View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

A Framework for the Analysis of
Moderate Inflations

WP 97-04

This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/

Marvin Goodfriend
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Working Paper 97-4

A Framework for the Analysis of Moderate Inflations
Marvin Goodfriend*
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, P.O. Box 27622, Richmond, VA 23261
(First Version: March 1995)

Abstract
Optimal monetary policy is studied in a model with no contractual restrictions or physical costs of changing prices. Nevertheless, the price level is sticky
in a range of markup indeterminacy, and inflation occurs only when employment
presses against capacity. Under full information, the monetary authority can exploit price level stickiness to minimize the markup and keep employment at a
constrained optimum without inflation. Under uncertainty, negative aggregate
demand shocks produce real contractions and positive shocks raise the price level.
The monetary authority can raise the likelihood that aggregate demand will maximize employment, but at the cost of higher expected inflation.
Key Words: Optimal Monetary Policy, Inflation, Unemployment
JEL classification: E3, E4, E5

”

*The paper was prepared for the March 1995 Swiss National Bank Conference on “Rules versus Discretion in Monetary Policy.” It is forthcoming in the
Journal of Monetary Economics. The paper has benefitted from presentations at
the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve Board, the Federal Reserve Research
Committee on Macroeconomics, the Norwegian School of Management, the University of Helsinki, the University of South Carolina, the University of Vienna,
and the Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania. I would like to thank
Philippe Bacchetta, Mark Bils, Clive Briault, Satyajit Chatterjee, Neil Ericsson,
Robert King, Jeff Lacker, Bennett McCallum, John McDermott, Tom Sargent,
and Alan Stockman for valuable comments. The views expressed here are mine
alone and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
or the Federal Reserve System.

1. Introduction
This paper proposes a new framework within which to understand, interpret, and
evaluate monetary policy that is consistent with some common experiences and
perceptions of central bankers, and can potentially serve as a conceptual basis
for policy analysis. The model embodies a simple capacity constraint that relates
inflation to excessive levels of employment, and it presents the policymaker with
a Phillips curve tradeoff between unemployment and inflation.
The model is neoclassical in spirit in that firms never face contractual restrictions or physical costs of changing prices. Yet the model is Keynesian in the sense
that the price level is sticky for some states of the economy and configuration of
shocks, Under perfect information about states and shocks, the monetary authority has the power to keep the economy at a constrained optimum.

However, in

contrast to the standard Keynesian model there is no benefit to inflation under
full information. The Phillips curve tradeoff arises only as a consequence of the
fact that the monetary authority is imperfectly informed about the current state
of the economy.
At the heart of the model is a market structure in which goods are produced
by a large number of monopolistically competitive firms facing demand curves

that are kinked because customers are imperfectly informed about individual f?rm
price changes. The resulting discontinuity in marginal revenue curves means that
there is a range of markup indeterminacy and a corresponding range in which
fums are satisfied to keep their prices constant in response to shifts in marginal
revenue and marginal cost.
Two pricing practices are assumed to accompany this market structure. Together, these constitute an equilibrium selection device for the economy. Pricing
Practice 1 says that the price level adjusts if and only if the representative firm
wishes to change its relative price to bring its markup into an acceptable range.
This first practice is a natural one if firms care only about relative prices. Pricing
Practice 2 says that firms change prices by the minimum amount necessary to
bring the markup into an acceptable range. This second practice selects a natural
focal point for firms to coordinate on when changing prices.
The market structure, together with the pricing practices, implies three pricing regimes. Prices are sustained at the previous period’s level if the “incipient
markup” -the

markup calculated for current variables at last period’s prices-

lies in the range of markup indeterminacy. When that is the case, the incipient
markup is sustained in equilibrium, and changes in the money stock exert strong
effects on employment.

On the other hand, when the incipient markup lies be2

low the minimum, firms raise prices until that minimum is attained.

Likewise,

firms lower their prices whenever the incipient markup lies above the acceptable
maximum.
Equilibrium employment and output are inversely related to the markup in
this model because the markup acts like a tax that drives a wedge between the
price of output and its marginal cost of production. The model implies that there
can be inflation only if employment presses against a “capacity constraint”, and
deflation only if there is a sufficiently large “output gap.”
The monetary authority maximizes the utility of the representative agent by
attempting to minimize the two distortions in the model: the markup and the
nominal interest rate.

A suitably deflationary money growth rate can sustain

a zero nominal interest rate. But the monetary authority must maximize the
markup distortion in order to eliminate the nominal interest rate distortion.
A monetary authority mainly interested in maximizing employment and output would minimize the markup. Under full information, it could sustain that
minimum exactly, without inflation, by exploiting the sticky price level within the
range of markup indeterminacy. Since inflation yields no benefits under full information, the monetary authority would also maintain price stability in order to
support the lowest nominal interest rate consistent with maximum employment.
3

A Phillips curve tradeoff emerges only as a result of the fact that the monetary
authority is imperfectly informed and cannot manage the markup exactly. The
tradeoff emerges because firms react asymmetrically to the incipient markup at
the boundary of the range of indeterminacy. If the incipient markup comes in
below the acceptable minimum, firms raise prices; if it comes in above, firms
do not change prices, the incipient markup is sustained, and employment and
output fall. Hence, uncertainty creates both inflation and unemployment risk for
a monetary authority targeting maximum employment and output.
The monetary authority can influence the balance of risks by its choice of
money stock relative to the previous period’s price level. Choosing a higher money
,
stock raises the probability that the incipient markup will lie below the minimum
acceptable to firms. That raises expected inflation-but

it also increases the prob-

ability that the actual markup will be minimized, and employment and output
maximized. Choosing a lower money stock reduces expected inflation, but raises
expected unemployment.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, the basic macroeconomic model
is presented for an exogenously given markup in order to illustrate core model
mechanics. We focus on the effect of the markup and the nominal interest rate
distortions on equilibrium work effort and transaction time allocations because
4

the two distortions are at the heart of the analysis of monetary policy in Section
4. Before leaving Section 2, we show that the steady state welfare cost of inflation
as a percent of GDP is proportional to the markup. We also compare the welfare
cost of inflation in the model to earlier estimates.
Section 3 introduces the monopolistically competitive market structure and the
pricing practices that serve as the equilibrium selection device. It then describes
the implied pricing regimes that underlie the endogenous behavior of the markup
and employment. It explains the dependence of the markup on aggregate demand,
and shows how the behavior of the markup governs inflation.
Optimal monetary policy is characterized in Section 4. Section 4.1 fixes ideas
by discussing optimal policy in a nonstochastic steady state. There are two contenders for welfare maximizing policy in this case: a deflationary Friedman Rule
and a Zero Inflation Rule. We compare them using the welfare cost of inflation
formula presented in Section 2.3. In Section 4.2, we characterize the optimal rule
when the monetary authority is incompletely informed.

We show how the in-

troduction of uncertainty presents the monetary authority with a Phillips curve
tradeoff that causes it to depart from zero inflation. Section 4.3 argues that the
optimal rule is sustainable in the model even in the absence of a commitment
technology.

Section 5 briefly addresses some aspects of the model in more detail, and
suggests some desirable extensions. A conclusion follows.

2. The Core Real Business Cycle Model
The core of the framework is a monopolistically competitive real business cycle
model in which capital is not present, The model is one in which employment and
output vary because of fluctuations in the markup of the price of output over its
marginal cost of production. The core macromodel closely parallel’s the standard
setup of Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987). A real business cycle interpretation is
adopted here because it simplifies the discussion of endogenous markup variation
later on. We abstract from capital because it is not central to the inflation and
unemployment issues that are the focus of the paper.
The real business cycle model is specified as follows.

Representative agent

utility depends on consumption (C) and leisure (L):

(1)

CZ(l + py[(l - 4) logG + dJ1% 4

Money is assumed to buy goods according to a transations technology that
relates holdings of real money balances (M/P)
6

and the fraction of “shopping

time” devoted to transacting (S) to the spending flow that the representative
agent carries out:

(2)

where k is a constant.

This constraint is a specialization of the McCallum-

Goodfriend (1987) shopping-time technology proposed and utilized in Lucas (1993,
1994). We assume that money may be acquired at the beginning of the period in
which it yields transaction services. However, money balances that yield transaction services in period’t must be carried into period t+l.
The production function for nonstorable output is:

(3)

Ct = Xt Nt”

where Nt is hours worked (employment), X t is a productivity coefficient, and
O<cr<l. There is also a time constraint:

1 = Lt + Nt + St

7

Agents begin period t with Mt-r units of money carried over from t-l, which
is augmented by a lump sum transfer Ht. They earn a real wage (W/P)

per hour

of work effort supplied to firms, and they own firms and receive all profits, i.e.,
the excess of revenue over wage payments. There is also a one-period nominal
bond that is purchased at price l/(l+Rt-1)

in period t-l and is redeemed for one

unit of money in period t. The number of bonds purchased in t-l and redeemed
in t is Bt-r. So the representative agent’s resource constraint in real terms is:

(5)

%,/P, + &/fi + &-I/P, + (W/P),N, + X, @ - (W/P),&

= (M/p>, + (B/P)J(l

- c,

+ &)

where Rt is the net interest rate on a one-period nominal bond carried from period
t into period t+l, and I’$ is the average economy-wide fraction of time w0rked.r
The representative agent maximizes

(1) subject to (2), (4), and (5). Forming

the Lagrangian with (5), and using (2) and (4) to substitute out for Ct and Lt,
the FOCs with respect to St, Nt, and Mt imply:

(6)

& (M/P), = (W/P), St
8

I-

(7)

Nt

- St = [d/(1 - #>]~G/(W/P>t]~1+

((W/P)t/k

@VW]

Condition (6) equates the marginal opportunity cost of transaction services from
another dollar to that from another minute of transaction time.2 Condition (7)
equates the marginal utility of leisure to the marginal utility of work effort, net
of transaction cost.
Define the (gross) markup, p, as the ratio of price to marginal cost. Take the
markup as exogenous for now. The markup will be endogenized when we specify
the market structure and the pricing practices in Section 3.
Expressed directly as price over marginal cost using (3), the markup is:

(8)

pt = P,/[W/C~W-~]

Rewriting (8), we can express the real wage in terms of the markup:

(9)

Expressions

(W/P>, = &N,Q-l/~t

(8) and (9) make clear that when the markup pushes price above
9

marginal cost, it also pushes the real wage below the marginal product of labor.
Solve for equilibrium employment (N) and transaction time (S) allocations as
follows. First, use (3) and (9) to yield:

(10)

(W/P>t/G = 4dh

Next, substitute (2) and (10) into (7) and derive:

(11)

where p/o

St,= 1 - 4 - [4((pt/c”)- 1) + l]Nt

> 1. Finally, use (2)) (6)) and (10) to arrive at:

Equations (11) and (12) can be solved for Nt and St as functions of pt and I&.
These dependencies are summarized as follows:3

(13)

Nt = N(pt,
- Rt)
-

10

The equilibrium demand for money is derived from (2) and (6) as:

(M/P), = J(W/P)tCt/kRt

(15)

Apart from the usual dependence on the transaction scale variable Ct and the
nominal interest rate, money demand is also positively related to the real wage,
The reason is that the real wage measures the consumption opportunity cost of
shopping time, so a higher real wage induces agents to substitute real money
balances for shopping time in the transaction technology.
In what follows it is useful to write money demand by using (10)to eliminate
(W/P),

(16)

in (15):

tM/p>t

= Ctj/~/WtRt

11

2.1. The Mechanics of the Markup
The effect of the markup on equilibrium employment is straightforward. When
the markup is unity, price equals marginal cost, the real wage equals the marginal
product of labor, and equilibrium employment is such that the private marginal
rate of substitution of consumption for leisure equals the marginal product of
labor.
A markup in excess of unity pushes the real wage below the marginal product
of labor, forces the private marginal rate of substitution of consumption for leisure
below the marginal product of labor, and reduces equilibrium employment. The
elasticity of employment with respect to the markup is greater in absolute value
the smaller the diminishing returns to labor and the larger the elasticity of labor
supply with respect to the real wage.
A markup in excess of unity can be interpreted either as a tax imposed by
firms on work effort or one imposed on output, whose proceeds firms distribute
as profits.

In effect, the imposition of a markup is a tax and transfer fiscal

policy administered by firms--one that has distortionary substitution effects but
no wealth effects. Equilibrium employment and consumption vary inversely with
the markup because there is only the negative substitution effect.

12

2.2. Steady State Growth
The model has a steady-state growth path in which time allocations are constant
and consumption grows at an exogenous trend rate of productivity growth, g.
The nominal interest rate in the steady state is therefore given approximately by:

R = P + 9 + E log (Pt+dPt>

where the last term denotes steady state expected inflation. By money demand
function (16), money growth governs steady-state inflation, and the level of the
nominal interest rate.

Expressions (13) and (14) determine steady state time

allocations for an exogenously given markup ~1and the nominal rate R consistent
with steady state money growth. Production function (3) and the productivity
growth trend then determine the consumption growth path; the money demand
function and the money supply path determine a path for the price level. Although
steady state output growth is given exogenously by g, the level of the path for
output varies with ~1and R through their effects on employment according to (13).

13

2.3. The Steady State Welfare Cost of Inflation
This section derives a formula for the welfare cost of inflation and shows the cost
to be proportional to the markup. By (12), S is t ime wasted from the social point
of view due to the fact that the nominal interest rate is not zero. The fraction
of time, S, spent economizing on money holding is, therefore, a direct measure of
the welfare cost of inflation. To measure the welfare cost as a percentage of GDP,
value S at the social opportunity cost of shopping time-the
labor-and

marginal product of

divide by GDP. Using (9) exp ress the steady state welfare cost as a

percentage of GDP: 100 x S (W/P)

p/C; and using (lo), write it as 100 x c&/N.

Substituting for S with (12) yields the welfare cost formula:

(18)

9 = 100 x (o/N)

,/m

In order to evaluate Q’, we need to calibrate the constant k. To do so use (6)
and (10) and eliminate S in (12) to express k as:

(1%

k = WPW/[R @‘W’)/C121~

To facilitate the comparison below to the welfare cost formula presented in Lucas
14

(1993)) calibrate k using his 1990 observations for the inverse Ml velocity and the
short-term interest rate in the U.S., 0.15 and 0.075, respectively. Doing so yields
k = 593 (ct/pN).
Substituting for k in (18) yields the welfare cost as a percentage of GDP
expressed as a function of R and 1-1:

(20)

@(R, /x) = 100 x ,~(O.O41)a

Welfare cost function (20) is exactly Lucas’s (1993) welfare cost of inflation formula for transaction technology (2) when the markup is unity.
To see why the welfare cost varies directly with the markup, recall that 9 =
100 x cyS/N. As discussed above, a higher markup reduces employment because
it amounts to a tax on work effort. A higher markup raises S as follows. First,
a higher markup lowers the real wage.

By (6), the lower opportunity cost of

shopping time causes agents to substitute money for time in transactions. Since
the percentage decline in C is less than the percentage decline in W/P,

S must

rise to satisfy transactions constraint (2).
Evidence regarding the size of the average markup in the U.S. economy is
reported, for instance, in Hall (1988), and Basu and Fernald (1994).
15

Although

Hall reports markups ranging from 1.8 to 3.8 for the seven one-digit industries he
considers, modifications of his work by Basu and Fernald and others show much
smaller markups. If the economy were characterized by markups at the low end
of Hall’s estimates, the welfare cost of inflation would be nearly twice as high
as if the markup were unity. More reasonable estimates ranging, say, below 1.5
still raise the cost of inflation significantly. In any case, economists who believe
in large markups should recognize that their view multiplies the welfare cost of
inflation accordingly.
To get an idea of the welfare gain to bringing inflation down from 4 percent
per year to zero, consider that according.to Ibbotson (1994) the average inflation
adjusted yield on Treasury bills between 1926 and 1993 (excluding the ‘42 and ‘47
wartime peg) was 0.8 percent per year. Formula (20), thus, roughly yields Q(O.05,
4 = 0.9p at 4 percent inflation and q(O.01, p) = 0.4~ at zero inflation. Even at
a markup of unity, the welfare gain to eliminating this moderate inflation is half
a percent of GDP per year. At a markup of 2, the gain is a full percent of GDP
per year. The gain to pursuing deflation sufficient to bring the nominal interest
rate to zero is another 0.4 percent of GDP if the markup is unity, and 0.8 percent
of GDP if the markup is 2. The estimates are overstated somewhat to the extent
that deposits pay interest.
16

At any rate, these gains are very large compared to those implied by Bailey’s
(1956) welfare cost formula. Technically, the reason is that the welfare cost rises
with the square root of the nominal interest rate in (20), but with the square
of the nominal interest rate according to Bailey. The difference arises because
a shopping-time technology like (2) implies that real balances increase without
bound as the nominal interest rate approaches zero. Lucas (1994) defends this
implication by pointing out that managing an inventory always takes some time so
that a larger average stock must always reduce the time requirement. Moreover,
he argues that the log-log money demand function implied by the shopping-time
technology fits the U.S. data at low interest rates much better than does the semilog form implicit in Bailey’s work. At any rate, the point here is that a markup in
excess of unity has the potential to further increase the welfare cost of inflation.

3. Market Structure, Pricing Practices, and the Markup
This section describes the market structure underlying the behavior of the markup.
The main purpose is to show how equilibrium variations in the markup are sustained endogenously in the model. Second, it is to illustrate the dependence of
the markup on aggregate demand, opening the way for the analysis of monetary
policy in Section 4. Third, it is to specify how firm pricing practices depend on
17

the markup and how the behavior of the markup governs inflation.

3.1. Monopolistic Competition and the Range of Markup
Indeterminacy
Aggregate output is assumed to consist of a large, fixed number of differentiated
products, each produced by a single firm that acts as a monopolistic competitor.
The demand for each good depends negatively on its relative product price and
positively on aggregate demand. Firms produce output with technology (3).
Each firm maximizes profit by choosing a product price in excess of the
marginal cost of production in order to exploit its market power. Hence, firms
willingly sell as much as demand will allow at their profit ma&mixing relative
product price Pi/P, where Pi is a firm’s nominal product price and P is the price
level. We assume symmetry among goods and firms so that profit maximizing
relative product prices are all unity in equilibrium. This means that aggregate
output can be thought of as a single composite good, and further, that output
and employment are proportional to aggregate demand.
We assume, in addition, that the representative firm faces not only a downward
sloping demand curve, but a kinked demand. Stiglitz (1987) has shown that a
kink results at the common relative product price in a model of sequential search

18

by consumers if there are increasing marginal search costs and a large number
of competitors. 4 A firm’s demand is relatively elastic above the common relative
price because its customers see the price increase immediately and can expect to
find a lower price elsewhere. But a firm’s demand is relatively inelastic below the
common relative price because new customers that the low price would potentially
attract are initially unaware of the price reduction. In short, a firm gains fewer
customers when it lowers its price than it loses when it raises its price-giving
rise to a kink. The existence of a kink at the existing price, in turn, makes that
the profit maximizing price.
Stiglitz discusses two cases that support a kink, one with price dispersion and
search in equilibrium, and another with no price dispersion and no search. The
application in this paper explores the case in which all firms charge a common
price and there is no search.
The kink in the demand curve implies a discontinuity in the marginal revenue
curve. This means that a firm will not change its relative product price in response to changes in aggregate demand, real wages, or productivity, as long as
marginal cost cuts through the gap in the marginal revenue curve. Therefore, the
kink creates a range in which the representative f&-mis indifferent to changes in
its markup. Only when marginal cost cuts above or below the gap in the marginal
19

revenue curve does the representative firm react by raising or lowering its product
price to bring marginal revenue into equality with marginal cost for profit maximization. In what follows, we assume that the bounds on the range of markup
indeterminacy are fixed at p and 14,respectively.
The existence of a range in which the representative firm allows its markup
to vary implies a corresponding range of real equilibria for the economy.5 Subject
to the constraint that the markup lies in the range of indeterminacy, firms are
always willing to hire more labor to accommodate increased demand because
the real wage is below the marginal product of labor. An increase in aggregate
employment raises the marginal cost of production by both increasing the wage
and lowering the marginal product of labor. Nevertheless, the representative firm
accepts the decline in its markup without passing along the cost increase in its
product price as long as the markup remains above I.
In effect, this thought experiment runs (13) in reverse-determining

the markup

as a function of the employment necessary to satisfy aggregate demand. The labormarket-clearing real wage is exactly the one that yields the markup required to
support the equilibrium level of output that satisfies aggregate demand.
The upshot is that changes in aggregate demand bring forth accommodating
changes in aggregate supply-as

long as the markup remains within the range of
20

indeterminacy. This transmission mechanism opens the door for monetary policy
to influence employment and output through aggregate demand management.
It is worth pointing out that anecdotal evidence from customer markets is
consistent with the view that underlying cost increases are absorbed and decreases
are enjoyed by firms within limits without being passed through to product prices.
In other words, firms producing differentiated products do appear to allow their
markups to vary inversely with their costs over some range before changing their
prices.6

3.2. Equilibrium Selection Device: The Pricing Practices
This paper explores the implications of one particular equilibriuni selection device
in the form of two pricing practices that are assumed to accompany the market
structure. Firm pricing practices are premised on three features of the model. The
f’!irstis that firms do not face contractual restrictions or physical costs of changing
prices. Second, firms observe all the components of their markup when setting
product prices. According to (8), this means that a firm knows the nominal wage
(W), which it takes as given in the labor market, as well as its productivity (X),
and its desired employment (N), w hen setting its nominal product price (Pi).
Firms also know they are all alike (except for producing differentiated products)

21

and that relative product prices are all unity in equilibrium.
The first pricing practice is a natural one if firms care only about relative
prices:

Pricing Practice 1-The representative f&m taking other firms’ prices
as given changes its product price if and only if its markup lies outside
the range of indeterminacy.
The second pricing practice selects a natural focal point for firms to coordinate
on when changing prices:

Pricing Practice 2-Firms change prices the minimum necessary to
bring the equilibrium markup into the range of indeterminacy.

3.3. The Pricing Regimes
Pricing practices 1 and 2 imply three pricing regimes. To illustrate these, consider
a simple money demand function that determines real aggregate demand:

(21)

log c,D =logM~logPt+logV,

where Vt is velocity. Assume the monetary authority determines Mt. To keep
matters simple, (21) ignores the interest sensitivity of money demand.
22

Let aggregate supply depend on the markup, ptr and productivity, Xt:

(22)

log c,s = log Xt - log /At.

We characterize the three pricing regimes in terms of an incipient markup in
period t-the

markup calculated for period t variables at the period t-l price

level. The incipient markup (,u:) is determined by equating aggregate demand
and supply in (21) and (22) and setting Pt = Pt-1:

(23)

1% d = 1% xt + log P&l - log Mt - log &

The pricing practices imply that when the incipient markup falls in the range
of markup indeterminacy (,u<&<$
-

the representative firm does not wish to

change its product price. In this case, both the previous period’s price level and
the incipient markup are sustained in equilibrium. The money stock and velocity
shocks exert powerful effects on the markup and aggregate supply in this case.
This is the Stable Price Level Regime:

(24)

E < &< Ji: pt = & and Pt = Pt-l
23

On the other hand, when aggregate demand is strong enough to push the
incipient markup below the minimum acceptable to firms (pi<&,

then firms

raise their product prices until the minimum acceptable markup is attained. This
is the Inflation Regime:

(25)

pi< -~1: ~t=~andlogPt=log~+logMt+log&-logXt
-

Money and velocity affect the price level in the Inflation Regime, but they do not
affect aggregate supply.
Finally, if aggregate demand is too weak to push the incipient markup below
the maximum acceptable to firms (PC&),

then firms cut product prices until JZ

is attained. This is the Deflation Regime:

(26)

ii<&:

/Jt=ZIandlogPt=logp+logMt+log&-logXt.

Before proceeding to analyze optimal monetary policy when firms price according to practices 1 and 2, it is worth pointing out that the model is entirely
compatible with other pricing practices that could supplement or substitute for
24

the ones assumed above. In fact, firms could coordinate on other pricing practices
that would select very different equilibria. Ultimately, one would have to choose
from among the various possible pricing practices on the basis of their empirical
implications,
One supplemental pricing practice, for instance, could have firms adjust prices
proportionately with the money stock. If every firm believed that others would
price that way, then each would have an incentive to price that way too, and the
supplemental pricing practice would select an equilibrium in which real money
balances were invariant to changes in the money stock. The price level could still
change according to pricing practices 1 and 2, so real balances could still move
around. And changes in money growth and expected inflation’could still affect
real output through the nominal interest rate in the money demand function.
But the equilibrium with the supplemental pricing practice would differ radically
from the one without, because now any inflation rate could be consistent with any
markup and employment in the range of indeterminacy.

4. Optimal Monetary

Policy

In this section we discuss the money supply rule that an optimizing monetary
authority would follow in the environment presented in Sections 2 and 3. The
25

monetary authority’s policy problem is to choose a rule to maximize representative agent utility (1), subject to transaction technology (2), production function
(3), and time constraint (4). The monetary authority must also respect implementation constraints (6) and (7) that reflect representative agent optimization,
as well as the pricing practices and regimes that reflect firm profit maximization.
To fix ideas we first discuss optimal policy in a nonstochastic steady state.
Next, we discuss optimal policy in a stochastic setting assuming the monetary
authority is incompletely informed about the current state of the economy. We do
the analysis in both cases assuming that the monetary authority has a technology
enabling it to commit to a rule. We close the section, however, by arguing that
the optimal money supply rule in this model is sustained by reputational forces,
even in the absence of a precommitment mechanism.

4.1. Optimal Policy in a Nonstochastic Steady State
The easiest way to determine the optimal money supply rule in a nonstochastic
steady state is to work backward from the welfare maximizing combination of
markup and nominal interest rate, since by (13) and (14) these determine the
other equilibrium allocations.
If it were possible, the monetary authority would clearly like to set R to zero

26

by deflating prices at p + g, while minimizing the markup distortion at p =I.
According to the pricing regimes described in Section 3.3, however, firms cannot
be induced to deflate prices unless the markup is at the top of the range of
indeterminacy.
This creates the possibility that a rule that minimizes the markup might dominate one that pursues deflation.

Since firms never let their markup fall below

the minimum g, there are no benefits to inflationary monetary policy when the
monetary authority is fully informed.

The best alternative to deflation is zero

inflation with p= I.
Thus, we have two contenders for welfare maximizing policy in the nonstochastic steady state, which we denote as follows:

The Friedman Rule:7

R=Oandp=p

The Zero Inflation Rule: R = p + g and p = -p
We saw in Section 2.3 that the welfare gain as a percentage of GDP of going
from zero inflation to the Friedman Rule was 0.4,~ percent of GDP. Some tedious
algebra yields a formula for the deadweight cost as a percentage of GDP of a one
percent increase in the markup in the neighborhood of steady state values for p
and N:
27

(27)

A log

GDP=

[[a(1 -IV)+

N]/[l

+ (pN/a(l

- N))]](p-

1)A log p

According to (27), the deadweight cost of an incremental increase in the
markup would be negligible for a steady state markup near unity. But calibrated
at Q = 2/3, N = l/3, and, say, p = 2, a one percent increase in the markup would
yield a welfare loss of about l/3 percent of GDP per year. In this case, for example, the Zero Inflation Rule would dominate the Friedman Rule if and only if p
exceeded -p by about three percent. The prevailing view widely shared by central
bankers and financial market participants is against the Friedman Rule. That
view is potentially justifiable in this model if the range of markup indeterminacy
is wide enough and the steady state markup is high enough.
The money supply rule that supports a stable price level and p = k is found
by using (13) to eliminate N in (16) to yield:

In (28) it is easy to see that the nominal money stock must grow at the rate of
productivty growth, g, in order to maintain stable prices. With R = p + g and P
28

given by history, (28) may be solved for the level of the money growth path that
supports p = k.

4.2. Optimal

Policy When

the Monetary

Authority

Is Incompletely

Informed
We characterize optimal monetary policy when the monetary authority is incompletely informed about the current state of the economy due to a one-period
data-processing lag. In this case, the monetary authority sets the period t money
stock conditional only on lagged information (It-i) and on the period t nominal
interest rate (Rt). There are two serially uncorrelated sources of uncertainty, a
productivity shock and a velocity shock. Because the monetary authority conditions on only one indicator, Rt, it can no longer manage the markup exactly. The
best it can do is target the conditional mean of the markup by its choice of the
money stock relative to the previous period’s price level.
The idea is to see how the introduction of uncertainty affects the optimal
monetary policy relative to a full information steady state in which the monetary
authority would follow the Zero Inflation Rule described above. We work with a
log-linearized system in the neighborhood of /.J= k and R = p + g, first deriving
the marginal rate of substitution of Rt for F [log pt 1It- 1, Rt] , then characterizing

29

the marginal rate of transformation, and f?nally comparing the two.
Working from the FOCs in Section 2, with some effort we can write the
marginal rate of substitution of Rt for F logp,

at steady state values for ~1,

R, L, and N as:

(29)

MRS (Rt for E log pt) = -(2OOL~//4[c41
t

+ (cr(1 - N)/@v))

- iv]

To characterize the marginal rate of transformation of Rt for F logpt, consider
the effect of uncertainty when the monetary authority continues to choose Mt to
target the conditional mean of the incipient markup at the minimum acceptable
to firms. The introduction of uncertainty spreads the probability mass of the conditional distribution of log & above and below log E. Because k is the boundary
of the Stable Price Level Regime and the Inflation Regime, firms respond asymmetrically to the incipient markup above and below -P.~ When pLIfalls below I,
firms raise prices until the minimum acceptable markup is established; when $
falls above p
- (but below pi) firms sustain both the previous period’s prices and the
incipient markup. So uncertainty in the neighborhood of the minimum markup
raises both expected inflation, F log &/&I,
Formally, we can write:
30

and the expected markup, F log pt.

where Fr, F2>0, Gr<O, Gz>O.
A positive Vfr pi presents the monetary authority with a tradeoff between
the expected markup and expected inflation that it can exploit by its choice of
B log(d/&.

Lo wering the mean of the conditional distribution of the incipient

markup relative to k, shifts the distribution further into the region where & falls
below k and out of the region where & exceeds k, Hence, by lowering its target
for $! log(pf/h)-

the monetary authority lowers the expected markup and raises

expected inflation.
The tradeoff between expected inflation and the expected markup implies one
between expected inflation and expected unemployment.

Expected unemploy-

ment is governed by the expected markup approximately according to: log N(e)Flog&

= TN,, B log(pt/&,

where

7~~ 3 2L/(1+

L + N).

The Phillips curve tradeoff per se is between expected current inflation and
the expected current markup or employment. We still need to translate it into
31

one between the nominal interest rate and the expected current markup in order to characterize the marginal rate of transformation between the latter two.
This is straightforward once we recognize that exploiting the Phillips curve to
tolerate higher current expected inflation in order to reduce current expected unemployment translates into higher expected future inflation, and a higher average
nominal interest rate according to (17).
We are finally in a position to compare the marginal rate of transformation
(MRT) with th e marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of ER for Elogp

in the

neighborhood of the minimum markup and zero inflation. Consider first the MRT.
When expected inflation is near zero, very little probability mass of the conditional
distribution of the incipient markup falls below CL.If the conditional distribution
is shaped like a bell with thin tails, the monetary authority can then target a
smaller conditional mean of the incipient markup (with a commensurate reduction
of the expected equilibrium markup and unemployment) without moving much
probability mass of the incipient markup below I, that is, without raising expected
inflation and the nominal interest rate much. Thus, the marginal cost in terms of a
higher interest rate of reducing unemployment is close to zero in the neighborhood
of zero inflation.
On the other hand, by (29) the MRS is bounded away from zero in the neigh32

borhood of zero inflation, which means that it is worth accepting some increase in
the nominal rate for an incremental reduction in unemployment. In other words, a
monetary authority that is otherwise inclined to maintain price stability under full
information will optimally pursue some inflation in order to reduce unemployment
somewhat under incomplete information.
With some algebra, the optimal money supply rule in this situation can be
shown to support a price level generating process that is difference-stationary in
logs with an inflationary trend and serially uncorrelated departures from trend.
In particular, both the money stock and the price level optimally exhibit base
drift.

4.3. Monetary Policy without Commitment
The world’s monetary authorities, including the Federal Reserve, make monetary policy on a discretionary basis, that is, in the absence of a technology or
institutional mechanism that commits policy to a rule. Optimal policy without
commitment may not coincide with that under a rule. Hence, the relevance of the
view of monetary policy advanced in Section 4.2 would be enhanced if it could be
supported in a discretionary equilibrium.
In the language of Chari, Kehoe, and Prescott (1990) the outcome without

33

commitment requires that policy actions be sequentially rational. In a sequentially
rational equilibrium, the money supply must maximize the monetary authority’s
objective function at each date, given that private agents behave optimally. Likewise, private agent optimal&y requires that they forecast future monetary policies
that are sequentially rational for the monetary authority. A sequence of monetary
policy rules, time allocations, and prices that satisfy these conditions is a time
consistent or sustainable equilibrium.
To verify that the optimal money supply rule is sustainable in this model
without commitment, first consider the full information case. Assume that the
Zero Inflation Rule is optimal. In this case, because there are no contractional or
physical restrictions on changing prices and wages, firms would react to surprise
money growth by raising their prices in order to keep the markup from falling
below -p. Wages would rise too, neutralizing any effect on real variables. Since
there is no benefit to a positive money growth surprise, and none to a negative
surprise, the Zero Inflation Rule in the model is clearly sustainable under full
information.
Now consider the incomplete information case. Here the optimal money supply
rule dictates that E log pt exceeds log E, so that a positive deviation of M from the
rule reduces the expected markup distortion. Hence, the monetary authority has
34

an incentive to deviate from the rule under incomplete information. Suppose that
log & is normally distributed within finite upper and lower bounds. In that case,
the benefit from a positive deviation would be exhausted once surprise money
growth put the upper bound of the log pf distribution at log cl, since that would
put the markup at its minimum with certainty. Accompanying the high money
growth would be an expected rate of inflation in excess of that associated with
the optimal money supply rule.
Without commitment, then, the monetary authority would be tempted to
depart from the optimal rule in order to assure that p would always equal E
However, if the monetary authority were to attempt a money growth surprise, it
could expect private agents to react by raising expected inflation immediately.g In
that case, the monetary authority’s deviation would create an immediate social
cost associated with a higher nominal interest rate, as agents respond by immediately substituting shopping time for real money balances. A monetary authority
that understands that its deviation would trigger an immediate corresponding increase in the nominal interest rate will abide by the optimal rule because, in that
case, the choice among deviations merely reproduces the choice among rules.
Thus, as in Barro and Gordon (1983), the potential loss of reputation--or
credibility-motivates

the monetary authority to follow the rule here. Reputation
35

alone was not able to completely sustain their ideal rule because the punishment
from cheating occurred with a lag in their model. Here, however, if the cost of any
deviation is borne simultaneously with the benefit, reputation alone is capable of
fully enforcing the optimal rule.i’

5. Discussion
This section addresses some aspects of the model in more detail and suggests some
extensions.

5.1. A Smooth Phillips Curve
As it now stands, the model does not generate inflation and unemployment realizations that lie smoothly along a curve such as that presented by Phillips (1958).
According to the pricing regimes specified in Section 3.3, the economy is in the
Inflation Regime only when the realized markup is at the minimum acceptable
to firms (E), that is, only when unemployment is at its minimum. Moreover, the
price level is stable as long as unemployment is above its minimum. Thus, the
model generates an L-shaped Phillips curve (ignoring the Deflation Regime).
This was not a problem for the policy analysis in Section 4 because the incompletely informed monetary authority had to choose between expectations of
36

inflation and unemployment, and the tradeoff in expectations does exhibit smoothness. In a more realistic model firms’ markups could depend on relative and aggregate shocks, so that there would be a dispersion of incipient markups around
the economy-wide average. I1 This way, realized aggregate inflation and unemployment that obtain in a given period could vary smoothly with the fraction
of firms whose incipient markups fall below -/L. Needless to say, this elaboration
would greatly complicate the model because it would introduce price dispersion
and search in equilibrium.

5.2. Inflation Scared2
A model such as this that would determine inflation at a tangency’between a social
marginal rate of transformation and a social marginal rate of substitution provides
a natural framework within which to study inflation scares: fluctuations in private
agents’ inflation expectations. Although inflation expectations are constant in the
economy studied in Section 4.2, expected inflation could vary in a more realistic
model. Moreover, when private agents have more information than the monetary
authority, variations in expected inflation could constitute another source of shock
to the economy from the monetary authority’s point of view.
Forecastable changes in the variances of the underlying productivity or velocity

37

shocks would be one way to introduce variable inflation expectations. In a more
elaborate model, forecastable cyclical movements in employment would do the
same. Moreover, changes in fiscal policy involving government purchases, transfers, and taxes could shift the social marginal rate of substitution between the
nominal interest distortion and the markup distortion.

And, fiscal policies that

affect the private marginal return to work effort could shift the Phillips curve
tradeoff.

5.3. A Long-Run Phillips Curve Tradeoff
In a recent paper, King and Watson (1994) p rovide empirical support for the existence of a long-run Phillips curve tradeoff between unemployment and inflation
in postwar U.S. data. For a Keynesian identification in the early sample period,
they find that a 1 percent increase in inflation is associated with a 1.3 percentage
point decline in the unemployment rate; the estimate is cut roughly in half in the
latter part of the sample period. A Rational Expectations Monetarist identification yields a long-run tradeoff of about 1 to 0.5 in the earlier period, and 1 to 0.3
in the latter.
The model offered in this paper is consistent with the evidence of a permanent Phillips curve tradeoff under rational expectations and optimization on the

38

part of private agents, firms, and the monetary authority. The model predicts
the extent of a tradeoff to depend on the conditional forecast variance of the
incipient markup.

The model also predicts the tradeoff to worsen with higher

marginal income taxes, increasingly generous unemployment compensation,

or

more liberal welfare programs. The reasons is that such distortions operate much
as the markup does, by driving a wedge between labor’s marginal product and
its marginal compensation.

Since each level of employment in the model is sup-

ported by a specific gap between the marginal product of labor and the real wage,
it takes a higher before tax real wage, or equivalently, a smaller markup, for the
economy to support a given level of employment in the presence of an income tax.
An income tax worsens the Phillips curve tradeoff that arises under uncertainty
because it associates a given mean incipient markup and expected inflation with
higher average unemployment.

6. Conclusion
The model was offered as a conceptual framework for understanding and analyzing
moderately inflationary monetary policy. It deliberately embodies Keynesian price
level inflexibility to study the cost of a moderate inflations in a way that addresses
the concerns of central bankers. The result is a transmission mechanism that
39

allows monetary policy to influence aggregate supply by managing the “markup
tax” on employment.
The monetary authority faces a Phillips curve tradeoff that arises because
it is imperfectly informed about the state of the economy. The tradeoff emerges
because firms react asymmetrically to the incipient markup at the boundary of the
range of indeterminacy. If the markup comes in below the acceptable minimum,
firms raise prices, if it comes in above, firms do not change prices, the markup is
sustained, and employment and output fall.
Since the actual markup cannot fall below the minimum acceptable to firms,
policymaker uncertainty raises the average markup and lowers the levels of employment and output at which the economy can be expected to operate.

The

monetary authority can compensate with monetary policy for the negative effect
of its ignorance on economic performance. Expansionary policy raises expected
employment by improving the chances that aggregate demand will be sufficient to
minimize the markup; but it does so at the cost of higher expected inflation. The
optimizing monetary authority chooses an inflation (or deflation) rate to minimize the overall deadweight cost due to the nominal interest rate and the markup
distortions.
Sufficiently inflationary monetary policy can keep the realized markup approx40

imately equal to the minimum acceptable to firms in the model, avoiding Keynesian unemployment entirely. In fact, at high inflation rates the model behaves like
a noncompetitive real business cycle model in which money affects real variables
only through expected inflation. Nevertheless, such highly inflationary policy is
not optimal.

The reason is that the Phillips curve tradeoff becomes very steep

at low levels of unemployment.

The marginal welfare cost, in terms of a higher

nominal interest rate that must be tolerated to reduce unemployment, exceeds
the marginal benefit before Keynesian unemployment is eliminated entirely.
We showed that the welfare cost of inflation may very well be much higher
than is commonly supposed if a shopping time technology underlies the demand
for money and the average markup in the economy is significant. Making use of the
fact that Keynesian unemployment in the model is due entirely to the markup
distortion, we also calculated the welfare cost of unemployment.

It is an open

question, in terms of welfare, how much inflation the monetary authority should
be willing to tolerate to reduce unemployment. In fact, it is entirely possible that
the deflationary Friedman Rule is optimal in this model, in spite of the model’s
Keynesian features.

41

FOOTNOTES

1. The population size is fixed and normalized to unity.

2. Rt in equation (6) is an approximation for Rt/(l + Rt).

3.

Employment and shopping time are invariant to productivity growth (X)

because the latter exerts exactly offsetting substitution and wealth effect on employment. And money demand is proportionate to the transactions scale variable,
which means that shopping time is invariant to productivity growth by (2) and
(3).

4. Stiglitz (1984) a1so d iscusses monopolistic competition with a kinked demand
curve. Such a market structure has been employed by Woglom (1982) to demonstrate the possibility of underemployment with rational expectations. It has also
been used by Ball and Romer (1990), in combination with small frictions in nominal adjustment, as a source of real rigidity in a model designed to explore the
nonneutrality of money.

5. Woodford (1991) stresses the importance of multiple real equilibria for understanding business cycles in a model with a market structure closely related to the
one studied here.

6. Bils (1987) reports that markups in two-digit manufacturing data for the U.S.
decline on average by 3.3 percent with a 10 percent expansion. Rotemberg and
Woodford (1991, 1992) do‘scuss the attractiveness of countercyclical markups for
macroeconomics, and survey alternative theories of endogenous markups. Carlton
(1989) also surveys evidence of the cyclicality of markups.

7. This policy prescription is associated with Milton Friedman (i969).

8. Assume that the shocks are small enough that the incipient markup never falls
above iZ and the economy is never in the Deflation Regime.

9. Since private agents observe all the variables in the monetary authority’s rule,
they immediately observe any deviation from that rule, and calculate the implied
increase in inflation that a deviation implies.

2

10. In a different context, Grossman and Van Huyck (1986) also show that an
optimal rule can be sustained without commitment if the loss of reputation from
deviations is immediate. Ireland (1994) contains a thorough analysis of sustainable
monetary policies.

11. Such an elaboration would be along the lines of the imperfect information
model in Ball and Romer (1990).

12. See Goodfriend (1993).

Ball, Laurence, and David Romer, 1990, Real rigidities and the nonneutrality
of money, Review of Economic Studies 57, 183-203.
Bailey, Martin, 1956, The welfare cost of inflationary finance, JoumaZ of
Political Economy 64, 93-110.
Barro, Robert, and David Gordon, 1983, Rules, discretion, and reputation in
monetary policy, Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 101-21.
Basu, Susanto, and John G. Fernald, 1994, Constant returns and small
markups in U.S. manufacturing, (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Paper, Washington, DC).
Bils, Mark, 1987, The cyclical behavior of marginal cost and price, American
Economic Review 77, 838-55.
Blanchard, Olivier and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, 1987, Monopolistic competition
and the effects of aggregate demand, American Economic Review 77, 647-666.
Carlton, Dennis, 1989, The theory and the facts of how markets clear: Is industrial organization valuable for understanding macroeconomics?

In: R. Schmalensee

and R.D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 1 (North Holland, Amsterdam) 907-946.
Chari, V.V., Patrick Kehoe, and Edward Prescott, 1989, Time consistency and

policy, In: Robert Barro, ed., Modern Business Cycle Theory (Harvard University
Press, Cambridge, MA).
Friedman, Milton, 1969, The optimum quantity of money and other essays,
(Chicago, Aldine Publishing Co.).
Goodfriend, Marvin, 1993, Interest rate policy and the inflation scare problem:
1979-1992, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, l-24.
Grossman, Herschel I., and John B. Van Huyck, 1986, Seigniorage, inflation,
and reputation,
Hall, Robert,

Journal of Monetary Economics 18, 21-31.
1988, The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S.

industry, Journal of Political Economy 96, 921-947.
Ibbotson, Roger, 1994, Stocks, bonds, bills, and inflation 1994 Yearbook, (Chicago,
Ibbotson Associates).
Ireland, Peter, 1994, Sustainable monetary policies, (Richmond, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond).
King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson, 1994, The post-war U.S. phillips
curve: A revisionist econometric history, (Charlottesville, University of Virginia),
forthcoming in the Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy.
Lucas, R.E., Jr., 1993, 1994, On the welfare cost of inflation, (Chicago, University of Chicago).
2

McCallum, Bennett T., and Marvin Goodfriend, 1987, Demand for money:
Theoretical studies, In: John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds.,
The New Palgrave: A Dictiona y of Economics, (Stockton Press, London: Macmillan; NewYork) 775-81.
Phillips, A.W.,

1958, Th e relation between unemployment and the rate of

change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957, Economica 25,
283-300.
Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford, 1992, Oligopolistic pricing and the
effects of aggregate demand on economic activity, Journal of Political Economy
100, 1153-1207.
--9

1991, Markups and the business cycle, In: O.J. Blanchard and S.

Fischer, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991, (MIT Press, Cambridge) 63129.
Stiglitz, Joseph E., 1987, Competition and the number of firms in a market:
Are duopolies more competitive than atomistic markets?

Journal of Political

Economy 95, 1041-61.
----,

1984, Price rigidities and market structure, American Economic Re-

view 74, 350-355.
Woglom, Geoffrey, 1982, Underemployment equilibrium with rational expec3

tations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89-107.
Woodford, Michael, 1991, Self-fuElling expectations and fluctuations in aggregate demand, In: Mankiw and Romer, eds., New Keynesian economics (MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA) 77-112.