View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

A Monetarist Critique of ECB Monetary
Policy in the Great Recession

WP 13-07R

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Robert L. Hetzel
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

A Monetarist Critique of ECB Monetary Policy in the Great Recession

Robert L. Hetzel
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
robert.hetzel@rich.frb.org
November 18, 2014
Working Paper No. 13-07R

Abstract: Since 2008, the Eurozone has undergone two recessions, which together constitute the Great
Recession. The explanation offered here attributes them to contractionary monetary policy.
Interpreted in a way consistent with monetarist principles, the New Keynesian model provides the
framework for identifying the precipitating shocks as monetary.

JEL: E52 and E58
The author is senior economist and research advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. He
gratefully acknowledges helpful criticism from Ernst Baltensperger, Douglas Diamond, Michael
Dotsey, Marvin Goodfriend, Joshua Hendrickson, Andreas Hornstein, Peter Ireland, Thomas Lubik,
Christian Matthes, Alberto Musso, Edward Nelson, Andrew Owen, Ricardo Reis, Felipe Schwartzman,
Peter Welz, and Alexander Wolman, as well as participants in seminars at the Bundesbank, European
Central Bank, Swiss National Bank, and the Banca D’Italia without implicating any of these
individuals in the exposition. Samuel Marshall, Raymond Wong, and Steven Sabol provided
invaluable research assistance. The views in this paper are the author’s not the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond’s or the Federal Reserve System’s.

Since 2008, the Eurozone has undergone two recessions (Figure 1). A monetarist
explanation in terms of contractionary monetary policy can account for them.1 Because of its
generality, the New Keynesian (NK) model can serve as a framework for testing this monetarist
hypothesis.
The analysis adopts the monetarist methodology used in order to attribute causation for
cyclical fluctuations to monetary disturbances. Milton Friedman believed that economists would
never know enough about the structure of the economy in order to build and estimate models capable
of offering numerical predictions of the evolution of the economy. 2 As illustrated in Friedman and
Schwartz (1963), he instead provided historical narrative organized around a small number of
hypotheses in order to explain a diverse set of historical episodes.
Along with the hypothesis that the monetary arrangements of a country determine the
behavior of prices, a fundamental monetarist hypothesis is that the empirical correlation between
nominal and real instability arises from monetary instability. A corollary is that if countries put into
place monetary arrangements that prevent monetary disturbances from becoming a source of
instability the price system will work well to prevent major cyclical instability. In this respect, the
NK model offers a guide as to when the central bank should allow the price system to work in an
unhindered way. As defined here, “unhindered” means avoiding any attempt to create an output gap
in order to manipulate a Phillips curve relationship between output and inflation. The NK model
restricts the kinds of shocks that make optimal attempts to exploit Phillips-curve trade-offs. For
shocks to preferences and technology, it should stick to an objective of price stability in the stickyprice sector and allow the price system to work unhindered.
The European Central Bank (ECB) has a single mandate—price stability. However, the issue
is in the Great Recession in response to high headline inflation generated in the flexible-price sector
how should it have pursued this goal? Should it have relied on a rule that establishes credibility for
nominal expectational stability in order to control price setting in the sticky-price sector while
allowing the price system to work unhindered to maintain an output gap equal to zero? Alternatively,
was it desirable to reduce high headline inflation through creation of a negative output gap? The
answer offered here is that the ECB attempted inappropriately to create a negative output gap in
response to a commodity-price shock (negative terms-of-trade shock), which is like a negative
technology shock.
Section 1 exposits the model. Section 2 discusses how to give empirical substance to the
central bank’s rule in order to provide a baseline that allows the price system free rein to control the
output gap but also allows for periodic attempts to exploit a Phillips curve trade-off. Section 3
1

The standard exposition by Milton Friedman does not provide a model. For example, Friedman
(1989) began only with a statement of the long-run neutrality of money and then continued with a list
of empirical regularities that he and Anna Schwartz had identified concerning the cyclical properties
of money. Since the early 1980s, the increased interest-sensitivity of and volatility in money demand
has limited the applicability of these observations.
2

The ideal of building and estimating models with microeconomic foundations is the organizing
principle in macroeconomics. The issue is whether economists can succeed in providing microfoundations to the degree necessary in order to achieve a consensus that there is a “true” model
whose estimation provides reliable identification of shocks. For a skeptical view of the adequacy of
estimated DSGE models for identifying shocks, see Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2009).

2
associates this baseline with Bundesbank policy starting in the 1980s. Like other central banks, in
response to the experience of the 1970s, the Bundesbank made price stability its central objective but
did not rely on manipulating an output gap in order to achieve it. Section 4 examines ECB monetary
policy during the Great Recession. Section 5 summarizes.
1. The NK model and divine coincidence
Equation (1) is the consumer’s Euler equation.3
(1) rt     ( Et yt 1 )
with yt the log of real output and yt 1 the percentage change in output between periods t and t+1,
 the consumer’s rate of time preference,  the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in
consumption (with consumption equal to output). The real rate of interest rt equals rt  it  Et t 1
with it the gross nominal interest rate and  t 1 the inflation rate between periods t and t+1.
The natural rate of interest, rt n , which is given to the central bank and shown in (2), is

(2) rt n     Et ytn1 .
The issue addressed here is when the central bank should allow the price system to work in an
unhindered way in order to maintain equality between the real rate, rt , and the natural rate, rt n . As
evident from (1) and (2), doing so implies a rule that maintains equality between Et yt 1 and Et ytn1
- between expected real growth and natural (potential or trend) real growth.
Equivalently, one can state the issue by expressing (1) in terms of output gaps as (3).
~
 ~

(3) rt  rt n    Et y t 1  y t 


~

with the output gap ( y t  yt  ytn ), expressed in logs, equal to the difference between real output and
natural output. Natural output is the value of output that would obtain with price flexibility and is
given exogenously to the central bank. Solving (3) forwards yields
~

(4)

yt  

1





r
k 0

t k

 rt nk 

A baseline rule is then a rule that keeps the real rate equal to the natural rate and thus the output gap
equal to zero and also maintains equality between expected growth in real and natural output.
Introduction of a Phillips curve (5) allows one to ask when the central bank should deviate
from the baseline rule by attempting to exploit a trade-off between inflation and the output gap.
~

(5)  t   Et t 1   y t  t .

3

The NK model exposited below follows Gali (2008).

3
The coefficient  is the inverse of  . Standard practice is to write (5) under the assumption that the
~

central bank has an inflation target of zero. Implicitly, (5) is  t  0   ( Et t 1  0)   y t  t . The

t are markup shocks of price over marginal cost. They are not “inflation shocks” originating in the
flexible-price sector. The model applies to inflation in the sticky-price sector, that is, to firms that set
prices for multiple periods, not to inflation in the flexible-price sector.4
As illustrated by (5), if the central bank maintains price stability in the sticky-price sector, so
~

that  t  0 and Et t 1  0 , it also maintains the output gap, y t , equal to zero. Blanchard and Gali
(2007) characterized this combination of price stability and real stability as the divine coincidence
first highlighted by Goodfriend and King (1997).5
If the central bank maintains price stability, it also maintains the nominal interest rate equal
to the natural real rate, it  rt  rt n , which is a manifestation of divine-coincidence. Equation (6) is
one representation of a rule that produces this result.6 Equation (7) introduces the term ( t   tnz ) in
order to capture deviations of the policy rate from the divine coincidence benchmark. This term
provides for a time-varying, positive (non-zero) inflation target (  tnz ).
In principle, the class of rules represented by (7) is optimal because it includes (6) as a
special case. The NK model distinguishes between shocks that limit optimal policy to allowing the
price system to work unhindered to keep the output gap at zero, represented by (6), and shocks that
offer in principle a desirable trade-off between inflation and the output gap represented by (7).
(6) it     Et ytn1   t

(7) it     Et ytn1   ( t   tnz )
The class of rules represented by (7) allows for the “markup” shocks in (5). Blanchard and
Gali (2007) identify them as disturbances to the markup,  p , of price over real marginal cost.7 They
More generally, Mankiw and Reis (2003, 1058) show that “[T]he weight of a sector in the stability
price index depends on the sector’s … sluggishness of price adjustment.”
4

5

Divine coincidence is an expression of the monetarist hypothesis that if the central bank maintains
monetary stability the price system will work well to ameliorate cyclical fluctuations.
6

Indeterminacy is ruled out by the assumption that the central bank will behave in a way that
eliminates undesirable equilibria even if one never observes such behavior.
7

Firms in the sticky price sector, which exercise monopoly power, set prices so that the markup of
price over marginal cost (relative to its steady-state level) is zero. That is, mc   p  0 , where mc is

  
(the logarithm of) real marginal cost and  p  log 
 . Markup shocks affect the monopoly
  1 
power of firms (  ) without affecting real marginal cost, mc (Blanchard and Gali 2007, 39).
Woodford (2003, 451-2) classifies markup shocks as shocks to the degree of inefficiency of the
natural rate of output.

4
contrast shocks that alter the economy’s technologically-feasible production possibilities frontier (the
efficient level of output) with markup shocks. Blanchard and Gali (2007, 38) offer as an example of
the former a shock to the physical inputs in the production function (9), where M t is an input and

N t is labor input.

(9)

yt  M t Nt1
A disturbance to the efficient level of output, shown in (9) by changes in M t , alters equally

the natural (flexible-price-equilibrium) level of output ( y n ) along with the efficient level of output.
In response, the central bank should maintain the price level constant and keep the output gap at zero.
The normative guide for the central bank remains divine coincidence. In contrast, a markup
disturbance makes it optimal for a central bank to engineer transitory inflation or deflation. Because
such a shock changes the flexible-price level of output without changing the efficient level of output,
maintaining price stability and keeping the output gap equal to zero increases the welfare-relevant
output gap. The central bank should use its power to affect real variables due to nominal price
rigidities in order to offset the effects of such a shock on output.8
Equation (10) adds a money demand function.

(10) mt  pt  yt  it

The log of nominal money is mt , the log of the price level is pt , and the semi-elasticity of money
demand with respect to the interest rate is  . In order to avoid the need for the price level to change,
the central bank must follow a rule that causes nominal money, mt , to grow commensurately with
real money demand, yt   it . The divine-coincidence characteristic of the NK model elucidates that
rule. With an interest rate target, nominal money is demand determined. A rule like (7) disciplines
that nominal demand to equal ytn   rt n . That fact is important for understanding the monetary
control procedures of the Bundesbank before 1999 and for interpreting money as an indicator.
2. Identification of the central bank’s reaction function
Giving empirical content to a general policy rule in a way that distinguishes between (6) and
(7) over different intervals of time entails the interaction of the model and empirical generalization
based on observation of the policy process.9 The challenge arises because central banks do not
characterize their actions as emerging from a rule.
8

A monetarist position is that the central bank lacks the knowledge of the structure of the economy
required in order to implement (7) in a way that trades off between inflation and an output gap. Also,
in a repeated game, monopolists would come to anticipate inflation engineered by the central bank.
For the purposes of this paper, it is not necessary to take a stand on the issue of whether a central
bank in practice could actually implement a rule like (7) without destabilizing the economy.
9

There is a vast empirical Taylor-rule literature. While this work contains many useful insights, the
resulting reduced-forms fail to capture the key role played by the monitoring by central banks of
financial markets, especially, with respect to inflationary expectations and with respect to the way in
which the term structure of interest rates moves in response both to incoming “news” on the
economy and to the policy actions of the central bank.

5

Guidance from the model starts with the reasons for abandoning the standard IS-LM/
Phillips-curve-augmented model of the 1970s in favor of the NK model. In the post-World War II
period, many countries experimented with aggregate-demand policies designed to engineer low,
stable unemployment. Based on period-by-period discretion, policy makers attempted to trade off
achievement of low unemployment against the cost in terms of inflation using a Phillips curve
relationship (Hetzel 2008a, 2013a and 2013b). The repeated failures of aggregate-demand
management produced the intellectual sea change that encouraged work on the NK model.
The NK model explains how central banks controlled inflation after the disinflations of the
early 1980s without recourse to Phillips curve trade-offs instead relying on the way in which rules
shape the behavior of forward-looking agents. The policy rule aligns the expectation of inflation of
firms in the sticky-price sector with the inflation target. In the 1980s, central banks moved to the
control of trend inflation through creation of an environment of nominal expectational stability that
conditioned the way in which firms set prices for multiple periods. Second, the model limits the
class of shocks whose impact on output could in principle be ameliorated through exploitation of an
inflation-output trade-off. In the 1980s, central banks adopted rules that allowed the price system to
work unhindered by causing the interest-rate target to track the natural rate of interest.10
Organization of empirical generalizations about the actual rule usefully begins with the
problems the central bank must solve given its use of a short-term interest rate as the policy variable.
To start, central bankers lack a detailed, structural model (a large-scale econometric model) of the
economy capable of identifying the natural (flexible-price) values for variables such as the real rate
of interest, unemployment, and potential output (equivalently the output gap). 11 Policy debates are
not structured around forming a consensus over numerical gaps between actual and natural values of
output, employment, and the real interest rate as the basis for an analytical determination of the rate
target. Standard procedure is to raise the rate target above its prevailing value if output is growing at
a rate that strains rates of resource utilization, and conversely. Former FOMC chairman William
McChesney Martin termed these procedures “lean-against-the-wind” (LAW).
The choice of a short-term interest rate as the target variable creates another problem because
the transmission of monetary policy depends upon the behavior of the entire term structure of interest
rates. An essential ingredient of the rule followed by the central bank is communication of the
degree of persistence the central bank intends to impart to changes in its rate target. The starting
point is the LAW practice of constraining the sign of changes in the rate target to be either positive or
negative over significant intervals of time with inflection points occurring only infrequently. One
way that central banks communicate the extent of their concern about the strength or weakness in the
economy and thus the degree of persistence markets should expect in changes in the rate target is by
accompanying changes with discount rate changes.
10

On the move to rule-based policies designed to shape inflationary expectations in contrast to the
earlier policies based on exploiting Phillips-curve trade-offs, see Hetzel (1986, 2008a, 2012a),
Goodfriend (2004), and Goodfriend and King (2005).
11

Forecasts from quarterly, structural models of the economy can help in organizing forecasts given
the discipline they impose on making an overall estimate of growth consistent with sectoral
estimates. However, such models require continual ad hoc adjustments in order to make reasonable
near-term forecasts and exhibit forecast errors only slightly lower than rule-of-thumb forecasts
(Hetzel 2012b).

6

What imparted the distinctive character to LAW procedures subsequent to the disinflations of
the early 1980s was the way that central banks monitored financial markets for stability of
inflationary expectations. (See Goodfriend 1993 on inflation scares.) The commitment to maintain
the expectation of low, stable inflation required communication of a commitment to effect whatever
cumulative increase in the policy rate was required in response to above-trend growth in output in
order to prevent trend inflation from rising above target. Analogous statements hold for the
occurrence of sustained weakness. Hetzel (2006, 2008a, Ch. 13-15 and 21; 2008b) termed these
procedures “lean-against-the-wind with credibility,” or LAW with credibility and associated them
with the Great Moderation, which followed the disinflations of the early 1980s.
The identification assumption made here is that LAW with credibility implements (6).
Although central banks do not maintain stability of the price level, LAW with credibility maintains
the expectation of inflation equal to their inflation target. With this rule, they do not respond to
fluctuations in headline inflation, which contains significant noise from the flexible-price sector.
However, maintaining expected inflation equal to the inflation target keeps core inflation (ex food
and energy) quite steady. The LAW search procedure for moving the rate target causes the real
interest rate to track the natural rate. As shown in (4), causing the real rate to track the natural rate
stabilizes the output gap.
Central banks lack a direct measure of the term in (6) showing growth in expected natural
output ( Et ytn1 ). In practice, they estimate persistent changes in the output gap measured by
sustained changes in the degree of utilization of resources. LAW with credibility effectively assures
markets that changes in the policy rate will cumulate to whatever extent required to maintain equality
between Et yt 1 and Eytn1 , that is, between expected real growth and sustainable real growth. That
assurance causes the entire term structure of interest rates to respond to incoming information on the
economy in a stabilizing way reflecting changes in real forward rates not inflation premia.
The empirical association of LAW with credibility with (6) allows identification of the
departures represented by (8). In practice, departures have typically occurred when central banks
became concerned with inflation. In that event, they raised their policy rates until the economy
weakened and then maintained a cyclically high level of rates while it weakened. Although central
banks do not use the language of trade-offs, they attempted to create a negative output gap in order to
lower inflation. An analogous statement holds for times when unemployment was the main concern.
Departures from (6) appear in the data as inertia in the policy rate relative to cyclical turning points
(Hetzel 2008a, Ch. 23-25 and 2012a, Ch. 8).
3. The Bundesbank and LAW with credibility
Bundesbank policy after 1980 provides an example of a rule intended to accomplish the
divine-coincidence result. After floating the Mark upon leaving the Bretton Woods system in March
1973, the Bundesbank adopted a target for “central bank money” (akin to the monetary base).
However, the governments of Chancellors Brandt and Schmidt favored a policy of full employment.
During the 1970s, the Bundesbank engaged in a “dirty float” in which it resisted an appreciation of
the mark against the dollar through lowering interest rates (von Hagen 1999).
The creation of the European Monetary System (EMS) of fixed exchange rates in March
1979 with the prospect it carried for lowering interest rates in order to defend the exchange rate

7
against the mark of weaker currencies like the French franc consolidated opinion within the
Bundesbank in favor of a policy of price stability organized around money targets. That policy
allowed the Bundesbank to rally public opinion against the government’s desire to subordinate policy
to the EMS system. The Bundesbank then emerged as the dominant central bank in the EMS system
with the mark as the anchor currency (von Hagen 1999, Hetzel 2002). The initiation of money
targets as a credible device for signaling the Bundesbank’s commitment to price stability began with
the reduction in the announced money range in 1979 (Baltensperger 1999).12
In the 1980s, the Bundesbank derived its money target using the equation of exchange.
Critically, it used as a measure for output growth an estimate of potential growth taken to be 2
percent. In 1985, it combined that measure with a low value of its inflation target intended to
approximate price stability. When combined, these two measures expressed “the estimated growth of
potential output in nominal terms” (Baltensperger 1999, 458).13 That formulation highlighted the
intention of the Bundesbank to cause aggregate nominal expenditure to grow in line with potential
output as the prerequisite for price stability. Although the Bundesbank never adopted the targeting
procedures recommended by monetarists using a reserves/money multiplier, its procedures captured
the spirit of the Friedman (1960) k-percent rule for money but with the goal of stabilizing nominal
output growth at a noninflationary rate. In doing so, it not only accorded primacy to the inflation
target but also precluded the pursuit of objectives based on a strategy of manipulating output gaps.
The money targets were never operational intermediate targets chosen to achieve the inflation
objective, set at 2% starting in 1986. The Bundesbank established wide bands (3 percentage points)
for its money targets and in practice missed its targets as often as it achieved them. 14 Nevertheless,
the money targets rendered the inflation target credible through the seriousness with which the
Bundesbank explained misses.15
Operating procedures focused on a short-term market interest rate encased in a corridor. The
upper limit was the Lombard rate, which allowed for bank borrowing in the event of financial
stringency. The lower limit was the Discount rate, which allowed for short-term, rationed borrowing.
The Bundesbank controlled a day-to-day money market rate using the rate set on repurchase
agreements. It “steered” the market’s expectation of the persistence of the short-term rate through
accompanying changes in the repurchase rate with changes in the Lombard and Discount rates and
through the maturity of the repurchase agreements into which it entered.

12

Unlike the ECB in 2008, the Bundesbank in the 1980s and 1990s never experienced a persistent
inflation shock that raised headline inflation above core inflation. It never had to decide between
targeting core and headline inflation.
Neumann (1997, 178) wrote, “[T]he target rate of monetary expansion is based on the
Bundesbank’s expectations about the rate of change of normal output and the trend rate of change in
velocity rather than on the expected actual changes of output and velocity.”
13

Neumann (1997, 186) found “that the midpoint [money] target range has no predictive value for
actual money growth….”
14

“[T]he announcement of the monetary target … anchors their [economic agents] expectations. For
the central bank, this at the same time implies a binding commitment and an obligation to justify any
failure to meet the target” (Baltensperger 1999, 452). See also Beyer et al (2013, 320) and
Schlesinger (2002).
15

8
LAW with credibility provides a natural characterization of Bundesbank policy. The money
targets communicated the commitment to follow a rule that stabilized inflation and, as a result,
provided a nominal anchor through the way in which they tied down the expectation of inflation.16
In the context of nominal expectational stability, the Bundesbank moved its rate target in order to
counter unsustainable weakness and strength in the economy. 17 Baltensperger (1999, 455 and 461)
provided an example of the LAW character of policy:
[I]n the course of 1982 the German economy suffered … a further cyclical setback…. Real
GDP contracted by 0.9 percent in 1982, employment fell, and the unemployment rate rose to
6.7 per cent…. [T]he Bundesbank oriented its monetary policy … towards bolstering
economic recovery, cutting interest rates repeatedly in 1982 and at the start of 1983…. [I]n
1983 MI expanded by 8 per cent [above the targeted range of 4% to 7%].
4. Using the NK model to organize a narrative account of the Great Recession
Adjusted for the fact that central banks target inflation rather than price stability, the class of
rules represented by (6) implies maintenance by the central bank of trend inflation equal to target
through credibility for a rule that controls the price setting of firms in the sticky-price sector while
allowing the price system to work unhindered in order to determine real variables. In contrast, (7) is
consistent with departures from this benchmark that incorporate an attempt to control inflation
through manipulation of an output gap. Initially, the monetary policy of the ECB, like the
Bundesbank, followed the spirit of (6). As shown in Figure 2, expected inflation remained close to
the ECB’s objective of 2% or somewhat less until 2014. As shown in Figure 3, after 2000 and before
2009, core inflation never deviated more than about half a percentage point from target. Figure 4
shows Eurozone inflation and the ECB’s policy rate (the MRO or main-refinancing-operations rate).
For most of the decade until fall 2000, there is little detectable relationship between the two series.
Because of its credibility, the ECB had the latitude to pursue a LAW policy of responding in
a consistent way to growth gaps. Figure 5 plots changes in the ECB’s MRO policy rate as a bar
chart. As a measure of economic activity, it also plots the growth rate in real retail sales. 18 The two
periods of increases in the MRO rate (2/2000 to 10/2000 and 12/2005 to 6/2007) correspond to
increases in the growth rate of the economy measured by retail sales strong enough to lower the
unemployment rate (Figure 6). The two periods of decreases in the MRO rate (5/2001 to 11/2001
and 12/2002 and 6/2003) correspond to growth in retail sales weak enough to raise the
unemployment rate.
Aastrup and Jensen (2010) offer econometric support for the characterization of ECB
procedures until the Great Recession as LAW with credibility:

16

See also Neumann (1997, 197).

17

That is, the Bundesbank ignored estimates of output gaps but moved its rate target in response to
growth gaps. Beyer et al (2013, 335) wrote, “[T]he response to the perceived output gap … is close
to zero and insignificant under monetary targeting…. [T]he coefficient on the output growth gap …
becomes highly significant.”
Use of either the Markit purchasing manager’s index (PMI) or industrial production as measures of
economic activity yields similar graphs.
18

9
We show that the ECB’s interest rate changes during 1999-2010 have been mainly driven by
changes in economic activity in the Euro area. Changes in actual or expected future HICP
inflation play a minor, if any, role.
As shown in Figure 7, which graphs the CRB Commodity Spot Price Index, commodity
prices increased significantly over the interval from late 2003 to mid-2008.19 Starting in late 2007,
this commodity price inflation passed into headline inflation (Figure 3). 20 The commodity-price
shock that affected the euro-area economy in 2007 and 2008 was an adverse terms-of-trade shock
that acted like a negative technology shock. As Blanchard and Gali (2007, 36) noted, “The effects of
changes in factors such as the price of oil or the level of technology appear through their effects on
natural output” [ ytn ] . In (9), M t declined in a persistent way.
The ECB then raised rather than lowered its policy rate as the economy weakened. In July
2008, the ECB raised its MRO rate from 4.0% to 4.25%. In 2008 while economic activity declined,
the ECB raised rather than lowered its policy rate (Figure 5). Moreover, the ECB’s communications
caused markets to anticipate increases in rates. Figure 8, which plots the difference between 12month and 1-month Euribor rates, shows that until the end of 2008 markets expected a significant
increase in rates. After economic recovery commenced in mid-2009, markets again expected an
increase in rates. Only in mid-2012 did they reverse that expectation.21 As shown in Figure 5, the
smoothed year-over-year change in real retail sales, which began to weaken after August 2007, fell to
-1.6 in August 2008. The ECB lowered rates only when headline inflation fell (Figures 4 and 5).
The ECB explained the motivation for its actions by a concern that high headline inflation
would exacerbate wage demands of French and German unions.22 Wage inflation (year-over-year in
the business sector) had increased from 3% over the interval 2003Q1 through 2006Q1 to 5.1% in
2008Q1. In terms of the model, one can interpret ECB actions as reflecting the belief that this wage
19

The growth of emerging-market economies, especially, China, India, and Brazil accounted for the
increase in the relative price of commodities. For example, in 2000, China accounted for 12% of
global consumption of copper. In 2012, the number had grown to 42% (Financial Times, 6/3/13).
See Eickmeier and Kűhnlenz 2013.
20

Initially, the commodity-price shock did not pass through to headline inflation (Figure 3). One
explanation is an offsetting negative inflation shock in the form of an appreciation of the euro. From
2002 until mid-2008, the euro appreciated from less than .9 dollars/euro to almost 1.6 dollars/euro.
21

Plausibly, a rate difference between 25 and 50 basis points represents a liquidity premium.

22

See Financial Times (6/5/13, 8). Lucas Papademos (2013, 510), vice president of the ECB,
explained, “For more than a year after the outbreak of the global financial crisis, the ECB did not
ease monetary policy, as determined by its key interest rates, mainly because it was concerned about
the materialization of second-round effects of supply shocks on wage- and price-setting and the
potential unanchoring of inflation expectations.” The ECB (July 2008, 6) noted at the time: “This
worrying level of inflation rates results largely from sharp increases in energy and food prices at the
global level…. There is a … very strong concern that price and wage-setting behaviour could add to
inflationary pressures via broadly based second-round effects.”
In order to have facilitated the change in the internal terms of trade between the core countries of the
Eurozone with the peripheral countries required by the cessation of capital flows into the latter, the
ECB should have allowed higher price and wage inflation in the core countries like Germany.

10
inflation would increase inflation in the sticky-price sector. It could not have reflected concern for a
transitory increase in monopoly power (a positive markup shock) because the ECB did not raise its
inflation target as provided for by (7).
A normative assessment of ECB policy entails a difficult counterfactual. In the absence of
contractionary monetary policy, perhaps union demands for higher wages in order to compensate for
high headline inflation would have passed into inflation in the sticky-price sector. A positive
analysis of the cause of the Great Recession, however, highlights the inertia in the policy rate relative
to the decline in economic activity.23 The ECB created a negative output gap when a negative termsof-trade shock required a lower real rate in order to prevent emergence of a negative output gap.
The negative impact of the shock on households appears in the way in which the jump in
commodity price inflation reduced the real income of households. Figure 9 shows the cessation in
2007Q2 of the prior steady increase in real disposable income. Growth in real consumption peaked
in 2007Q3.24 Consumer confidence (Economic Sentiment Indicator) peaked in May 2007 and then
fell rapidly25. The resulting pessimism of households about their future income prospects required a
lower real interest rate.26 The decline in 2009 in both core inflation and in real output with the latter
accompanied by an increase in the unemployment rate (Figures 1, 3, and 6) is consistent with
contractionary monetary policy.
The monetary-contraction explanation of the Great Recession has the advantage of simplicity
in that the same hypothesis explains the occurrence of back-to-back recessions. The euro and world
economies began to recover in mid-2009. In the past, strong recoveries had followed deep
recessions. However, growth in real GDP peaked in 2011Q1 (Figure 1). In the second recession, a
sequence of events unfolded in a way similar to the first recession.
When the world economy began to revive, commodity price inflation rose and again raised
headline inflation. Turmoil in the Middle East starting in early 2011 also caused oil prices to rise.
CPI inflation, which had fallen to -.5% in 2009, rose to 3% by end-2011. Core inflation also rose but
remained below the ECB’s 2% target (Figure 3). The second commodity-price shock intensified the
As shown in (4), the central bank can keep the real rate above the natural rate ( rt  rt n ) by creating
a strong contemporaneous negative output gap that causes households to anticipate a return of output
to a higher, normal level. Another possible factor in maintaining cyclically high real rates at the start
of a recession is a household utility function containing as an argument negatively-signed
consumption growth. That is, the difficulty of adjusting to a lower level of consumption offsets the
desire of households to save despite increased pessimism about future consumption prospects.
23

24

Over the interval 2004Q4 through 2007Q3, real personal consumption (PCE) expenditures grew at
an annualized rate of 2%. Annualized real PCE growth then declined as follows: 1.4% (2007Q4),
.2% (2008Q1), -.3% (2008Q2), and -1.2% (2008Q3).
25
26

Data from Economic and Financial Affairs page of the European Commission website.

Although not incorporated into the model, it is plausible to conjecture that tail risk of a disastrous
outcome due to the possible breakup of the Eurozone in 2011 and 2012 and later concern over
inability of the ECB to conduct expansionary monetary policy through a QE (quantitative easing)
policy of buying government debt exacerbated pessimism about future growth. For a discussion of
how disaster risk can lower the natural rate of interest, see Rietz (1988).

11
ongoing decline in real disposable income. Consumption, which had been recovering slowly, again
began to decline after 2010Q4 (Figure 9). Real retail sales peaked in September 2010 (Figure 5).
The growth rate of real aggregate demand (final sales to domestic purchasers) began falling after
2011Q1.27 Similarly to 2008, concentrating on the increase in headline inflation, the ECB raised its
policy rates twice in 2011, from 1% to 1.25% in April and then to 1.5% in July (Figures 4 and 5).
The monetary-contraction explanation has another advantage in that it possesses implications
for money growth and inflation: both should decline.28 The monetary aggregate M1 is used here
under the assumption that it offers a better measure of transactions demand than M3, which includes
a significant amount of debt instruments.29 Banks issue debt to finance loan growth when loan
demand is high. As shown in Figure 10, apart from 2002-2003 and 2012-2013 when banks made up
for weak loan demand by holding more government securities, M3 growth and loan growth move
together. For this reason, it is hard to disentangle causation between growth in M3 and in the
economy. M3 is a contemporaneous indicator of the economy.
M1 growth slowed starting in 2006Q3 and slowed sharply starting in 2007Q4 (Figure 11).30
Real GDP growth declined from an annualized growth rate of 2.2% in 2008Q1 to -1.5% in 2008Q2.
After falling to near zero in 2008Q3, M1 growth revived. Real GDP growth reached a trough in
2009Q1 with annualized growth of -10.8%. M1 growth fell sharply starting in 2010Q3. Real GDP
growth declined from an annualized growth rate of 2.9% in 2011Q1 to -1.2% in 2011Q4.
Unfortunately, the signal to noise ratio is low for the monetary aggregates. In a time of
financial turmoil when market participants desire liquidity, they transfer out of the illiquid debt
instruments in the non-M1 part of M3 into the liquid demand deposits of M1. From fall 2008
through 2009, investors transferred out of illiquid deposits and debt instruments into demand deposits
and inflated M1 without any implications for the stance of monetary policy. One is on firmer ground
27

Final sales to domestic purchasers is GDP minus the change in inventories minus exports plus
imports. It is a measure of domestic demand while GDP is a measure of output. From 2010Q2
through 2011Q1, real final sales to domestic purchasers grew at an annualized rate of 2.3%. In
2011Q2, growth fell to -.9%.
28

As noted in Section 1, if the central bank follows a rule intended to implement the divinecoincidence outcome, given its interest rate target, the real quantity of money demanded causes
nominal money to grow at a rate consistent with price stability. In this environment, money offers no
information about the evolution of the economy. However, if the central bank interferes with the
unhindered operation of the price system and creates a difference between the natural and real rates
of interest, the behavior of money becomes informative.
29

M1 includes currency in circulation and overnight deposits. M3 includes M1 plus time deposits
with maturity up to 2 years, deposits redeemable given notification up to 3 months, repurchase
agreements, money market fund shares, and debt instruments with maturity up to 2 years.
In May 2003, the ECB demoted the behavior of money (M3) to a “cross-check” from one of its
two “pillars,” the other pillar being the behavior of the economy (Deutsche Bank 2013). For
example, the Editorial in the July 2010 ECB Monthly Bulletin (ECB 2010, 6) noted, “[T]he annual
growth rate of M3 was unchanged at -.2% in May 2010…. [T]hese data continue to support the
assessment that the underlying pace of monetary expansion is moderate and that inflationary
pressures over the medium term are contained.” The ECB Governing Council left its policy rates
unchanged.
30

12
using M1 growth as a measure of the stance of monetary policy in the first half of 2008 when growth
in M1 and M3 both declined and after May 2010 through early 2012 when M1 growth declined while
M3 growth remained low (Figure 12).
A monetarist explanation of the Great Recession does not raise problems presented by the
common explanation based on an unwinding of speculative excess. Figure 13 shows real house
prices for a number of countries. Nothing in the series suggests speculative excess for the Eurozone
as a whole. The most commonly expressed explanation for the Great Recession centers on a collapse
of speculative excess originating in the peripheral countries. Constâncio (2014, 251) pointed to
“imbalances [that] originated mostly from rising private sector expenditures, which were in turn
financed by the banking sectors….”31 As elaborated by Honkapohja (2014, 261-2), “The emergence
of a boom-bust cycle” resulted from “the disappearance of interest rate differentials between
members of the euro area” which resulted in the “mispricing of risk that characterized the years
leading to the financial crisis—a bubble not unlike the subprime bubble…. [T]he convergence of
interest rates to low levels provided incentives for countries and private agents in the GIIPS countries
to borrow a lot.”32
This explanation suggests both that the initial decline in output should have started in the
peripheral countries (the GIIPS) and spread subsequently to the core countries and that the decline in
output should have been significantly more pronounced in the GIIPS.33 As shown in Figure 14,
growth in real GDP did decline somewhat faster in the GIIPS than in the core countries, but until late
2009 the behavior of output was quite similar in the two sets of countries.
Possibly, a debt crisis could have disrupted financial intermediation throughout the Eurozone.
The Lehman Brothers bankruptcy on September 15, 2008, precipitated a run of cash investors who
ceased funding financial institutions with long-term, illiquid mortgage assets (Hetzel 2012a, Ch. 13).
However, the euro area economy had already entered into recession by then with real GDP falling at
annualized rates of -1.5% and -2.4% in 2008Q2 and 2008Q3, respectively. Industrial production
including construction peaked in February 2008.
In contrast, loan growth remained healthy even while the economy entered recession. Loans
to the private sector from banks (monetary financial institutions or MFI) averaged 10.7% year-overyear from May 2006 through May 2008 (Figure 10). Only in June 2008, did loan growth begin to
fall below 10%.34 Similarly, after the recovery took hold in 2009Q3, loan growth recovered steadily
31

For the Eurozone, government debt as a percent of GDP declined from 81% in 2005 to 74% in
early 2008.
32

GIIPS refers to Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain. Vitor Constâncio was vice president of
the ECB. Seppo Honkapohja was a member of the Board of the Bank of Finland.
33

The core countries are Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and the Netherlands.

34

In an environment of contemporaneously weakening economic activity and falling loan demand, it
is hard to disentangle the causal impact on bank lending due to tightening lending standards. The
July 2008 “Euro Area Bank Lending Survey” (European Central Bank 2008) reported:
The most important factor in the net tightening continued to be a deterioration in expectations
about the economic outlook…. Banks reported that net demand for loans to enterprises and
households continued to be negative in the second quarter of 2008.

13
until peaking in 2011Q3 and then declining sharply. In contrast, the recovery in domestic demand
aborted earlier. As noted in footnote 18, growth in real final sales to domestic purchasers fell from
2.3% over the 2010Q2 to 2011Q1 interval to -.9% in 2011Q2.
There is little evidence that the subprime crisis disrupted financial intermediation. In August
2007, cash investors ceased buying the commercial paper issued by banks to finance the holding of
subprime mortgages in off-balance-sheet entities called structured investment vehicles or SIVs
(Hetzel 2012a, 179). European as well as American banks held many of these mortgages (Hetzel
2012a, 242). Uncertainty over the extent to which individual European banks held such mortgages
lessened the willingness of European banks to lend to each other in the interbank market. Instead of
relying on short-term loans to meet liquidity needs, European banks began to hold additional excess
reserves (Heider et al 2009). The ECB accommodated that increased demand. The Eonia rate (the
euro equivalent of the funds rate) remained fixed at the ECB’s MRO rate. Through its swap lines,
the Fed provided the dollars to the ECB that it relent to European banks to replace the dollar funding
no longer supplied by cash investors (Hetzel 2012a, 244 and 267). In short, central banks made
certain that funding pressures on European banks did not affect their intermediation function.
Attribution of the Eurozone recession to a debt crisis received popular support from events
occurring from mid-summer 2011 to mid-summer 2012 when investors fled the sovereign debt
markets of Italy and Spain. Attribution of the renewal of recession to this debt crisis, however,
conflicts with the timing of events. Sovereign credit default swap spreads for Italy and Spain started
their climb to alarming levels in mid-2011. In early July 2011, the spread of two-year yields on
Italian over German debt climbed above 2% and reached 7% in late November 2011. However, the
Eurozone economy had already begun to weaken after 2011Q1. The timing suggests causation going
from the economic weakness to a debt crisis rather than the other way around.35
5. Concluding comment
The NK model distinguishes between two categories of shocks with different implications for
monetary policy. With shocks to tastes and technology, the central bank should concentrate on the
objective of price stability in the sticky-price sector (stability of core inflation) while allowing the
price system to work unhindered to maintain the output gap at zero. With markup shocks, the central
bank can in principle improve welfare by trading off between the objectives of price stability and a
zero output gap.
In 2008 and again in 2011, in response to a negative technology shock in the form of a
commodity-price shock, the ECB created a negative output gap in order to prevent the accompanying
high headline inflation from passing into inflation in the sticky-price sector. It did not allow the price
system to work unhindered in order to keep the output gap at zero. Contractionary monetary policy
as the explanation of the Great Recession has the advantage that it explains both cycle peaks and
predicts the decline in both output and inflation that followed.

35

The spread in the interest rates on loans made to corporations in Germany and France compared to
Italy and Spain only began to widen in July 2011along with, not prior to, the end of recovery from
the first recession. In 2011, the unemployment rate rose sharply in Italy and was already above 20%
in Spain. Plausibly, this interest rate spread reflected a normal risk premium and was therefore not
indicative of a failure of financial intermediation.

14
References
Aastrup, Morten and Henrik Jensen. “What Drives the European Central Bank’s Interest-Rate
Changes?” University of Copenhagen, November 2010.
Baltensperger, Ernst. “Monetary Policy under Conditions of Increasing Integration (1979-96).” in
Fifty Years of the Deutsche Mark. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.
Beyer, Andreas; Vitor Gaspar; Christina Gerberding; and Otmar Issing. “Opting Out of the Great
Inflation: German Monetary Policy after the Breakdown of Bretton Woods.” in The Great
Inflation: The Rebirth of Modern Central Banking, Michael D. Bordo and Athanasios
Orphanides, eds. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2013, 301-346.
Blanchard, Olivier and Jordi Gali. “Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keynesian Model.” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 39 (February 2007), 35-65.
Chari, V. V.; Patrick J. Kehoe, and Ellen R. McGrattan. “New Keynesian Models: Not Yet Useful for
Policy Analysis.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (January 2009), 242-66.
Constâncio, Vitor. “The European Crisis and the Role of the Financial System.” Journal of
Macroeconomics 39 (March 2014), 260-271.
Deutsche Bank Research. Focus Europe. “ECB reaction function(s).” September 13, 2013.
Eickmeier, Sandra and Markus Kűhnlenz. “China’s Role in Global Inflation Dynamics.” Deutsche
Bundesbank Discussion Paper, No. 07/2013.
European Central Bank. “Editorial.” Monthly Bulletin, July 2008, 5-8.
_____. “Editorial.” Monthly Bulletin, July 2010, 5-8.
_____. The Euro Area Bank Lending Survey, July 2008.
Financial Times. “Beijing returns to global metals market.” June 3, 2013, 15.
_____. “ECB’s untimely change of mind.” June 5, 2013, 8.
Friedman, Milton. “The Methodology of Positive Economics.” in Milton Friedman, ed., Essays in
Positive Economics. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1953.
_____. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press, 1960.
_____. “The Quantity Theory of Money.” in John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds.,
The New Palgrave Money. New York: W. W. Norton, 1989, 1-40.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Gali, Jordi. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New
Keynesian Framework. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2008.
Goodfriend, Marvin. “Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem.” Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Economic Quarterly 79 (Winter 1993), 1-24.
_____. “The Monetary Policy Debate since October 1979: Lessons for Theory and Practice.” in
“Reflections on Monetary Policy: 25 Years after October 1979.” Conference at Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October 7 -8, 2004.

15
Goodfriend, Marvin and Robert G. King. “The New Neoclassical Synthesis.” NBER
Macroeconomics Annual, eds. Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, 1997.
_____. “The Incredible Volcker Disinflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52, (July 2005), 9811015.
Hagen, Jűrgen von. “A New Approach to Monetary Policy (1971-8).” in Deutsche Bundesbank, ed.,
Fifty Years of the Deutsche Mark.” 1999, 403-38.
Heider, Florian; Marie Hoerova, and Cornelius Holthausen. “Liquidity Hoarding and Interbank
Market Spreads: The Role of Counterparty Risk.” Working Paper Series No. 1126, European
Central Bank, December 2009.
Hetzel, Robert L. “Monetary Policy in the Early 1980s.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review 72 (March/April 1986), 20-32.
_____. “German Monetary History in the Second Half of the Twentieth Century: From the Deutsche
Mark to the Euro.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 88 (Spring
2002), 29-64.
_____. “Making the Systematic Part of Monetary Policy Transparent.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 92 (Summer 2006), 255-90.
_____. The Monetary Policy of the Federal Reserve: A History. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2008a.
_____. “What Is the Monetary Standard, Or, How Did the Volcker-Greenspan FOMC’s Tame
Inflation?” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 94 (Spring 2008b), 147171.
_____. The Great Recession: Market Failure or Policy Failure? Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2012a.
_____. “Central Bank Accountability and Independence: Are They Inconsistent?” Journal of
Macroeconomics 34 (March 2012b), 616-25.
_____. “The Monetarist-Keynesian Debate and the Phillips Curve: Lessons from the Great Inflation.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 99 (Second Quarter 2013a), 83-116.
_____. “The Great Inflation of the 1970s.” in Randall Parker and Robert Whaples, eds., The
Handbook of Major Events in Economic History. New York, NY and Oxford,
UK: Routledge. 223-238, 2013b.
Honkapohja, Seppo. “The Euro Area Crisis: A View from the North.” Journal of Macroeconomics
39 (March 2014), 260-271.
Mankiw, Gregory N. and Ricardo Reis. “What Measure of Inflation Should a Central Bank Target?”
Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (September 2003), 1058-1086.
Neumann, Manfred J. M. “Monetary Targeting in Germany.” in ed. Iwao Kuroda. Towards More
Effective Monetary Policy. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1997, 176-198.
Papademos, Lucas. “The Great Inflation: Lessons for Central Banks.” in Bordo, Michael D. and
Athanasios Orphanides, eds. The Great Inflation: The Rebirth of Modern Central Banking.
New York and London: The University of Chicago Press, 2013, 503-511.
Rietz, Thomas A. “The Equity Risk Premium: A Solution.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22
(1988), 117-131.

16
Schlesinger, Helmut. “The Bundesbank and Its Money Supply.” in B. Scheffold, ed., Exogeneity and
Endogeneity—The Money Supply in the History of Economic Thought and in Modern Policy.
Marburg: Metropolis Varlag, 2002.

17

18

19

20

21

22

23