The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
An Alternative Measure of Core Inflation: The Trimmed Persistence PCE Price Index WP 23-10 John O'Trakoun Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond An Alternative Measure of Core Inflation: The Trimmed Persistence PCE Price Index John O'Trakoun 1 October 20, 2023 ABSTRACT I introduce the "trimmed persistence PCE," a new measure of core inflation in which component prices are weighted according to the time-varying persistence of their price changes. The components of trimmed persistence personal consumption expenditures (PCE) display less tendency to mechanically pass-through the level of the prior period's inflation to the current period; thus, the impact of the current stance of monetary policy and real economic factors are more likely to be visible in recent trimmed persistence inflation compared to headline inflation. Trimmed persistence inflation performs comparably to existing popular measures of core inflation in terms of volatility and relationship with economic slack. Model selection procedures confirm trimmed persistence PCE contributes additional information to inflation forecasting models when stacked against other popular measures of core inflation. Applying the new index in a Taylor rule analysis suggests the Fed's aggressive path of federal funds rate hikes during the pandemic may have achieved appropriately restrictive levels by the fourth quarter of 2022, clearing the way for more measured policy adjustment thereafter as risks of policy overshooting became more salient. Keywords: inflation, core inflation, inflation persistence, time-varying, inflation dynamics JEL Classification Numbers: C22, E31, E37, E52 I. Introduction Following the shock of the COVID-19 pandemic and the subsequent fiscal and monetary policy response, inflation in the United States reached multidecade highs. As shown in Figure 1, inflation as measured by year-over-year growth in the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index rose to 7.12 percent in June 2022, which was the highest rate since December 1981. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, PO Box 27622, Richmond, VA 23261. Email: John.OTrakoun@rich.frb.org. The views and opinions expressed in this article belong to the author and do not reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. 1 1 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% -2% Jan-60 Jan-62 Jan-64 Jan-66 Jan-68 Jan-70 Jan-72 Jan-74 Jan-76 Jan-78 Jan-80 Jan-82 Jan-84 Jan-86 Jan-88 Jan-90 Jan-92 Jan-94 Jan-96 Jan-98 Jan-00 Jan-02 Jan-04 Jan-06 Jan-08 Jan-10 Jan-12 Jan-14 Jan-16 Jan-18 Jan-20 Jan-22 0% -4% Figure 1 Personal consumption expenditure (PCE) price inflation, 1:1960-5:2023. Gray shading indicates recessions. Interpreting the rise in inflation was a major challenge for policymakers on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), who referred to a number of different inflation metrics when they communicated to the public. In parsing the inflation data during the pandemic, one challenge that became particularly salient was judging the extent to which disaggregated pricing data contained useful information about the trajectory of future inflation. As shown in Figure 2, the period of elevated inflation in PCE ex food and energy (PCExFE) prices beginning in 2021 initially manifested as an outsized contribution of used vehicle prices to month-over-month growth rates, before broadening in scope. In early diagnoses of rising inflation in 2021, policymakers and academics debated whether the used vehicle price increase represented a transitory relative price change or the initial manifestation of inflation resulting from a broader imbalance between aggregate supply and demand. 2 As an example of one such public debate, Nobel laureate Paul Krugman stated on Twitter, "Inflation [is] somewhat higher than expected, but I don't think we should get too worked up about the prices of used cars." (https://twitter.com/paulkrugman/status/1392458554578247685, 12 May 2021, accessed 14 Dec. 2022). Former Council of Economic Advisers chair Jason Furman expressed a contrary view, stating, "You want to be cautious about taking different sectors out of your price basket in assessing inflation trends ... If people have a lot more money to spend and car prices did not go up then maybe they would have spent even more on other stuff and inflation would have been similar in aggregate, just spread out differently." (https://twitter.com/jasonfurman/status/1458886069093556229, 11 Nov. 2021, accessed 14 Dec. 2022). 2 2 Month-Over-Month Core PCE Growth (Annualized) 10 8 6 4 2 Jul-22 Aug-22 Jun-22 Apr-22 May-22 Mar-22 Jan-22 Feb-22 Dec-21 Nov-21 Oct-21 Sep-21 Aug-21 Jul-21 Jun-21 Apr-21 May-21 Mar-21 Jan-21 Feb-21 Dec-20 Oct-20 Nov-20 Sep-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Jun-20 May-20 Apr-20 Feb-20 -4 Mar-20 -2 Jan-20 0 -6 -8 New vehicles Rent+OER Used vehicles Bars and restaurants Hotels and Motels Air transportation Admissions Everything else Core PCE inflation (mom % ann.) Figure 2 PCExFE inflation by selected expenditure categories, 2020-2022 The resulting debate renewed public interest in measuring inflation and in the differences between popular price indices. The Economist calculated an alternative core price index, commenting on the popular PCExFE and trimmed mean PCE inflation measures that "both of these methods have flaws. Changes in food and energy prices are not necessarily unusually large or short-lived. And trimmed means' weighting schemes are plagued by abrupt cliffs." (The Economist, 2021) Leigh et al. (2021) distinguish core price indices according to "fixed-exclusion" and "outlier-exclusion" categories based on whether the indices exclude signals from fixed categories of consumer expenditure (i.e., food and energy, or “sticky price” categories), or whether large price changes are dropped from the index. During the COVID-19 pandemic, they find PCExFE performed poorly for most of 2020-2021 because large industry price changes occurred outside of the food and energy sectors. Other fixedexclusion measures such as the Atlanta Fed sticky consumer price index (CPI) omitted more industries and fared better than PCExFE during the pandemic. However, outlier-exclusion measures such as the trimmed mean and median PCE inflation measures displayed superior performance on the basis of volatility and negative comovement with economic slack. In this article, I propose an alternate measure of core inflation called the “trimmed persistence PCE.” The trimmed persistence PCE price index is neither a fixed-exclusion measure, as it does not omit changes in a pre-specified group of expenditure components, nor an outlier-exclusion measure, as it 3 does not necessarily omit all large component-level price changes. Similar to the popular trimmed mean and median measures of PCE inflation, trimmed persistence PCE takes inflation signals from a subset of the PCE expenditure basket. But in contrast to existing measures which exclude expenditure categories based on realized monthly price changes, trimmed persistence inflation excludes price categories based on the time-varying persistence of price changes in each category. Large price changes for a spending category are omitted from the trimmed persistence PCE index only when they cause the category's estimated time-varying persistence coefficient to cross an optimal inclusion threshold. Trimming the relatively persistent components, which are more variable, reduces the volatility of trimmed persistence inflation compared to headline PCE inflation. In addition, the trimming process results in an inflation measure that is less prone to mechanically inheriting the prior period's level of inflation and is arguably more responsive to real-time changes in real economic and monetary policy factors determining inflation. During the post-COVID-19 recession inflationary episode, trimmed persistence PCE displayed less volatility than headline PCE inflation with a standard deviation of monthly annualized inflation prints falling between those of median PCE and PCExFE. However, over a longer sample beginning in 1988, trimmed persistence was more volatile than trimmed mean and median PCE. Nevertheless, the benefit of this approach is that it preserves potentially useful signals about changes in inflation dynamics which might have been dropped from the trimmed mean and median PCE. For example, in times of accelerating inflation, it may be particularly important to retain such signals from outlying relative price changes if a high-inflation regime initially manifests as large price changes in a smaller number of categories before becoming more broad-based across multiple categories. Trimmed persistence inflation also performs comparably to other core inflation measures in displaying a negative relationship with economic slack, with a correlation coefficient falling between that of PCExFE and median PCE inflation following the pandemic recession. Despite the visual similarity between twelve-month changes in trimmed persistence PCE and PCExFE, as well as the similarity of the two measures in terms of the volatility of monthly annualized inflation and inverse comovement with resource slack, trimmed persistence PCE contributes a distinct perspective about the trajectory of inflation and implications for policy. Model selection procedures applied to statistical inflation forecasting models that pit trimmed persistence inflation against other core inflation measures show evidence that trimmed persistence inflation contributes to improved forecast accuracy for inflation at horizons up to three years ahead. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section II discusses how this article fits into the existing literature on inflation. Section III discusses the basic intuition and motivation behind the trimmed persistence PCE. Section IV describes the methodology underlying the construction of the index, along with data sources. Section V examines the behavior of trimmed persistence PCE inflation during the pandemic with an application to policy, and Section VI offers concluding thoughts. 4 II. Literature Review This paper is related to studies exploring time-variation in inflation dynamics. In an early contribution, Barsky (1987) presents evidence that inflation persistence evolved from a white noise process in the pre-World War I years to a highly persistent, nonstationary ARIMA process after 1960. Cogley and Sargent (2002) use a time-varying parameter Bayesian vector autoregression (TVP-VAR) model to characterize inflation as weakly persistent in the 1960s and strongly persistent in the 1970s, with persistence declining again in the 1990s. Williams (2006) studies time variation in inflation persistence by estimating Phillips curves over different samples of historical data, finding some evidence that inflation has become less persistent since the 1990s. Stock and Watson (2007) fit an unobserved components model with stochastic volatility on inflation data finding further evidence of time variation in inflation persistence. Beechey and Österholm (2012) find that inflation persistence declined rapidly during the Volcker and Greenspan tenures compared to the experience of the 1970s. In contrast, Pivetta and Reis (2007) find very wide Bayesian credible sets associated with estimated persistence coefficients and conclude that inflation persistence has essentially been unchanged between 1965 and 2001. Cogley et al. (2010) document inflation persistence increasing during the Great Inflation and falling after the Volcker disinflation. In this article—unlike these studies which focus on aggregate inflation measures—I study time-varying dynamics of the price indices of disaggregated expenditure categories. This article is most closely related to those which focus on extracting core inflation from disaggregated inflation data. Bryan and Pike (1991) examine the CPI, finding that median price changes give a superior signal of underlying inflation compared to headline CPI because the median purges noise from transitory relative price movements. Bryan et al. (1997) introduce a version of the trimmed mean CPI. In a crosscountry study, Brischetto and Richards (2006) find that trimmed mean CPI inflation outperforms headline and exclusion-based core CPI inflation (such as CPIxFE inflation) at separating inflation signals from noise, and in terms of near-term predictive ability. Bryan and Meyer (2010) group CPI components into sticky and flexible categories based on the speed at which prices adjust, calculating a sticky-price CPI which displays superior inflation forecasting performance relative to the headline CPI measure. Meyer et al. (2013) and Meyer and Venkatu (2014) find that the median CPI outperforms other trimmed mean inflation measures in predicting CPI inflation, and that it also outperforms PCExFE in predicting PCE inflation. Other contributions, including this paper, focus on the PCE price index which is the Fed's preferred measure of consumer prices. Dolmas (2005) introduces the trimmed mean PCE measure, which strips out expenditure components associated with the largest absolute monthly price changes. In a related study, Dolmas and Koenig (2019) explain that while trimmed mean PCE does not dominate PCExFE in terms of forecasting, it is more successful at filtering out transitory variation from the headline PCE inflation number. Carroll and Verbrugge (2019) calculate median PCE inflation rates and find that these measures perform comparably to other trend inflation estimators such as trimmed mean PCE. Mahedy and Shapiro (2017) sort PCE spending categories into procyclical and acyclical groups according to their sensitivity to the unemployment gap, developing alternative measures of cyclical and acyclical core inflation. Stock and Watson (2019) introduce a similar measure of cyclically sensitive inflation, which reweights seventeen broad components of PCE inflation according to their correlation with a broad 5 measure of economic slack estimated during the 1984-2019 period. Shapiro (2022) classifies PCE components into supply- and demand-driven groups based on the comovement of price and quantities of each component in response to unexpected shocks. The motivation of the trimmed persistence PCE index is similar to that of Stock and Watson (2016) who use disaggregated data on sectoral inflation to construct indices of core inflation that feature timevarying sectoral weights. These authors use a multivariate unobserved-components stochastic volatility model to recover common volatilities and trends, sector-specific volatilities and trends, sector-specific factor loadings, common and sector-specific outlier factors, and the aggregate inflation trend from quarterly inflation series of seventeen components of the PCE price index. The model is computationally intensive, and the authors note that extending the approach to more finely disaggregated data presents substantial challenges due to instability in measurement. In a more recent contribution, Almuzara and Sbordone (2022) introduce the Multivariate Core Trend, extending the Stock and Watson (2016) approach to monthly data from seventeen sectors, although their MCT index ultimately excludes the food and energy sectors. In contrast to these authors, I use a simpler approach on even more granular monthly data, using 180 components of PCE. My approach allows a more disaggregated level analysis of the contributors to core inflation while preserving the use of monthly data to provide higher-frequency information to policymakers making decisions in real time. As mentioned in the previous section and shown in Table 1, these alternative measures of core inflation can largely be classified into fixed-exclusion and outlier-exclusion categories. In contrast, the trimmed persistence PCE measure introduced in the next section is neither a fixed- nor outlier-exclusion measure. Fixed-exclusion CPIbased CPI ex food and energy, Atlanta Fed Sticky CPI PCEbased PCE ex food and energy, San Francisco Fed cyclical and acyclical core PCE, San Franscisco Fed supply- and demand-driven PCE, Stock and Watson (2019) cyclically sensitive inflation, Almuzara and Sbordone (2022) Multivariate Core Trend Outlier-exclusion Cleveland Fed 16 percent trimmed mean CPI, Cleveland Fed median CPI Dallas Fed trimmed mean PCE, Cleveland Fed median PCE Neither fixed- nor outlierexclusion Stock and Watson (2016) unobserved components stochastic volatility trend inflation, Trimmed persistence PCE Table 1 Classification of core inflation measures III. Motivation How is time-varying inflation persistence related to identifying underlying “core” inflation? To motivate the basic intuition behind the trimmed persistence PCE index, consider the AR(1) process: 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝛼𝛼(1 − 𝜌𝜌) + 𝜌𝜌𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡 , (1) 6 where ϵt ∼ IID(0, σ2𝜖𝜖 ). We assume that the random variable 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 has some degree of persistence, so that 0 ≤ 𝜌𝜌 ≤ 1. 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 is covariance-stationary if 𝜌𝜌 < 1, which then implies 𝐸𝐸(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 ) = 𝛼𝛼. Importantly, the variance of 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 is 𝜎𝜎𝜋𝜋2 = 𝜎𝜎𝜖𝜖2 , 1−𝜌𝜌2 which is increasing in 𝜌𝜌. If 𝜌𝜌 = 1, then setting 𝛼𝛼 = 0 to prevent 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 from trending, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 follows the driftless random walk process: 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡 . (2) 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝜋𝜋0 + ∑𝑡𝑡−1 𝑗𝑗=0 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡−𝑗𝑗 . (3) Given initial condition 𝜋𝜋0 , by repeated substitution of lagged values into (2) it can be shown that 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 follows the moving average representation: Thus, if 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 follows a random walk, 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡−𝑗𝑗 shocks have a permanent effect on 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 . Furthermore, the variance of 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 does not exist: initializing 𝜋𝜋0 = 0, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡 + 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡−1 + ⋯ + 𝜖𝜖1 ∼ 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼(0, 𝑡𝑡𝜎𝜎𝜖𝜖2 ). In other words, the variance of 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 grows linearly with 𝑡𝑡, and as 𝑡𝑡 increases without bound, so too will the variance of 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 . This has implications for building a price index. Suppose our goal is to construct a price index that smooths out the impact of its most volatile underlying components. If we can estimate an AR(1) process for the price index of each component 𝑖𝑖, we can assess its volatility 𝜎𝜎𝜋𝜋2𝑖𝑖 by judging how far 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖 is from 1: in other words, how far away the price index for 𝑖𝑖 is from being a random walk. Giving greater weight to components with lower estimated persistence would reduce the variance of the aggregated index compared to headline PCE which is essentially weighted by expenditure shares. An index constructed in this manner would arguably better reflect changes in present conditions versus echoes of the past, compared to the headline index. The higher 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖 , the more that current inflation 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 will mechanically inherit its level from the prior period 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 , and the less visible that current period changes in other determinants of inflation, such as cumulative policy effects and real economic activity as of date 𝑡𝑡, will be. As a further refinement to the index, we can take into account evidence of time-varying inflation dynamics discussed in the prior section by allowing 𝜌𝜌 and 𝛼𝛼 to vary over time. This entails estimating a time-varying parameter version of Equation (1) as follows: 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝛼𝛼𝑡𝑡 (1 − 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 ) + 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝜖𝜖𝑡𝑡 . The basic idea that the variance of 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 is increasing in 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 continues to hold with some slight modifications. (4) 7 A. Determining inclusion criteria Having established that the AR(1) persistence coefficient is a potentially useful criterion for including category-level prices in a trimmed persistence core PCE price index, the question remains: how persistent is too persistent? In other words, at what levels of |𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 | should we discount the signals from 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ? I draw on Dolmas (2005), who outlines a trimming process that minimizes the discrepancy between the inflation rate captured by a newly constructed price index and three proxies for core inflation. The first proxy of core inflation is a centered thirty-six-month moving average of monthly inflation rates, first proposed by Bryan et al. (1997). The second proxy is obtained by applying a Christiano-Fitzgerald bandpass filter to monthly headline inflation; Dolmas (2005) describes this measure, which discards high-frequency movements in PCE inflation lasting less than thirty-nine months, as the inflation rate that the FOMC appears to have responded to in setting monetary policy. The last proxy represents an inflation signal that contains information about future inflation and is calculated as a moving average of inflation in the current month and twenty-four coming months. B. The optimal trimming problem The optimal trimming problem chooses the threshold 𝜌𝜌∗ to minimize the root mean square deviation 𝑇𝑇 ���} between trimmed persistence inflation and the proxy of core inflation. Letting { 𝜋𝜋 𝑡𝑡 𝑡𝑡=1 denote the proxy ∗ of core inflation, the optimal threshold 𝜌𝜌 solves: ∗) (𝜌𝜌 𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑛𝑛𝜌𝜌∗ �𝑇𝑇 −1 ∑𝑇𝑇𝑡𝑡=1 �𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 2 − ���� 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 . (5) Table 2 shows the optimal trim for each core proxy. The selection process chooses an optimal threshold value of 𝜌𝜌∗ = 0.23 for all three proxies. Core proxy 36-month centered moving average Trend correlated with Fed Funds Rate Forward-looking moving average Average across alternative proxies Table 2 Optimal trimming for various core proxies IV. Optimal threshold ρ* 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 Data and methodology A. Data Data on the underlying components of the PCE price index are retrieved from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and accessed via Haver Analytics. The data are also publicly available on the BEA's website in the Underlying Detail tables 2.4.4U and 2.4.5U for chain-type price indices and nominal 8 personal consumption expenditures (used to calculate monthly PCE shares) by detailed type of product, respectively. When choosing the degree of disaggregation, there is a trade-off between sample length and finer granularity. For the purposes of this study, I include 180 subcategories of PCE consumption whose expenditure weights add up to 100 percent of the PCE consumption basket. This level of aggregation is very similar to that used in the trimmed mean PCE index. While the many component price indices have data starting as early as January 1959, the price indices for digital videos, personal computers and tablets, and computer software are only available post-1977. Furthermore, the price indices for personal computers and computer software were constant from January 1977-March 1979; this further restricts the sample for estimating time-varying persistence and delays the starting date for the trimmed persistence PCE until 1979. Further information on the components is presented in Appendix Table 1. B. Estimating time-varying persistence For each of the 180 components of the PCE consumption basket, I fit a time-varying AR(1) model to the month-over-month annualized change in the component's corresponding price index similar to Equation (4): 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼�𝚤𝚤𝚤𝚤 + 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝜖𝜖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 , (6) where 𝑖𝑖 is the index for component 𝑖𝑖 and 𝛼𝛼�𝚤𝚤𝚤𝚤 ≡ 𝛼𝛼𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 (1 − 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ) is the time-varying intercept term. Our main object of interest is the 𝑇𝑇 × 𝑖𝑖 matrix 𝒫𝒫 of time-varying AR1 persistence parameters 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 . Equation (6) is estimated via a generalized additive model approach (Hastie & Tibshirani, 1986; Hastie & Tibshirani, Generalized Additive Models, 1990; Wood, 2017), which models price growth as a sum of smooth basis functions of covariates (i.e., time and lagged price changes). For the underlying basis functions, I use twenty thin plate regression splines, an approximation of optimal thin plate spline smoothers which, unlike some other basis function alternatives, allow bases to represent smooths of multiple predictor variables and avoid subjectivity in choosing knot locations. The assumption that changes in the dynamics of inflation happen smoothly over time, rather than suddenly and abruptly, is key to the construction of the trimmed persistence PCE index and is built into the methodology. It allows for large relative price changes to potentially be retained in the computation of the index, so long as these changes do not push the estimated AR(1) coefficient in the current period above the optimal inclusion threshold. As discussed in Wood (2017), the prior belief that the “truth” is more likely to be smooth rather than volatile and wiggly can also be formalized through a Bayesian interpretation of the smoothing penalty. However, there may exist real-world scenarios where inflation dynamics are highly unstable, such as in episodes of hyperinflation observed in some emerging markets, where this underlying assumption of the methodology is invalid. 9 To illustrate an application of this methodology, Figure 3 plots estimates of 𝛼𝛼�𝑡𝑡 ≡ 𝛼𝛼𝑡𝑡 (1 − 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 ) and 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 when Equation (4) is fitted to monthly annualized PCE inflation from January 1959 through August 2023; the shaded gray region indicates the 95 percent Bayesian credible sets associated with each estimate. As shown in the first panel, during the COVID-19-related inflationary episode, the estimated time-varying intercept sharply increased, while the second panel suggests a decline in the persistence of headline PCE inflation after 2020. (a) Time-varying intercept 𝛼𝛼 �𝑡𝑡 10 (b) Time-varying AR1 coefficient 𝜌𝜌𝑡𝑡 Figure 3 Time-varying coefficient estimates of fitted AR(1) model of month-over-month annualized headline PCE inflation, January 1959-August 2023 C. Building the index Following Wolman and Ding (2005), I construct the trimmed persistence PCE price index as an expenditure-share weighted average of the rates of change of component price indices. 𝑁𝑁 Specifically, let �𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 , 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 �𝑖𝑖=1 denote a set of prices and real quantities for 𝑁𝑁 expenditure categories that make up the PCE price index at time 𝑡𝑡. The growth rate of the PCE price index 𝑝𝑝𝑡𝑡 between 𝑡𝑡 + 1 and 𝑡𝑡 is given by the Fisher ideal index formula: 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = 𝑝𝑝𝑡𝑡+1 𝑝𝑝𝑡𝑡 ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 . ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 = � (7) This can be rewritten as: 11 𝑁𝑁 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 = ��∑𝑁𝑁 𝑖𝑖=1 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡−1 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ��∑𝑖𝑖=1 𝜃𝜃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 �, (8) where 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 is the rate of price change for category 𝑖𝑖 from period 𝑡𝑡 − 1 to period 𝑡𝑡, and 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ≡ 𝜃𝜃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ≡ 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝑁𝑁 ∑𝑗𝑗=1 𝑥𝑥𝑗𝑗,𝑡𝑡 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ⁄𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ∑𝑁𝑁 𝑗𝑗=1(𝑥𝑥𝑗𝑗,𝑡𝑡 ⁄𝜋𝜋𝑗𝑗,𝑡𝑡 ) (9) (10) for 𝑖𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑁𝑁, with 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 ≡ 𝑃𝑃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 × 𝑄𝑄𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 referring to period 𝑡𝑡 dollar expenditures on category 𝑖𝑖. In equation (8), both objects in square brackets are weighted averages of the rates of price change for each expenditure category. The weights 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡−1 are expenditure weights for category 𝑖𝑖 in period 𝑡𝑡 − 1, while the weights 𝜃𝜃𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 are hypothetical expenditure shares that combine period 𝑡𝑡 real quantities with period 𝑡𝑡 − 1 prices. PCE inflation 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 is the geometric average of the two weighted averages. From here, I employ a further approximation that aggregates prices for each expenditure category using a Divisia index. As described in Ding and Wolman (2005), the Divisia index is a simpler calculation that gives a good approximation of the true PCE inflation rate, and it is obtained by using the expenditure share of component 𝑖𝑖 at time 𝑡𝑡, 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 , as the weight for the price change of component 𝑖𝑖 between 𝑡𝑡 and 𝑡𝑡 + 1: 𝐷𝐷 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1 = ∑𝑖𝑖 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 . (11) As described in Section III.B, only a subset of PCE expenditure components whose estimated AR(1) coefficients 𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 fall below the optimal inclusion threshold 𝜌𝜌∗ will be included in the trimmed persistence PCE at time 𝑡𝑡. The weight for component 𝑖𝑖 in the trimmed persistence PCE is: 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 = 𝐼𝐼(𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ≤𝜌𝜌∗ )𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝑁𝑁 ∑𝑖𝑖=1 𝐼𝐼(𝜌𝜌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ≤𝜌𝜌∗ )𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 , (12) where 𝐼𝐼(⋅) is equal to one if the argument in parentheses is true, and zero otherwise. Month-overmonth changes in the trimmed persistence PCE are calculated as: 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1 = � 𝜔𝜔𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 . 𝑖𝑖 (13) 12 The level of the trimmed persistence PCE, which is used to calculate year-over-year inflation rates, is computed by setting the period preceding the first 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 equal to 100, and cumulatively applying the month-over-month growth rates. The composition of the trimmed persistence PCE index thus changes over time as shown in Figure 4. During the COVID-19 inflation episode, the number of expenditure components included in the index declined from 128 in December 2019 to 98 as of August 2023, as the estimated persistence of many inflation components rose above the inclusion threshold. The share of PCE expenditure included in the index, plotted on the right axis, declined from 60.1 percent in December 2019 to 51.1 percent in August 2023. Components Included in Trimmed Persistence PCE 150 0.8 0.75 140 0.7 130 0.65 0.6 120 0.55 110 0.5 100 98 0.45 0.4 Number of components included (left axis) Jun-21 Dec-22 Jun-18 Dec-19 Dec-16 Jun-15 Dec-13 Jun-12 Jun-09 Dec-10 Jun-06 Dec-07 Jun-03 Dec-04 Dec-01 Jun-00 Dec-98 Jun-97 Jun-94 Dec-95 Jun-91 Dec-92 Dec-89 Jun-88 Dec-86 Jun-85 Jun-82 Dec-83 Jun-79 Dec-80 90 Expenditure share included (right axis) Figure 4 Count and expenditure share of components included in trimmed persistence PCE Figure 5 plots the final result. The first panel of Figure 5 compares month-over-month annualized growth rates of the trimmed persistence PCE index to those of the headline PCE price index. The second panel plots year-over-year inflation rates of the trimmed persistence PCE and headline PCE price indices. 13 -2 Trimmed Persistence PCE Jul-23 Jan-22 Jul-20 Jan-19 Jul-17 Jan-16 Jul-14 Jan-13 Jul-11 Jan-10 Jul-08 Jan-07 Trimmed Persistence PCE Jul-05 Jan-04 Jul-02 Jan-01 Jul-99 Jan-98 Jul-96 Jan-95 Jul-93 Jan-92 Jul-90 Jan-89 Jul-87 Jan-86 Jul-84 Jan-83 Month-over-month (% annualized) Oct-22 Mar-21 Aug-19 Jan-18 Jun-16 Nov-14 Apr-13 Sep-11 Feb-10 Jul-08 Dec-06 May-05 Oct-03 Mar-02 Aug-00 Jan-99 Jun-97 Nov-95 Apr-94 Sep-92 Feb-91 Jul-89 Dec-87 May-86 Oct-84 Mar-83 Aug-81 Jan-80 -5 Jul-81 Jan-80 Year-over-year (%) 20 15 10 5 0 -10 -15 Headline PCE Month-over-month annualized change in headline and trimmed persistence PCE price indices, January 1980-August 2023 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -4 Headline PCE Figure 5 Headline and trimmed persistence PCE inflation, January 1980-August 2023 Year-over-year headline and trimmed persistence PCE inflation rates, January 1980-August 2023 14 V. The post-COVID-19 inflation Figure 6 compares year-over-year trimmed persistence PCE inflation to year-over-year PCExFE, trimmed mean PCE, median PCE, cyclical core PCE inflation, and multivariate core trend inflation. Year-over-year trimmed persistence PCE inflation as of August 2023 was 3.1 percent—1.8 percentage points from its February 2020 level. In comparison, year-over-year PCExFE inflation in August 2023 was 2.2 percentage points from its February 2020 level, while trimmed mean and median inflation were both 1.9 percentage points from their February 2020 reading. 9.00 8.00 Year-over-year (%) 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 PCExFE Trimmed mean PCE Median PCE Cyclical Core PCE Multivariate Core Trend Trimmed Persistence PCE Jan-21 May-22 Sep-19 Jan-17 May-18 Sep-15 May-14 Jan-13 Sep-11 Jan-09 May-10 Sep-07 May-06 Jan-05 Sep-03 Jan-01 May-02 Sep-99 May-98 Jan-97 Sep-95 Jan-93 May-94 Sep-91 May-90 Jan-89 Sep-87 Jan-85 May-86 0.00 Comparison of core inflation proxy measures, 1980-present Figure 6 Trimmed persistence PCE inflation versus other core inflation measures Typically, authors introducing new core inflation measures use their new index to perform some kind of forecasting exercise. These exercises typically take the form of a horse race pitting the new core inflation measure against other alternatives in a forecasting regression, or against some rule of thumb such as a random walk forecast of inflation computed as the average of the previous four quarters of inflation (Atkeson & Ohanian, 2001). I skip this step for two reasons. 15 First, previous authors have found that out-of-sample predictive power is similar across alternative measures of core inflation: Dolmas and Koenig (2019) find that trimmed mean PCE does not dominate PCExFE inflation in terms of forecast performance; Carroll and Verbrugge (2019) find that median PCE inflation performs comparably to other trend inflation estimators such as trimmed mean PCE; and Bryan and Meyer (2010) find similar out-of-sample forecasting accuracy of sticky CPI, core sticky CPI, and CPI ex food and energy. Second, sticking the trimmed persistence PCE in a forecasting model to generate unconditional forecasts of inflation may not be the best use of this measure. If a central bank is credible in its ability to influence the price level, then any forecast for inflation should be conditioned on the forecaster's assumptions about the future path of monetary policy. As evident in the FOMC Summary of Economic Projections from March 2022 (see Figure 7), intelligent people armed with the same information on realized inflation, economic fundamentals, and even inside knowledge of FOMC deliberations might still disagree on the path of inflation if their views of the appropriate future path of policy differ. Figure 7 Distribution of FOMC projections for 2022 full-year core PCE inflation, March 2022 Source: Board of Governors, 16 March 2022. https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20220316.pdf}. Accessed 17 Dec. 2022. Instead, the best use of the trimmed persistence PCE may be to serve as an additional signal about underlying inflationary pressures when incoming inflation readings are mixed. The COVID-19-era inflation spotlighted a number of challenges identifying and interpreting inflation data in an environment of mixed shocks to aggregate demand and supply. Ball et al. (2022) show that narratives explaining the trajectory of underlying inflation can be sensitive to the choice of core inflation metric used. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2022) find that narratives explaining the rise in inflation during the pandemic can also be sensitive to the length of the historical sample used in the supporting empirical analysis. As discussed in Section I, Leigh et al. (2021) find that fixed-exclusion and outlier-exclusion measures of inflation can offer different perspectives on the trajectory of inflation. 16 The trimmed persistence PCE is neither a fixed-exclusion measure, as it does not omit changes in a fixed group of components, nor an outlier-exclusion measure, as it does not necessarily omit all large component-level price changes. This is clearly seen in Table 3, which lists the first ten items of all 180 PCE expenditure categories, sorted in ascending order by month-over-month price change for September 2022. Focusing on these ten categories with the largest monthly annualized price decreases reveals that some of the categories in the top ten, such as window coverings and spectator sports, are retained in the trimmed persistence PCE index whereas they would be excluded from trimmed mean and median PCE. Additionally, the price index for eggs is retained in the index in that month’s trimmed persistence PCE reading, in contrast to PCExFE. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Category Gasoline & Other Motor Fuel Eggs Window Coverings Calculators/Typewriters/Other Info Processing Eqpt Telephone and Related Communication Equipment Spectator Sports Fuel Oil Other Recreational Vehicles Bicycles & Accessories Pleasure Boats Price change (% MoM ann.) -49.92 -42.55 -41.31 -37.49 -37.48 -34.69 -32.34 -30.7 -30.69 -30.69 AR1 coefficient Included? 0.25 No 0.22 Yes -0.17 Yes 0.33 No 0.33 No 0.17 Yes 0.3 No -0.29 No -0.11 Yes -0.29 No Table 3 Top 10 PCE price changes and inclusion in trimmed persistence PCE, in ascending order (Sep. 2022) Because it retains information from a subset of components with large relative price changes, the trimmed persistence PCE displays higher month-to-month volatility compared to other measures of core inflation. From January 1988 through July 2023, the standard deviation of month-over-month annualized changes in trimmed persistence PCE was 1.7, compared to 1.6 for PCE ex food and energy, 1.1 for median PCE, and 1.0 for trimmed mean PCE. However, the relative performance of core inflation measures in terms of volatility can vary depending on the sample window. Figure 8 shows the standard deviation of monthly annualized inflation across various measures of inflation following the pandemic recession (May 2020-July 2023). Over this period, volatility of the trimmed persistence PCE has fallen between that of median PCE and PCExFE, suggesting that trimmed persistence inflation has performed comparably to other measures of core inflation during a period of elevated inflation and uncertainty. 17 Standard Deviation of Monthly Annualized Inflation (May 2020-July 2023) 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Headline PCE Cyclical core PCE Median PCE Trimmed persistence PCE PCExFE PCE core services excluding housing Trimmed mean PCE Multivariate core trend Figure 8 Volatility of monthly annualized inflation, May 2020-July 2023 (standard deviation, percentage points) In terms of the relationship between inflation and economic slack, the trimmed persistence PCE compares favorably against the alternative core inflation measures examined in this article. I follow Leigh et al. (2021), who assess comovement between inflation measures and economic slack as measured by the twelve-month average gap between the unemployment rate and the Congressional Budget Office's estimate of the natural rate. Figure 9 shows the estimated coefficient in a regression of twelve-month inflation against the average unemployment gap following the pandemic recession, with larger absolute magnitudes indicating a greater degree of negative comovement between inflation and slack. Based on this measure, the trimmed persistence PCE displays a similar degree of comovement with slack as median PCE, performing favorably in comparison to trimmed mean and multivariate core trend inflation. 18 Comovement of Inflation and Unemployment Gap (May 2020-July 2023) -0.68 Headline PCE Cyclical core PCE PCExFE Trimmed persistence PCE Median PCE Trimmed mean PCE Mulitvariate core trend -0.66 -0.64 -0.62 -0.60 -0.58 -0.56 -0.54 Figure 9 Comovement of inflation and unemployment gap (May 2020-May 2023) Given the comparability of trimmed persistence inflation to other core inflation proxies in terms of volatility and correlation with economic slack, it would be reasonable to question whether the trimmed persistence PCE contributes any additional information to a forecaster's information set over preexisting core inflation measures. I allow the data to decide, estimating inflation forecasting regression equations of the form: (ℎ) π({𝑡𝑡+ℎ},{𝑡𝑡+ℎ}−12) = α + βπ𝑐𝑐(𝑡𝑡,𝑡𝑡−12) + ϵ𝑡𝑡 , (14) where π({𝑡𝑡+ℎ},{𝑡𝑡+ℎ}−12) represents ℎ-month ahead, year-over-year headline PCE inflation, and π𝑐𝑐(𝑡𝑡,𝑡𝑡−12) represents a vector of core inflation proxies measured as year-over-year inflation rates at month 𝑡𝑡. I look at horizons of ℎ ∈ {6, 12, 18, 24, 30, 36} months ahead. π𝑐𝑐 contains some subset of the core inflation proxies displayed in Figure 9 . I use statistical variable selection procedures to let the data decide which subset of the core inflation measures to retain in equation (14). These are tools designed to simplify models and tackle issues of collinearity that can arise when correlations between regressor variables (i.e., multicollinearity) are high. I consider three such procedures: 1. Forward stepwise regression, which starts from a model with no variables and individually tests each candidate variable according to a model fit criterion, selecting the best variable and repeating the process until no remaining variable results in an improvement in the fit; 19 2. Backward stepwise regression, which starts from a model that contains all candidate predictor variables and tests the deletion of each variable using a model fit criterion, removing the variable that results in the best improvement in the fit criterion and repeating the process until no variable can be deleted without a deterioration in model fit; and 3. LASSO (least absolute shrinkage and selection operator) regression, which selects a subset of known covariates in a model by shrinking coefficients toward and setting some coefficients equal to zero. For the two stepwise regressions, I use the standard choice of Akaike's information criterion (AIC) as a measure of model fit. Results for the model selection procedure are presented in Table 4. Trimmed persistence PCE is retained as a predictor variable in forecasting headline inflation at every horizon across all three model selection algorithms, with the exception of the six-month ahead inflation forecasting model selected via backward stepwise selection. Notably, trimmed persistence inflation is retained under every model selected via LASSO regression, which has been found to outperform stepwise selection procedures in out-of-sample forecast accuracy. 20 Forward stepwise selection Backward stepwise selection LASSO Forecast Horizon Multivariate core PCE, Median PCE, Headline PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE, Cyclical core PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed mean PCE, Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed persistence PCE Multivariate core PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Multivariate core PCE, PCExFE, Headline PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE, Median PCE Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE, Median PCE, Headline PCE, Cyclical core PCE Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE, Trimmed mean PCE, PCExFE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Median PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, Trimmed mean PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Median PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE Headline PCE, PCExFE, Trimmed mean PCE, Cyclical core PCE, Multivariate core PCE, Trimmed persistence PCE 6 12 18 24 30 36 Table 4 Inflation forecasting at various horizons: Model selection results 21 The alternative signal about true core inflation provided by the trimmed persistence PCE may be useful to monetary policymakers assessing the appropriate level of the policy rate through the framework of policy rules such as the Taylor (1993) rule. For example, former Richmond Fed president Jeffrey Lacker and Philadelphia Fed president Charles Plosser argued in 2022 that the Fed should routinely make reference to the implications of systematic monetary policy rules when discussing the likely future path of interest rates (Lacker & Plosser, 2022). The policy prescriptions of such rules can be sensitive to the choice of inflation metric used in the calculation (Dhawan & Jeske, 2007; Mehra & Sawhney, 2010; Garciga, Knotek, & Verbrugge, 2016). During the pandemic inflation, St. Louis Fed president James Bullard suggested using different measures of core inflation, including trimmed mean PCE and PCExFE, along with different calibrations of a Taylor-type rule to derive upper and lower bounds for the recommended level of the federal funds rate (Bullard, 2022). To illustrate this application of the trimmed persistence PCE, I compare policy rule prescriptions obtained from using different measures of inflation in a generalized version of the Taylor rule, described �𝑡𝑡 given by the in the Atlanta Fed's online Taylor Rule Utility (Higgins, 2016). The policy prescription 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑅𝑅 rule is calculated via the formula: �𝑡𝑡 = ρ𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + (1 − ρ)[(𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡∗ + π∗𝑡𝑡 ) + 1.5(π𝑡𝑡 − π∗𝑡𝑡 ) + β𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑝𝑝𝑡𝑡 ], 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑅𝑅 (15) where 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 denotes the fed funds target rate at the end of month 𝑡𝑡, π𝑡𝑡 denotes inflation, π∗𝑡𝑡 denotes the inflation target (set to 2.0 percent), 𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡∗ denotes the natural (real) interest rate (set to 1.0 percent), and 𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑝𝑝𝑡𝑡 is a measure of resource gap in the economy. Various measures of the resource gap are commonly used, but here I use a measure based on the difference between the unemployment rate in month 𝑡𝑡 and the Congressional Budget Office's estimate of the natural rate of unemployment for the corresponding period. ρ in Equation (15) refers to the interest-rate smoothing parameter, which I set to 0.85 in line with the inertial Taylor rule in the Federal Reserve Board's FRB/US model of the U.S. economy, and β refers to the weight on the resource gap which is set to 0.5. Table 5 shows that as of July 2023, the actual federal funds rate (FFR) of 5.375 was within the range of prescribed values obtained by incorporating various core inflation measures into the Taylor rule described in equation (15). However, the Taylor rule prescription under trimmed persistence PCE inflation was on the lower end of the range of prescriptions, suggesting the FFR setting may have been more restrictive than suggested by formulations of the policy rule using other inflation metrics. 22 Inflation Measure Headline PCE PCExFE Trimmed Mean PCE Median PCE Cyclical Core PCE Multivariate Core Trend Trimmed Persistence PCE Actual Fed Funds Rate Taylor Rule Prescription 5.25 5.44 5.43 5.59 6.12 5.12 5.21 5.38 Table 5 Taylor rule prescriptions for fed funds rate (July 2023) Figure 10 plots the actual FFR versus the prescribed rate from the trimmed persistence PCE-based Taylor rule. The gray shaded region indicates the range of rate prescriptions obtained from incorporating the alternative inflation measures listed in Table 5 into the specified rule. The figure shows that prior to the pandemic recession, the trimmed persistence PCE-based rule characterized the FOMC's setting for the FFR reasonably well, despite a notable period from 2009-2013 when the effective lower bound (ELB) was a binding constraint, with the rule recommending levels at or below zero. During the early phase of the pandemic, the ELB once again became binding as the Taylor rule recommended negative rates from April through October 2020. The situation quickly reversed when inflation began to rise in March 2021; the rule-prescribed FFR was over 100 basis points higher than the actual FFR by the end of 2021. With historically rapid policy tightening beginning in March 2022, including a string of four consecutive 75 basis point hikes, the gap between the actual FFR and the prescribed value narrowed rapidly. While the prescribed rate remained above the actual FFR through the first ten months of 2022, the gap between the two series was eliminated with a large 75 basis point FFR hike in November 2022, bringing the funds rate to 3.875 versus the rule-based prescription of 3.76. Thus, from the perspective of this particular specification of the Taylor rule, steep rate hikes by the FOMC were successful in bringing policy close to “appropriate” levels as quickly as the fourth quarter of 2022—though the rule-based prescription continued to rise in following months with ongoing elevated inflation, indicating further adjustment remained necessary. Still, taken as a whole, aggressive FFR normalization may have contributed to signs of progress for overall PCE inflation in the fourth quarter of 2022. This in turn may have allowed the FOMC to slow the pace of its rate hikes beginning in December 2022 as policy overshooting risks became more relevant. 23 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 May-23 Oct-22 Mar-22 Aug-21 Jan-21 Jun-20 Nov-19 Apr-19 Sep-18 Feb-18 Jul-17 Dec-16 May-16 Oct-15 Mar-15 Aug-14 Jan-14 Jun-13 Nov-12 Apr-12 Sep-11 Feb-11 Jul-10 Dec-09 May-09 Oct-08 Mar-08 Aug-07 -1 Jan-07 0 -2 Taylor Rule Prescription Actual FFR Figure 10 Fed funds rate versus prescription of trimmed persistence PCE-based Taylor rule, 2007-present VI. Conclusion I introduced an alternative measure of core inflation called the trimmed persistence PCE in which expenditure categories are weighted according to the time-varying persistence of their corresponding price changes. Excluding categories associated with more persistent price changes yields an inflation measure that is less volatile than headline PCE inflation. Additionally, because the underlying components of trimmed persistence inflation display less tendency to mechanically pass-through the prior period's level to the current period, the contemporaneous influence of fundamental drivers of inflation such as real supply and demand effects and the cumulative impact of monetary policy actions are likely to be more visible in recent trimmed persistence PCE inflation compared to the headline measure. In contrast to other popular measures of core inflation, the trimmed persistence PCE is neither a fixedexclusion measure omitting pre-specified expenditure categories such as food, energy, or “sticky price” categories, nor is it an outlier-exclusion measure that automatically strips out expenditure categories that experience outsized monthly price changes. Because it retains some information from expenditure categories with large price changes, the trimmed persistence PCE can be a more volatile measure of 24 core inflation than trimmed mean or median PCE. However, following the pandemic recession, the trimmed persistence PCE performed favorably versus other measures of core inflation, with a standard deviation of monthly annualized inflation falling between that of median PCE and PCExFE. Additionally, the trimmed persistence PCE performs comparably to other core inflation proxies in terms of relationship with economic slack. In the aftermath of the COVID-19 recession, trimmed persistence PCE displayed a stronger negative relationship with the unemployment gap than trimmed mean and multivariate core inflation, with the degree of comovement with slack similar to median PCE. In variable selection procedures pitting trimmed persistence PCE against other inflation measures, trimmed persistence PCE is shown to contribute to the predictive fit of regression-based inflation forecasting models for horizons up to three years ahead. The trimmed persistence PCE can provide a helpful alternative signal of underlying inflation pressure. By relying on alternative weighting and exclusion criteria compared to other core inflation proxies, it contributes to policy debates about how, if at all, to take signals about aggregate inflation from disaggregated, expenditure category-level data. Additionally, for policymakers and economic forecasters judging the appropriate level of the benchmark policy rate through the framework of Taylor-type rules, incorporating trimmed persistence PCE inflation into such rules may provide additional context about the possible range of appropriate settings for the FFR. Using trimmed persistence PCE inflation in a Taylor-type rule calibrated to fit data observed prior to the pandemic shows a considerable deviation between the actual FFR and levels prescribed by the rule at the end of 2021, while aggressive rate hiking in 2022 may have returned policy to appropriate levels—as indicated by the rule—by the fourth quarter of that year. This study also opens further avenues for additional research. For example, I estimated a simple timevarying AR(1) process for component-level price indices; further research could explore whether having richer specifications that include more autoregressive lags, or allowing for moving-average terms could improve the performance of the index. Another simplifying step used in this paper was a Divisia approximation to construct the trimmed persistence price index; further work could be done to move toward the Fisher ideal index construction. Additionally, I use a simple rule to determine whether an expenditure component is included at any given period; further work could explore alternative inclusion criteria relating each components' weight in the aggregate index to their estimated persistence coefficient. Future research could also explore whether other methods of estimating time-varying inflation dynamics, different from the generalized additive approach used in this paper, might yield superior results. VII. Appendices A. Component 1 2 3 4 Appendix 1: List of PCE components used in calculation Description Start Date New Domestic Autos New Foreign Autos New Light Trucks Used Autos 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 25 Component 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 Description Used Light Trucks Tires Accessories & Parts Furniture Clock/Lamp/Lighting Fixture/Other HH Decorative Item Carpets & Other Floor Coverings Window Coverings Major Household Appliances Small Elec Household Appliances Dishes and Flatware Nonelectric Cookware & Tableware Tools, Hardware & Supplies Outdoor Equipment & Supplies Televisions Other Video Equip Audio Equipment Audio Discs/Tapes/Vinyl/Permanent Digital Downloads Video Discs, Tapes & Permanent Digital Downloads Photographic Equip Personal Computers/Tablets & Peripheral Equipment Computer Software & Accessories Calculators/Typewriters/Other Info Processing Eqpt Sporting Equip, Supplies, Guns & Ammunition Motorcycles Bicycles & Accessories Pleasure Boats Pleasure Aircraft Other Recreational Vehicles Recreational Books Musical Instruments Jewelry Watches Therapeutic Medical Equip Corrective Eyeglasses & Contact Lenses Educational Books Luggage & Similar Personal Items Telephone and Related Communication Equipment Cereals Bakery Products Beef and Veal Pork Other Meats Poultry Start Date 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1977-01-31 1959-01-31 1977-01-31 1977-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 26 Component 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 Description Fish and Seafood Fresh Milk Processed Dairy Products Eggs Fats and Oils Fresh Fruit Fresh Vegetables Processed Fruits & Vegetables Sugar and Sweets Food Products, Not Elsewhere Classified Coffee, Tea & Other Beverage Mtls Mineral Waters, Soft Drinks & Vegetable Juices Spirits Wine Beer Food Produced & Consumed on Farms Women's & Girls' Clothing Men's & Boys' Clothing Children's & Infants' Clothing Clothing Materials Standard Clothing Issued to Military Personnel Shoes & Other Footwear Gasoline & Other Motor Fuel Lubricants & Fluids Fuel Oil Other Fuels Prescription Drugs Nonprescription Drugs Other Medical Products Games, Toys & Hobbies Pets & Related Products Flowers, Seeds & Potted Plants Film & Photographic Supplies Household Cleaning Products Household Paper Products Household Linens Sewing Items Misc Household Products Hair/Dental/Shave/Misc Pers Care Prods ex Elec Prod Cosmetic/Perfumes/Bath/Nail Preparatns & Implements Elec Appliances for Personal Care Tobacco Newspapers & Periodicals Start Date 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 27 Component 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 132 133 Description Stationery & Misc Printed Materials Expenditures Abroad by U.S. Residents Less: Personal Remittances in Kind to Nonresidents Rental of Tenant-Occupied Nonfarm Housing Owner-Occupied Mobile Homes Owner-Occupied Stationary Homes Rental Value of Farm Dwellings Group Housing Water Supply & Sewage Maintenance Garbage & Trash Collection Electricity Natural Gas Physician Services Dental Services Paramedical Services Nonprofit Hospitals' Services to HHs Proprietary Hospitals Govt Hospitals Nursing Homes Motor Vehicle Maintenance & Repair Motor Vehicle Leasing Motor Vehicle Rental Parking Fees & Tolls Railway Transportation Intercity Buses Taxicabs and Ride Sharing Services Intracity Mass Transit Other Road Transportation Service Air Transportation Water Transportation Membership Clubs/Participant Sports Centers Amusement Parks/Campgrounds/Rel Recral Svcs Motion Picture Theaters Live Entertainment, ex Sports Spectator Sports Museums & Libraries Audio-Video, Photographic/Info Process Svcs Casino Gambling Lotteries Pari-Mutuel Net Receipts Veterinary & Other Services for Pets Package Tours Maint/Repair of Rec Vehicles/Sports Eqpt Start Date 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1973-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 28 Component 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 170 171 172 173 174 175 176 Description Elementary & Secondary School Lunches Higher Education School Lunches Other Purchased Meals Alcohol in Purchased Meals Food Supplied to Civilians Food Supplied to Military Hotels and Motels Housing at Schools Commercial Banks Other Dep Instns/Regulated Invest Companies Pension Funds Financial Service Charges, Fees/Commissions Life Insurance Net Household Insurance Net Health Insurance Net Motor Vehicle/Oth Transportation Insur Communication Proprietary & Public Higher Education Nonprofit Pvt Higher Education Svcs to HHs Elementary & Secondary Schools Day Care & Nursery Schools Commercial & Vocational Schools Legal Services Tax Preparation & Other Rel Services Employment Agcy Services Other HH Business Services Labor Organization Dues Prof Assn Dues Funeral & Burial Services Hairdressing Salons & HH Grooming Establishments Misc HH Care Services Laundry & Dry Cleaning Services Clothing Repair, Rental & Alterations Repair & Hire of Footwear Child Care Social Assistance Social Advocacy/Civic/Social Organizations Religious Organizations' Services to HHs Sales Receipts: Foundatns/Grant Making/Giving Svcs to HH Domestic Services Moving, Storage & Freight Services Repair of Furn, Furnishings/Floor Coverings Repair of HH Appliances Start Date 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 29 Component 177 178 179 180 Description Other Household Services Foreign Travel by U.S. Residents Less: Exps in the US by Nonresidents Final Consumptn Exps of Nonprofit Instns Serving HH Start Date 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 1959-01-31 Appendix Table 1 PCE components used in calculating trimmed persistence PCE VIII. References Almuzara, M. A. (2022, April). Inflation Persistence: How Much Is There and Where Is It Coming From? Liberty Street Economics. Aoki, K. (2001). Optimal Monetary Policy Responses to Relative-Price Changes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 48(1), 55-80. Atkeson, A., & Ohanian, L. (2001). Are Phillips Curves Useful for Forecasting Inflation? Quarterly Review, 25(Winter), 2-11. Ball, L. M., Leigh, D., & Mishra, P. (2022). Understanding U.S. Inflation During the COVID Era. NBER Working Papers, 30613. Barsky, R. B. (1987, January). The Fisher Hypothesis and the Forecastability and Persistence of Inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 19(1), 3-24. Beechey, M. a. (2012). The Rise and Fall of U.S. Inflation Persistence. International Journal of Central Banking, 8(3), 55-86. Brischetto, A., & Richards, A. (2006, December). The Performance of Trimmed Mean Measures of Underlying Inflation. RBA Research Discussion Papers, rdp2006-10. Bryan, M. F., & Meyer, B. (2010, May). Are Some Prices in the CPI More Forward Looking than Others? We Think So. Economic Commentary, 2010(2), 1-6. Bryan, M. F., & Pike, C. J. (1991, December). Median Price Changes: An Alternative Approach to Measuring Current Monetary Inflation. Economic Commentary, 1. Bryan, M. F., Cecchetti, S. G., & Wiggins II, R. L. (1997, September). Efficient Inflation Estimation. NBER Working Papers, 6183. Bullard, J. (2022, November). Getting Into The Zone. Retrieved 11 30, 2022, from https://www.stlouisfed.org/news-releases/2022/11/17/bullard-presents-getting-into-the-zone Carroll, D. R., & Verbrugge, R. (2019, July). Behavior of a New Median PCE Measure: A Tale of Tails. Economic Commentary. 30 Cogley, T., & Sargent, T. (2002). Evolving Post-World War II US Inflation Dynamics. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, Volume 16 (pp. 331-388). National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Cogley, T., Primiceri, G. E., & Sargent, T. J. (2010, January). Inflation-Gap Persistence in the US. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(1), 43-69. Dhawan, R., & Jeske, K. (2007). Taylor Rules with Headline Inflation: A Bad Idea. FRB Atlanta Working Paper, 2007(14). Ding, F., & Wolman, A. L. (2005). Inflation and Changing Expenditure Shares. Economic Quarterly, 91(Winter), 1-20. Dolmas, J. (2005, July). Trimmed Mean PCE Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Working Papers(0506). Dolmas, J., & Koenig, E. F. (2019). Two Measures of Core Inflation: A Comparison. Review, 101(4). Garciga, C., Knotek, E. S., & Verbrugge, R. (2016, July). Federal Funds Rates Based on Seven Simple Monetary Policy Rules. Economic Commentary. Goodfriend, M., & King, R. G. (1997). The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12 (pp. 231-296). National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Hastie, T., & Tibshirani, R. (1986). Generalized Additive Models. Statistical Science, 1(3), 297-310. Hastie, T., & Tibshirani, R. (1990). Generalized Additive Models (1st ed.). Routledge. Higgins, P. (2016, September 8). Introducing the Atlanta Fed's Taylor Rule Utility. Policy Hub: Macroblog. Retrieved 12 8, 2022, from https://www.atlantafed.org/blogs/macroblog/2016/09/08/introducing-the-atlanta-feds-taylorrule-utility Lacker, J. M., & Plosser, C. I. (2022, November). The Fed Should Talk about the Prescriptions of Systematic Policy Rules. Hoover Institution Economics Working Papers, 22129. Retrieved from https://www.hoover.org/sites/default/files/research/docs/22129-Lacker-Plosser.pdf Leigh, D., Ball, L. M., Mishra, P., & Spilimbergo, A. (2021, December). Measuring U.S. Core Inflation: The Stress Test of COVID-19. IMF Working Papers(2021/291). Mahedy, T. a. (2017). What's Down with Inflation? FRBSF Economic Letter, 35. Mehra, Y. P., & Sawhney, B. (2010). Inflation Measure, Taylor Rules, and the Greenspan-Bernanke years. Economic Quarterly, 96(2Q), 123-151. Meyer, B., & Venkatu, G. (2014, March). Trimmed-Mean Inflation Statistics: Just Hit the One in the Middle. FRB Atlanta Working Paper, 2014(3). Meyer, B., Venkatu, G., & Zaman, S. (2013, April). Forecasting Inflation? Target the Middle. Economic Commentary. 31 Pivetta, F. a. (2007, April). The Persistence of Inflation in the United States. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31(4), 1326-1358. Schmitt-Grohé, S., & Uribe, M. (2022, August). What Do Long Data Tell Us about the Inflation Hike Post COVID-19 Pandemic? NBER Working Paper Series, 30357. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w30357 Shapiro, A. H. (2022). How Much Do Supply and Demand Drive Inflation? FRBSF Economic Letter, 2022(15), 1-6. Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2007, February). Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(1), 3-33. Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2016, October). Core Inflation and Trend Inflation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 98(4), 770-784. Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2019, June). Slack and Cyclically Sensitive Inflation. NBER Working Papers, 25987. Taylor, J. B. (1993). Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39(1), 195-214. The Economist. (2021, November 6). A Handful of Items Are Driving Inflation in America. Retrieved 12 14, 2022, from The Economist: https://www.economist.com/graphic-detail/2021/11/06/ahandful-of-items-are-driving-inflation-in-america Williams, J. C. (2006, October 13). Inflation Persistence in an Era of Well-Anchored Inflation Expectations. FRBSF Economic Letter. Wood, S. N. (2017). Generalized Additive Models: An Introduction with R (2nd ed.). Chapman & Hall. Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 32