View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CURRENCY COMPETITION
AND INFLATION CONVERGENCE

William C. Gruben
Darryl McLeod

Center for Latin American Economics
Working Paper 0204
Center for Latin American Economics
Working Paper 0201
May 2004

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Currency Competition and Inflation Convergence
by
November -6, 2004
William C. Gruben+ and Darryl McLeod*

Center for Latin American Economics
Working Paper 0204

JEL Classifications: F360- Financial Aspects of Economic Integration; E310 - Inflation
F400 - Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance
Key words: Dollarization, inflation, capital controls, Latin America.
Abstract: All agree partial dollarization or currency substitution is a legacy of past inflation and
exchange rate instability. Some argue partial dollarization contributes to exchange rate instability.
However, if Central Banks respond to dollarization by lowering money growth and maximizing
seigniorage revenue, inflation falls and converges on dollar inflation rates. We present a simple model of
currency competition with open capital markets to illustrate these points. Empirical tests for Latin
America and about twenty other countries suggest that dollarization is both a legacy of past inflation and
a constraint on future inflation. Dollarization may complicate monetary policy and prudential regulation,
but one silver lining is that currency competition appears to have accelerated the sharp fall in and
convergence of Latin inflation rates over the past decade.

+

Center for Latin American Economics, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
P.O. Box 655906, 2200 North Pearl Street, Dallas, TX 75201-2272, USA
*
Department of Economics, Fordham University, 441 East Fordham Road, NY 10458-5158, USA
E-Mail: mcleod@fordham.edu, william.c.gruben@dal.frb.org;
**Please check www.fordham.edu/economics/mcleod for updated versions of this paper.

Currency Competition and Inflation Convergence
“Currency substitution renders the domestic currency decidedly non-essential, expanding the scope for
self-validating domestic price spirals. In sum, if weak legal restrictions and an inflationary environment
lead to currency substitution, considerable instability in prices and exchange rates can result.”
Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) page 552 of Section 8.3.8 “Dollarization”
“Dollarization, for example, in many emerging markets, forces inflation-prone governments to
temper their behavior for fear of having residents flee to other currencies.”
Kenneth Rogoff (2003) speaking to central bankers gathered at Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
The usual expression of [Gresham’s] law, "bad money drives out good" is a mistake. Schumpeter
refers to this common definition as "not quite correct." But as the statement stands, it is not just "not
quite correct;" it is quite false. The opposite is true! … "good money drives out bad," is the more correct
empirical proposition. Historically, it has been good, strong currencies that have driven out bad, weak
currencies.
Robert Mundell (1998) “Uses and Abuses of Gresham’s law”

Developing country inflation rates have fallen sharply in the past decade, and they appear
to be converging on the same “low” 5-6% rate. As Figures 1 and 2 indicate, average inflation
fell from 380% annually in 1990 to about 6% in 2003 as the standard deviation of log inflation
declined from about 101% to 7% (σ convergence in the economic growth literature). Since high
inflation hits poor households hardest and wreaks havoc on credit markets, its abatement must be
regarded as a major victory for Latin American policy makers.1 Yet how disinflation occurred
amidst the currency and debt crises of the late 1990s remains a something of a mystery. Many
expected high inflation to return once Brazil and Argentina floated their currencies, for example,
but it did not. The global forces driving inflation lower are not well understood, as Rogoff
(2003) emphasizes. Whatever explains Latin America’s dramatic and lasting escape from high
inflation certainly is a major part of the global disinflation and convergence story.
1

It is largely an unsung victory, however, perhaps because of Argentina’s dramatic default and disappointing overall
economic growth during the 1990s. But lower inflation means greater exchange rate stability, a gradual recovery of
local credit markets, and, with time, these developments will boost economic growth (and no doubt reverse the
dollarization trends). On the effects of high inflation on poverty, see Cardoso (1992) and Romer and Romer (1998).

2

This paper explores a possible piece of the puzzle: the connection between disinflation
and “dollarization.” Recent studies focus on dollar liabilities, internal or external, and on full
dollarization as in Ecuador and El Salvador.2 We focus on the use of the dollar as a substitute for
local currency in everyday transactions, or more to the point, competition among currencies,
typically foreign versus domestic.
As shown in Figure 3 the average share of dollar deposits among twelve Latin countries
that report these data drifted up from an average of 30% to 50% during the 1990s. How does
creeping dollarization affect monetary policy and inflation? The answer obviously depends on
how the monetary authorities react to currency competition. If policy-makers do not take steps
to prevent or roll back currency competition, dollarization acts as a constraint on Central Bank
behavior as the Rogoff (2003) quote above suggests. Section I sets up this shifting political
economy of monetary policy using standard Barro and Gordon (1993) central bank reaction
functions. Section II explores the impact of currency competition more concretely, using a basic
two-money utility function. Greater substitutability among currencies causes inflation rates to
fall and converge, assuming Central Banks optimize under constraints (and, at the limit, even if
they don’t). “Dollarization” is a legacy of past high inflation, but it also makes future high
inflation less feasible. As “dollarization” afflicts high-inflation economies most, their inflation
falls faster, and inflation rates converge.
Section III turns to the empirical evidence on dollarization and disinflation in Latin
America and about 20 other countries for which data are available. With the strong caveat that
unofficial dollar holdings are hard to track, our results suggest high inflation drove up

2

Substitutable currencies imply currency competition. Full dollarization, on the other hand, is an effort to end such
competition by fiat, replacing one official currency with another-- as when Ecuador and El Salvador adopted the
U.S. dollar as their national currency. Of course, some old Ecuadorian notes remain in circulation in rural areas so
even full dollarization may not end currency competition.

3

dollarization ratios in Latin American, which in turn helped bring inflation rates down in the
1990s. Evidence of this disciplining effect of currency competition as noted by Rogoff (1993),
complements a number of recent studies that search, largely in vain, for harmful effects of
dollarization. 3
To the extent that the forces affecting Latin America are global, the same should be true
for other countries. What is driving the dollarization trends shown in Figure 3? In the 1980s
inflation and near hyper-inflation in many Latin countries made dollars the savings vehicle of
choice in the 1908s.
But inflation fell in the 1990s and real interest rates rose, so why did dollarization
continue? Three supply side factors likely fueled dollarization in the 1990s: i) many “emerging
market” economies gained easier access to capital markets at lower interest rates (nominal and
real); ii) easier access to dollar notes and bonds created by changes in U.S. tax laws affecting
foreign bond holders, by electronic banking and by new currency issues (such as “counterfeitproof” hundred dollar bills) tailored to international users. And last but not least, iii)
dollarization increased due to wider official acceptance of dollar accounts and dollar holdings as
part of a trend toward current and capital account openness4 and financial market liberalization.
Some of these trends can be stopped by LDC governments, some can not. It is this
universal, “spontaneous” and often unauthorized dollarization dynamic that makes it a force for
global disinflation. Central Banks may not wish to cope with currency competition, but they find
3

Arteta (2003) finds “little evidence that high dollarization heightens the probability of banking crises or currency
crashes” and “when such crises and crashes do come they are no more costly in highly dollarized countries than
where dollarization is low.” In their provocatively titled survey “Addicted to Dollars,” Reinhart, Rogoff and
Savastano (2003) find that dollarization does not impede monetary control or disinflation, or even reduce
seigniorage revenues (though dollarization does not typically subside when inflation falls). De Nicoló, Honohan and
Ize (2003) find that, in highly inflationary economies, dollarization contributes to financial deepening and deposit
dollarization is associated with reduced solvency risk in banking systems. Somuano, Serrano, and Gomis-Porqueras
(2000) however, claim the probability of future crises and volatility rise with “dollarization” ratios.
4
Capital and current account openness can reduce inflation, with or without dollarization, as emphasized by Romer
(1993) and Gruben and McLeod (2001, 2002, 2004).

4

they must. For this reason, among others, unofficial dollarization is controversial. Many view
Latin America’s “addiction” to dollars as source of exchange rate instability and risk to banks
with dollar-denominated loans or assets.5 All agree however, that unofficial dollarization grew
rapidly in Latin America heading into the 1990s (see Figure 3 and Table 1 below).
How did “currency substitution” change hats: from the great destabilizer of Obstfeld and
Rogoff (1996) to an enforcer of monetary discipline as in Rogoff (1993)? In fact models of
currency substitution generate both outcomes. The dark view of commingling currencies, a la
Kareken and Wallace (1981), sees greater substitutability among two intrinsically worthless
currencies as a source of exchange rate instability and even hyperinflation. Others see
competition among official currencies as stabilizing discipline. Canzoneri and Diba (1992) and
Sturzenegger (1992) for example, present models of currency competition similar to those of this
paper 6 and more in line with the Rogoff (2003) quote above.
Dollarization may initially be a symptom of poor monetary policy. But as “good money
drives out bad” as Mundell (1998) claims Gresham meant to say, Central Bankers have to defend
their less good money. The key question is how policy makers respond to competition.7 If
imported dollars are met with tighter capital controls or efforts to ban competing monies, the
result is financial repression circa 1970s Latin America. However, if governments take steps to
make their currencies more competitive, dollarization can lead to a pandemic of price stability, as
5

Currency competition can occur with or without banks and or legal sanction. In fact currency competition may just
be the “threat” of entry by alternate currencies. We ignore dollar denominated assets or loans at local banks, thereby
overlooking the important and perhaps related issue of currency mismatches leading to banking crises. On these
issues see Baliño, Bennett, and Borensztein (1999) or De Nicoló, Honohan and Ize (2003).
6
Sturzenegger (1992) argues hyperinflation fears result from a misunderstanding. Whereas Obstfeld and Rogoff
(1996) argue substitute monies lead to “self-fulfilling inflationary spirals” Sturzenegger points out that, on the
contrary, a readily available alternative currency allows households to dump the depreciating currency sooner rather
than later. Hyper-inflation is only possible when the households must hold some of home currency no matter how
costly such holdings become.
7
This issue surfaced in some of earliest currency substitution literature. Girton and Roper (1981) for example, first
derive the “instability” similar to Kareken and Wallace (1981) but argue that once monetary policy makers “react”
to incursions of foreign currency, competition among currencies can be a disciplining force.

5

in the models of the next two sections. Perhaps because everyone seemed to have dollars, or
perhaps invigorated by competition, most policy makers chose the latter course in the 1990s.
“Black market premiums” faded into the history books (almost).8

I. Globalization and the Political Economy of Monetary Policy
Low inflation ultimately reflects better fiscal and monetary policy. But why did
monetary discipline improve in so many countries in the 1990s? Latin American inflation
plunged from triple to single digits in just a decade. Perhaps more impressive is that even after
inflation-prone Brazil and Argentina abandoned their currency pegs, high inflation did not return.
Similar patterns are evident throughout the developing world. With a few exceptions (e.g., the
Congo) high inflation seems again to be an artifact for history books. Low and falling inflation
is now the norm.9
Whereas Rogoff (2003) and Romer (1993) emphasize the effects of trade on labor and
product markets, greater currency competition reflects the “globalization” of currency and
banking services. Local currencies must compete with easy-to-get, low-inflation, low-interestrate dollars. Whether Central Bankers are disciplined and independent or not, globalization can
raise the costs and reduce the benefits of printing national currency. Rogoff (2003), Romer
(1993) and Gruben and McLeod (2001) provide Barro-Gordon style stories of how globalization
8

Of course some responded to currency competition with delaying tactics: pegging their currencies, de jure, to the
dollar was the first response of many inflation-prone nations. But when exchange rate anchors failed or became too
costly, most upgraded - setting their currencies free to compete head on with the dollar, liberalizing and deepening
local financial markets, and in some cases, opening their capital and trade accounts. Chile abandoned its capital
controls. Even countries that kept their capital markets largely closed, such as Brazil, managed their currencies more
carefully, floating, and paying very high real interest rates to head off dollarization.
9
Disinflation may also reflect a global upgrade in the quality and autonomy of central bankers. The first tenet of
Williamson’s (1990) “Washington Consensus” was fiscal discipline, and policy fashion has certainly shifted in this
direction. These two processes are complementary, as more integrated global goods and currency markets increased
the rewards for disciplined policy and the penalties for high inflation. Globalization thus punishes inflationary
finance ministers and rewards more those who pursue more fiscal and monetary. Brazilian President “Lula” da
Silva’s “surprisingly” conservative appointments and fiscal policy, for example, seem to fit this description.

6

changes the constraints monetary authorities face. Rogoff (2003) argues central bankers are
tempted to engineer inflation “surprises” (π - πe) > 0 occasionally, in response to random
productivity shocks x, and chronically to overcome some distortion k that drives a wedge
between actual and desired output,
UCB = [µ(π - πe) – k – x]2 + χ(π – π*)2

(1.1)

where the government sets π, the private sector expects πe and χ is the weight the government
places on its inflation target π*. Where Barro and Gordon (1993) blame the distortion k on
income taxes, Rogoff attributes k to firms’ and unions’ monopoly powers. Import competition
erodes these monopoly powers, reducing k. Globalization also lowers the output effect of money
surprises µ by reducing the share of inflexible wages and prices in the economy. Hence, greater
international competition created by globalization reduces trend expected inflation,
πe = π* + µ k/χ and π = π* + µ (k - x)/ χ.

(1.2)

Since the random productivity shock is assumed to have mean zero, πe = π on average, so the
expected inflation equals actual inflation on average. While trade liberalization certainly
lowered µ and k and greater fiscal discipline and/or central bank independence may have raised χ
in many developing countries, it seems unlikely that the chronic triple-digit and occasional
hyperinflations characteristic of Latin America in the 1980s were engineered inflation surprises
designed to achieve some desired level of output or counter productivity shocks.
Gruben and Mcleod (2001) argue inflation is driven by the seigniorage revenues – that
Barro (1983) is more relevant to developing countries than Barro and Gordon (1983). As in
McLeod and Welch (1993) they argue LDC governments are more constrained by balance of
payments considerations, as indicated by the high level of reserves these governments hold, with

7

or without “floating” exchange rates. Hence the desire to raise inflation is tempered by the
potential effect on official foreign exchange reserves R such that,
UCB = [s(πe,α(σe)]2 + χ(R(πe) - R*)2

(1.3)

where R* is some desired level of reserves, α is the interest elasticity of money demand and σe
measures expected capital account restrictions.10 Ignoring, for now the impact of inflation on
foreign currency reserves (dollars do reappear in the next section) this set-up yields a trend
inflation rate of,

π e = πˆ (α (σ e ))

(1.4)

where πˆ is the revenue-maximizing rate of inflation, perhaps tempered by inflation-induced
losses of tax revenue and the expected level of capital account restrictions, σe. Easing capital
controls and/or greater availability of substitute moneys raises σ and the interest elasticity of
demand α(σ) thereby lowering the seigniorage-maximizing inflation rate. The next section
develops a fuller version of this story in a two-currency world.
Figure 4 pulls together the implications of equations 1.3 and 1.4 using the familiar
inflation Laffer curve. Liberalization of the capital account or greater access to substitute
currencies raises the elasticity of demand for domestic money, shifting the seigniorage Laffer
curve down and lowering the optimal inflation tax from A to B. However, if a government is
determined to extract a fixed amount of seigniorage revenue, inflation accelerates from E to F. If
the fiscally stubborn government’s seigniorage revenue target is above smax the result can be
10

This particular set of “dependent economy” priorities is articulated more fully in McLeod and Welch (1993) and
very nicely in Agénor (2001) chapter 8. The microfoundations for such a formulation may be found in the currency
substitution model of Calvo and Rodriguez (1976). In their model a burst of local money growth leads to greater
desired holdings of “dollars.” Since dollars are the only foreign asset in their model, the country must run a current
account surplus, implying a real depreciation of the currency. Though it boosts exports, nominal exchange rate
depreciations raise the costs of higher money growth for the Central bank, as in Romer (1993). A modern fear of
floating version of the Calvo and Rodriguez model might have prudent governments increase desired reserve
holdings to insure against a sudden flight of dollars, yielding a very similar Central Bank loss function to 1.3.

8

hyper-inflation. The idea of currency substitution (aka dollarization) as an object of dread
revolves around this scenario.
If, on the other hand, central bankers lower domestic money growth in response to
changes wrought by globalization currency competition, is it exercising more discipline?
Compared to the fixed deficit government; yes. However, rational central bankers are in a sense
no more disciplined at point A than B. It is the reality of a higher-inflation elasticity of demand
for local currency that changes central bank behavior, lowering the optimal inflation rate from
point A to B in Figure 4.11 In the next section, we add spontaneous dollarization to the
constraints central bankers face more formally.

II. Currency competition and Inflation Convergence
Currency substitution or partial-dollarization has many implications. Our focus is the most
rudimentary form of currency substitution, that is, the use of foreign currency for everyday
transactions. More taxi drivers accept payment in dollars, more landlords demand it, etc. In this
context, dollarization is really a synonym for currency substitution or competition. Though we
do not focus on “asset” substitution or dollar-denominated bank accounts, households can hold
dollar-denominated bonds, or borrow in dollars creating the usual “opportunity cost” for holding
cash foreign or domestic. The key idea is that now two rather than a single currency can provide
similar transaction or convenience services. Our model is a small country version of Canzoneri

11

Point C represents the less-than-credible policy shift case. Expected inflation moves to some intermediate level C
and the liberalization is less effective at reducing inflation. One can tell a story along the lines of Rodrik (1991)
where the private sector places a positive probability on a policy reversal (or new exchange controls) in period 2.

9

and Diba (1992).12 Households derive utility from consumption ct and transaction services
v(mt,nt) provided by domestic and/or foreign real money balances mt and nt,
∞

U = ∑ β t [ct + v(mt , nt )]

(2.1)

t =0

where β = 1/(1+δ) and δ is the discount rate, assumed identical at home and abroad. Utility is
linear in c and separable in consumption and transactions services, fixing the real interest rates
rt* = rt = δ. We assume income effects on money demand. The degree of substitutability
between the two currencies in providing transactions services v(•) is determined by σ. The
higher σ the more substitutable the two currencies become. As σ → ∞ the two currencies
become perfect substitutes. The properties of v(•) are spelled out further for a particular
functional form below. Household maximizes (2.1) subject to the budget constraint,
ct + nt + mt + bt − dt* / et ≤
yt − τ t + mt (1 + π t ) −1 + nt (1 + π t* ) −1 + (1 + rt −1 )bt −1 − (1 + rt*−1 )ϕt d t*−1 / et

(2.2)

where (1+πt ) = pt/pt-1 and (1 + π t* ) = pt* / pt*−1 . The identical consumption good costs p at home

and p* abroad yielding the flexible home currency price of foreign exchange e = p/p*. Note that
up to a point, households can borrow abroad but transactions fees and capital controls increase
the cost, as ϕt < 1.13 A high ϕt may also reflect risks of future taxes or restrictions on dollar
borrowing. Since dollars nt can either be held as cash or used to pay down foreign debt, the real
opportunity cost of holding foreign currency is (1 + r*)ϕ. Capital controls and restrictions on
currency use affect the degree of substitutability between home and foreign currency (σ) as well.
Completing the fiscal side of the story is the government budget constraint,
12

Sturzenegger(1992) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) employ a very similar transactions cost driven money
demand function.
13

The ability of households to borrow abroad adds current account adjustment issues that we ignore here.

10

gt + (1 + rt-1) bt-1 = τt + st - κ(π) + bt

(2.3)

The government needs to finance fixed spending gt and retire bonds (1 + rt-1) bt-1 using new local
bond issues bt or lump-sum tax revenues τt or real seigniorage revenues st net of Olivera-Tanzi
tax revenue losses κ(πt). Assuming that seigniorage generated by domestic pesos circulating
abroad is negligible, total gross real seigniorage revenue is,
st = mt – mt-1 + πt mt-1 .

(2.4)

Ignoring income related money demand, this reduces to πt mt-1. The government sets the inflation
rate to maximize the present value of seigniorage net of inflation-induced tax revenue losses
κ(π),
∞

max π s′ = ∑ β t
0

{[ β (δ + π )] m − κ (π )}
t +1

t

t

(2.5)

The linearity of the consumption function creates an intimate relationship between nominal
interest rates and inflation (the real interest rate is fixed at δ), so the term in square brackets can
also be written in terms of the nominal interest rate,

[ β (δ + π t +1 )] =

it

= iˆt
(2.6)
(1 + it )
To solve the government’s maximization problem for an explicit optimal inflation rate, we use
the functional form for transactions services suggested by Canzoneri and Diba (1992),

v(m, n) = −.5(2V − m − n) 2 − (.5 / σ ) ⎡⎣(V − m) 2 + (V − n) 2 ⎤⎦ ,

(2.7)

where households are satiated once they hold V ≥ .5 of each type of money. Transactions
demand is limited by the opportunity cost of money. As the elasticity of substitution σ > 0

11

increases, the two moneys become increasingly substitutable and the second term in (2.7) goes to
zero.14 The first-order conditions implied by (2.7) are,
vm = 2V − mt − nt + (1/ σ )(V − mt ) = iˆt
vn = 2V − mt − nt + (1/ σ )(V − nt ) = iˆt*ϕt

(2.8)

Solving for money demand mt implied by (2.8) yields,
mt = V − η ⎡⎣σ (iˆt − iˆt*ϕt ) + iˆt ⎤⎦
nt = V − η ⎡⎣σ (iˆt*ϕt − iˆt ) + iˆt* ⎤⎦

(2.9)

where η = 1/(2+1/σ). As σ becomes large, η→1/2 and ση becomes large, pushing demand for
the high inflation currency to zero. As in Mundell’s version of Gresham’s law, good, lowinflation money drives out bad high-inflation money. Equation (2.9) makes it clear why
empirical studies of dollarization may be inconclusive: dollarization has many potential causes.
High domestic inflation raises i relative to i* leading to substitution of foreign for domestic
currency. A fall in i* due to low inflation abroad, or easier access to international credit markets
also increases dollarization. Or financial innovation or relaxed currency restrictions can raise σ.
Using (2.6) we can rewrite in (2.9) in terms of foreign and domestic inflation,
m = V − ηβ ⎡⎣σ (π − π *ϕ ) + π + δ ⎤⎦
n = V − ηβ ⎡⎣σ (π *ϕ − π ) + π * + δ ⎤⎦

(2.10)

where we drop the time subscripts to focus on the key inflation differentials. Again as the
substitutability among currencies increases, σ becomes large and η→1/2 - increasing the
importance of the inflation differential. The optimal inflation rate can be solved for by

14

This particular functional form has some advantages of the CES specification used by Imrohoroglu (1994) or the
more intuitive specifications used by Sturzenegger (1996) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996).

12

maximizing net seigniorage revenues s’ = πm - τ(π). Setting

∂ {s − τ (π )}
= 0 and solving for
∂π

πˆ yields,

πˆ =

1 ⎧⎛
1
⎨⎜
2 ⎩ ⎝ (1 + σ )ηβ

⎞
⎛ δ
⎟ [V − τ ′(π )] + θπ *ϕ − ⎜
⎝ 1+ σ
⎠

⎞⎫
⎟⎬
⎠⎭

(2.11)
⎛ σ
where θ = ⎜
⎝ 1+ σ

1
⎞
.
⎟ and as before η =
2 + 1/ σ
⎠

Note that as currency substitution increases (i.e. σ →∞), θ → 1 and η → 1/ 2 and all of the terms
in (2.11) except the θπ* term go to zero. In sum, the optimal inflation rate converges to the
foreign inflation rate π* as currency substitutability becomes greater.
If governments ignore currency competition dollarization ratios rise and eventually force
their hand (unless they succeed in lowering σ by imposing restrictions on uses of and access to
dollars). Using (2.10) and setting ϕ = 1 to simplify notation, the dollarization ratio z = n/(n+m)
is,
z=

V − ηβ ⎡⎣σ (π * − π ) + π * + δ ⎤⎦
n
=
.
n+m
2V − ηβ (π + π * + 2δ )

(2.12)

Suppose central banks ignore falling dollar inflation π* and a rising σ, and increase domestic
inflation. The speed with which dollarization (z) rises is determined by,
*
*
∂Ζ 2ηβσ ⎡⎣V − ηβ (π + δ ) ⎤⎦ + ηβ ⎡⎣V − ηβ (π + δ ) ⎤⎦
=
,
2
∂π
⎡⎣ 2V − ηβ (π + π * + 2δ ) ⎤⎦

(2.13)

which is clearly positive as long as money holdings are positive. As dollars become better
substitutes for pesos, z rises faster for a given increase in domestic inflation. Note that as σ rises,

13

the denominator of (2.13) remains fixed and positive (σ →∞, η → 1/ 2 ) while the numerator
continues to increase and becomes dominated by: βσ ⎡⎣V − (1/ 2) β (π * + δ ) ⎤⎦ .

To the extent that dollarization is beyond their control, greater currency substitutability
presents central bank policy makers with two options: reduce domestic inflation or suffer
steadily rising dollarization ratios. These results are familiar and intuitive, but they can also
explain recent trends toward inflation convergence. As access to dollars became easier, for
example, via internet banking, newly minted $100 bills or via new access to international
financial markets, small inflation differentials continue to drive dollarization ratios (z) up. But
this same process drives inflation rates down as central banks seek to slow dollarization and to
find their new lower optimal inflation rate πˆ defined in (2.11) above. As σ increases domestic
rates tend to converge on π* providing our potential, as yet untested, explanation of global
disinflation, as Rogoff (2003) suggested. Following the notation of Canzoneri and Diba (1992)
and assuming central banks choose an optimal inflation rate, we have, for better or worse, σconvergence driven by σ.
As Canzoneri and Diba (1992) and Chang and Velasco (2000) point out, the international
“dollar” inflation rate is not necessarily the optimal rate for all countries, particularly if
alternative sources of tax revenue are limited and costly. If dollarization drives seigniorage
revenues down to very low levels, national welfare may decline despite welfare gains from lower
inflation. However, as Friedman and Verbetsky (2001) argue for Russia, until inflation falls
below (say) 5%, the welfare gains from reduced inflation are likely swamp losses due to lower
seigniorage. 15

15

Put differently, at low inflation rates, and to the extent governments can costly alter σ, there may be an optimal σ
for each country. The welfare consequences of dollarization-induced disinflation are beyond the scope of this paper.

14

III. Deposit dollarization and inflation: some empirical evidence

Any empirical evaluation of the causes or consequences of unofficial dollarization must
begin with a stronger than usual caveat regarding data availability. Use of dollars for everyday
transactions is particularly difficult to track, in part because dollar payments and dollar deposit
accounts are illegal in many countries. However, a number of researchers have put together data
on deposit dollarization as reported to the IMF or by the Central Banks of those countries. Table
1 combines “spontaneous” dollarization data from Berg, Borensztein and Mauro (2003) with
changes in inflation from the early 1990s to the late 1990s. Plotting disinflation rates against
dollarization ratios as in Figure 5 reveals a correlation between disinflation and dollarization: the
higher the rate of dollarization, the faster the rate of disinflation. Of course, causality can run in
either or both directions. High inflation leads to higher levels of dollarization (see especially
Peru, Nicaragua and Argentina) but dollarization may also play a role in bringing down inflation,
as the model of the previous section suggests.
To explore these relationships for a larger number of countries we use data on dollar
deposit ot total deposit rates reported in Table 1 in De Nicoló, Honohan and Ize (2003).
Unfortunately, the data cover only the period 1990 to 2001 and are only those deposits reported
by the authorities: the actual use of dollars in everyday transactions could be a larger or smaller
share of total money in circulation. Nevertheless, we can use deposit dollarization as a crude

But we suspect seigniorage-related welfare losses are largely irrelevant to Latin America and most LDCs until
inflation falls below 5%. As inflation falls from double or triple to single digits, the welfare gains from lower
inflation likely swamp losses due to forgone seigniorage. This is what Friedman and Verbetsky (2001) find for
Russia until inflation falls below 2-3% (they ignore the costs of alternative taxes, but the inflation tax is not costless
either, and it is regressive). Also as countries “remonetize” at low inflation rates, increased money holdings help
offset seigniorage losses due to lower inflation. Finally lost seigniorage can be replaced with a low check cashing
fee as Brazil did in the 1990s.

15

proxy for transactions demand for dollars, as a ratio of total currency in circulation (see
Appendix A and Table A.1 for the data set used in this paper).

Dollarization: a legacy of past inflation

Table 2 reports regressions of dollar deposit ratios on past inflation. As indicated in
Table 1, there are a few countries that report exceptionally high dollarization ratios and not
coincidentally also experienced very high inflation in the 1980s or early 1990s. To avoid letting
these four high inflation countries drive all of our results, we routinely remove them from our
sample (Bolivia, Peru, Nicaragua and Argentina fall into this category). A general pattern that
emerges from Table 2 is that past inflation is an important determinant of dollarization.
Somuano, Serrano, and Gomis-Porqueras (2000) obtain similar results, but rule out reverse
causality, from dollarization to lower inflation since inflation falls, but dollarization ratios do not.
For Latin America, high inflation in the 1980s explains almost all the variance in dollarization.
Adding information on 1990s inflation contributes little predictive power to these equations.
However, outside Latin America, inflation in the 1990s is an important determinant of
dollarization.
Some Table 2 equations also include an “inflation rate squared” term to capture the
potential diminishing effect of inflation on dollarization. This term also allows us to compute a
crude “maximum dollarization” ratio - which varies between 50% and 70% for the country
samples we use. In light of widespread concerns that the dollar may spontaneously drive out any
use at all of domestic currency in some countries, the implications of these estimates are
important. They suggest that even with very high inflation, dollarization ratios might peak at 50-

16

60%: just about the baseline share of foreign currency assumed in the model of the previous
section.
Table 3 expands our list of explanatory variables to include a number of policies that may
also affect dollarization ratios. Country size as measured by total GDP in $PPP 1990 reduces
dollarization rates. Policy reversals (retreats from open to closed capital markets) increase
dollarization, as one would expect if dollar holdings reflect confidence in the monetary
authorities and expected inflation rates (assuming that closed capital accounts give the monetary
authorities more leeway to raise the inflation tax). Recall that in the model of the previous
sections relaxing capital controls can have two effects on the dollarization ratio. If the result is to
increase the substitutability between dollars and local currency (i.e., raise σ) dollarization
increases. However, if the result is to raise the return on dollar assets or the cost of dollar debt,
the opportunity cost of holding currency shifts against dollars and towards the local currency (an
increase in ϕ). Both effects may be at work in Table 3. In the 1980s relaxing capital and current
account restrictions raised 1990s dollarization rates, while the same capital account opening
reduced dollarization in the 1990s. Why the opposite effects? One explanation is that during the
debt crisis, high inflation 1980s investors were looking for a safe haven, even if it paid little
interest. The liberalizations in the 1990s, on the other hand, increased confidence and raised the
return to dollar denominated assets, thereby reducing dollarization ratios (as the model in above
would predict for a rise in ϕ).
However, there is another interpretation of these opposite and roughly equal effects16 of
capital controls in the two decades: liberalizing capital controls in the 1990s reduced
dollarization either by raising the return on dollar assets or by increasing confidence in the
16

Wald tests of the hypothesis that the sum of these coefficients is zero cannot be rejected for any of these
equations—the two effects appear to cancel each other out, unless we subtract 1980 from 1990 openness levels—in
other words focus on capital account liberalization rather than levels of openness.

17

discipline of the monetary authorities. Equations 3.1a, 3.2a and 3.6a all re-estimate the previous
equation using the change in, as opposed to an index of the levels of, capital and current account
restrictions. In every equation, the goodness of fit improves when we switch from levels to
changes (that is, from the degree of openness to changes in openness). This suggests capital
account liberalization may be, in effect, a substitute for dollarization. Both rising dollarization
and/or a more open capital account increase the penalties for high inflation and reduce the
potential seigniorage revenue generated, inducing policy makers to issue less domestic money.

Dollarization, Capital Account Liberalization and Inflation

Table 4 examines the effect of “past dollarization” on future inflation. Unfortunately,
since we only have data back to the early 1990s “past dollarization” means early 1990s
dollarization ratios. Fortunately, since we know that past inflation explains significant variation
in dollarization ratios we can use the equations of Table 3 to construct instruments for deposit
dollarization ratios.
Equation 4.1 regresses log average inflation in the 1990s on early dollarization ratios,
together with some other policy and geographic determinants of inflation. Capital account
openness shows the same pattern of opposite signs for the 1990s and 1980s. Latitude is our
proxy for developing countries, as this regression includes all the countries available in the De
Nicoló, Honohan and Ize (2003) data set. To look at the potential interaction between
dollarization and capital account opening, equation 4.1a adds an interaction term to equation 4.1,
multiplying the dollarization ratio times the capital account openness index. Note that the
explained variation in inflation across countries jumps substantially each time we add this
interaction term to the equation (the adjusted R2 jumps from .63 to .77 in equation 4.1 and from

18

.80 to .92 in equation 4.2). In Latin America, equation 4.2a explains a remarkable 90% of the
variation in inflation rates, albeit for a very small sample of 15 countries (note that due to the
small size of our Latin America sample, and that all four high inflation-high dollarization
countries were Latin American, these results reflect the experience of those four countries).
The interaction between capital account openness and dollarization is consistent with the
hypothesis that capital account openness is a substitute for dollarization—as discussed above.
Either dollarizing or capital account openness constrains the behavior of the monetary authorities
and brings down inflation. An alternative interpretation is that dollarization has a greater impact
in economies with open capital accounts, as dollars may flow in or out in response to higher
inflation rates or expected devaluations. Removing the high inflation four from our sample
clearly reduces the explanatory power of this regression (also capital account openness in the
1980s instead of the 1990s interacts positively with dollarization to bring down inflation quicker
for this sample, perhaps because of technological advances in moving assets). Note also that
equations 4.1 vs. 4.2 show that policy reversals are largely a Latin American problem, as this
variable does not have a significant effect in our full sample of countries (equation 4.1 vs. 4.2).
Finally, we estimate equations 4.1 and 4.3 using 2SLS-GMM methods. The results carry
through for the most part, increasing our confidence that causality is running from dollarization
(the endogenous rhs variable in equations 4.4 and 4.5) to inflation as the regression of Table 4
suggest. Note that Sargan tests of our instruments, which include 1980s inflation and various
country size variables, suggests that they are indeed suitable for their role in this context.

19

IV. Conclusions and Policy Implications

The main idea of this paper is easily summarized. Dollarization is both a legacy of past
inflation and a constraint on future inflation. Switching from pesos to dollars provides a refuge
from the inflation tax. If the monetary authorities ignore dollarization and pursue the same
seigniorage revenue, high or even hyper-inflation can be the result, followed by even more
dollarization. In this fashion growing “spontaneous” dollarization inevitably drives down future
inflation, though governments can delay this process by implementing new capital controls.
Fortunately, with few exceptions Latin and developing country governments did not ban
currency competition, and inflation fell as dollarization ratios increased. This is consistent with
both the model and the empirical results of this paper.
The risks of “spontaneous” dollarization or widespread currency substitution have been
given much attention in the literature of late. However, most recent empirical studies of
dollarization fail to find many negative impacts. We add a small silver lining. It appears from
the very preliminary empirical evidence present here, that dollarization and capital account
openness act in concert to drive inflation down. Since dollarization ratios rose sharply in many
Latin American countries during the high inflation debt crisis years, Latin disinflation and
convergence have been especially sharp and dramatic. That said, there is much room to improve
both the model and the empirical results of this paper. Longer data series for dollarization ratios
would be most helpful and apart from one footnote, the welfare consequences of lower
seigniorage revenues have not been addressed (Chang and Velasco (2000) for example, cite lost
seigniorage revenues as a major drawback of “full” dollarization). Still, the results of this paper
suggest Rogoff (2003) may be correct: easier access to dollars is one factor driving global
inflation rates down in the 1990s, particularly in Latin America.

20

References
Agénor, Pierre-Richard (2000) The Economics of Adjustment and Growth , Academic Press, New York.
Baliño, Tomás, Adam Bennett, and Eduardo Borensztein (1999). “Monetary Policy in Dollarized
Economies,” IMF Occasional Paper 171 March.
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon (1983) “A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate
Model,” Journal of Political Economy, 91, 1983, 589-610.
Barro, Robert J. (1983) “Inflationary Finance Under Discretion and Rules” Canadian Journal of
Economics, 16, February, 1-16.
Berg, Andrew and Eduardo Borensztein (1999). “The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime and Monetary
Target in Highly Dollarized Economies.” IMF Working Paper 00/29 (February)
Berg, Andrew, Eduardo Borensztein and Paulo Mauro (2003), “Monetary Regime Options for Latin
America,” Finance and Development, (September) 24-26.
Bowman, David (2003), “Market Power and Inflation,” Federal Reserve Board of Governors International
Finance Discussion Paper No. 783 (October).
Calvo, Guillermo A. and Carlos, A. Rodríguez (1977), “A Model of Exchange Rate Determination Under
Currency Substitution and Rational Expectations,” Journal of Political Economy 85, 617-624.
Campillo, Marta and Jeffery Miron (1996) “Why Does Inflation Differ across Countries?” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #5540, NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Canzoneri, Matthew and Behzad T. Diba (1992), “The inflation discipline of currency substitution,”
European Economic Review 36, 827-845.
Cardoso, Eliana. (1992) “Inflation and Poverty,” NBER Working Paper # 4006.
Chang, Roberto and Andres Velasco (2000) Dollarization: Analytical Issues, NBER and Harvard
University.
De Nicoló, Gianni, Patrick Honohan and Alain Ize (2003), “Dollarization of the Banking System: Good
or Bad?”, IMF Working Paper WP/03/146.
Friedman, Alla and Alexey Verbetsky (2001), “Currency Substitution in Russia,” Economics Education
and Research Consortium Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 01/05.
Girton, Lance and Don Roper (1981), “Theory and Implications of Currency Substitution,” Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 13, 12-30.

21

Gruben, William and Darryl McLeod (2001) “Capital Account Liberalization and Disinflation in the
1990s,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Center for Latin America Working Paper 0101.
Gruben, William C. and Darryl McLeod (2002), “Capital Account Liberalization and Inflation,”
Economics Letters, October, 77(2), 221-225.
Gruben, William C. and Darryl McLeod (2004) “Openness and Inflation Revisited” Applied Economics
Letters, 11(8), July.
Hanson, James A. (1995), “Opening the capital account: costs, benefits and sequencing,” in Edwards
(ed.) Capital controls, exchange rates, and monetary policy in the world economy, 383-429,
(Cambridge; New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press)
International Monetary Fund, Various Issues, Annual report on exchange arrangements and exchange
restrictions, (International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.).
McKinnon, Ronald I. and Donald J. Mathieson (1981) How to Manage a Repressed Economy, Essays in
International Finance #145, December, Economics, Princeton University, NJ.
McLeod, Darryl and J. Welch (1993) “Costs and Benefits of Fixed Exchange Rates in Latin America,
Economic Review, 1st Quarter, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 31-43.
Mundell, Robert (1998) “Uses and Abuses of Gresham's Law in the History of Money”
Columbia University, to appear in Zagreb Journal of Economics.
Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff (1996), “Foundations of International Economics,” (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press)
Reinhart, Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano (2003), “Addicted to Dollars,” NBER
Working Paper 10015 (October).
Rodrik, Dani (1991), “Policy uncertainty and private investment in developing countries,” Journal of
Development Economics, 36, 229-242.
Rogoff, Kenneth (2003), “Globalization and Global Disinflation,” Paper prepared for the Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City conference on “Monetary Policy and Uncertainty,” Jackson Hole, WY.,
August 28-30, 2003. September 10, 2003 revision.
Romer, David, (1993), “Openness and Inflation: Theory and Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
CVII (4), November , 869-904.
Romer, David and Christina Romer (1998) “Monetary Policy and the Well-Being of the Poor,” NBER
Working Paper #6793, November, Cambridge, MA.
Somuano, Alejandro Carlos Serrano, and Pere Gomis-Porqueras (2000) “Currency Substitution in Latin
America: Lessons from the 1990s” World Bank Working Paper # 2340, May 2000 Wash D.C.
Sturzenegger, Federico A. (1994), “Hyperinflation with Currency Substitution: Introducing an Indexed
Currency,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 26 (3), August, 377-395.

22

Figure 1: Latin American Inflation Declines, sharply
25

1400

Latin American
average annual
inflation Rate
1980- 2004

1000

15
10

800
5

600
0

400

19
96
19
97
19
98
19
99
20
00
20
01
20
02
20
03
20
04

Annual % CPI Inflation

1200

LatAm inflation
Rate 1996-2004

20

200

Unweighted average

04

02

20

20

20

00

98
19

96
19

94
19

19

92

90
19

88
19

86
19

84
19

19

19

80

82

0

Weighted Average

Source: IMF, WEO April 2004 weighted average based on PPP GDP weights, also from the WEO.

Figure 2 Latin America Inflation σ Convergence
180%

CPI Inflation = log(1+π)

Weighted Average Inflation

160%
140%

Variance of log(1+π )

120%
100%
80%

Std deviation of log(1+π )

60%
Weighted
Std dev

40%
20%

Source: IMF, WEO April 2004

23

04
20

02
20

00
20

98
19

96
19

94
19

92
19

90
19

88
19

86
19

84
19

82
19

19

80

0%

Figure 3 Deposit Dollarization in Latin America
Foreign Currency Deposit Share

80

60

40

12 LatAm Cty Average
20

0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
LatAm avg

Argentina

Chile

Costa Rica

Ecuador

Peru

Nicaragua

Figure 4

Seigniorage
Revenue
(% of GDP)

A
C

smax
B

s*

E
F

σL

σH

Inflation Rate

24

π

Figure 5: LatAm Disinflation and Dollarization 1990-2000
Dollar Deposit Ratio (see Table 1)
0

20

40

60

80

100

Log Change in Inflation (Table 1)

0.0
MEX

-1.0

ARG

CRI
PER

CHL

-2.0
SLV

ECU

-3.0

URG

-4.0
-5.0
-6.0

NIC

-7.0
PERU

-8.0

25

ARG

Table 1
/1
Spontaneous dollarization and Inflation
South America
Argentina
Bolivia
Chile
Ecuador
Paraguay
Peru
Uruguay
Average
Mexico and Central America

Costa Rica
El Salvador
Honduras
Mexico
Nicaragua
Average

Dollarization2/
19903/ 20004/

CPI Inflation (%)
19903/
20004/

48
82
5.8
20
40
62
78
48

69
93
13
54
64
64
83
63

1855
18
22
3.9
30
3281
98
758

-1.1
2.8
3.6
0.3
7.7
2.4
5.0
3.0

31
4.2
7.7
5.6
41
18

46
8.9
30
11
69
33

21
19
22
23
5197
1057

11
1.6
11
11
11
9.0

Sources: Nicoló, Honohan and Ize (2003) and IMF WEO September 2004 database
1/ Berg, Borensztein and Mauro (2003) provide a similar table with only 2000 data on foreign currency deposits.
We omit the same countries they do. As they point out, "dollar deposits are not allowed in Brazil and Guatemala"
and "Colombia and Venezuela have negligible foreign currency deposits. Panama has been dollarized for many
years. The data for Ecuador and El Salvador precede their full dollarization."

2/ Foreign currency deposits as percent share of total deposits,
3/Averages for 1989-1991 or closest years for which data are available.
4/Averages for 1999-2001 or closest years for which data are available

26

Table 3: Past Inflation and policy Determinants of Dollarization
Dependent Variable: Dollarization Ratio late 1990s
Sample:

Constant

Country Size
($PPP GDP 1990)

Avg Inflation in the 1980s

Policy Reversals in 1990s2/

Financial integration 1990s3/

Financial Integration 1980s

3.1
3.1A
3.2
3.2A
All ctys All ctys LDCs
LDCs
exc. HI4 exc. HI4 exc. HI4 exc. HI4

3.4
All
Ctys

35

32

21

27

14

12

12

(3.8)

(4.7)

(3.8)

(2.5)

(4.2)

(1.4)

(1.8)

(1.9)

-4.8

-4.7

-4.5

-4.4

-2.9

(-3.3)

(-3.7)

(-2.4)

(-2.3)

(-2.4)

40

36

34.2

17

22

32

24

25

(2.3)

(2.4)

(2.2)

(1.8)

(6.7

(7.9)

(8.9)

(9.4)

4.7

4.9

11.1

10

9.1

14

15

16

(1.4)

(1.4)

(2.5)

(2.4)

(2.3)

(2.3)

(2.3)

(2.3)

-7.6

-6.4

-13

(-2.4)

(-1.9)

(-2.6)

8.1

8.3

17

(3.8)

(2.0)

(4.1)

-7.8

-8.4

-12

-15

(-2.4)

(-2.4)

(-2.3)

(-6.9)

Private Capital Flows

-.34

-1.94

(-2.3)

(-2.5)

Floated Exchange Rate 1990s

2

Adjusted R
SE regression
Mean dependent variable

3.6
3.6A
Latin
Latin
America America

34.6

Capital Account Liberalilization

Government Deficits (1980s)
( % of GDP average 1980s)
Number of Observations

3.5
All
LDCs

20

14

17

(2.5)

(1.5)

(2.2)

1.7
(2.4)

44

44

34

34

46

27

16

16

0.36
14.8
19.3

0.38
14.6
19.3

0.3
16
23.5

0.34
15.4
23.5

0.61
14.2
21

0.76
13.3
29

0.7
15.9
38

0.72
15.3
38

1/ The high inflation four (HI4) include and Peru, Bolivia, Argentina, Nicaragua
2/ This variable counts the number of times in the 1990s and 1980s the country "reversed course" by moving to close its capital
or current account. Argentina, Uruguay, Peru, Costa Rica, Honduras, Trinidad and Tobago had single reversals. Ecuador had
two reversals in the 1990s.
3/ This "financial integration" index adds current and capital account restrictions to "seize export proceeds" all 0/1 indicatore
reported in various issues of the IMF's "Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions." These
measures are created as ten-year averages of the three component index. A country that reported no restrictions any of these
three areas for 10 years earns a "3" for this index. If it had capital and current account controls for five of ten years, for
example, its average openness index would be "2". In Table 4 capital account openness measure was used also used alone,
separately from the "current account" and "seize export proceeds" index.

27

Table 4: Dollarization and Inflation
Dependent Variable: Disnflation 1980s to 1990s5/
Sample:

Constant

DDR: Dollar Deposit Ratio
(early 1990s)

4.2
Latin
America

4.2a
Latin
America

.2

.02

.03

.06

.14

.14

.18

.10

(.2)

(1.5)

(0.4)

(2.1)

(2.0)

(4.0)

(2.0)

-.02

-.01

-.03

-.024

-.03

(-4.0)

(-1.2)

(-5.4)

(-3.4)

(-6.9)

-.03

-.03

(-3.4)

(-3.4)

DDR* OCA 1980s
(OCA: open capital account)

Policy reversals in the 1990s
Latitude (distance from equator)

4.4
All
Ctys

4.54/
All ctys
exc. HI4

(2.1)

(OCA: open capital account)

Open Capital Account 1980s

4.3a1/
All ctys
exc. HI4

4.1A
All
Ctys

DDR* OCA 1990s

Open Capital Acount 1990s2/

4.31/
All ctys
exc. HI4

4.1
All
Ctys

-.004

-.004

-.003

(-2.5)

(-2.5)

(-2.4)

-.97

-.41

-1.04

-.36

-.14

-1.0

(-3.0)

(-2.2)

(-2.9)

(-1.7)

(-2.5)

(-4.0)

1.2

1.2

1.8

1.8

.16

1.4

(3.6)

(5.2)

(3.5)

(4.8)

(2.5)

(4.2)

.12

.56

.42

(.7)

(3.0)

(3.0)

.57

.40

.12

.17

.45

.14

(2.7)

(2.4)

(1.8)

(2.2)

(1.8)

(2.2)

Capital Account Liberalilization
(1990s vs 1980s change in)

Country Size ($PPP GDP 1990)

-.14

-.11

(-2.6)

(-2.4)

-02

-02

-07

-024

(-1.5)

(-1.4)

(-1.6)

(-2.2)

34

30

Number of Observations
Estimation Method

37

37

15

15

31

31

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

Adj. R2
SE regression

0.63
0.36

0.77
0.28

0.80
0.38

.92
0.26

.39
0.106

.41
0.105

.51
0.42

.36
0.11

Sargan Test (prob value) 3/
Mean of the dependent variable

-20%

-20%

-46%

-46%

-2.1%

-2.1%

0.78
-22%

.50
-2%

GMM-2SLS GMM-2SLS

1/ The high inflation four (HI4) include and Peru, Bolivia, Argentina, Nicaragua which are excluded for some estimates. These countries
experience triple digit average inflation rates in the 1980s.
2/ See Table 3 footnote 3 for a definition of these capital account openness indices. For all equations except 4.3 the only the capital
account liberaliztion index was used. Equation 4.3 the broader financial integration index including capital account and current account
restrictions plus "seize export proceeds". Capital account liberalization alwasy refers the the change in this three component index,
averaged for the 1980s and 1990s.
3/ This is the p-value of rejecting the GMM overidentifying restriction that the instrument set is orthogonal to the dependent variable,
analogous to the Sargan test for suitible instruments. Instruments include average inflation in the 1980s, fuel export dummy, log country
size in square miles, and the capital account liberalization and geograpy variables included about-- only the DD ratio was considered
endogenous.
4/ This regression also included a "floating exchange rates in the 1990s" index, with coefficent of 1.6 (1.8). The index measures the
number of years a given country had a floating exchange rate, as reported in the IMF's survey on Exchange Rate Arrangements.
5/ Disinflation is natural log(1+π90σ) - log(1+π80s) but the change in log(π) yeilds similar results. The 1980s are 1981-1990 while the
1990s are 1991-2000. Data on CPI inflation came from the WDI 2002.

28