View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Alfred Marshall and the Quantity Theory
of Money

WP 04-10

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Thomas M. Humphrey
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Alfred Marshall and the Quantity Theory of Money1
Thomas M. Humphrey2
Senior Economist and Policy Advisor
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Richmond, VA
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 04-10
December 2004

Abstract
Marshall made at least four contributions to the classical quantity theory. He endowed it
with his Cambridge cash-balance money-supply-and-demand framework to explain how
the nominal money supply relative to real money demand determines the price level. He
combined it with the assumption of purchasing power parity to explain (i) the
international distribution of world money under metallic standards and fixed exchange
rates, and (ii) exchange rate determination under floating rates and inconvertible paper
currencies. He paired it with the idea of money wage and/or interest rate stickiness in the
face of price level changes to explain how money-stock fluctuations produce
corresponding business-cycle oscillations in output and employment. He applied it to
alternative policy regimes and monetary standards to determine their respective
capabilities of delivering price-level and macroeconomic stability. In his hands the theory
proved to be a powerful and flexible analytical tool.
JEL Classification Numbers: B31, E40, E30, F31.
Key Words
Quantity theory, Cambridge cash balance approach, monetary neutrality and
nonneutrality, direct causality, exogeneity, purchasing power parity, symmetallism,
indexation, managed paper currency, price-level stability.

1

Forthcoming in The Elgar Companion to Alfred Marshall, edited by Tiziano Raffaelli, Giacomo Becattini,
and Marco Dardi. Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd., 2005. For valuable comments, the
author is indebted to Marco Dardi, Peter Groenewegen, Tiziano Raffaelli, and John Whitaker.
2
E-mail: Tom.humphrey@rich.frb.org

1

.

Alfred Marshall and the Quantity Theory of Money
In his Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution, David Laidler (1999, 79-80n) notes
that Alfred Marshall never claimed to be a quantity theorist. To Marshall the quantity
theory meant Irving Fisher’s rate of use or circulation velocity version in which velocityaugmented stocks of money per unit of real transactions determine price levels. While
acknowledging that his own Cambridge cash balance approach yielded predictions
similar to Fisher’s version, Marshall always distinguished between the two and denied, at
least implicitly, that his was a variant of the quantity theory. With all due respect to
Marshall, however, an impartial observer must rule that he was a quantity theorist par
excellence, his claims to the contrary notwithstanding. His writings reveal that he made
heavy use of the theory, which he derived from earlier British economists. In his hands
the theory became a powerful and subtle analytical tool.
Modern students know the quantity theory as the proposition that an exogenously
given one-time change in the stock of money has no lasting effect on real variables, but
leads ultimately to a proportionate change in the money price of goods. As we will see,
Marshall would have accepted this proposition, although he also would have observed
that it hardly does justice to the versatility and power of his particular theory of pricelevel determination. His theory, he would have claimed, was more flexible and nuanced
than that defined above.

Money Supply and Demand Framework
Already in his early (1871) manuscript Money, as well as in his 1879 book
Economics of Industry (coauthored with his wife), and in his later monetary writings,
Marshall gave the quantity theory, as inherited from his classical predecessors, its
distinctive Cambridge cash-balance formulation. In so doing, he accomplished two tasks.
First, he expressed the theory rigorously in a microeconomic demand-and-supply
framework, thus establishing the monetary theory of price-level determination as part of
the general theory of value. Second, he adopted, coordinated, clarified, refined, extended,
and qualified what quantity theorists Locke, Hume, Cantillon, Ricardo, Thornton,
Wheatley, Jevons, and others had stated before him, namely the five core propositions
absolutely essential to the theory. These referred to (1) equiproportionality of money and
prices, (2) money-to-price causality, (3) long-run neutrality and short-run non-neutrality
of money, (4) money-stock exogeneity, and (5) relative price/absolute price dichotomy
attributing equilibrium relative price movements to real causes and absolute price
movements to monetary causes, respectively.
Marshall articulated and amended these propositions with the aid of his money
supply and demand framework, the main elements of which he inherited from Petty,
Thornton, Ricardo, Senior, J. S. Mill, Bagehot, Giffen, Jevons, and other predecessors
and contemporaries (Eshag 1963, 13-18). That framework states that in monetary

2

equilibrium when nominal money demand-and-supply equality (Md = M) prevails, the
price level is determined by the nominal stock of money per unit of real money demand,
or P = M/D. Here P is the aggregate price of currently produced final goods and services,
M is the nominal money stock defined by Marshall as metallic coin and banknotes freely
convertible into the metal at a fixed price, and D is the public’s demand for real, or pricedeflated nominal, cash balances M/P -- this demand interpreted as a function of
cashholder real resources, variously identified by Marshall as income and/or wealth.
Employing the portfolio balance assumption that agents make their cash-holding
decisions by weighting the advantages of keeping their resources in cash form against the
costs of doing so, namely the benefits sacrificed by refraining from holding those
resources in non-cash forms, Marshall (1923, 227-8; 1926, 267-8) in some of his later
work tended to suppress the wealth variable and to express real money demand as the
fraction K of real national income Y that the public wishes to hold in real balances, or
D(Y) = KY.
Of the public’s desired cash-balance ratio K, Marshall (1923, 38-40, 43-8)
specified at least eight sets of variables determining it. These included (1) the marginal
utility of holding money for the convenience and security it yields, (2) the corresponding
marginal utility (“direct benefit”) of holding one’s resources in the form of goods rather
than money, (3) expected rates of return to holding earning assets such as business plant
and stock-exchange securities, (4) inflationary expectations regarding the prospective
value (“credit”) of the currency, (5) bank credit instruments in the form of banknotes and
checking deposits that substitute for money in asset portfolios and the payments
mechanism, (6) institutional factors such as business habits and practices, banking
arrangements, methods of transportation, and techniques of production, (7) degree of
confidence in the strength of the economy and the associated ease of meeting payment
commitments, and (8) unforeseen shocks in the form of wars, rumors of war, crop
failures and the like. Summarizing these determinants by the vector of variables Z, one
can write Marshall’s cash-balance fraction as K = K(Z). Of the variables composing Z,
items (1) and (8) enter with positive signs indicating that rises in their values exert
upward pressure on K. Conversely, increases in the magnitudes of variables (2) through
(7) tend to cause K to fall.

Equiproportionality
All the fundamental classical quantity theory propositions follow from Marshall’s
formulation. Regarding equiproportionality of money and prices, he (1926, 268) writes
that “other things being equal,” then “there is this direct relation between the volume of
currency and the level of prices, that, if one is increased by ten per cent, the other also
will be increased by ten per cent.” The proviso “other things being equal,” however, he
regarded as “of overwhelming importance.” He realized that proportionality holds only
for the ceteris paribus thought experiment in which the price equation’s other
components, namely income and the K ratio (and its underlying determinants),
provisionally are held fixed. In actual historical time, however, these components evolve
secularly just as they interact with each other over the business cycle. In these cases,
proportionality refers to the partial effect of money on prices. To this partial effect must

3

be added the parallel effects of coincidental changes in income and the K ratio. The sum
of these separate effects shows the influence of all on the price level.
Thus if M, Y, and K evolve secularly at the percentage rates of change denoted by
the lower case letters m, y, and k, respectively, then the price level P evolves at the
percentage rate p = m – k – y. Of these separate elements, Marshall (1923, 19; 1926, 12,
54) thought that income growth and financial innovation, namely the development of
credit arrangements and money substitutes – the last two items causing falls in the cashbalance ratio -- dominated money growth in determining the long-term path of the price
level. Likewise, he (1926, 269) argued that over the course of the cycle, changing
expectations of both the future value of the currency and the strength or weakness of real
activity affect the cash-balance ratio and thus the price level even if the money stock
remains unchanged.

Long-run Neutrality
Marshall was equally adamant on the neutrality of money other than during shortrun adjustment periods. Regarding long-run neutrality, he argued that currency expansion
or contraction has no permanent effect on real activity since the latter depends solely
upon real factors such as production techniques; organization of business; the quantity
and quality of labor, land, and capital; the social and political security of the citizenry;
and the like (Eshag 1963, 72-3) The long-run independence of these real variables from
money means that money cannot affect them or the levels of output and employment they
determine. Money is neutral with respect to the volume of real activity in the long run.

Short-run Non-neutrality
Money and the quantity of bank-credit substitutes erected thereupon can,
however, influence real activity temporarily. Indeed the classical, or Hume-ThorntonCairnes-Jevons, proposition regarding the short-run non-neutrality of money posits that
very point. Marshall (1887, 190-2) in his theory of the business cycle attributes such nonneutrality to sticky nominal wage and interest rates (see Laidler 1999, 79, 82). Because
nominal wages are sluggish and slow to adjust, price-level changes transform them into
cycle-amplifying variations in real wages. Likewise, price level changes transform sticky
nominal interest rates into cycle-amplifying movements in real rates of interest (Marshall
1887, 191; 1923, 18; Laidler 1999, 82-3; Eshag 1963, 81).
Thus in the upswing when rising prices (fueled by credit expansion as banks
accommodate business loan demands) are not matched by compensating rises in sticky
nominal wage and interest rates, the resulting fall in the real, or price-deflated, values of
those rates causes real profits to rise. Spurred by rising real profits, businessmen expand
their operations. Output and employment rise. These same factors work in reverse in the
downswing when the failure of sluggish money wage and interest rates to fall as fast as
prices causes real rates to rise, real profits to fall, and real activity to slacken. In short,
money- and credit-financed fluctuations in prices translate sticky wage and interest rates
into cycle-intensifying variations in real rates, thus affecting real activity.

4

Money to Price Causality
As for unidirectional M to P causality in open trading economies, Marshall (1926,
51-2; 1923, 256) explains it by tracing the transmission mechanism through which an
influx of gold through the balance of payment works in a fractional reserve banking
system to drive up prices. His statement to the 1888-9 Gold and Silver Commission
offered an early account (and still one of the best) of that mechanism. Drawing on work
of Thornton, Mill, and especially Giffen, Marshall’s account anticipates Knut Wicksell’s
famous 1898 theory of the cumulative process in virtually every detail.
Marshall (1926, 51-2; 1923, 256) starts his analysis by assuming a specie inflow
occurs through the balance of payments. The recipients of the specie deposit it in their
bank accounts. Bankers, desiring to hold a certain fraction of their note and deposit
liabilities in the form of metallic reserves, find the extra specie raises their gold reserve
above the level they wish to hold. The resulting pressure of excess reserves induces them
to lower their loan rates of interest, which fall below businessmen’s expected rate of
profit on new capital investment. With the borrowing cost of capital less than capital’s
expected rate of return, investment becomes profitable. Consequently business demands
for bank loans to finance such investment increase. Banks accommodate these loan
demands by supplying additional checking deposits and notes, which in the fractionalreserve banking system constitute a multiple of the gold reserves backing them. Flush
with such augmented purchasing power, businessmen increase their spending. The
resulting excess demand for goods bids up prices.
At this point Marshall introduces a new element, inflationary expectations, into
the mechanism. He (1926, 51-2) notes that throughout the expansionary process such
expectations work to augment the upward pressure on prices emanating from note and
deposit expansion alone. Initially aroused by the gold inflow, entrepreneurs’ anticipations
of future inflation are realized and intensified by the subsequent rise in prices. Factored
into the real loan rate of interest when the sticky nominal rate is temporarily given and
fixed, these expectations act to reduce the real loan rate below the anticipated real rate of
profit on the use of the borrowed funds. This real rate/profit rate differential stimulates
additional borrowing, additional lending, additional deposit creation, and additional
aggregate demand leading to additional upward pressure on prices. Through these interest
rate and expectational channels, causation runs from gold inflow M to general prices P as
predicted by the quantity theory.
Marshall (1926, 51) then invokes stability analysis to assure that the extra gold
actually gets into circulation so that money held by the non-bank public moves
proportionally with, and so supports, the higher level of prices as required by the theory.
He argues that as prices rise, people accustomed to holding a certain amount of real
balances M/P will find those balances shrinking. To restore their real balances to the
accustomed level, people convert demand deposits and notes into gold coin at the banks.
The result is a drain on bank gold reserves that threatens to deplete them below the level
banks desire to hold. To protect their reserves, banks raise their lending rates so that extra
borrowing and spending are no longer profitable. In the new equilibrium, the extra

5

monetary gold held outside the banks just matches the higher prices such that real cash
balances are exactly what they were before the gold inflow. At that point, money/price
equiproportionality reigns and there is no loan rate/profit rate differential to induce
expansionary borrowing and spending. Monetary equilibrium prevails.
In sum, with respect to open trading economies Marshall posits direct causality
and rejects reverse causality. He argues that gold, far from flowing passively across
countries to support given equilibrium price levels, distributes itself actively to correct
disequilibrium ones. Suppose a gold discovery in a gold-producing nation increases the
equilibrium world price level. Because the new gold has not yet been distributed
worldwide, however, prices in non-gold-producing countries are below their equilibrium
level. These too-low local prices will, by rendering their countries’ goods cheap on world
markets, generate trade-balance surpluses financed by monetary gold movements. The
resulting gold influx will, in Marshall’s account of the transmission mechanism described
above, bid local prices up to their equilibrium level. In this way, open economies find
their money stocks exogenously determined through the balance of payments and
causality runs from money to prices.

Absolute Price/Relative Price Dichotomy
The remaining classical propositions follow directly from Marshall’s analysis.
Regarding the relative price/absolute price dichotomy – more an axiom than a result since
it implies that real long-period equilibrium is unique in that it yields but one set of
relative prices whatever the monetary arrangements -- he argues that real factors
permanently determine relative prices and monetary factors determine absolute prices,
both of which are therefore independent of each other in steady-state equilibrium. While
accepting dichotomization, however, he did not necessarily accept, nor was he even
cognizant of, its uniqueness implication. After all, it was Marshall who, avoiding the
presumption of a unique, single equilibrium, introduced multiple equilibria into his
partial analysis and into his pure theory of foreign trade. Furthermore there is evidence of
a concern with path-dependent (hysteresis) mechanisms in his discussion of the process
of economic development in Appendix H of the Principles. All of which renders
conjectural the notion that he saw uniqueness as an essential or even a plausible property
of steady-state equilibrium. Nevertheless, when it came to separating relative and
absolute price determination into separate, watertight departments, he gave what David
Laidler (1990, 48) calls his “unequivocal endorsement to the Classical dichotomy
between the real and the monetary economy.”
As a representative example of a relative price, Marshall cites the equilibrium real
interest rate. Determined in the long run by the nonmonetary forces of productivity and
thrift, or more precisely by the demand for and supply of real investible resources (Eshag
1963, 46), the real rate’s movements, when matched in equilibrium with corresponding
movements in loan rates so that bank credit and aggregate spending remain unchanged,
cannot affect the price level. Nor can changes in the absolute price level caused by
changes in the quantity of money alter the real equilibrium interest rate. “The supply of
gold,” Marshall (1926, 41) writes, “exercises no permanent influence over” it. Relative

6

and absolute prices are independent of each other in long-run equilibrium. Marshall
admits but one possible exception to this rule: the real wage rate. A slight degree of longrun stickiness of nominal wages means that the absolute price level can permanently
affect the real wage rate (Laidler 1991, 97).

Exogeneity
Finally, with respect to exogeneity of money, Marshall draws on page 282 of his
Money, Credit and Commerce a money-supply-and-demand diagram that depicts the
money supply of a closed economy as a vertical straight line. He notes that this line, as
drawn, represents the money stock as an exogeneously given variable whose magnitude
is independent of both the price level and money demand. This independence, of course,
is required if causality is to run directly from M to P as the quantity theory predicts. For if
the money supply is not independent of, but instead responds passively to, the price level
and to money demand, one cannot claim that it is an active variable causing price-level
change.
Earlier, in his 1871 manuscript Money, Marshall had already extended the
exogeneity proposition to the long-run when the stock of metallic money, far from being
a given constant, grows or shrinks as its value, or purchasing power over goods, exceeds
or falls short of its marginal cost of production (see Laidler 1991, 54-5). Here fortuitous
events such as new gold discoveries and technological progress in mining, both of which
sink the cost of production of the metal below its value and so increase the profitability of
producing more of it, lead to increases in the money stock. These increases -- exogenous
inasmuch as the events initiating them are purely adventitious -- continue until the
resulting rise in prices brings gold’s value down to its marginal cost making additional
output unprofitable. Marshall does, however, acknowledge one major case of
endogeneity, namely shifts in money demand. By raising or lowering the price level,
these shifts drive a wedge between the value and marginal cost of producing gold. The
resulting profitability or unprofitability of mining causes the gold stock to expand or
contract. In this important case, the key one cited by Marshall, money-stock changes
indeed are demand determined.

External Value of Money
Not only did Marshall use the quantity theory to explain money’s internal value,
or purchasing power over domestically produced goods and services, he also used it to
explain money’s external value, or purchasing power over foreign currencies and,
through them, over foreign goods and services as well. He (1926, 191-2) extended the
quantity theory to the open economy by expounding what Gustav Cassel would later
christen the purchasing power parity (PPP) theory of exchange rates. This theory, which
Marshall took from Thornton, Wheatley, Ricardo, Senior, J. S. Mill, Goshen, Giffen, and
others, says that the equilibrium exchange rate E, or domestic currency price of a unit of
foreign currency, tends to equal the ratio of aggregate or general price levels P/P* of the
two countries, each price level denominated in terms of its country’s respective currency.
In short, Marshall’s version of the theory stated symbolically is E = P/P* where the
asterisk denotes a foreign country variable. As Marshall (1926, 170, 191) himself put it,

7

this exchange rate makes the value of money, or price of goods, measured in terms of a
common currency at the rate of exchange everywhere the same, or P = EP*.
According to Marshall (1926, 191-2), PPP tends to hold for any pair of countries
whether they are on the same or different metallic standards or on an inconvertible paper
standard. In the case of metallic standards, any deviation from PPP that renders one (e.g.
the home) country’s goods cheaper (P < EP*) and more competitive in world markets
will create, via the consequent cheapness-induced rise in that country’s exports and fall in
its imports, a trade balance surplus and a compensating specie inflow. The resulting
increase in monetary metal in the home country and its decrease in the foreign one will
raise prices in the former and lower them in the latter until purchasing power parity is
reestablished. In the case of inconvertible paper currencies, adjustment is achieved
primarily through exchange rate changes rather than through specie flows and domestic
prices. Exchange rate deviations from PPP that underprice one country’s goods and
overprice the other’s will, on the market for foreign exchange, precipitate a deluge of the
currency of the high-price country seeking conversion into the currency of the low-price
one to make cheaper purchases there. The resulting surplus of the overvalued currency
and shortage of the undervalued one quickly bids the exchange rate back to PPP
equilibrium.

Quantity Theory Propositions Again
All the closed-economy quantity theory propositions and postulates apply to
Marshall’s open-economy analysis of the exchange rate. The quantity theory itself of
course applies. For Marshall had already shown that the national price levels, whose ratio
equals the equilibrium exchange rate, are themselves determined by national nominal
money supplies and real money demands. In short, since P = M/D and P* = M*/D*, it
follows that E (= P/P*) = (M/D)/(M*/D*). This condition then yields the proportionality
postulate, which holds because with all else being equal, namely both money demands
and the foreign money supply, the exchange rate E necessarily varies equiproportionally
with the domestic money stock M.
The neutrality proposition likewise holds. It holds, Marshall pointed out, because
equilibrium exchange rate changes are matched by corresponding price level changes so
as to keep the common currency price of goods everywhere the same. This being the
case, equilibrium exchange rate changes exert no effect on real variables like exports,
imports, the trade balance, and the terms of trade. Indeed Marshall (1926, 192-5) used the
neutrality proposition to refute British complaints that the depreciation of India’s silver
rupee relative to the gold pound in the 1870s and 1880s would give India’s exporters a
lasting competitive advantage over their British counterparts.
True, Marshall (1926, 192-5) admitted that the rupee’s depreciation, if not offset
immediately by higher inflation in India than in England, would give Indian exporters a
temporary price advantage (or “bounty”). With the undervalued rupee rendering the
price of Indian goods cheaper than English ones in world markets, however, the effect
would be to stimulate India’s exports, curtail her imports, and improve her trade balance.
In this way transitory departures from PPP do indeed affect real variables.

8

Acknowledging this point, Marshall advanced the open economy equivalent of the
proposition of the short-run non-neutrality of money. But he then stressed that the
resulting export surplus would be paid for by a corresponding silver inflow that would
bid up India’s prices until no advantage remained. Short-run non-neutrality gives way to
long-run neutrality as the quantity theory predicts.
Of course, Marshall realized that non-neutrality, though temporary, could last for
a protracted length of time. As an example of such prolonged non-neutrality, Marshall
(1923, 316-17) cited a capital flight from Russia induced by foreign investor
apprehension of political instability there. Since the resulting Russian capital account
deficit necessitates a corresponding current account (or trade) surplus to keep that
country’s overall balance of payments in balance, a prolonged ruble exchange rate
depreciation from its PPP equilibrium must occur to provide the “bounty” to net exports
that generates the surplus. Even so, the non-neutrality, which in this case arises from
political distrust and the consequent withdrawal of capital rather from monetary
disturbance, ends with the termination of the capital outflow and the corresponding
restoration of the exchange rate to its PPP equilibrium. Neutrality, though delayed,
eventually prevails.
Direct money-to-price (and exchange rate) causality likewise prevails. It prevails
in metallic regimes where specie flows through the balance of payments bring national
price ratios into line with the equilibrium exchange rate as defined by the ratio of the
official mint prices of the metals (plus and minus cost of specie carriage) in the two
countries (Marshall 1923, 317-18). And in inconvertible paper regimes, supplies of each
currency seeking conversion into the other on the market for foreign exchange bid the
exchange rate into equality with the ratio of the price levels (Marshall 1923, 315-16).
Causation runs from M and M* to P/P* and E as the quantity theory requires.
As for the absolute price/relative price dichotomy, Marshall’s PPP theory displays
it with a vengeance. Except for the case of political distrust and capital flight mentioned
above, Marshall essentially treats the nominal exchange rate as an absolute price
determined in the monetary sector by national currency supplies and demands. With
respect to the real exchange rate (or terms of trade or real relative price of imports
measured by the quantity of exports sacrificed to obtain them), however, Marshall’s PPP
equation implicitly assigns it a fixed equilibrium value of unity and then ignores it. (To
be sure, actual departures of the exchange rate from its PPP equilibrium produce
corresponding terms-of-trade deviations from unity. But these deviations are selfcorrecting via their effects on specie flows, price levels, and/or exchange rates. They
vanish with the restoration of PPP equilibrium.) The equilibrium unitary terms of trade,
of course, suggest a one-good world (equivalently, one where different goods are such
close substitutes for each other that they can be treated essentially as a single good), or at
least a world in which all countries produce and consume the same set of traded goods.
Evidently Marshall regarded the latter assumption as a serviceable first approximation
and useful common point of departure to use in quantity theoretic accounts of nominal
exchange rate determination.

9

True, elsewhere, in his account of the pure theory of foreign trade, Marshall
(1923, 330-60) has real forces operating through his reciprocal demand, or offer curve,
apparatus determine the equilibrium terms of trade. That equilibrium, he explains, can
undergo changes when real structural forces shift the offer curves. Even so, his PPP
equation ignores such changes and their potential effects on the nominal exchange rate.
The equation’s unitary terms of trade assumption rules them out. In the same way, the
equilibrium terms of trade, or real exchange rate, remains untouched by, and independent
of, monetary influences in his analysis. For Marshall, equilibrium nominal and real
exchange rate changes are mutually exclusive phenomena. They are part and parcel of
the classical tendency to partition the economy in the long run into real and monetary
sectors.

Advocate of Price Stability
The preceding has argued that Marshall was a quantity theorist who underscored
and indeed enriched the theory’s postulates. But there is an easier way to prove, or
confirm, Marshall’s credentials as a quantity theorist. That way is to examine his policy
views. Here one can employ a simple litmus test: An economist essentially is a quantity
theorist if he believes either that the monetary authority can and should stabilize the price
level through control, direct or indirect, of the money stock, or failing this, that schemes
can be devised to prevent price-level movements from affecting real activity. Marshall
passes this test with flying colors.
Marshall (1887, 190-2) advocated price-level stability on the grounds that
deflation and inflation are injurious to the real economy. Deflation is harmful because in
the face of sticky nominal wage, interest, and other costs, it raises the real value of those
items, diminishes real profits, and destroys the incentive to hire and produce. “The fall of
profits resulting from low prices might throw production…out of gear, our factories
might stand idle” (Marshall 1926, 75). And rising prices are harmful not only because
they transform sluggish money wages into lower real wages of labor (the group already
closest to the poverty line), but also because they make it easy for incompetent people to
enter business and encourage careless and lax behavior on the part of lenders.

Policy Reform Rankings
Marshall’s desire for price level stability influenced his ranking of alternative
monetary arrangements according to their ability to attain that goal. Worst of all was the
monometallic gold standard. The annual flow output of the metal was but a tiny fraction
of the existing stock. This meant that the stock supply of monetary gold in the closed
world economy adjusted too slowly to changes in the demand for it. Prices fluctuated as a
result.
Not much better was bimetallism (Marshall 1887, 193-6). It offered one small
advantage: Provided gold and silver both remained in circulation, the value of money
would vary with the mean values of the two metals instead of with the more variable
value of one of them alone. But bimetallism suffered from one overriding defect: The
fixed mint gold price of silver easily could overvalue one of the metals and drive it from

10

circulation. When that happened, Gresham’s Law would cause bimetallism to degenerate
into monometallism with all its disadvantages.
Somewhat better was Marshall’s novel concept of symmetallism (Marshall 1887,
204-7). It abolished gold coin in favor of a money supply consisting wholly of banknotes
convertible into gold and silver ingots joined together in fixed physical proportions.
Unlike bimetallism, in which the gold price of silver is set at the mint, symmetallism
would not degenerate into monometallism. Instead, the market would determine the
relative price of the two metals so that both could remain in the reserve base. Another
advantage of symmetallism was that it abolished coin, which meant that gold and silver
could be withdrawn from circulation where they were no longer needed and placed in the
country’s metallic reserve. With this enlarged buffer-stock reserve, the country could
weather external gold-and-silver drains and the resulting crises without being forced into
violent, deflationary contractions of the banknote money supply.
Marshall’s (1887, 188-199) next-best regime – preferred by him over
symmetalism because it involved no change in the makeup of the existing monetary
system and stock of currency (Eshag 1963, 118) -- was the Wheatley-Lowe-ScropeJevons notion of indexation, or tabular standard of value, in which the nominal values of
wage, interest, and rent contracts are automatically adjusted one-for-one with movements
in the price level. By removing lags, or time delays, of changes in nominal costs behind
product price changes -- lags that cause profits, actual and anticipated, to wax and wane - indexation would eliminate the source (fluctuating profit expectations) of the
speculative activity that destabilizes prices. Most of all, indexation would, through the
contemporaneous adjustment of money wage and interest rates to price level changes,
prevent any remaining price instability from affecting real wages and interest rates and so
smooth the business cycle. In these ways, indexation either stabilizes prices or keeps their
movements from influencing real activity.
Best of all price stabilizers, Marshall (1887, 206-7n) thought, were managed
paper currencies, inconvertible as well as convertible. Their supplies could readily be
adjusted to match corresponding changes in the demand for them, thereby stabilizing
their value (Marshall 1923, 50). The monetary authority would expand the stock of
inconvertible paper through open market purchases of government securities when prices
were below target and contract the stock through open market sales when prices were
above target. Such operations on the currency volume would restore prices to target. In
the case of managed convertible currency, the authority would regulate its quantity
through variations in the official nominal prices of gold and silver consistent with the
ratio of those prices being determined in the market. The authority would raise the
official prices of the metals when the general price level was above target and lower them
when general prices were below target. The result would be to raise and lower,
respectively, the nominal value of the country’s metallic reserves and so the quantity of
notes and deposits that could be issued on the basis of those reserves. In this way, the
second scheme, like the first, would stabilize prices through variations in the money
stock. In short, by countering price-destabilizing changes in metals’ purchasing power

11

over goods with offsetting variations in the metallic content of the currency, the second
scheme would achieve the same end as the first.
Having ranked managed paper currencies highest in terms of their capacity to
stabilize prices, Marshall stopped short of advocating them. He failed to recommend their
adoption not because he doubted their technical feasibility as a stabilizing standard.
Rather he feared they might give too much discretionary power to the policymakers.
Further, he believed that managed currencies, being national in scope and origin, would
impede the development of a truly international currency that he thought would best
facilitate world commerce.

Conclusion
Marshall took the classical quantity theory, endowed it with his Cambridge cashbalance money-supply-and-demand framework, and used it to explain how the nominal
money supply relative to real money demand determines the price level and value of
money. Demonstrating the theory’s versatility, he then combined it with the assumption
of purchasing power parity to explain the international distribution of world money under
metallic standards and fixed exchange rates. Likewise he used the theory to explain
exchange rate determination under floating rates and inconvertible paper currencies. In
each case, he drew heavily from the work of earlier British authors.
Further exhibiting the flexibility of the theory, he paired it with the idea of money
wage and/or interest rate stickiness in the face of price level changes to explain how
fluctuations in the money stock produce corresponding movements in real wage and
interest rates, and, through them, oscillations of output and employment. That is, he used
it to explain the trade cycle. He also applied the theory to alternative policy regimes or
monetary standards to determine their respective capabilities of delivering price-level and
macroeconomic stability. With respect to the quantity theory (as with so much else in
economics) the adage “it’s all in Marshall if you’ll only take the trouble to dig it out”
surely holds.

References
Eshag, E. (1963), From Marshall to Keynes, Oxford: Blackwell.
Laidler, D. (1990), ‘Alfred Marshall and the Development of Monetary Economics’ in J.
K.Whitaker (ed.) Centenary Essays on Alfred Marshall, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Laidler, D. (1991), The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Laidler, D. (1999), Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.

12

Marshall, A. (1871). ‘Money’ in J. Whitaker (ed.) (1975). The Early Economic Writings
of Alfred Marshall. 2 vols, London: Macmillan.
Marshall, A. (1887), ‘Remedies for fluctuations in general prices’, Contemporary
Review, reprinted in A. C. Pigou (ed.) (1925), Memorials of Alfred Marshall, London:
Macmillan.
Marshall, A. (1923), Money, Credit and Commerce, London: Macmillan.
Marshall, A. (1926), Official Papers of Alfred Marshall, edited by J. M. Keynes, London:
Macmillan.
Marshall, A., and Marshall, M. P. (1879), The Economics of Industry, London:
Macmillan.

13