View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 86-6

A CRITIQUE OF THEORIES OF MONEY STOCK DETERMINATION

Robert L. Hetzel

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

October 1986

We are grateful to Marvin Goodfriend and Bob King for a number of valuable
suggestions as well as to Monica Hargraves and Tony Kuprianov for helpful
comments. The views expressed in this paper are solely those of the authors
and do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
or the Federal Reserve System.

1. Introduction
Many different models of money stock determination exist in the literature.
An attempt is made here to understand why the differences in these models arise.
Differences in models are ascribed first to the (usually implicit) role assigned
to the price level.

From this perspective, models fall into two categories.

Models in the quantity theory tradition require that the price level adjust in
order to cause the real quantity of money to equal the real quantity demanded.
In contrast, in the real bills or banking school tradition, the nominal quantity
of money adjusts in order to provide the real quantity demanded. Much of the
discussion below deals with the way in which the macroeconomics inspired by
Keynes' General Theory encouraged models in the latter tradition. Differences
in models also arise according to whether the monetary authority directly
manipulates an interest rate or a reserve aggregate.

Sec. 2 presents a model of

the money stock general enough to include the models discussed in succeeding
sections as special cases.

Variation in its parameter expressing the extent to

which the monetary authority smooths the rate of interest allows it to capture
the range of operating procedures running from total reserves control to rate
pegging.
2. A general model of the money stock
The model in this section is McCallum's (1986) model extended to include the
banking sector.

Let rt denote the nominal rate of interest; pt, ht, and mt

denote logs of the price level, reserves, and the nominal money stock, respectively.

Let t denote time.

Also, vt, nt, and et are independent white noise

disturbances. E is the expectations operator and It 1 is the information set of
realizations of variables dated t-1 or earlier.

Equation (1) is a reduced form

derived by eliminating real output through equating an aggregate demand and
aggregate supply schedule.

The latter makes deviations in real output from a

normal value a function of unanticipated realizations of the price level.

The

assumption of rational expectations then endows the model with a natural rate of

-2interest in that the real rate of interest is unaffected by the systematic
actions of monetary policy.
Equation (1) expresses the nominal interest rate as the sum of expected
inflation (first term) plus the real rate of interest (last three terms), where
the real rate of interest equates the flow of investment and saving.

Equation

In (3), the monetary rule is specified in terms

(2) is a money demand function.

of control of a reserves aggregate (high-powered money, total bank reserves, or
nonborrowed reserves).

Equation (4) defines the relationship between nominal

money, the interest rate, and reserves.
five endogenous variables (r t, mt

Also, mt = m5.

The model comprises

Pt. ht. and Ep t+1) and can be solved with the

constraint imposed by rational expectations.
t

Ept+1

d- Pt = c

0

,trt) -Pt] + bo + b 1pt - E(pt:It1)] + v1
+ c rt + c [p

1t

2 t

ht

(rt - )
t
u+ Ut+A

mS

do + d re + d h + et
2t
0
1t

-

n
++nc

E(p :I

t t-1

1

C

c2

(1)
(2)

(2

A

(3)

< d2

(4)

Q(
d <
12

bI<

The parameter \ measures the degree to which the monetary authority smooths
the nominal interest rate.
r.

As A becomes large, the interest rate is pegged at

The rule incorporated in (3) provides for a complete future offset of the

contemporaneous innovation in reserves that arises because of rate smoothing.
Money fluctuates randomly around a trend line.

Alternatively, (5) provides for

no offset to innovations in reserves; money becomes a random walk.1/

ht = ht

+ U1 +A(rt -)

o

A

(5)

In a model incorporating the natural-rate hypothesis, an arbitrary interest
rate target renders nominal money and the price level indeterminate [Sargent
(1979), pp. 92-95; Sargent and Wallace (1975)].

Two kinds of interest rate

targets are compatible with nominal money and price level determinacy.

First,

indeterminacy does not obtain if the interest rate is used by the monetary
authority as an instrumental variable for controlling a nominal variable [Parkin

-3(1978); McCallum (1981)].

Second, indeterminacy does not obtain in the case of

an interest rate peg provided two requirements are fulfilled.2/ The trend rate
of inflation chosen by the monetary authority, which above is the trend rate of
growth of money (u1 ), must equal the difference between the nominal rate target

(r) and the expected real rate (b ) [Canzoneri, Henderson, and Rogoff (1983),
appendix]. Also, the monetary rule must define the extent to which the contemporaneous innovation in money due to rate smoothing will be offset subsequently
[Dotsey and King (1983), appendix, and McCallum (1986)].
In order to illustrate how the model works in a regime of rate pegging,
consider a transitory rightward shift in the public's investment schedule
captured by a positive realization of vt.

An incipient rise in the market rate

of interest causes the monetary authority to increase reserves.
mt, and the price level, Pt, rise.
approximately equal to r.

Nominal money,

Two separate effects keep the market rate

First, given (3), the public does not anticipate a

corresponding rise in mt+1 and pt+1
tion from t to t+1 falls below trend.

Consequently, the expected rate of inflaA reduction in the inflation premium

built into the nominal rate mitigates a rise in rt.

Second, the price level

surprise associated with a higher than anticipated value of Pt stimulates
output, and the public's savings schedule shifts rightward. The combination of
these effects keeps the nominal rate of interest at the targeted value.
In this natural-rate model, the price of nominal money is the inverse of the
price level.

(The interest rate is the price of real, not nominal, money.)

The

supply and demand schedules for nominal money are graphed with the inverse of
the price level on the vertical axis and nominal money on the horizontal axis.
The demand schedule for nominal money balances derives from the real money
demand function (2) evaluated at different price levels.

An increase in the

price level (a fall in the price of nominal money) in itself leads to a
proportional rise in the demand for nominal money.

Given the particular money

-4supply rule (3), which ties down p

independently of Pt, a rise in Pt leads

the public to anticipate a reduction in the one-period inflation rate.
reduction increases the demand for nominal money.

This

Finally, a rise in Pt., given

E(pt:It 1), leads to an increase in the demand for nominal money through an
increase in real output.

For all these reasons, the demand for nominal money is

inversely related to the price level.

The money supply rule (3) produces a

vertical supply of nominal money schedule, which shifts over time at a rate
determined by the parameter u 1 .
Assume a rate peg of r and consider first the effect of a positive monetary
shock (nt > 0).
rightward.

Both the nominal money demand and supply schedules shift

The supply schedule shifts because the monetary authority increases

the money stock in order to prevent a rise in rt above r.
effect of a positive real shock (vt > 0).

Consider next the

The nominal money demand schedule is

unaffected. The supply schedule shifts rightward, however, because of the
monetary authority's defense of its rate peg.

The price level rises.

The monetary rule determines the characteristics of the supply and demand
schedules for nominal money.

A well-defined rule is, therefore, a necessary

condition for the existence of a determinate price level.

This rule determines

the nature of the nominal money supply schedule by setting the trend rate of
growth of money, the degree of interest rate smoothing, and the extent to which
contemporaneous innovations in money are offset.

It also determines the nature

of the nominal money demand schedule by rendering the real demand for money well
defined.

The rule allows the public to form an expectation of the future money

stock, which allows formation of an expectation of the future price level.

The

contemporaneous demand for real money then is well defined.
A major source of confusion has been the frequent failure to recognize that
the reserves-money multiplier relationship (4) does not summarize behavioral
relationships important to the determination of the money stock in a regime of

-5rate control.

Furthermore, in those instances when the conditions for the

superfluity of the multiplier relationship have been recognized, it has usually
been concluded that "money is demand determined." Consider a regime of a rate
Given knowledge of the parameters of (3) and (4), it is possible to form

peg.

an expectation of p

.3/

1

With rt equal

7,

it is then possible to solve (1) and

Given the solution for mt, ht can be derived from (4).

(2) for mt and Pt.

It

is possible with a rate peg, however, to solve for mt without also solving for
ht. the contemporaneous value of the reserve aggregate.
The failure of the reserves-money multiplier relationship to summarize
behavioral relationships important in the determination of the money stock in a
regime with a rate peg extends to a regime in which the interest rate is used as
an instrumental variable for controlling macroeconomic variables [McCallum
(1981), p. 322; Goodfriend (1982), p. 8].

For example, assume that the monetary

authority consistently sets the interest rate to achieve an expected value for
money, m.

The rate target, r

,

can be solved for by using (2) to form an

expectation of money and by substituting m for this expectation.
r*

=

1/c1 [E - c0

-

E(p :I)](7)

Equations (1) and (2) and knowledge of m allow the public to determine the
expected value of pt+1- With rt = r

,

the relevant system of equations is now

just equations (1) and (2), which can be solved for mt and Pt.

The reserves-

money multiplier (4) is superfluous to determination of the money stock.
This result can be seen by examining a simple reserves-deposits multiplier:
D

=

(D/R)* * R ,

(8)-

where D is deposits, (D/R)* is banks' equilibrium deposits-reserves ratio, and R
is total reserves of banks.

In order for (8) to be a useful summary of deposit

determination, R must be determined independently from D; also D must adjust to
(D/R)*, given R.
rate control.

Neither of these two conditions is fulfilled in a regime of

First, the targeted rate determines the cost to the banking

-6system of credit extension; therefore, deposit creation is determined by shifts
in the nominal credit demand schedule of the nonbank public.

These shifts are

determined by the shocks that originate in the real and monetary sectors of the
economy and by the choice of the monetary rule.

Deposits and reserve demand are

determined simultaneously with credit creation.

As a consequence of defending

its rate target, the monetary authority, by creating an infinitely elastic
supply of reserves, accommodates whatever reserve demand emerges.-/
Second, as a consequence of maintaining its rate target, the monetary
authority necessarily supplies reserves to preclude any effect on deposits of
changes in banks' equilibrium ratio of reserves to deposits. For example,
consider an increase in this ratio due to a rise in equilibrium excess reserves
or due to a shift of deposits from banks with a low required reserve ratio on
marginal deposits to banks with a high ratio.

In both cases, the monetary

authority must supply additional reserves in order to prevent the funds rate
from rising.5/

In a regime of rate targeting, neither the quantity of reserves

nor the desired reserves-deposits ratio of the banking system exercises a causal
role in the determination of the money stock.
When economists have noted the irrelevance of the reserves-money multiplier
in a regime of rate control, they have usually concluded that money is demand
determined [for example, Pierce and Thomson (1972)].
leading in a natural-rate model.

This conclusion is mis-

The importance to money-stock determination of

factors affecting the supply of money is obvious in the case of real sector
shocks and also appears in the role played by the monetary rule.

The form of

this rule shapes the time series behavior of nominal money independently of the
nature of the demand function for real money.
3. Thornton's model of the money stock
Henry Thornton exposited the first rigorous model of a non-commodity money.
Suspension by the Bank of England in 1797 of convertibility of its notes into

- 7 gold led to the famous bullionist - anti-bullionist debate..

The anti-bullionist

Directors of the Bank argued that note creation by the Bank could continue to be
regulated by the real bills principle.
by the public's demand.

That is, money creation would be limited

The bullionist Henry Thornton countered this view with
In

a model of the money stock in the quantity theory tradition [Hetzel (1986)].

order for nominal money to play a causal role in determining the price level, at
least some of the determinants of nominal money supply must differ from the
determinants of real money demand.

Thornton achieved this differentiation

through a model of the money stock that incorporated a natural rate of interest,
that is, a real rate of interest determined ultimately only by nonmonetary
According to Thornton, the monetary authority creates money by

phenomena.

driving a wedge between the market rate of interest, controlled by its discount
rate, and the natural rate of interest, determined in the market for real
capital.

This wedge between the market and the natural rate does not affect the

demand for real money, so the price level must adjust to the associated nominal
money creation [Thornton (1802), pp. 227; 253-4; 255-6].
The natural rate model of Sec. 2 is similar in spirit to Thornton's model,
where changes in nominal money derive from discrepancies between the market and
natural rate of interest.

Assume a rate peg of r and rewrite the reduced-form

expression for the nominal rate of interest (1) as (9).

The left side of (9)

can be viewed as the difference between the market rate, r, and the natural
rate, (b

+ vt).

r- (b0 +V t

Also, Pt is a function of the current money stock.
[E(pt++1 :It 1,rd)

-

Pt] + b1[pt - E(pt:I

1

)]

b1 <

0

(9)

(10)
aCpt/amt > 0
vt E(pt:It1)]
f[m t, E(pt+i:It ) n
Consider a positive real sector shock, vt > 0. The value of the left side of
Pt

(9) falls.

The sum of the two terms on the right side must fall; therefore, Pt

must rise.

Because pt varies positively with mt, mt must rise.

Consequently,

when shocks originate in the real sector, shifts in the supply of nominal money

-8may be considered, in the spirit of Thornton's model, to be a function of the
In contrast, the demand for

difference between the market and the natural rate.
real money is a function of just the market rate.

Finally, in the spirit of

Thornton's model, the model of Sec. 2 implies the absence of any permanent
relation between the interest rate and nominal money.
4. Pigou's reserves-money multiplier model
As had happened in the Napoleonic War, suspension of the gold standard in
World War I spurred theorizing about money stock determination.
Pigou (1917) introduced a reserves-money multiplier model.

In 1917, A. C.

His model possesses

relationships analogous to those of (2), (3), and (4) of the model of Sec. 2.
Pigou posits a real money demand function in the form of the Cambridge cashbalances version of the quantity equation.

He discusses a variety of institu-

tional arrangements for determining high-powered money.

He formulates the money

supply function as the product of high-powered money and a multiplier expressed
in terms of the nonbank public's desired currency to money ratio and banks'
desired reserves to deposits ratio.

Finally, the nominal money supply function

is equated to the product of the price level and the real money demand function.
Pigou's model is in the spirit of the natural-rate model of Sec. 2, despite the
absence of any formal way of incorporating the natural-rate hypothesis.

In

particular, the scale variable in the money demand function is understood as a
nonmonetary phenomenon. Consequently, when the nominal quantity of money
changes, the price level must do the work of bringing the public's real quantity
of money back into equality with the real quantity demanded.6/
Reasoning within Pigou's static reserves-money multiplier framework,
Patinkin (1961, p. 116) states that a necessary condition for rendering the
price level "determinate is that there be an exogenous fixing of (1) some
nominal quantity and (2) some rate of return."

That is, the magnitude of some

nominal quantity must be set and the real demand for this nominal quantity must

-9be well defined.

For example, fixing high-powered money, which possesses a

nominal interest rate of zero, fixes the price level.

Note that in the dynamic

model of Sec. 2 a well-defined monetary rule replaces the requirement of "an
exogenous fixing of some nominal quantity."

(In Pigou's model, when it is

assumed that nominal money is the nominal quantity fixed, it is appropriate to
adopt the usual practice of referring to the money stock as the "money supply."
In the dynamic model of Sec. 2, however, where the money stock is determined by
factors affecting both demand and supply, this practice is inappropriate.)
5. The Tinbergen model
Models of the money stock inspired by the economics of the General Theory
reflect Keynes' liquidity preference theory of interest.

In the General Theory,

Keynes omits an aggregate supply function with a natural rate of output in order
to allow equilibrium levels of output below full employment. In this way, he
also allows variations in output to equilibrate savings and investment. The
role of the interest rate is to equilibrate the demand and supply of money
through affecting the speculative demand for money.

A fall, say, in the inter-

est rate, relative to what investors consider a long-run normal rate, increases
the speculative demand for money as investors, anticipating a future rise in
rates and a capital loss on bonds, move out of bonds into money [Keynes (1936),
pp. 201-202].

Keynes' theory rejects the idea of a natural rate of interest.

The implicit assumption that the price level is fixed or is determined as a
nonmonetary phenomenon allows each nominal quantity of money to be associated
with a different equilibrium real interest rate.
Tinbergen's (1939, 1951) model of the money stock incorporated Keynes'
theory of liquidity preference and continues to be standard in the literature.
[See Teigen (1964, 1970) for an exposition.]

It serves as the core of the

financial sector of large-scale econometric models [de Leeuw (1965), Goldfeld
(1966), and Modigliani, Rasche, and Cooper (1970)].

Also, it is the primary

-

10 -

model used by the Federal Reserve [Thomson, Pierce, and Parry (1975)] to forecast money.

It is commonly used to study monetary control issues [Davis (1974),

LeRoy (1979), Sivesind (1980), Tinsley (1982) and Lindsey (1984)].
The Tinbergen model possesses relationships analogous to those of (2), (3),
and (4) of the model of Sec. 2.
function.

Tinbergen includes a standard real money demand

He assumes that the monetary authority sets values for the discount

rate and for nonborrowed reserves.

The money supply function is built around

the behavior of banks' demand for free reserves.

Let FR be free reserves; NBR

nonborrowed reserves; RR required reserves; ER excess reserves; BR borrowed
reserves; rr the legal required reserve ratio; D deposits; r the interest rate;
and rd the central bank discount rate.
policymaker.

(For expositional simplicity, currency is ignored).

FR = NBR - RR = ER - BR

(11)

RR = NBR - FR

(hla)

RR

rr.D

(12)

FR = fr(r:rd)

(13)

-

NBR and rd are values set by the

Free reserves are defined in alternative ways in (11) and (Ila), and (12)
defines required reserves.

Equation (13) explains bank demand for free reserves

as a function of the rate of interest, given the discount rate.

The money

(deposit) supply function (15) is derived by substituting (12) and (13) into
(hla) and solving for money (deposits).
In expositions of this model, no distinction is made between nominal and
real money, and the price level never appears.
Dd= c0 + clr + c2Y

(14)

D=- 1/rr [NBR - fr(r:rd)]

(15)

(Y is real output.)

The model is written as follows:

The real money demand function (14) is equated to the

nominal money supply function (15) in order to determine the interest rate,
which is substituted into (14) or (15) in order to solve for (nominal and real)

-

money.

11

-

Because real money equals nominal money divided by the price level, in

order to equate (14) and (15) and solve for D and r, it is necessary to take the
price level as given.

In a natural-rate model, the price level equilibrates the

nominal quantities of money supplied and demanded.

In the Tinbergen model, the

rate of interest equilibrates the nominal quantity of money supplied and the
nominal (and real) quantity of money demanded.

In the latter model, the price

level must be given in order to determine the nominal quantity of money.
Causation runs from prices to money.

Much of the popularity of the Tinbergen

model has derived from the association of (14) and (15), respectively, with
money demand and supply functions.

The appeal of this application of the supply

and demand apparatus to money stock determination, however, requires a willingness to assume that the price level is fixed.
The character of the Tinbergen model derives not so much from its assumptions about bank behavior, as from its assumption about the role assigned to the
price level.

When the Tinbergen model was first incorporated in the large-scale

econometric models in the mid-1960s, these models possessed a Phillips curve in
which inflation was inversely related to excess capacity or the unemployment
rate.

Although the price level was not fixed in the larger models, it was

determined as a nonmonetary phenomenon. Consequently, the character of the
Tinbergen model conveyed in its expositions remained the same when it was
incorporated in the larger models, despite the fact that in the larger models
the price level was no longer exogenous. If, however, the Tinbergen model were
to be used in a larger model incorporating an expectations-adjusted Phillips'
curve and the assumption of rational expectations, then its character would be
transformed from that suggested by its expositions.
It is instructive to compare the Pigovian and Tinbergen models.

Both

comprise a real money demand function and a reserves-money multiplier relationship and both assume reserve-aggregate control.

Explicit incorporation of

- 12 -

price-level determination in the Pigovian model and implicit exogeneity of the
price level in the Tinbergen model, however, make these models very different.
In the latter, but not the former, the determinants of the public's demand for
real money balances are determinants of the nominal quantity of money.

A major

source of confusion in the money supply literature is the practice of modeling
bank behavior only without also incorporating price level determination.

This

practice leaves the character of the resulting model ambiguous.-/
By omitting the reduced form (1) of the model of Sec. 2, the Tinbergen model
makes innovations in nominal money identical to shocks to the real money demand
function.

Equate (14) and (15) and transpose the 1/rr term so that the left

side becomes the reserve demand schedule and the right side becomes the reserve
supply schedule.
[c0 + c 1 r + c2 Y] rr - NBR - fr(r:rd)

(16)

Reserve demand, the left side of (16), is identified with the public's demand
for real money balances.

In any model, changes in reserve demand derive from

changes in bank credit and the accounting link in a fractional reserves system
between bank credit and deposits.

As exposited, the Tinbergen model makes

excess supply in the credit market identical to excess demand in the market for
the quantity of money.

The post-War preeminence of Keynesian liquidity prefer-

ence theory made this assumption seem natural.
The money supply and demand schedules in the natural-rate model of Sec. 2
differ from those of the Tinbergen model.

In the latter, they are graphed with

(nominal and real) money on the horizontal axis and the interest rate on the
vertical axis.

The money demand schedule is a real money demand schedule.

With

nonborrowed reserves targeting, the money supply schedule is upward sloping
because a higher interest rate produces a lower level of free reserves - excess
reserves fall and borrowed reserves rise.
support deposits increases money supply.

This rise in reserves available to
An increase, say, in nonborrowed

-

13 -

reserves causes the money supply schedule to shift rightward. The interest rate
falls and the money stock increases as the public is moved along its real money
demand schedule.

In a regime of rate control, the money supply schedule is

horizontal [Pierce and Thomson (1972), p. 119].

Kaminow (1977, p. 391),

employing Tinbergen's model, states:
With an interest rate instrument, the rate is set so as to achieve a particular point on the demand for money curve - the point which is thought to
coincide with the targeted stock. . . . the authorities hold the supply of

money curve horizontal at the chosen rate in the hope that it will cross the
demand curve at the targeted money stock. For this reason, misses are due
only to variances in the demand for money.
The frequent failure of economists to incorporate explicitly their assumptions about the role assigned to the price level has obscured the character of
their models of the money stock.

A similar criticism is made below about the

failure of economists to incorporate explicitly the way in which the monetary
regime affects the working of their models.

Confusion has been especially great

over the effect of the choice by the monetary authority between reserves and
interest rate manipulation.
6. Use of reserves-money multiplier models in a regime of rate control
i. Sources of confusion
As discussed in Sec. 2, in a regime of rate control, the reserves-money
multiplier relationship is not relevant to the determination of the money stock.
Given the monetary rule, the actual evolution of money depends upon the real and
monetary shocks (the vt and nt) that impinge upon the system.

In the 1950s, the

Fed operated by controlling a rate of interest, rather than a reserve aggregate.
Despite this fact, quantity theorists revived Pigou's reserves-money multiplier
model, rather than Thornton's model.

Thornton's model had disappeared in the

Depression. The prevalence of "elasticity pessimism," the belief that economic
agents are insensitive to relative prices in general and interest rates in
particular, precluded its consideration. Even quantity theorists considered the

- 14 central bank discount rate ineffective as an instrument of monetary control
[Mints (1945), p. 279].

Perhaps quantity theorists espoused reserves-money

multiplier models in the 1950s because of a continuing belief that central bank
manipulation of the interest rate was an ineffectual means of monetary control.
Their concentration on reserves-money multiplier models, therefore, represented
a normative choice about desirable monetary control procedures.
Probably more important was the unsatisfactory state of interest rate theory
in the 1950s.

Debate centered on loanable-funds versus liquidity-preference

models, that is, over whether the interest rate is determined by excess demand
in the market for credit or the market for the quantity of money.

The develop-

ment of general equilibrium analysis led to the abandonment of this debate as
pointless. Discussion of the interest rate as a real phenomenon [for example
Patinkin (1956), p. 2671 was the exception.

It was not until the natural

rate-rational expectations models of the 1970s that the natural-rate characteristic of the real rate of interest could be modeled in an analytically satisfactory way [Sargent (1973)].

Quantity theorists desired a theory of the money

stock that allowed money to be exogenous in the context of the equation of
exchange.

It was, however, the natural rate concept that Thornton had exploited

in order to achieve this exogeneity.

In the general absence of this concept in

the 1950s, quantity theorists did not appreciate the significance of his model.
Models of money with reserves-money multiplier relationships generally
assume nonborrowed reserves control.

Misunderstanding about the role assigned

to nonborrowed reserves targets by the monetary authority has encouraged the
inappropriate use of these models.

It has not always been appreciated that

nonborrowed reserves have often been manipulated by the monetary authority in
order to control an interest rate operating variable.8/ For example, in the
1950s and 1960s and again recently, nonborrowed reserves have been manipulated
only in order to maintain a positive level of borrowed reserves, that is, to

- 15 -

"keep banks in the window." The level of the discount rate, taken in conjunction with a positive relationship between borrowed reserves and-the marginal
nonpecuniary costs of borrowing, is used to control the interest rate.
Multiplier formulas based on nonborrowed reserves targeting involve the
ratio of borrowed reserves to deposits.

If the central bank grants banks ready

access to the discount window as a way of controlling the interest rate, this
ratio will be interest elastic.

The relevant model then is one where the

monetary authority's instrument is an interest rate, rather than a reserve
aggregate.

If access to the window is tightly rationed or the discount rate is

kept at a level that permits only frictional borrowing, the borrowed reserves to
deposits ratio will be interest insensitive.

The reserves-money multiplier

relationship is then relevant.
In general, if any of the reserves to deposits ratios in money multiplier
formulas are interest sensitive, these formulas do not constitute an analytically useful summary of the key determinants of money.

Their ratios then merely

register the effects of more fundamental determinants of the money stock, like
the shocks vt and nt.

This point can be made by considering the control of bank

deposits by total reserves control.

(It is assumed that only checkable deposits

are reservable and that they are reservable at a uniform required reserve
ratio.)

The money stock remains subject to the same influences as with rate

control, but now these influences must work through changes in bank excess
reserves.

For example, real and monetary shocks shift the bank credit demand

schedule.

Given the association of nominal credit and deposit creation, shifts

in this schedule cause shifts in the reserve demand schedule.

The money stock

can change only if these shifts in reserve demand cause the excess reserves of
banks change.

If it is assumed that bank demand for excess reserves is interest

insensitive, total reserves control can ensure efficient money stock targeting.

- 16 ii. Problems with empirical work
In the post-War period, the use of reserves-money multiplier relationships
to organize empirical work on the supply of money has often produced irrelevant
results.

Parameters from reserves-money multiplier formulas estimated with

post-War data do not provide the intended empirical description of the supply of
money.

For example, in multiplier models, the elasticity of supply of total

reserves and deposits depends upon the interest elasticity of free reserves.
The assumption that the elasticity of free reserves (or its chief component,
borrowed reserves) is a key empirical parameter of money stock determination has
prompted a number of empirical studies [Polakoff (1960); Goldfeld and Kane
(1966)].

In a regime of rate control, however, this elasticity is not a deter-

minant of the money stock.9/
Also problematic is the practice of using post-War data to estimate
reserves-money multipliers in order to determine how closely the money stock
could be controlled with a reserve-aggregate targeting procedure.
and Rasche (1981).]

[See Johannes

For example, the behavior of reserves-money multipliers

estimated with post-War data depends upon the behavior of excess reserves.
behavior would change with reserves control.

This

Because the the Fed has operated

with an interest rate instrument, the supply of reserves has accommodated
whatever level of deposits and reserve demand has emerged at the targeted rate.
With reserve-aggregate control where, in contrast, deposits are forced to adjust
to reserves, excess reserves would become more variable.

At the current low

level of required reserve ratios, small exogenous changes in reserves would
necessitate large changes in bank asset holdings.

Reserve-aggregate control

would increase the use by banks of their excess reserves as a temporary buffer
between changes in reserves and assets.

- 17 The Tinbergen model, as part of large-scale econometric models, has been
estimated over periods like the 1950s and 1960s in which nonborrowed reserves
control was only incidental to interest rate control.

Such estimation will of

course reveal a correlation between borrowed reserves and the interest rate,
given the value of the discount rate.

This correlation, however, does not

describe a behavioral relationship significant in the determination of the money
stock.

Simulation of the estimated model under the assumption of nonborrowed

reserve control is then subject to the Lucas critique.
In general, the Lucas critique is applicable to empirical work on bank
behavior conducted without considering the way in which the monetary regime
affects bank behavior.

This point is made by Goodfriend (1983) in his criticism

of existing regression analysis explaining borrowed reserves. He points out
that banks are rationed in their use of the window through a limitation on the
allowable quantity of borrowing over a period of time.

Banks try to distribute

their borrowing so that it occurs when the differential between the funds rate
and discount rate is relatively high.
future level of interest rates.

Banks, then, are required to forecast the

With rational expectations, this requirement

makes bank borrowing behavior depend upon the character of the monetary regime.
iii. The reverse-causation debate
Interest rate smoothing by the monetary authority makes reserves and the
money stock endogenous. Especially in the 1960s, it was argued that this
endogeneity renders the quantity theory problematic.

Davis (1968, p. 68) used

reserve endogeneity to criticize Friedman's explanation of the business cycle.
Tobin (1963, p. 230) argued that it allows banks to adjust their nominal deposits in response to changes in the public's demand for real deposits.
In arguing the exogeneity of money in the context of the equation of
exchange, quantity theorists emphasized the stability of reserves-money multiplier relationships. They then argued that because the monetary authority

-

18 -

creates reserves the money stock is, at least in part, caused by the monetary
authority, rather than the public.

[See also Warburton (1975).]-1°

(i) Federal Reserve actions dominate the movement of the monetary base
over time; (ii) movements of the monetary base dominate movements of the
money supply over the business cycle; and, (iii) accelerations or decelerations of the money supply are closely followed by accelerations or
decelerations in economic activity. Therefore, the Monetarist thesis puts
forth the proposition that actions of the Federal Reserve are transmitted
to economic activity via the resulting movements in the monetary base and
money supply [Brunner (1968), p. 24].
This rebuttal of the "reverse-causation" criticism was ill founded given the
irrelevance of the reserves-money multiplier relationship in the contemporaneous
monetary regime of rate control.

In the context of the natural-rate model of

Sec. 2, quantity theorists should have responded that the endogeneity of
reserves and the money stock possesses no implications for the usefulness of
organizing an analysis of the price level and nominal income around the behavior
of the money stock.

The analytical usefulness of the quantity theory depends

upon the extent to which independent movements occur in the nominal money supply
and demand schedules. The importance of independent movements increases as the
magnitude of real shocks rises relative to monetary shocks and as the monetary
authority attempts to control real variables.
7. Models of bank behavior
i. Choice of model
Economists' choice of analytical apparatus to study bank behavior, like
their choice of a model of money, depends on the role assigned to the price
level.

This point is made below with an example of analysis from the quantity

theory tradition and a contrasting example from the real bills or banking school
tradition.

In A Tract on Monetary Reform and A Treatise on Money, Keynes argued

that the central bank should control the money stock in order to achieve price
level stability. Control of the money stock was to be effected within the
framework of a reserves-money multiplier and reserves targets.

Keynes desired

-

19 -

an analytical apparatus with banks as "creators" of nominal money, albeit constrained by the reserve creation of the central bank.

He wanted a model that

distinguished between bank creation of nominal deposits and bank intermediation
of real savings in the form of real deposits [Keynes (1930), vol. 6, p. 191]:
A banker . . . is acting both as provider of money for his depositors, and

also as a provider of resources for his borrowing customers. Thus the
modern banker performs two distinct sets of services. He supplies a
substitute for State [high-powered] Money by acting as a clearing-house and
transferring current payments. . . . But he is also acting as a middleman in

respect of a particular type of lending, receiving deposits from the public
which he employs in purchasing securities, or in making loans. . . . This

duality of function is the clue to many difficulties in the modern Theory of
Money and Credit and the source of some serious confusions of thought.
According to Keynes, analysis of the role of banks as intermediaries between
savers and investors can be conducted soley in real terms.

Analysis of their

role as suppliers of money must distinguish between real and nominal money.

If

it does not, it ignores the fact that "the manufacture of Representative Money
[bank deposits] uses up no real resources" [Keynes (1930), vol. 6, p. 214].
Tobin (1963), implicitly arguing from the Tinbergen model, contends that
introducing the public's money demand function into a theory of the money stock
invalidates the logic of the quantity theory, which requires that the price
level vary in order to cause nominal money to yield the amount of real purchasing power demanded by the public.

The public procures the real purchasing power

of money it demands, Tobin asserts, through direct adjustment of the quantity of
(nominal) money.

In the spirit of the Tinbergen model, no distinction is made

between real and nominal deposits or between financial intermediation and the
determination of bank deposits.

Banks are solely intermediaries between savers

and investors, not creators of money [Tobin (1963), p. 227]:
a bank can make a loan by "writing up" its deposit liabilities. . . .
Borrowers do not incur debt in order to hold idle deposits. . . . The
borrower pays out the money. . . . Whether or not it stays in the banking
system . . . depends on whether somewhere in the chain of transactions

initiated by the borrower's outlays are found depositors who wish to hold
new deposits.

-

20 -

ii. Irrelevance of the deposit expansion and contraction process
Since Phillips (1921), reserves-money multiplier formulas have been derived
from a model of the banking sector summarized in the multiple expansion of
deposits produced by an injection of reserves.-l/ The existence of markets for
bank reserves, however, renders this model untenable.

Phillips' model assumes

that the individual bank is constrained by the quantity of its reserves and that
its asset acquistion and deposit creation are driven by discrepancies between
actual and desired reserves.

Given the existence of markets for bank reserves,

such as the fed funds and CD markets, however, individual banks are constrained
by the price, rather than the quantity, of reserves they hold.

An alternative

to Phillips' model of individual bank behavior is offered below.
Banks are middlemen between investors and savers.
credit summarizes the return to lending to investors.
summarizes the cost of borrowing from savers.-2/
strains the asset acquisition of banks.

The market for bank
The market for reserves

The price of reserves con-

A bank purchases an asset by crediting,

either directly or via a correspondent bank, the deposit account of the seller
of the asset.

The cost of purchasing an asset depends upon the price of the

reserves that must be replaced when the seller draws down his account.

When

interest rates in the credit and reserves markets differ, banks have an incentive to alter their holdings of interest-bearing assets.

Changes in bank credit

and deposits derive from bank arbitrage of the rates in these two markets.
Fig. 1 depicts the markets for bank credit and reserves.

It is assumed that

the monetary authority targets total reserves and that the resulting vertical
reserve supply schedule, R , fluctuates randomly around a fixed level, Ro.
reserve demand schedule, Rd, is drawn for a given level of deposits.

The

Its

downward slope reflects negative interest elasticity of demand for excess
reserves.

The intersection of the reserve supply and demand schedules deter-

mines the funds rate, rf.

The bank credit demand schedule, BCd , is drawn for

F-I
ri
H-

o
rr
00
to

rI
0

H

..

OQ
H
f-I
I-a

oiC rt Y

/

rr ID O
0

ao rt
.

rt co

CD-

CD rt

D
i

.D

/

0
Ft

.t

/

0

t-h
0

r=1

co

to

ma

:j

0

I

0

H

<

0' C

H

_

/ I
I

al
0t
0

rth

co D0~

t3toto -

0

H a

CD
Fth

0to

to

~a.

to o'
o' 5wh

f-li to
X

0

frt0
DI-h
03

to0 0'

0

_

I

0

to
0
0to
CD

to

tq

CD I-

I.
CD
co
I-5H0

C~

rrtD

to

to C-'

0o

I-aI

P rt
P- 0

fh
I-I

0

0'

t
X

0e r

F-

F-h

0

HFt

rt5b
P0 AtD
f't

I-

tn

- 21 -

the price level consistent with the level of deposits assumed for the reserve
demand schedule.

At the existing funds rate, which is taken as given by indi-

vidual banks, banks will supply whatever credit their customers demand.

For

this reason, the supply of bank credit schedule, BC5 , is horizontal.Consider now a positive shock to reserves, shown by R1 .
falls from rf

0

to rf".

The funds rate

(At the original funds rate, banks' ratio of reserves to

0

deposits now exceeds the equilibrium ratio.
sell reserves, the funds rate falls.)

As they attempt collectively to

With the price of acquiring assets (the

less than the return to acquiring assets,
price of replenishing reserves), rf/,
0
rl0, banks acquire assets.
its increase.

As a consequence of asset acquisition, their depos-

This increase in deposits lowers the reserves/deposits ratio of

banks and causes their reserve demand schedule to shift rightward to R1.

As

described in Sec. 2, the increase in deposits (mt) stimulates real output and
raises prices.

The rise in prices causes the bank credit demand schedule to

shift rightward to BCJ.
.1

(In final equilibrium, the price level rises by the

same proportion as reserves, and interest rates return to their original levels.)

With total reserves control, the deposits of the banking system adjust to

the reserves of the banking system, and the reserves-money multiplier relationship is a useful summary of the determinants of the money stock.

Phillips'

model, however, lacks relevance.
8. Models of the money stock and policy
It has been argued that the role economists assign to the price level
determines their choice of model of the money stock.

It is instructive to apply

this generalization to the choice by the Fed of the model of the money stock
used in its policy deliberations. Monetary policy evolves under the assumption
that an optimal long-run policy will result from a concatenation of policy
actions, each of which appears optimal within the context of a short time
horizon. No systematic procedure is imposed whereby long-run objectives con-

22 -

-

strain-policy actions.

Each period the policy maker retains the freedom to

alter the relative priorities assigned to ultimate objectives [Hetzel (1986)].
Within this decision-making framework, it is natural for the monetary
policymaker to take the price level as given over the immediate policy horizon
14/
[Barro and Gordon (1983)].The Tinbergen model concentrates analysis at a point in time, rather than on
the evolution of stock equilibrium over time.
is natural to take the price level as given.

In a point in time exercise, it
The Tinbergen model then was the

natural model for the Fed to use in its policy deliberations.15/ With the price
level taken as given, there is no need to distinguish between nominal and real
magnitudes. The implicit assumption that the price level is given produces a
one-to-one association between the interest rate and nominal (real) money.

In

this way, the Tinbergen model appeared to capture the dilemma of policy as
perceived by the Fed in the 1970s.

It could avoid overshooting its target for

money, but only if it were willing to accept a higher rate of interest.
In the Tinbergen model, the monetary authority induces changes in money by
engineering changes in market rates that move the public along its money demand
schedule.

The low interest elasticity estimated for real money demand appeared

in the 1970s to require unacceptably large increases in rates in order to
rectify overshoots of the Ml target.

Also, the initial coefficients estimated

on the contemporaneous and lagged interest rate term in the Board's monthly
money market model were small relative to later terms.

It was argued that with

this pattern of coefficients attempts to target money closely would produce
large cycles in money and interest rates [Ciccolo (1974)].

These implications

of the Tinbergen model increased Fed reluctance to achieve its Ml target.
9. Concluding comment
According to the real bills and banking school, the demand for real money
determines the quantity of nominal money.

According to the quantity theory, at

- 23 -

least some of the determinants of the supply of nominal money differ from the
determinants of the demand for real money.

With the real rate of interest and

real output determined ultimately as nonmonetary phenomena, the price level must
vary in order to make the quantity of real money equal to the quantity of real
money desired by the public.
level.

These schools assign different roles to the price

Economists choose models of the money stock according to the roles they

assign to the price level.

The common failure to include the determination of

the price level explicitly in models of the money stock, however, has made the
character of the resulting models ambiguous.

In particular, one cannot deter-

mine to what extent, if any, the determinants of real money differ from the
determinants of nominal money.

Also, economists have commonly failed to incor-

porate the way in which the monetary regime affects the behavioral relations
relevant to determination of the money stock.

Consequently, there is a great

deal of confusion about which models of money are relevant to which monetary
regimes.

- 24 Footnotes

1.

Goodfriend (1986) studies the stochastic behavior of nominal money and the

price level in the general case where the extent to which innovations in money
are offset can lie anywhere between the extremes represented by (4) and (5).
2.

The two kinds of interest rate targets mentioned here, an interest rate

target used as an instrument for controlling a nominal (intermediate or ultimate) objective and a straight interest rate peg, imply very different monetary
regimes.

When it is not necessary to distinguish the two kinds of regimes,

reference is simply made to a "regime of rate control."
3.

First, use (3) and (4) to eliminate ht. the reserve aggregate, and to

produce an expression for mt.

This expression yields an expectation of mt+I.

Note that E(rt+1:It 1) = r, given that u1 in (3) and r are chosen to be compatible.

Therefore, the term E(rt+1 - r) is zero.

large in order to peg rt at r.
E(mt+, It_ ,,)

= (d

Now let A become arbitrarily

The result is

+ d2u) + dlr + (d2u

.)t

(6)

Equation (6) and its counterparts specify a future path for expected money.
Equations (1) and (2) and this path allow formation of an expectation of pt+14.

This accommodation could be seen in the 1970s when the Fed targeted the

funds rate.

Because of lagged reserve accounting, changes in reserves followed

changes in deposits with a two week lag.
5.

Non-interest-bearing reserves constitute the base of a tax on bank interme-

diation.

The reserves-deposits ratio of banks then has implications for the

demand for real money through its effect on the cost of intermediation.
6.

The assumed nonmonetary character of the determinants of the scale variable

in the money demand function is reflected in the comment that this variable "is
likely in general to be increased by developments that bring the forces of
nature more effectively under man's control; such as an increase in the efficiency of the people . . . through mechanical inventions or through inventions

- 25 -

in business organization' [Pigou.(1917), p. 166].

Pigou [1917, pp. 168-9]

assumes that the demand for money depends upon the alternative real resource
cost of holding money [for example, "the expected fruitfulness of industrial
activity"] and the inflation rate.
interest rate.

These factors are captured by the nominal

Pigou, however, does not include the interest rate explicitly in

his model, so the price level is left as the sole equilibrating variable.
7.

Through a series of papers written in the 1960s and early 1970s, Karl

Brunner and Allan Meltzer became the most persistent advocates of expositing
theories of the money stock in a general equilibrium framework.
their model is contained in Brunner (1973).

A summary of

They incorporate a reserves-money

multiplier relationship into a model in the spirit of the neoclassical synthesis
of Keynesian macroeconomics that occurred in the 1960s.

Explicit incorporation

[Brunner and Meltzer (1972)] of a market for real capital facilitated their
criticism of models of money making excess demand in the market for the quantity
of money identical to excess supply in the credit market, for example, Gramley
and Chase (1965).

The quantity theory character of their model of the money

stock derives from its incorporation of a long-run vertical Phillips' curve
[Brunner and Meltzer (1976), p. 84].
8.

An example of this misunderstanding occurred when the Fed announced a change

in operating procedures on October 6, 1979 [Hetzel (1982)].

The operating

variable of immediate concern to the Desk was changed from the funds rate to
nonborrowed reserves.

Many economists concluded incorrectly that the new

procedures represented monetary control within a reserves-money multiplier
framework. With lagged reserve accounting, however, bank demand for total
reserves was essentially predetermined.

The new procedures worked by supplying

an amount of nonborrowed reserves less than the predetermined demand for total
reserves and, thus, by forcing banks into the discount window.
borrowing at the window then determined the funds rate.

The cost of

That is, the funds rate

- 26 equalled the discount rate plus an amount varying positively with borrowed
reserves.

The funds rate determined the cost of bank credit extension and, in

combination with the demand for bank credit schedule, determined bank asset
acquisition and, as a consequence, bank liabilities and the money stock.

In

sum, the new procedures, like the old, worked through control of the funds rate,
although this control was exercised indirectly under the new procedures.
9.

Given the discount rate, a decreased sensitivity of borrowed reserves to the

interest rate increases the level of nonborrowed reserves required in order to
achieve a rate target.

The interest sensitivity of free reserves, therefore,

affects the division of total reserves between nonborrowed and borrowed
reserves.

Given the rate target, however, this division does not affect the

magnitude of the money stock.

(This division has implications for how the

monetary authority shares the seigniorage from reserve creation with banks.)
10.

The major response of quantity theorists to the "reverse causation" criti-

cism was that the persistence of empirical regularities between money and
nominal output over different kinds of monetary regimes implies that the primary
influence runs from money to nominal output, rather than vice versa [Brunner
(1971), p. 99; Friedman and Schwartz (1982), p. 6261.
11.

There were good reasons in the 1920s for the popularity of Phillips' model.

Under the influence of Keynes, economists at Cambridge in particular began to
advocate control of bank deposits and credit in order to stabilize the price
level.

These ideas were resisted by bankers, who criticized the idea that banks

create deposits and argued instead that banks only relend deposits entrusted to
them by the public.

They argued that banks cannot create deposits because of

the discipline exerted on deposit creation by reserve drains.

Phillips' exposi-

tion of the multiple expansion process was a tailor-made refutation to bankers'
denial that banks can create money.

- 27 -

12.

Banks acquire reserves in many markets, like the Eurodollar, RP, and CD

market.

Because they arbitrage rates across these markets, the funds rate can

then be used as a proxy for the price of obtaining reserves.
13.

Because nominal credit creation by banks does not require real resources,

it is not constrained by the real marginal cost curve applicable in the theory
of the firm.

The model then is in the spirit of models advocated in the quota-

tion from Keynes in the preceding subsection. The contrary view is reprsented
by Tobin.

[See Pesek (1976) for an extended statement of Tobin's view.]

Intermediation of the public's real savings does involve real costs.

These

costs are captured by the markup of the loan rate over the funds rate (abstracting from term-structure complications). This differential can affect the
nominal quantity of bank credit transitorily, for example, by affecting the
extent to which intermediation occurs through banks as-opposed to the commercial
paper market [Hetzel (1982), Sec. 5].
14.

Alternatively, the policymaker could start with a long-term objective, for

example, price level stability.

Optimal policy in the long run could then be

viewed as being achieved through the constraint that the long-term objective
places on policy actions each period.

The actual policy procedure, which allows

the contemporaneous inflation rate to be considered as given, facilitates
near-term forecasting of the economy.

The alternative procedure would elucidate

more clearly the way in which past actions constrain the policymaker's current
choices.

The concern of policy with the near-term behavior of the economy

dictates the actual procedure.
15.

Hetzel (1981) and Lombra and Moran (1980) describe the use of the Board's

money market model (the Tinbergen model) in the preparation of the Bluebook, a
document used by the Federal Open Market Committee.

Since the early 1970s, this

model has been used by the Board staff to offer the FOMC a menu of paired
choices of inversely-related values of the funds rate and rates of money growth.

- 28 -

BIBLIOGRAPHY
Barro, Robert J. and Gordon, David B. "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a
Natural Rate Model," Journal of Political Economy, Aug. 1983, 91(4), pp.
589-610.
of St.
Brunner, Karl. "The Role of Money and Monetary Policy," Federal Reserve Bank
9-24.
pp.
Louis Review, July 1968, 50(7),
"A Survey of Selected Issues in Monetary Theory," Schweizerische Zeitschrift
fur Volkwirtschaft und Statistik, March 1971, 107(1), pp. 1-146.
. "A Diagrammatic Exposition of the Money Supply Process," Schweizerische
Zeitschrift fur Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, Dec. 1973, 109(4), pp.
481-533.
Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan H. "Money, Debt, and Economic Activity," Journal
of Political Economy, Oct. 1972, 80(5), pp. 951-77.
. "An Aggregative Theory for a Closed Economy," in Monetarism. Ed.: Jerome L.
Stein. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1976, 69-103.
Canzoneri, Matthew B.; Henderson, Dale W. and Rogoff, Kenneth S. "The Information
Content of the Interest Rate and Optimal Monetary Policy," The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Nov. 1983, 98(4), pp. 545-65.
Ciccolo, John H. "Is Short-run Monetary Control Feasible," in Monetary Aggregates
and Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Oct. 1974, pp. 82-91.
Davis, Richard G. "The Role of the Money Supply in Business Cycles," Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Monthly Review, April 1968, 50(4), pp.6 3 -7 3 .
. "Implementing Open Market Policy with Monetary Aggregate Objectives," in
Monetary Aggregates and Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
1974, pp. 7-19.
de Leeuw, Frank. "A Model of Financial Behavior," in The Brookings Quarterly
Econometric Model of the United States. Ed.: J. Duesenberry, et al. Chicago:
Rand McNally and Co., 1965, pp. 465-530.
Dotsey, Michael and King, Robert G. "Monetary Instruments and Policy Rules in a
Rational Expectations Environment," Journal of Monetary Economics, Sept. 1983,
12(3), pp. 357-82.
and the
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna. Monetary Trends in the United States
1982.
Press,
United Kingdom. Chicago: The University of Chicago
Goldfeld, Stephen M. Commercial Bank Behavior and Economic Activity.
North Holland, 1966.

Amsterdam:

Goldfeld, Stephen M. and Kane, Edward J. "The Determinants of Member Bank Borrowing: An Econometric Study," Journal of Finance, Sept. 1966, 21(3), pp. 499-514.
and a
Goodfriend, Marvin. "A Model of Money Stock Determination with Loan Demand
Richmond
of
Bank
Reserve
Federal
Banking System Balance Sheet Constraint,"
Economic Review, Jan./Feb. 1982, 68(1), pp. 3-16.

- 29 . "Discount Window Borrowing, Monetary Policy, and the Post-October 6, 1979

Federal Reserve Operating Procedures," Journal of Monetary Economics, Sept.
1983, 12(3), pp. 343-56.
. "Interest Rate Smoothing and Price Level Trend Stationarity." Federal

Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper, April 1968.
Gramley, Lyle and Chase, Samuel B. "Time Deposits in Monetary Analysis," Federal
Reserve Bulletin, Oct. 1965, 51(10), pp. 1380-1406.
Hetzel, Robert L. "The Federal Reserve System and Control of the Money Supply in
the 1970s," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Feb. 1981, 13(1), pp. 31-43.
. "The October 1979 Regime of Monetary Control and the Behavior of the Money

Supply in 1980," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, May 1982, 14(2), pp.
234-251.
. "A Congressional Mandate for Monetary Policy," The Cato Journal, Winter

1986, 5(3), pp. 797-820.
. "Money Stock Determination in a Monetary Regime of Rate Targeting: A Histor-

ical Survey." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper, June 1986.
Johannes, James M. and Rasche, Robert H. "Can the Reserves approach to Monetary
Control Really Work?" Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Aug. 1981, 13(3),
pp. 298-313.
Kaminow, Ira. "Required Reserve Ratios, Policy Instruments, and Money Stock Control," Journal of Monetary Economics, Oct. 1977, 3(4), pp. 389-408.
Keynes, John Maynard. A Tract on Monetary Reform (1923). in The Collected Writings
of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 4. London: The Macmillan Press, 1971.
___.

A Treatise on Money (1930). in The Collected Writings of John Maynard

Keynes, vol. 5 and 6. London: The Macmillan Press, 1971.
. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936). in The Col-

lected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7. London: The Macmillan Press,
1973.
Lombra, Raymond E. and Moran, Michael. "Policy Advice and Policymaking at the
Federal Reserve," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1980,
13, pp. 9-68.
LeRoy, Stephen F. "Monetary Control under Lagged Reserve Accounting," Southern
Journal of Economics, Oct. 1979, 46(2), pp. 460-70.
Lindsey, David E.; Farr, Helen T.; Gillum, Gary P.; Kopecky, Kenneth J. and Porter,
Richard D. "Short-run Monetary Control, Evidence Under a Nonborrowed Reserve
Operating Procedure," Journal of Monetary Economics, Jan. 1984, 13(1), pp.
87-111.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Price Level Determinacy with an Interest Rate Policy Rule and
Rational Expectations," Journal of Monetary Economics, Nov. 1981, 8(3), pp.
319-29.

- 30 . "Some Issues Concerning Interest Rate Pegging, Price Level Determinacy, and

the Real Bills Doctrine," Journal of Monetary Economics, Jan. 1986, 17(1),
135-160.
Mints, Lloyd W. A History of Banking Theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1945.
Modigliani, Franco; Rasche, Robert and Cooper, J. Philip. "Central Bank Policy, the
Money Supply, and the Short-Term Rate of Interest," Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, May 1970, 2(2), pp. 166-218.
Parkin, Michael. "A Comparison of Alternative Techniques of Monetary Control Under
Rational Expectations," Manchester School, Sept. 1978, 46(3), pp. 252-87.
Patinkin, Don. Money, Interest and Prices. NY: Row, Peterson, and Co., 1956.
. "Financial Intermediaries and the Logical Structure of Monetary Theory," The

American Economic Review, March 1961, 51(1), 95-116.
Pesek, Boris P. "Monetary Theory in the Post-Robertson 'Alice in Wonderland' Era,"
Journal of Economic Literature, Sept. 1976, 14(3), pp.8 5 6 -8 8 4 .
Phillips, Chester A. Bank Credit. NY: The Macmillan Co., 1921.
Pierce, James L. and Thomson, Thomas D. "Some Issues in Controlling the Stock of
Money," in Controlling Monetary Aggregates II: The Implementation. Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston, Sept. 1972, pp. 115-36.
Pigou, Arthur C. "The Value of Money," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Nov. 1917,
32, pp. 38-65.
Polakoff, Murray E. "Reluctance Elasticity, Least Cost, and Member Bank Borrowing:
A suggested Integration," Journal of Finance, March 1960, 15(1), pp. 1-18.
Sargent, Thomas J. "Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the
Natural Rate of Unemployment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1973, 2,'
pp. 429-72.
Macroeconomic Theory. NY: Academic Press, 1979.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Wallace, Neil. "'Rational' Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule," Journal of Political
Economy, April 1975, 83(2), pp. 241-54.
Sivesind, Charles and Hurley, Kevin. "Choosing an Operating Target for Monetary
Policy," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Feb. 1980, 94(1), pp. 199-203.
Teigen, Ronald L. "The Demand for and Supply of Money." in Readings in Money,
National Income and Stabilization Policy. Eds.: W. L. Smith and R. L. Teigen.
Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, 1970, pp. 74-112.
. "Demand and Supply Functions for Money in the United States: Some Structural

Estimates," Econometrica, Oct. 1964, 32(4), pp.4 7 6 -5 0 9 .
Thomson, Thomas D.; Pierce, James L. and Parry, Robert T. "A Monthly Money Market
Model," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Nov. 1975, 7(4), 411-31.

- 31 Thornton, Henry. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of
Great Britain (1802) and Two Speeches (1811), edited with an Introduction by F.
A. v. Hayek. NY: Rinehart and Co., 1939.
Tinbergen, Jan. Statistical Testing of Business Cycle Theories. Geneva: League of
Nations, 1939.
. Econometrics. NY: The Blakiston Co., 1951.

Tinsley, Peter A.; Farr, Helen T.; Fries, Gerhard; Garrett, Bonnie and von zur
Muehlen, Peter. "Policy Robustness: Specification and Simulation of a Monthly
Money Market Model," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking Nov. 1982, 14(4),
Part 2, pp. 829-56.
Tobin, James. "Commercial Banks as Creators of 'Money'," in Banking and Monetary
Studies. Ed.: Deane Carson. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, 1963, pp. 408-19.
Warburton, Clark. "Endogeneity of Federal Reserve Behavior and the System's Responsibility for the Stock of Money: Comment," Southern Economic Journal, Oct.
1975, 42(2), pp. 299-302.