View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

IS FOREIGN-CURRENCY INDEXED
DEBT A COMMITMENT TECHNOLOGY?
SOME EVIDENCE FROM BRAZIL AND MEXICO
William C. Gruben
Darryl McLeod
Research Department
Working Paper 9913
Center for Latin American Economics
Working Paper 0299
December 1999

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Is Foreign-Currency Indexed Debt a Commitment Technology? Some Evidence
from Brazil and Mexico
William C. Gruben
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Darryl McLeod
Fordham University

PRELIMINARY PAPER

We examine the effects of foreign currency-indexed debt upon inflationary expectations
in Brazil and Mexico. Conjecturing that markets will view increasing overhangs of
foreign currency-indexed debt as a commitment technology that fiscally punishes
devaluation – we test whether increasing such overhangs will attenuate the effect of
monetary growth upon inflationary expectations. We find some econometric
confirmation of these conjectures in both the Brazilian and Mexican cases. Finding that
the results are consistent with the notion that increasing the share of dollar indexed debt
may also permit some temporary monetary independence even under pegged exchange
rate regimes, we present some evidence of independent policy behavior during periods
when are model results would suggest it.

Opinions expressed in this paper do not reflect the opinions of the Federal Reserve
System or Fordham University.

1

Although the literature of the last fifteen years has devoted much attention to
credibility problems and to commitment technologies, the role of foreign currencydenominated or foreign-currency indexed debt has not received much note. Even so,
there is not only evidence to suggest that such debt may be a commitment technology, but
that countries with pegged exchange rates and relatively open capital markets have
treated it as a medium that would allow them temporarily to pursue monetary
independence.
We offer tests of dollar-indexed debt as a commitment technology in Mexico
during the early 1990s and in Brazil in the late 1990s. We present evidence to suggest
that this debt may have been a sufficiently strong commitment technology that it
significantly offset the effects of monetary growth upon rates of price increase in both
countries. That is, rates of monetary growth that would otherwise have caused price
inflation would not be inflationary if accompanied by increasing levels of debt indexation
Consistent with the notion that debt choice may affect monetary independence, at
the times Brazilian and Mexican foreign currency indexed debt were increasing as shares
of total debt, the two countries appear to have pursued monetary policies that were not
fully consistent with those of the United States. At those times, each country’s currency
was pegged to the dollar.
Foreign Currency Indexed Debt as a Policy Instrument
A typical reaction among analysts when a country suddenly begins to issue large
quantities of debt that is denominated in or indexed to a foreign currency is that this step
is a last resort. That is, analysts may guess that the country’s domestic currency
denominated debt has become expensive because of market fears of exchange rate risk

2

under a pegged exchange rate regime, and that the country is issuing foreign currency
denominated debt to avoid paying the exchange risk premium.1
Consistent with this reasoning, it is in fact not unusual to see interest rates on
domestic currency denominated bonds increase significantly while foreign currency
interest rates for the same stressed sovereign debtor do not. But while foreign currency
indexed debt may sometimes be viewed as a debt instrument that investors will accept as
a way to avoid exchange rate risk, this debt can also be seen as a policy instrument or more narrowly - an instrument of commitment.
This debt can serve as a commitment instrument because of the punishment such
debt inflicts on debtor countries that devalue. Recall that a devaluation increases the real
domestic currency value of foreign currency indexed debt. If issuance of this debt
increases the cost of devaluation, then an issuing country may be more likely to avoid
policies that could lead to devaluation – including monetary instability and fiscal
imbalance.
To highlight the penalizing implications of foreign currency denominated debt,
consider in contrast the fiscal impacts of devaluation upon domestic currency
denominated debt. A burst of inflation typically follows a nominal devaluation, reducing
the real value of debt that is denominated in the domestic currency.2 In fact, the
reduction may be seen as the purpose of the devaluation.3

1

Note that if the market’s concerns solely involved default risk that was unconnected to exchange risk, the
use of foreign currency indexed bonds would not result in any interest rate differential. That is, foreign
currency indexed debt would not have a different interest rate than domestic currency denominated debt if
foreign exchange risk were not the problem.
2 For much fuller development of this notion see, for example, Ize and Ortiz (1987). For inflation to
reduce the real value of domestic currency denominated debt, of course, the debt must not be indexed to
inflation.
3 On a related note, the devaluation may also be seen as a way of increasing the domestic currency value
of foreign exchange reserves. This approach to accounting is based on the notion that these reserves could

3

Because of the penalizing effects of foreign currency denominated debt when a
devaluation occurs, the presence of such debt could affect market interpretations of what
a government’s tactics may imply at some given point in time. With such a commitment
technology in place, what might otherwise look like the beginning of a disturbing pattern
of monetary expansionism might be interpreted as a temporary blip that will be followed
by a return to monetary stability. Foreign capital may be expected to remain longer in the
country, ceteris paribus, and devaluation may become less likely. It may take longer than
otherwise for the market to decide that a government is pursuing a persistently expansive
monetary policy, or pursuing an expansive monetary policy at all.
As a result, it may even appear that such debt might permit a country with a
pegged exchange rate to pursue an independent policy temporarily with impunity –
despite the usual concerns about monetary independence in a regime with pegged
exchange rates and open capital markets. If the payoff to a transitory deviation toward
independence were sufficiently large – or compelled by a negative shock that seemed
only temporary – a country might use the issuance of such debt as a sort of shield against
investor concerns to allow some monetary independence.
Testing for a Commitment Interpretation: The Inflation Equations
To test whether the market interprets foreign currency denominated debt as a
commitment technology we begin with equations that link changes in prices to changes in
other variables, including foreign currency denominated debt’s share of total debt. The
idea behind using prices may be seen in the work of Brown and Whealen (1993), which
offers econometric and survey evidence to suggest that current changes in prices reflect

be used to retire the debt holdings of foreign creditors who wish to exchange domestic currency
denominated debt for the creditors’ own currency. .

4

changes in agent expectations of future prices. Using equations for Brazil and Mexico
that include inflation on the left hand side, and monetary growth and the share of foreign
currency denominated debt (among other variables) on the right hand side, we find that
the share of foreign currency debt in total debt offsets the effect of monetary growth on
prices. Consistent with the findings of Brown and Whealan, this result can be interpreted
as signifying that increasing the share of foreign currency denominated debt to total debt
would offset the (positive) effect of a given rate of monetary growth on price (and
ultimately, devaluation) expectations.
If increases in the share of foreign currency denominated debt offset market
expectations of the inflationary impact of increases in monetary growth, then markets
may be interpreting this debt as assuring that the country will not persist in monetary
expansionism long enough and sufficiently to accelerate inflation. That is, even though a
given increase in monetary growth without an increase in foreign currency denominated
debt would suggest inflation, the same increase with an increase in foreign currency
denominated debt need not suggest it. This conclusion would be consistent with a notion
expressed by Sachs, Tornell, and Velasco (1995, p.9) concerning Mexico’s application of
this commitment: “The move toward dollar denominated debt was greeted with
enthusiasm by the financial markets: only a government that would never devalue could
contemplate borrowing in a foreign currency.”
In contrast, if increases in the share of foreign currency denominated debt did not
offset the impact of monetary growth on inflationary expectations, the market must not be
interpreting foreign currency denominated debt issuance as a commitment technology.

5

That is, if the market thought a given increase in money stock implied a given increase in
expected inflation regardless of the issuance of such debt, then the market clearly would
not be interpreting foreign currency denominated debt as meaning the country would not
inflate significantly.
To test for this relationship between inflation expectations, monetary growth, and
the share of foreign currency denominated debt in total debt we began with a very
simplified inflationary expectations model similar to Gould (1994). We use month-overmonth inflation rates as the dependent variable and apply measures of growth in
monetary aggregates as an independent variable.4
Consistent with what could be expected in a money demand equation, which this
equation somewhat resembles before rearrangement of variables on the two sides of the
equation, we also applied a domestic interest rate variable on the right hand side.
Specifically we used the rates on the most common three-month government bonds in
each country – rates on Selics in Brazil and on Cetes in Mexico.5 In the case of a model
that attempts to characterize inflationary expectations the interest rate variables may be
expected to be positively related to the dependent variable, however, as the market
expresses its concern about increases future inflation by increasing interest rates now.
Finally, we applied measures of the ratio of foreign exchange indexed debt for
each of the two countries. It should be noted that the periods we model are different for
the two countries. Brazil’s use of foreign currency denominated debt was heaviest during

4

We used first differences of logs – growth rates - for these variables because raw measures of both CPI
and money stock tested out (both Augmented Dickey Fuller and Phillips Perrone) as having unit roots.
5 The similarity of this equation to a money demand equation also motivated us to include growth in
industrial production as an independent variable in preliminary testing. However, neither contemporaneous
nor lagged industrial production variables ever proved significant even at the .30 level – much less the .10,
.05 or .01 levels, and we accordingly removed these from later estimates.

6

Table 1
BRAZIL

BRAZIL

MEXICO

MEXICO

Constant

0.001976
(0.395440)

-0.000375
(-0.067121)

0.001644
(0.596397)

0.001025
(0.415284)

FM1(-1)

0.031624
(2.626720)***

0.052031
(7.173744)***

FM1(-2)

0.005639
(0.489852)

0.024062
(3.222305)***

FM2(-1)

0.032242
(0.793373)
0.026162
(0.718586)

FM2(-2)

0.101615
(7.019095)***
0.038792
(2.648751)***

Dollar Debt

-0.000712
(-2.669234)***

-0.000633
(-2.316516)**

-0.000270
(-1.381641)

-0.000300
(-1.684613)*

Bond Rate

0.000373
(3.453491)***

0.000395
(3.933624)***

0.000390
(3.458252)***

0.000371
(3.700687)***

Colosio

-0.002705
(-0.837409)

-0.003778
(-1.106342)

Aguinaldo

0.004533
(2.945348)***

0.005279
(3.483274)***

AR(1)

0.291086
(1.855453)*

0.178705
(1.086964)

0.572315
(5.037573)***

0.507544
(4.991106)***

_
R2

0.614910

0.565006

0.818835

0.809620

_
R2

0.564241

0.507770

0.796586

0.786240

7

the latter 1990s. We use the period January 1995 – December 1998 to allow the
considerable variation in the role of foreign currency indexed debt after the initiation of
the Real plan in 1994 but before Brazil’s major devaluation in January of 1999. We use
August 1989 through December 1994 to give a period during which Mexico’s foreign
currency denominated debt went from a very small portion of total debt to a very large
one.
The results can be seen in Table 1, where FM1(-1) and FM1(-2) represent month
over month percentage changes in M1 lagged once and twice respectively and FM2(-1)
and FM2(-1) represent the same lags for M2. Dollar Debt refers to the share of foreign
currency indexed debt to total debt, inasmuch as the debt of both Brazil and Mexico in
the respective periods under analysis were indexed to the dollar. Bond Rate refers to the
interest rate on three-month government paper, Selics in the case of Brazil and Cetes in
the case of Mexico. The AR(1) variable is simply an autoregressive term used to
accommodate autoregressive disturbances. Finally, two dummy variables are used for
Mexico. Aguinaldo refers to the practice of the same name in Mexico of giving an
thirteenth month of salary to workers each December, which may be seen as affecting the
relation between monetary growth and prices. Colosio refers to a three-month period
following the assassination in 1994 of Partido Revolucionario Institucional presidential
candidate Luis Donaldo Colosio, when financial markets were particularly disrupted.
Interestingly, while the relation between M1 growth and inflation is positive and
significant in both Mexico and Brazil, the relation between M2 and inflation is positive in
both countries but significant only in Mexico. Certainly a positive relation between
growth in monetary aggregates and inflation is to be expected, since inflation is too much

8

money chasing too few goods, although this connection is sometimes less clear in other
countries.. With respect to the absence of statistical significance in the case of Brazilian
M2, the disconnection between M2 and inflation may be more tenuous in Brazil because
of measurement peculiarities. Unlike that of Mexico, Brazilian M2 includes certain types
of security holdings which may signify that this measure is farther removed from a
medium of exchange role not only than Mexican M2 but than M2 in most countries
In contrast, the ratio of dollar denominated debt to total debt, as expressed in the
Dollar Debt variable, is negative and significant (at least at the .10 level) for both
Brazilian equations but for Mexico is significant only for the M2 equation. Indeed, the
Dollar Debt variable was significant at only the 0.1725 level of significance. In any case,
Dollar Debt and the monetary aggregate variables were of the expected and opposite
signs and both were significant in the cases of Brazilian M1 and Mexican M2. These
models offer evidence of opposite and significant effects of monetary growth and of the
share of debt that is foreign currency (specifically dollar in these countries)
denominated.6
What these equations signify is that it is possible to offset the effect of monetary
growth upon inflationary expectations – perhaps only temporarily – by increasing the
share of foreign currency denominated debt. That result was not only a conjecture of this
paper, but is implied in the statement of Sachs, Tornell and Velasco (1995,b) with respect
to the Mexican case. It should be noted that the time period under consideration includes
the same period to which Sachs, Tornell and Velasco applied their remark.

6

In various equation configurations using Mexican M1 growth and growth rates of the share of dollar
denominated debt, we derived significance for both variables, but the relationship did not hold for Brazil.

9

Index
Jan.1995 = 100

Chart 1
M1 Levels in Brazil & The United States

280

Brazil

260
240
220
200
180
160
140
120

U.S.A.

100
80
1995

1996

1997

10

1998

Interest
Rate

Chart 2
Mexican 91 Day Cetes & U.S. 3 Month T-Bills

18

Mexican Cetes

16
14
12
10
8

U.S. T-Bills

6
4
2
Jan-94

Feb-94

Mar-94

Apr-94

May-94

Jun-94

11

Jul-94

Aug-94

Sep-94

Oct-94

Nov-94

Interpreting Monetary Policy Under Foreign Currency Indexed Debt Regimes
Some aspects of monetary policy in Brazil and Mexico may at least be tentatively
interpreted as consistent with the policy implications of the results in Table 1. In the wake of
Brazil’s implementation of its Real plan in 1994, for example, Brazilian M1 expansion far
outstripped that of the United States (Chart 1) despite the pegging of Brazil’s currency to
the dollar. The presence of an increasing share of dollar denominated debt particularly in
1997-1998 is certainly not the only explanation for this differential in growth. Drastic
reductions in inflation, as occurred after the inception of the Real plan, typically motivate
increases in the demand for domestic currency. After all, a currency can serve the
function of a store of value in periods of low inflation far more than during high inflation.
However, both countries in this study offered examples of what might be interpreted as
monetary-policy-related performance that was inconsistent with U.S. performance during
the same period.
In the case of Mexico, for example, following the assassination of Luis Donaldo
Colosio in March of 1994, Mexican interest rates increased rapidly both in relation to
U.S. rates and in absolute terms. However, in June 1994, rates were caused to fall and
they remained low until the December 1994 devaluation pushed them up rapidly. While
U.S interest rates moved up steadily throughout 1994, as can be seen in Chart 2, Mexican
rates softened after middle of the year. Central bank credit to the nation’s financial sector
went up markedly. The expansion was presented as an offset to falling foreign currency
reserves, the decline of which was seen as taking place because of political factors. As
one motivation, Mexico’s central bank cited incipient problems in the commercial
banking system that would have worsened if interest rates had been increased (Mancera,

12

1995). While this conjecture about the effect of increased Mexican interest rates on
Mexican commercial bank asset quality would likely meet with little disagreement from
any analyst, the central bank’s perception that lowering interest Mexican rates while U.S.
rates were increasing might raise questions.7 Our econometric results suggest that the
increasing share of Mexican dollar-indexed debt to total Mexican debt during this period
would, however, be consistent with greater options for independent monetary policy, at
least temporarily. Moreover, if there were a time when monetary independence might be
particularly attractive, 1994 would be it.
Conclusion
We offer preliminary and tentative evidence to suggest that foreign currency
denominated debt offered a commitment technology not only consistent with Sachs,
Tornell and Velasco’s assessment in the Mexican case during the early and middle 1990s,
but in Brazil in the late 1990s. That is to say, foreign currency denominated debt serves
other functions than allowing a country to borrow money at less expensive interest rates
then domestic currency denominated debt would permit, particularly during periods of
financial stress.
Our results permit the conclusion that central banks that are motivated to pursue
monetary independence despite a pegged exchange rate regime may reasonably guess
that increasing the nation’s share of foreign currency denominated debt might allow such
independence temporarily. The problem, of course, is that it is difficult to know how
temporary temporary is. At the end of the periods we evaluated econometrically, both
Brazil and Mexico faced capital outflows large enough to motivate devaluation.

7

The Federal Open Market Committee of the U.S. Federal Reserve System acted to push up Federal
Funds interest rates by more than 300 basis points during 1994.

13

Moreover, in the case of Mexico, it will be remembered that the devaluation resulted in
considerable economic destabilization.
What we have presented so far in this preliminary study can be seen only as cases
of circumstantial econometrics. We have not shown that countries increase their foreign
currency indexed debt because they wish to pursue independent monetary policies.
However, we have shown evidence to suggest that foreign currency denominated debt
does influence market expectations about prices and that foreign currency denominated
debt can temper the effect of monetary growth on price expectations. Despite some
circumstantial evidence, whether central banks definitely act on the basis of such
knowledge remains to be demonstrated.

14

References

Brown, Steven P.A. and Kelly Whealan (1993), "Oil Price Expectations and U.S.Oil
Conservation," Paper presented at the North American meetings of the
International Association of Energy Economics (October).
Gould, David M. (1994), "Forecasting Mexican Inflation," Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas mimeo, (August).
Ize, Alan and Guillermo Ortiz (1987), "Fiscal Rigidities, Public Debt, and Capital
Flight," IMF Staff Papers, 311-332.
Kamin, Seven B. and Karsten von Kleist (1999), “The Evolution and Determinants of
Emerging Market Credit Spreads in the 1990s,” Bank for International
Settlements Working Paper No. 68 (May).
Mancera, Miguel (1995), “Don’t Blame Monetary Policy,” Wall Street Journal,
A-20 (January 31).
Sachs, Jeffrey, Aarón Tornell, and Andrés Velasco (1995), "The Mexican Peso Crisis:
Sudden Death or Death Foretold?" (Center for International Affairs, Harvard
University and C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics, New York University).

15