View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 79-3

THE DETERMINANTS

OF LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION:

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

William E. Cullison

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
April 1979

The views expressed here are solely those of
the author and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

THE DETEBNIWNTS OF LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATIOZ1:
AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

IHTRODUCTION
Before the mid-1960's economists generally accepted, with two major
exceptions, the neoclassical theory of aggregate labor supply, i.e.,

the

theory that the number of workers supplied to the market varied with wages,
population, and work preferences, with work preferences and population
treated as exogenous and outside the realm of economics. The two major
exceptions were the “additional" worker and "discouraged" worker effects.
The additional worker effect is based upon the idea that, as unemployment
rates rise, additional or "secondary" breadwinners enter the labor market
to maintain family income.

In neoclassical terms, increased unemployment

shifts the aggregate labor supply curve to the right. The "discouraged"
worker effect, on the other hand, states that as unemployment rates and
the average duration of unemployment rise, individuals will become discouraged and stop seeking work, thus dropping out of the labor force.
In neoclassical terms, when unemployment rises the "discouraged" worker
effect causes the aggregate labor supply curve to shift to the left.
Seminal articles by Tella [16] and Dernberg and Strand [4] in,the mid1960's devoted attention to the relative importance of the two effects.
They concluded that the discouraged worker effect was dominant. Subsequently, the U.S. Department of Labor began publishing regular estimates of the number of discouraged workers in the economy.
During the second half of the sixties and the seventies, renewed
attention was directed to aggregate labor supply theory because of unexpected changes in the actual data. The rate of growth of the civilian

labor force, which is approximately equal to the aggregate quantity of
labor supplied, had unexpectedly begun to accelerate rapidly. The acceleration, which was the result of fundamental societal changes in such
things as birth rates, the status of the family, and the role of women,
fostered an interest in extending the neoclassical theory of labor supply.
The progress on extending the theory is probably best seen in
John Seater's unified model of consumption, labor supply, and job search
n41, at least as it relates to the individual work/leisure decision.
Seater views the individual as a utility maximizer who must decide how
best to divide his time among labor, leisure,and job search. Wages are
viewed as a means of achieving consumption goods, but an individual may
forego consumption for leisure, or present for future consumption via
investment in job search time, etc.
The set of models that best show the progress in measuring aggregate
labor force behavior, however, view the household rather than the individual
as the primary economic unit. Wachter (181, in a 1972 paper, outlines a
relative income model that relates changes in labor supply to the difference
between the household's desired or anticipated standard of living and its
actual standard of living. When the differential is large, additional
persons (more specifically, additional members of the household) enter the
labor market* Wachter's view of labor force participation broadens the
older additional worker effect, which related unemployment to the supply of
additional workers. A recent article by Leonall Anderson [l] provides
another example of a labor force model that uses the household as the basic
decision-making unit.
Other recent research on labor supply theory stresses the distorting
effects of governmental programs such as unemployment insurance and

-3-

various welfare programs on the labor supply curve (see Cagan [2] and
McElhattan [S]). These analyses emphasize that governmental programs
designed to alleviate poverty and/or unemployment raise the unemployed
worker's reservation wage (the wage below which he finds it undesirable
to accept employment) and the time that the unemployed worker can spend
in job search.
This paper will develop and test empirically a simple reduced form
model of labor supply in order to (1) provide guidelines for developing
more accurate labor supply equations in large econometric models and
(2)

aid in determining the extent to which the acceleration in labor

force participation is attributable to economic rather than sociological
forces.

The first section of the paper is devoted to developing the

model of labor supply that will be tested in subsequent sections. The
subsequent sections are devoted to the empirical test of the model.

THE MODEL OF LABOR SUPPLY
The early neoclassical theory of labor supply, which stressed the
effect of real wages on the hours of labor supplied by the individual
(given work-leisure preferences and demographic factors), can be specified
as follows:
QL

- f(W), f' > 0 if w < Wo,f' < 0 if w > w. .

QL is the number of labor hours supplied by an individual, W is the real
wage, and W, is the level of real wages at which workers substitute leisure
for labor. By incorporating (1) a modernized additional worker effect-i.e., the worker's offer of his services depends not only upon the wage
offered to him but also upon his household's income relative to its expenditure plans, (2) a modernized "discouraged" worker effect--i.e., an
individual's decision to be in the labor force depends upon his perception

-4-

of economic opportunity, (3) the effects of governmental programs on
labor-leisure choices, and (4) the effects of sociological forces, e.g.,
the women's movement; the labor supply function can be augmented and
respecified. If QL now represents the quantity of labor hours supplied
by the household,
4, - f (W,Yh-Yhe, 8, E,, G) , f2 2 0, f3 ' 0, fq ' 0, fg < 0,
yh-yhe represents the difference between actual and budgeted purchasing
power of the household, S represents a vector of sociological variables
that increase labor force participation, G represents a vector of governmental programs that increase the worker's reservation wage, and E, represents perceived employment opportunity.
Since it is impractical to estimate each household's supply function
separately, aggregate labor supply is usually assumed to be represented
by the behavior of a typical household. The typical behavior of members
of one demographic subset of the labor force, however, often differs
radically from that of members of another demographic group (see Wachter
[13] and Sniderman [lo]). For example, sexagenerians view employment quite
differently from persons in their twenties and the older workers react
differently to work incentives. As a result, the aggregate labor supply
is actually composed of an amalgam of quantitatively and qualitatively
different labor supply functions. Based upon the presumption that labor
force behavior patterns are more homogenous within age-rate-sex cohorts,
the empirical work in this paper on labor supply therefore involves estimating several cohort labor supply functions rather than one aggregate
function. The labor force is separated into only eight cohorts, although
a further degree of disaggregation would have been preferable. The labor
Supply

function that will be tested in the subsequent part of the paper

is specified as follows:'
Qi - fi(Wi,

Yh-Yhe

i,

s,

E,,

Gt pi),

I=' 1, 2, .... 8.
Where white males 20-24=1, white females 20-24~2, nonwhite males 20-24~3,
nonwhite females 20-24~4, white males 25-6415, white females 25-6416,
nonwhite males 25-64=7, and nonwhite females 25-64=8.
Qi represents the quantity of labor supplied by each group and P

i

rep-

resents the population of the group. wi (Yh-Yhe)i 1 and E, now represent
wages offered to members of the group, deviation of actual and expected
household purchasing power for a typical cohort's family, and perceptions
of employment opportunities, respectively.
One can establish the following apriori
1.

hypotheses:

Female and younger male labor force participation is affected

more strongly by household budgetary surprises than is older male labor
force participation.
2.

Older white male labor force participation is affected less

strongly by changes in employment opportunity than the labor force participation of the other cohorts.
3.

.

White female labor force participation is affected most strongly

by the long-term changes in the social climate.
The first hypothesis follows from the observation that relatively more
females and younger males are "secondary" workers than are prime-age
males, 25-64. As a result, an unpleasant surprise with respect to expected
household income will draw a relatively larger number of females and younger
males into the labor force. The second stems from the observation that
.

'Teenagers were excluded on the grounds that their labor supply
function is specified differently from that of older workers. See
Sniderman (151.

-6-

older white males, having been least troubled by discriminatory employment
opportunity in the past, will benefit least from its reversal. The third
hypothesis follows from the fact that the women's movement has primarily
affected white female labor force participation.
Proxies for Theoretical Variables
Much of the difficulty associated with empirical tests of theoretical
models revolves around choosing proxies to capture the effects of unobservable theoretically postulated variables. First, the theoretical model of
labor supply relates the explanatory variables to the quantity of labor
supplied in hours. The data on hours of work, however, are not available
by demographic group. As a result, the quantity of labor supplied is
assumed to be denominated in numbers of persons.

In addition, it was

necessary to accept the definitions use.dby the U.S. Department of Labor,
so it

is assumed that the quantity of labor supplied by each cohort is

equivalent to its civilian labor force.
Secondly, data on actual and planned household purchasing power were
unavailable by cohort group. The proxy chosen to represent household
budgetary stress, therefore, had to be based upon aggregate data.

It is

defined as the difference between the percentage change (annual rate) in
U.S. real capita disposable personal income in the current quarter and the
percentage change over the previous four quarters, but with one exception.
The exception is that the percentage change in the relative price of food
is deducted from the percentage change in real per capita disposable personal income in order to capture the differential effects of changes in
the household's power to purchase postponable rather than non-postponable
items. It was also assumed that households formulate expenditure plans
by extrapolating income changes in the recent past.

The budgetary stress

-7-

ij r

variable, SB is specified as f0ii0ws:
- PFt
PFt-1

SB, =

4

+1

-

yDpC,-l - pFt-l + 1
YDPCt,j P"pj
J

where YDPC = per capita disposable personal income, 1972 dollars,
PF = relative price of food (food component of Consumer Price
Index divided by all item Consumer Price Index), and
t

- time

in*quarters.

An inverse relation between SB and labor force participation indicates
the presence of an additional worker effect, i.e., workers entering the
labor force in response to household budgetary stress.
Thirdly, wage data are not available by cohort. The wage variable
that was used in the estimation, average real hourly earnings of production
workers (adjusted for overtime and interindustry shifts), represents mostly
wages of adult males. The lack of wage data for the cohorts was especially
unfortunate, because average earnings of production workers is not an appropriate proxy for the incentive effects of wages on female labor force
participation. Wage data for production workers, in fact, was negatively
associated with female labor force participation if at all, which

sug-

gested that it was proxying an additional worker effect rather than a
wage incentive effect.
Fourthly, real GXP was chosen to proxy the effects of cyclical
economic fluctuations on worker perceptions of employment opportunity,
thus capturing the traditional discouraged worker effect. Other sources
of employment opportunity such as the effects of the Equal Opportunity Act
could not be proxied directly, but it could be assumed that the effects of
long-term changes in economic opportunitieswould be captured as part of
the long-term trend.

-80

Fifthly, the model included a variable designed to represent the
effects of governmental programs on the costs of accepting employment.
The variable that was chosen to proxy this effect was the number of
participants in the Food Stamp program. This proxy was chosen because
participation in this program since 19712 has increased more rapidly
than in other such governmental programs. Bonus food stamps issued in
1971, for example, cost the Federal government $500 million. This cost
had risen to $5.0 billion by 1977.

Increased food stamp distribution

is assumed to increase the reservation wages of workers in the household,
and an increase in food stamp participation is thus assumed to be associated with a decrease in labor supply. There is, however, an ambiguity
associated with the choice of this proxy as well.
In order to be eligible for food stamps, all able-bodied adults in
the applicant's household (excepting persons responsible for the care of
children or aged dependents, students, or those already employed for at
least 30 hours a week) are required to register for work with the state
or local unemployment office. This work registration requirement applies
only to households who are not eligible for other forms of public assistance, but since 1972 work registration has been required for recipients
of other federal welfare programs. If the work registration requirement
were controlling, an increase in food stamp participation would be associated with an increase in the measured labor supply. Apparently, however,
the registration requirement is not controlling, for the empirical results
discussed later in this paper show increased food stamp participation to
be associated with decreases in labor force participation.

'The period of extraordinary labor force growth began in 1972, as
will be shown subsequently. The Food Stamp program has been in effect
since August, 1962, but its major growth has come about since the Act
was amended in January, 1971.

-9-

Finally, it was found that changes in real wages, real GNP and
food stamp participation were correlated, particularly in the 1972-1978
period. To remove this multicollinearity, it was necessary to modify
the real wages and food stamp variables using an instrumental variable
technique. Accordingly, changes in real wages were regressed on changes
in real GNP, and the residual (de-cyclicized real wages) was used to measure
the wage incentive effect on labor force participation. Changes in food
stamp participation were de-cyclicized in a like manner.
The Civilian Labor Force data, which are used to proxy the quantity
of labor supplied, have two serious limitations. First, the definition
of the Civilian Labor Force fails to distinguish between part-time or
full-time workers, nor does it allow recognition of differences in the
number of overtime hours worked.

Second, persons who will not actually

accept employment at existing wage rates are often included in the measured
data. These individuals may be searching for certain jobs at higher wage
levels, jobs in specific occupations or locations, or they may not be willing to accept employment at all.

Since increases in average real weekly

benefits paid under unemployment insurance programs are assumed to motivate
increased divergence between the actual and the measured labor supply,
average real benefits are also included in the analysis as an explanatory
variable.
Preliminary Data Adjustments
Because it was hypothesized that labor force participation changed
radically after 1971, the labor force data were adjusted to facilitate a
juxtaposition of labor force behavior in the 19651971 and 1972-1978
periods before the supply functions were estimated. The reasoning behind
the hypothesis is shown quite dramatically in Chart I.

Chart I

UNEMPLOYMENT

RATE AND EMPLOYMENT

FOR ALL

CIVILIAN

WORKERS,

PRESSURE INDEX

16 AND

OVER

wcent

Index

1.0

104
Employment

Pressure Index

102

3.0

5.0

98

7.0

96

9.0
Unempioyment A3te
(Right Scale)

94

11.0

1955

\

67

59

61

63

66

67

69

71

73

7s

77

- 10 -

Chart I depicts the employment pressure index3 for all civilian
workers, sixteen and over, plotted against the unemployment rate
(inverted) for the 1955-1978 time period.

It shows that the employment

pressure index, actual employment divided by a population-adjusted
employment trend, moved in tandem with the unemployment rate from 1955
through 1971 but that the two series began to diverge in 1972. The
chart thus illustrates that employment was growing, during the 1972-1978
interim, at rates that would have brought about substantial declines in
the unemployment rate if the labor force had been growing at its historical rate. Thus, had labor force participation conformed to its longrun
trend, the unemployment rate would have declined to approximately 3.1
percent by the fourth quarter of 1978.

Contrast the chart's depiction

of labor markets during the 1975-1977 interim to the prevailing view as
it is stated by George Perry [ll, p. 261.
From 1975 through 1977, all available measures of tightness in
either labor markets or product markets registered ample slack.
And no large upward movements have occurred in particular components of the price level since the organization of Petroleum.
Exporting Countries increased oil prices in 1974. Yet despite
all these disinflationary developments, the rate of inflation,
by any broad measure, has continued at a historically high
rate. . . .
In order to illustrate the change in the labor force since 1971,
even more dramatically, population-adjusted trend equations were estimated
over the 1955-1971 time period,4 and the estimated parameters were used

3Developed at this Bank. See Cullison "An Employment Pressure
Index as an Alternative Measure of Labor Market Conditions," Review of
Economics and Statistics, February 1975.
4These equations were of the form used to derive the employment
pressure index for Chart 1, El =8il+8i2*t+8i3et2+8i4*Pi,where Ei represents employment of the ith cohort, t represents time, Pi represents
civilian noninstitutionaliz~ population of the ith
- cohort, and Bij
represent parameters.

- 11 -

to derive employment trend estimates for the entire 1955-1978 time
period.

These trend estimates were used to calculate the employment

pressure indexes, which are shown in conjunction with unemployment rates
in Chart II.
The detailed breakdowns in Chart II show post-1971 divergences
between the employment pressure indexes and the unemployment rates (inverted) to be especially pronounced for female workers. Most remarkable
is the bottom chart, which depicts the employment pressure index and
unemployment rate for adult nonwhite females. Although the nonwhite
female unemployment rate remained in the lo%-12% range after the 1975
recession, that labor force group was experiencing such extraordinarily
rapid increases in employment that their employment pressure index ended
1978 at 115.3. Thus, nonwhite female employment at year-end 1978 was
15.3% higher than would have been predicted by extrapolating the 1955-1971
employment trend. Additional attention will be devoted to this remarkable
situation subsequently.
To develop civilian labor force trend estimates, each of the employment trend data sets was divided by its 1955-1971 average employment rate.
The extrapolated 1955-1971 labor force trend was then subtracted from the
actual civilian labor force values. The resulting sets of data thus provide direct measures of both short-run variations in the labor supply and
longer-term deviations from the 1955-1971 trend.

ESTnUTING THE MODEL
Overview.--The labor supply function was estimated with ordinary least
squares, and the results are shown in Table 1.

The empirical results

suffer to some extent from the incomplete nature of the model.

Ideally,

a demand function should have.been specified and the model should have

8. POR MALES. NEGRO PNO OTHER RACPS. 20-w
1

I

106

I04

0.4

102

L4

TOO

A.1

9a

a.4

0. MR LEMALES. NEGRO AN0 OTHER RACES. ZG-84
116 ,

I

IIECllESSlON COEYFIClINTS,

“t”

STATISTICS
(All

km

vorlablce

IIECI~ESS~DNSOF ~~+wmtw~l~ I.Anm

are In flret

dlffcrences

mum*

ON EXI’LANATMY ECONOIIIC VARIAIILES

except SU.)
corrcctcd

StonJord
Conet4nt

WIIILC

SD

SU

20-24

Holcu

1972-l to

UL’

lil’

1978-1v
1978-111

20.04

(1.44)
21.39

1977-IV

1.59
(3.46)

39.69

0.31

1.74

40.42

0.34

38.11

0.23

13.81

n. 30

-1.77
(-1.69)

(2.46)

20-24

III

PS

FS

2%.

(-1.09)

!zEft2
12.00

(1.43)

2%

Tiis
.

1978-111

0.07
(2.50)

4.00
(1.86)

i4.n4

0.20

1977-IV

0.95
(2.65)

6.21
(2.16)

14.24

0.33

11.01

0.24

-1.87
(-1.56)

34.91

0.33

-2.11

31.33

0.41

32.95

0.35

47.40

0.25

Il.08

0.61

11.22

0.60

1972-1 to

(2:57)

1970-1v

(2.10)

w

1965-11 to 1971-IV

20-24
White Femolce
1972-1 to
197fl-IV

1970-111

1977-IV

(-2:
LBg
-35.98

(-3.00)

m
13.85
(2.25)

19.11
(2cGl)

-39.57
(-3.65)

Q.63
(1.40)

10.2H

20.25

-38.59
(-3.13)

(1.10)

m

io 1971-IV

-3.35

(-1.55)

Ima

(-5.24)

-14.91
(-5.13)

-0.94
(-3.33)

-17.30
(-3.77)

0.75
(4.28)

0.44
(2.73)

-0.93

-16.72

0.77
(4.05)

(2.6,2_!

-14.99
.

(-4.74)
-.

(-3.11)

!elu

(1.81)

(-1.96)

13.63
(1.90)

-2.03
(-1.64)

* .
(-2.88)
*
-1G.07
(-3.90)

-15.01

1977-IV

0.51

!?!&A
-0.90
(-3.31)

20-24

197B-III

5.07
(2.60)

30)

ML
0.65
(1.37)

16.34
(2.02)

(2.49)

Noswhitc FemalCS
1972-1 to
1978-1v

&lJ

L&

-0.68
(-1. 36)

19b5-II

n.25

w

29.77

Halee

41.43

III

0.53)

(1.36)

1965-11 to 1971-IV

Noauhlte

112

CNL’ 72

Lqg
1.61
(3.35)

+ge
(1: 19)

Error

CHI’ 72

(-3.29)

0.71
(4.39)

-.

u
0.45

(2.94)

0.45

0.61

( 11.80
_

._

.

-.

piI@ 2

con’ t

Constnnt

Non~hlta
1965-11

SD

SU

WI’

Pemalee 20-24

Pi2

to 1971-IV

(1:95)

WIllto kllce

25-64

k?fL-L

?pg.

1972-I to
197H-IV

WI’

CNI’ 72

CNI’ 72

w

III

III

PS

yj$

-19.40
(-1.81)

PS

Stawhrd
Error

Corrected
t!2

14.92

0.23

(-2138)

u

I&n%

-53.83
(-1.56)

-6.20
(-1.88)

90.06

0.20

(-2.70)

tin.31
(2.21)

1978-111

18.07
(1.03)

-5.61
(-2.47)

Ill.72
(2.25)

-43.49
(-1.22)

-6.69
(-2.02)

90.56

0.27

1977-IV

19.37
(1.01)

-6.14
(-2.53)

105.95
(2.4‘))

-52.28
(-1.31)

-6.79
(-1.93)

93.72

0.31

30.31
(1.62)

w
-5.20
(-1. U3)

61.69

0.34

1965-11 to 1971-IV

Nonul~lte M.~lce
25-64
1972-I to
1978-1v

_LJp:

y$

y$

(-1:4*)

(-2:Oh)

(2.47)

19.15
(2.44)

-3.80
(-2.60)

33.43

0.36

-29.12
(-2.31)

34.63
(2.75)

19.85
(2.63)

-4.27
(-2.91))

32.14

0.40

-33.28
(-2.37)

41.26
(2.71)

18.28
(2.04)

-4.35
(-2.83)

33.06

0.37

15.42

0.55

-R.59
(-2.88)

90.37

0.24

74.60

0.45

75.43

0.46

911.09

0.44

-30.04
(-2.29)

L970-111

11.21
(1.70)

-1.65
(-2.04)

1977-IV

11.90
(1.70)

-1.64
(-1.87)

s.

kg.

(-2.98)

1978-111

1977-1v

2%
(4h3)

(-3.42)

54.38
(3.18)

m
-27.92
(-1.79)

44.71
(3.11)

-42.69
(-3.16)

-in.05

42.27
(2.74)

-50.90
(-3.32)

-9.37
(-3.61)

1965-11 to 1971-IV

24.48
(3.17)

!&!&!I

-15.36
(-1.35)

!!!!a2

(-4.03)

w

l.tJ@

7.76
(3.50)

-173.62
(-2.47)
lh,,~vl,l~c Fcmalcs 25-64
1972-I to
1970-1v

w

IAs

-1.91
(-2.30)

Wlllte hunlee
25-64
1972-l to
1978-IV

w

-46.23
(-2.96)

2%
.

I.clg

13.18
(2.06)

1965-11 to 1971-IV

I.aS

-35.23
(-2.5H)

m

-31.78
(-2.26)

u

0.57
(1.43)

!r”A

0.54
(1.12)

$g
(2:52)

I.ng

-3.42
(-2.49)

I 29.27

0.15

page 3
UP

WP

23.05

w
-20.00

1978-111

(3.34)

1977-IV

18.32

can’t

Coustnnt

Ncrnuhlta Fcw~lce 25-64

1972-I to

CNP 72

CNP 72

I.ilJ$J
-33.78

+A&

!+lg

(-1.95)

(-2.69)

(1: 76)

(1:97)

$it
(2: 73)

-21.33

-38.29

0.74

0.93

(-2.12)

(-2.92)

(2.11)

(2.20)

SH

SU

(2.73)

III

III

FS

FS

Standnrd
Error

Correcrcd

It2

yg
(-2:30)

26.06

0.21

16.00

-2.67

24.17

0.34

(2.46)

(-2.27)
23.9!,

0.50

1965-11 to 1971-IV
(-2.06)

Definitions

SU-

PP

(&&+Q4-(Ii+-~+i)

-

Relative

price

YUPC - Per copita
UP

-

dlepoeable

Reel averace

hourly

GNP 721Crow National
UI

-

Average

FS

-

Number of

are denoted

***Inotrumentnl

earnings

Product

pereone

(food

variable

of private

under

participating

item CPI).

income, 1972 dollare.

mcnaurad

Lobor Force leao
In

component of CPI/All

poreonal

weekly benefite

fiActua1 Clvillan
**Loge

of food

in

nonferm production

workere.

adjuated

1972 dollars.

unemployment componeation progrome measured in 1972 dollars.
In

Food Stnmp progrcm.

Population-Adjuetcd

de-cyclicired.***

Trend (1955-1972 parometere).

qunrtere.

developed,

for overtime

actually

resldual

from rcgreeoion

on real

GNP.

and Inter-industry
sl~lflc
and de-cycllcized.***

- 12 -

been estimated simultaneously. The demand side, however, is quite complicated in this disaggregated model because of the interrelationships between
the demand for workers from one cohort group and the quantity of workers
supplied by other cohort groups.
This paper, by ignoring the demand side, thus risks the danger of
simultaneous equation bias.

Some of the peculiarities of the data, however,

make the problem less serious than it might be.

The supply function was

estimated separately for the 1965-1971 and the 1972-1978 time periods.5
Although the two periods were kept separate in order to focus attention on
the reasons behind the post-1971 divergence of labor force participation
from its past historical pattern, the splitting of the time periods turned
out to be useful in evaluating the simultaneous equation bias.
As will be discussed at greater length subsequently, the labor supply
,
equations fit over the 1972-1978 time period were consistently better, in
that only two of the regression coefficients bore the incorrect sign, compared to eight incorrect signs in the 1965-1971 time period. These differences suggest the possibility that simultaneous equation bias, which seems
to have affected the results for the 1965-1971 period,6 may have had considerably less serious effects in the 1972-1978 period. The characteristics
of the economy in 1972-1978 also suggest that possibility.
The economy in 1972-1978 was characterized by large fluctuations in
the aggregate demand, since that period included such events as the severe
1973-1975 recession, the OPEC-sponsored oil price adjustments, the floating

'The model could not be estimated for the 1955-1965 time period
because of insufficient data.
%ee

subsequent discussion.

- 13 -

of the dollar, and the recovery of the economy from the Nixon wage-price
control program. As a result, relatively large fluctuations in demand
for labor7 apparently traced out the supply function.
The regression coefficients reported in Table 1 were estimated from
quarterly data over four time periods, 1965-11 to 1977-IV, 1972-I to 1977-IV,
1972-I to 1978-111, and 1972-I to 1978-18. The three different sets of
regression results for the post-1971 period are reported to indicate in
summary form the stability (or lack thereof) of the estimated coefficients
over time.8

In the event that a regression coefficient for one or another

of the proxies is missing from a particular equation, its absence means
that it explained little if any of the variation in the labor force.9
All data were converted to first differences."
The estimated coefficients were generally stable in the post-1971
period, but there was one major exception--the set of regression results
for older white and nonwhite females. For these cohorts, the results
estimated over the 1972-I to 1978-18 time period differed substantially
from the results estimated over the 1972-I to 1978-111 time period. Not
only were the regression coefficients substantially different, but the R2
(corrected) values were substantially lower for the regressions estimated

7The Standard deviations for quarter-by-quarter percent changes in
real GXP and the GNP Implicit Deflator, for example, were 0.78 and 0.34,
respectively in the 1965-1971 period, but 1.21 and 0.61 in the 1972-1978
period.
/
'Regression results were examined for all periods beginning with
the 1972-I to 1976-11 time period and continuing through the 1972-I to
1978-11X period, but the changes in the coefficients reported in the table
between the 1972-I to 1977-IV time period and the 1972-I to 1978-111 time
period adequately illustrate the changes in the coefficients over the
longer interim.
'Whenever the "t" statistic for a particular regression coefficient
fell below 1.0 (the 70 percent confidence level for this set of regressions),
the variable was dropped.
loThe matrices of simple correlation coefficients among the independent
variables are shown in the Appendix for purposes of reference.

- 14 -

on the 1972-I to 1978-IV period. The source of this instability was an
unexplained surge in 25-64 female labor force participation during the
fourth quarter of 1978.

Since this one-period surge may be an aberration

or a data error that subsequently will be revised, however, it has been
ignored for the present.

Subsequent discussion of the results for the

post-1971 time period will be based upon the regression coefficients
estimated over the 1972-I to 1978-111 time period.
Chart 111 shows the actual detrended civilian labor force plotted
against the values simulated from the model.

The simulation was performed

using two sets of dummy variables that allowed one set of regression
coefficients (estimated over the 1965-1971 period) to provide the estimates for the early period and another set (estimated over the 1972-1978
period) to provide the estimates for the later period.

Since the equations

were estimated using first differenced data, the simulation technique first
inserted actual 1965-11 data values, then estimated subsequent values.
No actual data were inserted in the series after 1965-11. The simulated
data explained 98.6 percent of the variation in the actual detrended data
over the sample period, 1965-11 to 1978-111, and 98.4 percent of the
variation over the entire period (including 1978-IV).
Evaluation of the Individual Regression Coefficients
Trend.--One of the basic motivations for this study was the hope of
finding an explanation for the post-1971 change in the U.S. worker's
work/leisure preferences. The observation that such a change in fact
occurred may be corroborated in part by examining the post-1971 trend
estimates shown in the table (the constant terms in these equations).
Because of the preliminary data adjustments, any remaining trend represents a change from that in evidence before 1972.

Chart III

ACTUAL

AND SIMULATED

LABOR FORCE, 20-64

CIVILIAN

(DE-TRENDED)+

~;h;5nds of
5,000

4,000

3,000

2,000

1,000

0 .

-1,000

I

I
1966

l1955-1971

I

I
1968

I

I
1970

I

I

I

1972

trend,and extrapolation
of thattrend,deleted

1974

I

I

I

1976

I

197

- 15 -

Regression coefficients representing trend were significantly
different from zero at a better-than-95% confidence level in five of the
eight regressions performed over the 1972-1978 time period.

In the cases

of both white and nonwhite females (25-64), the trend was highly significant and positive. Since the continuation of the 1955-1971 trend was
already adding a large number of persons (an average of 158 thousand.per
quarter over the 1972-1978 time period) to the white female labor force
(25-641, the additional 50 thousand per quarter trend over the 1972-1978
time period meant that long-term noneconomic forces accounted for an
average increase in the mature white female labor force of almost 4% per
year over the 1972-1978 period. The mature nonwhite female 25-64 labor
force also trended toward substantially increased labor force participation in the 1972-1977 time period, rising almost 5% per year on average.
Budgetary Stress.--The proxy for budgetary stress, SB, had been
expected to carry a negative sign and to be particularly applicable to
female and young male labor force participation, since these groups have
been thought to contain a larger percentage of "secondary" workers than
the other groups. The expectation of a negative sign was fulfilled except for the younger

nonwhite male group, whose participation was pos-

itively related to changes in the SB variable in the 1972-1978 period.
The positive sign, although inexplicable, is highly significant. It
undoubtedly indicates either that the equation is imporperly specified
and that a key variable has been omitted or that a simultaneous equation
bias appeared in that equation. The SB variable is not highly correlated
with the other independent variable in the equation, however. Budgetary
stress, interestingly enough, was inversely related to 20-24 nonwhite
male labor force participation in the early time period.

_- 16 -

SB had been expected to be an especially important determinant of
female and young male labor force participation, but contrary to expectations it turned out to affect mature male participation more strongly
than it did any other group, other than young nonwhite females. Labor
force participation was generally associated with lagged budgetary stress
if it was significantly associated at all.

This delayed response had

been expected, for individuals usually must modify or postpone other
activities in order to enter the labor force.
Real Wages.--Real hourly earnings of nonfarm production workers
was associated with labor force participation of three of the four male
groups with the expected positive sign, at least in periods of steadily
changing real wages.

The real wage proxy was not statistically signifi-

cant in the nonwhite male 20-24 regression. The real wage proxy, however,
had a statistically significant net negative association (again in periods
of steadily changing real wages) with all female labor force groups during
the 1972-1978 time period, except white females 25-64. The latter cohort
has had no statistically significant association with the real wage proxy
in the later period, although there was a significant negative association
in 1965-1971. As noted earlier, the proxy for wages, based as it is upon
the average real earnings of production workers, is not a good proxy for
the earnings of female workers. As a result, WP undoubtedly proxies a
part of the additional worker effect (according to which the wife enters
the labor market when the husband's real wage falls) that is not wholly
accounted for by SB.

SB and WP, however, are not highly correlated.

Employment Oonortunitv.--Real GNP was chosen to proxy the effects
of cyclically induced changes in employment opportunity (and perceptions
of opportunity) on labor force participation because it

is a widely-

- 17 -

publicized coincident economic indicator. Since it.was hypothesized that
the larger the increase in real GNP, the better the prospective worker's
chance of finding a job, a positive relation was expected between real
GNP and labor force participation. During the 1972-1978 period, significant
positive associations were found to exist between real GNP and participation
of younger white males and females, younger nonwhite females, and older
nonwhite females; and no statistically significant negative relationships
were found.
The labor force participation of younger workers was expected to be
subject to wider cyclical fluctuations as a result of changes in emnloyment opportunity than the labor force participation of older workers. The
properly signed and statistically significant coefficients found for three
of the four younger groups in the 1972-1978 period were consistent with
that hypothesis. The participation of 25-64 nonwhite females was also
found to be subject to a discouraged worker effect.
During the 1965-1971 time period, statistically significant negative
associations were found with all male groups. These results appear to be
anomalous and suggest substantial simultaneous equation bias in the 19651971 time period (as discussed earlier), but it was necessary to include
real GNP in those equations or suffer a large loss in the R2's. The consistency of the finding, in that all male groups had negative associations
with real GNP in the early period and no labor force group did in the
later period, casts particular suspicion that the regressions may have
been measuring labor demand in 1965-1971, not labor supply.
Employment opportunity, of course, is only partially proxied by
real GNP.

Noncyclical changes in employment opportunity are often included

in the trend, although they also show up with changes in other coefficients

- 18 -

as well.

As was noted earlier, nonwhite female labor force participation

changed dramatically after 1971. This change was illustrated not only
by the change in the trend coefficient, but also by the changes in the
other coefficientsas nonwhite female participation became generally more
related to economic forces. The explanation for these changes is probably related to long-run changes in economic opportunity for nonwhite
females. The Equal Opportunity Act (which became law on Xarch 24, 1972)
had, along with other programs designed to remedy the effects of racial
and sexual discrimination, a more-than-proportionate influence on the
hiring of nonwhite females. Also, dramatic changes were taking place in
the occupational structure of nonwhite female labor force during the 19651978 time

period.

In 1965, roughly 30 percent of employed nonwhite fe-

males were working as private household workers; by the end of 1977, less
than 8.5 percent were so employed.
Governmental Programs.--Participation in the food stamp program was
assumed to raise the worker's reservation wage, so the number of persons
in the program was expected to be negatively associated with labor force
participation. As the table shows, this expectation was fulfilled. The
food stamp program, according to the analysis, has had statistically
significant effects on the labor force participation of older workers and
of younger white females. These results indicate that the program's work
registration requirements, mentioned earlier, have not been effective for
older workers. However, more of the exclusions from the work registration
requirements apply to older workers.
The food stamp program was found to have no statistically significant
effect on labor force participation in the earlier period, but it was a
much different program before it was amended in January 1971. According

- 19 -

to a Federal court ruling [12], for example, the 1971 amendments changed
the

U.S. food stamp policy from one of supplementing the diets of low

income households to one of guaranteeing those households an adequate diet.
Real average weekly benefits under unemployment insurance programs
were expected to be positively related to labor force participation. The
positive sign was expected because, as was pointed out earlier, individuals
are required to be unemployed and seeking work (i.e., in the labor force)
in order to qualify for unemployment benefits. Positive and statistically
significant associations were found between average real weekly benefits
and participation of all nonwhite males, older nonwhite females, and younger
white females in the 1972-1978 period. One implication of this finding is
that workers in these groups, seeing higher benefits, deliberately "seek"
jobs only to qualify for unemployment benefits. Such behavior is exactly
what critics of the unemployment insurance program have predicted that it
would produce. Another implication, however, is that higher benefits induce workers to stay in the labor force and look for a job when they might
otherwise have become discouraged and have dropped out.

This behavior is

exactly what supporters of the program have predicted.
Although four of the eight regression coefficients had the predicted
sign, participation of one of the groups, mature white females, was
statistically significant and negatively associated with average real
unemployment insurance benefits in the 1972-1978 period. To date, no
plausible rationale has been developed for a negative sign on real unem.
ployment insurance benefits. Its appearance probably indicates an unresolved missing variable bias.

Three of the associations were negatively

signed in the 19651971 analysis, again possibly indicating demand rather
than supply effects.

- 20 -

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The model, as noted above, has limitations in that some of the proxy
variables were inadequate and, especially in the case of real wages,
ambiguous. As Chart III shows, however, the model predicts well during
the sample period. The simulated labor force does not go off track through
accumulated errors, and it explains over 98 percent of the change in.the
actual labor force. The model appears to track slightly better during the
post-1971 period, excepting of course the fourth quarter of 1978.
The estimation results of the model clearly show the extent of the
change in labor force participation since 1971. Very few similarities
were in evidence between the 1965-1971 regressions and the 1972-1978 regressions in either the regression coefficients or the explanatory variables
themselves. Moreover, the empirical results leave no doubt that workers
in each cohort respond differently to various economic incentives and
disincentives.
The empirical results were generally consistent with the postulates
of the theoretical model, with of course some outstanding exceptions.
Perhaps the most unsatisfactory result was the negative sign between older
white female labor force participation and real average unemployment insurance benefits. Table 4 summarizes the signs of the coefficients relative
to expectations. As noted at the outset, the results of the 1972-1978
estimation is far superior with respect to the signs of the coefficients.
Only in two cases, budgetary stress for the young nonwhite male cohort
and average unemployment insurance benefits for the older white female
cohort, were the signs clearly inexplicable. The explanatory power of
the model

seems such that the relatively few unsatisfactory results may

be left to further research.

TABLE 4
SUMMARY OF REGRESSIONS, ACTUAL SIGNS VERSUS EXPECTED SIGNS
FOR ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS OF INDEPENDENT VARIABLES
Budgetary
Stress

Real
Wages
--

Real
GNP

Unemployment Food Stamp
Insurance
Participation
Benefits
+

+ Males
+
- Females

Expected Signs

(1972-I to 1078-111 Regression)
White males 20-24

Oa

+

+

0

0

Nonwhite males 20-24

+

0

0

+

0

White females 20-24

0

+

+

+

0

Nonwhite females 20-24
White males 25-64

+

0

0

Nonwhite males 25-64

+

0

+

0

0

White females 25-64

0

Nonwhite females 25-64

0

+

0

+

(1965-11 to 1971-IV Regression)
0

-

Nonwhite males 20-24

0

-

+

White females 20-24

0

0

0

+

0

White males 25-64

0

-

Nonwhite males 25-64

0

-

+

+

0

White males 20-24

Nonwhite females 20-24

White females 25-64
Nonwhite females 25-64

0

0

0
0

‘+

0

aZero indicates that the variable was not statistically significant.

- 21 -

Changes in labor force participation over recent years have caused
perplexing policy questions that are yet to be solved. As an example of
one such question--if labor force participation is changing and if the
"stickiness" in the unemployment rate in the post-1975-11 recovery has been
attributable to increased labor force participation, how may one calculate
the welfare loss from a given unemployment rate? As an example of another
such question, will the economy ever be able to expand rapidly enough to
bring the unemployment rate down to historically tolerable levels without
bringing about intolerable rates of inflation?
The relationship between the change in output and the change in'the
unemployment rate, sometimes known as Okun's Law, has been different in
the post-1975-11 recovery; it has taken a larger-than-usual increase in
real GNP to bring about a reduction in the unemployment rate. A change in
the realtionship could, theoretically, stem either from (1) an increase
in labor productivity, (2) an increase in the employers desired capital/
labor ratio, or (3) a change in labor force participation. The latter
is the source of the current disparity. A calculation of the relationship
between the percent change of real GYP and the percent change of employment
supports this assertion. For all recoveries between 1955-I and 1973-IV,
a one percent increase in real GNP was associated with a 1.5 percent increase in civilian employment. During the 1975-11 to 1977-IV time period,
however, a one percent increase in real GNP was associated with a 1.9 percent
increase in civilian employment. Thus, employment is currently more responsive than usual to the rate of growth of real output. As a result,
the "stickiness" of the unemployment rate can only be attributed to unusually rapid labor force growth. That unusually rapid labor force growth,
the raison d'etre for this paper, has been shown to be predictable, by-andlarge, and to be related to economic as well as sociological forces.

g

.

Y
PE

m

Table A-2
Matrix of Simple Correlation Coefficients, Quarterly Data from 1965-11 to 1971-W
(All data are in first differences except SD, negative numbers in parentheses indicate lags in quarters.)
SB

-

WI?

WP

GNP 72 GNP 72

0

0

0
SU

SU

SD

0

IINP
I-pa

72 GNP 72

IJI

UI

UI
I -!xL

-0.06

1.0

sa (-2)

-0.28

-0.07

1.0

0.34

0.19

0.10

1.0

-0.32

0.35

0.22

0.20

1.0

0.07

-0.08

-0.22

0.03

-0.10

1.0

CNP 72 (-1)

-0.59

0.07

-0.11

-0.26

0.00

0.22

1.0

GNP 72 (-2)

-0.03

-0.58

0.09

-0.13

-0.25

0.29

0.18

1.0

GNP 72 (-3)

-0.06

-0.03

-0.59

-0.34

0.13

0.24

0.29

0.18

1.0

UI

0.00

-0.15

0.26

0.15

0.07

-0.11

-0.13

0.40

-0.31

1.0

UI (-1)

0.04

-0.01

-0.22

0.11

0.17

0.07

-0.07

-0.15

0.41

-0.30

1.0

III (-2)

0.12

0.08

0.05

-0.11

0.06

0.23

0.09

-0.08

-0.16

-0.40

-0.20

1.0

UI (-3)

-0.16

0.11

0.06

0.02

-0.08

-0.16

0.21

0.10

-0.09

-0.07

-0.48

-0.14

WP (-1)
CNP 72

0

1.0

SR (-1)

WP

UI

1.0

REFERENCES

1.

Anderson, Leonall. "An Explanation of Movements in the Labor Force
Participation Rate, 1957-76," FRB St. Louis Review, August 1978.

2.

Cagan, Phillip. 'The Reduction of Inflation and the Magnitude of
Unemployment." Contemporary Economic Problems, Washington: American
Enterprise Institute for Policy Research, 1977.

3.

Cullison, William E. "An Employment Pressure Index as.an Alternative
Measure of Labor Market Conditions." Review of Economics and
Statistics, February, 1975.

4.

Dernburg, Thomas and Strand, Kenneth. "Hidden Unemployment 1953-1963."
American Economic Review, 56 March 1966.

5.

McElhattan, Rose. 'Labor Force Participation and Unemployment Insurance-A Time Series Study." FRB San Francisco Economic Review, Spring 1977.

6.

.

'How Much Economic Slack?" Circulated paper, June 2,

1978.
7.

Monhollon, J.R. and Cullison, W.E. "Okun's Law and the Natural Rate
of Growth: Comment." Southern Economic Journal, October 1970.

8.

Okun, A.M. "Potential GNP: Its Measurement and Significance.'
Proceedings of the Business and Economics Section of the American
Statistical Association, 1962.

9.

Perry, George L. 'Potential Output and Productivity." Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, I, 1977, pp. 11-47.

10.

"Changing Labor Markets and Inflation." Brookings
Papers on Econolkc Activity, III: 1970, pp. 411-441.

11.
View."

Brooki&

"Slowing the Wage-Price Sniral, the Macroeconomic
Papers on Economic Activity, II: 1978, pp. 251-299.

12.

Rodway versus U.S. Department of Agriculture, 514F 2d, 809, 820.

13.

Santomero, Anthony and Seater, John. "The Inflation-UnemploymentTradeOff: A Critique of the Literature." Journal of Economic Literature,
June 1978.

14.

Seater, John. 'A Unified Model of Consumption, Labor Supply, and
Job Search." Journal of Economic Theory, April 1977.

15.

Sniderman, Mark and Bagshaw, Michael. 'A Casuality Approach to Labor
Force Participation: Tests for Structural Change." Working paper 7801,
FRB Cleveland.

16.

Tella, A.J. "Labor Force Sensitivity to Employment by Age, Sex."
Industrial Relations, 4, February 1965.

17.

Thirlwall, A.P. "Okun's Law and the Natural Rate of Growth." Southern
Economic Journal, July 1969.

18. Wachter, Michael. "The Demographic Impact on Unemployment: Past
Experience and the Outlook for the Future." Demographic Trends and
Full Employment, National Commission on Manpower Policy, Special
Report No. 12, December 1976.