'ussion. First, the marginal perceived effective cost
of borrowing is assumed to rise with borrowing in the current
period.

Second, given the current level of borrowing, the marginal

perceived effective cost of borrowing'is assumed to be positively
related to the level of borrowing last period.
A simple cost of borrowing function that embodies the
two essential features of the nonprice rationing mechanism
described above may be written
(1)

Ct = klBtel
where d

t

co’

cO
+ l)-+(Bt

+ 1)

2

- 11 + dtBt

= the period t discount rate
cl

’ 0,

Btr

BtBl

1

0

This cost function is graphed in Figure 1 for a given current
discount rate and lagged level of borrowing.
has a number of reasonable characteristics.

The functional form
First, the cost is

zero when current borrowing, Bt, is zero, i.e., the function passes
through the origin.

Second, the marginal cost of current borrowing

is positive and rises with the level of current borrowing, i.e.,
the function is convex downward.

Third, at any level of current

borrowing, Bt, the marginal cost of borrowing is positively related
to the level of lagged borrowing, Btml, i.e., roughly speaking the
function rotates counterclockwise

with a rise in BtWl.

Fourth, the

marginal cost of current borrowing rises and falls one-for-one with
the current discount rate, i.e., again roughly speaking the curve
rotates counterclockwise

with a rise in the current discount rate.

-

5

-

A bank borrows in the current period

(period t) until

the marginal cost of an additional dollar of current borrowing
just equals the marginal benefit.

The first component of the

current cost of an additional dollar of discount window
borrowing is found by differentiating

the cost function with,

respect to Bt, yielding

(2)

(clBtml

+ lko

(Bt

+

1)

+ dt

This component of the current marginal cost rises with Bt, d,,
and BtWl.
In rationally assessing the cost of additional current
borrowing, a bank must also consider that current borrowing
raises the marginal cost of borrowing in the future through the
In particular, the bank must

nonprice rationing mechanism.

include in its marginal cost of current borrowing the present
discounted value of next period's increased marginal cost of
borrowing due to an extra dollar of current borrowing.

This

second component of the current cost of an additional dollar of
discount window borrowing

is found by updating the B elements

in the cost function one period and differentiating with respect
to Bt, yielding
(3)

bCICO
y---L

(Bt+l

+ II2

-

11

where b E a constant rate of time discount'

-6Note that this component of the current marginal.cost

is zero if

next period's borrowing, Bt+l, turns out to be zero.

But current

(Bt) borrowing raises the marginal cost of borrowing next period
for any positive, Bt+l, borrowing level next period.
The inclusive marginal cost of Bt borrowing is the sum
of (2) and (3)
(4)

(CIBt-l)

+ l)co(Bt + 1) + dt + b 'lco[(B
2

t+1 + 1)

2

- 11

The current marginal benefit of an extra unit of discount
window borrowing is the opportunity cost of obtaining the funds in
the Federal funds market, i.e., the current Federal funds rate, ft.
A bank maximizes profits

(the net benefit from borrowing

at the discount window) by raising Bt to the point where the
inclusive marginal cost of Bt borrowing just equals the marginal
6
opportunity cost. In other words, profit maximizing behavior
leads a bank to set Bt so that expression
funds rate.

(4) equals the Federal

This condition, known as the Euler equation, is

necessary for Bt to be an optimum.

The Euler equation for the

bank borrowing problem is
(5)

(CIBt-l

+ l)co(Bt + 1) + dt + b2clco[(B

t+1

'+ 1)

2

- 11 = ft

7

where f

t

G the period t Federal funds rate

As is seen above, the Euler equation is nonlinear in the
B's.

Since the Euler equation is extremely difficult to solve in

its nonlinear form, we shall work with a linearized approximation
6
to the Euler equation.
The linearized Euler equation is

-7-

(6)

Bt+i + Wt
where S

t

= a + hSt

+ kBt-1
q

ft - dt

a E -

1

L
+ B (cocl + co + bclcO)

cO

bCf(-J
h E l/bclcO
BL z long run "normal" borrowing

In technical terms, the linearized Euler equation is a second order
difference equation in borrowing, B, that is forced by the spread
between the Federal funds rate and the discount rate, S.
To understand how this Euler equation works, recall that
a bank's decision on how much to borrow in period t (Bt) depends
on historically determined
period's borrowing

(Bt+l).

lagged borrowing

(Btml) and on next

Now next period's borrowing will.be

chosen by a bank to satisfy a similar updated Euler equation which
embodies the current borrowing choice as a predetermined condition;
and each successive period's borrowing will be chosen similarly.
In other words, each period's optimal borrowing choice depends on
planned borrowing for all future periods.

A rational bank must

choose a current level of borrowing simultaneously with a desired
borrowing path for the entire future.

For the path to maximize

profits, planned borrowing must satisfy successively updated Euler
conditions all along the path.

This means that in order to choose

-8a current

(Bt) level of borrowing, the bank must solve the Euler

equation as a second order difference equation in borrowing

(B).

Formally, the bank must find a solution to the difference equation
(7)

Bt+k+l + OBt+k + iBt+k-1

= 't+k

for k = 0,1,2,3,...

where Zt % a + hSt
The entire optimal borrowing plan chosen in period t can be
concisely written
i
(8)

B

t+k = 'lBt+k-1 -

't+k-l+i

k = 0,1,2,3,...

where -1 < Xl < 0 and A2 < -1
:a+hS
Zt

t;
9,

St

a<O,h>O
10

I ft - dt

Expectations and Discount Window Borrowing
If a bank had perfect foresight about the spread between
the funds rate and the discount rate, then equation

(8) would in

fact be an optimal demand schedule for borrowing from the discount
window.

It would give current

(period t) borrowing as a function

of lagged borrowing and current and future spreads.

However, a

bank does not know what future spreads will be with certainty.
A bank must forecast future spreads based on information it has
in period t.

This point is formalized by rewriting the period t

demand for borrowing as

(9)

i
)]

Bt = Apt-1
where E[
t

- bt
x2

- hig2

t-l+i'

I : the math ematical expectation conditional
on information available in period t

In (91, the currently observable St variable has been
separated from the future spreads which must be forecast.

The

E[S t-l+i] term indicates an optimal forecast of future spreads
t
based on information available in period t.
Equation

(9) is still not a decision rule since optimal

current borrowing'Bt

is not written as a function of variables that

have been observed as of period t.

In order to derive a decision

rule, it is necessary to specify a process generating the spread.
For illustrative purposes, assume the spread follows a first-order
autoregressive process.

In particular, suppose the S process may

be written
(10)

St

= aStwl + Et

where 0 c a < 1
Et

5 a random disturbance term

This process says that if S is displaced from zero, it
will return to zero asymptotically,
a proportion a each period.
future movement of S as
(11)

k
:[St+kl = a St

falling back toward zero by

This means that we could forecast

- 10 In other words, under the assumed simple process determining the
spread,.the only useful variable in forecasting the spread is
the current spread.
Substituting from (11) into (9) yields the following
decision rule for period t discount window borrowing

(12)

Bt = yt-1

- ak

+ iz2(ty]

- hk

+ iE2(+yci-l]5r

where B t L 0
-1 < Al < 0
A2 < -1
0 < a ,.<1
O<h
O>a
Equation

(12) is a decision rule or an operational demand schedule

for discount window borrowing since it shows the optimal level of
period t borrowing as a function of variables in a bank's period t
information set.
Qualitative Features of the Demand Schedule
for Discount Window Borrowing
Ignore aggregation problems and consider the aggregate
demand for borrowing schedule to have the same form as (12).
The demand for borrowing has two main features.

First, current

borrowing demand is negatively related to lagged borrowing.
This is a consequence of a nonprice rationing mechanism at the
discount window which discourages continuous borrowing by raising

- 11 the marginal perceived cost of current borrowing as borrowing
in the recent past rises.

The particularly simple way in which

lagged borrowing enters is due entirely to the assumed simplicity
of the cost of borrowing function used here.

In practice,

the nonprice rationing costs imposed on banks to discourage
continuous borrowing are much more complicated and difficult
to explicitly identify; so the relationship between current and
lagged borrowing is in practice difficult to specify.
Second, current borrowing demand is related to the
current spread between the funds rate and the discount rate, S

t'

The current spread affects current borrowings through the two
channels associated with the two terms in the coefficient on s

t
term to

in

h
A higher current spread works through the "- -"
x2
raise current borrowing demand. A higher spread works through this
(12)

l

channel by raising the net marginal benefit to current borrowing.
term captures the effect of the
current spread as a predictor of future spreads.
important role here.

Ira” plays an

A look at (11) suggests that a can be

thought of as measuring a kind of speed of adjustment or steepness
of descent of the spread toward zero after a disturbance.

A

zero a means there is no inertia in the spread; it is expected
to move immediately back to zero next period.

An a close to one

indicates a great deal of inertia in the spread, since it means

- -

the spread will return to zero extremely slowly.
The term
a

(x2 - a)A2

< 0.

can be written as

The net coefficient on the spread may be written

- 12 -h
as X2-a

>o

'

The derivative of the net coefficient with

respect to a is negative.

This means, for example, that a given

positive displacement of the spread from zero causes borrowing
demand to rise more the faster the expected movement of the spread
back toward zero, i.e., the smaller is a.
To see why, compare "corner"'cases where a is zero,
i.e., the displacement

is purely transitory lasting just one period,

and a is near one, i.e., the displacement is more persistent.

When

the high spread is purely transitory, banks expect net benefits
to borrowing and -actual borrowing to be low tomorrow.

On the other

hand, if the high spread is more persistent, banks expect the net
benefits and actual borrowing to remain high tomorrow.

Since the

marginal cost component of current borrowing stemming from future
planned borrowing is lower in the transitory case, the level of
current borrowing at which marginal cost just equals marginal
benefit will be reached at a higher level of current borrowing
when the spread displacement
A particularly

is transitory.

simple process for the spread has been

assumed to keep this example simple.

If the process determining

the evolution of the spread were more complicated, the future
spread forecast embodied in the borrowing decision rule could be
a more complicated

function of the current spread.

It might

also involve lagged spreads and other variables if they play a
role in explaining the evolution of the spread.
It bears emphasizing that banks care about lagged
borrowing and future spreads in deciding how much to borrow

- 13 currently because the nonprice rationing mechanism they face at
the discount window introduces "progressive pressure" into the
cost of discount borrowing, making longer duration borrowing
11

more costly.

If appropriate discount window borrowing ought to

be temporary, it is reasonable to raise the administrative
pressure on borrowing banks with the duration of their borrowing.
Duration provides an objective measure of appropriateness and
"progressive pressure" provides an automatic inducement for banks
to wean themselves from the discount window after an "emergency."
Unfortunately,

although "progressive pressure" based

on duration is a useful feature of the nonprice rationing
mechanism, it introduces a dynamic element into the bank discount
window borrowing decision problem.

A bank is forced to take

account of past borrowing and forecast future spreads to decide
how much to currently borrow.

Not only does "progressive

pressure" make the bank's borrowing decision more difficult,
it makes the econometric task of specifying and estimating an
aggregate borrowing function for use in monetary control more
difficult as well.

This last point is discussed in more

detail below.
The Borrowing Function and Fed Policy
The Federal Reserve plays a major role in the evolution
of the spread between the discount rate and the funds rate.
Movements in the spread are heavily influenced by Fed policy.
This means that rational bank forecasts of the spread must be
based on an understanding

of Fed policy toward the spread.

Since

- 14 future expected spread movements influence current borrowing
demand, not only the size of coefficients but also the form of
the borrowing function depends on Fed policy toward the spread.
The process on the spread assumed in equation
be thought of as policy induced, i.e., a policy rule.

(10) may
In this

view, unanticipated changes in the spread might be induced by the
Fed as part of its program for monetary control.

Thereafter,

the spread's return to a normal level might be smoothed.

The

size of a would be indicative of the degree of smoothing, a close
to unity indicating a greater degree of smoothing.

The analysis

above has shown that the sensitivity of current borrowing to the
current spread is smaller the more smoothing or persistence
there is in deviations of the spread from a normal long run value.
The current borrowing-spread

sensitivity depends on Fed policy

because the current spread appears in the borrowing function as
a predictor of future spreads.
The above analysis has implications for estimation of
the borrowing function and its use in implementing monetary policy.
First, in order to decide how much to borrow from the discount
window, banks must try to understand the Fed policy effect on the
spread.

Banks must understand Fed policy toward the spread

whether it is by direct manipulation of the Federal funds and
discount rates or induced through reserve management.

This means

that if the Fed wants to estimate and utilize a borrowing
function, it should make its policy intentions toward the spread
as simple and understandable

as possible.

Any deliberate

- 15 obfuscation of policy toward the spread makes it more difficult
for banks to forecast future spreads.

This can only make

specification and estimation of the borrowing function
more difficult.
Second, if the Fed's implicit policy toward the spread
depends on other variables besides the spread such as recent
levels of borrowing, the money supply, or the level of interest
rates, the policy links between these other variables and the
spread should be announced explicitly.

This would let banks know

what variables would help them forecast the spread and, at the
same time, let the Fed know what variables would be in the bank
borrowing function.

Such a procedure would enable the Fed to

more accurately specify the borrowing function and, by implication,
to estimate and utilize it more adequately.

In short, the Fed,

if it wishes to forecast bank borrowing accurately and
12

systematically, must take banks and the public into its confidence.
Third, if the Fed's implicit policy toward the spread
changes, the form of the borrowing function will change as well.
In particular,

the sensitivity of current borrowing to the current

spread will depend on the implicit policy toward the spread.
This means that when the Fed makes a policy change, altering the
time series characteristics

of the spread, the borrowing function

estimated over historical data from the previous policy regime
will not likely remain adequate for use in forecasting bank
borrowing under the new policy regime.

If the policy change

occurs by a sequence of decisions following no clearly discussed

- 16 or preannounced pattern, it will become known to banks only
13

gradually.

This will complicate adaptation of bank borrowing

behavior to the new policy environment and further complicate
the task of forecasting that behavior.'
Discount Window Borrowing Under PostOctober 6, 1979 Reserve Targeting
The above analysis is relevant to reserve targeting as
it has been carried out by the Federal Reserve since October 6,
14

1979.

The method of discount window administration in force

does not al-low the Fed to exercise direct control over total
reserves.

The Fed directly controls nonborrowed reserves only.

Under this setup the Fed manipulates nonborrowed reserves to
influence the funds rate and other short-term rates of interest
and thereby affect the quantity of money demanded.

The FOMC chooses

an initial intermeeting path for nonborrowed reserves designed to
induce the banking system to obtain a target volume of borrowed
reserves from the discount window.

The target volume of discount

window borrowing is chosen, for a given discount rate, to produce
the desired level of the funds rate and other short-term rates of
interest and ultimately the desired effect on the money supply.
This operating procedure depends critically on the link between
discount window borrowing and the spread between the discount
rate and the funds rate, the link provided by the demand function
15

for discount window borrowing.
The Fed is having difficulty relying on the demand
function for discount window borrowing under the new operating

- 17 procedure.

The difficulty

is well described in the following

account of the means by which the FOMC chooses the initial
intermeeting target for borrowed reserves:
Typically, the Committee [FOMC] has chosen levels
[an interim borrowing objective] close to the recently
prevailing average --though the level chosen on October 6
was shaded higher to impose some additional initial
restraint.
Ideally, the assumed initial borrowing level
should be such that the resultant mix of borrowed
and nonborrowed reserves would tend to encourage bank
behavior consistent with the emergence of desired
required reserves, and hence of desired monetary growth.
In practice, [for a given spread between the discount
rate and the funds rate] there seem to be significant
short-term variations in the willingness or desire of
banks to turn to the discount window. This adds to the
difficulty of choosing an appropriate level for path
construction purposes, and may necessitate adjustment
in a path in response to changes in bank attitudes
toward the discount window.16
This account indicates that the demand for discount
window borrowing appears to the Fed as relatively volatile and
17

difficult to predict.

The difficulty the Fed is having in

pinning down the borrowing

function may be simply due to the

complexity and lack of uniformity of the nonprice rationing
mechanism in force at the discount window or to the irregular
use of the discount rate surcharge.

However, the analysis of

this paper provides another explanation for the apparent
unreliability

of the relation between borrowing demand and the

spread between the discount rate and the funds rate.

First,

the analysis shows that as long as "progressive pressure" is
employed as a means of nonprice rationing, borrowing demand
depends in a potentially

complicated way on lagged levels

- 18 of borrowing and on expected future spreads.

Second, unwillingness

of the Fed to publicly specify its policy intentions toward the
spread makes it difficult for banks to form expectations about
future spreads.

Both of these factors have likely contributed to

the apparent difficulty the Fed has experienced in specifying,
estimating, and utilizing a reliable borrowing function in
monetary control.
Conclusion
A demand schedule for discount window borrowing based on
profit maximizing bank behavior has been derived.

The form of

the borrowing function has been shown to depend on a feature of
the nonprice rationing mechanism at the discount window that
introduces "progressive pressure" into the cost of discount window
borrowing, making longer duration borrowing more costly.
"Progressive pressure" based on duration makes lagged borrowing
and future spreads between the discount rate and the Federal funds
rate relevant to the current borrowing decision.

Since movements

in the spread are heavily influenced by Fed policy, and since
expected spread movements
size of the coefficients

influence borrowing demand, both the
in the borr‘owing function as well as the

form of the function itself depend on Fed policy toward the spread.
This analysis is relevant to reserve targeting as it
has been carried out by the Fed since October 6, 1979.

Under this

operating procedure, the demand function for discount window
borrowing has provided the critical link by which nonborrowed

- 19 reserve control has been made to affect short-term rates of
interest and ultimately the money supply.

Unfortunately, the

relation between discount window borrowing and the spread between
the discount rate and the Federal funds rate has appeared to the
Fed as volatile and difficult to predict.

This analysis suggests

that this may be the case because borrowing also depends in a
potentially complicated way ,on lagged borrowing and expected
future spreads.

In addition, unwillingness -of the Fed to publicly

specify its policy intentions toward the spread makes it difficult
for banks to form expectations about future spreads.

Both of

these factors have likely contributed to the difficulty the Fed
has experienced

in specifying, estimating, and utilizing a

reliable borrowing function in monetary control.

FOOTNOTES
1

Federal Reserve Board Rules and Regulations,
Regulation A (as adopted effective September 1, 1980), Sec. 201.3,
Par. a. Regulation A also entitles depository institutions to
get seasonal and other so-called extended credit. Such borrowing
is ignored throughout this paper.
A good discussion of discount window administration
is found in Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
"Operation of the Federal Reserve Discount Window Under the
Monetary Control Act of 1980,' September 9, 1980.
2

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Reappraisal Of the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism, ~01s. l-3
(August 1971), p. 41;
3

See, for example, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
"Guidelines for the Administration of Short-Term Adjustment Credit
in the Twelfth Federal Reserve District" (effective April 11, 1977)
or Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Operation
of the Federal Reserve Discount Window Under the Monetary Control
Act of 1980," September 9, 1980.
4
The Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary
Control Act of 1980 requires all depository institutions to
maintain reserves with the Federal Reserve.
Included in the term
depository institution are banks (whether or not they are members
of the Federal Reserve System), savings banks, mutual savings
banks, savings and loan associations, and credit unions. The act
entitles any depository institution in which transaction accounts
are held to the same discount and borrowing privileges at the
Federal Reserve Banks as Federal Reserve System members.
Consequently, depository institutions other than banks have access
to the discount window.
Since this is the case, this paper should
refer to 'the .depository institution borrowing decision' rather
than "the bank borrowing decision."
However, in the interest of
simplicity the word bank is retained throughout on the understanding
that'it stands for all depository institutions having access to
the discount window.
5

The rate of time discount may not
be constant.
But allowing for this greatly complicates the
bank's maximization problem and obscures the main implications
to be drawn from its solution without contributing any essential
new insights.
- 20 -

- 21 6

A formal statement of the bank's maximization problem
is given in Appendix A.
7

With no progressive pressure, cl equals zero. In
this case, the marginal cost of period t borrowing involves
Bt and dt; neither the past nor the future is relevant to the
bank borrowing decision.
The linearization procedure is outlined in Appendix B.
9

The solution procedure is discussed in Sargent [1979],
Chapters 9 and 14. Without knowledge of the actual relative
sizes of c and b, there is,no way of sufficiently restricting
the charac &eristic roots of this difference equation. However,
the illustrative purpose of the solution in this paper is well
served by assuming that cl and b are such as to make -1 < Xl < 0
and X2 < -1. A transversality condition is obtained by assuming
that if the spread between the discount rate and the funds rate
were expected to be constant for all time, then planned borrowing
would eventually converge to a constant optimal level.
"The optimal borrowing plan has been derived implicitly
only for the case where B and f - d are both positive. Although
B can never be negative and current borrowing cannot be nonzero
unless current f - d is positive, these constraints have not been
formally built into the solution.
11

See Footnote 7.
12

This statement is paraphrased from Lucas 119761, p. 42.
The points made in this section are based on arguments originally
advanced at a more general theoretical level in Lucas' paper.
13

This statement is also paraphrased from Lucas

[19761,

p. 40.
14

Technical descriptions of the post-October 6, 1979
operating procedure may be found in "Monetary Policy and Open
Market Operations in 1979," pp. 60-64, "Techniques of Monetary
Policy," and "The New Federal Reserve Technical Procedures for
Controlling Money." Federal Reserve experience with the new
operating procedure is discussed in Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Staff Study, New
Monetary Control Procedures.
15

The Fed has allowed the funds rate to fall below the
discount rate for prolonged periods since October 6, 1979. When
this happens there is no incentive for banks to borrow at the
discount window, and borrowing volume becomes very small. The
borrowing function plays no role in the operating procedure in
such situations.
Whenever the funds rate has been below the

- 22 discount rate, the operating strategy has essentially reverted to
the pre-October 6, 1979 policy of direct funds rate control.
16

"Monetary Policy and Open Market Operations in 1979,"
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review (Summer
1980): 60.
17

The following comment from "Monetary Policy and
Open Market Operations in 1979," p.' 63, provides a specific
illustration of the difficulty the Fed has had in utilizing the
borrowing function:
The behavior of the Federal funds rate during
November and December was somewhat puz.zling, as it often
did not follow a usual relationship to the volume of
The Federal funds rate did
discount window borrowings.
decline in early November, when borrowing dropped, but
then continued to fall through the rest of the month,
while borrowings stabilized around $1.8 bill*on to
$1.9 billion. The average funds rate slipped as low as
12 l/2 percent in the final week of the month, compared
with about 13 3/4 percent at the start. However, in
December, when borrowings declined further, though
irregularly, ranging between $1.2 billion and $1.7
billion after the first week, the funds rate jumped back
up to around 13 3/4 to 14 percent through December and
into January.
Normally, one would not have anticipated a drop
in the Federal funds rate in late November when
borrowings were steady. Nor would one have expected
the rate to rise and then stay up in December as
borrowings resumed their decline.
Levin and Meek [1981] and Keir [1981] contain additional
evidence of the difficulty the Fed has had in using the borrowing
function in monetary control.

APPENDICES
Appendix A
Maximize

(at each point in time t) the discounted

present value

1

.
cO
y
b'
ftBt - (clBtml + 11, 4(Bt + 1)2 - 11 - dtBt
't = j=O
c
by choosing a sequence for {Bt+j'jlo
transversality

subject to Btml = ztml, a

condition and a known sequence {f
t+j - dt+j lW
j=O*

Appendix B
A linear approximation to the Euler equation is
constructed as follows.
run value.

Define AXt a Xt - XL , where XL is a long

Then
[cl(BL + ABtWl) + llcO(BL
+bCTo
-[(BL
Assume B

L

+ ABt + 1)

+ ABt+l + 1)2 - 11 = (f - d)L + A(ft - dt)

is small and redefine Bt Z AB

t' so that the

linearized Euler equation may be written
B

1
t+1 +qBt+

+ BL(cocl + co + bclcO)
;BtWl

= bCICO
+ bc;co(ft - dt)

- 23 -

I

REFERENCES
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Federal
Reserve Board Rules and Regulations, Regulation A (as
adopted effective September 1, 1980).
"Operation of the Federal Reserve Discount Window
Under the Monetary Control Act of 1980," September 9, 1980.
(&s.

Reappraisal of the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism
l-3) : August 1971.

Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act
of 1980, PL 96-221, March 31, 1980.
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
"Guidelines for the
Administration of Short-Term Adjustment Credit in the
Twelfth Federal Reserve District," effective April 11, 1977.
Keir, Peter.
"Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the
Effectiveness of Reserve Targeting."
In Federal Reserve
Staff Study--Volume l,.New Monetary Control Procedures.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
February 1981.
Levin, Fred, and Meek, Paul. "Implementing the New Operating
Procedures: The View from the Trading Desk." In Federal
Reserve Staff Study--Volume 1, New Monetary Control
Procedures.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, February 1981.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique."
In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, ed. K. Brunner and
A. H. Meltzer.
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy 1: 19-46. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1976.
"Monetary Policy and Open Market Operations in 1979." Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review (Summer 1980):
50-64.
"The New Federal Reserve Technical Procedures for Controlling
Money."
Appendix to a statement by Paul A. Volcker,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the Joint Economic Committee, February 1, 1980.
Subsequently published in U.S., Congress, House, Committee
- 24 -

- 25 on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs, Conduct of
Monetary Policy (Pursuant to the Full Employment and
Balanced Growth Act of 1978, P.L. 95-523), Hearing,
February 19, 1980 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office, 1980), pp. 108-15.
Sargent, Thomas. Macroeconomic Theory.
Press, 1979.

New York: Academic

"Techniques of Monetary Policy." Remarks by Henry C. Wallich,
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a meeting of the Missouri Valley Economic Association,
Memphis, Tenn., on March 1, 1980.