View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

PRIVATIZATION, COMPETITION, AND
SUPERCOMPETITION IN THE
MEXICAN COMMERCIAL BANKING SYSTEM
William C. Gruben
Robert P. McComb
Research Department
Working Paper 9904
Center for Latin American Economics
Working Paper 0199
July 1999

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

PRIVATIZATION, COMPETITION, AND SUPERCOMPETITION
IN THE MEXICAN COMMERCIAL BANKING SYSTEM

by
William C. Gruben
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
and
Robert P. McComb
Texas Tech University

Opinions expressed in this document do not reflect opinions of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas or of the Federal Reserve System. We wish to thank Pierre Richard Agenor, Agustin
Carstens, Brenda Gonzalez-Hermosillo, Ricardo Hausmann, Liliana Rojas-Suarez, Moises
Schwartz, Sherrill Shaffer, John H. Welch, Alejandro Werner and participants in sessions at
the Bank of Mexico, at the 1996 meetings of the Network of Central Bank Researchers of the
Americas in Mexico City, at the 1997 Latin American Meetings of the Econometric Society in
Santiago, Chile and at the 1997 meetings of the Western Economics Association in Seattle.

"Mr. Pereguna...suggests that after privatisation in 1991-92 most
banks abandoned common sense in a race to sign up customers and expand
their credit base."
Financial Times, London Edition.
October 15, 1996

A major theme in the literature of privatization is that the benefits are much abridged if a government
monopoly is simply replaced by a private sector monopoly or oligopoly (Hanson, 1994). Variations on this
theme surfaced in many discussions of Mexico's bank privatization of 1991-1992, in which controlling interests
in Mexico's 18 government-owned commercial banks were sold to financial groups - chiefly organizations that
already dominated the nation's securities industry.1
A near-universal concern was that years might pass between when Mexico's banking system was
privatized and when its performance might approach most standards of competitiveness. Although Mansell
Carstens (1993) argued that privatization would raise some measures of efficiency, she also suggested that
spreads between banks' cost of funds and interest rates on loans could remain high for years - in part because the
high degree of oligopoly power in the provision of bank services would likely continue.2 Bazdresch and
Warneck (1994) developed similar themes and - consistent with other authors - viewed Mexico's high interest
rate margins as indicative of anti-competitive market power.
An important reason for many observers' pessimism about competition in Mexican banking was the
market's heavy concentration. Gavito, Sánchez and Trigueros (1992) developed the anti-competitive implications
of concentration in the Mexican commercial banking system while Gavito and Trigueros (1993) argued that
"some additional measures would be useful to induce greater competition" in it.

1

Mexico's commercial banks had been nationalized in 1982 under the presidential administration of Jose Lopez
Portillo. Under the administration of Miguel de la Madrid Hurtado (1982-8), so-called nonbank functions of the
bank were allowed to be performed by private sector institutions. The 1991-92 privatizations of the Carlos Salinas
de Gortari administration (1988-94) were part of a series of radical reforms in the financial services industry that
actually began in 1987 during the de la Madrid Hurtado administration (1982-88).
2

At the time of the nationalization of the Mexican commercial banking system in 1982, there had been 60
Mexican banks, of which 58 were nationalized. In order to capture perceived economies of scale, Mexico
reorganized the commercial banking industry - merging the 58 commercial state-owned banks into just 18. Although
the industry had been consolidating prior to 1982 in any case, these new mergers represented a significant increase in
industry concentration. Indeed, at the time of privatization, the three largest banks accounted for nearly three-fifths of
total assets in the commercial banking system, while the three largest U.S. banking organizations at that time held
about one-seventh of U.S. commercial bank assets.

Market indicators suggested that, in fact, the new banks' purchasers themselves expected not to face
very intense competition. Gruben, Welch and Gunther (1994) and Gruben and Welch (1996) suggested that the
high price-to-book ratios paid for the banks signaled that the new owners expected the banking system's
industrial organization to remain relatively uncompetitive. Lopez-de-Silanes and Zamarripa (1995) measured the
excess of expected returns over competitive returns and found them positive and significant. The North
American Free Trade Agreement might ultimately allow greater competitive pressures in Mexico. So might the
decrease in restrictions on starting new banks (Gavito and Trigueros, 1993). All of this, however, would take
time and maybe much time. Even though privatization was expected to bring increases in lending and in the
capture of financial assets by the banking system, analysts also anticipated that Mexican banks would still behave
collusively for years - underloaning, at least compared with a competitive regime, so that they could overcharge.
But even as this industrial organization of privatization literature depicted a collusive system following
financial liberalization and privatization in Mexico, a parallel literature on the general trajectory of reactions to
financial liberalization in developing countries suggested a different pattern of possible outcomes. In that
paradigm the problem is not inadequate expansion of credit, but too much too fast. The excessiveness becomes
recognizable ex post in a wave of loan defaults and a banking crisis.
Consistent with this narrative, a common trajectory following financial liberalization and the appearance
of new or newly privatized banks (Gorton, 1992) includes rapid increases in bank assets - which would typically
include loans. Similarly de Juan (1995) notes that on a bank-by-bank level, when new owners take control of a
bank, they typically increase lending relative to the value of equity capital or the deposit base. Whether or not
these liberalizations and related rapid loan expansions are followed by large increases in loan defaults - as they
typically are in Gorton (1992), de Juan (1995), Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996), and McKinnon and Pill (1994) a common adjunct to financial liberalization is often markedly increased competition in the banking system (IMF
1993).
Under this paradigm of financial liberalization, large spreads between cost of funds and interest rates on
loans are not prima facie evidence of an uncompetitive financial system. Instead, after a repressed financial
system is liberalized, the banks are unable to supply intermediation services efficiently because they lack
expertise, qualified human resources, and adequate technology. The result is high intermediation costs that are in
3

turn covered by a large spread between cost of funds and interest rates charged (de la Cuadra and Valdés, 1992).3
Banks' portfolios become riskier because banks cannot evaluate the riskiness of loans and higher real interest
rates under the new regime. Lenders lack past distributions on which to base their assessments.4
These depictions of post liberalization/privatization banking markets are consistent with a more general
theoretical literature on strategic interaction among firms in growing markets where investment and growth of the
firm are constrained by physical factors (which could include qualified personnel) or financial factors. In this
literature, firms make pre-emptive investments as part of a struggle for market share (Spence, 1979).
These same depictions of post liberalization/privatization banking markets are also consistent with
studies of consumer behavior in which, for example, a credit card holder typically develops a long-standing
affinity for the first credit card he or she receives (Wall Street Journal, 1996). That is, banks fighting for market
share may be willing to engage in riskier strategies in newly opened markets (as, in a de facto sense, consumer
credit turned out to be in Mexico in the early 1990s) than they might in a more mature market for the simple
reason that the long-term stream of rewards might be correspondingly greater to survivors who practiced preemptive behavior.
Moreover, while concerns were raised about concentration in Mexico's privatized banking system,
concentration by itself does not imply uncompetitive behavior. Although five banks accounted for 87 percent of

3

Among the reasons de la Cuadra and Valdés (1992) offered for increasing spreads is that - when
liberalization frees up funds for intermediation and when borrowers who were credit rationed under the old
financially repressive regulations now cue up for loans - the increase in loan riskiness outstrips the increase in
loan volume. This change must be factored into the spread. Mansell Carstens (1993) notes that in the Mexican
case the increased risk was manifested in relative asset shifts toward consumer credit - the demand for which had
long been pent up. It should be noted that between December 1991 and December 1993 alone, gross past due
loans in Mexican commercial banks more than tripled, rising from 10,250.36 to 32,681.60 million. During the
same period, the indice de morosidad (gross past due loans as a percentage of total loans) increased from 4.13 to
7.26.
4

It should be noted that while bank privatization was an important financial market reform, it was by no
means the only one. Beginning in November 1988 and largely finishing in 1990 Mexico removed controls on
interest rates on bank liabilities and assets, eliminated sector-by-sector quotas and all other obligatory or targeted
lending, and phased out reserve requirements and liquidity coefficients. Moreover, as Mansell Carstens (1995)
notes, in 1988 20 percent of Mexican government financing came from the banking system but by 1993 all such
financing occurred in the money market. To offer another perspective, in 1988 only 25 percent of bank lending
was unrestricted, meaning that the rest was required as credits to the federal government, as deposits in the
central bank, or as other obligatory credits. By 1990, the year before the privatizations began, 70 percent of
bank lending was unrestricted and by 1991 100 percent was.
4

all Canadian bank assets in the early to mid-1980s - a measure of concentration similar to that of the Mexican
banking system - Shaffer's (1993) results from econometric tests of market contestability for 1969-89 "are
generally consistent with perfect competition, and strongly reject the hypothesis of joint monopoly" and Nathan
and Neave (1989) derived similar results for Canada using another measuring technique for 1982-84.
Nevertheless, concentration has been shown able to attenuate competition in banking markets under
conditions that are common in the western hemisphere. In a study of concentration and competitive behavior in
regional U.S. banking markets, Clark and Speaker (1992) found that the relation between concentration and
measures of non-competitive behavior was positive and significant under regimes of high entry restrictiveness.
Although research on bank liberalizations or privatizations are not uncommon, it is somewhat more
difficult to find econometric characterizations and hypothesis tests about them. In an effort to offer a past
distribution - and so to facilitate assessments of future bank privatization outcomes - we use Bresnahan's
approach (1982) as developed for banking by Shaffer (1993) to identify the strategies that banks in Mexico
typically followed in the wake of privatization. Some possible alternatives - although they are mutually exclusive
at any point in time - include the following. (1) Banks acted as price takers - behaving as if their demand
functions and marginal revenue functions were identical and producing to a point where marginal cost equaled
marginal revenue. The results would have included loan levels and interest rates consistent with perfect
competition. (2) Banks recognized a distinction between demand and marginal revenue functions, colluded,
produced at levels where marginal cost equaled marginal revenue, and so (compared to the perfectly competitive
outcome) effectively underloaned in order to overcharge. (3) As in case (1), banks behaved as if the marginal
revenue function and the demand function were identical. Differing from case (1), banks produced at output
levels beyond where marginal cost equals marginal revenue (or price) - moving to a point where marginal cost
exceeded marginal revenue - and creating what Shaffer (1993) refers to as a "supercompetitive market."
Our results for 1987 (when Mexico sold to the private sector a total of 34 percent of the ownership in
the publicly-owned commercial banks) through 1991 (when Mexico began to sell controlling interest in each
commercial bank to the private sector), are consistent with case (1) above, the more or less competitive case.
That is, the mean bank treated the marginal revenue and demand functions as the same and produced where
marginal cost equaled marginal revenue. Starting in 1992, however, when Mexico completed the sale of
5

controlling interest in each commercial bank to the private sector, the supracompetitive case (case (3) above)
held.
The case (3) bank strategy is consistent with efforts to derive the long-term benefits of an early lead in
market share (Shaffer, 1994) for those who can survive the obvious short-run inefficiencies. Although it is either
tenuous or impossible to draw any conclusions from just two examples, it is interesting to note that Shaffer
(1993) identifies a systemic shift to case (3) behavior in Canada immediately following liberalization there in the
early 1980s just as we do for Mexico after liberalization and privatization there. More to the point, such findings
raise supervisory and regulatory questions that can only be answered with many more models of financial
liberalizations and privatizations than two. When human capital constraints are binding, as Lopez-de-Silanes and
Zamarripa (1995) argue was true in the Mexican case, a loan expansion strategy to a point where marginal cost
exceeds marginal revenue might also be consistent with increases in past due loan ratios like those that occurred
in Mexico well before the peso crash of 1994.
1. The Model
Perhaps because of the intense regulation to which the banking industry is subject, measuring the degree
of competition in banking markets has long been the subject of study. In early work (see Gilbert's 1984 survey),
a positive link between concentrations and returns was imagined to be prima facie evidence that competition had
been abridged. This approach actually did not offer a clear statistical delineation of what competitive returns
were, however, and offered other statistical problems that are well-documented in the literature.
To avoid these difficulties, we apply a simultaneous equation model that Shaffer (1989, 1993, 1995)
introduced to the banking literature and that has been applied to additional areas and countries by Shaffer and
DiSalvo (1994), Shaffer (1994), Molyneux, Lloyd -Williams and Thornton (1994), and Molyneux, Thornton,
and Lloyd-Williams (1996). This approach allows us to test the competitiveness of the Mexican commercial
banking system by estimating an index of market power (U) and then identifying breaks in competitiveness by
applying a dummy variable. The test revolves around the idea that profit-maximizing firms set marginal cost
equal to what the literature refers to as their perceived marginal revenue. If the firm's perceived marginal
revenue schedule and the firm's demand schedule are identical, then setting marginal cost equal to perceived
marginal revenue is the same as setting marginal cost equal to demand price, yielding the classical conditions for
6

a competitive equilibrium. Here, of course, firms behave simply as price takers. In the collusive extreme, in
which firms act as a joint monopoly, the firm sets marginal cost equal to a perceived marginal revenue that
corresponds to the industry's marginal revenue curve (Bresnahan, 1982). Because the firm only perceives the
marginal revenue schedule and the demand schedule as identical under competitive equilibrium, the index we use
to gauge the competitiveness of the Mexican commercial banking system simply expresses the deviation of the
average bank's perceived marginal revenue curve from the industry demand schedule. If there is no deviation,
we have pure competition.
Following Bresnahan (1982)) we write a demand function for commercial bank services:
Q = D(P, Y, ?) + I,

(1)

where Q is quantity, P is price, Y is a vector of exogenous variables, ? is a vector of demand equation
parameters to be estimated, I is a random error term. Actual (as distinguished from perceived) marginal revenue
is:
MR

= P + h(Q, Y, ?),

(2)

= P + Q/(jQ/jP)
The function h(Q, Y, ?) is the semi-elasticity of demand, and h(]) @ 0. Firms’ perceived marginal revenue is:
MRp = P + Uh(Q, Y, ?),

(2')

where U is a new parameter to be estimated, 0 @ U @ 1. Here, U measures the degree to which firms recognize
the distinction between demand and marginal revenue functions. Let c(Q, W, A) be the average firm’s marginal
cost function, where W is a vector of exogenous supply side variables and A is a vector of supply side parameters
to be estimated. Maximizing firms will set perceived marginal revenue equal to marginal cost, or
P = c(Q, W, A) - Uh(Q, Y, ?) + M,

(3)

where M is a random error term. If firms act as price takers, so that they do not perceive a difference between
their marginal revenue functions and demand function, then U = 0. If firms act as a joint monopoly, clearly
perceiving a difference between their demand and marginal revenue functions, they set output where marginal
cost equals marginal revenue such that U = 1. Intermediate values of U correspond to other oligopoly solution
concepts. Of particular interest, U = 1/n suggests a Cournot equilibrium.

7

From the point of view of our analysis, an important detail of this procedure is that (Shaffer,1993) -U is
also a local estimate of the percentage deviation of aggregate output from the competitive equilibrium level of
output. Since actual price deviates from the competitive price by -UQ/(jQ/jP), and actual quantity deviates
from the competitive quantity by jQ/jP times the deviation in price, actual quantity will deviate from the
competitive quantity by -UQ. Thus, the percentage deviation in quantity is -UQ/Q = -U. If -U<0 then output is
less than what would occur in competitive equilibrium, meaning that firms are behaving as if they perceived that
they had market power. Even more interestingly if -U>0, then actual output seems to exceed the competitive
equilibrium level of output, although static allocative efficiency requires the marginal cost pricing outcome of U
= 0.
To estimate U, it is necessary to estimate simultaneously specifications of both (1) and (3), treating P
and Q as endogenous variables. The demand function is specified as:
Q = ?0 + ?1P + ?2Y + ? 3 PZ + ? 4 Z + ? 5 PY +? 6YZ + I

(2")

where Q is output quantity, P is output price, Y is a measure of macroeconomic activity, assumed to be an
exogenous variable, and Z is the price of a substitute for bank output, also assumed to be exogenous. The
interaction terms, the products PZ, PY and YZ, are necessary to permit rotation of the demand curve as required
to identify U.5
Following Shaffer (1993), we utilize the translog cost function to estimate the average commercial
bank’s cost function, as follows:
ln C = E0 + E1 ln Q + E2 (ln Q)2 + E3 ln W1 +

E4 ln W2 + E5 ln 2(W1) + E6 ln2 (W2)/2 +
E7 ln W1 ln W2 + E8 ln Q lnW1 + E9 ln Q ln W2,

(4)

As Shaffer (1993) explains, according to Lau (1982), a necessary and sufficient condition to identify U is
that the demand equation not be separable in at least one exogenous variable that is included in the demand
function, but excluded from the marginal cost function. This condition is satisfied if ?3 and ?5 do not both equal
zero. This specification of the demand function, apart from the interaction terms, represents a first-order
(linearized) approximation of the true demand function (Shaffer 1993). Our results lead to the conclusion that ?3
and ?5 are not zero, therefore U is identified.
5

8

where C is total cost, W1 and W2 are exogenous input prices, as explained below. Equation (4) gives rise to
following marginal cost function, c(Q, W, A),
MC = (C/Q)(A1 + A2 lnQ + A3 ln W1 + A4 ln W2) + M

(5)

Therefore, equation (3) is specified as follows:
P = -UQ/(?1 +?3 Z + ?5Y) + (C/Q)(A1 + A2 ln Q + A3 ln W1
+ A4 ln W2) + [ .

(3')

For our purpose of analyzing the effect of privatization of the commercial banking sector in Mexico, we
estimated, rather than equation (3'), the following specification of (3):
P = -UQ/(?1 +?3 Z + ?5 Y) + (C/Q)(A1 + A2 ln Q + A3 ln W1 + A4 ln W2)
- A5 DQ/(?1 +?3 Z + ?5Y) + [ ,

(3")

where D is a dummy variable to be explained below and [ is a random error term. We then estimate
simultaneously the system of equations represented by (2") and (3").
Many articles on the Mexican banking system disaggregate the system according to market scope
including large national, small national, multiregional and regional. Out of appreciation for this bank-by-bank
heterogeneity of market scope, it should be noted that the technique offered here does not rely on any particular
definition of bank markets. As long as the data sample spans at least one complete market, then estimates of U
are unbiased. In cases where the industry comprises multiple markets, U signifies the average degree of market
power over the separate markets. Note here that U reflects the behavior of the average firm in the sample. As
Shaffer (1993) notes, a dominant firm or cartel plus a competitive fringe would generate estimates of U that are a
weighted average of the competitive and collusive values - therefore exceeding the competitive value.
Another detail that could be particularly important in the Mexican context is that although this model
assumes banks are input price takers, violations of the assumption do not damage the results in a way that would
bother most modelers. If banks have market power over deposits, in violation of the assumption, it can be
shown that the specification of U overstates the overall degree of market power by misattributing any deposit

9

power to the asset side.6 Here, a finding of perfect competition or supracompetition would be even more striking
than if the input price taking assumption were not violated.
2. Data
Monthly data on all Mexican commercial banks were made available from the Central Bank of Mexico
and from Mexico's National Banking Commission for the period April, 1987 through December, 1993. These
data covered all commercial banks that were owned by the state as well as the two private banks, Obrero and
Citibank. Following December, 1993, data are reported only on a quarterly basis by the CNB, making
subsequent observations incompatible with our monthly series.
This period gives us roughly two years of monthly observations on the Mexican commercial banks after
the largest banks --and those banks holding most of the system's assets and deposits-- had been returned to
private ownership. Of the total of 81 observations on the variables in the data set, there were two missing
observations on total assets for the months of January and February, 1990. These observations were simply
excluded from the data supplied by the CNB. Thus, these estimations were based on a sample of size 79.
As in Shaffer (1993), we utilize the intermediation model of a bank. This approach, developed by Klein
(1971) and Sealey and Lindley (1977) treats a bank as a firm that uses labor to acquire deposits and, then, uses
labor and deposits to generate assets. The measure of output (Q) is thus total assets measured in 1000s of new
pesos. The price of output (P) is total interest income in 1000s of new pesos divided by total assets, i.e., the
average rate earned on assets. It should be noted that this average rate of return will be affected not only by
market lending rates but by changes in the past due loan ratio.7 Since deposits and labor are the only production
inputs, we require input prices for deposits (W1) and labor (W2). We use the average interest rate paid on
deposits, i.e., total financial costs/total liabilities for W1 and the average monthly cost of labor, i.e., total
personnel expenditures/total personnel in 1000s of new pesos for W2 in the marginal cost function.

6

For proof of this point, see Shaffer (1994), 8-9.

7

Regulatorily speaking, interest income that a past-due loan would have earned if it had not been past
due would actually have been booked for one month and thereafter would have been required to be provisioned
against. We are indebted to Javier Gavito of Mexico’s National Banking Commission for this point.
10

The substitute for banking services we utilize is commercial paper, although this market is thin in
Mexico. To proxy the price of this paper (Z), we use the rate on 28-day peso-denominated treasury bills (Cetes).
As a measure of national output, we employ the monthly index of industrial production (Y). This is the only
output measure available on a monthly basis. All nominal variables were deflated using the consumer price
index. The dummy variable (D) was set equal to zero for all months in the sample prior to January, 1992. It
took the value of 1 for all months in the sample beginning with and following January, 1992.
An attractive feature of 1987 as a starting point for the data is that it offers fewer opportunities for
expense preference behavior to affect our results than earlier commencement points would have. The expense
preference hypothesis describes an operational environment where managerial preferences for large staffs,
leisure, political accommodation or plush offices motivate deviations from cost-minimizing behavior. Expense
preference behavior represents the diversion of monopoly profits to cover inflated marginal costs, closing the gap
between price and marginal cost and masking monopoly or other noncompetitive behavior.
The virtually complete government ownership (complete except for two commercial banks) that
characterized the Mexican commercial banking system for the five years following the 1982 bank nationalization
seems to have offered opportunities for expense preference behavior. Indeed, when the Mexican government in
1987 sold to the private sector 34 percent of its ownership in the commercial banking system, and subsequently
liberalized bank regulations associated with interest rates and credit allocation, measures of bank efficiency and
profitability rose rapidly - simultaneously suggesting expense preference behavior before these events and much
reduced expense preference behavior thereafter.

3. Estimation and Results
Equations (3') and (3") were each paired with two variants of the marginal cost equation, equation (5), a
version on which no a priori restrictions were placed and a version in which the linear restriction b3 + b4 = 0
(linear homogeneity in input prices) was included. Therefore, a total of four different systems of equations were
estimated. This restriction would be appropriate if physical capital is not an input to the banks’ production.
Data that enable us to measure physical inputs over this time frame were unavailable, but Shaffer's (1993)
estimates for Canada do not show substantive differences in results between those in which physical capital was
11

included and those in which it was not. As long as physical capital does not vary much from month to month the
linear restriction does not seem unreasonable.
Our a priori expectations on the parameter estimates (ai for ?i , bi for Ai) were generally confirmed by
the results, with the exception of a4. Since the demand curve is assumed to be downward sloping, the estimate of

jQ/jP = a1 + a3Z + a5Y < 0 must hold. We also expected to find a2 > 0 and a4 > 0. As earlier noted,
either a3 or a5 must be different from zero in order to identify U, a conclusion we can reach most easily in the
case of a3. Our estimate of the parameter vector A also met with a priori expectations, although we held no a
priori expectation on b5.
The systems of equations were estimated by the method of Full Information Maximum Likelihood using
SAS. Full Information Maximum Likelihood estimation assumes normally distributed errors. Initial parameter
values for the FIML estimation were supplied by first estimating the system by non-linear Three-Stage Least
Squares. The interaction variable YZ had to be omitted in the estimation because it was nearly perfectly linearly
correlated with the variable Z. This was due to the small variation in industrial production that occurred over the
period of the sample. Therefore, in the reported results, there are no estimates for ?6.
Problems with multicollinearity remain in this sample. In particular, ln W1 is highly correlated with Z,
causing difficulty in estimating and making inferences on the parameter vector A. Nevertheless, convergence of
the estimates was fairly rapid in all cases. The estimates also appear to be robust relative to initial values of the
parameter estimates. Different sets of initial values chosen arbitrarily from within a fairly wide neighborhood of
the FIML estimates (a range from a factor of .5 to 2 times the reported FIML estimates) did not yield
significantly different results.
4. Interpretation and Discussion of Results
The results suggest bank behavior that is consistent with competitiveness before the privatization8 but
with supercompetitiveness - in which bankers still treat the marginal revenue function and the demand function as

8

Despite our distinction between a publicly-owned and a privately owned banking system, it is useful to recall that
Mexico's commercial banks were at least partially privatized during our entire sample period. In 1987, 34 percent of
the equity in the 18 publicly-owned was sold to private investors and large increases in profitability and efficiency
soon followed. It was not until the privatization of 1991-92, however, that private investors were permitted to hold
the majority of the equity in each bank.
12

identical but marginal cost exceeds marginal revenue - after the privatization. Recall that the value of -U
represents a typical bank's percentage deviation of output from competitive levels. Thus, a -U<0 signifies
output below the competitive level while -U>0 suggests that output for some reason exceeds the competitive
level.
In point of fact, we could not reject the hypothesis that U = 0 at a reasonable level of significance for
any of the estimations. However, instead of equaling U, the index of market power will equal U + A5 whenever
the dummy variable is equal to one, as it does for 1992-3. In both models that we test, the hypothesis that the
1992-3 dummy variable A5 equals zero can be rejected at the .05 level of significance
The sign and value of A5, the dummy variable coefficient, deserve attention. Note that a positive and
significant coefficient would suggest that the industry is acting less competitively after the government’s
divestiture of the largest banks. But instead of a positive and significant coefficient, those on our dummy
variables took on negative and significant values, so that (U + A5))<0.9 Here, the value of -(U + A5)) represents
the typical bank's output's percentage deviation from competitive levels after privatization. This suggests that the
supercompetitive level of output in the post-privatization market was 7-10 percent above what would have
prevailed in a competitive market.10
Although our findings of supercompetitiveness for the average bank are inconsistent with a paradigm in
which all banks underproduce in order to overcharge (where overcharging signifies prices that are higher than in

In light of the previous discussion of expense preference behavior, it deserves note that where (U +
A5))<0, expense preference behavior would by definition be unsustainable. Although it is conceivable that under
some circumstances a negative (U + A5)) could capture a time-consuming transition from expense preference
9

behavior towards cost-minimizing behavior, it can be argued that the change in bank behavior after 1987 but
before the privatization suggests at the very least significant reductions in such behavior well before the
privatization.

10

Because of the peculiarity of the supercompetitive outcome, we performed a Goldfeld-Quandt (1973)
switching regression, following the application in Shaffer’s (1993) model of the Canadian banking system. The
only notable regime shift (in fact, the only regime shift) took place at the 1991-92 privatization process, as we
had hypothesized.
13

a competitive outcome) the supercompetitive result nevertheless is consistent with several other paradigms. As
noted earlier, supercompetitive behavior is consistent with short-run efforts to grab market share. If banks
believe they can derive long-run profits from engaging in short-run inefficiencies in the extension of credit overproducing and undercharging, given the risks involved. This approach is consistent with a model delineated
by Spence (1979).
Although the market share argument as we have presented it might apply to many newly deregulated
industries, the peculiarities of a deregulated banking environment with deposit insurance and lender-of-last-resort
options in a McKinnon and Pill (1996) overborrowing model can clearly aggravate the phenomenon. That is,
without these governmental supports the overborrowing (or, as we have cast it, overlending) could be less
profound. The reaction to liberalization might not be qualitatively different, but deposit insurance against bad
outcomes can be seen as lowering the constraints on risky behavior (Kareken and Wallace, 1978; Merton, 1977;
Calomiris, 1990a, 1990b; Grossman, 1992; Hooks and Robinson, 1996; and a host of others) even if bank
charter or franchise value does mitigate the risk-taking incentives of deposit insurance.
To the extent that our findings of supercompetitive bank behavior may signify a struggle for market
share in Mexico, they are consistent with assessments of bank behavior in the wake of other liberalizations although these other assessments have rarely involved econometric testing. Drees and Pazarbaóioµlu (1995) note
that, following deregulation in Finland, Norway, and Sweden, banks appeared to have employed market-share
strategies after deregulation.
Although we have argued that our post-privatization results are consistent with a temporary struggle for
market share, other analytics could explain the risky behavior banks pursued in the early 1990s. Large inflows
of international capital might explain the entrance of banks into riskier investments. This phenomenon could
explain the subsequent large increases in the ratio of past due loans to total loans, but it may be more difficult to
use as an argument for why banks suddenly produced services where marginal cost exceeded marginal revenue
immediately after the privatizations.
Another argument that might be offered is that the deregulation of the banking system is tantamount to a
reduction in the franchise value of the banking system and therefore a motivation to take larger risks. However,

14

for the case of Mexico during our study period, Rojas-Suarez and Weisbrod (1994) offer statistical evidence and
arguments that the franchise value actually increased, rather than declined.
It is difficult to generalize from our results about what may occur as a general result of financial
liberalization, but the consistency of Shaffer's (1993) findings for Canada with ours for Mexico offer grounds for
concern although not for despair. Both Shaffer's (1993) results and ours find post-liberalization shifts in bank
behavior away from an apparent matching of marginal cost to marginal revenue where banks treated the marginal
revenue function and the demand function as if they were the same and toward supercompetition. Although the
Canadian liberalization was not followed by banking problems of a magnitude anyone would characterize as a
banking crisis, even Canada saw a significant increase in problem banks in the years following the liberalization.
That Canada did not suffer from a banking crisis demonstrates that a simple finding of the anomalous
relation we identified between marginal cost and marginal revenue in Mexico is not necessarily the basis for
serious subsequent banking difficulties. Moreover, whether or not supercompetitive behavior is really typical
after privatizations or financial liberalization is a question that can only be answered by modeling the
liberalizations of additional countries. But if supercompetitive behavior is indeed widespread in the wake of a
liberalization, the fact that it is suboptimal in the long run raises questions about how regulators might optimally
respond in the short run to a discovery that it has become typical - at least temporarily .
A common argument in the financial literature is that bank crises do not necessarily signal bad bank
supervision or regulation or a bad legal structure on which bank supervision is based. Just as dams are
economical means to avoid some floods but not all, it is possible that some types of bank crises would require
such coercive regulation in order to avoid them that the regulations offer more problems than the crisis.
Even a finding that after liberalizations banks typically operate in the short run in ways that are not
consistent with long-run optimality does not necessarily signal either bad bank supervision and bad bank
regulations or law either. However, such a finding raises these questions in ways that a simple outcome of a
banking crisis in and of itself would not. The reason is, operating at a point where marginal cost exceeds
marginal revenue may be seen as far more likely to be endogenous than a bank crisis itself, whose causes may
have more exogenous elements than those involved with producing supercompetitively.

15

Table 3.1
Results for Estimation of Equations (2") and Unrestricted (3')

DF

DF

Equation

Model

Error

SSE

MSE

Root MSE

R²

Adj R²

Q

4.5

74.5

4.3641E11

5.85779E9

76536.22

0.7237

0.7107

P

6.5

72.5

0.000432

5.9519E-6

0.002440

0.9714

0.9692

Approx. `TD

Approx.

Parameter

Estimate

Std Err

Ratio

Prob>|T|

A0

1379754.79

825572.1

1.67

0.0989

A1

83924415

36580204

-2.29

0.0247

A2

-7590.33

6843.7

-1.11

0.2710

A3

2321286.24

495190.9

4.69

0.0001

A4

-200183.33

32634.6

-6.13

0.0001

A5

840009.48

337258.6

2.49

0.0150

U

-0.043033

0.12236

-0.35

0.7261

B1

0.00599766

0.0016404

3.66

0.0005

B2

0.00043163

0.0001496

-2.89

0.0051

B3

0.00014460

0.00006671

2.17

0.0335

B4

0.00056957

0.0002237

2.55

0.0130

16

Table 3.2
Results of Estimation of Equations (2") and (3")
DF

DF

Equation

Model

Error

SSE

MSE

Root MSE

R2

Adj R2

Q

4.5

74.5

3.5798E11

4.80506E9

69318.57

0.7733

0.7627

P

7.5

71.5

0.000297

4.151E-6

0.002037

0.9803

0.9785

Approx. `TD

Approx.

Parameter

Estimate

Std Err

Ratio

Prob>|T|

A0

714001.65

580105.9

1.23

0.2223

A1

-52278384

23980389

-2.18

0.0325

A2

-1946.58

4693.3

-0.41

0.6795

A3

1998425.38

402359.6

4.97

0.0001

A4

-177860.12

25506.7

-6.97

0.0001

A5

549220.03

221777.6

2.48

0.0156

U

0.097824

0.11329

0.86

0.3908

B1

0.00318320

0.0013531

2.35

0.0214

B2

-0.00016678

0.0001186

-1.41

0.1639

B3

0.000086297

0.00005676

1.52

0.1329

B4

0.000076402

0.0001628

0.47

0.6403

B5

-0.147526

0.06916

-2.13

0.0364

17

Table 3.3
Results of Estimation of Equations (2") and (3") with Linear Restriction
DF

DF

Equation

Model

Error

SSE

MSE

Root MSE

R2

Adj R2

Q

4.5

74.5

3.1233E11

4.19237E9

64748.48

0.8022

0.7930

P

6.5

72.5

0.000261

3.5999E-6

0.001897

0.9827

0.9814

Approx. `TD

Approx.

Parameter

Estimate

Std Err

Ratio

Prob>|T|

A0

497897.33

504405.5

0.99

0.3268

A1

-40279385

20148688

-2.00

0.0493

A2

18.682204

4027.2

0.00

0.9963

A3

1904847.34

376275.7

5.06

0.0001

A4

-166562.92

21583.4

-7.72

0.0001

A5

428758.59

185228.8

2.31

0.0234

U

0.072766

0.07562

0.96

0.3392

B1

0.00207106

0.0005600

3.70

0.0004

B2

-0.00006023

0.00004645

-1.30

0.1989

B4

-0.00009061

0.00004109

-2.21

0.0306

B5

-0.133144

0.05046

-2.64

0.0102

18

References
Bazdresch, Carlos and Carlos Elizondo (1993), "Privatization: The Mexican Case," Quarterly Review of
Economics and Finance, Vol. 33, Special Issue, 45-66.
Bresnahan, Timothy (1982). “The Oligopoly Solution is Identified.” Economics Letters 10, 87-92.
Calomiris, Charles W. (1990a), "Is Deposit Insurance Necessary? A Historical Perspective," The Journal of
Economic History, 50, No. 2, (June), 283-95.
Calomiris, Charles W. (1990b), "Do Vulnerable Economies Need Deposit Insurance? Lessons from the U.S.
Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s," in Philip E. Brock (ed.) If Texas Were Chile (San Francisco:
Institute for Contemporary Studies Press).
Calvo, Guillermo (1995), "Varieties of Capital Market Crises," Center for International Economics, Department
of Economics, Univeristy of Maryland at College Park, Working Paper No. 15.
Clark, Jeffrey, and Paul J. Speaker (1992). “The Impact of Entry Conditions on the Concentration-Profitability
Relationship in Banking.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 32, 45-64.
de Juan, Aristóbulo (1995), "The Roots of Banking Crises: Micro-Economic Issues and Issues of Supervision
and Regulation," Paper prepared for the Conference on Banking Crises in Latin America, InterAmerican Development Bank, Washington, D.C. (October 6)
de la Cuadra, Sergio and Salvador Valdés (1992), "Myths and Facts About Financial Liberalization in Chile:
1974-1983," in Philip E. Brock (ed.) If Texas Were Chile (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary
Studies Press).
Drees, Burkhard and Ceyla Pazarbaóioµlu (1995), "The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls in Financial
Liberalization?", International Monetary Fund, WP/96/61, (June).
Gavito, Javier and Ignacio Trigueros (1993), "Los Efectos del TLC Sobre Las Entidades
Financieras," Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de México, May.
Gavito Mohar, Javier, Sergio Sánchez Garcia and Ignacio Trigueros Legarreta (1992), "Los
servicios financieros y el Acuerdo de Libre Comercio: bancos y casas de bolsa," in Eduardo Andere
and Georgina Kessel (eds.) México y el Tratado Trilateral de Libre Comercio (México, D.F.: Instituto
Tecnologico Autonomo de México and McGraw-Hill).
R. Alton Gilbert (1984), "Bank market Structure and Comeptition: A Survey," Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 16 (November), 617-45.
Goldfeld, Stephen and Richard Quandt (1973), “The Estimation of Structural Shifts by Switching Regressions,”
Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 2, 475-485.
Gorton, Gary, (1992) "Comment," in Phillip E. Brock (ed.) If Texas Were Chile (San Francisco: Institute for
Contemporary Studies Press).

19

Grossman, Richard S., (1992), "Deposit Insurance, regulation and Moral Hazard in theThrift Industry:
Evidence from the 1930s," American Economic Review, 82.4, 800-21.
Gruben, William C., John H. Welch, and Jeffrey W. Gunther (1994), "U.S. Banks, Competition and the
Mexican Banking System: How Much Will NAFTA Matter?" Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Research Department Working Paper 94-10.
Hanson, Gordon H. (1994), "Antitrust in Post-privatization Latin America: An Analysis of the Mexican
Airlines Industry," Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance Vol. 34 (Special issue), 199-216.
Hooks, Linda M. and Kenneth J. Robinson (1996), "Moral Hazard and Texas Banking in the 1920s," Financial
Industry Studies Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Mimeo.
International Monetary Fund (1993), International Capital Markets, Part II: Systematic Issues in International
Finance.
Kaminsky, Graciela L. and Carmen M. Reinhart (1996), The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and
Balance-of-Payments Problems," Federal Reserve System International Finance Dicussion Papers, No.
544, (March).
Kareken, John H. and Neil Wallace (1978), "Depoist Insurance and Bank Regulation: A Partial Equilibrium
Exposition," Joruanl of Business 51 (July), 413-38.
Klein, Michael (1971). “A Theory of the Banking Firm.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 7
(February), 205-18.
Lau, Lawrence J (1982). “On Identifying the Degree of Competitiveness from Industry Price and Output
Data.” Economics Letters 10, 93-99.
Lopez de Silanes, Florencio, and Guillermo Zamarripa (1995) , "Deregulation and Privatization of Commercial
Banking," Revista de Analysis Economico, Vol. 10, No. 2, 113-164 (November).
Mansell Carstens, Catherine (1993), "The Impact of the Mexican Bank Reprivatizations," Paper presented to the
Institute of the Americas La Jolla California Conference on Privatization in Latin America (January).
Mansell Carstens, Catherine (1995), Las Finanzas Populares en Mexico: El Redescrubrimiento de un Sistema
Financiero Olvidado (México, D.F.: CEMLA).
McComb, Robert, William C. Gruben, and John Welch (1994). “Privatization and Performance in the Mexican
Financial Services Industry.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 34 (Summer), 217-235.
McKinnon, Ronald I. and Huw Pill (1996), "Credible Liberalizations and International Capital Flows: "The
Overborrowing Syndrome," in Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger (eds). Financial Deregulation and
Integration in East Asia (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press).
Merton, Robert C. (1977), "An Analytical Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantees:
An Application of Modern Option Pricing Theory," Journal of Banking and Finance, 3-11.
Molyneux, Philip, John Thornton and D. Michael Lloyd-Williams (1996), “Competition and Market
Contestability in Japanese Commercial Banking,” Journal of Economics and Business, 48, 33-45.
Molyneux, Phil, D. M. Lloyd-Williams and John Thornton (1994), “Competitive Conditions in European
Banking,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 18, 445-459.
20

Nathan, Alli and Edwin H. Neave (1989), "Competition and Contestability in Canada's Financial System:
Empirical Results," Canadian Journal of Economics 22 (August), 576-94.
Ostos Jaye, Raul Leslie Gerardo Martinez (1996), Crisis Bancarias, Burbujas Racionales y Regulacion
Financiera: Lecciones Para El Caso de Mexico, Tesis Que Para Obtener El Titulo de Licenciado en
Economia, Instituto Tecnological Autonomo de Mexico.
Peltzman, Sam (1976), "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation," Journal of Law and Economics 20
(October), 211-40.
Rojas-Suarez, Liliana and Steven R. Weisbrod (1996), "Central Bank Provision of Liquidity: Its Impact on
Bank Asset Quality," Inter American Development Bank, (April).
Sealey, Calvin W., and James T. Lindley (1977). “Inputs, Outputs, and a Theory of Production and Cost at
Depository Financial Institutions.” Journal of Finance, 32 (September) 1251-66.
Shaffer, Sherrill (1989), "Competition in the U.S. Banking Industry," Economics Letters, 29, 321-3.
Shaffer, Sherrill (1993). “A Test of Competition in Canadian Banking.” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 25 (February) 49-61.
Shaffer, Sherrill (1994), “Evidence of Monopoly Power Among Credit Card Banks,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Working Paper No. 94-16.
Shaffer, Sherrill (1995), "Market Conduct and Aggregate Excess Capacity in Banking: A Cross-Country
Comparision," Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper No. 93-28R.
Shaffer, Sherrill and James DiSalvo (1994), “Conduct in a Banking Duopoly,” Journal of Banking and Finance,
18, 1063-1082.
Suominen, Matti (1994), “Measuring Competition in Banking: A Two-Product Model,” Scandinavian Journal
of Economics, 96, 95-110.
Spence, A. Michael (1979), "Investment Strategy and Growth in a New Market," The Bell Journal of
Economics, 1-19.
Wall Street Journal (1996), Business Bulletin, July 25, p.1.

21