View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Bubbles and the Value of Innovation

WP 20-08

Valentin Haddad
UCLA and NBER
Paul Ho
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Erik Loualiche
University of Minnesota

Bubbles and the Value of Innovation†
Valentin Haddad

Paul Ho

UCLA and NBER

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Erik Loualiche
University of Minnesota

July 3, 2020

Abstract
Episodes of booming innovation coincide with intense speculation in financial markets leading to bubbles—increases in market valuations and
firm creation followed by a crash. We provide a framework reproducing these
facts that makes a rich set of predictions on how speculation changes both
the private and social values of innovation. We confirm the theory in the
universe of U.S. patents issued from 1926 through 2010. Measures based on
financial market information indicate that speculation increases the private
value of innovation and reduces negative spillovers to competing firms. No
commensurate change occurs in measures grounded in real outcomes.

†

Haddad: vhaddad@ad.ucla.edu. Ho: paul.ho@rich.frb.org. Loualiche: eloualic@umn.edu. We
thank Andrew Atkeson, Markus Brunnermeier, Edouard Challe, Alexandre Corhay, Emmanuel
Farhi, Nicolae Garleanu, Harrison Hong, Pablo Kurlat, Deborah Lucas, Alberto Martin, Stavros
Panageas, Gill Segal, Alp Simsek, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Jaume Ventura, and seminar
participants at Columbia University, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, HKUST, London Business School, Minnesota, MIT Sloan, Princeton, UBC
Sauder, UCLA, University of Luxembourg, Banque de France, Bank of England, Finance in the
Cloud, FIRS, Macro Finance Society meetings, NBER Asset Pricing, SED, and WFA for useful
comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent
the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

1

Introduction

Episodes of booming innovation often coincide with intense speculation in financial markets, leading to periods that have been described as bubbles: large increases in firm creation and market values followed by a crash (e.g. Scheinkman,
2014). This connection is natural: when faced with new ideas, people disagree;
disagreement leads to bubbles in which high prices generate more investment.
But a crucial aspect of how innovation spreads is missing from this narrative:
the interactions of various actors and their spillovers on each other during the
bubble.
We address this issue with a new theory that enriches the simple narrative
in two ways, motivated by the following observation. To evaluate spillovers, each
investor must have an opinion not only about the firms she invests in, but also
about their competitors — how do other firms affect my firm and how do I affect others? First, we entertain consequential disagreement across agents about
these questions, without succumbing to the high dimensionality they typically
imply. In our model, investors disagree about which firms are more likely to succeed, in contrast with the existing literature’s focus on disagreement about the
aggregate state. Second, we account for a rich range of spillovers across firms,
and show how they interact with speculation.
The theory delivers a set of novel insights about the private and social value
of innovation during these episodes. We test the main predictions using over a
million patents issued from 1926 through 2010. In both our model and the data,
we find that during bubbles: (i) the increase in market value of a firm following
the introduction of a new patent is larger; (ii) the relative spillover to the market value of competitors is smaller; and (iii) there is no commensurate change
in outcome-based measures of value focusing on patent citations or output. In
addition, the model highlights how the effect of bubbles depends on the source
of spillovers—competition, learning, etc. We also show how these measures of
spillovers can guide policy, emphasizing the importance of distinguishing between market- and outcome-based spillovers in the presence of speculation.
Formally, we analyze a model in which new ideas are implemented by firms
that compete with each other. We allow for a rich range of firm interactions
while remaining parsimonious enough to be tractable and yield clear testable
predictions. In the first stage, firms are created by raising money on financial
1

markets; in the second stage, competition and production occur. In our baseline analysis, competition takes a simple form: only a fixed number of the best
firms get to produce. A novel ingredient of our theory is that investors agree
to disagree about which firms will be more productive. Each investor picks her
favorite firms for her portfolio and therefore values her investments more than
her beliefs about the average firm.1 This mechanism increases valuations and
incentivizes more firms to enter. In the second stage, not all investors can be correct about which firms produce: prices drop and many firms fail. This rise and
fall as a result of speculation echoes broad narratives of bubble episodes as well
as some of their more subtle features. Disagreement is more natural in the face
of new ideas, making these episodes more likely following the introduction of a
broad new technology (Brunnermeier and Oehmke, 2013; Scheinkman, 2014) or
among younger firms (Greenwood, Shleifer, and You, 2018). In a dynamic extension of the model, we show that they are also related to more intense trading
activity (Hong and Stein, 2007; Greenwood, Shleifer, and You, 2018).
We use the model to study the private and social values of innovation. When
people disagree, there appears to be a multitude of private and social values.
Whose beliefs should one focus on? Our framework for heterogeneous beliefs
overcomes this challenge. We are able to entertain rich disagreement and define private and social value corresponding to clearly measureable objects that
all agents agree on. Market participants agree on the aggregate distribution of
firms—and therefore all macroeconomic outcomes—but disagree on the relative
positions of specific firms in this distribution. Each firm faces the same distribution of beliefs across investors even though the identity of these investors differs,
leading to a symmetric equilibrium in the first stage. Using this symmetry, we
define private and social value in both market-based and outcome-based ways.
The market-based approach considers prices of firms in financial markets. Under this criterion, the private value of a firm is its price, while the social value of
that firm is the amount by which its introduction changes the price of all firms
in the economy.2 From an outcome-based perspective, the private value is the
average output of a firm, while the social value is how much the introduction of
a firm changes total output in the economy.
The model makes two predictions about the market-based value of firms.
1
2

Van den Steen (2004) studies how disagreement and choice lead to optimism.
In richer specifications, we also incorporate effects on other participants in the economy.

2

First, it predicts that speculation increases the market-based private value of
firms. When disagreement increases, investors have higher valuations of their
chosen firms because they expect these firms to be more productive than the
average firm in the economy, even though the aggregate productivity distribution of new firms is unchanged. Second, it predicts that the wedge between the
market-based social and private values of a firm is attenuated by speculation.
Each new firm introduces a business-stealing effect as it displaces other firms.3
With speculation, investors believe they are investing in the most productive
firms in the economy, making them less concerned about being displaced by a
new firm. Their valuation of their chosen firms is thus impacted less by any
additional firm entry. In contrast, the outcome-based measures of value remain
unchanged since speculation affects neither the aggregate productivity distribution nor the competitive structure.
A historical episode offers an illustration of our model. In 1686, William
Phips secured funding in England from the Second Duke of Albemarle and his
syndicate to search for sunken Spanish ships in the Bahamas.4 He found 34
tons of treasure, yielding large returns to his investors. This successful expedition generated considerable speculation around treasure-hunting technology.
The speculation was accompanied by a large spike in patenting activity for the
time, with 17 patents for ways to recover underwater bounty registered between
1691 and 1693. Based on these innovations, numerous firms were introduced
on equity markets and raised large amounts of capital despite competing for
what was clearly a small pool of treasures. These high valuations were consistent with our notion of high market-based value that is unaffected by competitive spillovers in the presence of speculation. The boom was so large that it is
sometimes credited for the emergence of developed equity markets in England.
However, there was no corresponding increase in the outcome-based value of the
new patents and firms because the expeditions only succeeded in finding a few
worthless cannons.
To verify the model’s predictions empirically, we use the universe of patents
issued by public firms from 1926 through 2010 to measure the relation between
3

While the term of business-stealing suggests malfeasance, it is simply the textbook name for
how the entry of a new firm takes customers and profit away from existing firms, conveying a
negative externality, see Acemoglu (2008).
4
See Scott (1912) for background information on this episode, a landmark in the history of
the stock market in the United Kingdom.

3

innovation and market values. We follow the literature and construct empirical counterparts to the private and social values in our model. Specifically, we
measure the market-based private value of new innovations using the stock returns of issuing companies in the days following a patent approval, as in Kogan,
Papanikolaou, Seru, and Stoffman (2017). We estimate the market-based social value relative to private value of new innovations by using the response of
firm valuations to innovations by their competitors, controlling for innovation
by technologically related firms, as in Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen
(2013). We proxy for speculation by isolating bubble episodes following Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018): industry-years that have experienced a sharp
run-up in stock prices.
During a bubble, the market-based private value of innovation increases by
30% at the patent level and between 40% to 50% at the firm level, corroborating
the model’s prediction that speculation increases private value. The effect is
smaller for firms that span multiple industries. Intuitively, an investor is likely
to have a range of views about the different products of a firm, hence reducing
the effect of speculation about a given product on the firm’s stock prices. The
change in market-based private value is not accompanied by a corresponding
change in outcome-based private value. In particular, we show that the increase
in number of patent citations is small relative to the increase in market-based
private value, reflecting little change in the quality of innovation in bubbles.
The data also support the prediction that speculation dampens market-based
but not outcome-based measures of spillovers. In particular, our estimates suggest that during bubbles the business-stealing effect measured by asset prices
completely vanishes. In our model, this disappearance occurs asymptotically for
large levels of speculation. We do not see any change in the business-stealing
effect measured through sales during bubbles, again in line with our theory.
Competition is only one of the many ways through which the effects of an
innovation are felt in the economy. An innovation also affects owners of scarce
production inputs, alters consumers’ choices over their consumption baskets,
and allows other firms to learn. We incorporate these prominent sources of
spillovers in our theory. Doing so is interesting for three reasons. First, we
obtain new testable predictions of our theory for the interaction between speculation and innovation that can help discipline future empirical work on these

4

channels. Second, by comparing across many different specifications, we obtain
a more systematic typology of how speculation shapes spillovers. We find that
the main determinant for the impact of speculation on market-based spillovers
are the beliefs of those who receive the spillovers rather than those who create
them. Third, we confirm that the divergence between market- and outcomebased measures is not only quantitative but also qualitative. The effect of industry characteristics on these two measures is often reversed. Speculation can
also reverse their sign. Finally, while the outcome-based spillover only depends
on macroeconomic quantities, the market-based one depends on the microeconomic structure of the economy.
Our results also have normative implications because the spillover measures
are important inputs for optimal innovation policy. We derive the optimal Pigouvian tax on firm entry under different notions of social welfare. On the one hand,
the Pareto approach is non-paternalistic: it evaluates the welfare of each agent
under her own beliefs. Under this approach, the optimal entry tax is simply
the opposite of the market-based measure of spillover since asset prices reflect
agents’ beliefs. On the other hand, a paternalistic approach evaluates welfare
under a single belief, the population distribution. Then, the optimal tax combines two components: the outcome-based measure of spillover and the privatevalue distortion caused by the bubble . These two components might offset each
other: by fostering more entry, a bubble might fix an economy that would otherwise have under-entry due to positive externalities. The two welfare approaches
highlight that there is no single “correct” measure of spillover, but rather that
different objectives call for different measures. Our theoretical results provide
a mapping between outcome-based and market-based measures, allowing one to
derive optimal tax policy using data on only one of the two types of measures.
Related Literature. Our approach to representing speculation and the bubbles that ensue builds on a large body of work. The effect of belief disagreement
on asset prices in the theoretical literature goes back to Miller (1977), Harrison
and Kreps (1978), and Scheinkman and Xiong (2003). More recent contributions
include Barberis, Greenwood, Jin, and Shleifer (2018), who emphasize the role
of extrapolation, and Chinco (2020), who incorporates social interactions. We
enrich this literature by focusing on disagreement at the micro level, specifically

5

across many firms. We develop a framework that makes the high-dimensionality
of this problem tractable; we use it to consider implications for firm creation and
innovation. Empirically, we use the methodology from Greenwood, Shleifer, and
You (2018) to identify bubble episodes in stock market data. There is a broader
set of empirical evidence that supports the relation between speculation, heterogeneous beliefs, and asset prices, such as Chen, Hong, and Stein (2002) or
Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002). Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013) and
Scheinkman (2014) review the theory and evidence.5
Our focus on the implications of bubbles for innovation connects us to work
emphasizing the real effects of financial markets, dating back to Tobin (1969)
and Hayashi (1982). Bond, Edmans, and Goldstein (2012) offer a survey. In
the context of bubbles, Panageas (2015) highlights implications for investment,
while Hombert and Matray (2020) focus on labor market outcomes.6 Dong, Hirshleifer, and Teoh (2020) document effects of overvaluation on the quantity and
ambitiousness of innovation at the firm level. We go beyond the direct effect of
high stock prices by considering how speculation shapes the private and social
values of innovation. To that end, we use data and measurement methods developed by Pakes (1986), Griliches, Pakes, and Hall (1986), Bloom, Schankerman,
and Van Reenen (2013), and Kogan, Papanikolaou, Seru, and Stoffman (2017).
Furthermore, our theoretical framework gives rise to a more nuanced set of tests
of innovation transmission.
Naturally, there are other approaches to studying the relation between financial markets and innovation. Like us, this work builds on classic models of
technological growth (e.g. Acemoglu, 2008). However, the extant literature considers different sources of asset-price fluctuation. One strand of the literature
centers on uncertainty and risk compensation rather than speculation. Pastor and Veronesi (2005, 2009) offer quantitative accounts of innovation booms
focused on learning. Gârleanu, Kogan, and Panageas (2012) and Kogan, Papanikolaou, and Stoffman (2020) highlight risks associated with displacement.
Kung and Schmid (2015) study the long-run risk associated with innovation.
Corhay, Kung, and Schmid (2015) and Loualiche (2020) measure risks associated with competition across firms. Another stream of work focuses on rational
bubbles (as in Samuelson (1958) and Tirole (1985)) and whether they crowd in or
5
6

Janeway (2012) offers a first-person account of the interaction of bubbles and innovation.
van Binsbergen and Opp (2019) quantify the effects of mispricing more generally.

6

crowd out investment. Farhi and Tirole (2011) and Martin and Ventura (2012)
are two recent examples. Our results contribute to these lines of research by
highlighting important variations in the characteristics and social implications
of innovation around speculative episodes.
Finally, we also contribute to the literature discussing welfare in the
presence of disagreement. Heterogeneous beliefs raise the question of how
to evaluate each agent’s welfare.7 One approach is to impose one common
“correct” belief for welfare evaluation. Brunnermeier, Simsek, and Xiong (2014)
circumvent the need to choose a specific belief by studying allocations that
are efficient across all convex combinations of agents’ beliefs. Davila (2020)
follows this approach in the context of financial-transaction taxes. Kondor and
Köszegi (2017) consider sophisticated financial products. A second approach
uses the Pareto criterion and evaluates each agent’s welfare under their own
beliefs, which Duffie (2014) calls the “consenting-adults” criterion. We derive
optimal innovation policies for both approaches and point out their differences.
Interestingly, we relate the two types of policies to the measurement of both
market prices and real outcomes.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we introduce our model of speculation with business-stealing. In Section 3, we derive predictions for private and
social values, which we verify empirically in Section 4. We extend the analysis
to richer sources of firm interactions in Section 5 and consider the normative
implications of our model in Section 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes.

2

A Model of Disagreement and Innovation

We introduce a stylized framework to study the interaction between speculation
and innovation. Innovation and competition are represented by a set of firms
implementing new ideas. Speculation is represented by households who disagree about which firms will succeed. Households trade shares of the firms. The
interplay between these two aspects yields equilibrium patterns that are consistent with stylized facts about bubbles. We then use the model to make testable
7

This question is closely related to the debate around the possibility that people agree to
disagree; see Morris (1995) for a general perspective.

7

Date 0

Date 1

Firms i

z
y
w
w x
w

? ?
? ?
Buy shares

Households j

Sell
Own

Consume

Firm Creators

Firms i

Households j

collects pi − pb

Produce
effort cost W (b)

Buy

Blueprints
c c c
c cc
c
c
c c c
c

Figure 1
Summary of model structure.
The left panel represents the stage of firm creation at date t = 0, when blueprints are created
and households buy shares in firms on financial markets based on their beliefs. The right panel
represents the production stage at t = 1.

predictions about the private and social values of innovation.
Figure 1 illustrates the overall structure of the model. At date 0, households
work to create blueprints. They sell the blueprints to firm creators, who implement them as firms. Households buy the claims to these firms’ production. At
date 1, firms compete and produce; households receive the payoffs from their
positions in firms and consume. We now detail each of these steps.

2.1

Firms

A continuum of firms, indexed by i and with total mass Me , is created in equilibrium at date 0. At date 1, firms enter the production stage, and their productivity ai is revealed. To capture competition across these firms, we assume that
only a fixed number M of the most productive firms is able to produce. Given
the cumulative distribution function of productivities in the population F , only

8

firms above a cutoff a are able to produce, with
a := F

−1



M
1−
.
Me

(1)

The profits of a firm with productivity a are then given by
π(a) = aη · 1 {a ≥ a} ,

(2)

where η determines how differences in productivities translate into differences
in generated profits, and the indicator function captures whether the firm produces or not.8 We concentrate on situations where Me < M , so that fewer firms
produce than are created; the case where Me = M is straightforward.
This allocation of production slots is the key assumption to capture the notion of business-stealing. Indeed, firms do not internalize that they might take
over the slot of another firm. The assumption of a fixed mass of production slots
is especially plausible in industries that depend heavily on innovation. For instance, intellectual property law often provides exclusive use of a technology to
its inventor.9 We can interpret the fixed production slots as corresponding to a
fixed number of M processes to produce the homogeneous good. The first firm to
discover a process gets its exclusive use, and the speed of discovery is perfectly
correlated with the productivity type a. Alternatively, we can assume that to produce, a firm needs one unit of an indivisible good that has not been discovered
yet, and that only M of those exists in nature. Again firms with a higher type
a find the ingredient faster.10 Our assumption relies more generally on scarcity
in the ability to produce that is not internalized by individual firms. We show in
Appendix C how our results hold for a wide range of models of business-stealing,
some of which allow for endogenous variation in M .
Formally, these firms constitute the whole economy. However, one can inter8

The fact that the marginal active firm collects positive profits improves tractability but is
not crucial to our conclusions. We show in Appendix C.3 that our results also hold in a variant
of the model where the marginal firm earns zero profits.
9
Another motivation for the incompleteness is the difficulty of establishing markets for what
has not been encountered yet. It is often the case that nobody owns something before it is
discovered. For instance, how could we trade nuclear power before Henri Becquerel, Marie
Curie, and Pierre Curie discovered radioactivity?
10
Network goods or industries facing institutional constraints can face similar frictions in the
allocations of productive positions that lead to a business-stealing effect—see Borjas and Doran
(2012) for evidence in the context of scientific research.

9

pret the model as representing one sector of an economy.11 Our results would
be unchanged as long as firms do not interact across sectors because we assume
the presence of a quasilinear good in the next section.

2.2

Households

Households play two roles in the model. They work to create the blueprints
for new firms, and they speculate on which of the new firms will succeed. Formally, there is a unit mass of households indexed by j. At date 0, household
j is endowed with a fixed unit of consumption good c0 and her share of firm
creators, which we describe in the next section. In addition, each household decides how many blueprints to supply, bj . Blueprints are produced at a convex
cost W (bj ) = fe bθ+1
M −θ /(θ + 1), where the parameter θ is the elasticity of supply
j
of blueprints and fe controls the level of production costs. Finally, each household also decides on the number of shares to invest in each firm on the financial
market, {sji }i . Households have heterogeneous beliefs about the distribution of
productivity ai for each firm i, which we describe in detail below. We assume
that they can only take long positions in claims to firms.12
Households behave competitively and take prices as given. Hence, household
j solves the problem
j

Z

sji πi di



− W (bj )
max c0 + E
Z
s.t. c0 + sji pi di ≤ 1 + pb bj + Π,
c0 ,sji ≥0,bj

(3)
(4)

where pi and pb are the respective prices of firm i and blueprints, Ej is household
j expectation and Π denotes firm creators’ aggregate profits.13
11

In an economy with multiple sectors, the inefficient levels of innovation we will show in the
model are a form of misallocation.
12
Such a hard constraint facilitates the analysis, but the important assumption is some limit
or cost to the ability to take short positions. The importance of limits to short-selling in models of disagreement has been well-known since the work of Miller (1977), Harrison and Kreps
(1978), or more recently Scheinkman and Xiong (2003). D’avolio (2002) and Jones and Lamont
(2002) document empirical evidence of such short-sale constraints, with the former showing that
these constraints increase with disagreement. A theoretical justification is provided by Duffie,
Garleanu, and Pedersen (2002), who microfound short-sale costs using a search model.
13
The assumption of risk neutrality does not play any role in the analysis.
alloour
 nFormally,
R j
−1
j
results would be identical if the objective of households were: c0 + U
E U( si πi di)
−

10

2.3

Beliefs

To capture the notion of speculation, we assume that households disagree about
which firms will be successful. Disagreement arises naturally in innovative
episodes: households must rely on their priors to evaluate new firms (or ideas)
and, in the absence of data on these firms, agree to disagree.14 In general, it is
challenging to keep track of heterogeneous beliefs about an entire set of firms.
We overcome this issue by imposing structure on the distribution of beliefs. We
assume that even though agents disagree about each individual firm, they agree
on the population distribution of firm productivity.15 We also assume that the
population distribution F follows a Pareto distribution: F (a) = 1 − a−γ for a ≥ 1.
A simple narrative for our specification of individual beliefs is as follows.
Each household organizes firms into a continuum of packets containing n firms
each and believes it knows the exact ranking of productivity draws within each
packet. We assume that the composition of packets and the order of firms within
packets is drawn in an i.i.d. equiprobable fashion across agents and firms, and
that each firm can only be in one packet. The parameter n controls the intensity
of disagreement. When n = 1, households consider all firms to be the same, with
their productivity drawn from F . As n increases, households can compare more
firms in each packet and thus have a stronger prior that the best firm in each
packet will have high productivity.
In equilibrium, household j only invests in the subset of firms that it considers to be the most productive in each of their respective packets. These firms
are perceived by household j to have productivity drawn from F n , the distribution of the maximum of n independent draws from F . Since households rank
firms differently, they have different beliefs about the productivity distribution
of any given firm and invest in different sets of firms, as illustrated in Figure 2.
Each household believes that the firms it invests in are, in expectation, more
W (bj ), where U(.) is an increasing and concave function.
14
Morris (1995) discusses arguments for heterogeneous priors, many of which are particularly
applicable in our setting. Besides the lack of information about new technology, the model generates specific testable predictions for the belief structure.
15
A motivation for focusing on disagreement across firms rather than about the aggregate is
the empirical observation that high firm entry in a sector often follows disruptive innovation,
either through a large technological change or the introduction of new products. New firms then
conduct micro innovations to take advantage of a macro innovation (Mokyr (1992)). Empirically,
these episodes appear particularly relevant to economic growth, as discussed for instance in
Abernathy (1978) and Freeman (1982).

11

32

43
14

etc.

21

34
23

14
Households

42

23
31

42

11

Figure 2
Households’ beliefs and choice of firms to invest in.
The figure illustrates the case of n = 4. For this figure, the composition of each packet is identical
across agents for exposition purposes. This choice does not affect the model results.

productive than the average firm in the economy.
Our analysis does not rely on the specific narrative of packet formation, even
though we find it intuitively appealing. The key mechanism is that when investors disagree, they each tilt their portfolio towards their favorite firms. As
disagreement increases, this specialization strengthens, and investors in each
given firm become more and more optimistic about its prospects. The crux of
our assumptions is to reduce the distribution of beliefs to two parameters: the
actual population distribution F and a single parameter n for the intensity of
disagreement. Two features of our assumptions facilitate the analysis. First,
while households disagree on which firms will succeed, they agree on the population distribution of firms. Hence, they agree on aggregate outcomes: both the
threshold a and market conditions, which will play a role in the richer settings in
Section 5. Second, beliefs are symmetric across households. This overcomes the
issue of having to keep track of the entire distribution of beliefs and allocations.

2.4

Firm Creators

Finally, firm creators connect the step of innovation and trading in financial
markets. They pay households to create blueprints, and issue claims to the corresponding firms on the financial market. Formally, there is a continuum of
12

short-lived firm creators. At date 0, each firm creator can use a unit blueprint to
create a new firm, which is then sold on competitive financial markets. They participate in competitive markets for blueprints and firms, taking their respective
prices pb and pi as given.16 The firm creator problem at time t = 0 is therefore:
max c · (pi − pb ).

(5)

c∈{0,1}

2.5

Competitive Equilibrium

The competitive equilibrium of the economy is defined as follows. Firm creators
maximize profits from selling their firms, taking prices as given. Households
maximize their perceived expected utility by choosing their optimal blueprint
discovery effort and a dynamic optimal portfolio allocation, taking the prices of
blueprints and firms as given. Firms maximize profits given their production
status. Finally, the markets for blueprints and claims to firms’ profits (the stock
market) clear:
Z
bj dj = Me ,
(6)
Z
∀i ∈ [0, Me ],
sji dj = 1.
(7)
Combining the equilibrium conditions yields a single equation determining
the quantity of firm entry Me :
0

W (Me ) = V

(n)

Z

∞

π(a)dF n (a).

(Me ) =

(8)

a

In equilibrium, the marginal cost of creating an additional firm, W 0 (Me ), is equal
to the expected profits to an investor who favors it, V (n) (Me ). Both of these
quantities are equal to the prices at which blueprints and firms trade in the
economy, pi = pb . Therefore, this condition also pins down the price of new firms.
We define the expected value of the firm:
Z

∞

aη dF n (a).

In (Me , η) :=
F −1 (1−M/M
16

e)

We assume firm creators do not have any information about the firms they create.

13

(9)

This value will play a prominent role in our analysis, with V (n) (Me ) = In (Me , η)
in the model here.

2.6

Bubbles

Our framework yields equilibrium behavior consistent with features of bubble
episodes related to the introduction of new technologies. Some well-documented
examples include railroads, electricity, automobiles, radios, micro-electronics,
personal computers, bio-technology, and the Internet. Scheinkman (2014) and
Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013) survey the field of speculation and bubbles;
Janeway (2012) gives a first-person account of the relationship between innovation and speculation.
In the model, when investors disagree more, they assign a higher value to
the firms they value most. As n increases, the demand for firms V n (.) shifts
up. The higher demand from financial market participants increases the price
of firms pi and leads to more new firms Me . This reflects the boom phase of a
bubble: many new innovations are implemented and firms created, and prices
on financial markets are high. Subsequently, however, not all investors can
be right. Prices fall as output is below the level they imply. Formally, firms
are priced at In , under the distribution F n , but the average output is only I1 ,
under the population distribution F . This drop corresponds to the bust phase
of a bubble. In the empirical analysis in Section 4, we use the abnormal price
increase in the first phase of a boom to distinguish bubble periods, following
Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018). While they also show that conditioning
on a bust helps capture more features of bubbles, the ex-post nature of this
conditioning would be an issue for our empirical tests.
A more formal definition of a bubble is a situation in which asset prices exceed an asset’s fundamental value (see, for example, Brunnermeier (2016)). The
drop in prices at date 1 is expected by all investors—they agree on aggregate
outcomes—and supports this definition. How can all investors agree that the
market portfolio is overpriced? Such a situation arises from households’ heterogeneous beliefs. Different households view different firms as the most valuable
and specialize their portfolios in those firms, which seem fairly priced to them.
The short-sale constraint prevents each household from shorting the other firms,

14

which it views as overpriced.17 Chen, Hong, and Stein (2002), Diether, Malloy,
and Scherbina (2002), and Yu (2011) establish empirically the link between dispersed beliefs and low future returns.18
Our model takes a static view of speculation, but in practice, investors’ views
change over time. In Appendix C.1, we study an extension of the model that
entertains this possibility. A stronger form of overvaluation arises: the price
of each firm exceeds the maximum valuation of its cash-flow by any specific
investor in the economy. This difference comes from the fact that when investors
change views, the current investor of a specific firm will typically not favor it
anymore and sell it to somebody else. Hence, each time households trade firms
signals a change in who values which firms the most, a mechanism similar to
the models of Harrison and Kreps (1978) and Scheinkman and Xiong (2003). We
show that this dynamic overvaluation is increasing in volume per period and the
length of the bubble. Historically, abnormally high trading volume is seen as a
hallmark of bubbles — see Scheinkman (2014) for a survey. For example, during
the Roaring Twenties, daily records of share trading volume were reached ten
times in 1928 and three times in 1929, with no new record set until 1968 (Hong
and Stein, 2007). More recently, during the dot-com bubble, internet stocks had
three times the turnover of otherwise similar stocks. Greenwood, Shleifer, and
You (2018) also document that large stock price increases are more likely to end
in a crash when they are accompanied by increased trading volume.
Finally, while our model does not provide an explicit premise for increases in
disagreement, it is natural to expect disagreement during innovative episodes.
As investors see these ideas and firms for the first time, they must rely on their
priors to evaluate them. In contrast, more mature industries are likely associated with more common information that investors might have accumulated
over time, accompanied by stronger agreement about what makes a firm successful. Consistent with this view, Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) find
17
Van den Steen (2004) describes how disagreement combined with optimal choice leads to
overvaluation and Miller (1977) first pointed out the importance of short-sale constraints in
financial markets.
18
Using investor survey data to quantify disagreement, Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002)
find that stocks with dispersed analysts’ forecasts experience low subsequent returns. Yu (2011)
aggregates this measure to portfolios such as the market portfolio and finds a similar result.
Using stock market positions to measure disagreement, Chen, Hong, and Stein (2002) construct
the fraction of the mutual fund population investing in a given stock, a measure of the breadth
of ownership for individual stocks. They find that this measure predicts low stock returns.

15

that when the price run-up in an industry occurs disproportionately among the
younger firms, crashes and low future returns are more likely.
All these observations suggest that the model is a useful representation of
the episodes we are interested in. They are comforting as we turn to use the
model to make new predictions about the value of innovation.

3

The Value of Innovation

We are interested in two notions of the value of an innovation: the private value,
which accrues to its investors, and the social value, which is its impact on the
economy overall. Understanding these two notions is important because they
shed light on how the process of innovation alters the economy and ultimately
creates growth. We study two approaches to measure these values: marketbased measures of value that use asset prices and outcome-based measures of
value that use real outcomes, such as patent citations or output. In our model,
these two spillover measures diverge in systematic ways during bubbles, providing predictions that we test in Section 4.

3.1

Private Value

The private value of a firm is the value of that firm to its investors. Consider
first the market-based measure of this value. Empirically, the change in stock
price of a firm following an innovation, as measured by Kogan et al. (2017),
reveals the market-based private value. In the model, the market-based private
value is simply the price pi = In (Me ) at which the firm trades. This is because
an innovation and a firm coincide, an assumption we make for simplicity.19 As
discussed in the previous section, this value increases during bubble episodes
(large n).
The outcome-based counterpart to this metric is the actual effect of an innovation. In the data, it can be measured by the number of citations a patent
receives or changes in sales following the introduction of an innovation. In the
model, the realized output of the firm is the outcome-based private value. On
average, the output of a firm is given by I1 (Me ), and all investors agree about
19

In our empirical exercise, we will come back to the distinction between innovation and firm.

16

this. In the absence of disagreement, n = 1, market-based and outcome-based
private values coincide. However, as n increases, the two values diverge and the
ratio In (Me )/I1 (Me ) increases. In other words, the increase in market value due
to speculation does not reflect a commensurate increase in fundamentals.
These two predictions are the defining properties of bubbles applied to innovation. The market value of an innovation increases during a bubble. This
increase is not justified by a change in outcomes. However, our analysis below of
social value in the model paints a more subtle picture than a naive theory that
simply states that all valuations are higher than usual during a bubble.

3.2

Social Value

The social value of a firm is the effect of introducing this firm on the whole
economy. A new firm in the economy has a direct effect (its private value) and
an indirect effect because it affects the value of other firms. To characterize how
social value departs from private value, we introduce the measure spillover. We
define spillover as the indirect effect of a new firm scaled by its private value:
spillover =

social value − private value
private value

(10)

Empirically, this definition coincides with estimating the elasticity of firm value
to the unexpected entry of another firm, closely related to Bloom, Schankerman,
and Van Reenen (2013). Similar to the measure of private value introduced
above, we consider both market-based spillover using asset prices and outcomebased spillover using output.
In the model with agreement, we find no distinction between the market- and
outcome-based spillover, since the price of claims to a firm in period 0 is equal
to the mean firm profits in period 1. In contrast, speculation introduces a gap
between the two spillover measures, leading to novel empirical predictions.
3.2.1

Spillovers in the Model

In the model, spillovers arise because of the business-stealing effect. A new firm
that enters may take up a production slot and displace an existing firm.
Computing the spillovers in the model is challenging because the baseline

17

model of Section 2 does not feature unexpected entry: the number of firms is
deterministic in equilibrium. We overcome this challenge by introducing the
possibility that some blueprints randomly fail to be implemented. Formally, after firm creators purchase blueprints but before they introduce these blueprints
to public markets, a fraction of them disappear. If Me blueprints are created, either they all succeed or a mass ∆ fails, with probability 1 − ε and ε, respectively.
By focusing on the limit when ε and ∆ go to zero, we trace out the equilibrium
effect of the unanticipated entry of an atomistic firm on the total value of the
economy.
Comparing the total market value of the economy across the two outcomes,
we obtain the market-based social value of an extra firm:
social valuemkt

Me V (n) (Me ) − (Me − ∆)V (n) (Me − ∆)
= lim
∆→0
∆
(n)
(n)0
= V (Me ) + Me V (Me )

(11)
(12)

For the outcome-based social value, simply replace n by 1 in this expression. We
recognize the two effects of introducing a new firm. The first term is the direct
effect: the private value of a new firm V (n) (Me ). The second term is the change in
the value of all other firms in response to the entry of the new firm. Each of the
Me firms in the economy sees its value decrease by V (n)0 (Me ). Taking the ratio of
the direct and the indirect effect, we obtain the two measures of spillover:
spillmkt
spillout

Me V (n)0 (Me )
,
=
V (n) (Me )
Me V (1)0 (Me )
=
.
V (1) (Me )

(13)
(14)

We recognize the elasticity of the value of a firm to the number of firms, EIn .20
Again, this elasticity is negative because of the business-stealing effect. The
entry of a new firm makes all other firms less likely to produce.
In the remainder of this section, we derive properties of the spillover measures. In particular, we relate them to the intensity of speculation. Before doing
so, it is worth pointing out a deeper interpretation of the spillover. The spillover
20

Throughout the paper, we denote the elasticity of quantity X to firm entry Me by EX =
d log(X)/d log(Me ).

18

measures the intensity of entry externalities in the economy and, as such, corresponds to a Pigouvian tax on entry. We come back to this implication at length in
Section 6. For now, just note that for a non-paternalistic planner, the expression
for the optimal tax rate is negative of the spillover: τ = −spillmkt .
3.2.2

Outcome-Based Spillover

The outcome-based spillover is the elasticity of the average output of a firm with
respect to the number of firms in the economy. We compute explicitly spillout
from the expression of equation (14), replacing the output of a firm with I1 :
Z

∞

π(a)dF (a)
a

spillout = − Z

=−

∞

π(a)dF (a)

γ−η
.
γ

(15)

a

The ratio of the two integrals has an intuitive explanation. The numerator represents the expected amount of profits displaced by the introduction of a new
firm. It is the product of the output of the marginal producing firm (the firm that
R∞
will get displaced) with the probability that that firm gets displaced, a dF (a).
The denominator is the expected output of a new firm.
Displacement lowers aggregate output, thus spillout is negative. However, displacement only occurs when the new firm is more productive than an existing
firm, thus |spillout | < 1. There are less spillovers if the distribution of firm productivity is more dispersed (lower values of γ) or when productivity differences
translate into larger output differences (larger values of η).
The outcome-based spillover spillout does not depend on the equilibrium number of firms Me . Technically, this result is the consequence of specifying a power
production function and a Pareto productivity distribution.21 As the level of disagreement changes, the outcome-based spillover stays constant. This prediction
provides a useful benchmark against which to evaluate the behavior of marketbased spillovers. In Section 4, we confirm this prediction empirically, thereby
validating our framework.
21

Under a Pareto distribution, the ratio between marginal and average productivity is independent of the lower cutoff.

19

3.2.3

Market-Based Spillover

The market-based spillover is the elasticity of the value of a firm to the number
of firms in the economy. In the case of agreement (n = 1), market values and average outputs coincide; therefore, market-based and outcome-based measures of
spillovers are identical. However, with disagreement, the two measures diverge,
and spillmkt is not constant.
Proposition 1. Speculation lowers the intensity of market-based spillovers:
|spillmkt (n)| < |spillmkt (1)| ,

for n > 1

(16)

Under disagreement, value spillovers are smaller despite the level of firm entry being higher. This seeming contradiction arises because the beliefs of households impact their valuation of equilibrium allocations. Under disagreement,
households only invest in their favorite firms. Therefore, each household places
a lower probability on being displaced by new entrants, thereby reducing the
effect of the business-stealing externality on the market prices that determine
the market-based spillovers.
More formally, we can rewrite the market-based spillover from (13) in its
integral form:
∞

Fn0
π(a) 0 (a) dF (a)
0
F
Me V (n) (Me )
a
= −Z ∞
.
spillmkt (n) =
(n)
Fn0
V (Me )
π(a) 0 (a) dF (a)
F
a
Z

(17)

This ratio compares the value of displaced firms to the value of the firm displacing them, evaluated through the beliefs of their respective investors. Holding
Me and thus a constant, consider how this ratio changes with n. The numerator is the expected value of a displaced firm from the point of view of its owners.
Disagreement affects this value through the change in probability weights Fn0 /F 0
at the threshold a. In contrast, the denominator is the profit of an average firm
from the point of view of its owners. This quantity is affected by changes in the
probability weights throughout the distribution above the threshold. Because increasing n corresponds to shifting the perceived distribution of productivities to
the right, the change in probability weights is increasing as we move to higher
20

productivities (see Appendix Figure IA.1). Such an increase affects expected
profits more strongly than the value of displaced firms, decreasing the wedge.
In Appendix A.1, we show that this result holds more generally with minimal
assumptions on the productivity distribution F (·) and profit function π(·).
This proposition gives rise to a clear prediction we test in the data: the
market-based spillovers are lower in speculative periods. Following Bloom,
Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013), we can measure these spillovers by
gauging the reaction of firms’ valuations to variation in the amount of innovation by their competitors. In addition, we can also compare market-based
and outcome-based spillovers. An immediate corollary of Proposition 1 is that
the presence of speculation reduces market-based spillovers relative to outcomebased spillovers. These results of our model of bubbles differ from naive theories.
For example, one common view is that bubbles inflate the price of all firms proportionally, either because people use too low a discount rate or overestimate
the output of all firms. Under such a theory, because the market-based spillover
is a ratio of valuations, it is unaffected and remains equal to the output-based
spillover.
High speculation limit. We now consider the limiting case of high speculation: n → ∞. This case is extreme: the total quantity of entry goes to infinity. However, it is useful because it gives rise to sharp characterizations of the
spillovers, allowing us to highlight the distinction between market-based and
outcome-based spillovers with disagreement.
Proposition 2. In the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), the market-based
spillover converges to a finite limit that depends on the sign of γθ − η:
• If γθ > η, the market-based spillover vanishes: limn→∞ spillmkt (n) = 0
• If γθ < η, then τ converges to the spillover in the agreement case (n = 1):
limn→∞ spillmkt (n) = γ−η
γ
ˇ mkt > − γ−η , where
• In the knife-edge case of γθ = η, limn→∞ spillmkt (n) = spill
γ
ˇ mkt is defined in Appendix equation (IA.16).
spill
Figure 3 illustrates these cases. Appendix C.2 shows that the results hold in
more general models of business stealing.
21

0

Spillover

γθ > η

−0.2

γθ = η

−0.4
γθ < η

−0.6

Disagreement n
Figure 3
Market-based spillover with increasing disagreement.
Two forces determine the asymptotic behavior of the market-based spillover.
First, with more disagreement, investors increasingly believe that the firms they
invest in are in the right tail of the productivity distribution. They are therefore
less concerned about the risk of being displaced by new entrants because they
expect that a smaller mass of firms in their portfolio will fail to meet the entry
threshold. For a given level of entry Me , this mass converges to 0 as n goes to
infinity. This is an extreme case of the result in Proposition 1.
Second, disagreement increases firm entry. For a given level of disagreement,
n, as Me converges to infinity, the M producing firms end up in the tail of both
the population distribution, F , and the favorite-firm distribution, Fn . The tails
of these two distributions have the same shape since limx→∞ Fn0 (x)/F 0 (x) = n.22
Therefore, disagreement does not affect the relative position of the marginal and
average valuation in the tail. This force brings the market-based spillovers back
toward the level of outcome-based spillovers.
The relative strength of the forces depends of how fast firm creation increases
with speculation. If γθ > η, the first force dominates. When θ is large, the
marginal cost of firm creation rises more rapidly, which reduces equilibrium
entry Me and weakens the second force. As γ increases, we have a thinner-tailed
firm-productivity distribution. The size of the tail becomes less important than
the relative ordering of firms, which weakens the second force. As η decreases,
profits increase less with productivity, which again diminishes the importance
22

This extreme value theory result is not the byproduct of power distributions but rather
applies to a larger class of distributions.

22

of the second force. In the data, we find that the valuations increase faster than
quantity during bubbles, consistent with the case of γθ > η.23 The relevant
prediction is therefore a decrease in spillovers toward 0.

4

Empirical Evidence

We now take the three main predictions of the model to the data. First, the
market-based measure of the private value of innovation increases with speculation. Second, market-based competitive spillovers decrease in the presence of
speculation. Finally, outcome-based measures respond relatively less, or not at
all.

4.1

Data

To test these predictions, we combine variation in whether an industry experiences a bubble with measures of the private and social values of innovation at
the firm and patent level. This approach maps to an interpretation of the model
in which there are multiple sectors, and each sector and time experiences its
own level of disagreement. Summary statistics of the main regression variables
are contained in Table 1.
Bubbles. We proxy for the presence of speculation using the empirical definition of bubbles from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018). We split firms
into 49 industries following the classification from Fama and French (1997). An
industry-month is defined as being in a bubble if it satisfies three conditions simultaneously. First, the value-weighted portfolio of the corresponding industry
experienced a return of 100% or more over the previous two years. Second, this
industry value-weighted return also exceeds the return of the market by at least
100% over the past two years. Third, the industry value-weighted return over
the past five years is larger than 50%. We aggregate to the industry-year level—
the coarseness of the remainder of our data—by considering an industry-year in
23

Specifically, we find in the next section that the valuation of innovation increases by 40%
during bubbles, while the quantity of innovation increases only by 15%, so θ > 1. Because η < γ
is always satisfied, we have γθ > η.

23

Table 1
Summary Statistics

Bubble
Bubble Periods Dummy

N

Mean

Std. Dev.

25th pct.

Median

2,734

0.0271

0.162

0

0

0

14
12

37.8
22.6

2.32
2

5.46
5

12.7
13

Value of Innovation (KPSS)
Patent Level Value
Stock Market ($ Mn)
1,171,806
Citations (fwd. looking) 1,171,806

75th pct.

Firm Level Value
Stock Market ($ Mn)
Citations (fwd. looking)

47,887
47,887

232
52.9

1880
236

0.519
2.88

3.06
7.8

24.5
26.7

Firm Level Statistics
Mkt. Cap. ($ Mn)
Segments (# NAICS-4)
Segments (# NAICS-6)

47,887
53,066
53,066

2854
1.33
1.41

14667
0.646
0.729

47.2
1
1

200
1
1

949
2
2

Measuring Spillovers (BSvR)
Firm Outcomes (real or market valued)
Sales ($ Mn)
9,382
Tobin’s q
9,382

3563
2.46

12626
3.09

135
0.86

509
1.49

2037
2.71

Measures of Spillovers (Jaffe)
Technology
9,382
Competition
9,382

9.8
7.32

1.02
2.35

9.34
6.33

9.97
7.64

10.5
9.01

Measures of Spillover (Mahalonobis)
Technology
9,382
Competition
9,382

11.4
8.53

0.821
1.73

10.9
7.87

11.5
8.77

11.9
9.74

Note: Table 1 presents summary statistics of the main variables included in the regression specifications. The bubble
dummy corresponds to bubble detected across the Fama-French 49 industries, according to the methodology outlined
in Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018). The value of innovation both at the firm and patent level is directly taken
from Kogan et al. (2017). The stock market value of innovation at the patent level corresponds to the appreciation
in the value of a firm issuing a patent around the patent-issuance date. The stock market value of innovation at
the firm level corresponds to an annual aggregation of the total value of all patents issued by a firm in a given year.
Both the patent- and firm-level citation value of a patent corresponds to its forward looking number of citations
(until the end of the sample in 2010). Other firm-level statistics correspond to the CRSP-Compustat merged file (for
market capitalization, sales, and Tobin’s q) and to the Compustat segments file. Tobin’s q is measured from Bloom,
Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) as the market value of equity plus debt divided by the stock of fixed capital.
We obtain measures of technological and competition spillovers from Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013),
corresponding to the distance between the technological class of patents issued by a firm with other public firms and
to the distance between the set of product market of a firm and other public competitors.

a bubble if the industry is in a bubble for at least a month in the year. In practice, multiple months are always in a bubble year due to the persistence of the

24

bubble criteria. This approach identifies 74 industry-years in a bubble between
1962 and 2017.
Consistent with our model, Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) find that
“price run-ups ... involving younger firms [and] having higher relative returns
among the younger firms ... [are] more likely to crash.” These industries with
young and innovative firms are likely to have scarce information, making them
more susceptible to the disagreement that we model. We also confirm the validity of the bubble classification empirically and show that it predicts increases
in innovation like the model. In Appendix Table IA.1, we show that there are
1.4 more patents issued within a USPTO technology class during bubbles, which
translates to a 15% increase in the number of patents created in a patent class
during a bubble.
Private value of innovation. We use the measures of private value of innovation from Kogan et al. (2017). Their dataset combines stock market and
patent data for U.S. firms for the period from 1926 through 2010. They measure the stock market response in the three-day window after a firm has a new
patent issued, controlling for the return on the market portfolio during that period. This number is the direct counterpart to the market-based measure of
private value of a new innovation in our framework. Kogan et al. (2017) also
aggregate the stock market value from all the patents of a given firm every year
to measure the value of innovation at the firm level. To capture the ultimate
quality of each patent, Kogan et al. (2017) use the forward-looking number of
citations generated by a patent for their patent-level analysis and the number
of citations generated by all the patents produced by a firm in a given year for
their firm-level analysis. This corresponds to the outcome-based measure of the
private value of a new innovation in the model. While our baseline model takes
each firm to correspond to exactly one blueprint and thus does not distinguish
between the patent and firm level, we conduct both patent-level and firm-level
empirical analysis and show that the two approaches support our model predictions.
Social value of innovation. For the social value of innovation, Bloom,
Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) identify spillovers from different sources

25

of firm interactions. They regress a firm-level outcome—log market value or log
future sales—on the quantity of innovation by groups of “neighboring” firms. Because the set of close competitors and the set of close innovators do not coincide,
this approach separates competitive spillovers arising from firms in neighboring industries and knowledge spillovers coming from firms issuing patents in
the same technology USPTO class. Specifically, they first construct distances
between firms in each of these two spaces. Then, for each firm-year, they compute distance-weighted stocks of innovative capital from all other firms. The
resulting firm-level exposures are spillsic and spilltech, respectively, and regressions on these quantities measure competitive and innovative spillovers. Because our baseline model only considers competitive interactions—Section 5 extends to other sources of interactions—we are particularly interested in competitive spillovers. Nevertheless, we control for innovative interactions. When
the left-hand side of the regression is log market value, this approach identifies
the market-based spillover. When focusing on log sales, the coefficients identify
the outcome-based spillover. Taking the log ensures that we are considering a
semi-elasticity, the counterpart to the spillover in the model.
Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) propose a variety of metrics for
distance. We follow their construction. Proximity between two competing firms
in the product market space is the correlation of the firms’ distribution of sales
across their industry segments. Technology proximity is analogously defined
as the correlation of patent USPTO technology classes between firms, following earlier work by Jaffe (1986). The quantities of innovation by competitors
and close innovators are the stocks of innovation weighted by these correlations.
The stock of innovation is constructed using a perpetual-inventory approach.
Both measures are extended using the Mahalanobis distance to allow for flexible weighting of the correlation between firms across different technology or
product market classes. Further details on the measures of spillovers can be
found in Appendix E and in Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013).

4.2

The Private Value of Innovation During Bubbles

Market-based private value of innovation increases in bubbles. To
study the effect of speculation on the private value of innovation at the patent

26

level, we consider the following regression specification:
log ξj,t = βBj,t + γZj,t + εj,t ,

(18)

where ξj,t is the private value of patent j issued during year t using the marketbased measure from Kogan et al. (2017). The variable Bj,t is an indicator for
whether the firm issuing patent j was in an industry experiencing a bubble
during year t. As in Kogan et al. (2017), the controls Zj,t include log of the
number of citations for the patent, market capitalization, and year dummies.
We take the market capitalization lagged by one year because the value of a
firm’s stock tends to rise during a bubble. The lagged market capitalization
variable controls for the size of the firm without contaminating our estimate of
how the private value varies with speculation. To ensure that our results are not
driven by the type of firms or industries that go through bubbles, we include firm
fixed effects. We run a similar regression at the firm level, replacing the private
value and citation variables with their firm-level analogs. We no longer control
for market capitalization because the firm-level measure of private innovation
value is normalized by book value. Following Kogan et al. (2017), we include
year fixed effects in this specification.
Table 2 shows that speculation indeed increases the private value of innovation. In particular, the presence of a bubble increases the private value of
innovation by approximately 30% at the patent level and 40% to 50% at the firm
level. These effects are both economically and statistically significant.
We stress that an increase in the market-based measure of the private value
of innovation in a bubble is not mechanical. We measure bubbles as times of
high stock market valuations, which do not necessarily coincide with a strong
positive response to the news of issuing a patent. This positive response is a
direct implication of our model in which bubbles arise in times of high private
value of innovations. In contrast, the common view that bubbles are episodes
in which prices are completely disconnected from fundamentals would not make
such a prediction. Under this view, valuations could be high overall but would
not be responsive to patent issuance.
Diversity dampens the effect of speculation. In our model, one firm coincides with a single blueprint. In the data, firms can issue multiple patents
27

Table 2
Private Value of Innovation in Bubbles
Patent Level

Bubble Dummy

Firm Level

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

0.317∗∗∗
(0.094)

0.315∗∗∗
(0.094)

0.306∗∗∗
(0.096)

0.514∗∗∗
(0.114)

0.427∗∗∗
(0.123)

0.427∗∗∗
(0.080)

0.016∗∗∗
(0.004)

0.023∗∗∗
(0.005)
0.562∗∗∗
(0.028)

0.823∗∗∗
(0.011)

0.716∗∗∗
(0.009)
0.626∗∗∗
(0.020)

Log Citations
(forward looking)
Log Market Cap
(lagged)
Fixed Effects

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Observations
R2

1,171,806
0.68

1,171,806
0.68

1,169,860
0.74

47,886
0.89

47,886
0.94

47,484
0.96

Note: Table 2 presents panel regressions of the value of innovation, as measured in Kogan et al. (2017) at the patent
and firm levels, on a dummy from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) that captures whether the firm is in an
industry that is in a bubble or not. We control for the lagged market capitalization of the firm and include fixed
effects for firm F and patent grant year Y . Standard errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *,
**, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

during the same year. The empirical distinction between patent and firm yields
an additional source of variation not captured by our simple theory: some firms
operate in multiple sectors. This variation naturally interacts with our mechanism: the effect of a bubble should be smaller for firms that have more diversified activities. Narrow firms, as opposed to firms that span multiple product
lines, cater to specific investors who tend to have strong beliefs in their success.
Thus, we expect a “conglomerate discount” on the value of innovation in times of
bubbles: in the presence of disagreement or bubbles, multiple-product firms experience a smaller increase in the value of their innovation than narrow firms.24
To test this prediction empirically, we measure diversity with the variable
Segmentsj,t , which is the number of four-digit NAICS industries that a firm is
active in. We collect this information from the Compustat segments files. We
augment regression (18) with Bj,t × Segmentsj,t .25
As predicted, we find in Table 3 that the greater the number of segments, the
24

Reed, Saffi, and Van Wesep (2020) provide empirical evidence of a similar conglomerate
discount in stock valuations. Huang et al. (2020) document a similar discount in portfolios.
25
Appendix Table IA.3 shows that the results are robust to using a definition of different segments using six-digit NAICS industries.

28

Table 3
Diversity and Private Value of Innovation in Bubbles
Patent Level
(1)
Bubble x Segments −0.612∗∗∗
(NAICS 4 digits)
(0.157)
Bubble
Segments
(NAICS 4 digits)
Log Citations
(forward looking)
Log Market Cap
(lagged)

1.471∗∗∗
(0.198)
0.309∗∗∗
(0.097)

Firm Level

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

−0.600∗∗∗
(0.155)

−0.533∗∗∗
(0.148)

−0.473∗∗∗
(0.109)

−0.402∗∗∗
(0.080)

−0.307∗∗∗
(0.069)

1.441∗∗∗
(0.192)
0.305∗∗∗
(0.096)
0.047∗∗∗
(0.010)

1.335∗∗∗
(0.205)
0.296∗∗∗
(0.100)
0.044∗∗∗
(0.009)
0.154∗∗∗
(0.040)

1.576∗∗∗
(0.267)
0.062
(0.043)

1.431∗∗∗
(0.323)
0.015
(0.045)
0.044∗∗∗
(0.009)

1.180∗∗∗
(0.288)
0.014
(0.037)
0.044∗∗∗
(0.009)
0.286∗∗∗
(0.046)

Fixed Effects

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Observations
R2

180,636
0.72

180,636
0.72

177,911
0.72

10,426
0.88

10,426
0.93

10,256
0.94

Note: Table 3 presents panel regressions of the value of innovation, as measured in Kogan et al. (2017) at the patent
and firm levels, on a bubble dummy interacted with the number of industries spanned by the different segments of
the parent firm. The bubble dummy is from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) and captures whether the firm is in
an industry that is in a bubble or not. Compustat segments are measured at the four-digit NAICS code level from the
Compustat segments file. We control for the forward-looking number of citations generated by a patent (or firm) from
Kogan et al. (2017), and the lagged market capitalization of the firm. We include fixed effects for firm F and patent
grant year Y . Standard errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance
at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

less the private value of innovation increases in a bubble, as indicated by the
significantly negative coefficient on the Bj,t × Segmentsj,t regressor. Moreover,
the effect of a bubble on the value of a patent for a firm with more than one
segment is not statistically significant. Qualitatively, we find the same results
whether we run the regressions at the patent level or the firm level.
Innovation quality does not see a commensurate increase in bubbles.
Another prediction of our theory is that the market-based private value of innovation increases during bubbles relative to the outcome-based private value.
In the model, this comparison is particularly sharp because firm productivity is
drawn from the same distribution F in date 1 regardless of the level of disagreement, thus innovation quality does not depend on speculation. We now show
empirically that there is, in fact, no significant increase in innovation quality,
29

Table 4
Number of Citations for Innovation in Bubbles
Patent Level
(1)
Bubble Dummy

0.112∗∗∗
(0.028)

Firm Level
(2)

(3)

(4)

0.113∗∗∗
(0.027)

0.106∗∗∗
(0.034)

0.107∗∗∗
(0.041)

−0.034∗∗∗
(0.008)

Log Market Cap
(lagged)

0.234∗∗∗
(0.008)

Fixed Effects

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Observations
R2

1,171,806
0.35

1,169,860
0.35

47,887
0.78

47,484
0.79

Note: Table 4 presents panel regressions of the number of citations (forward looking until the end of the sample),
as measured in Kogan et al. (2017) at the patent and firm levels, on a bubble dummy interacted with the number of
industries spanned by the different segments of the parent firm. The bubble dummy is measured from Greenwood,
Shleifer, and You (2018) and captures whether the firm is in an industry that is in a bubble state or not. We control
for the lagged market capitalization of the firm and include fixed effects for firm F and patent grant year Y . Standard
errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%
levels, respectively.

the outcome-based measure of the value of innovation, during bubbles.
In particular, we consider:
log (1 + Cj,t ) = βBj,t + γZj,t + εj,t ,

(19)

where Cj,t is the forward-looking number of citations received by a patent j issued in year t. The controls Zj,t include the lagged market value of the firm,
and a year and firm fixed effect as in equation (18). As before, we also run the
firm-level analog.
Table 4 reports that the quality of innovation sees a slight increase during
bubbles. The number of citations is 10% higher in times of bubbles. This increase arises partly from the higher number of patents issued during bubbles.
To understand why the increase in citations is small relative to the increase
in the market value of innovation in bubbles from Table 2, we need to translate
these two sets of estimates into the same units. We convert citations into dollars
by reproducing the estimates from Kogan et al. (2017) in Appendix Table IA.4.
We find that within a patent-class-year (i.e. excluding the variation due to bubbles), a 10% increase in citations corresponds to a 0.1% to 1.7% increase in stock
30

market valuation. This number is substantially smaller than the direct effect of
a 30% increase in market-based private value during bubbles. Thus, the quality
of innovation as measured by future citations does not experience a rise comparable to the market-based private value, in line with the model predictions.

4.3

The Social Value of Innovation During Bubbles

Our model predicts that market-based measures of spillovers from competitors are dampened during bubbles, while outcome-based measures of spillovers
are not. We test these hypotheses empirically by enriching the specification of
Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) to estimate spillovers conditional
on a bubble:
log Xi,t = β (Bi,t × log spillsici,t ) + γ1 log spillsici,t
+ γ2 log spilltechi,t + γ3 Bi,t + δZi,t + εi,t ,

(20)

where Xi,t is either the market value (Tobin’s q) or output (sales normalized
by an industry price index) of firm i in year t. As before, Bi,t is an indicator
of whether firm i is in an industry that experienced a bubble in year t. The
controls Zi,t are taken from Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) and
include firm and year fixed effects. Taking Xi,t to be the market value of the firm,
we measure the market-based spillovers. On the other hand, for outcome-based
measures of spillovers, we take Xi,t to be firm output. Our hypotheses are that β
is positive for the market value, and β is equal to 0 for firm output. Market-based
spillovers disappear with speculation as investors ignore the business-stealing
effect, while outcome-based spillovers are unchanged.
Table 5 shows that the regression results are consistent with the predictions
of our model. The coefficient on the interaction term captures the change in
spillovers accompanying an increase in speculation. The coefficient is significantly positive in the market-based spillover regressions, indicating a reduction
in the business-stealing effect. Moreover, the estimated business-stealing effect in a bubble, captured by the sum of coefficients on spillsic and the interaction term, is not significantly different from zero, although the point estimate
is positive. These estimates suggest that the business-stealing effect vanishes
completely during bubbles, consistent with our high speculation asymptotics in
31

Table 5
Social Value of Innovation and Bubbles
Market-based Spillovers
Jaffe
(1)
Bubble x Spill-SIC
Spill-SIC
Spill-Tech

Outcome-based Spillovers

Mahalanobis
(2)

Jaffe
(3)

Mahalanobis
(4)

0.152∗∗∗
(0.027)

0.200∗∗∗
(0.037)

0.004
(0.009)

−0.000
(0.013)

−0.088∗∗∗
(0.016)
0.405∗∗∗
(0.145)

−0.103∗∗∗
(0.033)
0.844∗∗∗
(0.174)

−0.021∗∗∗
(0.006)
0.175∗∗∗
(0.025)

−0.021∗∗
(0.010)
0.159∗∗∗
(0.040)

Fixed Effects

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Observations
R2

8,896
0.74

8,946
0.74

8,775
0.99

8,825
0.99

Note: Table 5 presents panel regressions of firm value (Tobin’s q or log of sales) on a measure of competition from
Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) interacted with a dummy from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018)
that captures whether the firm is in an industry that is in a bubble or not. We control for the technological spillover
measure that corresponds to public firms that issue patents in similar technological space. We follow the specification
from Tables III and V of Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) for the Tobin’s q and sales regressions,
respectively. We also include fixed effects for firm F and patent grant year Y . Standard errors clustered at the year
level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Proposition 2 with inelastic entry (γθ > η). In contrast, the presence of a bubble
does not have any effect on outcome-based measures of spillovers. Again, this
result is in line with our model.
Besides confirming our theory, these results also reject some alternative theories of bubble episodes. Common views of the episodes we assign as bubbles are
that these are periods of high expectations of fundamentals (rational or not) or
of low discount rates. These theories predict a proportional increase in all market valuations. Recalling that spillovers are the ratio of valuations of displaced
profits from new innovation, these alternative theories pose two conflicts with
our findings. First, they predict that market-based spillovers would tend to be
unchanged. Second, if market-based spillovers vary due to changes in the nature
of innovation, they would do so in parallel with the outcome-based spillovers.
These results highlight the importance of distinguishing between marketbased and outcome-based measures of spillovers and, more generally, of the
value of innovation during speculative episodes. While we have focused on com-

32

petition as the source of spillovers thus far, we now show how to enrich our
theory to make further predictions specific to other sources of spillovers. Testing these additional predictions would require a more sophisticated econometric
analysis, which is beyond the scope of this paper.

5

How Other Spillovers Interact with Speculation

Competition is only one of the many ways through which the effect of an innovation are felt in the economy. When a firm innovates, it not only affects
shareholders but also workers (see, e.g., Kogan et al. (2020) for recent evidence).
Moreover, a new product alters consumers’ choice over their entire consumption
basket (Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987)). Finally, others can learn from this innovation, as emphasized by Romer (1986). We incorporate these three prominent
sources of spillovers in our theory.
Doing so is interesting for three reasons. First, we obtain new testable predictions of our theory on the interaction of speculation and innovation that can
help discipline future empirical work. Second, by comparing across many different specifications, we obtain a more systematic typology of what drives the divergence between market-based and outcome-based measures arising from speculation. Finally, the results highlight the flexibility of our theoretical framework,
which is reinforced in Appendix D through many more realistic extensions.26
Derivations and proofs are presented in Appendix B.

5.1

Model with Richer Spillovers

In all the settings that follow, we maintain the same preferences, beliefs, firmcreation technology, and allocation of production slots as in the model of Section 2. However, we now endogenize how profits π(a) are determined in equilibrium, which creates new sources of spillovers. These spillovers, while important,
26

In particular, we study the role of an elastic supply of labor input, a variable number of
producing firms M , a setup in which firms compete to participate, and a setting where fixed
costs determine the set of producing firms, as in Melitz (2003). For all these models, we obtain
simple generalizations of the spillover formula of Proposition 3 and show that the comparative
statics of the spillovers remain valid.

33

do not change qualitatively the aggregate behavior of the economy in response to
speculation. Specifically, an increase in disagreement n always yields a bubble
and increases the market-based private value of innovation (in absolute terms
and relatively to the outcome-based measure). For this reason, we focus only on
the novel predictions for spillovers below.
5.1.1

Labor

Workers supply the labor that is necessary to operate the firms and thus take advantage of blueprints. We formalize this in the model: households are endowed
with a fixed quantity of labor L. Firms use labor to produce a homogeneous good
according to a technology with decreasing returns to scale.27 The production
function for a given productivity level a is:
y(a) = a ·

σ−1
σ
` σ ,
σ−1

(21)

where y is firm output, ` is firm labor input, and the parameter σ ∈ [1, ∞] controls the returns to scale in labor. In equilibrium (see Appendix B.1), labor trades
at a competitive wage w, and the profit function of a firm with productivity a is:
π(a) =

1
· w1−σ aσ .
σ−1

(22)

As in Section 2, profits are isoelastic with respect to productivity a.
The presence of workers gives rise to two new sources of spillovers. First,
workers capture some of the surplus from better innovations through higher
wages. Investors on financial markets do not take into account this value when
deciding on new firm creation. This externality is commonly known as the appropriability effect. Second, the competition of firms for the same source of labor
leads to an interaction between them beyond business-stealing. When a new
firm enters, it pushes wages up. This input price effect makes labor more expensive for every other firm. For example, the entry of new technology firms such as
Facebook creates new opportunities for software engineers (the appropriability
effect), bidding their wages up and making it more difficult for other firms to
27

This perfectly competitive approach, introduced in Hellwig and Irmen (2001), differs from
the most commonly used models with imperfect substitution and monopolistic competition. We
study these models and the role of the demand complementarities they induce in Section 5.1.2.

34

hire (the input price effect). More generally, these spillovers also apply to other
production inputs: ` could stand for intermediate goods in scarce supply.
Measuring the spillovers. We extend our measure of social value to account
for the presence of labor. For the market-based social value of an extra firm,
we compute the change in expected utility of households created by this new
firm. This calculation includes both the market value of profits from investing
in the firms and the income from working in these firms. In our model, it is
a dollar amount because of the presence of a quasi-linear good at date 0. The
outcome-based social value of an extra firm is still the change in total output in
the economy. Importantly, both definitions coincide with the work in Section 3
in the absence of labor.
This overall measure sums the effect of each type of spillover. Here the
sources are the appropriability, input price, and business-stealing effects. Each
additional source of spillovers introduces extra terms. The separation of different types of spillovers in the overall measure maps naturally to estimation
strategies from the empirical literature. For example, as described in Section 4.3, Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013) separate the businessstealing and knowledge spillovers. One could also imagine measuring the effect
of firm entry on workers, the appropriability effect. Similarly, the response of
firm value to innovation by other firms that compete for the same workers but
operate in different product markets would identify the input price effect.28
Predictions. The business-stealing effect of the model in Section 2 is still
present in this economy given the similar market structure. As before, this
spillover, which arises because entrants displace marginal firms, has magnitude
EIn . Hence, the predictions for this spillover we made in Section 3.2 still hold.
However, we now also have an appropriability effect. When new firms enter,
aggregate output increases, with constant elasticity EC = 1/γ. The production
function implies that workers receive a constant fraction of aggregate output
given by the labor share (σ−1)/σ. Therefore, the social value of entry for workers
EC C/Me . Importantly, this quantity does not depend directly on the amount
is σ−1
σ
of disagreement: all firms offer the same wage in equilibrium, so beliefs are
28

For clarity, we do not include multiple sectors in the model. The additive property of total
spillover with respect to each type of spillover allows us to isolate the different effects.

35

irrelevant for workers. However, the market-based private value of the firm
does. This value is In /I1 × σ −1 C/M : the relative expected output of a favorite
firm to an average firm multiplied by average profits of firms. The spillover is
the ratio of these two values,
Appropriability Spillover = (σ − 1) EC I1 /In .

(23)

When focusing on the outcome-based measure, we can just replace n with 1, and
the spillover becomes (σ − 1) EC . According to either metric, the appropriability
effect is a positive spillover, larger when workers capture more of total surplus—
high σ—or when entry has a stronger impact on output—high EC . Novel to our
model, we see that disagreement does not affect the outcome-based spillover. In
contrast, the market-based spillover decreases in n, disappearing altogether in
the limit when n → ∞. This is because the bubble inflates the market value
of firms, but workers’ acknowledge that their earnings are determined by the
average producing firm and realize that not all firms will be winners.
Finally, the input price spillover comes from the effect of firm entry on wages.
From equation (22), we see that profits have an elasticity of 1 − σ relative to the
wage. In addition, the wage grows as fast as aggregate output, EC = Ew , because
of the constant labor share and labor supply. A change in wage affects all firms
proportionally, irrespective of their productivity. Hence, disagreement does not
impact the input price spillover. Rather, both market-based and outcome-based
measures of the spillovers are constant and equal to:
Input Price Spillover = −(σ − 1)EC .

(24)

This negative externality is larger when firms rely more on labor—high σ—or
when the economy responds more to entry—high EC .29
5.1.2

Aggregate Demand

With goods that are not perfect substitutes, households prefer a consumption
basket that is diversified. Higher productivity for any particular good thus in29
In the case of agreement, n = 1, the appropriability and input price spillovers exactly cancel
out. It is a situation where pecuniary externalities cancel out even though the first welfare
theorem does not hold because of business-stealing.

36

creases aggregate demand. This implies not only more profit for the specific
firm but also for other firms producing the rest of the consumption basket. To
formalize the role of aggregate demand, we study an economy with differentiated goods, where firms operate under monopolistic competition at date 1 in the
style of Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). Each firm produces a differentiated variety
indexed by i, and household utility over the set of goods produced is:
Z

Me

Z

∞

C=

c (a, i)
0

σ−1
σ

σ
! σ−1

dF (a)di

.

(25)

M
F −1 (1− M

)
e

Firms operate a linear technology in labor, and output for a firm with productivity a is y = a`. We leave our other assumptions unaltered.
At the aggregate level, the economy behaves similarly to the previous
model.30 However, the microeconomics of firms’ interactions is different and
so are profits:
1
π(a) = ·
σ



σ
σ−1

1−σ

w1−σ · C · aσ−1 .

(26)

The elasticity of profits to individual firm productivity is no longer σ but rather
σ − 1. However, profits are now increasing in aggregate demand C because of
imperfect substitution across goods.
This role of aggregate demand gives rise to an additional source of spillovers:
a demand externality as in Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987). Similar to the role
of the wage, aggregate demand affects all firms proportionally. Therefore the
demand spillover is the product of the elasticity of aggregate output to entry C
and the elasticity of profits to aggregate output:
Demand Spillover = EC .

(27)

Demand spillovers do not depend on disagreement and are identical whether
measured using outcomes or market value.
30

The profit share is 1/σ, the aggregate production function is homogeneous of degree one in
the distribution of productivities, and the relative labor allocations are efficient. This result was
first shown in Lerner (1934). It is the consequence of the homogeneous distortions at the firm
level when markups are constant. The macroeconomic elasticities of aggregate consumption and
wages to firm entry are therefore EC = Ew = 1/γ.

37

5.1.3

Knowledge Spillovers

Firms also learn from each other’s innovations. We capture the role of knowledge
spillovers in the style of Romer (1990) by assuming that a firm’s productivity
combines its own type, a, and an aggregate of all the active firms’ productivity,
A. We assume the aggregator is homogeneous of degree one in the productivity
distribution.31 The production function extends (21) and becomes:
y=

σ−1
σ
a1−α Aα ` σ ,
σ−1

(28)

where α is the intensity of knowledge spillovers. Again, the macroeconomic features of the simple economy with labor are preserved.32 However, the microeconomics of firms’ interactions differ. Profits are:
π(a) =

1
· w1−σ · Aασ · a(1−α)σ .
σ−1

(29)

As the role of knowledge increases—larger α—firm profits respond more to aggregate knowledge A instead of individual productivity a.
The role of aggregate knowledge for profits highlights how knowledge
spillovers operate. Just like the previous two cases, the impact of knowledge
on profits is the same irrespective of each individual firm’s productivity. The
knowledge spillover is therefore the product of the elasticity of profit to knowledge ασ, and the elasticity of knowledge to entry 1/γ 33
Knowledge Spillover = α(σ − 1)EC .

(30)

This expression does not depend on disagreement and is identical for marketbased and outcome-based measures.

1/q
R∞
In Appendix B.3, we derive the case of Hölder mean of degree q, A = Me /M a aq dF (a)
,
where the parameter q < γ controls how much aggregate knowledge comes from the top firms.
32
The labor share is (σ − 1)/σ and EC = Ew = 1/γ.
33
Because both knowledge and output are determined by the distribution of firm productivity,
they grow at the same pace with entry EA = EC .
31

38

5.2

Social Value and Disagreement

The previous results provide useful predictions for how each channel through
which innovation affects the economy varies with disagreement. We now turn to
the behavior of social value overall, i.e., the total effect of an innovation, which
combines all sources of spillover. This quantity is interesting in its own right,
but also because it represents the optimal subsidy or tax on firm entry. The
following proposition shows that the spillovers we have introduced so far can be
organized in three categories, each with its own response to disagreement.
Proposition 3. For all the models of Section 5, the market-based spillover is:
spillmkt (n) =

EIn
bus. stealing

Eπ

+

+

general equilibrium

(σ − 1)EC

I1
.
In

(31)

appropriability effect

The outcome-based spillover, which does not depend on disagreement, is:
spillout = EI1 + Eπ + (σ − 1)EC .

(32)

This decomposition highlights how disagreement can matter for marketbased measures of spillovers. While our theoretical exercise is not exhaustive,
most spillovers considered in the innovation literature fit in one of our three
categories.
The first category is business-stealing. As we have discussed before, disagreement dampens the effect of business-stealing. The risk of displacement is particularly acute for relatively less productive firms. However, with speculation,
each investor places a relatively higher weight on her investments having high
productivity. In the limit when n goes to infinity, this force can be so strong that
the spillover disappears altogether.34 Competitive interactions between firms of
different productivities can take different forms than the displacement of our
model. Regardless, the takeaway is that spillovers that are more bottom-heavy
tend to be dissipated by disagreement.
This stands in contrast to the second category: general equilibrium effects.
In our models, these are the effects of the wage, aggregate demand, and aggregate knowledge on firm profits. The common force across all these sources of
34

In the model of Section 2, this occured when γθ > η, while now the condition is γθ > 1.

39

spillovers is that they affect all firms proportionally, irrespective of their productivity. Therefore, they can be summarized by the elasticity of firm profits
to firm entry, holding productivity constant, Eπ . Because the response to these
general equilibrium forces does not interact with the productivity distribution,
these spillovers do not depend on beliefs.
Finally, the third category of spillovers is appropriability effects. Not all
spillovers affect firms. In our models, workers capture some of the surplus due
to firm entry. Because the surplus of workers is determined in the spot market
for labor, it does not depend on the relative positions of firms. Unlike firm valuations, wage expectations are not affected by speculation about the relative positions of firms beyond its direct impact on entry and overall labor demand. When
disagreement increases, the market-based spillover to workers disappears. This
insight is not specific to workers but rather affects all stakeholders of the innovation process. Other key stakeholders, which we could have similarly introduced
in the model, include owners of production inputs in scarce supply other than
labor or consumers who enjoy some of the surplus.

5.3

Three Illustrations of the Role of Disagreement

We draw three implications from Proposition 3 that illustrate that disagreement
fundamentally alters how to measure and interpret the value of innovation.
5.3.1

Macroeconomic versus Microeconomic Elasticities

Without disagreement, market-based and outcome-based measures of spillovers
coincide because valuations are expected outcomes. In the economies we have
considered, the result is even stronger. The spillover under agreement is the
same across all specifications: with labor only, with aggregate demand, and with
aggregate knowledge. It takes the value:
spillout = spillmkt (1) = σEC − 1.

(33)

While we can derive this expression from equation (32) separately for each
model, a simple macroeconomic argument justifies the result. The total effect
of entry is the response of aggregate output to entry dC/dMe . Ex ante, each
firm contributes an equal fraction to total output, and the value of a firm is out40

put times the profit share 1/σ. Hence, the value of a firm is C/(Me σ), and the
spillover is given immediately by equation (33).
Regardless of the nature of firm interactions, only two macroeconomic quantities are needed to evaluate the total spillover—the capital share and the elasticity of aggregate output to firm entry. In particular, all our specifications lead
to the same values of these two quantities. Disagreement breaks this result.
Because different spillovers respond differently to disagreement, the aggregate
reasoning under agreement no longer works.
One particularly telling example is the limit of large n when the marketbased spillover converges to the profit elasticity Eπ . This spillover measure is
a microeconomic elasticity. It is the response of the profits of one specific firm
(i.e., of given productivity) to overall entry. This implies that one needs firmlevel data rather than aggregate data to estimate spillovers. Moreover, across
our three model specifications, while the outcome-based spillover is identical,
the market-based spillover for large disagreement takes different values:
σ−1
γ
σ−2
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −
γ
(1 − α)σ − 1
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −
γ
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −

with labor only,

(34)

with aggregate demand,

(35)

with aggregate knowledge.

(36)

In other words, the nature of microeconomic interactions matters for marketbased spillovers in the presence of disagreement.
5.3.2

Reversal of Comparative Statics

The divergence between market-based and outcome-based spillovers is not only
quantitative but also qualitative. Key properties of the economy often have an
opposite impact on the total spillover, depending on whether it is measured using outcomes or market values. The following proposition highlights one such
reversal, for a parameter common to all of our specification, σ.
Proposition 4. For all models, the outcome-based spillover is increasing in the
labor share. Conversely, with high disagreement (n → ∞ and θ > 1/γ), the
market-based spillover is decreasing in the labor share.
41

0

Spillover

γ
Higher γ 0 > γ

Outcome
Market

−(γ − 1)/γ
(γ − 1)/γ

0

Labor share: (σ − 1)/σ
Figure 4
Market-based and outcome-based spillovers.
The figure reports the outcome-based (black lines) and market-based spillovers (red lines) as a
function of the labor share for the model with labor only. Solid lines correspond to a larger value
of γ than dotted lines.

The outcome-based spillover is given by the macroeconomic formulation of
equation (33). An economy with a larger labor share has mechanically a lower
capital share. Thus, the importance of social value relative to the value of one
firm is larger. For the market-based spillover, the focus is on the elasticity of
individual firm profits to entry. A higher labor share implies higher reliance on
labor and therefore stronger negative spillovers through the wage effect.
By examining our results, the reader can find more situations where reversals occur. In the model with labor, comparative statics with respect to the thickness of the tail of the productivity distribution γ are also reversed. Figure 4
illustrates these results. Appendix D has more examples.
5.3.3

Reversal of Sign of the Spillover

More strikingly, we also identify situations where the sign of the total spillover is
reversed. These are cases where firm entry brings positive externalities according to market-based measures but negative externalities according to outcomebased measures or vice-versa.
Proposition 5. With demand externalities or knowledge spillovers, if the labor
share is close to zero, the outcome-based spillover is positive and the market42

based spillover is negative with large disagreement. The converse happens when
the labor share is close to its upper bound.
When the labor share is low, the labor surplus is relatively small, and the
dominant force for the wedge is that firms do not internalize the aggregate decreasing returns to scale of the economy, leading to negative real spillovers.
With disagreement however, since firms do not rely much on labor, the general equilibrium effect is small. Hence, the demand or knowledge externality
dominates, leading to positive value spillovers. The sign reversal across measures of spillovers is not a knife-edge case. Reversals happen throughout the
entire range of the labor share whenever γ = 2 with demand externalities or
α = 1 − 1/γ with knowledge spillovers. The proposition also shows that the sign
reversal can happen in both directions: a positive spillover becoming negative
or a negative spillover becoming positive.

6

Welfare Implications

One of the reasons why measuring innovative spillovers is important is because
such estimates can guide the design of policies. In this section, we study the
welfare implications of spillover measures. We focus on a simple question: If a
planner can choose a subsidy or tax on firm entry, what would it be? The presence of disagreement complicates answering this question because the choice
of planner objective is not trivial. Which beliefs should the planner use when
evaluating allocations?
We follow two approaches: a Pareto criterion and a paternalistic approach
imposing common beliefs. For each approach we map the market-based and
outcome-based measures of the private and social values we have studied so
far to an optimal tax rate. These results further emphasize the importance of
acknowledging the presence of speculation and understanding the divergence
between measurement approaches.

6.1

Non-Paternalistic Approach

A classic approach to welfare evaluation is the Pareto criterion. An allocation
improves overall welfare if all agents in the economy favor it. This criterion is
43

not paternalistic: moving away from the competitive equilibrium requires the
support of all agents in the economy. In other words, the optimal tax policy
under the Pareto criterion is one that would receive support by all agents in a
vote.35 Interestingly in our case, this approach does not take a stand on what are
correct beliefs but rather lets each individual agent evaluate their own utility.
Not having to choose beliefs is a useful feature in the situations we study.
We are interested in episodes when there is little information about new firms.
Households thus rely on their priors to evaluate these firms, and there is no
way to forecast who is correct. The Pareto criterion respects this difficulty. The
planner is no better judge of firms’ futures than any investor. In contrast, a
paternalistic approach might be more appropriate when heterogeneous beliefs
are viewed as inherently inefficient due to a failure of communication or the
irrationality of some agent.
Our model is symmetric: despite agents having different beliefs, they each
have the same evaluation of their own utility. This symmetry facilitates solving for the optimal allocations because the problem reduces to maximizing the
utility of all agents in the economy. The planner chooses a tax τ for each additional firm created from blueprints, rebated as a lump sum to households.36 The
optimal tax can be obtained from a standard Pigouvian taxation problem:
max Uj = 1 + Me Ej {πi } − W (Me ).
τ

(37)

The planner chooses the tax rate that equalizes private incentives to create firms
with their social value according to the planner’s objective. When a firm creator
introduces a new firm, it pays (1 − τ )pi . Hence, the optimal tax rate is τ =
1 − socialpivalue . Social value for the non-paternalistic planner is given by changes
in expected utility, which correspond to market prices. This yields the following
35
This interpretation provides a positive—as opposed to normative—view of these results as
the outcome of political decision-making.
36
We could also consider a more general constrained planner problem. In this general version,
the planner allocates date-1 consumption. Consumption plans must be linear combinations of
firm profits with positive coefficients. The positive coefficients reflect our assumptions ruling
out short-selling and derivative contracts. In the model in Section 2, the allocation chosen by a
planner with a linear tax is Pareto optimal for the general constrained planner. It is the most
efficient allocation if we impose additionally that welfare weights are equal across agents.

44

simple expression for the optimal tax:
τpareto = −spillmkt .

(38)

Therefore, for a non-paternalistic planner, the market-based spillover, rather
than the outcome-based spillover, is a sufficient statistic for the optimal tax.
We have seen that the market-based spillover is often very different with
agreement compared with disagreement. Our framework thus implies that one
should not use estimates from normal market conditions to draw policy conclusions during bubbles. From a positive perspective, the distinction explains why
policies to reduce firm entry may not receive support even during bubbles, even
when investors agree that there is excess entry. Further, if the only available
data is on outcomes, one should use a framework like ours to convert these estimates into their market-based counterparts. The reversal results of the previous
section highlight the importance of having a theoretical framework to do so.

6.2

Paternalistic Approach

Alternatively, one could follow a paternalistic approach by assuming that the
planner knows the “true” distribution and evaluates allocations under this distribution. Brunnermeier, Simsek, and Xiong (2014) propose an improvement
on this approach that avoids taking a stance on the true distribution. In their
work, the planner considers efficiency across any convex combination of agents’
beliefs. In our setting, all agents agree on the distribution of firm productivity,
and therefore, this distribution is the only choice for the paternalistic planner. A
benefit of the paternalistic approach is that, from the perspective of social choice,
it resolves the tension that not all beliefs can be right at the same time.
The paternalistic planner maximizes expected utility under the population
distribution F , which coincides with aggregate consumption net of entry costs,
C − W (Me ). As before, this is a standard Pigouvian taxation problem, except
that now social value is the marginal effect of entry on output rather than on
households’ perception of utility. Hence, the optimal tax becomes:
τpater = 1 − (spillout + 1)

45

private valueout
.
private valuemkt

(39)

Two aspects drive the choice of policy. First, the planner accounts for
spillovers. Here the relevant measure of spillovers uses outcomes rather than
market values. Similar to the Pareto planner problem, directly using estimates
of spillovers measured using market values leads to incorrect inference. If these
estimates are the only ones available, one should use a theoretical framework to
convert them in outcome-based spillovers.
Second, there is a wedge between the private value on markets, which shapes
incentives to create firms and the private value according to the planner’s beliefs. We have seen that the bubble inflates market-based private value relative
to outcome-based private value. As a result, this second force will generally push
toward taxing entry in order to lean against what the planner views as excessive valuations. In particular, if outcome-based spillovers are positive, implying
that there is under-entry absent disagreement, a bubble can actually push the
economy toward efficiency.
With agreement, the two planner objectives coincide and lead to the same
optimal tax. The optimal tax in this case is the negative of the total spillover,
regardless of whether it is measured using market- or outcome-based measures.

7

Conclusion

Speculation and innovation often coincide. A naive view of the role of speculation and the bubbles it generates is that they do not matter for the innovation
process even though they disrupt financial markets. In contrast, we argue that
there is structure in these disruptions—innovation and speculation interact systematically. Failing to understand and account for this interaction can distort
our qualitative and quantitative understanding of the private and social values of innovation, leading to erroneous answers to both positive and normative
questions about innovation.
To that end, the paper introduces a model of the interaction between innovation and speculation. Our theory makes sharp predictions for the value of
innovation under market- and outcome-based measures. We study the impact of
disagreement on both the private and social values of innovation. The structure
of the model reflects reality. During bubbles, information from financial markets
and real outcomes about the value of innovation diverge from each other in the
46

direction predicted by our theory. Extending the work of Kogan et al. (2017), we
find that asset prices indicate increases in the private value of innovation during
bubbles, with no commensurate increase in outcome-based measures. Using the
method of Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013), we show that competitive spillovers disappear during bubbles when measured in financial markets
but remain unchanged when looking at sales.
Thus, accounting for the link between speculation and innovation is a fruitful enterprise. Our paper provides the first steps toward digging deeper, showing how our framework can entertain many sources of innovative spillovers and
highlighting broad principles of their interaction with disagreement. We also explain how to map data to innovation policy decisions in periods of disagreement.
Another avenue suggested by our work is the use of financial market regulation as a novel form of innovation policy.37 We look forward to seeing the future
implementation of these ideas improve our understanding of the outcomes of
innovation.

37

Jørring et al. (2017) discuss the example of Food and Drug Administration hedges to share
risk in medical innovation. Our results show that disagreement can dramatically change the
consequences of such instruments both in terms of outcomes and welfare.

47

References
Abernathy, W.J. 1978. The Productivity Dilemma: Roadblock to Innovation in
the Automobile Industry. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Md.
Acemoglu, Daron. 2008. Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton
University Press.
Barberis, Nicholas, Robin Greenwood, Lawrence Jin, and Andrei Shleifer. 2018.
“Extrapolation and Bubbles.” Journal of Financial Economics 129 (2):203–
227.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki. 1987. “Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand.” American Economic Review
77 (4):647–666.
Bloom, Nicholas, Mark Schankerman, and John Van Reenen. 2013. “Identifying Technology Spillovers and Product Market Rivalry.” Econometrica
81 (4):1347–1393.
Bond, Philip, Alex Edmans, and Itay Goldstein. 2012. “The Real Effects of Financial Markets.” Annual Review of Financial Economics 4 (1):339–360.
Borjas, George J. and Kirk B. Doran. 2012. “The Collapse of the Soviet Union
and the Productivity of American Mathematicians.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3):1143–1203.
Brunnermeier, Markus K. 2016. “Bubbles.” In Banking Crises. London: Palgrave
Macmillan UK, 28–36.
Brunnermeier, Markus K and Martin Oehmke. 2013. “Bubbles, Financial Crises,
and Systemic Risk.” In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, vol. 2. Elsevier,
1221–1288.
Brunnermeier, Markus K., Alp Simsek, and Wei Xiong. 2014. “A Welfare Criterion for Models with Distorted Beliefs.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
129 (4):1753–1797.
Chen, Joseph, Harrison Hong, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2002. “Breadth of Ownership and Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2):171–205.
Limits on Arbitrage.
Chinco, Alex. 2020. “The Madness of Crowds and the Likelihood of Bubbles.”
Mimeo, University of Illinois.
Corhay, Alexandre, Howard Kung, and Lukas Schmid. 2015. “Markups, Competition and Asset Prices.” Working paper, Duke University.
48

Davila, Eduardo. 2020. “Optimal Financial Transaction Taxes.” Mimeo, Yale.
D’avolio, Gene. 2002. “The Market for Borrowing Stock.” Journal of Financial
Economics 66 (2-3):271–306.
Diether, Karl B., Christopher J. Malloy, and Anna Scherbina. 2002. “Differences of Opinion and the Cross Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance
57 (5):2113–2141.
Dixit, Avinash K and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1977. “Monopolistic Competition and
Optimum Product Diversity.” American Economic Review 67 (3):297–308.
Dong, Ming, David Hirshleifer, and Siew Hong Teoh. 2020. “Stock Market Overvaluation, Moon Shots, and Corporate Innovation.” Mimeo, UC Irvine.
Duffie, Darrell. 2014. “Challenges to a Policy Treatment of Speculative Trading Motivated by Differences in Beliefs.” The Journal of Legal Studies
43 (S2):S173–S182.
Duffie, Darrell, Nicolae Garleanu, and Lasse Heje Pedersen. 2002. “Securities
Lending, Shorting, and Pricing.” Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2-3):307–
339.
Fama, Eugene F and Kenneth R French. 1997. “Industry Costs of Equity.” Journal of Financial Economics 43 (2):153–193.
Farhi, Emmanuel and Jean Tirole. 2011. “Bubbly Liquidity.” The Review of
Economic Studies 79 (2):678–706.
Freeman, Christopher. 1982. The Economics of Industrial Innovation. MIT
Press.
Gârleanu, Nicolae, Leonid Kogan, and Stavros Panageas. 2012. “Displacement
Risk and Asset Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 105 (3):491–510.
Greenwood, Robin, Andrei Shleifer, and Yang You. 2018. “Bubbles for Fama.”
Journal of Financial Economics .
Griliches, Zvi, Ariel Pakes, and Bronwyn H. Hall. 1986. “The Value of Patents
as Indicators of Inventive Activity.” Working Paper 2083, National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Harrison, J. Michael and David M. Kreps. 1978. “Speculative Investor Behavior
in a Stock Market with Heterogeneous Expectations.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 92 (2):323–336.
Hayashi, F. 1982. “Tobin’s Marginal q and Average q: A Neoclassical Interpretation.” Econometrica 50 (1):213–224.
49

Hellwig, Martin and Andreas Irmen. 2001. “Endogenous Technical Change in a
Competitive Economy.” Journal of Economic Theory 101 (1):1–39.
Hombert, Johan and Adrien Matray. 2020. “Technology Boom, Labor Reallocation, and Human Capital Depreciation.” Mimeo, HEC.
Hong, Harrison and Jeremy C. Stein. 2007. “Disagreement and the Stock Market.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (2):109–128.
Huang, Shiyang, Byoung-Hyoun Hwang, Dong Lou, and Chengxi Yin. 2020.
“Offsetting Disagreement and Security Prices.” Management Science.
Jaffe, Adam. 1986. “Technological Opportunity and Spillovers of R&D: Evidence
from Firms’ Patents, Profits, and Market Value.” American Economic Review
76 (5):984–1001.
Janeway, W.H. 2012. Doing Capitalism in the Innovation Economy: Markets,
Speculation and the State. Cambridge University Press.
Jones, Charles M and Owen A Lamont. 2002. “Short-Sale Constraints and Stock
Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2-3):207–239.
Jørring, Adam, Andrew W. Lo, Tomas J. Philipson, Manita Singh, and Richard T.
Thakor. 2017. “Sharing R&D Risk in Healthcare via FDA Hedges.” Working
Paper 23344, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Kogan, Leonid, Dimitris Papanikolaou, Lawrence D. W. Schmidt, and Jae Song.
2020. “Technological Innovation and Labor Income Risk.” Working Paper
26964, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Kogan, Leonid, Dimitris Papanikolaou, Amit Seru, and Noah Stoffman. 2017.
“Technological Innovation, Resource Allocation, and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (2):665–712.
Kogan, Leonid, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Noah Stoffman. 2020. “Left Behind:
Creative Destruction, Inequality, and the Stock Market.” Journal of Political
Economy 128 (3):855–906.
Kondor, Péter and Botond Köszegi. 2017. “Cursed Financial Innovation.” Mimeo,
CEU.
Kung, Howard and Lukas Schmid. 2015. “Innovation, Growth, and Asset Prices.”
The Journal of Finance 70 (3):1001–1037.
Lerner, A. P. 1934. “The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly
Power.” Review of Economic Studies 1 (3):157–175.

50

Loualiche, Erik. 2020. “Asset Pricing with Entry and Imperfect Competition.”
Mimeo, University of Minnesota.
Martin, Alberto and Jaume Ventura. 2012. “Economic Growth with Bubbles.”
American Economic Review 102 (6):3033–3058.
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and
Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6):1695–1725.
Miller, Edward M. 1977. “Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion.” Journal of Finance 32 (4):1151–1168.
Mokyr, Joel. 1992. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic
Progress. Oxford University Press.
Morris, Stephen. 1995. “The Common Prior Assumption in Economic Theory.”
Economics and Philosophy 11 (2):227–253.
Pakes, Ariel. 1986. “Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding
European Patent Stocks.” Econometrica 54 (4):755–784.
Panageas, Stavros. 2015. “The Neoclassical Theory of Investment in Speculative
Markets.” Mimeo, UCLA.
Pastor, Lubos and Pietro Veronesi. 2005. “Rational IPO Waves.” Journal of
Finance 60 (4):1713–1757.
———. 2009. “Technological Revolutions and Stock Prices.” American Economic
Review 99 (2):1451–1483.
Reed, Adam V., Pedro A. C. Saffi, and Edward D. Van Wesep. 2020. “Short-Sales
Constraints and the Diversification Puzzle.” Management Science.
Romer, Paul M. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth.” Journal of
Political Economy 94 (5):1002–1037.
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political
Economy 98 (5):71–102.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1958. “An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with
or without the Social Contrivance of Money.” Journal of Political Economy
66 (6):467–482.
Scheinkman, J.A. 2014. Speculation, Trading, and Bubbles. Kenneth J. Arrow
Lecture Series. Columbia University Press.
Scheinkman, Jose A. and Wei Xiong. 2003. “Overconfidence and Speculative
Bubbles.” Journal of Political Economy 111 (6):1183–1220.
51

Scott, William Robert. 1912. The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish
and Irish Joint-stock Companies to 1720, vol. 1. Cambridge University Press.
Tirole, Jean. 1985. “Asset Bubbles and Overlapping Generations.” Econometrica
53 (6):1499–1528.
Tobin, James. 1969. “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory.”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1 (1):15–29.
van Binsbergen, Jules H. and Christian C. Opp. 2019. “Real Anomalies.” The
Journal of Finance 74 (4):1659–1706.
Van den Steen, Eric. 2004. “Rational Overoptimism (and Other Biases).” American Economic Review 94 (4):1141–1151.
Yu, Jialin. 2011. “Disagreement and Return Predictability of Stock Portfolios.”
Journal of Financial Economics 99 (1):162–183.

52

Internet Appendix
A
A.1

Derivations for Simple Model
General Results

We first express the spillovers in integral form, then prove Proposition 1 for general functions
F and π.

A.1.1

General Formulas

The market-based spillover is
0

spillmkt (n; Me ) = [Me V (n) (Me )]/[V (n) (Me )].
The numerator and denominator have interpretable expressions. First rewrite the denominator in the following integral form:
Z ∞
(n)
V
=
π(x)dFn (x)
F −1
Z ∞
F0
=
π (x) n0 (x) dF (x),
(IA.1)
F
F −1
where we denote F −1 (1 − M/Me ) by F −1 for convenience. Now the numerator can be written:
Me


 F0 

M
dV (n)
=
· π F −1 · n0 F −1
dMe
Me
F
Z ∞
 −1  Fn0  −1 
=−
π F
F
dF (x).
F0
F −1

(IA.2)
(IA.3)

This leads to the following formula for the market-based spillover:
R∞
spillmkt (n) = −

F −1


 0 

π F −1 FFn0 F −1 dF (x)

R∞

F −1

A.1.2

0

π (x) FFn0 (x) dF (x)

(IA.4)

.

Comparing Spillovers

Lemma A.1. Holding Me constant, the market-based spillover is larger with agreement than
with disagreement.
(n)0

Proof. First recall the market-based spillover spillmkt (n; Me ) = MVe V(n) (M(M)e ) . We have the
e
derivative:


1 M  −1 
M n−1
(n)0
V
=−
π F
·n 1−
,
Me Me
Me

53

and we can bound V (n) :
V (n) =

Z

∞

π(x)nF n−1 (x)dF (x)

F −1

Z

∞



π(x)nF n−1 F −1 dF (x)
F −1


Z
M n−1 ∞
π(x)dF (x).
≥n 1−
Me
F −1
≥

Therefore, we are able to bound the market-based spillover for a given Me and n:
 −1 
R∞
dF (x)
FR−1 π F
|spillmkt (n; Me )| ≤ −
≤ |spillmkt (1; Me )|,
∞
F −1 π(x)dF (x)

(IA.5)

where the second inequality comes from the definition of spillmkt (1; Me ).

A.2

Power Case Derivations

We now outline the derivations for the case we focus on in the main text, with F (a) = 1 − a−γ
and π(a) = aη · 1 {a ≥ a} .
First, define
a=F

−1

Me
)=
(1 −
M



Me
M

1/γ
.

The ex-ante value of a firm V (n) (Me ) is:
Z ∞
n−1
η
−γ−1
V (n) (Me ) =
1 − x−γ
dx
1 x γnx
( MMe ) γ
Z ∞
n−1
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ t−γ
dt.
= γnaη−γ

(IA.6)
(IA.7)

1

The first derivative with respect to entrants is:
dV (n)
1
M
=−
·
dMe
Me M e



Me
M

η
γ



M n−1
·n 1−
.
Me

(IA.8)

0

It is convenient to express −Me V (n) (Me ) as:
0

−Me V (n) (Me ) = aη−γ · n 1 − a−γ

A.2.1

n−1

.

(IA.9)

Spillovers and Firm Entry under Agreement

Lemma A.2. The outcome-based spillover does not depend on the level of entry:
spillout (Me ) = −

54

γ−η
.
γ

(IA.10)

weight Fn0 /F 0

disagreement n
1
1

1.5
2

1

2

3

4

5

productivity draw ai
Figure IA.1
Distortion of productivity weights Fn0 /F 0
The level of entry is:
Me
=
M

γ


γ − η − γ(θ+1)−η
fe
.
γ

(IA.11)

Proof. The value of a firm is:
V

(1)

η−γ

∞

Z

tη−γ−1 dt

(Me ) = γa

1

γ
γ
aη−γ =
=
γ−η
γ−η



Me
M

 η−γ
γ

.

(IA.12)

From equation (IA.9) with n = 1, we have the numerator of the spillover:
dV (1)
−Me
=
dMe



Me
M

 η−γ
γ

(IA.13)

,

which leads directly to the desired formula (IA.10) for the outcome-based spillover. Finally,
we can rewrite equation (8):

fe

Me
M

θ

γ
=
γ−η



Me
M

 η−γ
γ

,

which reduces to (IA.11) as desired.

A.2.2

Disagreement Lowers Market-Based Spillovers

Proposition 1 follows directly from Lemma A.1 and Lemma A.2. In particular, we have
|spillmkt (n; Me )| ≤ |spillmkt (1; Me )| = |spillout (Me )| = |spillout (Me0 )|

(IA.14)

for any Me0 , and, in particular, the Me0 corresponding to the equilibrium entry under agreement. The inequality is from Lemma A.1; the first equality is from the definition of spillmkt
and spillout ; and the last equality is from Lemma A.2.

55

A.2.3

Disagreement Asymptotics

Lemma A.3. If θ ≥ 0, then as disagreement increases (n → ∞), the mass of entrants also
increases and goes to infinity: limn→∞ Me = ∞.
Proof. We define an = (Me /M )1/γ , where Me now depends on n, and show that an → ∞.
Equation (8) implies an implicit definition of the sequence an :
Z ∞

γ(θ+1)−η
−γ n−1
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ
= γn
dt.
fe an
n t
1

Suppose an has a finite limit that is strictly larger than zero, i.e., a∞ > 0.38 Then there exists
N large enough such that ∀n > N , an > A = a∞ −  > 0. We obtain a lower bound for the
right-hand side of the implicit equation above:
Z ∞
n−1
In = γn
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ t−γ
dt
1
Z ∞
n−1
dt.
> γn
tη−γ−1 1 − A−γ t−γ
1

Consider an arbitrary threshold Tn that depends on n and satisfies:
Z ∞
n−1
In > γn
tη−γ−1 1 − A−γ t−γ
dt
Tn
Z ∞

−γ −γ n−1
tη−γ−1 dt
> γn 1 − A Tn
Tn

n−1
γ
=
· n · Tnη−γ 1 − A−γ Tn−γ
.
γ−η
Choose the threshold Tn = n1/γ . The bound becomes:
η

γ
· n γ exp −(n − 1) log(1 − A−γ n−1 )
γ−η
η

γ
>
· n γ exp −(n − 1)A−γ n−1 + O(n−1 ) .
γ−η

In >

Since γ(θ + 1) − η ≥ γ − η > 0, this implies In → ∞, contradicting a∞ < ∞.
Lemma A.4 (Asymptotics for firm creation). In the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), we have
the following asymptotics for the mass of firms created, Me :

 γ
γ(θ+1)−η
1 γ
• If γθ < η, then Me /M = fe γ−η · n
.
• If γθ = η, then limn→∞ Me /M = α∞ n, where α∞ is a constant defined below.
Proof. Substituting a into (8), we have:
Z ∞
n−1
η−γ(θ+1)
fe = γa
n
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ t−γ
dt
1
Z ∞

' γaη−γ(θ+1) n
tη−γ−1 exp −(n − 1)a−γ t−γ dt,
1
38

Since the mass of firms producing cannot be higher than the mass of firms created, an ≥ 1.

56

where we have used the fact that a → ∞ from Lemma A.4, and log(1 − x) = −x + O(x2 ). To
find a solution, we guess the asymptotics of a(n). We rewrite a = α(n)n1/(γ(1+θ)−η) and show
that α(n) converges to a finite limit α. The above equation becomes:


Z ∞
η−γ−1
−γ n − 1
η−γ(θ+1)
−γ
t
exp −α(n)
dt.
fe = γα(n)
t
γ
1
n γ(1+θ)−η
Suppose γθ < η. Then the exponential term converges to zero and we have:
Z ∞
γ
η−γ(θ+1)
tη−γ−1 = αη−γ(θ+1)
fe = γα
,
γ−η
1
such that we have the following asymptotics for firm entry:
Me
=
M



1 γ
·n
fe γ − η



γ
γ(θ+1)−η

.

(IA.15)

Suppose γθ = η. Then a is defined by:
Z ∞
n−1
−γ
fe = γan n
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ t−γ
dt.
1

Since a = (Me /M )1/γ , it is sufficient to guess and verify that an = α(n)−1/γ n1/γ , and α(n) has
a finite limit α∞ defined by:
Z ∞

fe = γα(n)
tη−γ−1 exp −(n − 1)(α(n)n−1 + O(α(n)2 n−2 ))t−γ dt
1
Z ∞
−γ
−−−→ γα∞
tη−γ−1 e−α∞ t dt,
n→∞

1

where we take the limit when n → ∞. The outcome-based spillover implies:
Z ∞
fe > γα∞ e−α∞
tη−γ−1 dt
1

−α∞

> α∞ e

γ
,
γ−η

and thus
α∞ e−α∞
γ−η
<
,
fe
γ

(IA.16)

which implies a finite bound on α∞ .
Using the asymptotics derived in Lemma A.4, we now prove Proposition 2.
Proof. (Proposition 2) Suppose γθ < η. Substitute the asymptotics derived in equation

57

(IA.15) into the formula for the market-based spillover:

spillmkt (n; Me ) = −

M
Me

Me
M

 γη
fe


n 1−

M θ

M
Me

n−1
(IA.17)

e

M



γ−η 1
1
M n−1
γ−η
' − · fe
·n 1−
→−
,
fe
γ n
Me
γ

(IA.18)

where we have used the fact that (1 − M/Me )n−1 → 1.39 The market-based spillover therefore
converges to the outcome-based spillover in this case.
Now suppose γθ > η. We write the market-based spillover directly:
spillmkt (n; Me ) = −

naη−γ (1 − a−γ )n−1
.
fe aγθ

First suppose a → ∞. We rewrite the competitive equilibrium condition (8):
fe aγθ−η
.
γ 1 tη−γ−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt
R∞
The denominator is bounded from above by γ 1 tη−γ−1 dt, which implies na → ∞. Using a
first-order approximation, we have:

(1 − a−γ )n−1 ' exp −na−γ .
na−γ =

R∞

Therefore, the market-based spillover in the limit is:
spillmkt (n) ' −

na−γ exp (−na−γ )
→ 0,
fe aγθ−η

(IA.19)

since the numerator goes to zero and the denominator goes to infinity. Suppose instead that a
has a finite limit. We obtain the expression for spillmkt :
spillmkt (n) = −

n exp ((n − 1) log(1 − a−γ ))
n(1 − a−γ )n−1
=
−
→ 0,
fe aγ(1+θ)−η
fe aγ(1+θ)−η

(IA.20)

since the denominator has a finite limit and the numerator goes to 0.
Lastly, consider the case where γθ = η. The spillover expression simplifies to:
spillmkt (n) = −

n−1
1
· na−γ 1 − a−γ
.
fe

39

This follows from (1 − M/Me )n−1 =
e /M )] and
 exp [−(n− 1) log(M
 using the asymptotics derived
γ
− γ(1+θ)−η
γ
n
above for γθ < η: (1 − M/Me )n−1 = exp −(n − 1) fe−1 γ−η
→ 1.

58

Using Lemma A.4 and the result that a−γ = α(n)/n, and α(n) → α∞ , we have:
1
α(n) exp (−(n − 1)α(n)/n)
fe
1
1
' − α(n) exp (−α(n)) → − α∞ e−α∞ .
fe
fe

spillmkt (n) ' −

(IA.21)
(IA.22)

Moreover, using Lemma A.4, this also proves that in the limit, the magnitude of the marketbased spillover |spillmkt | is less than that of the outcome-based spillover |spillout | = (γ − η)/γ.

59

B

Derivations for General Equilibrium Model

Recall the definition of the average of a power function in productivity under measure F (n) :
Z ∞
In (Me , σ) =
aσ dF n (a).
a

The integral with no disagreement is I1 . We will use In when the dependence of the integral
to Me or σ is unambiguous. Under the Pareto distribution with parameter γ, we have the
following result:
γ
I1 =
·
γ−σ

B.1
B.1.1



Me
M

 σ −1
γ

.

(IA.23)

Model with Decreasing Returns to Scale
Equilibrium

The firm-optimization problem given the production function and the competitive input price
w is:
max π(a) = a ·
`(a)

σ−1
σ
`(a) σ .
σ−1

The first-order condition leads to demand for labor at the firm level:
 w −σ
.
`(a) =
a
Output and profit at the firm level are:
σ
· w1−σ · aσ
σ−1
1
· w1−σ · aσ .
π(a) =
σ−1
y(a) =

Market clearing on the input market yields:
Z ∞
−σ
L = Me · w
aσ dF (a) = Me · w−σ · I1 ,

(IA.24)

a

which, given (IA.23), leads to the following wage in equilibrium under a Pareto distribution
for F :

w=

γ
γ−σ

1 
1 
1 1
σ
Me σ
Me γ − σ
·
·
.
L
M

Given the equilibrium quantities, we can decompose aggregate output into the profit and
labor shares. First, observe that aggregate ouput is:
Z ∞
σ
C = Me ·
y(a)dF (a) = Me ·
w1−σ I1 .
σ
−
1
a

60

From this expression we immediately conclude that:
w1−σ · I1 =

σ−1 C
,
·
σ
Me

and we are able to simplify the ex-ante valuation of firms:
Z ∞
1
V (n) (Me ) =
π(a)dF n (a) =
· w1−σ · In (Me )
σ
−
1
a
=

1 C In (Me )
·
·
.
σ Me I1 (Me )

Finally, we express the wage as a function of the equilibrium mass of firms:

w=

− 1
1
σ
γ−σ
γ−σ
L
· M γσ · Meγ .
γ

The equilibrium condition that determines entry in equilibrium is:
W 0 (Me ) =

B.1.2

1 C In (Me )
·
·
.
σ Me I1 (Me )

(IA.25)

Spillovers

As before, the spillover is a ratio of the direct and indirect effect of firm entry. Consumption
for household j is the product of labor income and profits from its investment:
Cj =

σ−1
·C
σ

+

labor income: wL

1 In
·
·C
σ I1

.

firm profits: V (n)

Hence the social value under market-based measures of entry can be written:
1 d (In /I1 · C) σ − 1 dC
·
·
+
.
σ
dMe
σ
dMe

(IA.26)

To find the market-based spillover, we take the ratio of the direct and indirect effect of firm
entry:
1 − spillmkt (n) =

Me I1 dC
Me I1 d (In /I1 · C)
·
+ (σ − 1) ·
·
.
C In
dMe
C In dMe

This leads us immediately to the general formula for the market-based spillover:
spillmkt (n) = −EIn + (1 + EI1 − EC ) − (σ − 1)EC ·

I1
.
In

(IA.27)

The asymptotic environment is similar to that of Section 2. We start by studying the asymptotics of the business-stealing effect.
Lemma B.1 (Asymptotics for business-stealing effect). In the high-disagreement limit (n →
∞), the business-stealing effect converges to a limit that depends on the marginal cost of firm
creation θ:

61

• If θγ < 1, then limn→∞ EIn = EI1 =

σ
γ

− 1.

• If θγ > 1, then limn→∞ EIn = 0.
• If θγ = 1, then limn→∞ EIn = α∞ e−α∞ /fe .
Proof. The free-entry condition equation (IA.25) leads to:

(σ − 1)

 1−σ
1−σ
σ
σ−1
−θ
γ−σ
θ+ σ−γ
γ
σ
· Me γ
L
· fe = M
· In .
γ

We recast the free-entry condition using a to be able to use the asymptotic results from
Lemma A.4
Z ∞
1−σ−γθ
constant = a
xσ dFn (x).
a

Writing θ̃ = θ + (σ − 1)/γ and η̃ = σ, we recognize the expression from Lemma A.4 and use
Proposition 2.
For the labor surplus term, we study the behavior of I1 /In .
Lemma B.2 (Asymptotics for labor surplus distortion). In the high-disagreement limit (n →
∞), the labor surplus distortion disappears:
I1
=0
In

lim (σ − 1)EC

n→∞

Proof. Since θ̃ > 0, Lemma A.3 gives limn→∞ Me = ∞. The proof of Lemma A.3 implies
limn→∞ In = ∞. Finally, because σ < γ,
γ
I1 =
γ−σ



Me
M

 σ−γ
γ

→0

as n → ∞. Therefore, I1 /In converges to 0.

B.2
B.2.1

Differentiated Goods
Date 1 Economy

The introduction of differentiated goods in Section 5.1.2 changes the production stage. We
therefore focus on the equilibrium conditions at date 1.
Firms produce a mass M of differentiated goods, indexed by (a, i), where a is firm productivity and i indexes the firms. We drop the i index when unambiguous. Household utility
aggregates consumption of these goods with constant elasticity of substitution σ across goods.
At date 1, household j with total expenditure Ej solves:
Me

Z
C(Ej ) = max

{c(a,i)}

Z
s.t.
0

Me

∞

 c (a, i)

M
F −1 1− M

0

Z

Z

σ−1
σ

!

σ
σ−1

dF (a)di

e

∞


 p (a, i) c (a, i) dF (a)di
M
F −1 1− M
e

62

≤ Ej .

For reasons that will soon be clear, we denote by 1/P the Lagrange multiplier on the budget
constraint. Because the objective function is homogeneous of degree one in consumption and
the budget constraint is linear, C(Ej ) is linear in Ej . Thus, we have C(Ej ) = Ej /P. Therefore,
P is the price of one unit of the consumption basket. We use this consumption basket as
the numeraire at date 1 by normalizing P = 1. The linearity also implies that to aggregate
individual demands, it is sufficient to know the aggregate expenditure in the economy and
not the whole distribution of individual expenditures. The first-order condition in the problem
above implies the demand curve:
c(p) = Cp−σ .
Output for a firm with productivity a is y = a`. Firms face monopolistic competition. They
maximize profits by setting prices, taking as given the demand curve from each household:
max p(a)y (p (a)) −
p(a)

h
i
wy (p (a))
w
= C p(a)1−σ − p(a)−σ .
a
a

The optimal price is therefore
p(a) =

σ w
.
σ−1 a

Firms charge a markup σ/(σ − 1) over their marginal cost w/a.
We can then compute output y, revenue py, labor expenditure w`, and profits π as functions
of productivity:

−σ
σ
y = Cw−σ aσ
σ−1

1−σ
σ
py = Cw1−σ aσ−1
σ−1

1−σ
σ
σ − 1 1−σ σ−1
Cw
a
w` =
σ
σ−1

1−σ
1 1−σ σ−1
σ
π = Cw
a
.
σ
σ−1
We see that labor expenditure is a fraction (σ − 1)/σ of revenues, and profits make up the
remaining 1/σ share.
Labor market clearing gives C(σ − 1)/σ = wL. In equilibrium, aggregate expenditure is
equal to aggregate consumption, so we have:

C=C

σ
w
σ−1

1

1−σ
Me I1 (Me , σ − 1)

 1 
 (σ−1)−γ
σ−1
γ
Me (σ−1)γ
= Me
·L
γ − (σ − 1)
M

 1
1
σ−1
1
γ
−1
=
M σ−1 γ Meγ · L.
γ − (σ − 1)
σ−1

Therefore, we have EC = Ew = 1/γ. Alternatively, notice that the labor allocation is effi-

63

cient with monopolistic competition and the aggregate production function is homogeneous of
degree one in the distribution of productivity. Because an increase in Me increases all productivities with an elasticity 1/γ, this results in an elasticity of aggregate consumption of
1/γ.

B.2.2

Spillovers

All arguments behind Proposition 3 apply, so the proposition is still valid, but with I1 and In
now evaluated with parameter σ − 1.
Because the aggregate consumption elasticity is unchanged, the output-based spillover
(and market-based spillover under agreement) is unchanged: spillout = −(γ − σ)/γ.
With speculation, the free-entry condition is:


Me
M

θ

1
= C
σ

 1−σ
C
In ,
L

which we can rewrite as:
KMeθ−(1−(σ−1))/γ = In ,
where K does not depend on Me and n. This is again the same condition as the homogeneous goods model, with σ replaced by σ − 1. The condition for the convergence of EIn from
Lemma B.1 still applies as well. In the high-disagreement limit with θ > 1/γ, the marketbased spillover becomes:
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −1 − EI1 + EC = −

σ−2
.
γ

(IA.28)

The upper panel of Figure IA.2 shows the sign reversal of the market-based spillover, as
described in Proposition 5.

B.3
B.3.1

Knowledge Externalities
Date 1 Economy

We again focus on the date 1 economy and return to a setting with decreasing return to scale.
Now firm productivity depends on the productivity of other firms producing. In particular,
consider the production function:
y=

σ−1
σ
a1−α Aα ` σ ,
σ−1

where a is firm productivity and A is an aggregator of all producing firms’ productivities. α > 0
captures the intensity of knowledge spillovers. We use a Hölder mean of the productivity of
all firms producing:

A=

!1
Z
q
Me
q
a
dF
(a)
.
M ( Me ) γ1
M

64

(a) Demand externalities

Spillover

1/γ

1
γ

−

1
2

Outcome
Market

−(γ − 1)/γ
0

γ/(γ + 2)

γ/(γ + 1)

(b) Knowledge externalities

Spillover

α/(1 − α)

Outcome
Market

α/γ
γ+1
γ(2−α)

−1

−(γ − 1)/γ
(γ + α − 1)/(γ + 1)

0

1 − (1 − α)/γ

Labor share: (σ − 1)/σ
Figure IA.2
Market-based and outcome-based spillovers.
Imposing q < γ so that the integral is well-defined, we have:

A=

γ
γ−q

1 
q

Me
M

1
γ

.

Our results generalize to any aggregator that is homogeneous of degree one in the productivity
distribution of producing firms. Such aggregators similarly yield an elasticity 1/γ with respect
to Me .
Firms maximize their profits, taking the wage as given:
max
`

σ−1
σ
a1−α Aα ` σ − w`.
σ−1

65

The demand for labor is therefore
`=

w



a1−α Aα

−σ

,

and we have:
σ
σ
a1−α Aα w1−σ
σ−1
σ
σ−1
w`(a) = a1−α Aα w1−σ =
y(a)
σ
σ
1
1
π(a) =
a1−α Aα w1−σ = y(a).
σ−1
σ
y(a) =

The labor share is still (σ − 1)/σ.
The market-clearing condition for labor is:
L = w−σ Aασ Me I1 (Me , (1 − α)σ)
 ασ 
 ασ

 (1−α)σ −1

q
γ
Me γ
γ
Me
γ
Me
w−σ
=
γ−q
M
γ − (1 − α)σ M

 ασ

σ
q
γ
Me γ −σ
γ
=
M
w
γ−q
γ − (1 − α)σ
M
 1 
α 
1 
1
q
σ
M σ
γ
γ
Me γ
w=
.
L
γ−q
γ − (1 − α)σ
M
We still have (σ − 1)/σC = wL, and the same elasticities: Ew = EC = EA = 1/γ.

B.3.2

Spillovers

Proposition 3 and Lemma B.1 still apply, with I1 and In evaluated with parameter (1 − α)σ.
The outcome-based spillover is unchanged: spillout = −(γ − σ)/γ. The market-based spillover
in the high-disagreement limit with θ > 1/γ becomes:
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −1 − EI1 + EC = −

(1 − α) σ − 1
.
γ

(IA.29)

The lower panel of Figure IA.2 shows the sign reversal of the market-based spillover, as described in Proposition 5.

66

C
C.1

Extensions to Simple Model
Speculation with Dynamics

To capture the fact that investors’ views change over time, we consider a dynamic version of
the model in Section 2. The dynamic model produces predictions about the volume of trading
and the length of a bubble that are consistent with documented facts in Hong and Stein (2007)
and Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018).
We incorporate dynamics by assuming that, instead of producing at date 1, firms produce
at some stochastic date T . At each date t, the economy enters the production stage with
probability ψ −1 , and stays in the development stage with probability 1 − ψ −1 . At each date
t < T before production, firms engage into some development activity with productivity ai,t
that is unknown. With some probability ϑ, they change their activity and receive a new
productivity draw independent from their past productivity.40 With probability 1 − ϑ, firms’
productivity stays the same as last period and ai,t = ai,t−1 .

Dynamic overvaluation. In equilibrium, the price of each firm exceeds the maximum
valuation of its cash flow by any specific investor in the economy. At any point in time, an
investor ranking the firm first in a packet attains this maximum valuation, which we denote
as pmax
i,t . The difference between the two valuations is
pi,t − pmax
= (In − I1 ) · ψ
i,t

ϑ(ψ − 1)
> 0.
1 + ϑ(ψ − 1)

(IA.30)

This difference comes from the fact that when firms change their activities, the current investor will typically not favor firm i anymore. On average, a household investing in firm i
values it as a typical firm in the economy, with I1 , rather than a favorite, with In .

Predictions. The dynamic overvaluation has implications for trading volume and the
length of a bubble. Each time households exchange firms signals a change in who values them
most, a mechanism reminiscent of the models of Harrison and Kreps (1978) and Scheinkman
and Xiong (2003). From (IA.30), we can see that the strength of the overvaluation is increasing in the volume per period ϑ and the length of the bubble ψ.41

C.2

Generalizing the Business-Stealing Effect

We now consider more general functions for the business-stealing effect. In particular, suppose the expected profit of a firm with productivity a is:
π(a) = aη δ (r(a, Me )) ,
where r(a, Me ) ≡ (1 − F (a)) Me is the ranking of the firm, or the mass of firms with productivity greater than a. We can interpret δ as being the probability of producing conditional on a
firm’s ranking r. The main text focused on the special case of δ(r) = 1 {r ≤ M }.
We continue to focus on the case with F (a) = 1 − a−γ .
40
The change of firms’ activity before production captures, for instance, the pivot of startups in the
early stages of their development.
41
For instance, when ϑ  ψ −1  1, the overvaluation is proportional to ϑψ 2 .

67

C.2.1

Outcome-Based Spillover

Lemma C.1. The outcome-based spillover does not depend on the level of entry:
spillout = −

γ−η
.
γ

(IA.31)

Proof. Under agreement, n = 1, and we can derive an exact solution for the mass of firms
entering in equilibrium Me . Integrating by parts, the value of a firm is:
Z ∞
(1)
γxη−γ−1 δ(Me x−γ )dx
V (Me ) =
1


Z ∞
γ
η−2γ−1 0
−γ
x
δ (Me x )dx .
(IA.32)
δ(Me ) − γMe
=
γ−η
1
In addition, we have:
dV (1)
Me
= γMe
dMe

Z

∞

xη−2γ−1 δ 0 (Me x−γ )dx.

(IA.33)

1

(1)

(1) , we have the desired formula (IA.31) for the outcomeRecalling that spillout = Me dV
dMe /V
based spillover.

C.2.2

Disagreement Asymptotics with Multiple Cutoffs

We now consider the generalization of δ to allow for multiple cutoffs. In particular, suppose
k
we have cutoffs a1 < ... < aK , with ak ≡ F −1 (1 − M
Me ), and constants ∆1 , ..., ∆K so that
δ(r) =

K
X

∆k 1 {r ≤ Mk } .

(IA.34)

k=1

Notice that this imples that V (n) =

(n)
k=1 ∆k Vk ,

PK

(n)

where Vk

≡

R∞
ak

xη dFn (x), and


K 
X
dV (n)
Mk η Fn0
−Me
=−
∆k
· a · 0 (ak ) .
dMe
Me
F
k=1

−θ
For convenience, we normalize the cost of producing blueprints so that W (b) = fe bθ+1 MK
/(θ+
1).

Lemma C.2. Holding Me constant, the outcome-based spillover is larger than the marketbased spillover.
Proof. Apply the proof for Proposition 1 for each k.
Theorem C.3 (Asymptotics for the market-based spillover with multiple cutoffs). With
business-stealing of the form (IA.34), in the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), the marketbased spillover converges to a finite limit.
• If γθ < η, then spillmkt (n) → −(γ − η)/γ.
• If γθ > η, then spillmkt (n) → 0.

68

− f1e

• If γθ = η, then spillmkt (n) →



PK



∆k

k=1

MK
Mk

 η−γ
γ

α∞ exp



Mk
−M
α∞
K


.

Proof. Suppose γθ < η. As before, conjecture that we can write aK = α(n)n1/(γ(1+θ)−η) . This
yields
K
X

fe '


∆k

k=1

Mk
MK

 γ−η
γ

αη−γ(θ+1)

γ
.
γ−η

(IA.35)

Therefore, we have the asymptotics for firm entry:


K
1 X
Mk
Me
=
∆k
MK
fe
MK
"

γ−η
γ

k=1

γ
·n
γ−η

γ
# γ(θ+1)−η

(IA.36)

.

Substituting this into the formula for the market-based spillover, we have
PK

k=1 ∆k

spillmkt (n) = −



Mk
Me

 γ−η

fe

γ



Me
MK


n 1−
θ

Mk
Me

n−1
→−

γ−η
γ

(IA.37)

as desired.
Now suppose γθ > η. Then we have
n
spillmkt (n) = −
n
=−

η−γ
k=1 ak

PK

PK



a−γ
k

fe aγθ
K

 η−γ
γ

MK
Mk

k=1

n−1


a−γ
1−
K

Mk −γ
MK aK

n−1
(IA.38)

γθ−η
fe aK

Suppose aK → ∞. Then we can write the first-order condition for firm creation as:
fe aγθ−η
K
na−γ
K

=

K
X


∆k

k=1

MK
Mk

 η−γ

∞

Z

γ

γ
1

n−1

−γ
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ
t
dt.
k

(IA.39)

R∞
Since the integral on the right-hand side is bounded from above by 1 tη−γ−1 dt, we have that
na−γ
K → ∞, which implies that we can use a similar approximation to the proof of Proposition 2
to show that:
n

PK  MK  η−γ
γ

spillmkt (n) ' −

k=1

Mk



Mk −γ
a−γ
exp
−n
a
K
MK K

γθ−η
fe aK

→ 0.

(IA.40)



Mk −γ −γ
1−
a t
.
MK K

(IA.41)

Finally, suppose γθ = η. We then have
fe =

K
X
k=1


∆k γn

MK
Mk

 η−γ
γ

a−γ
K

Z

∞

t
1

69

η−γ−1

As before, we conjecture that aK = α(n)−1/γ n1/γ . Then

 η−γ

Z ∞
γ
MK
η−γ−1
−1 Mk −γ
dt
t
exp −(n − 1)α(n)n
t
γα(n)
fe '
∆k
Mk
MK
1
k=1


 η−γ

Z ∞
K
X
γ
MK
Mk
η−γ−1
−γ
→
dt.
∆k
t
exp −
α∞ t
γα∞
Mk
MK
1
K
X



(IA.42)

k=1

By analogous reasoning to the proof in Proposition 2, we can obtain a finite bound on α∞ . We
therefore have the market-based spillover:
"

 η−γ

#
K
γ
1 X
MK
Mk −γ
−γ
spillmkt (n) = −
∆k n
a
aK 1 −
fe
Mk
MK K
k=1
" 
 η−γ

#
K
γ
MK
1 X
Mk
→−
∆k
α∞ 1 −
α∞
(IA.43)
fe
Mk
MK
k=1

as desired.

C.2.3

Disagreement Asymptotics with Continuous Business-Stealing

We now consider a continuous function for the business-stealing effect
(
1
if r < 1
δ(r) =
−ζ
r
if r ≥ 1

(IA.44)

so that ζ parameterizes the business-stealing effect for low-productivity firms with r ≥ 1.
Larger ζ implies that low-productivity firms have a lower probability of producing, with ζ = 0
corresponding to the case with no business-stealing effect. With ζ → ∞, this converges to the
benchmark step function business-stealing effect with M = 1.
We now normalize the cost of producing blueprints, so that W (b) = fe bθ+1 /(θ + 1), and
1

define a ≡ Meγ to be the cutoff above which δ(a, Me ) = 1, i.e., firms produce with probability
one.
(n)
(n)
It will be convenient to consider the decomposition V (n) = VL + VU , where
Z a
(n)
−ζ
xη−γ(1−ζ)−1 (1 − x−γ )n−1 dx
VL ≡ γnMe
Z ∞ 1
(n)
VU ≡ γn
xη−γ−1 (1 − x−γ )n−1 dx
a

capture the expected profit conditional on having productivity below and above a respectively.
We can write
Z 1
(n)
η−γ(θ+1)
VL = γna
tη−γ(1−ζ)−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt
(IA.45)
a−1

(n)

VU

= γnaη−γ(θ+1)

Z

a−1

tη−γ−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt.

1

70

(IA.46)

Moreover, since
(n)

η−γ(1−ζ)−1
n−1
dVL
(n)
γ
= −ζMe−1 VL + γnMe−ζ Me
1 − Me−1
dMe

(n)

(n)

= −ζMe−1 VL

−

dVU
,
dMe

we have that
−Me

dV (n)
(n)
= ζVL .
dMe

(IA.47)

Theorem C.4 (Asymptotics for the market-based spillover with continuous business-stealing). Suppose we have business stealing of the form (IA.44) and ζ > γ−η
γ . In the highdisagreement limit (n → ∞), the market-based spillover converges to a finite limit.
• If γθ < η, then spillmkt (n) → −(γ − η)/γ.
• If γθ ≥ η, then spillmkt (n) → 0.
Proof. Suppose γθ < η. Conjecture that a = α(n)n1/(γ(1+θ)−η) . We have from the proof
(n)
(n)
γ
of Proposition 2 that VU → αη−γ γ−η
. In addition, we have from (IA.45) that VU →
γ
αη−γ η−γ(1−ζ)
. Therefore, we have

fe =

γ
γ
−
γ − η γ(1 − ζ) − η



αη−γ(θ+1) ,

(IA.48)

which verifies the conjecture. We thus have the asymptotic market-based spillover
(n)

spillmkt (n) = −ζ

VL
γ−η
→−
(n)
γ
V

(IA.49)

as desired.
Suppose γθ > η. Suppose a → ∞. Then we can rewrite (8) as:
fe aγθ−η /γ
.
R
η−γ(1−ζ)−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt + ∞ tη−γ−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt
t
−1
a
1

na−γ = R 1

(IA.50)

The
two terms in the
of the right-hand side are bounded from above by
R 1 η−γ(1−ζ)−1
R ∞ denominator
η−γ−1
dt and 1 t
dt, respectively, which implies that na−γ → ∞. Using the ap0 t
−γ
n−1
' exp(−na−γ ), we have that
proximation (1 − a )
spillmkt (n) = −

ζ
(n)
V
→ 0.
fe aγθ L

(n)

(IA.51)

If a has a finite limit, we can show that VL → 0 since n(1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 → 0 for t ∈ (a−1 , 1),
which implies that spillmkt (n) → 0 as well.
Suppose γθ = η. Using an analogous proof to Lemma A.4, we can show that an =

71

(n)

α(n)−1/γ n1/γ , where α(n) has a finite limit α∞ . Since we can bound VL
(n)
VL

Z

1

= γα(n)

from above by

tη−γ(1−ζ)−1 (1 − a−γ t−γ )n−1 dt

a−1

Z

1

≤ γα(n)

tη−γ(1−ζ)−1 dt →

a−1
ζV

γα∞
,
η − γ(1 − ζ)

(n)

we have that spillmkt (n) = − fe aLγθ → 0.

C.3

Results with a Zero-Cutoff-Profit Condition

Our results are robust to an extension in which the marginal firm earns zero profits. Our
baseline model specifies that the M most productive firms will be allowed to produce, which
allows for tractability but results in the marginal firm earning positive profits, π(a) > 0. We
now augment the model with an intermediate stage where firms, after entering the market,
compete to be among one of the M firms producing. The competition stage ensures that the
business-stealing externality remains. We keep the belief and production structure of the
model intact= and show that the main features of the spillovers remain unchanged despite
the introduction of a zero-cutoff-profit (ZCP) condition for the marginal firm.
In the new intermediate decision stage, firms can use some of their production as advertisement to reach consumers, a deadweight loss. Only the M firms that spend the most on
advertising produce in equilibrium. Formally, each firm chooses how much of its production to
use on advertisement, hi ≤ π(ai ). In doing so, firms take as given the equilibrium level h of advertising necessary to attract consumers. Their profit function is therefore π(ai )1{hi ≥ h}−hi .
The optimal advertisement choice is hi = h if π(ai ) ≥ h and 0 otherwise. The equilibrium value
of h is such that exactly M firms choose to spend on advertisement. Keeping the definition of
the production cutoff a from earlier, this implies
h = π(a).

(IA.52)

Firms must spend the profits of the marginal firm to be able to produce, resulting in zero
profits for the marginal firm.

C.3.1

General Derivations

Firm value in this model is modified to account for the cost of advertisement:
Z ∞
Ve (n) (Me ) =
(π(a) − π(a)) dF n (a).

(IA.53)

a

We can define the corresponding integral Ien . With this new definition of firm value, the
remainder of the competitive equilibrium and the planner problem are unchanged. In particular, the market-based spillover is spillmkt = EIen .
Decompose firms’ valuations into the revenue (from (IA.53)) and advertising cost compo-

72

nents:
V

(n)

Z
(Me ) =

∞




 π(a)dFn (a)
M
F −1 1− M

−

e

M
Me

1− η
γ



M
·n 1−
Me

n−1
.

(IA.54)

The first derivative of V (n) is:
dV (n) (Me )
η
−Me ·
=
dMe
γ



Me
M

η 
 

γ
M n
.
· 1− 1−
Me

Using the free-entry condition, V (n) (Me ) = W 0 (Me ), we have following formula for the marketbased spillover:
η 1
spillmkt (n; Me ) = ·
·
γ fe

C.3.2



Me
M

 η −θ 
 

γ
M n
.
· 1− 1−
Me

(IA.55)

Spillovers and Firm Entry

Lemma C.5. In the model with a ZCP condition, the outcome-based spillover is:
spillout = −

γ−η
.
γ

Proof. The free-entry condition with n = 1 gives us:


Me
M

 γ(1+θ)−η
γ

=

1
η
·
.
fe γ − η

Given the derivation of the spillover in (IA.55), we have:
η 1
·
spillout (Me ) = − ·
γ fe



Me
M

 η −θ
γ

·

γ−η
M
=−
,
Me
γ

(IA.56)

where we have used our equilibrium solution for Me /M .
Lemma C.6. In the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), the mass of entrants also increases and
goes to infinity: limn→∞ Me = ∞.
Proof. We adapt the proof from Lemma A.3, again defining the sequence an = (Me /M )1/γ and
showing that an → ∞. Equation (IA.54) implies the implicit definition of the sequence (an )n
in this case:
Z ∞

γ(θ+1)−η
−γ n−1
n−1
fe an
= γn
tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ
dt − n(1 − a−γ
.
n t
n )
1

Assume that an has a finite limit that is strictly larger than zero, a∞ > 0. Then there exists N
large enough such that ∀n > N, an > A = a∞ −  > 0. For any arbitrary threshold Tn , we have


n−1
γ
In > n
· Tnη−γ 1 − A−γ Tn−γ
−1 .
γ−η
As in Lemma A.3, we conclude by considering the threshold Tn = n1/γ .

73

Lemma C.7 (Asymptotics for firm creation). In the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), we have
the following asymptotics for the mass of firms created Me :
γ

γ
• If γθ < η, then limn→∞ Me /M = α∞
n γ(1+θ)−η .
−1 n.
• If γθ = η, then limn→∞ Me /M = α∞

In each case, α∞ is a constant defined below.
Proof. We adapt the proof from Lemma A.4. Starting from (8), and using a:
Z ∞

η−γ(θ+1)
(tη − 1) t−γ−1 exp −(n − 1)a−γ t−γ dt,
n
fe ' γa
1

where we have used the fact that a → ∞ and log(1 − x) = −x + O(x2 ). To find a solution, we
1

guess that asymptotically a ' α(n)n γ(1+θ)−η and show that α(n) converges to a finite limit α.
The first-order condition becomes


Z ∞
η
−γ−1
−γ n − 1
−γ
η−γ(θ+1)
(t − 1) t
exp −α(n)
t
dt.
fe ' γα(n)
γ
1
n γ(1+θ)−η
If γθ < η, then the exponential term converges to zero and we have:

α∞ =

η
1
·
fe γ − η



1
γ(1+θ)−η

(IA.57)

.

If γθ = η, then a is defined by:
fe =

γa−γ
n n

∞

Z

tη−γ−1 1 − a−γ t−γ

n−1

dt.

1

We guess and verify that an = α(n)−1/γ n1/γ , and α(n) has a finite limit α∞ :
Z ∞
−γ
fe = γα∞
(tη − 1) t−γ−1 e−α∞ t dt,
1

where we took the limit when n → ∞. Moreover, we are able to bound the magnitude of the
market-based spillover above using a bound on α∞ :
α∞ e−α∞
γ−η
<
,
fe
η

(IA.58)

which verifies that α∞ is finite.
We now show that, despite the presence of the ZCP, Proposition 2 holds.
Theorem C.8. In the high-disagreement limit (n → ∞), the market-based spillover converges
to a finite limit.
• If γθ < η, then spillmkt (n) → −(γ − η)/γ.
• If γθ > η, then spillmkt (n) → 0.
• If γθ = η, then spillmkt (n) → − γη f1e e−α∞ .

74

Proof. If γθ > η, then given equation (IA.55), we use that Me → ∞ to conclude that
limn→∞ spillmkt = 0.
If γθ < η, then we can use the asymptotics from C.7 and the formula for the market-based
spillover from (IA.55):
η−θγ
η 1 η−θγ
α∞ · n γ(1+θ)−η
γ fe
η−θγ
η 1 η−θγ
α∞ · n γ(1+θ)−η
'−
γ fe
η−θγ
η 1 η−θγ
'−
α∞ · n γ(1+θ)−η
γ fe

spillmkt (n; Me ) ' −

h

n i
−γ
−γ γ(1+θ)−η
· 1 − 1 − α∞
n



γθ−η
−γ γ(1+θ)−η
· 1 − exp −α∞ n
γθ−η

−γ γ(1+θ)−η
· α∞
n
→−

η 1 η−γ(1+θ)
α
.
γ fe ∞

(IA.59)
(IA.60)
(IA.61)

Using the definition of α∞ from the proof above, we conclude limn→∞ spillmkt (n; Me ) = −(γ −
η)/γ.
In the knife-edge case with γθ = η, we have
spillmkt (n; Me ) ' −

n 
η 1 
η 1 −α∞
.
· 1 − 1 − α∞ n−1
→−
·e
γ fe
γ fe

(IA.62)

−1 ·(γ−η)/γ.
We can bound the market-based spillover in the limit: limn→∞ |spillmkt (n; Me )| < α∞

Our conclusions are therefore robust to including competition to enter. Intuitively,
marginal firms drive the externality in both settings. In our baseline, the externality operates at the extensive margin: more entry displaces the profits of excluded marginal firms.
In this model, the externality is on the intensive margin: firm entry increases the productivity
of the marginal firm and thus advertisement costs for all producing firms.

75

D

Extensions to General Equilibrium Model

D.1

Elastic Labor Supply

D.1.1

Setting and Equilibrium

We now consider the case of variable labor supply. Households can provide labor L by exerting
an effort cost S(L). We assume


0

S (L) = fl

L
L0

1/κ
,

where κ is the Frisch elasticity of labor supply. As κ converges to 0, the model converges to a
constant labor supply L0 . The remainder of the model is unchanged.
In equilibrium, we have S 0 (L) = w, which implies that EL = κEw . Noting that we still have
a constant labor share ((σ − 1)/σC = wL), we also have EC = Ew + EL = (1 + κ)Ew .
Market clearing for labor yields:
Z ∞
−σ
L = Me · w
a−σ dF (a) = Me · w−σ · I1 ,
a

which given the expression for I1 in (IA.23) under a Pareto leads to the following restriction:
wL1/σ =



γ
γ−σ

1

1

σ



· Meσ ·

Me
M

1−1
γ

σ

.

Using the labor supply equation, we obtain
1 σ
γσ+κ
1 σ + κσ
EC =
.
γ σ+κ
Ew =

As we increase the elasticity of labor supply, the wage becomes less elastic to firm entry
and consumption becomes more elastic to firm entry as it becomes less costly to expand labor.

D.1.2

Spillovers

Asymptotics. To study the asymptotic behavior of the market-based spillover, recall the
free-entry condition:

fe

Me
M

θ
=

1
w1−σ In .
σ−1

We define
θ̃ = θ +

σ−1 σ
≥0
γ κ+σ

76

and recognize the free-entry condition from the pure business-stealing model. This guarantees that limn→∞ I1 /In = 0. In addition, EIn converges to 0 if:
(IA.63)

γ θ̃ > σ
κ
⇔ γθ > 1 + (σ − 1)
.
κ+σ

(IA.64)

Behavior of the spillovers. The market-based social value is characterized by:

=

1 In σ − 1
+
C
C − S(L) − W (Me )
σ I1
σ
1 In
1 In I10
σ−1 0
1 In In0
1 dL
+ C0
− C
+
.
C
C − S 0 (L)L
| {z } L dMe
σ I1 In σ I1
σ I1 I1
σ
σ−1
C
σ

The market-based spillover is similar to Proposition 3. However, the appropriability term now
accounts for the utility cost of expanding the labor supply:
spillmkt (n) = EIn − EI1 − 1 + EC + (σ − 1) (EC − EL )

I1
.
In

Ew

The outcome-based spillover is:
γ−σ
.
γ

(IA.65)

σ−1 σ
.
γ κ+σ

(IA.66)

spillout = −1 + EC + (σ − 1)Ew = −
With high speculation and large θ, we have:
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −(σ − 1)Ew = −

The outcome-based spillover is unchanged from the baseline model. Thee market-based
spillover with high disagreement is decreasing in σ and increasing in γ, as is the case in
Proposition 4. The elasticity of labor supply does not affect the outcome-based spillover, but
under market-based measures, increasing κ increases the spillover. As labor supply becomes
more elastic, the wage becomes less responsive to entry, and firms have less influence on each
other through general equlibrium effects. With perfectly elastic labor supply, there are no
general equilibrium effects and hence no market-based spillovers in the high-disagreement
limit, i.e., spillmkt (n → ∞) = 0.

D.2
D.2.1

Variable Number of Participating Firms
Setting and Equilibrium

We study a model where the number of participating firms, M , responds to firm creation
Me , which can be interpreted as households’ consumption bundles becoming more or less
concentrated as more firms enter the economy. We assume that M varies exogenously with

77

the level of firm entry Me :
M=

1
M0χ−1

· Meχ ,

where χ is the elasticity of firms producing to firms created and M0 a normalization constant.
We assume that χ ≤ 1 such that we always have M ≤ Me .
The cost of creating a firm only depends on M0 through:


0

W (Me ) = fe

Me
M0

θ
.

The productivity threshold to produce is now:
a := F

−1


 
 1−χ
M
Me γ
1−
=
.
Me
M0

The model still features a constant labor share and firm profits are still isoelastic in the
productivity:
π(a) =

1
1 C aσ
· w1−σ · aσ =
· ,
σ−1
σ Me I1

where we have redefined the integrals I1 and In to adjust for the new expressions for the
productivity threshold a:
Z ∞
In (χ) =   1−χ aσ dFn (a)
γ

Me
M0

γ
·
I1 (χ) =
γ−σ



Me
M0

(χ−1) γ−σ
γ

.

The market-clearing condition L = Me w−σ I1 implies the equilibrium wage:

w=

γ
γ−σ

1

σ

− σ1

·L



(1−χ) σ1 − γ1

M0

χ

· Meσ

+ 1−χ
γ

,

so that the labor elasticity is :
1
Ew = + χ ·
γ



1
1
−
σ γ


.

We obtain aggregate consumption by aggregating individual output C = Me σ/(σ −
1)w1−σ I1 , which yields equilibrium aggregate consumption and elasticity:


(1−χ)
σ−1
σ
γ
C=
· L σ · M0
σ−1γ−σ


1
1
1
EC = Ew = + χ ·
−
γ
σ γ

78

1−σ
+ γ−1
σ
γ



1
+χ·
γ

· Me



1
− γ1
σ



D.2.2

Spillovers

Given the constant labor share and isoelastic profits, we can apply Proposition 3 and obtain
the market-based spillover:
spillmkt (n) = EIn (χ) − 1 − EI1 (χ) − EC + (σ − 1)EC ·

I1 (χ)
.
In (χ)

(IA.67)

From the expression for In we have the following change in the elasticities:
EIn (χ) = (1 − χ)EIn (χ=0) = (1 − χ)EIn

(IA.68)

Asymptotics. We now turn to the high-disagreement limit. The first-order condition for
firm creation is:

fe
⇐⇒

Me
M0

θ
=

1
w1−σ In (χ)
σ−1

constant = a

γ
γ
−θ 1−χ
+(1−σ) 1−χ



1
+χ
γ



1
− γ1
σ

 Z ∞

aσ dFn (a).

a

We define:
1
θ̃ =
1−χ




σ−1
1
1
θ+
+ χ(σ − 1)
−
,
γ
σ γ

and recognize the entry condition of the baseline model. We apply our previous results, changing the condition for EIn (χ) → 0 to γ θ̃ > σ, which reduces to:
γ(θ + χ) > 1 + χ

γ
σ


−1 .

(IA.69)

If this condition is satisfied, then limn→∞ EIn (χ) = 0. When the inequality is reversed,
limn→∞ EIn (χ) = EI1 (χ) = (1 − χ)(σ − γ)/γ. With equality, the elasticity admits a finite limit
between these two values.

Behavior of the spillovers. The outcome-based spillover is
spillout

γ−σ
= −1 + σEC = −
+ χσ
γ



1
1
+
σ γ


.

The market-based spillover with high disagreement, when θ is large enough, is:


σ−1
1
1
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −1 − EI1 (χ) + EC = −
− χ (σ − 1)
−
γ
σ γ

(IA.70)

(IA.71)

As long as |χ| < 1, Proposition 4 still holds with the generalized version of In . A higher
elasticity of firm participation with respect to firm entry leads to opposite results with and
without disagreement. A large elasticity χ dampens the outcome-based spillovers because it
diminishes business stealing. However it strengthens the market-based spillover with disagreement: in response to firm entry, labor demand responds at the intensive margin with
more productive firms and at the extensive margin with more participating firms.

79

D.3

Advertising to Participate

We augment the previous model with an intermediate stage after market entry when firms
compete to be one of M firms producing, as in Appendix C.3.

D.3.1

Setting and Equilibrium

In the new intermediate decision stage, firms choose to spend on advertisement to reach consumers. We assume that only the M firms that spend the most on advertising produce in
equilibrium. Formally if a firm with productivity ai spends hi in advertising, its profit is:
π(ai )1{hi ≥ h} − hi . Hence there is a threshold level of advertising, h, below which firms
cannot reach any consumers and above which firms do produce. Firms take the threshold as
given and decide on their choice of advertising. Thus the advertising equilibrium is such that
the threshold matches the profit of the marginal firm: h = π(a).
Profits are modified with respect to the standard model of Section B.1 to incorporate the
advertisement payments:
π(a) =

1 1−σ σ
w
(a − aσ ) ,
σ

The ex-ante firm valuation is therefore:
V (n) (Me ) =

1 C Ien
·
·
,
σ Me I1

where we define the adjusted integral Ien as
Z
Ien (Me ) =

∞

( MMe )

1
γ

aσ −



Me
M

σ !
γ

dFn (a).

The entry condition in the competitive equilibrium is now:
W 0 (Me ) =

D.3.2

1 C Ien
·
·
.
σ Me I 1

Spillovers

The market-based social value is characterized by:
1 Ien Ien0
1 Ien
1 Ien I10
σ−1 0
C
+ C0
− C
+
C.
e
σ I1 In σ I1
σ I1 I1
σ
The market-based spillover is therefore:
spillmkt (n) = EIen − EI1 − 1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC

I1
.
Ien

(IA.72)

The outcome-based spillover (or market-based spillover under agreement) is:
spillout = −1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC

80

γ
1
1
=− + ,
σ
σ γ

(IA.73)

where we have used that, as in the baseline model, EC = Ew = 1/γ. However, the profit share
is now lower because of advertisement costs. A fraction (σ − 1)/σ of output accrues to labor
but only a fraction 1/γ (< 1/σ) is collected as profits. The larger importance of labor relative
to profits gives rise to a smaller outcome-based spillover. As in the standard model, |spillout |
is decreasing in σ and increasing in γ.
To derive the market-based spillover with high disagreement, notice that I1 /Ien → 0 and
therefore, if θ > 1/γ, then spillmkt (n → ∞) is unchanged from the standard model:
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −

σ−1
.
γ

(IA.74)

Therefore, Proposition 4 still holds.

D.3.3

Advertising with Demand or Knowledge Spillovers.

Introducing advertisement costs to the aggregate demand and knowledge externalities models
from Sections B.2 and B.3 yields the same formula for spillmkt (n) as in equation (IA.72), so
that we have the limit with high disagreement spillmkt (n → ∞) = −(σ − 1)/γ.
The main difference between spillovers in the standard model and the models in Section
B.2 and B.3 arises through the differences in the profit function, which affects the ratio I1 /Ien .
With aggregate demand externalities, the ratio is γ/(σ − 1), and the outcome-based spillover
is:
AD
spillout
=

1
.
γ

(IA.75)

For the model with knowledge spillovers, the ratio is γ/(1 − α)σ, and the outcome-based
spillover is:
KS
spillout
= −1 +

D.4

1
σ−1
+
.
γ (1 − α)σ

(IA.76)

Participation Costs in the Baseline Model

Another way to ensure the marginal firm makes zero profit is to assume firms invest in infrastructure to produce. In particular, suppose that upon entry all firms can participate on the
goods market, but firms must buy one unit of infrastructure to reach all of their customers.
Households produce infrastructure competitively at a cost of effort Φ. In an equilibrium with
M producing firms, the price of infrastructure is:
Φ0 (M ) = ϕ(M ) = ϕ0 · M ν
with ν > 0, so that the cost of infrastructure is increasing in the mass of producing firms M .

D.4.1

Setting and Equilibrium

Participating firms. Given Me and M , profits before the infrastructure costs are unchanged from the standard model with decreasing returns to scale:
π(a) =

1
· w1−σ · aσ .
σ−1

81

The equilibrium wage is also unchanged:

w=

γ
γ−σ

1 
1 
1 1
σ
Me σ
Me γ − σ
·
·
.
L
M

The marginal firm has productivity a and spends all of its profit on infrastructure. Therefore,
we have the zero-cutoff-profit condition Φ0 (M ) = π(a), which implies:
M

ν+ γ1 + σ−1
σ

1 1
=
ϕ0 σ − 1



γ−σ
γ

 σ−1
σ

L

σ−1
σ

1

· Meγ ,

where we use the fact that a = (Me /M )1/γ . In Section D.2, we specified an exogenous set of
producing firms M = Meχ /M0χ−1 . This arises endogenously through our cost of infrastructure
with


1
1 σ − 1 −1
χ=
ν+ +
γ
γ
σ

−1
! ν+ γ1 + σ−1

 σ−1
σ
σ−1
1 1
γ−σ σ
M01−χ =
L σ
,
ϕ0 σ − 1
γ
where the exponent satisfies χ ≤ 1.
We can also compute the elasticity EC :


1
1
1
1
1+ν
EC = + χ
−
= ·
= χ · (1 + ν).
γ
σ γ
γ 1 + ν + 1/γ − 1/σ

Equilibrium. The equilibrium condition in the competitive equilibrium is:
W 0 (Me ) =

1 C Ien
·
·
,
σ Me I 1

where we define the modified Ien integral to account for the infrastructure expenditures of the
firm:

σ 1−χ !
Z ∞
γ
M
e
σ
Ien (Me , χ) =   1−χ a −
dFn (a).
γ
Me
M0
M0

With n = 1, we have:
Ie1 (Me , χ) =

σ
·
γ−σ



M0
Me

(1−χ) γ−σ
γ

=

σ
· I1 (Me , χ).
γ

Aggregate profits therefore represent a fraction σ/γ of aggregate revenue after labor costs,
while aggregate infrastructure costs account for the other (γ − σ)/γ. Therefore, aggregate
profits represent a share 1/γ of consumption and aggregate infrastructure costs 1/σ − 1/γ.

82

D.4.2

Spillovers

The market-based social value is now characterized by:



d 1 Ien σ − 1
1
1
+
C −
C
C+
−
dMe σ I1
σ
σ γ

=


Φ(M )

cost of
consumption from
infrastructure
infrastructure


σ−1 0
Ien I10
1
1

1 Ien
1
1 Ien Ien0
+ C0
− C
+
C
σ I1 Ien σ I1
σ I1 I1

C +

σ

σ

−

γ

C 0 − Φ0 (M )M ·


1
− γ1
σ

1 dM
.
M dMe


C

The market-based spillover is therefore:
spillmkt (n) = EIen − EI1 − 1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC ·

I1
γ−σ
I1
+
,
(EC − EM ) ·
γ
Ien
Ien
surplus from
infrastructure costs

where the last term accounts for the surplus from infrastructure creation.
The outcome-based spillover (and market-based spillover under agreement) is:




σ
γ
spillout = −1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC + 1 −
(EC − χ)
.
γ
σ
Using the values of EC and χ, we obtain:
spillout



1
1
= 0,
= −1 + χγ 1 + ν − +
σ γ

(IA.77)

given the formula above for χ. Participation is now a good traded on a competitive market.
Hence the first welfare theorem applies, and there are no outcome-based spillovers.
Now we apply the reasoning from Appendix D.1 to find the condition for convergence when
θ is large. The condition for convergence of EIen is the same as for EIn :
γ(θ + χ) > 1 + χ
⇐⇒

γθ > 1 +

γ

1
ν+ +
1
γ

−1
σ 

σ−1
σ



(IA.78)


1
1
− −1 .
σ γ

As n → ∞, we have that Ien → ∞ and I1 → 0, and therefore, I1 /Ien → 0.
For the high-disagreement market-based spillover we have


σ−1
1
1
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −(σ − 1) · Ew = −
− (σ − 1)χ
−
γ
σ γ


σ−1
1+ν
=−
·
.
γ
1 + ν + 1/γ − 1/σ

(IA.79)

(IA.80)
(IA.81)

Again, Proposition 4 holds. Moreover, |spillmkt (n → ∞)| is decreasing in ν since 1/γ < 1/σ. As
the cost of producing infrastructure becomes steeper, the sensitivity of firm participation to

83

firm creation is smaller, and the market-based spillover is less responsive. In the limit with
ν → ∞, a fixed number of firms produces, and we are back to our baseline spillmkt (n → ∞) =
−(σ − 1)/γ. Finally, |spillmkt (n → ∞)| is increasing in σ.

D.5

Melitz (2003) Model: Participation Costs and Dixit-Stiglitz

We now introduce Dixit-Stiglitz preferences to the above model, as in Melitz (2003).

D.5.1

Setting and Equilibrium

Participating firms. Given Me and M , profits before the infrastructure costs are unchanged from the standard model with decreasing returns to scale:
1
π(a) =
σ



σ
σ−1

1−σ

· C · w1−σ · aσ−1 .

The equilibrium consumption is also unchanged:
C
=
L



γ
γ − (σ − 1)



1
σ−1

1

M σ−1

− γ1

1

Meγ .

The marginal firm has productivity a and spends all of its profit on infrastructure. Therefore,
we have the zero-cutoff-profit condition Φ0 (M ) = π(a), which implies
M

σ−2
ν+ γ1 + σ−1

1 1
=
ϕ0 σ



γ − (σ − 1)
γ

 σ−2

σ−1

1

L · Meγ ,

where we use the fact that a = (Me /M )1/γ . In Section D.2, we specified an exogenous set of
producing firms M = Meχ /M0χ−1 . This arises endogenously through our cost of infrastructure
with


1
1 σ − 2 −1
χ=
ν+ +
,
γ
γ σ−1

−1

 σ−2 ! ν+ γ1 + σ−2
σ−1
1 1 γ − (σ − 1) σ−1
M01−χ =
L
,
ϕ0 σ
γ
σ−2
where the exponent satisfies χ ≤ 1 if and only if ν + σ−1
∈ (−∞, −1/γ) ∪ [0, ∞). Otherwise, all
firms participate as Me grows to infinity.
Finally, we derive the elasticity EC :


1
1
1
1
1+ν
−
= ·
= χ · (1 + ν).
EC = + χ
γ
σ−1 γ
γ 1 + ν + 1/γ − 1/(σ − 1)

Equilibrium. The equilibrium condition in the competitive equilibrium is:
W 0 (Me ) =

1 C Ien
·
·
.
σ Me I 1

84

Aggregate profits represent a fraction (σ − 1)/γ of aggregate revenue after labor costs, and
aggregate infrastructure costs account for the other (γ − (σ − 1))/γ. Therefore, aggregate
profits represent a share (σ − 1)/(σγ) of consumption and aggregate infrastructure costs (γ −
(σ − 1))/(σγ).

D.5.2

Spillovers

The market-based social value is:




d 1 Ien σ − 1
γ − (σ − 1)
+
C − Φ(M )
C
C+
dMe σ I1
σ
σγ


1 Ien Ien0
1 0 Ien
1 Ien I10
σ−1 0
1 dM
γ − (σ − 1)
=
+ C
− C
+
C 0 − Φ0 (M )M
.
C
C +
σ I1 Ien σ I1
σ I1 I1
σ
σγ
M dMe
The market-based spillover is therefore:





σ−1
I1
.
− 1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC + 1 −
(EC − χ)
γ
Ien

(IA.82)

The outcome-based spillover (and market-based spillover under agreement) is:




σ−1
γ
spillout = −1 + EC + (σ − 1)EC + 1 −
(EC − χ)
γ
σ−1
1+ν
1
·
.
=
σ − 1 1 + ν + 1/γ − 1/(σ − 1)

(IA.83)

spillmkt (n) = EIen − EI1

(IA.84)

Now we apply the reasoning from Section D.1 to find the condition for convergence when
θ is large. The condition for convergence of EIen is the same as for EIn :


⇐⇒


γ
γ(θ + χ) > 1 + χ
−1
σ−1


1
1
1
− −1 .
γθ > 1 +
σ−1 γ
ν + γ1 + σ−2
σ−1

As n → ∞, we have Ien → ∞ and I1 → 0, and therefore I1 /Ien → 0.
For the high-disagreement market-based spillover we have


1+ν
σ−2
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −(σ − 1) · Ew + EC = −
·
.
γ
1 + ν + 1/γ − 1/(σ − 1)

(IA.85)
(IA.86)

(IA.87)

When ν → ∞, there is a fixed supply of infrastructure and thus a fixed number of firms, which
implies:
1
,
σ−1
σ−2
spillmkt (n → ∞) = −
.
γ
spillout =

85

E

Data Appendix

E.1

Data Construction Details

Bubbles. Following Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018), we identify bubbles as episodes
in which stock prices of an industry have increased over 100% in terms of both raw and net-ofmarket returns over the previous two years, followed by a decrease in absolute terms of 40%
or more. Industries are classified according to the Fama-French 49-industry scheme, and the
data begin in 1928.

Value of Innovation. We use the stock market value of patents at the patent level and at
the firm level directly from Kogan et al. (2017), as well as the number of citations that accrue
to a patent.42

Compustat Segments. We merge the Compustat funda file with the Compustat segments file. We estimate the number of segments with different industry codes. The Compustat segments file provides both a six- and a four-digit industry code, which gives two measures
of the number of different types of industries within a public firm.

Value of Spillovers. We obtain information on the quantity of competition spillovers
(variable spillsic) as well as technological spillovers (variable spilltec) from the replication
files in Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (2013). The exposure to spillovers from product market, spillsic, is defined as the correlation of the sales across two firms’ Compustat
segments. If we consider the vector of average sales share across each industry for a given
firm i, Si , product market
p proximity
between firm i and j is defined by the uncentered corq
0
0
0
relation: SICij = Si Sj /
Si Si Sj Sj . The product market spillover is the average stock of
R&D that is in the product market proximity of firm i:
X
spillsici =
SIC ij Gj ,
j6=i

where Gj is the stock of R&D for firm j. The exposure to knowledge spillovers is constructed
the same way, where we define for firm i a vector of share of patents across technology classes
from the USPTO as Ti . q
The uncentered
correlation of technology between firm i and j is:

p
0
0
0
TECH ij = Ti Tj /
Ti Ti Tj Tj . The product market spillover is the average stock of R&D
that is in the product market proximity of firm i:
X
spilltechi =
TECH ij Gj .
j6=i

To look at the effect of spillovers, we use sales item from Compustat funda file and Tobin’s
q (market-to-book ratio) from the CRSP-Compustat merged file.

42

We thank Dimitris Papanikolaou for graciously sharing his data with us.

86

E.2

Supplementary Tables
Table IA.1
Innovation in Times of Bubbles
Patents (#)
(1)

Bubble

1.385∗∗
(0.578)

Lagged Citations

0.982∗∗∗
(0.026)

Lagged Log Citations

Log Patents (#)
(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

0.148∗∗∗
(0.056)

0.154∗∗
(0.066)

0.169∗∗∗
(0.063)

0.178∗∗
(0.075)

0.824∗∗∗
(0.008)

0.795∗∗∗
(0.008)

0.827∗∗∗
(0.007)

0.799∗∗∗
(0.008)

Fixed Effects

C

–

C

Y

C, Y

Observations
R2

106,176
0.91

106,278
0.67

106,176
0.68

106,278
0.68

106,176
0.68

Note: Table IA.1 presents panel regressions of the quantity of innovation, measured by the number of patents issued at the
USPTO three-digit class level, on a dummy from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) that captures whether the firm is in
an industry that is in a bubble or not. We control for the lagged number of patents for column one and lagged logarithm for
columns two to five. Depending on the specification, we include fixed effects for the patent class level C and patent grant-year
Y . Standard errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%,
and 1% levels, respectively.

87

Table IA.2
Private Value of Innovation in Bubbles
Patent Level
(1)
Bubble Dummy

0.317∗∗∗
(0.094)

Firm Level

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

0.289∗∗∗
(0.090)

0.277∗∗∗
(0.083)

0.514∗∗∗
(0.114)

0.429∗∗∗
(0.123)

0.431∗∗∗
(0.080)

0.543∗∗∗
(0.026)

Log Market Cap
(lagged)

0.625∗∗∗
(0.020)

Fixed Effects
Interaction

Y, F
NA

Y, F
Ind x Cite

Y, F
Ind x Cite

Y, F
NA

Y, F
Ind x Cite

Y, F
Ind x Cite

Observations
R2

1,171,806
0.68

1,118,675
0.69

1,116,740
0.74

47,886
0.89

47,886
0.94

47,484
0.96

Note: Table IA.2 presents panel regressions of the value of innovation, as measured in Kogan et al. (2017) at the patent
firm levels, on a dummy from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) that captures whether the firm is in an industry that is
in a bubble or not. We control for the forward-looking number of citations generated by a patent (or firm) from Kogan et al.
(2017) and the lagged market capitalization of the firm. We include firm fixed effects F and patent grant year fixed effects
Y . Depending on the specification, we also use industry fixed effects (from the Fama-French 49-industry classification)
interacted with the log number of forward-looking citations to allow for different slopes in the relation between private
valuation and the patent quality across industries. Standard errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *,
**, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

88

Table IA.3
Diversity and Private Value of Innovation in Bubbles
Patent Level
(1)
Bubble x Segments
(NAICS 6 digits)
Bubble
Segments
(NAICS 6 digits)
Log Citations
(forward looking)
Log Market Cap
(lagged)

Firm Level

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

−0.562∗∗∗
(0.178)

−0.550∗∗∗
(0.175)

−0.488∗∗∗
(0.164)

−0.388∗∗
(0.155)

−0.370∗∗∗
(0.094)

−0.295∗∗∗
(0.072)

1.456∗∗∗
(0.232)
0.122
(0.096)

1.425∗∗∗
(0.227)
0.122
(0.095)
0.049∗∗∗
(0.010)

1.329∗∗∗
(0.235)
0.112
(0.101)
0.047∗∗∗
(0.009)
0.156∗∗∗
(0.042)

1.459∗∗∗
(0.317)
0.010
(0.044)

1.389∗∗∗
(0.342)
−0.031
(0.048)
0.047∗∗∗
(0.009)

1.167∗∗∗
(0.289)
−0.026
(0.041)
0.047∗∗∗
(0.009)
0.287∗∗∗
(0.046)

Fixed Effects

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Y, F

Observations
R2

180,636
0.71

180,636
0.71

177,911
0.72

10,426
0.88

10,426
0.93

10,256
0.94

Note: Table IA.3 presents panel regressions of the value of innovation, as measured in Kogan et al. (2017) at the patent and
firm levels, on a bubble dummy interacted with the number of industries spanned by the different segments of the parent
firm. The bubble dummy is from Greenwood, Shleifer, and You (2018) and captures whether the firm is in an industry that
is in a bubble or not. Compustat segments are measured at the six-digit NAICS code level from the Compustat segments
file. We control for the forward-looking number of citations generated by a patent (or firm) from Kogan et al. (2017) and
the lagged market capitalization of the firm. We also include fixed effects for firm F and patent grant year Y . Standard
errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,
respectively.

89

90

CxY
1,801,301
0.20

Fixed Effects

Observations
R2

1,801,301
0.71

CxY

X
—

1,801,301
0.79

CxY

X
X

0.054∗∗∗
(0.005)

(3)

1,801,301
0.93

CxY, F

X
X

0.013∗∗∗
(0.001)

(4)

1,801,301
0.95

CxY, FxY

X
—

0.004∗∗∗
(0.001)

(5)

1,801,301
0.82

Y, F

—
—

0.023∗∗∗
(0.004)

(6)

1,801,301
0.91

Y, F

X
—

0.019∗∗∗
(0.003)

(7)

1,801,301
0.92

Y, F

X
X

0.012∗∗∗
(0.002)

(8)

Firm-Year Fixed Effects

Note: Table IA.4 presents panel regressions of the stock market value of innovation on the logarithm of the number of citations received by a patent until the end of the
sample in 2010. Depending on the specification, we control for the logarithm of firm size and volatility. Depending on the specification, we include patent grant times year
fixed effects, CxY, year fixed effects F, and firm fixed effects Y. Columns (1) to (5) reproduce Table II from Kogan et al. (2017), while columns (6) to (8) only include year and
firm fixed effects to be comparable with the tables above. Standard errors clustered at the grant-year level are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%,
5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

—
—

0.099∗∗∗
(0.010)

0.174∗∗∗
(0.017)

Controls
Firm Size
Volatility

Log Citations

(2)

(1)

Table II from Kogan et al. (2017)

Table IA.4
Forward Citations and Patent Market Values