View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ARGENTINA’S RECOVERY AND “EXCESS”
CAPITAL SHALLOWING OF THE 1990S
Finn E. Kydland
Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga
Research Department
Working Paper 0204
Center for Latin American Economics
Working
Paper 0102
Center for
Latin American
Economics
Working Paper 0201
February 2002

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

ARGENTINA’S RECOVERY AND
“E XCESS” CAPITAL SHALLOWING
OF THE 1990S
Finn E. Kydland
Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga
Research Department
Working Paper 0204

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

ARGENTINA’S RECOVERY AND “EXCESS” CAPITAL SHALLOWING
OF THE 1990s *

Finn E. Kydland
Carnegie-Mellon University and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Schenley Park, Pittsburgh, PA 15213
E-mail: kydland@andrew.cmu.edu
Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
2200 N. Pearl St. Dallas, TX 75201
Telephone: 214.922.5165
Fax:
214.922.5194
E-mail: Carlos.Zarazaga@dal.frb.org
Corresponding Author: Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga
Key Words: Argentina, expansion, growth model.

* The views herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the positions of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. The authors are
grateful to Víctor Elías, J. Rodrigo Fuentes, Rodolfo Manuelli, and the participants at the
Seventh Economic Development, Technology and Human Resources Conference held in
Tafí del Valle, Argentina in 2001, under the auspices of the Economics Departments of
Universidad Nacional de Tucumán and of Universidad de Chile, as well as the Applied
Economics Institute of Fundación Banco Empresario de Tucumán.

Abstract

The paper examines Argentina’s economic expansion in the 1990s through the
lens of a parsimonious neoclassical growth model. The main finding is that investment
remained considerably weaker than what the model would have predicted. The resulting
excessive “capital shallowing” could be identified as a weakness of the rapid economic
growth of the 1990s that may have played a role in Argentina’s ultimate inability to
escape the crisis that started to unfold towards the end of that decade.
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Codes: E32.
Key Words: Argentina, depression, growth model.

1

1. INTRODUCTION
In the heyday of its economic boom of the 1990s, Argentina was used to be
proudly presented to the world as a living proof of the huge rewards that awaited all those
emerging economies brave enough to implement free-market-oriented reforms as
sweeping as the ones that country so diligently had carried out during that decade.
Indeed, between 1990 and 1998 Argentina’s real GDP per capita grew at an
average rate of 5% a year. This rapid growth, along with the far-reaching privatization
and trade and financial liberalization program implemented in that same period, lit the
hope that Argentina was leaving behind the economic stagnation of the previous “lost
decade.” In this optmistic view, Argentina, like its neighbor Chile and the so-called Asian
tigers before it, was heading full speed to convergence to the standards of living of
developed countries.
By the beginning of 2002 Argentina had not only lost its “success story” status
but also become the world’s leading counterexample of what emerging economies ought
not to do to move up in the development ladder. Borrowing the expression from Pastor
and Wise (2001), How come Argentina went “from poster child to basket case” almost
overnight? Such a sudden change of heart is not easy to justify by rigorous scientific
standards and certainly raises the suspicion that the optimistic views about the prospects
of Argentina’s economic growth often heard during the 1990s may have been formed on
shaky grounds. At the very least, Argentina’s abrupt downgrading from success to failure
suggests the need to reexamine its economic growth experience during those years with a
more systematic approach. The purpose of this paper is to do precisely that through the
lens of a parsimonious neoclassical growth model.

2

The main result of the paper is that an observer equipped with that model would
have detected early on in the 1990s reasons to be skeptical about the prevailing
enthusiasm about Argentina’s long run growth prospects. The worrisome sign for such an
observer, our paper argues, would have been that capital accumulation did not show,
during those years, nearly as much dynamism as a neoclassical growth model would have
predicted in the face of the startling measured total-factor-productivity gains that
Argentina’s economy was experiencing.
In particular, between the end of the lost decade in 1989, and 1997, the capital
stock was virtually unchanged, while the model predicts that it should have grown by at
least 20 %. Put differently, such an observer would have verified that capital
accumulation in the 1990s wasn’t being as dynamic as “advertised,” at least according to
the frictionless world of a neoclassical model economy. This hint at the presence of
considerable frictions in the capital accumulation process could have been exhibited by
the skeptics as an early sign that not everything in Argentina was as fine as many seem to
have believed at the time and that non-negligible growth risks might lie ahead. Indeed,
the paper cannot dismiss the conjecture that the failure to identify and remove whatever
frictions were responsible for the underperformance (relative to the model) of investment
during the 1990s played a role in Argentina’s ultimate inability to escape repeated threats
of financial meltdown, default, and devaluation, threats that finally materialized at the
beginning of 2002.

3

2. OVERVIEW OF THE EVIDENCE

The booming 1990s were preceded in Argentina, as illustrated in Figure 1, by a
protracted economic decline, the so-called “lost decade,” studied in detail in Kydland and
Zarazaga (2002)-- KZ hereafter.1 Given the performance during those lost-decade years,
in which output per capita fell at an annual rate of 2.2 %, the seemingly stellar expansion
of the 1990s would not appear as shocking to anyone familiar with neoclassical growth
theory. After all, a neoclassical growth theorist unaware of the structural reforms that
Argentina implemented in the first half of that decade would have failed to detect in that
expansion any signs of those reforms and would have had no trouble in attributing all of
it, in principle, to the typical strong recovery that theory would predict for any economy
that has been drifting longer than usual below its long run path.
Figure 1 would not be enough to dismiss that “bounce back effect” view, as the
line representing GDP per capita detrended with the average growth for the period 195097 shows indeed that by the end of the 1990s the economy had simply returned to trend.
A somewhat more pessimistic picture emerges when actual GDP per capita is detrended
by the average growth rate for the period 1950-79: by this measure, which completely
excludes from trend the negative effects of the lost decade years, actual GDP per capita
was still about 22 % below trend.
However, a neoclassical growth theorist would have indeed been puzzled by some
of the figures in Table 1, which reports the results of a standard growth accounting
exercise with the production function represented in its “intensive” (per capita) form.

1

See the seminal work by Elías (1992) for the period 1950-80.

4

To be precise, throughout this paper it is assumed that the production function has
the form:
Yt = At K tθ Lt

1−θ

(1)

where Y is aggregate output, A is total factor productivity (TFP), K is aggregate capital,
and L is employment, measured in terms of hours at work.2 After dividing both sides by
total population, Nt, and some algebra, it is possible to decompose output per capita into
three factors: the TFP factor A1 /(1−θ ) , labor intensity (L) and the capital intensity factor
( K / Y )θ /(1−θ ) . This decomposition in per capita terms, rather than in absolute terms, is
convenient because the growth rate of the efficiency factor coincides with the trend
growth rate of output per capita when employment per capita and capital intensity are
constant.3
For the purpose of this growth accounting exercise, as discussed in the section on
the calibration procedure below, the capital cost share was set at 0.4.
According to Table 1, GDP per capita during the lost decade declined at an annual
rate of 2.3 percent. The TFP factor accounted for almost all of this decline. By contrast,
the TFP factor experienced a big surge of almost 7% in the 1990s. In this case,
information about the structural reforms introduced over the period would have been
relevant to a neoclassical growth theorist who could otherwise be puzzled by the
magnitude of those productivity gains.
However, another figure of Table 1 would have called his attention: the fact that
the excess of TFP growth over GDP growth was compensated by a fairly large decline in
2

Capital input corresponds to the capital stock in place by the end of the previous period, rather than of the
current one, as in KZ . This different timing, along with updated GDP and employment series, accounts for
the differences between the figures in Table 1 of this paper and the same table of that other paper.
3
For details, see Kehoe and Prescott (2002.)

5

the capital-output ratio. This feature of the data would have led him naturally to wonder
whether the extent of such “capital shallowing” was consistent with productivity gains of
the magnitude observed in that same period. The goal of the quantitative exercise in the
next section is to answer precisely this question.

3. ANALYTIC FRAMEWORK
Model
In this paper we examine the growth performance in the 1990s through the lens of
the same stochastic neoclassical growth model as that studied in KZ, briefly summarized
here for convenience.
Household preferences can be represented by:
∞

Max E ∑ β t (1 + η ) t (ctα (1 − lt )1−α )1−σ /(1 − σ )

(2)

t =0

where ct represents consumption, lt hours of work, α is a preferences share parameter that
determines the fraction of utility originating in consumption and leisure, η the population
growth rate, and σ the coefficient of constant relative risk aversion.
Technology is described by

ct + xt = z t k tθ [(1 + γ ) t l t ]1−θ

(3)

xt = (1 + γ ) (1 + η ) k t +1 − (1 − δ ) k t

(4)

z t +1 = ρ z t + ε t

(5)

where kt is the capital stock, xt is investment, θ the labor input share in national income,
and zt a stochastic, stationary, exogenous technological shock, where the innovation εt is

6

assumed to be an i.i.d. process with mean zero and standard deviation 1/(1-ρ). As should
be apparent from the notation, the model assumes labor augmenting technological
progress at the rate γ. On the balanced growth path of this model economy, output,
consumption and capital grow at the rate (1 + η) (1 + γ).

Calibration

Following the approach described in Cooley and Prescott (1995), the model
economy was calibrated by choosing parameters so that the balanced growth path of the
model matches certain steady-state features of Argentina’s economy. With the exception
of the persistence parameter ρ, the parameter values reported in Table 2 are the same as
in KZ, where the readers can find a more thorough justification for the choices of those
values, as well as a detailed discussion of the sources of the data and methodology
followed in the construction of all the series, such as the capital stock, involved in the
estimation of the TFP (or Solow residual.)
In setting the persistence parameter ρ, the autoregressive component of the total
factor productivity process, we follow the same procedure as in KZ. That is, we set ρ to
the value of the point estimate of the coefficient from an autoregression on detrended
Solow residuals (TFP.) However, for the purpose of robustness check in this paper, we
explore the quantitative effects of detrending the Solow residuals by the average TFP
growth rate in two different periods: 1950-79, and alternatively, 1950-97, rather than
1950-70 as in KZ. As reported in Table 2, the resulting ρ for the first period was 0.7553
while for the second it was 0.8423.

7

Computation

The numerical experiments below report the allocations that a social planner
maximizing the welfare of a representative household would pick in our artificial
economy. Technically, this social planner problem was solved with the by now standard
linear quadratic approach pioneered by Kydland and Prescott (1982). As is well known,
under standards assumption that are satisfied in this paper, the social planner’s preferred
allocation can be decentralized as a competitive equilibrium in which households
maximize their welfare and firms their profits.

4. EXPERIMENTS
Purpose

The purpose of this section is to address the question that the imaginary
neoclassical growth theorist in the introduction might ask when confronted with Table 1.
That is, Did the capital stock and employment in the 1990s behave as predicted by a
neoclassical growth model in which TFP is taken as exogenous and no other exogenous
factors change? In particular, would the “capital shallowing” observed during the 1990s
stand as an anomaly from the perspective of a parsimonious neoclassical growth model?
To that end, we simulate the model by feeding the measured TFP into the competitive
equilibrium (or social planner’s) decision rules, after having set the initial capital stock at
the value (detrended) that it had at the end of 1989.
For the purpose of comparing the outcomes generated by the model with the actual
data, it is important to point out that the numerical experiments were carried out under the

8

assumption that the artificial economy does not exhibit any long-run growth. That is, with

η = 0 and γ = 0. As in KZ, based in turn in the findings reported by Hansen (1997,) the
appropriate comparison of the outcomes of the model with the data requires to detrend
the latter with the long run average rates consistent with the parameter values reported in
Table 2.

Findings

As more fully discussed in KZ, for the purposes of detrending there is some
uncertainty about the long run growth features of Argentina’s economy. In particular, as
inspection of Figure 1 should make apparent, it is unclear whether the lost decade of the
1980s should be considered a normal occurrence along Argentina’s long run growth path,
or rather, a rare occurrence that should not be taken into consideration at the time of
assessing the long run growth trend (or “potential output”) of that economy.
To take into account this uncertainty about the “true” trends, the outcomes from
the numerical experiments are compared with the data detrended with the relevant
average growth rates for two different periods: 1950-79, and 1950-97.
Thus, for example, the capital stock for the first numerical experiment was
detrended assuming long run population and TFP factor annual growth rates of,
respectively, 1.71% and 0.92%, the same as the average annual growth rates of those
variables during the period 1950-79 reported in Table 1. The corresponding detrending
rates for the second experiment were 1.54% and 1.02%. Since along a balanced growth
path employment should increase at the same rate as population, the employment series

9

were detrended by 1.71% and 1.54% for the comparisons with the first and second
experiment, respectively.
As the above figures should make clear, the differences in the average TFP factor
growth rates between the two benchmark periods were minimal, suggesting that the
unusually large productivity gains of the 1990s more than compensated for the unusually
heavy productivity losses of the 1980s. Accordingly, any differences between the first
experiment (detrending by 1950-79 averages) and second experiment (detrending with
1950-97 averages) can be attributed mainly to differences in the population growth rates.
The results of the numerical experiments are reported in Figures 2 through 7.
Figures 2 through 4 compare the outcomes of our “no growth” artificial economy
with the data detrended by the relevant 1950-79 average growth rates. As is apparent
from Figures 2 and 3, the model economy overestimates labor and capital input. The
overestimation of the latter is particularly important: while according to the model the
capital stock should have been about 25% larger by the end of the 1990s than in 1989, it
merely came back to its 1989 level according to the data. As a result, the extent of the
“capital shallowing” observed in the 1990s was much more pronounced than what the
neoclassical growth model would have predicted (Figure 4.) In particular, while,
according to the model, by the end of the 1990s the capital-output ratio should have been
only 10% below its long run (steady-state) value, in the data it was by then almost a
fourth below its steady state value.4

4

Some “capital shallowing” is not inconsistent with the predictions of a neoclassical growth model, as
above trend TFP realizations may induce such an increase in employment (and output) in order to take
advantage of the particularly “good times” to save and accumulate capital, that the capital-output ratio may
initially decline and start rising to its long run value only later, when the unusually good TFP realizations
subside.

10

As should be clear from Figure 5, the overestimation of capital input is a feature
of the model that is robust to the choice of long run trend. In particular, as was the case
when detrending by 1950-79 averages, the capital stock does not show much change
between 1997 and 1989 when detrended by the relevant average growth rates for the
period 1950-97 either. Yet, according to the model the capital stock in 1997 should have
been 20 % larger than in 1989. In correspondence with this result, the process of “capital
shallowing” was, again, much more pronounced in the 1990s than what the model would
have predicted. (Figure 7.)
The choice of trend, however, does make a difference for labor input. As is
apparent from comparing Figure 3 with Figure 6, the predictions of the model are much
more in line with the employment data when they are detrended by the average
population growth rate in the period 1950-97 than when they are detrended with the
corresponding 1950-79 average.

CONCLUSION

This paper has examined the economic expansion that Argentina experienced
during the 1990s through the lens of a very parsimonious neoclassical growth model. The
main finding is that investment remained much weaker than what the model would have
predicted. This result seems to be robust to different conjectures about the underlying
trend growth rates, be they the ones observed for the period 1950-70, as reported in KZ,
or for the periods 1950-79 and 1950-97 used for this paper.
A similar anomaly for the 1980s reported in KZ could be used to dismiss the
relevance of the model for analyzing Argentina’s growth experience in the last two

11

decades. However, as also pointed out in KZ, an open economy version of the
parsimonious neoclassical growth model used there and here could still account for the
1980s. The reason is that the productivity decline observed in the lost decade would
induce much larger capital outflows in that open economy model than in the closed
economy model considered here. As a result, the model would predict lower investment
than it does now and would produce, therefore, predictions eventually more in line with
the data.
However, those same open economy features are likely to enlarge, rather than
reduce, the overestimation of investment in the model during the expansion of the 1990s.
The reason would be that for that period the productivity surge would induce large capital
inflows and, therefore, an investment even higher than in the current closed economy
version of the model.
Given that intuition, it seems fair to conjecture that an open economy model could
correct the overestimation of investment during the 1980s but increase it during the
1990s. In other words, the open economy model would corroborate the finding in this
closed economy model that investment during the 1990s did not grow as much as it
should have. This discrepancy suggests the presence of considerable frictions to the
capital accumulation process that were particularly noticeable during the 1990s. Such a
result is not totally unexpected. In fact, a growing body of literature inspired by Alvarez
and Jermann (1998) suggests that small open economies face borrowing constraints that
are binding not during downturns, as intuition might suggest, but during expansions (see,
for example, Kehoe and Perri (2000).) The reason is that lenders do not have much
interest anyway in investing in a country undergoing a period of low or declining

12

productivity growth. Absent the possibility of default, however, the same foreign lenders
would like to invest a lot during a period of high productivity growth. However, if they
refrain from doing so as much as they would in a world without default, it is precisely
because they realize that it is at good times, when it has plenty of capital, that a country
will have the highest incentives to renege on its debt payments. If this conjecture were to
be confirmed more formally, a possible explanation of why investment remained so weak
(relative to the model) in Argentina during the 1990s is that investors still had fresh in
their memories that country’s sovereign debt default in the mid 1980s and confiscation of
deposits in 1990. By the same token, the new confiscation of deposits in 2001 and default
in 2002 would harbinger that a new lost decade lies ahead for Argentina.
Whether an open economy model that incorporates the possibility of default will
be able to resolve the “capital shallowing” anomaly of the 1990s uncovered in this paper
is a challenging open question that should stimulate much needed and exciting research
efforts.

13

Table 1
Accounting for Growth:
Time period

Factor
GDP per capita
TFP

Capital
intensity

Labor
intensity

1979-1990

-2.22 %

-2.61 %

0.19 %

0.22 %

1990-1997

4.94 %

6.84 %

- 2.47 %

0.71 %

14

Table 2
Parameter Values

For experiment detrending
with averages in period:
1950-79
1950-97

Time Period
γ (productivity factor)

0.92 %

1.02 %

η (population growth)

1.71 %

1.54 %

Technology level in 1989

0.8083

0.8007

Initial Capital Stock in 1989

1.3789

1.3878

ρ (shock persistence)

0.7553

0.8423

δ (depreciation Rate)

10 %

r (real interest rate)

10 %

σ (risk aversion)

2

θ (capital share)

0.4

α (intratemporal elasticity of substitution)

Steady State k/y (capital-output ratio)

15

0.3638
2

Figure 1
GDP per capita
Actual and Detrended
1.6000
1.5000

Actual

1.4000
1.3000
1.2000
1.1000

Average 1950-2001

1.0000
0.9000

Detrended

0.8000
0.7000
0.6000
0.5000
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Figure 2
Capital Input
1950-79 Trend
0.6
0.55

0.5
M od e l
0.45
0.4

0.35
0.3
Dat a
0.25
0.2
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

16

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Figure 3
Labor Input
1950-79 Trend
-1.14

-1.16
Model
-1.18

-1.2

-1.22
Data
-1.24

-1.26
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Figure 4
Capital-Output Ratio
1950-79 Trend
2

1.9
M o de l
1.8

1.7

1.6
Dat a
1.5

1.4
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

17

1995

1996

1997

1998

Figure 5
Capital Input
1950-97 Trend
0.6
0.55
Model
0.5
0.45
0.4

0.35
Dat a
0.3

0.25
0.2
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Figure 6
Labor Input
1950-97 Trend
-1.14

-1.16
Model

Ln(N)

-1.18

-1.2
Data
-1.22

-1.24

-1.26
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

18

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Figure 7
Capital-Output Ratio
1950-97 Trend
2

1.9
M o de l
1.8

1.7

1.6
Dat a
1.5

1.4
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

19

1995

1996

1997

1998

References

Alvarez, F. and Jermann, U. J. (1998), “Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications of
Endogenous Solvency Constraints” (Research Working Paper: 99/05, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia.)
Cooley, Thomas F. and Edward C. Prescott (1995) “Economic Growth and Business
Cycles,” in Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Thomas F. Cooley, ed. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Elías, Víctor J. (1992) “Sources of Growth: A Study of Seven Latin American
Countries,” ICS Press, San Francisco, California.
Hansen, Gary D. (1997) “Technical Progress and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 21, 1005-23.
Kehoe, Timothy and Edward C. Prescott (2002): “Great Depressions of the 20th Century,”
Review of Economic Dynamics 5: 1-18.
Kehoe, Patrick, and Fabrizio Perri (forthcoming): “International Business Cycles With
Endogenous Incomplete Markets,” Econometrica.
Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott (1982): “Time to Build and Aggregate
Fluctuations,” Econometrica 50:1345-70.
Kydland, Finn E. and Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga (2002): “Argentina’s Lost Decade,”
Review of Economic Dynamics 5: 152-165.
Pastor, Manuel and Carol Wise (2001): “From Poster Child to Basket Case,” Foreign
Affairs 8 (September-October): 60-72.

20

Capital Input
Perfect foresight, "Japanese" preferences
1950-97 Average TFP growth

1.2

1.1
Model

LN(K(t))

1

0.9

Data

0.8

0.7

0.6
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Labor input
Perfect foresight, "Japanese" preferences
1950-97 Average TFP growth

-0.2

-0.25

-0.3
Model
Ln(L(t))

-0.35

-0.4
Data
-0.45

-0.5

-0.55
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

C a p i t a l - o ut p ut r a t i o
P e r f e c t f or e si g ht , "J a pa ne se " p r e f e r e n c e s
19 5 0 - 9 7 A v e r a g e T FP g r owt h

0.8
0.75
0.7

0.65
0.6
0.55
0.5

0.45
0.4
0.35
1990

1991

1992

1993

21

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

22