View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

DO "VULNERABLE" ECONOMIES NEED DEPOSIT
INSURANCE?: LESSONS FROM THE U.S.
AGRICULTURAL BOOM AND BUST OF 1920s
Charles W. Calomiris
Working Paper Series
Issues in Financial Regulation
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
October, 1989 (WP-89-18)

Do

"Vulnerable" Economies Need Deposit Insurance?:

Lessons from the U.S. Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s

Charles W. Calomiris
Department of Economics
Northwestern University
and
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

October 1989

This paper was prepared for the Sequoia Institute
Conference on Financial Risk and Financial Regulation in
Commodity-Exporting Economies. The author thanks Lee Alston,
Jeremy Atack, Herbert Baer, Michael Bordo, Philip Brock,
Douglas Evanoff, Kenneth Kuttner, Larry Neal, Hugh Rockoff,
Larry Schweikart, Lawrence J. White, Eugene White, and seminar
participants at Northwestern, Rutgers, and the University of
Illinois--Urbana for helpful comments, and Eric Klusman for
excellent technical assistance.




I . INTRODUCTION

To justify the substantial protection that governments
offer banks, regulators frequently refer to banks' unique
position as the channel through which payments clear, and
through which essential short-term commercial and workingcapital credit are provided to parties whose access to other
sources of funds is limited.

Banks are "special" because all

other industries rely on them to maintain their operations and
execute their transactions in a timely, convenient way.

In

particular, whether one defines the payments system narrowly to
include only check clearing, or more broadly to include lines
of short-term credit to "information-intensive" borrowers, it
would be hard to conceive of a payments system without banks.
Thus shocks that threaten the viability of banks,
encourage financial disintermediation, and cause disruptive
bank failures or suspensions of deposit convertibility can be
very costly to society, and these costs may be far greater than
the reduced profits, or bankruptcy costs, incurred by banks.
Recent research on the peculiar severity of the Great
Depression and the vulnerability of agricultural producers to
banking disturbances in the 1980s have received particular
emphasis as examples of socially costly financial disruption
(see Bernanke, 1983; and Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock, 1986).
The externalities generated by banks' special role as check
clearing agents and commercial credit suppliers, therefore, may
provide a rationale for regulation of banks.




Notwithstanding this presumed vulnerability of the

payments system and the essential role of banks, critics of
current government interventions into banking have argued that
the government has gone too far in guaranteeing bank
liabilities and consequently has promoted an unacceptable
degree of socially undesirable risk taking by banks.

For

example, from a theoretical perspective, Calomiris and Kahn
(1988) argue that demandable-debt banking, and the first-come
first-served rule of bank repayment to depositors, were part of
an incentive-compatible equilibrium in which informed
depositors (often other banks) were rewarded for investing
resources in monitoring banks.

Insurance removes the reward,

and hence the incentive, that encourages such monitoring.
Insured banks' incentives to undertake excessively risky
projects are magnified by shocks that reduce bank
capital.

Such shocks increase the banker's potential gain from

pursuing long shots (see Calomiris and Kahn, 1989) by
increasing the implicit value of the put option inherent in
deposit insurance (see also, Karaken and Wallace, 1978).
Empirical evidence of excessive risk taking by insured
financial intermediaries, especially in response to adverse
shocks that reduce bank capital, has been provided by Kane
(1988) and Calomiris (1989), among others.
Furthermore, critics argue that regulators underestimate
the extent to which the financial "safety net" could be
provided with little or no government insurance of banks.
example, private clearinghouses historically provided




2

For

coinsurance among member banks that reduced the incentive for
depositors to remove funds from banks during periods of
financial uncertainty.

Mutual regulation and monitoring

ensured that members would not free ride on the group
protection (see Cannon, 1910; and Gorton, 1985).

Coordination

among banks, sometimes even across state lines, was enhanced in
and among states that permitted branch banking -- in
particular, in the antebellum American South (see Calomiris,
1989).1

With fewer, and better diversified, banks it was

easier for banks to respond to crises as a group, again
effectively coinsuring by continuing to "make markets" in other
banks' deposits and notes.
Similarly, in three unit-banking states of the antebellum
North, statewide bank liability insurance plans modeled on
private clearinghouse coinsurance arrangements managed to
protect the payments system and limit (or eliminate) bank
failures and suspensions of convertibility without encouraging
excessive risk taking by members.

These plans gave member

banks authority to enact and enforce regulations, and provided
the incentive for effective self regulation and monitoring by
making member banks fully and mutually liable for the
liabilities of any failing banks.

These systems managed to

maintain the smooth functioning of the payments system within
and across states, and saw few, if any, bank failures relative
to states that lacked an effective means of bank coordination.
A review of the experiences of these antebellum bank insurance




3

success stories, and the very different experiences of other
state bank insurance schemes, is provided in Calomiris (1989).
The apparent lesson of historical bank clearinghouses,
early Southern branch banking, and mutual-guarantee self­
regulating insurance plans under government sponsonship is that
banking coalitions can act to coinsure effectively against many
threats to the payments system.

The successful operation of

private clearinghouses in today's financial markets —

for

example, the CHIPS network, or the futures and options
clearinghouses —

indicate that these lessons can be applied

successfully in the modern context, as well.
Private coinsurance schemes, however, cannot offer
unlimited protection against financial collapse in all
circumstances.

Private insurance is not effective in

preventing disintermediation by depositors who question the
ability of the coalition to guarantee the losses of its
members.

Once a shock becomes large enough to threaten the

capital of the group of banks as a whole —
a small subset of its members —

rather than simply

coinsurance ceases to be

credible.
Furthermore, the geographic range of privately coinsuring
groups —

and consequently the potential for coinsurance -- may

be restricted by laws that limit branch banking, and thus
impair the ability of bankers in different locations to
communicate, monitor one another, and coordinate their
behavior.




Most financial crises in U.S. history began as small
4

disturbances, relative to aggregate bank capital, which were
insurable, in principle, by mutual protection among banks.
Reasonable fears of insolvency of a subset of banks, confusion
as to which banks had suffered most from the shock, and the
absence of a mechanism for mutual protection at the state or
national level, however, provided incentives to depositors, who
were unable to determine the precise incidence of the
disturbance, to withdraw their funds (see Gorton, 1989; and
Calomiris, 1989).

Lacking effective means to coinsure against

such disturbances, the thousands of independent and
geographically distant unit banks sometimes were forced to
suspend convertibility as a defensive reaction during such
economy-wide bank runs.

Suspensions of convertibility limited

depositors' and noteholders' liquidity, and reduced the
desirability of placing funds in banks, reducing the supply of
loans and forcing banks to adopt more conservative lending
practices than under normal circumstances.

Other banks failed

due to losses incurred as the result of "fire sales" of assets
to meet withdrawal requests (see Calomiris and Schweikart,
1988; and Calomiris, 1989).
The relative success of statewide systems of branching
banks, or mutual-liability banks, in meeting such crises as the
Panic of 1857 suggests that, for an economy as diverse
nationally as the United States, a combination of full
nationwide branch banking and government-sponsored, privatelymanaged mutual-liability insurance may be sufficient to prevent




5

large sector- or region-specific shocks to bank capital from
becoming a threat to aggregate bank capital, and therefore, the
payments system.^
One could argue, however, that this approach might not be
sufficient for economies with intrinsic vulnerability to large
sector-specific shocks that threaten aggregate bank solvency.
In the case of the United States, full interstate branching
virtually could eliminate the risk to banks from regionally
concentrated shocks to the terms-of-trade, which have proved
particularly important for the agricultural and oil-producing
sectors (see Alston, 1983; Stock, 1985; and Calomiris, Hubbard,
and Stock, 1986).

In smaller countries with less diversified

economies, however, the risk from terms-of-trade shocks is
large (see Brock, 1988), but the potential for reducing
payments system risk through diversification is more limited
because national sovereignty limits the development of full
international branch banking.

The limitations due to national

sovereignty can be viewed as an example of the "timeinconsistency" problem.

Banks chartered in country X may

decide to leave their local branches in country Y stranded
rather than pay for their losses during bad times, and there
may be no way for country Y to force them to do so.
Furthermore, governments may find it optimal to limit the
repatriation of bank profits to support bank branches in other
countries.
The central question I will address in this paper is




6

whether the governments of such intrinsically risky economies
stand ready to bail out banks in the event of a large adverse
shock to the country's economic base?

The question may be

posed in two parts: How great are the advantages of a
government's insuring the payments system (whether narrowly or
broadly defined) from the strains of such shocks, rather than
relying on a privately administered, mutual-guarantee system?;
Are the social costs of excessive risk taking by banks, which
result from the existence of bank deposit insurance, greater or
less than the supposed benefits of insurance?^
The specific historical cases I will discuss are the
experiences of agricultural areas of the United States in the
1920s —

a period that witnessed a rapid, sharp terms-of-trade

reduction for agricultural producers and an unprecedented rate
of farm, business, and bank failures in the most affected
regions.

The 1920s provide a particularly useful context to

investigate the role of different regulatory regimes in
reducing or magnifying the effects of the shock on the
viability of financial intermediaries.

Interstate branch

banking was not permitted, though some states allowed full, or
limited, intra-state branching.

Furthermore, some states had

enacted deposit insurance prior to the crisis.

Finally, the

existence in each state of nationally chartered banks (under a
common regulatory regime across states) provides a point of
comparison across states of the magnitude of the shock to banks
in each state, which can provide insight into the comparative




7

performance of the various state-chartered banking regimes, and
the contribution of deposit insurance or branch banking in
magnifying or lessening the impact on banks.
In Calomiris (1989) I presented evidence from the 1920s of
much higher initial growth, and subsequent failure rates, for
four state-chartered, insured banking systems relative to
national banks operating in the same state, which were
prohibited by the U.S. Comptroller of the Currency from joining
state deposit insurance funds.

While this comparison was a

useful first step, it is important to establish that the
differences between insured state-chartered and uninsured
national-chartered bank failure rates are not merely an
artefact of different exposure to agricultural risk, due to
different locational patterns (rural vs. urban) for state- and
national-chartered banks, or more restrictive regulations on
national-chartered banks —
on real estate loans.^

in particular, stricter limitations

Here I look at all eight of the insured

systems, and compare the performance of national- and statechartered banks within and across states, taking account of
differences in economic and regulatory environment (e.g., the
existence of branching and deposit insurance), and using
additional indicators of bank performance.
No single historical example can provide a conclusive
"answer" to the broad question of whether banking system bail­
outs are socially desirable in price-sensitive economies; but
it is only through the accumulation of evidence from examples




8

of the costs of such crises, and the consequences of the
decisions to provide insurance or allow branching, that policy
makers will be able to make the difficult choices of bank
regulatory policy in an informed manner.
Section II provides cross-sectional evidence on price,
income, and wealth movements, and indicators of financial
distress experienced by the various states in the 1920s.
Section III measures changes in the size, number, and portfolio
structure of national- and state-chartered banks prior to and
during the crisis.

Section IV evaluates differences in the

performance of the state-chartered banking systems in response
to the crisis -- specifically, the rates of bank suspension and
bank failure, the costs to depositors of failures, and the
ability of the banking systems to recover from the crises,
under different state regulatory regimes.

Section V returns to

the central question of whether deposit insurance is desirable
for economies with intrinsic vulnerability to large income
disturbances.I
.

II. THE POST-WORLD WAR I AGRICULTURAL CRISIS
Typically, wars have been good times for farmers.

World

War I, like the Napoleonic Wars, and the Crimean War of the
1850s, witnessed a rapid expansion of agricultural income.

As

for previous wartime booms, however, the end of war brought
with it a severe decline in the agricultural terms of trade.
Declines in price and income became translated into declines in




9

farm land values, and farmers who had expanded operations with
debt financing during the boom found their incomes slipping as
their leverage ratios rose, often to levels that were
unsustainable.
The crisis was quite sector- and region-specific.

Indeed,

for most sectors (and consequently, the "non-agricultural"
states) in the U.S. the 1920s were a "new age" of unprecedented
stability and growth.

In many states with a heavy reliance on

agricultural earnings, however, the period was one of sustained
declining income and financial collapse.^

Differences across

the states in the degree of agricultural stress reflected
different movements in earnings and wealth, as well as
differences in farmers' financial vulnerability to those
declines.
Table 1 provides an index of real gross farm income and
its components for 1910-1930.

These figures show that the

decline in agricultural income affected virtually all
producers, though the timing and severity of decline varied
across activities, with staple foodstuffs and textile raw
materials suffering the worst percentage declines from 1919 to
1921.
The uneven sectoral decline within agriculture produced
different responses of income and wealth across states.
Furthermore, Alston (1983) finds that similar farm wealth and
earnings reductions produced far greater rates of farm
foreclosure in some states than in others.




10

States that had

expanded farm acreage, and farm leverage, during the wartime
boom, suffered much higher rates of farm foreclosure, holding
declines in wealth and income constant.
Foreclosure rates for farms throughout the country during
the 1920s and 1930s reached historic highs that have never been
exceeded.

For 1921-1940 foreclosure rates averaged more than

five times the highest average levels for any other decade from
1913 to 1980.

While the national average was high during the

interwar period, the uneven incidence of foreclosure across
states made matters far worse in some states.

In Montana, from

1921 to 1923, 28 percent of farmers lost farms or property.^
From 1926 to 1930, foreclosures in Montana relative to owneroperated farms in the state averaged 52.2 per thousand, per
year.^

Other Northern and Western states with extremely high

foreclosure rates (per thousand owner-operated farms) for 19261930 include South Dakota (70.4), North Dakota (58.0), Oklahoma
(50.0), Iowa (48.3), Arizona (42.7), and Colorado (42.4).

In

the South, South Carolina (68.0), Georgia (56.5), Mississippi
(47.7), and Louisiana (40.1) had substantially higher rates of
foreclosure than the other Southern states.

Arkansas (39.7),

Nebraska (38.4), Idaho (37.6), and Missouri (34.1) also
experienced foreclosure rates substantially above the national
average of 27.1 per thousand.
Tables 2 and 3 provide a variety of measures of economic
conditions for each of the 48 contiguous states during the
period 1919-1930.




Table 2 contains data on: gross farm income
11

growth from 1919 to 1921; growth in total net income from all
sources received by the farm and non-farm populations from 1919
to 1921; the ratio of farmer to non-farmer income in 1920; the
percentage difference in the value of crops sold from 1922 to
1925, and from 1925 to 1928; and the percentage change in the
state-specific crop price index from 1919 to 1924.
Table 3 reports: the change in the value of farm real
estate per acre over the periods 1913-1920, 1920-1925, and
1925-1930; the ratio of mortgage debt to farm real estate value
in 1920; the farm-to-total population ratio for 1920; and the
farm foreclosure rate for 1926 to 1930.
The choices of dates for each series in Tables 2 and 3
reflect data availability, as well as the peaks and troughs of
the agricultural cycle.

While the income, wealth, and price

variables in Tables 2 and 3 are all expressed in nominal terms,
rather than adjusted for aggregate price level movements, the
GNP deflator was roughly constant for the years 1919-1929, with
the exception of 1920, according to recent estimates, both by
Romer (1989) , and Balke and Gordon (1989) .
reproduced in Table 4.

These estimates are

Moreover, from the standpoint of the

sustainability of farms and farmers' ability to repay debt to
banks, it is nominal income and wealth that matter, since debt
and debt service are set in nominal terms.
Tables 2 and 3 indicate that the first decade of the
agricultural crisis (1920-1930) can be divided usefully into
three stages: the initial shock of 1920-1921, a period of




12

partial recovery from 1922 to 1924, and a subsequent period of
decline.

Because of differences in crop mix, supply-side

variation, and financial vulnerability, the experiences of the
various states differed substantially during these three sub­
periods, as the tables show.
No single indicator provides an adequate index of the
experience of a particular state during one of these sub­
periods.

First, income and price indicators are extremely

sensitive to the specific dates over which they are calculated.
For example, 1924 was a relatively good year for Montana and
North Dakota, and differs markedly from either 1923 or 1925 in
this respect.

Second, some income or price movements are

perceived as transitory, while others are viewed as more
permanent.

Aside from the immediate cash-flow effects of such

changes, the economic impact of income shocks on farmers'
wealth and financial viability depended on perceptions of how
permanent these disturbances were.

Third, the impact of a

wealth or income shock depends on the vulnerability (leverage)
of farms —

that is, how severe the shock was relative to

previous expectations of future income.

The highest

foreclosure rates occurred in states with a relatively high
ratio of farm mortgage debt to farm real estate value, as
indicated in Table 3.

These considerations suggest that, while

the changes in prices and income provide measures of the
sources of disturbances, changes in the value of farms and the
farm foreclosure rate are more indicative of the likely




13

(anticipated) long-run changes in farm income associated with
those shocks.®
Finally, in evaluating the impact of agricultural shocks
on statewide bank performance, the proportion of state income
derived from farming, and the proportion of the labor force
employed in farming, are of obvious importance.

The

geographical isolation of farming communities is also relevant,
as it affects the abilities of merchants or bankers in these
areas to diversify.
The links (explored in section IV, below) between
indicators of economic condition reported in Tables 2 and 3,
and the threat to banks in a given state, therefore, are
subtle.

Ideally, in analysing these links, one would want to

take account of the perceived permanence of different income
shocks, the degree of financial leverage, the rapidity and
cumulation of shocks, and the link between the degree of
concentration of income in agriculture and the impact on banks
from agricultural shocks.
The focus of this study is on the role of regulatory
regimes in limiting the incidence and costs of financial
disruption in the face of a substantial challenge to the
financial system.

To evaluate the influences of the different

state regulatory decisions in propagating adverse shocks, I
compare the performance of banks in the states that were
substantially affected by the agricultural depression, under
different regulatory environments.




14

The sample of states defined to have been substantially
affected, whose financial systems are analysed in greatest
detail below, includes any state that experienced farm real
estate value reduction (per acre) of greater than 20 percent
from 1920 to 1930, or an average annual farm foreclosure rate
of greater than 20 per thousand from 1926 to 1930.

This sample

includes states that suffered extreme depression, as well as
those with more moderate commercial failure rates and bank
failure experiences (discussed in section IV).

The states in

the sample are listed in Table 5, categorized according to
their deposit insurance and branch banking laws.

III. BANK MEMBERSHIP AND BALANCE SHEET PATTERNS ACROSS STATES

Regulation's Influence on Membership. Location, and Risk
National banks were governed by common regulations across
different states, and thus their experience provides something
of a state-specific benchmark against which to compare the
behavior of state-chartered banks across states.

Bank entry

and asset growth, as well as financing and portfolio decisions
of state-chartered banks, can be compared to one another, in
absolute terms, as well as relative to the behavior of national
banks in the respective states.
Of course, national banks were not identical across states
and faced different exposure to agricultural risk.

While in

every state national banks were larger on average, and located




15

more often in cities than their state-chartered counterparts,
differences across states in the locational and size patterns
of national and state banks were important.

In some states,

national or state banks operated more in urban locations and
were larger on average than in others.

Furthermore, national

banks in cities that served as regional reserve centers for
agricultural areas may have suffered asset depletion due to the
impact of agricultural disturbances on correspondents.

In what

follows, I try as much as possible to control for these
differences across states.
The years prior to 1920 saw the establishment of deposit
insurance systems in several states.

Often it has been

remarked that incentive problems due to insurance made insured
banking systems grow at a "reckless" rate, and caused them to
limit the growth of capital, and overextend themselves in the
farm loan market (Thies and Gerlowski, 1989/ Calomiris, 1989;
White, 1983; FDIC, 1956; ABA, 1933; Robb, 1921); however, no
systematic quantitative comparisons of the behavior of the
different state-chartered systems have been made before, to my
knowledge.
It is difficult to distinguish incorrect expectations of
persisting prosperity from excess risk taking induced by
deposit insurance unless one has a standard against which to
measure the behavior of insured banks. When one controls for
differences in economic environment, using uninsured state
banking systems in other states, and national banks in the same




16

state, one has provided such standards of comparison.
The dates for which the different state deposit-insurance
systems came into and out of operation are given in Table 5.
For three states (Kansas, Texas, and Washington), participation
in state-run deposit insurance was voluntary.

Numbers and

deposits of participating and non-participating state banks in
these states are given in Table 10.

All state-run insured

banking systems were in operation during the boom of 1918-1920,
and with the exception of Washington, the state-operated
insurance systems were the dominant component of the statechartered systems by 1920.

In Texas, state banks that did not

belong to the state-run system were privately insured, as
required by regulation; while in Washington and Kansas statechartered banks could avoid insurance altogether.
In describing the peculiar incentives of insured banks,
one should distinguish between voluntary and involuntary state
systems.

Under voluntary insurance legislation, banks could

retain state charters without joining the insured system.
Since national charters were a costly means for many banks to
avoid the insurance fund, voluntary state insurance was an
important additional option.
The laws governing withdrawal from a state's insurance
plan were extremely important as well.

In two of the three

voluntary systems (Washington and Kansas), banks opting out of
state-run insurance could avoid any form of insurance.

These

two systems also limited the effectiveness of insurance —




17

and

thereby reduced risk subsidization among banks —

by allowing

member banks to leave the insurance system at any time.
Washington's system went further, and provided essentially no
protection for large losses, because it allowed banks to opt
out at any time without even retaining liability for past
losses.

In Washington, low initial insurance premia and the

ability to leave the voluntary systems seem to have encouraged
many banks that were not aggregious risk takers to join, only
to opt out once troubles began.

In Texas, voluntary withdrawal

was not permitted until the insurance law was amended in 1925.
Of course, banks could also opt out of any of the compulsory or
voluntary state systems by securing a national charter,
although this would have entailed costs to banks that relied on
activities prohibited by national law, or those with
insufficient capital.
In Texas, even though all state-chartered banks were
required to have some form of insurance, the privately insured
banks were unlikely to have had the same opportunities to take
advantage of insurance through excessive risk taking.

While

there is much evidence that supervision and regulation were lax
in the state-run plans, historical examples of privately run
insurance (see Calomiris, 1989) indicate that excessive risk
taking was not a problem because of strong incentives by
insurers to provide effective regulation and supervision.

Thus

Texas' state-chartered banks that chose private rather than
state-run insurance are likely to have assumed risks comparable




18

to uninsured banks in other states.
Both compulsory and voluntary insurance during this period
differed from current U.S. federal deposit insurance in several
important respects.

Typically, interest rates on insured

deposits were restricted by law (except in Nebraska), and
capital requirements were much higher than today (typically, 10
percent of deposits for insured banks). While these interest
rate ceilings were sometimes hard to enforce because of
outright fraud, or the use of discounts as an alternative to
interest (see Cooke, 1910), they constrained the availability
of funds somewhat, in contrast to FDIC and FSLIC regulations
that allow risk-taking member to attract funds by offering
unusually high-interest insured CDs.

Furthermore, as in

virtually all state systems, and the national banking system,
stockholders had extended liability equal to the amount of
capital in the bank.

This was not equivalent to a doubling of

the capital stock because collections from assessments on the
stockholders of failed banks averaged less than 50 percent of
assessments, for all state banking systems from 1921 to 1930.®
Finally, the state systems were not insured by the state
treasuries, but rather by member banks as a group, through an
insurance fund to which banks contributed annual assessments.
These assessments had upper bounds annually, which meant that
solvent banks' liability was limited.

Furthermore, by leaving

the system, or forcing repeal of the insurance statute by
threatening to do so, solvent banks who belonged to the insured




19

systems in the 1920s were able to avoid much of the liability
to depositors of failed banks (more on this below). All these
considerations imply that the effective protection of
depositors, and the potential for excessive risk taking would
have been less under the historical insured systems than under
current federal deposit insurance.

Thus evidence on incentive

problems in these plans provides an a fortiori case for
potential excessive risk taking under government-guaranteed
insurance of the kind available in the U.S. currently.

Evidence on the Effects of Deposit Insurance
Tables 6 through 10 present measures of state banking
system averages and aggregates, disaggregated by type of bank
charter and by state, for the 32 "agricultural-crisis" states
for various dates.

The indicators include: the number of

banks, the proportion located in towns or cities of 2500 or
more, average total assets per bank, aggregate total asset
growth, and the ratio of capital to assets.
As the data for the various state- and national-chartered
systems show, not all types of banks were equally likely to
join one or another system.

Larger minimum capital

requirements and more restrictive portfolio regulations for
national banks meant that small banks, particularly those that
wished to specialize in agricultural credit backed by real
estate, would be attracted to the state-chartered systems.




20

Table 7 reports the proportion of banks in each system that
were located in towns and cities of greater than 2500
inhabitants, and the average size of banks in each system.
While there is considerable variation among states, national
banks were always larger on average, and always had a higher
proportion of banks located in cities.
Historical accounts and economic theory lead one to expect
that deposit insurance for state-chartered banks reinforced
this propensity for small, rural banks to belong to the state
system, and for large, urban banks to join the national system,
because the potential benefits of deposit insurance were
greater for small rural banks.

White (1983, pp. 198-200) finds

that the support for deposit insurance regulation was greatest
among small bankers operating in agricultural areas in unit
banking states with low minimum capital requirements.

For

large, urban state banks (which opposed deposit insurance
legislation) deposit insurance was seen as a burden, a
legislated subsidy from large to small banks operating in the
periphery.I®

Insured deposits typically had interest rate

ceilings that kept them from being as competitive in the market
for large, sophisticated depositors as in the market for
deposits in rural areas.H

Capital requirements in the

insured systems (typically 10 percent of deposits) were more of
an impediment to risk taking for large banks than for smaller
banks operating in the periphery.

A group of oil men,

ranchers, or farmers could organize a small bank to finance




21

their expansion, while placing limited funds of their own at
risk.^

Many of the large city banks found advantages to

operating in a more disciplined environment, with stockholders
and subordinated debtholders keeping watch over conflicts of
interest between bank and banker.

For urban banks, the

expanding opportunities in trust activities and alternatives to
standard demand-deposit banking as a means of finance were the
wave of the future; for small rural banks, deposit-financed
agricultural lending was the way to expand.^
exceptions.

There were

Some particularly unscrupulous large city banks

chose to enter the insured systems, intending to use them as a
means to create and exploit conflicts of interest, and finance
speculative expansion on a scale that would not have been
possible for a rural unit bank.-^
Bank membership and balance sheet patterns indicate that
deposit insurance was an important force in determining who
joined or left the various systems, and in influencing bank
expansion and risk taking during the boom and bust.

No single

indicator in Tables 6 through 10 provides a "litmus test" of
the importance of deposit insurance for adverse selection in
bank membership and excessive risk taking, but a combination of
factors apparent in the tables indicates that state systems
that featured deposit insurance were a special class, during
both the era of expansion and that of contraction.
During the boom period of 1914-1920 the insured banks grew
more rapidly than others.




Sixteen state banking systems grew
22

by a factor of greater than 2.5 from 1914 to 1920, as shown in
Table 11.

Of these 16 systems, 7 were insured (one of the

voluntary systems, Washington, is excluded from this list).
The compulsory systems ranked first, fourth, fifth, eighth, and
eleventh in asset growth over this period.

Two of the

voluntary-participation state systems (Kansas and Texas) ranked
thirteenth and fifteenth.

High growth, by itself, does not

imply excessive risk taking.

As Table 11 shows, high growth

was not confined to insured systems, as the experiences of
Wyoming, North Carolina, and Idaho demonstrate, in particular.
Three factors, however, made the high growth rates of the
insured systems unique: they accomplished high growth mainly
through increases in the numbers of banks, rather than in
assets per bank; growth seems to have been concentrated in
relatively sparsely populated regions; and insured banks
operated with low capital-to-asset ratios, typically reserved
for systems of larger average size.

Of the 8 banking systems

that averaged less than $400,000 in total assets in 1920, 6
were insured banking systems, with the frontier states, Wyoming
and New Mexico, accounting for the remaining two.
The West as a region, therefore, was experiencing its era
of extraordinary banking growth, comparable to the growth of
New England banking in the early national period (1790-1830),
or the South from 1820 to 1860.^^

But the insured banks

differed in certain respects from the other high-growth Western
states.




In New Mexico, state-chartered banks operated in more
23

populous areas, on average (see Table 7), and the fragility
inherent in such rapid growth and small size were offset, in
part, by the unusually high capital-to-asset ratio of banks (12
percent) in 1920, as shown in Table 9.

Wyoming's capital-to-

asset ratio of 9 percent was higher than any of the insured
banks of comparable size, as well.

Thus if one uses the

combined standard of high growth, small bank size, and low
capital-to-asset ratios, the insured banking systems appear
especially vulnerable at the peak in 1920.

Texas operated with

a relatively high capital ratio, because its law required
capital as a percentage of deposits of between 10 and 20
percent (depending on deposit size), while other insurance
systems required 10 percent.
It is important to verify that the high growth and unique
vulnerability of the insured state systems relative to other
state systems is attributable to different banking responses,
rather than different fundamental economic conditions.

To this

end, additional comparisons of insured systems with other
banking systems within and across states are useful.
Specifically, I consider three standards of comparison: the
relative growth of insured and uninsured state banks in states
where insurance was optional; the growth of state-chartered
banks across states, relative to the growth of national banks
in the same state; and the growth of insured banking relative
to uninsured state-chartered banking in adjoining states with
similar "economic fundamentals."




24

For two of the three states with voluntary systems (Kansas
and Texas), it is clear that the growth differences between
national- and state-chartered banking from 1914 to 1920 (Table
8) were due to the disproportionate growth of state-run insured
banking, as Table 10 reveals.

These two voluntary systems grew

rapidly during the boom period 1914-1920 relative to other
state banking, both in number of banks and total deposits.
Texas' system —

The

which did not allow voluntary withdrawal by

member banks, and therefore, provided more anticipated
insurance protection than the Washington or Kansas system -was the fastest growing of the three voluntary insurance
systems, relative to national or uninsured banks in the state.
In Texas, the deposits in banks of all types in the state grew
by 271 percent from the end of 1914 to the end of 1919, while
those in insured banks grew by 402 percent.

The total number

of banks in the state increased by 11 percent, while the number
of insured banks increased 25 percent, from 1914 to 1920.

In

Kansas, total deposit growth was 131 percent for 1914-1919,
while insured-banking deposit growth was 173 percent.
In the third voluntary-insurance state, Washington, the
state-chartered system as a whole grew slowly compared to the
national system, and the insured system never accounted for
more than 41 percent of state-chartered deposits (FDIC, 1956,
p. 50).

Several features of the Washington experience made it

a special case.

First, Washington's free-exit provision

provided virtually no protection, and hence no encouragement




25

for excessive expansion.

Second, its was the last insurance

system to be established (in 1917), and there was less time for
banks to join prior to 1920.

Third, Washington's banking

growth during this period was concentrated more in the large
urban banks.

Its national banking system was third among the

sample of 32 states in average asset size of banks in 1920, and
experienced above average growth in assets from 1914 to 1920.
The lack of a rural/agricultural boom in Washington —

farm

land prices grew a modest 38 percent from 1914 to 1920 —
further limited any perceived advantages to small rural banks
of membership in the insured system.
A second standard for comparing growth during the boom -one that controls for state-specific economic conditions -- is
the relative growth of state and national systems across states
with and without insurance.

Typically, state banking systems

grew faster than national systems, but in some states this
difference is especially pronounced; in others it is actually
reversed.
A rough comparison is provided in Table 12 -- a four-byfour matrix, that arranges states according to the quartile
growth rates of their national- and state-chartered banking
systems for 1914-1920.

Only two state-chartered systems ranked

two or more quartiles higher in growth of assets than the
quartile rank of their state's national banks: Mississippi and
Nebraska.

These were two of the five compulsory insurance

states.




26

A more formal approach to comparing state-chartered
banking growth to national bank growth, across states, is
presented in Table 13.

Using cross-sectional data for the

sample of 32 states, I regress state-chartered bank asset
growth for 1914-1920 on: national-chartered asset growth, the
percentage rise in farm land value per acre, the ratio of farm
population to total population, and dummy variables for the
presence of insurance.

In one version I separate the

voluntary insurance states -- Kansas and Texas -- from the
compulsory insurance systems.

Washington is excluded from the

set of insured states altogether. I also add a dummy variable
(which interacts with the growth of national banking) for
states that contained especially important "reserve centers".
National asset growth is included as a measure of statespecific opportunities for expansion, holding regulation
constant.

The growth in the value of farm real estate is

included to control for different expectations of long-run
profitability from agricultural loans (which should have a
disproportionate effect on state banks).

The reserve center

dummy is included to control for peculiarities in the growth of
national-chartered banks due to interstate influences through
correspondent relations.
The regression results confirm that insurance was
associated with very high relative rates of growth of statechartered banks, and that national banks in reserve-center
states grew more than national banks elsewhere.




27

As predicted,

the effect of compulsory insurance is stronger than that of
voluntary insurance, because voluntary plans provide less
cross-subsidization, and because (in Kansas) withdrawal was
allowed for by law.

Even in Kansas and Texas, however, the

effects of insurance dummies were important (accounting for an
additional 33 percent of asset growth from 1914 to 1920),
although the few degrees of freedom, and consequent high
coefficient standard errors, limit the power of hypothesis
tests.
Finally, comparisons among state banking systems in the
same regions also support the conclusion that insured banking
growth was unusually high, and that insured states were more
vulnerable, during the boom.

First, consider the states in the

Western region adjoining the Western insured states.

These

include: Arkansas, Colorado, Idaho, Iowa, Missouri, Minnesota,
Montana, New Mexico, and Wyoming.

How do these states compare,

in growth, bank size, and capitalization, to the insured states
of Kansas, Nebraska, North Dakota, Oklahoma, South Dakota, and
Texas?

Data on the ratio of state-chartered bank assets in

1914 relative to 1920, average state-chartered bank size, and
capitalization are reported in Table 14.

A similar comparison

is performed in Table 14 between Mississippi statistics and
those of the uninsured states in the deep South in our sample:
Alabama, Georgia, and South Carolina (Louisiana is excluded,
because of the special role of New Orleans as a financial
center.).




28

These data reveal that the nine uninsured state-chartered
systems of adjoining Western states were larger on average,
grew less, and had higher capital than their counterparts in
the insured systems.

On average, uninsured Western asset

ratios (1914/1920) were 0.42, compared to 0.35 for the insured
group.

The average size of the uninsured group was $448,000 in

total assets, while the insured banks averaged $334,000.

The

historic vulnerability of small banks explains why, ceteris
paribus, their depositors required them to maintain higher than
average ratios of capital to deposits.^

But in this sample,

capital averaged 9 percent of assets for the uninsured group,
and 8 percent for the insured.

When Texas is excluded -- the

insured state with a high legally mandated capital-to-deposit
ratio that exceeded "market-determined" bank leverage in other
states -- the difference becomes even greater.
The comparison between Mississippi and its neighbors is
similar.

The asset ratio averaged 0.45 in the uninsured

states, as compared to 0.34 in Mississippi.

The ratio of

capital to assets for the uninsured states was 9 percent, as
compared to 6.6 percent in Mississippi.

Average bank size in

Mississippi was greater than that of the other states (664 as
compared to 538), but this size difference is partly
attributable to the much higher growth in assets in
Mississippi, which tripled from 1914 to 1920, compared to the
other states whose aggregate assets roughly doubled over the
same period.




Also, Mississippi's state-chartered banks
29

included older, relatively large branching banks (10 banks
with 24 branches in 1920) that were allowed to continue
operating, even though new branching was not allowed.

Finally,

as discussed in section IV, many of Mississippi's rural banks
had failed during the boll weevil crisis of 1912-1913, and the
state banking regulators were notoriously restrictive in
granting entry by new banks.

Insured Banking: From Boom to Crisis
Having established, using several standards of comparison,
that deposit insurance was associated with high growth and
greater bank vulnerability (small size and low capital) during
the boom, I now turn to evaluate the effects of insurance on
the membership and balance sheet responses of state banking
systems to the crisis.

As several authors (ABA, 1933; FDIC,

1956; White, 1983; and Calomiris, 1989) have documented, the
insurance plans did not provide effective protection to the
states' payments systems or to bank depositors.

Reimbursements

to depositors were neither timely nor complete, and exit from
the insured systems relieved solvent banks of the
responsibility of covering insolvent banks' liabilities.

Here

I quantify the role of deposit insurance, and the vulnerability
it entailed, in preventing state-chartered banking systems in
states with insurance from responding to the crisis as well as
other state systems.
As one would expect, failures and assessments rose during




30

the collapse, and there was widespread defection of relatively
healthy insured banks to alternative systems, as shown in Table
15.

In all cases, there was a net transfer of banks from the

insured state systems to the national system.
Table 15 reports data on changes of charter across the two
systems within each state from 1921 to 1930.

From 1921 to 1930

the 48 contiguous states as a group experienced a total of 346
net conversions from state- to national-chartered banking.

All

8 states with deposit insurance had positive net conversions
over this period, and as a group they accounted for 278 of the
346 net conversions -- an average of 43 per state.

At the same

time, neighboring states in the West experienced virtually no
net conversions to national banking.

As a group, Montana,

Iowa, Colorado, Idaho, Wyoming, Oregon, Arizona, Arkansas,
Minnesota, and New Mexico had only 5 net conversions in all.
Furthermore, few other states witnessed a substantial number of
conversions to national banking.

Only 8 states other than

those with insurance plans had net conversions of greater than
5:

Alabama, California, Illinois, Minnesota, Missouri, Oregon,

Virginia, and Wisconsin.

This group of states -- unlike the

insured states -- did not suffer a collapse of state banking
during this period.

Alabama's state system showed essentially

flat total assets over the period; California's, Wisconsin's,
and Virginia's state systems experienced substantial intensive
growth; in Illinois only a small percentage of banks converted,
and total state banking assets grew substantially relative to




31

that of national banks; in Minnesota, the percentage that
converted was also small; and Oregon was not an "agricultural
crisis" state.

Thus the insured state-chartered systems were

virtually the only cases of national banking gaining at the
expense of state banking in response to the agricultural
crisis.
In the states with voluntary state-run insurance
participation, there was widespread movement to the other state
systems, as well.
from 1924 to 1926.

In Kansas and Texas banks switched en masse,
The timing of the demise of the Texas

system reflects the fact that withdrawal was not allowed by law
until 1925.

In Kansas, the failure of the largest bank in the

insured system in 1923, and a court ruling in 1926 that
absolved withdrawing banks from liabilities for prior bank
failures (above the amount of securities already deposited in
the state fund), explain the timing of withdrawal.

In

Washington, one bank failure -- again, that of the largest bank
in the state, which accounted for one-fifth of insured deposits
—

prompted all other insured banks to leave the system.^-®
Thus while deposit insurance produced abnormally high

growth during the boom, it caused abnormally low statechartered growth during the crisis.

Table 16 reports

regression results analogous to those of Table 13, but for the
periods 1920-1926 and 1920-1930.

The average annual rate of

business failure from 1921 to either 1925 or 1929, relative to
the average rate for the four years prior to 1921, is included




32

in the regressions to capture better the financial distress
banks faced in each state.

The regressions are run for two

sub-periods because prior to 1930 Nebraska's insurance fund
chose not to close many insolvent banks, thus contaminating
the measure of solvent bank deposits.

For this reason I

exclude Nebraska from the dummy for insured states in the
1920-1926 regression.

Results for the 1920-1930 regression are

reported with and without including Nebraska in the dummy
banking variable.
The regressions show that the presence of insurance was
associated with lower growth during the decline.

Growth for

the insured systems from 1920 to 1926 was 27 percent lower (as
a fraction of the 1920 level) than in uninsured state systems.
Not surprisingly, the difference in growth is lessened if one
chooses a longer period (1920-1930) to gauge recovery from the
crisis. When the postponed collapse of Nebraska is included
for the 1920-1930 sample, there is an increase from a 19
percent to a 24 percent slowdown in decadal growth.
variables generally have the predicted signs —

Other

failure rates

and farm population concentration are associated with lower
growth, and controlling for omitted variables by including
national bank growth is important for the 1920-1926 period.
Land value changes add little after taking these other control
variables into account.
Insured banks were not the only ones that saw a decline in
growth during the crisis. Many states experienced a




33

substantial decline as agricultural earnings fell and
bankruptcies rose.

Interestingly however, there was

substantial variation in the rate of recovery from the crisis
across states, and across banks within states.

As Table 8

shows, the state systems of Arizona, Idaho, and Wyoming saw
high growth rates in the period 1927-1929 that essentially
reversed the negative growth of the previous seven years.

In

all three cases, state-chartered banking growth for the period
1920-1929 exceeded the growth of national-chartered banks in
those states . ^
Furthermore, within states the growth of state-chartered
banks was not identical across banks.

In almost all cases

(with the exception of the insured systems) the average size of
state-chartered banks increased from 1920 to 1929.

In some

extreme cases assets per bank doubled (Arizona, Illinois,
Michigan, Ohio, and Wyoming).
Interestingly, aggregate recovery of banking asset levels
and increases in average bank size are positively related
during this period (as exemplified by the experiences of
Arizona and Wyoming, in particular).

This suggests that as

small, rural banks failed they were not likely to be replaced
by similar institutions, but rather by larger banks.
(1985)

White

finds that the merger wave in banking from 1919 to 1933

was partly the result of the desire to move away from a system
of small, fragile unit banks.

While several factors could

account for variations across states in the extent of




34

consolidation (e.g., a reduction in the perceived desirability
of rural farm loans and a change in emphasis toward industry
located in cities and towns, in which larger unit banks
operate), in part this variation may reflect different
regulations across states, in particular laws governing branch
banking
In states that allowed branch banking, it should have been
easier to acquire small rural banks that failed or replace them
with new branches, because the cost (including risk) of
establishing branches was lower than that of opening a bank.^l
Chapman (1934, chapter XI) provides evidence of relatively high
growth of branching banks for the nation as a whole during the
1920s.

A thorough analysis of the relative growth of branching

banks and unit banks during the 1920s in states that permitted
branching would require a panel data study at the level of
individual banks, which is beyond the scope of this paper.
Instead, using available data, I examine the growth in the
number of branching banks and their branches at the state level
and link it to total banking growth, in number and total
assets.

I also report results using disaggregated data (at the

individual-bank level) for a few states where this is feasible.

Branch Banking and Banking System Recovery
Table 17 summarizes the data on the growth of the number
of total banks, branching banks, and branches of national and
state banks for 1924 (the earliest available data) and 1928




35

(the last disaggregated data available for the 1920s),
categorized according to state banking laws on branching, for
the 32 "agricultural-crisis" states.

The state-bank regulatory

regimes are divided into four groups: full free entry for
branching banks statewide, full free entry with locational
limitations on branches, limited (or zero) entry of new
branching banks but continuation of existing branching, and a
final category in which prohibitions kept branching from
developing.
Wyoming is an exceptional case in that it allowed
statewide branch banking, but no banks opened branches during
the 1920s.

Apparently, in Wyoming's mainly livestock-producing

hinterlands opportunities for diversification through branching
were limited (as contrasted to Arizona's economy in which
cotton, livestock, and copper all offered substantial
opportunities in rural areas), and profitable opportunities for
bank entry were concentrated in the major cities. As Woods
(1985, p. 101) points out, banking outside of major cities was
confined mainly to very small banks organized in rural areas to
provide financing for expansion to local groups of insider
entrepreneurs.

Of Wyoming's 113 non-national banks in 1920, 31

had a deposit base of under $100,000 (see Woods, 1985, p. 96) .
National banks often were permitted to maintain branches
in existence at the time of their conversion to national
charters, which explains why national banks operated branches
in some states.




In no states prior to 1927, however, did
36

national banks maintain significant branching systems.

Upon

passage of the McFadden Act (February 1927), limited national
bank branching was allowed in states that permitted branch
banking.

Even under the McFadden Act national banks were still

restricted to establishing branches within the "city, town or
village" of their main office.

Thus there is little cross-

sectional variation across states in national bank branching
during the 1920s.
Several interesting patterns are visible in Table 17.
Because of switching between national and state charters, it is
best to focus on branching within the states for national and
state banks as a whole.

Of the 18 states that allowed branches

to exist, only 3 saw a reduction in the number of total branch­
banking facilities from 1924 to 1928.

These reductions all

occurred in states that prohibited the establishment of new
branches, but allowed existing branches to be maintained
(Georgia, Minnesota, and Washington).

In all three cases, the

reduction is accounted for by the departure (failure or
closing) of a single b a n k . ^ 2

in all the other states that

allowed branching to continue, but prohibited the establishment
of new branches, the number of branching facilities remained
the same.

In states that allowed new branching, branching

facilities uniformly increased at a rapid rate, often as the
total number of banking facilities declined, and branching thus
came to comprise a much larger fraction of total banking
facilities.




37

Moreover, the recovery of total bank asset levels was
higher for systems that permitted growth in branch banking.
Arizona, Kentucky, Louisiana, Michigan, North Carolina, Ohio,
Tennessee, and Virginia all saw relatively high rates of asset
recovery in the late 1920s relative to other states.

These

were also the states that experienced the largest increases in
the average size of banks.

South Carolina was the only

exception to the rule, with negative asset growth in both
banking systems during this period.

Clearly, this exception

"proves the rule," as South Carolina witnessed a more than
doubling of its branch banking facilities from 1924 to 1929,
even though the combined growth of unit and branching banks was
negative.
More formally, in Table 18, I regress bank asset growth
from 1920 to 1926 and 1926 to 1930 on the same regressors used
in Table 16, with the addition of branching dummies for cityrestricted and out-of-city branching.

Out-of-city branching

includes the statewide branching systems, and Ohio, that
allowed limited out-of-city branching.

I also report

regressions using the change in average bank size as the
dependent variable.

While the few degrees of freedom in the

regressions recommends a cautious interpretation of the
results, the branching indicator variables were both relatively
large and statistically significant.

Indeed, branching

indicators have a larger, more significant, and more
persistent effect on total asset growth than deposit-insurance




38

indicators in the regression.

These results indicate that,

from the standpoint of long-run banking recovery, the
distinction between unit and branch banking was more important
than the distinction between insured and uninsured banking.
Deposit insurance mainly caused a retreat from the statechartered systems until the insurance fund was dissolved, after
which the state systems gradually recovered as well as other
unit banking systems.

In contrast, the effect of branching on

banking growth and average bank size increase with time.
These comparisons actually understate the difference in
growth between branching banks and independent unit banks,
because many unit banks operated as members of bank "chains."
The Federal Reserve, which collected data on "chain" banks,
distinguished chains from other banking conglomerates.

Chains

were defined as groups of corporately independent banks "under
centralized control. "^3

As was recognized at the time, chains

sometimes served as a "second best" substitute for branches in
states where branching was prohibited.

While banks in chains

were separate corporate entities, they imitated to a lesser
degree some of the advantageous features of branch banks.
First, chains of banks could reduce individual bank risk by
coordinating their response to crises and coinsuring as a
group.

Second, chains pooled resources and staffs to reduce

overhead expenses and improve account management procedures
(see Chapman, 1934, pp. 322-363).

The potential for chains to

allow member banks to diversify seems to have been more




39

limited, as the high failure rates of chains relative to
branching banks indicates.^4
As Table 19 shows, the freedom to branch was inversely
related to the prevalence of chain banking.

Table 19 reports

the number and proportion of chain banks in the state- and
national-chartered systems for our sample of 32 agriculturalcrisis states.

States with branching restrictions saw much

higher incidence of chain banking, and that incidence increased
with the extent of the branching prohibition.

Summary of Findings
The evidence on the aggregate growth, average size, and
membership patterns of banks during the 1920s indicates that
state banking systems can be usefully grouped into three
categories: states where deposit insurance made the system more
fragile, magnified the expansion in response to the
agricultural boom, and worsened the contraction during the
bust; other unit banking states with less drastic swings in
aggregate growth; and branch-banking systems (restricted, or
statewide) that managed to respond most successfully to the
challenges brought by the declining terms of trade in
agriculture.

IV. BANK FAILURE COSTS AND THE ROLE OF REGULATION
Aggregate data on numbers of banks and their assets over
time do not distinguish voluntary exits by banks from bank




40

failures.

In particular, it is conceivable that the decline in

insured banking was primarily the result of voluntary exit in
response to rising assessments once a few banks failed, in
conjunction with laws that permitted banks to switch charters.
If this were the case, skeptics of the failings of the insured
systems might argue that the prohibition of voluntary exit
would have been sufficient to make the systems viable.
Evidence on bank failures, and their costs, therefore,
provides a complement to the results reported in section III.
A study of bank failure propensities permits one to distinguish
exits from failures, and supplies further direct evidence on
the extent of risk taking during the boom across different
regulatory regimes.
ABA (1933), Calomiris (1989), and Thies and Gerlowski
(1989)

provide evidence that insured banks were more likely to

fail than national banks in the same state, uninsured state
banks in the same state, and uninsured state banks in other
states. While the within-state comparisons made by these
authors of the failure propensities of insured-state and
uninsured-state banks in Kansas (summarized below) is
compelling, the other evidence is less so.

Differences in

states' product specialization, and differences across states
in the relative agricultural risk exposure of national and
state banks (due to other regulatory differences between
national and state banks) must be controlled for if one wants
to isolate the role of deposit insurance regulation in




41

promoting risk taking.^5
Furthermore, the definitions of "bank failure" may differ
across these studies in ways that are not always clear.

In

analysing bank failures, I restrict attention to involuntary
liquidations of banks.

Sometimes banks suspended operations,

and reopened; other times banks were acquired by other
institutions; and, finally, banks could choose to close while
still solvent.

The withdrawal of a bank, therefore, may

reflect very different events with different social costs.
Suspensions, consolidations, and voluntary closings may have
had social costs as well -- consolidations and closings may
have reduced the supply of banking services in some areas, and
suspensions were disruptive to the payments system.

I focus on

failures because they offer a clearer index of the costs of the
crisis across states —
depositor losses —

forced permanent departure of banks and

and provide a clearer measure of the risk­

taking of banks, since closings, acquisitions, and suspensions
often had explanations other than bank insolvency.^®

I also

focus on average failure rates for several years, rather than
perform a year-by-year comparison across states.

Differences

in state closure rules (in particular, the long delay in
closing insolvent banks by the Nebraska Guaranty Fund)^7 argue
for this approach.
I

examine three dimensions of the failure "performance" of

banking systems: the rate of bank failure, the severity of bank
failure -- measured as the ratio of claims on failed banks to




42

their remaining resources (excluding payments by insurance
funds) -- and the efficiency of the bank-liquidation process,
with emphasis on the roles of deposit insurance and branching
regulations.

Bank Failure Rates
Table 20 provides data on average annual bank failure
rates, by state and type of banking system, for various sub­
periods from 1917 to 1929, for the sample of 32 agriculturalcrisis states.2®

These data echo the substantial variation in

economic fundamentals and banking system responses across
states and types of banks that were visible in earlier tables.
Clearly, the cotton belt and the grain-producing states
suffered disproportionately during the 1920s.

Table 20 shows

the pitfalls of using the difference between state and national
bank failure rates for a given state (as in Calomiris, 1989) as
a measure of the role of deposit insurance.

While it is true

that the difference between state and national bank annual
failure rates for 1921-1929 are greater for insured states than
for uninsured states on average (1.4 percent for compulsoryinsurance states, as compared to 1.0 percent for states without
deposit insurance), this difference is positive for most
states, presumably because of their smaller size and more
liberal real-estate lending regulations.
Similarly, state comparisons across state-chartered
systems reveal several cases where uninsured systems fared




43

worse than insured.

The difference in annual failure rates

between uninsured (2.26 percent) and insured (2.92 percent)
state-chartered banking systems for 1921-1929 on average is
0.68 percent, but by varying the definition of region -- a
control used in Thies and Gerlowski (1989) -- one could easily
conclude from such simple comparisons that insured statechartered banks had lower failure experiences than uninsured
state-chartered banks.

For example, one could define Texas and

Oklahoma to be in the same region as Arizona and New Mexico or
define Mississippi to be in the same region as Alabama,
Georgia, Louisiana, and South Carolina.
Regional distinctions, of course, are intended as rough
proxies for economic environments under which banking systems
operate.

Thus, rather than experiment with different

definitions of economic regions, I include measures of economic
environment directly in weighted-least-squares regressions to
capture the marginal effects of deposit insurance on bankfailure propensities.

i refrain from reporting these results

because I found that, depending on the precise mix of control
variables one uses, the measured impact of deposit insurance
(and the control variables) varied greatly and were typically
positive and insignificant.

In other words, given the few

degrees of freedom available, regression results seem unable to
deliver much information on the contribution of deposit
insurance to bank failure propensities.

The only robust

findings from this analysis were the strong positive




44

association between commercial failure rates and bank failure
rates, and the strong negative relation between average bank
size and bank failure rates.
Perhaps the best evidence of excess failure rates for
insured banks remains the simple comparison of failure
propensities of insured and uninsured state-chartered banks
operating in Kansas.^1

Kansas provides a unique "controlled

experiment" because it was the only state with a large number
both of insured and uninsured state-chartered banks.

The

annual failure rate for insured banks in Kansas from 1921 to
1924 (prior to the mass conversions of banks to uninsured
charters) is 1.90, compared to an annual failure rate of 0.67
percent for uninsured banks.
Bank Failure Severity for Insured and Uninsured Systems
It would be a mistake to place too much emphasis on bank
failure rates as indicators of the costliness of financial
crises.

Bank failures are discrete events; particularly severe

financial crises force many banks to cross the threshold of
failure.

For this reason, bank system performance may be

better gauged by the overall losses of depositors, rather than
the propensity to fail, which may show relatively little
variation.
Data exist with which to perform cross-state, cross-system
comparisons of insolvent banks' asset shortfalls in the 1920s
and thereby measure the average severity of bank failures
across states. Complete data for insured banking systems are




45

provided in FDIC (1956), but data for the rest of U.S. banking
systems are only available for banks whose liquidations were
completed by 1930 (see Data Appendix). As Table 21 shows, for
some state-chartered systems only a small percentage of
liquidations that occurred during the 1920s were processed in
time to be included in this sample.

The ratio of repayments to

total unsecured deposit claims from the limited sample in each
state is likely to be a biased indicator of the total sample;
for example, banks with higher losses might take longer to
liquidate.
Notwithstanding this problem, there is little room for
doubt that insolvent insured banks suffered worse asset
depreciation in the 1920s than state-chartered banks in other
states.

The rates of shortfall for insured state banks, were

among the highest in the country, as shown in Table 21.
Regional comparisons are particularly telling.

Consider the

difference between North and South Dakota's low ratios of
repayments from assets to total claims (17.2 and 24.1 percent,
respectively) and their neighbors' ratios: Montana (51.9),
Idaho (47.4), Wyoming (53.7), Colorado (68.1), and Minnesota
(48.2) . A comparison of insured banking in Nebraska (35.4)
with Iowa (53.6), Missouri (52.6), Colorado, and Wyoming is
similarly revealing.
Kansas, Oklahoma, Texas, and Mississippi showed ratios
more similar to the average experience of their neighbors.
Significantly, two of these were voluntary-insurance states,




46

and Texas' exceptionally high required capital ratio may have
played a role here, as well.
Oklahoma's compulsory insurance system lasted only until
1923, and thus should have had a relatively small influence on
failure propensity for the 1920s as a whole.

As current

critics of deposit insurance emphasize, much of the losses that
occur in an insured system reflect responses by banks to
adverse shocks that reduce bank capital and magnify the
incentives for risk taking (see Kane, 1988; and Calomiris and
Kahn, 1989).

By closing its system early in the 1920s Oklahoma

may have avoided this magnification of risk taking.
Mississippi had the lowest rate of asset shortfall of the
five compulsory-insurance states, as well as the lowest rate of
bank failure for that group by far for the period 1921-1929.
Mississippi's special experience may reflect, in part, the
circumstances of its creation.

The Mississippi deposit

insurance law was passed in response to the state banking
crisis of 1912-1913, induced by the destruction of cotton crops
in those years by the boll weevil.

The relatively low failure

rate and degree of asset shortfall in Mississippi during the
1920s may indicate simply that many of the most vulnerable
banks in that state had collapsed prior to the period of
deposit insurance coverage, leaving surviving banks that on
average were less likely to use deposit insurance protection to
promote high-risk agricultural expansion.

That is, larger,

more urban banks were more likely to survive the attack of the




47

boll weevil.

Entry by new banks seeking to take advantage of

deposit insurance was notoriously difficult in Mississippi, as
well, due to the strict chartering standards set by the state's
regulators.^2

Thus Mississippi seems to have avoided the

failure rates of the other compulsory systems mainly because
its insurance system was enacted after a major agricultural
depression, and because its regulators prevented the entry of
small rural unit banks that were so common in the other
insured states.

This view is consistent with the relatively

large average size of banks in 1918 and 1920 in Mississippi,
relative to its neighbors, or relative to other insured banking
systems (see Table 7).

Inefficient Bank Liquidation Procedures in Insured States
A final interesting difference between insured and
uninsured banking was the efficiency of the liquidation
procedures.

Delays in winding up the operations of banks

impose costs of illiquidity and forgone interest on
depositors, apart from the ultimate larger losses due to asset
shortfalls.

Delays in closing banks, or in final liquidation

of closed banks, also may afford insolvent bankers greater
opportunities for risk taking or fraudulent behavior.
On average, for the United States as a whole during the
1920s, it took 3 years and 11 months for state-bank
liquidations to be completed, and for national banks it took 4
years and 2 months.




In the five compulsory-insurance states
48

time delays for insured state banks were much longer than for
state banks in other states, and much longer than for national
banks in those states (see Table 22).

In Nebraska, state-

chartered banks that were liquidated before 1930 took an
average of 6 years and 4 months to be liquidated, compared to 4
years and 9 months for national banks•

In North and South

Dakota state-bank liquidation delays averaged 6 years and 3
months, and 5 years and 7 months, respectively, compared to 4
years, and 4 years and 8 months, for national banks in the
respective states.

In Oklahoma, delays averaged 5 years,

compared to 3 years and 8 months for national banks.
Voluntary-insurance systems showed roughly comparable average
delays to national banks operating within the same states, as
did virtually all other agricultural-crisis states.^3
What can explain this phenomenon?

Others have noted that

deposit insurance systems redeemed the losses of depositors
slowly and partially, owing in part to the limited resources of
the funds (see ABA, 1933; and FDIC, 1956), but these data
reveal that even the liquidation of failed banks was more
protracted in the insured systems than otherwise.

One

explanation for the inordinate delays is political.

Perhaps

solvent banks and bank regulators sought to delay insolvent
bank asset liquidation to limit the rate of increase of the
obligations of the guarantee funds.

The evidence of delayed

closure of banks, especially in Nebraska, is consistent with
this interpretation of delayed liquidation.




49

This is akin to

the FSLIC's recent policy of delaying the closure of insolvent
savings and loans, purportedly at the behest of members of
Congress or Savings and Loan owners themselves.^4

state

politicians of the 1920s may have acted similarly, and clearly
solvent banks had a motive in encouraging delays, as this would
have given them an opportunity to switch charters in
anticipation of increasing obligations and assessments.
Whether political motives or other factors explain delays in
closures and liquidations must await further historical
research into the process of bank liquidation in these states.

The Unusual Survivability of Branching Banks
In section III, I established that branch banking
flourished in response to the crisis of the 1920s in states
that allowed branching.

While it is likely that the physical

costs of entry of branches was lower than unit banks in many
cases, another dimension of the advantage to branching -- one
that was particularly noted by contemporaries in the 1920s -was that branching banks suffered lower risk of failure.
References to this phenomenon were quite common,
Cartinhour, 1931).

(e.g.,

The Congressional hearings of 1930 on

"Branch, Chain, and Group" provided data that allow some
quantification of the lower risks of branch banking in the U.S.
during the 1920s.

From 1921 to 1929, only 37 branching banks

operating 75 branches were liquidated.

More than two-thirds of

these banks operated a single branch, and no more than 6 of




50

them operated three or more branches.^5
In 1924 714 banks
operated 2,293 branches.

Thus only 112 of the 3,007 branch

banking facilities in existence in the middle of the decade, or
roughly 4 percent of branching facilities, failed over the
entire decade.
Of course, national comparisons can be misleading.
California and other states that were relatively prosperous
during this period account for a large percentage of branching
facilities.

In 1924, the 32 agricultural-crisis states

contained 1,312 of the 3,007 branch banking facilities.

But

even if all branching failures had been concentrated in these
states during the 1920s, the annual rate of branch-banking
facility failure would be only 0.85 percent.

This is a very

low rate of failure compared to those of state systems on the
whole.

Only four state-chartered systems had lower failure

rates than 0.85 —
Nevada —

Illinois, Michigan, Ohio, and

and none of these states was among those most

affected by the crisis; for example, they all had below-median
farm foreclosure rates (see Table 3).
In some cases, specific within-state comparisons are
possible.

In the states that prohibited new branching from

1924 to 1928, but allowed branching banks to continue to
operate branching (Alabama, Arkansas, Indiana, Minnesota,
Nebraska, Washington, and Wisconsin), branch-bank failures can
be derived from the difference between the number of branches
in operation in 1928 and the number in operation in




51

1924.

in

this sample of seven states, 28 branching banks operated 58
branches in 1924; and 26 branching banks operated 53 branches
in 1928, for a remarkably low annual failure rate (for all
facilities) of 0.02 percent.
Finally, for other states, branch-bank failure experiences
can be gleaned from data on bank "disappearances," using The
Bankers Encyclopedia to trace the presence or absence of banks
from 1920 to 1929.

In all cases, a careful review of entries

revealed whether disappearances were due to acquisitions or to
closings.

I traced the entries for the branching banks of

three states over this period: Arizona, Mississippi, and South
Carolina.

These states were chosen because they experienced

high rates of bank failure, had a small number of branching
banks (making data collection easier), and because branching
banks in these states operated branches mainly outside their
home city.

In Mississippi, all 24 branches in operation in

1920 were located outside their banks' home cities.

The same

was true of Arizona's 20 branches in operation in 1920.

In

South Carolina, 13 out of 15 branches operated outside the home
city. These banks, therefore, provide a useful measure of the
potential advantages of statewide branching during a crisis.
Arizona permitted statewide branching throughout the
period.

In Arizona in 1920, 8 banks operated 20 branches.

By

1929, 2 of these (each operating one branch) had been acquired
by larger branching banks.

One of the branching banks

(operating one branch) failed.




In the interim, three new
52

branching banks had entered, which explains the stability in
the total number of branch banks (see Table 17).

The average

annual failure rate for total branching facilities, therefore,
was 1.6 percent for 1921-1929, compared to 4.3 percent for the
state-chartered banks as a whole.
Mississippi had allowed branching outside home cities, but
later prohibited branching, except for the establishment of
limited agency facilities within home cities.

Nevertheless,

the existing statewide branches were permitted to continue
operating.

During the 1920s none of the 10 branching banks

operating 24 branches failed, while the average annual failure
rate for state-chartered banks as a whole was 1.4 percent.
In South Carolina from 1920 to 1929, 4 out of 8 branching
banks in operation in 1920 closed, but all of these were banks
that operated a single branch, and 2 of the 4 operated branches
within their home city.

Thus of the 23 towns or cities in

which branch banking facilities were located, 19 retained their
branch-banking facilities.

This is important since the lack of

available banking facilities in thinly populated areas (where
virtually all branches were located in Arizona, Mississippi,
and South Carolina) increases transactions costs in those
locations and can inhibit the flow of capital to worthy
enterprises located there.

The overall failure rate of

existing branching facilities in South Carolina was 2.9
percent, compared to a rate of 4.9 percent for all statechartered banks.




53

Entry into branch banking was especially strong in South
Carolina, and entrants apparently learned the importance of
establishing multiple branches.

Two new entrants -- The

Peoples Bank of South Carolina and the South Carolina Savings
Bank -- entered during the 1920s and established 18 and 9
branches, respectively, operating outside their home cities.
The lessons of the high survival rates of branching banks
during the crisis apparently were not lost on bankers. As
Table 17 shows, and these examples confirm, in states where
branching was allowed, it flourished and increasingly took the
form of multi-branch banks, where that was allowed.

Four of

the eight states that had enacted deposit insurance legislation
prior to the 1920s passed laws in the aftermath of the crises
of the 1920s and 1930s allowing branching.

By 1939, North

Dakota had provided for limited branching, and Mississippi had
reversed its previous prohibition on new branches to allow
limited branching as well.

South Dakota and Washington

permitted full statewide branching.

For the U.S. as a whole,

19 states allowed full branch banking, and 17 allowed limited
branching, compared to 12 statewide and 6 limited branching
systems in operation in 1924.37
Unfortunately, policymakers in many agricultural unit
banking states did not change their approach to branch banking
following the debacle of the 1920s and 1930s.

Thus the 1980s

saw a repeat of the same patterns of high unit bank failure
rate in states hit by the agricultural crisis of 1980-1985.




54

As

in the earlier period, branching banks weathered the storm far
better than unit banks.

In California, for example, despite

relatively high farm-loan delinquency rates and loan chargeoffs, only one bank failed during the crisis (see Calomiris,
Hubbard, and Stock, 1986, p. 469).

V. LESSONS FOR POLICY IN PRICE-SENSITIVE LDCs
It has been widely known that deposit insurance systems
enacted in the 1920s failed ex post to offer sufficient and
timely protection to depositors, or the payments system more
generally.

In this paper I have shown that deposit insurance

created costs as well.

It provided incentives for excess risk

taking by banks and hampered banking system recovery from the
agricultural crisis because of the costs to solvent banks of
remaining in the insured banking system.

The excessive growth

of the halycon days of 1914-1920 was matched by the excessive
failures of banks and declines in banking operations of insured
states in response to the crisis.
Voluntary insurance systems provided less coverage than
insured systems.

In the extreme case of Washington's free-exit

policy, there was virtually no insurance protection.

The

positive aspect of the failed voluntary plans, however, was
that the limits on depositor protection also limited the cross­
subsidization of risk among banks.

This explains the

differences between the observed responses to voluntary and
compulsory insurance.




55

During the boom voluntary-insurance systems grew less than
compulsory-insurance systems, but more than did unit-banking
state systems without insurance plans. Voluntary-insurance
states were also intermediate cases with respect to failure
rates and liquidation delays.

Branching banks suffered much

lower risks of failures and enjoyed disproportionately high
rates of growth and entry during the 1920s, relative to unit
banks, in states that permitted branching, especially those
that allowed branching outside the home city of the bank.

Thus

from the standpoint of desirability of outcomes during the
1920s the various regulatory regimes could be ranked (in
descending order) as follows:

full statewide branching,

limited branching, uninsured unit banking, voluntary-insurance
unit banking, and compulsory-insurance unit banking.®®
The contrast between the effects of branch-banking
regulations and deposit-insurance regulations is ironic, since
the two regulatory choices were viewed as alternative solutions
to the problem of providing banking-system stability, without
sacrificing banking services in remote areas, during the years
of active bank regulatory reform after the Panic of 1907
(White, 1982 and 1983).

The history of the 1920s reveals

that branching and deposit guarantee in fact had opposite
effects with respect to generating banking stability.

From

this perspective, an added cost of deposit insurance
legislation was that it was incorrectly perceived as an
alternative to branch banking, and thereby helped to perpetuate




56

unit banking.
Proponents of deposit insurance, however, might argue that
it was the manner in which deposit insurance was implemented,
not insurance per se, that caused systemic collapse in the
1920s.

They might argue that higher capital requirements,

better supervision, risk-based insurance premia, and government
financing of the insurance fund might have produced a better
result.

Clearly with high enough capital requirements and

sufficiently strict entry barriers (as in Mississippi), the
moral hazard and adverse selection problems of deposit
insurance will be reduced and may disappear, but at the expense
of higher financing costs to banks, and less entry of banking
into peripheral areas.

Elsewhere (Calomiris, 1989) I have

argued that a more successful, efficient, and historically
proven reform of deposit insurance would be to move to a
mutual-guarantee system of self-regulating branching banks, in
which the governments' main role would be to define membership
criteria for mutually insuring groups of banks.

Such systems

were extraordinarily successful in dealing with financial
panics during the pre-Civil War years in the U.S., while
providing access to affordable loans in peripheral areas.
Unlike virtually all government deposit insurance regulators,
banks regulated and monitored one another effectively,
discovered and corrected unsound banking practices quickly, and
kept the payments system operating smoothly in the face of
financial crises.^




Evidence of similarly successful self­
57

regulating systems in other countries is provided in Bordo and
Schwartz (1989) and Pope (1989).
A possible objection to this approach is the difficulty of
banks as a group to insure themselves against very large
disturbances because of limited aggregate banking capital.

In

such circumstances, a systemic collapse could occur.
Furthermore, given this possibility it might be impossible for
the government to commit credibly to allowing the banking
system to fail. Knowledge of this implicit guarantee may
provide incentives for risk taking.
I have two responses to this objection.

First, if an

economy is prone to shocks of this magnitude it may be that
deposit insurance is inadvisable altogether.

Why should not

banking capital in aggregate be allowed to fall drastically at
a time when the investment opportunities of an economy have
been so devastated?

In the presence of free entry and branch

banking, one would expect new banks or branches to arise to
take the place of failed ones, as in Arizona and South Carolina
in the 1920s.

Furthermore it seems inadvisable for an economy

so devastated by a terms-of-trade shock to attempt a bankingsystem rescue, particularly in a developing economy that relies
on indirect (often financial) taxation to finance such bail­
outs .

It might be more advisable to act in advance to

subsidize new industries with an eye toward diversifying the
economy, rather than focus on banking system solvency as a
panacea.




The fundamental problem of such an economy, after
58

all, is not its financial system, but its economic base.
My second response to the supposed need for governmentfinanced and government-regulated deposit insurance is an
empirical one.

In most cases during the 1920s aggregate

banking capital within each state would have been sufficient to
repay losses to depositors of failing institutions -- and thus
mutual-guarantee, self-regulating systems operating even at the
state level would have been feasible.
Table 23 reports total deposits of suspended banks
(deposits of failed banks are not available) aggregated by
state from 1921 to 1929 for national and state banks in the 13
states with the largest total bank failure rates and provides
estimates of the total shortfall of assets in failed banks of
each type.

A rough indication of the rate of asset shortfall

for national- and state-chartered banks that failed in these
states can be derived from Table 21, although as already noted
these data are imperfect indicators.

To obtain an estimate of

total asset shortfalls I multiply the total deposits of
suspended banks by the shortfall rate from Table 21 (one minus
the repayment rate) and multiply this product by the ratio of
failed banks to suspended banks.

As Table 23 shows, in many

states, the number of bank suspensions far exceeded the number
of bank failures, because banks were sometimes reopened or
acquired rather than being placed in receivership.

A

comparison of the average size of failed banks (estimated using
data on completed liquidations) and average size of suspended




59

banks revealed that larger banks were more likely to avoid
liquidation after suspension.

Thus I adjusted for the average

size difference between suspended and liquidated banks in
estimating the total asset shortfalls.

To summarize, the

estimated shortfall of assets (the difference between depositor
claims and receipts from asset liquidation) is given by the
product of four terms: total deposits of suspended banks, the
ratio of liquidations to suspensions, the shortfall ratio
(estimated using data from completed liquidations), and the
ratio of the average size of liquidated banks to the average
size of suspending banks (again, estimated using data from
completed liquidations).
These estimates appear in Table 23 for state- and
national-chartered banks.

The level of bank capital plus

surplus (bank equity) of solvent banks in 1930 is provided for
comparison.

Only 3 of the 13 states show a ratio of shortfall

to bank equity approaching or above unity: Nebraska, North
Dakota, and South Dakota.

For all other states banks as a

whole would have had sufficient capital to support failing
banks.

The national banking failures in all the states could

have been absorbed by surviving national banks, and statechartered systems could have covered losses of failed banks in
every state except Nebraska, North Dakota, and South Dakota.
These three state systems, however, suffered bank losses
several times the size of remaining state banks' equity.
Significantly, these were the only states that had compulsory




60

insurance for most of the 1920s (this criterion excludes
Oklahoma), and that also allowed substantial entry by new banks
(this criterion excludes Mississippi).

These states had

foreclosure rate and land depreciation experiences comparable
to several other states (see Table 3) — notably Montana,
Georgia, and South Carolina -- but none of these other states'
state-chartered systems approached the banking losses relative
to remaining equity of the three long-lived, compulsoryinsurance systems.
This evidence supports the evidence from balance sheet
data and the evidence on failure rates and failure severity
reported above.

Moreover, it supports the argument that,

absent compulsory deposit insurance (and free entry), the
fundamental disturbances experienced in these states would have
had very different consequences for their banking systems.

If

statewide branch banking had been permitted within these
states, bank failures would have been even lower, and the entry
of banking capital during the 1920s would have been higher.
Moreover, in a mutual-liability, self-regulating system of
banks (like that of three states in the pre-Civil War era) bank
risk, taking would have been substantially circumscribed by
self-imposed regulations and vigorous supervision of other
banks.
Of course, no degree of regulatory wisdom could, or
should, have made the 1920s a profitable time for banks in
agricultural regions affected by drastic declines in prices and




61

land values.
inevitable.

In the face of these shocks, some failures were
What regulation could have done, but did not do,

was make the system as a whole less susceptible to shocks and
more resilient in its response to failures.




62

NOTES
1. For a discussion of the behavior of Southern branching
banks during the Panic of 1837 and the Panic of 1857, see
Calomiris and Schweikart (1988).
2. Of course, there will still be a need for a properly
designed monetary authority and lender of last resort to manage
the money supply, but this is separate from the question of
insuring banks.
3. Of course, any government transfer program must be
financed somehow, and this gives rise to additional costs.
Raising revenue, either through direct taxation or money
creation, can have important adverse allocative consequences.
Indeed, as McKinnon (1973, 1988) and others (see Fry, 1988 for
a review) point out, in less-developed economies, the need to
raise revenue often places a disproportional burden on the
banking system. Reserve requirements and mandated loan
subsidies are among the means to tax financial intermediaries.
The ease of enforcing these taxes, and their indirect nature
presumably have made them a desirable means of raising funds
for governments with little power to impose or enforce direct
taxation. The fact that governments in less-developed
economies need to rely on banks as a source of finance may
limit the ability of the government to bail out banks. I
return to this point in the concluding section of the paper.
4. As White (1983) has shown, these points are related. Banks
wishing to locate in rural areas were more likely to choose a
state charter, presumably because of the less restrictive
provisions for making loans on agricultural real estate.
5. The sector-specific crisis of the 1920s was followed by
the general Depression of the early 1930s. The dust storms of
1934-1935 kept agriculture from sharing in the general
recovery of 1933-1937. These factors combined to produce a
period of agricultural depression that lasted for some fifteen
years.
6.

Alston (1983), p. 886.

7. Foreclosure data are provided in Table 3. These data are
not identical to those reported in Alston (1983), for two
reasons. First, 1928 rather than 1930 is used as a benchmark
for the number of farms operating from 1926 to 1930. Second,
and more important, Alston only subtracted "croppers" from the
total number of farms to estimate the number of farms at risk
of foreclosure; my estimates subtract all farms operated by
tenants, not only "croppers." This alternative definition is




63

meant to capture better the relevant population of farmers
subject to foreclosure risk, assuming that tenant-run farms
typically are owned by individuals who operate their own farms,
as well.
8. It is also important to note that the threat to the
financial viability of farms and farm lenders from a given
decline in income or wealth depends in a non-linear fashion on
the rapidity of the decline and its persistence. Two
consecutive years of drastic price and income reductions may
produce far more bankruptcies than a similar decline amidst
intervening good years, or a similar overall decline spread
over a longer period. This is especially true when a rapid
decline follows a boom period -- farm leverage, having first
been increased by borrowing during the boom becomes further
increased by reductions in farm values during the bust,
precisely at a time when the cash-flow necessary to meet debt
service requirements is reduced. For evidence on the
importance of such non-linearities see Rucker and Alston
(1987).
9.

See Goldenweiser et al. (1932), vol.5, pp. 205-207.

10. See, for example, the discussion of large urban bank
reactions to deposit insurance in cities such as Chicago and
Philadelphia in White (1983), pp. 191-197.
11. Specifically, in Oklahoma and Kansas interest rates were
limited to 3 percent; in Texas deposits bearing any interest
would be exempt from insurance; in Mississippi and South
Dakota interest rates were limited to 4 and 5 percent,
respectively; and in North Dakota and Washington interest rate
limits were set by the Guaranty Boards. Summary tables of
these and other regulations are provided in White (1983, pp.
210-11) and Calomiris (1989, p. 18) .
12. Evidence of this phenomenon can be found in numerous
historical studies of the operations of bankers under deposit
insurance. For example, see Robb (1921).
13. In Oklahoma and Kansas, trusts were not admitted to the
insured system, which further discouraged large urban banks
from joining.
14. Oklahoma's first bank failure, that of the Columbia Bank
and Trust, was a clear case of speculative expansion through
loans to the oil firms owned by the banker, W. L. Norton. For
details, see Robb (1921), pp. 50-53.




15. See Fenstermaker et al. (1984) and Schweikart
(1987) .
64

16. The data in Table 12 are end-of-year, unlike the other
tables which are end-of-June. Thus, the peak in Table 12
occurs in 1919, rather than 1920.
17. For the 48 contiguous states the correlation between the
ratio of capital to assets and the average size of banks is
strongly negative. For state-chartered banks the correlation
in 1920 is -0.47 (significantly different from zero at the 99
percent confidence level); for national banks the correlation
in 1920 is -0.43 (significant at the 97 percent confidence level).
18.

See FDIC (1956), pp. 55-58.

19. Some of this exceptionally high banking growth in these
states reflects favorable economic fundamentals. As Table 1
shows, livestock prices rose rapidly in the late 1920s relative
to grain prices; thus livestock-dependent states like Wyoming,
Idaho, and Arizona should have seen more banking recovery. In
regression results that follow, I control for economic
environment to isolate the role of regulatory regimes in
promoting banking growth.
20. Lee Alston has suggested to me that the increased use of
automobiles may have permitted greater bank consolidation, as
well, by reducing the need for banks to be located in thinly
populated areas.
21. The reduced riskiness of branch, as opposed to unit, banks
is established in section IV, where I show that branching banks
were less likely to fail during the 1920s than unit banks. See
also Cartinhour (1931), Schweikart and Doti (1989, chapter
III), and White (1983), pp. 218-219.
22. In Georgia, one of the largest banks in the state,
operating 30 branches, failed. According to Cartinhour (1931,
p. 307), the cause of this failure was "poor management."
23. The Federal Reserve's agents used their own judgment in
determining whether banks under a single holding company operated
under centralized control. While they attempted to provide an
exhaustive survey of bank practices, sometimes the agents found
that "neither the power to exercise such control nor the amount of
control actually exercised [could] be determined." See Board of
Governors (Dec. 1929), p. 766.
24. Data on chain bank failures have not been collected in a
consistent or thorough manner, but evidence reported in Chapman
(1934), and other examples of the collapse of large chains
indicates that unit banks belonging to chains were not
insulated from shocks as were branch banks. The failure rates
of branching banks are discussed in section IV.




65

25. Thies and Gerlowski (1989) provide a detailed discussion
of the Oklahoma experience, and describe regression results
showing that insured state systems had a 0.7 percent higher
propensity to fail on average than uninsured state-chartered
systems, for the period 1921-1929. A separate regression for
national banks found no significant difference for national
banks in the insured states. While the authors do control for
"time, region, and urbanization" (specific results and
explanation of data are not provided), this is insufficient to
capture differences across states in fundamental disturbances.
26. The distinction between failures and suspensions is
empirically important. Their incidences often differed
greatly, and the fraction of suspended banks that reopened
differed across states and chartering systems. A crosssectional analysis of these differences remains a topic for
future research. Thies and Gerlowski (1989) seem to have used
suspensions as their measure of bank failures.
27.

See FDIC (1956), p. 69

28. These are calculated using the banks in existence
immediately prior to the period of failure as a scale variable
(denominator) in the calculation. As noted above, insured
banks sought to avoid rising assessments, and converted to
national charters (as shown in Table 17). This avoids
exaggeration of failure rates due to voluntary exit by banks
that arises when the average number of banks in existence over
the whole period is used instead as the denominator. Using
either measure there is an adverse selection problem to
consider in measuring failure rates of different systems within
the same state. Early failures in the insured system could
lead insured banks to exit to the other available systems, and
thereby raise the subsequent observed failure rates for
national and uninsured state banks. This means that observed
differences in failure propensity provide a fortiori evidence
of greater riskiness of insured banks. Empirical evidence,
however, indicates that the movement of banks from one system
to another did not have an important effect on bank failure
rates. For example, compare failure rates for national and
state banks reported in Table 21 for the periods 1921-1924 and
1925-1929 for Kansas, North Dakota, Oklahoma, Mississippi, and
Texas -- all states with a substantial rate of conversion from
state to national charters. In two cases (Mississippi and
Oklahoma), national bank failure rates fell in the later
period; in the other three cases, they rose slightly.
29. Weighted least squares is the appropriate regression
technique in circumstances where aggregate failure rates are
compared across different samples. I used the log-odds ratio
(the log of p/(1-p)) as the dependent variable in the




66

regressions to control for truncation bias, where p is the
probability of failing, measured by the proportion of banks
failing. For a more complete description of the weightedleast-squares technique and its applicability to this case, see
Maddala (1984), pp. 28-30.
30. The variations I experimented with included: whether to
include Mississippi with the other compulsory-insurance states
(given its stricter entry requirements, discussed below);
whether to pool national- and state-chartered banks, estimate
them separately, or allow their coefficients to differ within a
pooled regression; whether to include the ratio of capital to
assets and the average size of banks in the regressions; and
whether to use commercial failures, real-estate loans, and land
price declines, by themselves, or interacted with farmpopulation proportion and bank real estate loan holdings, as
control variables.
31. See also ABA, 1933; Calomiris, 1989; and Thies and
Gerlowski, 1989. The inability to separate unincorporated and
incorporated state bank failures in Texas and Washington makes
a similar comparison impossible for those states. Also, the
small number of uninsured banks in Texas, and the short
duration of insurance in Washington make such comparisons less
interesting.
32. ABA (1933), p. 22 and Robb (1921), pp. 165-170 argue that
Mississippi maintained exceptionally high standards for
admission of new banks. For example, ABA (1933) writes that
"the banking authorities in Mississippi had full discretion in
the matter of granting new charters and used it liberally in
refusing permission for unneeded banks or to unqualified
promoters to open new institutions."
33.

For sources see Data Appendix.

34. For a discussion of the costliness of these delays in
liquidating Savings and Loans see Barth et al. (1989).
35.

U.S. House of Representatives (1930), volume I, p. 462.

36. Georgia is not part of this group because it prohibited
new branch banking only in August 1927.
37.

See Chapman and Westerfield (1942), pp. 126-130.

38. Note that I am not arguing that insurance systems should
allow voluntary exit. I would argue, however, that since none of
the insurance systems succeeded in providing payments system
protection, voluntary insurance was superior to compulsory
insurance in the 1920s because it engendered less loss.




67

39. Not only does branching lead to a, more stable banking
system; it also increases the ability of banks to meet the
banking needs of peripheral areas. Using current county-level
data from the U.S., Evanoff (1988) shows that branch banks
provide a far superior means of servicing remote areas than
unit banks. Holding demographic factors constant, branching
increases the number of banking offices per square mile by 65
percent.
40. Ideally, such a system would allow branching, as well. In
the absence of freedom to branch the large number of unit banks
creates a problem, as noted in Calomiris (1989). For mutual
guarantee systems to be effective they must be small enough to
make interbank monitoring worthwhile to individual banks. Systems
of hundreds of mutually liable banks entail trivially small
marginal gains to monitoring the behavior of another bank. An
alternative would be separate smaller groups of mutually liable
unit banks. A second problem that arises in either the branching
or unit banking versions of the mutual-guarantee system is the
potential for banks to abuse their self-regulatory power to
inhibit competition. To prevent this, the government should
create more than one group of banks, and define group membership
in a manner than encourages inter-group competition. For example,
in a unit-banking mutual-guarantee system (where local monopolies
may arise) groups should overlap geographically.




68

DATA APPENDIX

Income and Price Data
Data on indices of gross income by type of farm product
reported in Table 1 are taken from Strauss and Bean (1940),
p. 31.

Data on income —

farm and non-farm, gross and net —

and farm and non-farm population are taken from Leven (1925),
pp. 192-209, 259.

The state-specific crop price index is

defined as the relative price in 1924 of the bundle of crops
sold in 1919.

These data are reported in U.S. Department of

Commerce (1927), passim.

Data on the value of crops sold, by

state, was compiled by the Bureau of Agricultural Economics,
Department of Agriculture, and reported in U.S. Department of
Commerce, Statistical Abstract of the United States, various
years.

Farm Land Values. Mortgages, and Foreclosures
Data on farm real estate values per acre, total real estate
value, and amount of farm mortgage debt are provided in Clifton
and Crowley (1973).

Farm foreclosure data are from Stauber

(1931).

GNP Deflator Estimates
Alternative annual estimates of the GNP deflator, reported in
Table 4, are from Balke and Gordon (1989) and Romer (1989) .




69

Branch and Chain Banking
Data on state branching regulations, numbers of branch banks
and their branches, and banking chains are taken from Board of
Governors (1924, 1926, 1927, Feb. 1929, Dec. 1929).

Bank Balance Sheet Data
Bank balance sheet data, and total numbers of banks,
disaggregated by state and by type of charter are taken from
Board of Governors (1959), and —

for insured banking systems--

from FDIC (1956), pp. 66-67.

Locations and Survival of Individual Banks
Data for individual banks, and bank locations, are taken from
Bankers Encyclopedia Co., various years.

Numbers of Bank Liquidations
Liquidations of national banks are reported in the Annual
Report of the Comptroller of the Currency.

State-bank

liquidations for each state were published in the Comptroller's
Annual Report. as well.

The definition of banks employed in

Board of Governors (1959) is used to construct state-level
series for failed "state" banks.

This definition includes

trusts and unincorporated banks, as well as narrowly defined
state-chartered banking corporations.

It is not possible to

derive consistent series of narrowly defined state-chartered
bank balance sheet or failure data using these sources.




70

Charter Switching
Data on bank charter switching are taken from Board of
Governors (1937), pp. 1087-1122.

Business Failures
Business failures and number of solvent enterprises for each
state are reported in U.S. Department of Commerce, Statistical
Abstract of the United States.

Number and Deposits of Suspending Banks
The number and deposits of state and national bank suspensions
are reported in Board of Governors (1943), pp. 286-291.

These

are used to derive the average size of suspended banks in Table
23.

Data on Liquidated Banks
Data used in Tables 21-23 on the number, deposits, losses, and
time taken to liquidate banks for which liquidations had been
completed by 1930 are reported in Goldenweiser et al. (1932),
vol. 5, pp. 191-207.




71

REFERENCES
Alston, Lee J., "Farm Foreclosures in the United States During
the Interwar Period," Journal of Economic History, vol. 43,
December 1983.
American Bankers' Association, The Guaranty of Bank Deposits.
New York, 1933.
Balke, Nathan S. and Gordon, Robert J., "The Estimation of Prewar
Gross National Product: Methodology and New Evidence,"
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 97, February 1989.
Bankers Encyclopedia Co., The Bankers Encyclopedia. New York,
semi-annual.
Barth, James R., Bartholomew, Philip F., and Labich, Carol J.,
"Moral Hazard and the Thrift Crisis: An Analysis of 1988
Resolutions," Research Paper No. 160, Federal Home Loan Bank
Board, May 1989.
Bernanke, Ben S., "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in
the Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic
Review, vol. 73, June 1983.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, All Bank
Statistics. Washington D.C., 1959.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Banking and
Monetary Statistics. Washington D.C., 1943.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Changes in the
Number of National and State Banks During 1921-1936,"
Federal Reserve Bulletin. November 1937.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Branch Banking
in the United States," Federal Reserve Bulletin.
December 1924.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Branch Banking
in the United States," Federal Reserve Bulletin. June 1926.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Branch Banking
Developments June 30, 1928," Federal Reserve Bulletin.
February 1929.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Branch and
Chain Banking Developments: 1929," Federal Reserve Bulletin.
December 1929.




72

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "McFadden Bill
Now Law," Federal Reserve Bulletin, March 1927.
Bordo, Michael D. and Schwartz, Anna J., "The Performance and
Stability of Banking Systems Under 'Self-Regulation': Theory
and Evidence," Unpublished manuscript, 1989.
Brock, Philip L., "The Transmission of Terms of Trade Shocks in
Latin America," Unpublished manuscript, Duke University,
November 1988.
Calomiris, Charles W., "Deposit Insurance: Lessons from the
Record," Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, May/June 1989.
Calomiris, Charles W., Hubbard, R. Glenn, and Stock, James H.,
"The Farm Debt Crisis and Public Policy," Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, vol. 2, 1986.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Kahn, Charles M., "The Role of
Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements,"
Unpublished manuscript, Northwestern University, 1988.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Kahn, Charles M., "Interbank Monitoring
as Seignorage Sharing: The Suffolk System," Northwestern
University, 1989.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Schweikart, Larry, "Was the South
Backward?: North-South Differences in Antebellum Banking
During Crisis and Normalcy," Unpublished manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1988.
Cannon, James G., Clearing Houses. Washington D.C., 1910.
Cartinhour, Gaines T., Branch, Group, and Chain Banking. New York,
1931.
Chapman, John M., Concentration of Banking. New York, 1934.
Chapman John M. and Westerfield, Ray B., Branch Banking; Its
Historical and Theoretical Position in America and Abroad.
New York, 1942.
Clifton, Ivery D. and Crowley, William D., Jr., "Farm Real Estate
Historical Series Data: 1850-1970," U.S. Department of
Agriculture, Economic Research Service, June 1973.
Comptroller of the Currency, Annual Report. Washington D.C.,
various years.




73

Cooke, Thorton, "The Insurance of Bank Deposits in the West," in
George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies.
Washington D.C., 1910.
Evanoff, Douglas D., "Branch Banking and Service Accessibility,"
Journal of Money. Credit and Banking, vol. 20, May 1988.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Annual Report.
Washington D.C., 1956.
Fenstermaker, J. Van, Filer, J.E., and Herren, R.S.,
"Money
Statistics of New England, 1785-1837," Journal of Economic
History. June 1984.
Fry, Maxwell, Money. Interest, and Banking in Economic
Development. 1988.
Goldenweiser, E.A., et al., Bank Suspensions in the United States.
1892-1931. Material prepared for the information of the
Federal Reserve System by the Federal Reserve Committee on
Branch, Group, and Chain Banking, 1932.
Gorton, Gary, "Clearing Houses and the Origin of Central Banking
in the U.S.," The Wharton School, 1985.
Gorton, Gary, "Self-Regulating Banking Coalitions," The Wharton
School, 1989.
Kane, Edward J., "How Incentive-Incompatible Deposit-insurance
Funds Fail," Unpublished manuscript, Ohio State University,
1988.
Kareken, John H. and Wallace, Neil, "Deposit Insurance and Bank
Regulation," Journal of Business. July 1978.
Leven, Maurice, Income in the Various States: Its Sources and
Distribution. 1919. 1920. and 1921. New York, 1925.
Maddala, G.S., Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in
Econometrics. London, 1984.
McKinnon, Ronald I., Money and Capital in Economic Development
Washington D.C., 1973.
McKinnon, Ronald I., "Financial Liberalization and Economic
Development: A Reassessment of Interest-Rate Policies in
Asia and Latin America," International Center for Economic
Growth, Occasional Paper No. 6, 1988.
Pope, David, "Free Banking in Australia Before World War I,"
Unpublished manuscript, 1989.




74

Robb, Thomas B.f The Guaranty of Bank Deposits, New York, 1921.
Romer, Christina D., "The Prewar Business Cycle Reconsidered: New
Estimates of Gross National Product, 1869-1908," Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 97, February 1989.
Rucker, Randal R. and Alston, Lee J., "Farm Failures and Government
Intervention: A Case Study of the 1930s," American Economic
Review, vol. 77, September 1987.
Stock, James H., "Real Estate Mortgages, Foreclosures, and
Midwestern Agrarian Unrest, 1865-1920," Journal of Economic
History, vol. 43, March 1984.
Schweikart, Larry, Banking in the American South. Baton Rouge,
1987.
Schweikart, Larry, and Doti, Lynne Pierson, Banking in the
American West from Gold Rush to Deregulation. Unpublished
Manuscript, University of Dayton, 1989.
Stauber, B.R., "The Farm Real Estate Situation," U.S. Department
of Agriculture, Circular No. 209, Washington D.C., December
1931.
Strauss, Frederick, and Bean, Louis H., "Gross Farm Income and
Indices of Farm Production and Prices in the United States,
1869-1937," Technical Bulletin No. 703, U.S. Department of
Agriculture, December 1940.
Thies, Clifford F., and Gerlowski, Daniel A., "Deposit Insurance:
A History of Failure," Cato Journal, vol. 8, Winter 1989.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Statistical Abstract of the United
States. Washington D.C., various years.
U.S. Department of Commerce, United States Census of Agriculture.
1925. Washington D.C., 1927.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Fifteenth Census of the United
States. Washington D.C., 1932.
U.S. House of Representatives, "Branch, Chain, and Group Banking,"
Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, 71st
Congress, Second Session (1930).
White, Eugene N., "The Political Economy of Bank Regulation,"
Journal of Economic History. March 1982.
White, Eugene N., The Regulation and Reform of the American
Banking System. 1900-1929. Princeton, 1983.




75

White, Eugene N., "The Merger Movement in Banking, 1919-1933,"
Journal of Economic History, vol. 45, June 1985.
Woods, L. Milton, Sometimes the Books Froze: Wyoming's Economy
and Its Banks. Boulder, 1985.




76




Table 1

Indices of gross Income, from various groups of farm products and from total farm production, crop years [1909-13=100]

Year

12 important
crops1

Staple
food-stuffs2

Fruits3

Dairy products,
chickens, and
eggs

Textile raw
materia1s4

Meat animals
slaughter and
export of
live cattles

Meat animals
adjusted for
for changes
in inventory
values

Total farm
production
adjusted for
changes in
inventory
Total farm
values of
production_ meat anijrals

1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929

99.8
97.6
102.4
101.3
102.4
112.1
143.3
220.3
239.5
269.4
177.5
109.6
132.9
150.2
167.9
167.9
142.4
156.6
147.0
143.7

93.2
97.7
101.0
99.6
131.3
146.5
154.6
222.2
284.2
326.2
252.7
150.7
140.5
127.3
162.0
176.4
176.8
177.3
144.9
159.7

101.6
106.8
108.5
102.4
109.0
117.7
126.0
147.3
189.2
260.7
269.4
183.5
222.3
203.1
222.8
223.6
231.5
220.1
221.0
233.6

100.3
88.7
101.5
103.9
105.5
104.5
117.1
158.6
191.7
223.1
241.6
173.8
167.0
189.4
191.3
211.9
223.8
223.6
234.9
245.0

105.3
96.0
99.5
110.0
77.0
85.9
134.3
201.6
231.9
255.4
136.5
84.7
135.6
179.2
195.4
198.8
145.6
167.6
170.6
161.7

99.7
89.9
95.2
107.7
107.5
104.4
129.0
180.8
242.7
239.0
186.6
116.4
129.1
132.0
135.8
163.2
172.8
158.9
163.6
171.4

96.1
83.0
92.7
110.9
117.3
112.2
133.1
189.5
232.8
219.5
173.6
112.5
126.5
122.5
118.6
147.4
163.5
155.2
164.1
172.6

101.4
95.3
102.1
105.6
106.5
110.1
134.2
194.6
231.5
253.5
204.0
132.6
146.3
160.0
169.6
182.8
178.0
179.5
180.4
184.1

101.5
94.2
102.4
107.7
110.6
113.6
136.9
199.2
231.3
250.5
202.3
132.8
147.0
158.7
166.1
180.0
177.3
180.2
182.4
106.4

1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937

87.5
56.7
50.5
74.1
71.2
82.4
110.3
105.4

106.8
65.5
51.9
83.0
73.4
88.0
116.3
121.2

184.4
150.0
102.9
137.3
145.6
160.8
166.5
195.7

205.7
157.1
119.8
112.3
126.0
155.5
160.8
169.7

90.3
62.3
53.1
80.9
87.0
83.0
107.1
111.0

146.5
102.6
68.2
73.8
86.0
114.1
139.2
141.8

147.6
105.8
73.4
76.7
64.8
110.8
130.3
136.2

141.0
100.9
76.7
89.0
95.0
115.8
133.1
139.6

143.0
103.0
79.0
90.7
89.7
116.1
132.0
139.5

^Contained in the index of crop production of the Business of Agricultural Economies: wheat, corn, oats, barley, rye, buckwheat,
flaxseed, hay, potatoes, sweetpotatoes, cotton and cottonseed, tobacco.
^Wheat, rye, potatoes, sweetpotatoes, dry beans, rice.
^Orchard fruits, citrus fruits, grapes.
^Cotton and cottonseed, flaxseed, wool.
^Slaughter of cattle, calves, hogs, sheep, and lambs, and export of live cattle.
Sources: See Data Appendix.

Table 2

Price and Income Changes Across States
1919-1921
l A
gross farm
income
Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming

-44
-37
-44
-24
-41
-7
-39
-35
-57
-39
-50
-48
-50
-45
-46
-47
-26
-42
-14
-34
-48
-51
-48
-30
-51
-38
-12
-29
-37
-25
-41
-46
-44
-50
-30
-32
-22
-56
-53
-39
-44
-43
-15
-41
-21
-33
-30
-43

Sources: See Oata Appendix.



1919-1921
X A
total net
farm income
-38
-26
-49
58
-19
162
-39
8
-78
-58
-89
-101
-113
-66
-32
-64
24
-10
111
-6
-75
-54
-116
NA
-92
NA
222
17
40
35
-40
-39
-49
-76
-32
11
64
-88
-101
-28
-63
14
77
-36
-21
1
1
106

1919-1921
X A
total net
non-farm inc.
25
14
27
82
56
44
39
51
20
20
45
23
3
39
51
35
48
45
53
27
38
17
42
34
16
53
40
44
47
61
29
69
25
14
29
42
61
-6
-19
42
37
37
43
32
37
43
40
77

1919-1924
t A
crop price
index
-29
-35
-33
-45
-43
-36
-34
-37
-54
-54
-45
-55
-50
-32
-48
-43
-65
-45
-41
-55
-34
-37
-51
-47
-37
-38
-49
-51
-18
-50
-47
-1
-56
-32
-48
-46
-48
-62
-36
-39
-16
-50
-44
-46
-55
-48
-54
-34

1922-1925
X A
value of
crops sold
2
18
1
20
41
-7
13
8
11
61
11
10
5
9
-10
-23
-60
-20
-35
-23
-23
-25
-14
2
23
0
10
8
51
19
4
21
11
21
17
23
18
6
3
-10
-15
43
1
-5
41
14
26
28

1925-1928
X A
value of
crops sold
-16
44
-10
0
-24
-19
-15
31
0
-22
-4
-14
3
19
-2
-43
-65
-45
-41
-55
-34
-37
-51
47
2
-3
-39
-11
-6
-36
-9
-16
-21
0
-13
-34
-42
-14
-14
-6
27
-16
-30
-7
-25
-22
-26
1

Table 3

Farm Land. Population, and Foreclosure Data
1913-1920

1920-1925

t A value

% A value

farm real
estate per acre

farm real
estate per acre

77
65
122
67
41
37
39
78
117
72
60
61
113
51
100
98
42
66
40
54
113
118
67
26
79
35
29
30
44
33
123
45
59
66
30
40
30
130
81
100
74
67
50
89
40
54
71
76

-11
-56
-20
10
-31
10
-3
75
-40
-34
-27
-32
-34
-19
-30
-22
2
-5
8
-6
-27
-34
-30
-37
-32
-41
11
24
-31
3
-7
-28
-23
-20
-13
-4
14
-34
-37
-19
-14
-20
-7
-7
-17
-8
-12
-54

Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming

Sources: See Data Appendix.




1925-1930
% A value
farm real
estate per acre
-7
2
-12
-2
-10
2
-1

0
-14
-6
-21
-22
-17
-2
-9
-6
0
-6
-1

-9
-16
-10
-18
-4
-8
-3
-2
1
2
-7
-16
-13
-18
-3
-3
-6
5
-25
-19
-10
-5
-3
-2
-13
-3
-13
-10
-2

1920
ratio of farm
mortgage debt
to farm value
.12
.20
.11
.13
.17
.13
.15
.08
.08
.21
.09
.08
.16
.12
.09
.10
.10
.13
.13
.15
.15
.11
.14
.22
.13
.20
.10
.16
.13
.16
.06
.19
.08
.16
.14
.10
.08
.07
.13
.09
.12
.16
.18
.07
.13
.04
.21
.15

1920
ratio of farm
to total
popul.
.57
.27
.65
.15
.28
.07
.23
.29
.58
.46
.17
.31
.41
.42
.54
.44
.26
.19
.03
.23
.37
.71
.36
.41
.45
.21
.17
.05
.44
.08
.58
.61
.20
.50
.27
.11
.02
.63
.57
.54
.48
.31
.36
.46
.21
.32
.35
.34

1926-1930
average am
farm forec
(per 1000)
29.5
42.7
39.7
16.3
42.4
5.3
13.7
11.1
56.5
37.6
29.0
23.8
48.3
27.2
20.2
40.1
10.5
16.8
6.5
21.6
36.2
47.7
34.1
52.2
38.4
21.0
7.3
7.2
26.3
13.8
23.4
58.0
16.4
50.1
17.4
6.9
6.0
68.0
70.4
20.5
23.7
13.5
10.6
15.6
20.0
9.0
22.6
26.3

Table 4
GNP Deflator Estimates
Balke and Gordon (1989)
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929

Sources:




11.36
13.35
15.23
17.58
15.30
14.22
14.63
14.64
14.90
14.98
14.72
14.60
14.64

See Data Appendix.

Romer (191
13.06
15.20
15.58
17.75
15.12
14.30
14.69
14.51
14.77
14.84
14.48
14.59
14.60

Table 5
32 State Regulatory Regimes of the 1920s

No deposit
Insurance

Full intrastate
branching allowed

Arizona
North Carolina
South Carolina
Virginia
Wyoming1

Limited
new branches

Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Ohio
Tennessee

No new
branching, old
branches remain

Alabama
Arkansas
Georgia2
Indiana
Minnesota
Wisconsin

No branches
allowed

Colorado
Idaho
Illinois
Iowa
Missouri
Montana
Nevada
New Mexico

Compulsory
Insurance

Nebraska (1911-30)
Mississippi (1914-30)

North Dakota (1917-29)
Oklahoma (1908-23)
South Dakota (1916-27)

^Branches authorized by Implication; none 1n existence.
2New branching prohibited In 1927.

Sources:

See Data Appendix.




Voluntary
Insurance

Washington (1917-21)

Kansas (1909-29)
Texas (1910-27)

Table 6

Number of banks

National banks

Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Sources:

1918

1920

1923

90
13
57
124
115
55
463
255
341
212
143
31
99
273
37
130
61
228
10
37
73
146
379
343
51
105
113
518
133
77
131
32

91
18
72
122
97
68
469
258
352
234
132
31
105
294
33
131
126
191
10
43
81
165
369
340
81
125
106
543
149
80
147
38

101
20
83
141
93
81
480
254
358
249
134
38
112
331
30
136
145
188
10
47
87
181
370
348
82
136
98
556
165
87
151
47

106
20
88
143
97
73
505
251
349
266
139
34
119
344
31
132
121
182
11
42
83
184
368
459
84
131
105
561
181
115
155
45

See Data Appendix.




State banks

1914

1927
105
15
79
124
83
52
490
233
287
257
142
32
134
277
36
135
74
153
10
29
77
141
340
350
65
98
104
649
167
109
156
30

1929

1914

1918

1920

1923

1927

1929

106
14
73
121
80
43
487
224
265
247
138
33
133
272
35
134
69
158
10
28
73
125
323
307
53
93
99
623
164
106
157
25

267
47
425
206
675
134
1439
664
1410
932
467
217
702
863
282
1337
226
749
21
47
384
619
746
574
329
526
378
1038
274
296
652
72

238
60
389
236
659
136
1434
773
1561
1037
444
218
740
1141
266
1407
277
946
23
74
434
693
778
580
336
517
415
1037
300
281
778
98

251
67
404
262
686
141
1489
798
1564
1100
450
229
739
1177
302
1516
286
1037
23
76
491
718
772
612
379
543
450
1125
331
306
819
113

254
55
403
224
586
109
1416
854
1506
1068
474
232
765
1151
303
1495
242
968
24
59
477
648
745
446
345
556
466
1071
343
274
838
89

251
32
376
175
412
92
1358
827
1222
923
444
200
739
912
290
1304
136
896
25
30
432
390
724
348
216
319
418
852
334
224
810
58

244
34
347
159
362
94
1319
757
1129
830
432
193
718
794
277
1191
129
714
25
30
399
309
703
344
170
303
393
791
321
233
801
62

Table 7

Total Assets per bank, and bank location
Proportion of banks in towns of
greater than 2,500 people, 1920^

Total Assets per bank
1929

1914

banks
1918

1920

1923

1927

1929

2311
2608
1352
2244
3377
1094
3295
2097
1381
1104
2162
4099
4991
2468
2702
4509
1489
1615
2299
1331
2634
702
2785
1448
2371
871
3033
1771
2347
3306
3413
1711

283
555
164
263
224
162
739
352
314
146
245
581
635
235
238
350
269
155
593
197
232
106
806
95
241
136
240
159
329
449
365
148

368
807
304
397
355
335
996
451
423
269
389
950
988
287
450
493
391
298
817
277
345
165
1162
228
342
271
396
242
478
637
440
242

543
974
456
460
534
487
1322
609
563
326
497
1592
14780
425
664
572
436
335
1030
347
578
248
1645
346
536
395
562
375
613
752
626
300

522
974
404
514
519
334
1610
628
542
285
537
1472
1505
403
552
631
393
319
947
364
565
211
2167
211
424
344
558
304
656
520
634
307

578
1745
445
437
489
436
2085
769
562
304
651
2029
2272
443
632
722
605
365
1063
365
744
262
3095
279
471
272
626
379
819
606
776
431

545
2107
492
477
538
568
2584
806
596
320
826
2184
2555
466
660
741
680
383
1228
466
809
289
3271
292
588
318
714
429
878
703
752
514

National banks_______________________________

Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming

1914

1918

1920

1923

806
1215
607
1069
884
546
1912
960
692
531
900
2075
2054
1220
756
2820
895
694
972
612
921
338
1545
343
908
446
1026
705
1265
1610
1592
630

1224
1299
818
1614
1676
811
2764
1319
1010
839
1474
3677
2826
1682
1281
4276
746
1342
1545
879
1379
499
2484
766
1244
718
1583
1081
2045
2570
2065
1102

1516
1766
1020
1801
2145
1088
3562
1667
1301
977
1824
4119
3784
1979
1843
5507
761
1566
1823
963
2064
563
2912
1096
1818
862
2352
1588
2461
3039
2720
1365

1449
1389
1004
1695
1704
827
3068
1635
1144
870
1957
3416
3634
1785
1956
4162
766
1424
1529
968
2086
528
2470
848
1520
731
2070
1356
2110
2482
2476
1369

^Branches excluded.
Sources: See Data Appendix.



1927

1944
1863
1285
2116
3299
1079
3737
1890
1264
1016
2118
3846
4324
2325
2589
4887
1191
1496
1990
1047
2544
644
2638
1219
2048
733
2459
1567
2381
2958
2979
1442

State

National banks

.55
.70
.66
.42
.75
.58
.52
.57
.36
.43
.63
.79
.71
.34
.80
.63
.28
.40
.60
.47
.77
.16
.59
.51
.72
.27
.65
.49
.50
.56
.62
.47

State banks

.26
.54
.31
.23
.31
.25
.31
.37
.15
.18
.24
.31
.25
.18
.28
.22
.16
.12
.39
.37
.28
.06
.41
.21
.43
.07
.23
.24
.29
.29
.24
.13

Table 8

Asset Growth (% A)

Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming

National banks______________________________

State banks

1914
1918

1918
1920

1920
1923

1923
1927

1929
1930

1914
1918

1918
1920

1920
1923

1923
1927

1927
1929

1929
1930

53
48
70
48
60
84
46
39
51
74
51
77
46
48
51
53
72
62
59
67
66
67
57
121
118
91
45
61
81
66
46
108

37
51
44
29
23
60
32
24
31
24
26
37
43
32
31
34
17
15
18
20
61
24
18
46
48
31
37
50
33
29
35
53

0
-21
4
-5
-17
-32
-9
-3
-14
-5
11
-26
2
-6
10
-27
-16
-12
-8
-10
-4
-5
-16
2
-14
-18
-6
-14
-6
8
-7
-4

33
1
15
8
65
-7
18
7
-9
13
11
6
34
5
54
20
-5
-12
18
-25
13
-7
-1
10
4
-25
18
34
4
13
21
-30

60
3
17
7
35
-47
-6
11
-21
12
22
-14
57
2
71
-19
-7
-13
26
-18
7
-14
-17
17
-16
-31
30
25
0
33
30
-33

16
86
70
73
55
94
34
49
56
105
51
64
64
61
78
48
78
142
51
121
68
75
50
142
45
96
81
52
59
35
44
122

56
35
56
29
57
51
38
39
33
28
30
76
48
53
68
25
15
23
26
28
89
56
40
60
77
46
54
68
41
29
50
43

-3
-18
-12
-4
-17
-47
16
10
-7
-15
14
-6
6
-7
-17
9
-24
-11
-4
-19
-5
-23
27
-56
-28
-6
3
-23
11
-38
4
-19

9
4
3
-33
-33
10
24
19
-16
-8
14
19
46
-13
10
0
-13
6
17
-49
19
-23
39
3
-30
-55
1
-1
22
4
18
-9

-8
28
2
-1
-3
33
20
-4
-2
-5
23
4
9
-8
0
-6
7
-16
16
28
0
-13
3
3
-2
11
7
5
3
11
-4
27

-2
10
-7
-37
-47
-22
73
26
-24
-26
60
16
69
-26
-9
2
-30
-21
30
-47
14
-50
81
-53
-51
-47
11
-19
39
-29
17
-6

Sources: See Data Appendix




1927
1929
20
31
-3
0
-1
-16
-12
7
1
4
-1
10
15
4
1
-8
17
12
16
23
-2
-3
0
4
-6
13
17
9
-3
9
15
-1

Table 9

Capital as a percent of total assets
National banks_____________________
1918
1920
1923
1927
1929
1914

Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming
SOURCES:

14
7
15
8
15
12
9
n

10
11
14
11
8
8
13
10
10
10
15
9
13
11
11
13
17
9
11
14
11
9
9
9

See Data Appendix.




10
7
10
5
8
7
6
8
7
7
9
7
6
7
9
7
8
6
9
7
8
8
7
6
9
6
8
9
7
6
6
5

8
5
8
5
7
6
5
7
6
7
7
6

5
5
7
6
8
6

8
7
7
7
6
6

8
5
6

7
6

5
6

5

9
6
9
5
8
8
6
8
7
8
7
7
6
7
8
8
8
7
9
8
8
8
7
8
10
6
8
9
8
6
7
6

7
5
7
5
7
6
5
7
7
7
7
7
5
6
6
7
6
6
7
7
8
6
6
6
7
6
7
8
8
6
6
6

7
5
7
5
7
6
6
7
6
7
6
7
5
6
6
6
5
6
7
6
8
6
7
6
8
5
7
8
8
7
6
5

State banks
1914
1918

17
7
20
12
20
17
10
13
10
14
17
12
8
10
16
12
14
14
14
19
13
14
8
16
16
12
16
21
15
12
9
16

12
6
12
8
12
9
8
10
8
8
11
8
6
9
8
9
10
8
9
13
9
10
6
8
11
7
9
14
10
9
8
10

1920

1923

1927

1929

9
6
8
8
10
8
7
8
7
8
9
6
5
7
7
7
9
8
7
12
7
8
5
7
8
6
8
11
11
7
6
9

9
9
10
8
11
10
7
9
7
9
9
7
6
8
7
8
10
9
8
12
9
10

10
7
9
8
12
7
7
8
7
9
8
6
5
6
6
8
7
8
7
11
8
9
5
8
10
9
9
11
10
9
6
7

9
6
9
7
12
6
7
7
7
9
9
6
5
6
6
8
7
8
6
8
8
9
6
8
9
8
9
10
10
8
6
6

6

10
11
7
9
13
12
9
7
10

Table 10

Voluntary Insurance Systems

Kansas_________________________________Texas_______________________________ Kashi ngton

1917
1919
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1917
1919
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928

Participating
Deposits
JL

Not participatinq
Deposits
JL

Participating
Deposits
JL

577
649
683
698
651
399
794

430
427
409
369
371
547
39

828
907
990
936
8%
34

152
205
191
180
195
79
219

Sources: See Data Appendix.




46
41
41
34
37
748

-

73
88
81
62
75
154
3

Not participating
»
Deposits

-

204
321
266
252
302
3
-

12
15
14
11
21
226
-

Participating
Oeposits
JL

Not participating
Deposits
JL

46
104
116

239
191
190

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

40
80
75

109
123
107

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

Table 11

High-Growth States: Insured vs. Uninsured

Assets 1914/Assets 1920
National Bank
State Bank

Assets per bank in 1920
State Bank
National Bank

1920, capital/total assets
National Bank
State Bank

Arkansas
Colorado
.Idaho
Iowa
Minnesota
Missouri
"Montana
New Mexico
jtyoming
Average

.406
.522
.341
.507
.509
.490
.495
.501
.314
.454

.379
.450
.316
.503
.406
.540
.489
.352
.315
.418

1020
1069
1088
1301
1979
5507
761
963
1365
1673

456
460
487
562
425
572
436
347
300
448

.084
.081
.059
.057
.054
.063
.077
.073
.048
.066

.085
.083
.088
.104
.069
.072
.091
.119
.090
.090

Kansas
Mississippi
Nebraska
«North Dakota
Oklahoma
“South Dakota
Texas
Average

.463
.506
.537
.485
.309
.400
^414
.447

.380
.335
.335
.367
.259
.351
.391
.344

977
1843
1566
563
10%
862
1588
1231

326
664
335
248
346
376
375
389

.066
.069
.057
.068
.126
.053
.071
.073

.079
.066
.082
.081
.070
.062
.112
.078

Sources:

See Data Appendix.




Table 12

Growth Quart!le Comparison

Nationa1-chartered

State-chartered
Lowest
25th percentile
growth

25% - 50%
(second
quartile)

Lowest
growth quartile

Nevada, Illinois,
Kentucky

Colorado, Georgia,»
Indiana, Ohio

Nebraska

Second
quartile

Iowa, Missouri,
Montana

Minnesota,
Wisconsin

New Mexico,
Tennessee

Mississippi

Third
quartile

Alabama,
Washington

Michigan,
Virginia

Arizona, Kansas,
North Dakota, Texas

Arkansas,
South Carolina

Fourth
quantile

Sources:

50% - 75%
(third
quartile)

See Data Appendix.




Highest
25th percentile
growth

Idaho, Louisiana
North Carolina,
Oklahoma, South
Dakota, Wyoming

Table 13
Regression Results:

Early Asset Growth of State-Chartered Banks

Dependent variable:

Growth in total assets of state-chartered banks, 1914 - 1920
Coefficient

Independent Variables
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Growth in land values, 1914-1920
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Presence of voluntary insurance
Presence of compulsory insurance

0.156
0.682
-0.115
0.526
-0.328
0.327
0.609

Standard Error
0.468
0.147
0.063
0.334
0.655
0.251
0.189

Prob >
0.741
0.000
0.080
0.127
0.621
0.205
0.004

R2 = 0.683
R2 = 0.607

Dependent variable:

Growth in total assets of state-chartered banks, 1914 - 1920

Independent Variables
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Growth in land values, 1914-1920
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Presence of vol. or comp, insurance
R2 = 0.670
R2 = 0.607




Coefficient
0.101
0.681
-0.132
0.555
-0.283
0.518

Standard Error
0.465
0.147
0.060
0.333
0.654
0.165

Prob >
0.829
0.000
0.038
0.107
0.669
0.004

Table 14
State-Chartered Reqional Comparison:
Assets 1914/
Assets 1920

Insured vs. Uninsured
Assets per
bank in
1920

Capital /total assets
in 1920

Arkansas
Colorado
Iowa
Idaho
Minnesota
Missouri
Montana
New Mexico
Wyoming
Average

.379
.450
.503
.316
.406
.540
.489
.352
.315
.417

456
460
563
487
425
572
436
347
300
450

,085
.083
.067
.077
.069
.072
.091
.119
.090
.084

Kansas
North Dakota
Nebraska
Oklahoma
South Dakota
Texas
Average

.380
.367
.335
.259
.351
.391
'.347

326
248
335
346
376
374
334

.079
.081
.082
.070
.062
.112
.081

Alabama
Georgia
South Carolina
Average

.553
.412
.390
.452

543
534
536
538

.087
.097
.085
.090

Mississippi

.335

664

.066

Sources:




See Data Appendix.

Table 15

Charter Switches
From State - to NationalAlabama
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Sources: See Data Appendix




10
1
7
16
6
0
0
4
7
0
13
3
2
14
7
0
0
1
4
4
19
10
10
1
31
0
0
2
1
7
6
12
2
113
7
11
0
4
4
8
130
0
0
16
27
2
9
1

From National - to State0
1
4
0
1
1
2
6
0
13
3
7
2
2
3
2
1
1
1
0
5
0
4
0
0
0
1
11
1
8
5
0
1
50
0
8
1
1
1
3
8
0
1
3
2
0
1
6

Net Change
10
0
3
16
5
-1
-2
-2
7
-13
10
-4
0
12
4
-2
-1
0
3
4
14
10
6
1
31
0
-1
-9
0
-1
1
12
1
63
7
3
-1
3
3
5
122
0
-1
13
25
2
8
-5

Table 16
Regression Results:

Late Asset Growth of State Chartered Banks

Dependent Variable:

Growth in total assets of state-chartered banks, 1920-1926

Independent Variable

Coefficient

Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth in land values, 1920-1925
Business failure rate. 1921-1925
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
Presence of deposit insurance
(excluding Nebraska)

Standard Error

Prob >

0.400
0.598
0.213
-0.251
0.269

0.458
0.239
0.098
0.347
0.540

0.391
0.019
0.039
0.477
0.622

-0.048

0.039

0.233

-0.271

0.123

0.036

R2 = 0.537
R2 = 0.426

Dependent Variable:

Growth in total assets of state-chartered banks, 1920-1930

Independent Variable
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth in land values, 1920-1930
Business failure rate. 1921-1929
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
Presence of deposit insurance
(excluding Nebraska)
R2 = 0.405
R2 = 0.262




Coefficient

Standard Error

Prob >

1.482
0.063
0.141
-0.648
-0.091

0.554
0.225
0.135
0.475
0.659

0.013
0.782
0.308
0.185
0.891

-0.095

0.053

0.088

-0.194

0.171

0.267

Table 16 (continued)
Dependent Variable:

Growth 1n total assets of state-chartered banks, 1920-1930

Independent Variable
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth 1n land values, 1920-1930
Business failure rate, 1921-1929
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
Presence of deposit Insurance
(Including Nebraska)
R2 = 0.429
R2 = 0.292




Coefficient

Standard Error

Prob >

1.467
0.055
0.130
-0.593
-0.065

0.529
0.220
0.133
0.465
0.641

0.010
0.803
0.337
0.214
0.920

-0.094

0.052

0.079

-0.240

0.155

0.134

Table 17

Growth in Branch Banking

Total
fac.

National Banks_____________________ State Banks________________________ All Banks
Br.
8ran- Tot.
B.B.
Br. Tot. B.B. 8r. Tot. B.B.
Br. Tot. B.B. & Br. Tot.
Banks ches
1924
1928
1924
1928
1924

B.B.& Br.
1928

Arizona
North Carolina
South Carolina
Virginia
Wyoming

19
86
84
352
37

0
2
2
7
0

0
3
3
11
0

15
83
66
182
26

0
4
3
9
0

0
6
8
16
0

64
535
347
216
79

6
39
7
24
0

20
64
17
34
0

53
437
247
376
60

8
39
12
30
0

23
73
28
47
0

83
621
431
568
116

26
108
29
76
0

68
520
313
558
86

31
122
66
102
0

Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Ohio
Tennessee

145
41
144
363
110

3
1
10
4
2

7
8
23
4
2

155
41
181
338
122

4
1
9
7
7

15
8
48
7
19

483
303
906
947
512

1
33
53
47
19

5
85
309
199
51

480
299
989
960
446

29
42
55
52
20

34
103
374
243
42

628
344
1050
1310
622

16
127
395
254
74

635
340
1170
1298
568

82
154
486
309
88

Alabama
Arkansas
Georgia
Indiana
Hi nnesota
Mississippi
Nebraska
Washington
Wisconsin

105
88
101
248
345
36
177
114
157

0
0
2
0
3
1
2
1
1

0
0
7
0
11
1
2
2
2

107
79
97
229
285
37
160
111
159

0
0
4
1
2
1
2
1
1

0
0
16
2
6
1
2
2
2

276
400
608
863
1081
346
925
272
839

5
2
19
4
0
10
0
4
6

19
3
46
8
0
24
0
5
7

269
361
394
808
855
313
746
247
817

5
2
15
3
0
10
0
3
6

19
3
21
7
0
24
0
4
7

381
488
709
1111
1426
382
1102
386
996

24
5
74
12
14
36
4
12
16

376
440
491
1037
1140
350
906
358
976

24
5
56
13
8
36
4
10
16

Colorado
Idaho
Illinois
Iowa
Kansas
Missouri
Montana
Nevada
New Mexico
North Dakota
Oklahoma
South Dakota
Texas

141
70
502
347
260
134
93
11
33
165
421
116
573

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

123
46
484
270
250
134
70
10
29
136
333
97
638

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

201
107
1408
1438
1033
1478
155
23
43
523
388
437
1046

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

164
94
1337
1169
864
1231
132
25
29
354
337
315
816

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

342
177
1910
1785
1293
1612
248
34
76
688
809
553
1619

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

287
140
1821
1439
1114
1365
202
35
58
490
670
412
1454

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

Sources:

See Data Appendix




Table 18
Reqression Results:

Late Asset Growth and Bank Size of State-Chartered Bank

Dependent Variable:

Growth in total assets of state--chartered banks, 1920-1926

Independent variable

Coefficient

Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth in land values, 1920-1925
Business failure rate. 1921-1925
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
Presence of deposit insurance
(excluding Nebraska)
Out-of-city branch banking
Within-city branch banking

Standard Error

Prob >

0.544
0.602
0.178
-0.404
0.037

0.450
0.235
0.098
0.346
0.541

0.239
0.018
0.084
0.254
0.946

-0.040

0.038

0.308

-0.190

0.126

0.146

0.179
0.204

0.124
0.132

0.163
0.136

R2 = 0.601
R2 = 0.462

Dependent Variable:

Growth in total assets of state-chartered banks, 1920-1930

Independent variable
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth in land values, 1920-1930
Business failure rate. 1921-1929
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
Presence of deposit insurance
(excluding Nebraska)
Out-of-city branch banking
Within-city branch banking
R2 = 0.625
R2 = 0.495




Coefficient

Standard Error

Prob > 1T1

1.539
0.124
0.078
-0.936
-0.386

0.449
0.200
0.115
0.405
0.551

0.002
0.539
0.502
0.030
0.490

-0.072

0.044

0.118

-0.065

0.140

0.647

0.398
0.428

0.150
0.161

0.014
0.014

Table 18 (continued)
Regression Results:

Late Asset Growth and Bank Size of State-Chartered Bank

Dependent Variable:

Assets per bank for state-chartered banks In 1926

Independent variable
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth 1n land values, 1920-1925
Business failure rate. 1921-1925
Buslnes failure rate, 1917-1920
0ut-of-c1ty branch banking
W1th1n-c1ty branch banking

Prob > IT!

Coefficient

Standard Error

1341.96
0.101
0.084
-1782.05
-160.61

739.24
0.115
0.072
580.74
884.00

0.082
0.385
0.256
0.005
0.857

-40.55

60.60

0.510

593.49
540.64

198.93
257.51

0.007
0.047

R2 = 0.688
R2 = 0.597

Dependent Variable:

Assets per bank for state-chartered banks 1n 1930

Independent variable
Intercept
National bank growth
(Reserve center)x(Nat. bank growth)
Ratio of farm to non-farm popul.
Growth 1n land values, 1920-1930
Business failure rate. 1921-1929
Business failure rate, 1917-1920
0ut-of-c1ty branch banking
W1th1n-c1ty branch banking
R2 = 0.700
R2 = 0.612




Coefficient

Standard Error

Prob > IT!

1868.64
0.072
0.100
-2642.12
-375.72

847.17
0.128
0.079
725.33
952.96

0.037
0.577
0.219

-24.39

75.20

0.749

876.91
736.32

244.74
330.63

0.002

0.001
0.697

0.036

Table 19
Chains and Banks in Chain Systems, by States:

June 30, 1929

Banks in chain systems

Numbers of Chain systems

Total

Total
230

Total
1,561

National
596

State
965

State--Wide Branch Banking Permitted
Total

A

49

25

State
6

Arizona
California
Delaware
District of Columbia
Maryland
North Carolina
Rhode Island
South Carolina
Virginia
Wyoming

30

1

5

20

10

10

Branches Restricted as to Location
Total

61

337

135

202

z
1
4
11

4
10
5
33
71

4
6
2
19
3

4
3
14
68

12
17
1
9
3

49
111
6
38
10

22
58
3
12
6

27
53
3
25
4

State
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Massachusetts
Michigan
Mississippi
New Jersey
New York
Ohio
Pennsylvania
Tennessee

Establishment of Branches Prohibited by Law
Total

141

1,026

365

661

22
63

11
13

11
50

State
Alabama
Arkansas




Table 19 (cont'd)
State
Colorado
Connecticut
Florida
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Minnesota
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
Oregon
Texas
Utah
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin

2

13

8

5

4
6
3
11
1
12
10
34
4
2
9
2
1
6
6
5
11

32
23
23
81
3
92
55
279
26
15
63
14
6
32
37
50
62

13
8
7
20
2
33
15
130
7
4
15
2
4
14
7
12
26

19
15
16
61
1
59
40
149
19
11
48
12
2
18
30
38
36

5

35

14

21

Establishment of Branches Prohibited in Practice

Total

20

149

71

78

7
8
5

60
59
30

20
41
10

40
18
20

State
New Hampshire
North Dakota
Oklahoma
South Dakota
Vermont

Sources:




See Data Appendix.

Table 20

Average Annual Bank Failure Rate: 32 "Aqricultural-Crisis" States
1918-1920
National State
AFR1820 AFR1820
Alabama
Arkansas
Arizona
Colorado
Georgia
Iowa
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Missouri
Mississippi
Montana
North Carolina
North Dakota
Nebraska
New Mexico
Nevada
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming

.0000000
.0049751
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0011614
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0008985
.0009921
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000

.0014124
.0034364
.0000000
.0029240
.0031299
.0004424
.0000000
.0016317
.0017683
.0016617
.0007491
.0015798
.0004617
.0045537
.0021536
.0000000
.0000000
.0000000
.0009592
.0007491
.0000000
.0000000
.0004323
.0017889
.0000000
.0006588
.0000000
.0019685
.0033784
.0023474
.0000000
.0000000

Sources: See Data Appendix.




1921-1924
National State
AFR2124
AFR2124
0.002475
0.003012
0.037500
0.007092
0.002688
0.002793
0.043210
0.000521
0.000984
0.004016
0.000000
0.006579
0.000000
0.005287
0.000000
0.008333
0.067241
0.008621
0.035912
0.017287
0.079787
0.000000
0.001351
0.017241
0.000000
0.040441
0.000000
0.005845
0.001515
0.005747
0.003311
0.042553

0.00697
0.01052
0.07090
0.02958
0.03098
0.01055
0.05674
0.00386
0.00533
0.01432
0.00667
0.01638
0.00169
0.01954
0.01022
0.01407
0.10140
0.01884
0.07103
0.01808
0.08882
0.01087
0.00130
0.04820
0.02309
0.05985
0.00389
0.01689
0.00982
0.01961
0.00336
0.06195

1925-1929
National
State
AFR2529
AFR2529
0.005714
0.013636
0.000000
0.015603
0.019149
0.043228
0.028571
0.004382
0.005645
0.005385
0.000000
0.000000
0.001653
0.031138
0.007463
0.005714
0.032258
0.019277
0.036364
0.016000
0.018182
0.000000
0.001671
0.014727
0.037037
0.048276
0.003704
0.006283
0.001099
0.0107T4
0.005161
0.016216

0.011673
0.029219
0.031111
0.024876
0.058007
0.027816
0.028037
0.004830
0.012164
0.021878
0.011416
0.014679
0.001038
0.039630
0.023275
0.014667
0.019355
0.024000
0.066922
0.042737
0.051163
0.000000
0.005906
0.028866
0.079394
0.058581
0.021166
0.013958
0.009169
0.011321
0.009615
0.050633

1921-1929
National
State
AFR2129
AFR2129
0.004400
0.009371
0.016667
0.011820
0.011947
0.024519
0.032922
0.002778
0.003500
0.004909
0.000000
0.002924
0.000992
0.019805
0.004085
0.007407
0.041379
0.014049
0.034377
0.015957
0.042553
0.000000
0.001502
0.017561
0.020325
0.040850
0.002268
0.006195
0.001347
0.010217
0.004415
0.026005

0.009739
0.020627
0.043118
0.023749
0.040168
0.018897
0.037037
0.004253
0.009607
0.017778
0.009630
0.015041
0.001353
0.028887
0.017150
0.014349
0.050894
0.021951
0.058651
0.029787
0.055556
0.004831
0.003742
0.031590
0.048666
0.052793
0.013827
0.014716
0.009735
0.014161
0.006919
0.047198

Table 21
1921-1930 Bank Liquidations (as of 1930)

# completely
liquidated
Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming

2
2
3
8
5
17
2
1
14
4
0
1
0
13
2
2
38
13
0
12
4
21
3
25
8
16
1
21
1
4
2
8

National Banks___________
# in process repayment
of liquid. ratio2
11
0
15
9
ii
4
31
12
69
10
3
0
4
43
3
10
15
15
0
2
17
38
7
26
16
34
4
22
3
5
6
2

1.00
.50
.87
.60
.51
.47
.76
.77
.69
.79
.NA
.69
.NA
.58
.88
.66
.34
.44
.NA
.51
.71
.45
.66
.43
.51
.51
.93
.58
.90
.84
.30
.70

__
State Banks
# completely # in
liquidated
process
9
4
37
62
120
28
9
6
182
1191
18
16
2
50
641
109
27
3171
0
18
2
3401
0
13 91
16
2421
12
13 81
4
1*
20
15

39
20
96
9
130
11
131
109
130
O1
41
19
8
245
oi
200
28
01
0
19
87
01
42
01
189
01
61
01
41
O1
40
13

repayment
ratio2
.59
.91
.36
.68
.44
.49
.63
.88
.54
.531
.NA
.41
.72
.48
.521
.53
.52
.351
.NA
.70
1.00
.171
.NA
.561
.66
.241
.83
.541
.57
.751
.66
.54

^Insured Banks only. Includes liquidations completed after 1930.
2The repayment ratio is defined as the ratio of deposits repaid from asset liquidation for
banks that were completely liquidated.
Sources:

See Data Appendix.




Table 22
Average Time elapsed between closing and Completed Liquidation
(for banks liquidated 1921-1930)

Years
Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Mexico
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Virginia
Washington
Wisconsin
Wyoming

Sources:

3
4
2
4
3
4
3
7
3
3
NA
7
NA
4
1
3
4
4
NA
4
2
4
3
3
3
4
0
4
4
4
3
4

See Date Appendix




National Banks
Months
2
10
5
5
9
2
3
6
8
3
NA
2
NA
1
1
6
6
9
NA
5
11
0
5
8
10
8
11
0
8
2
8
10

# banks
2
2
3
8
5
17
2
1
14
4
NA
1
NA
13
2
2
38
13
NA
12
4
21
3
25
8
16
1
21
1
4
2
8

Years
3
3
2
2
3
4
3
4
3
3
3
4
6
5
6
3
4
6
NA
5
7
6
NA
5
3
5
3
3
3
4
3
3

State Banks
Months
3
8
10
11
8
6
10
4
7
4
4
3
3
7
0
2
4
4
NA
0
1
3
NA
0
11
7
11
9
11
1
2
4

# banks
8
3
37
60
113
28
8
5
179
117
17
14
2
48
2
109
23
15
IMA
17
1
35
IMA
64
8
22
6
19
4
32
20
10

Table 23

Estimated Asset Shortfalls of Failed Banks Relative to Remaining-Bank
Equity in MSevere-Failure*1 States

National Banks
Deposits of Nunrtber of Liq.
Relative to
Suspended
Banks
Suspensions
1921-30
Arizona
Colorado
Georgia
Idaho
Iowa
Minnesota
Montana
Nebraska
North Dakota
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Wyomi ng

Sources:

1256
11003
16538
10601
55984
28338
16287
13695
17438
27364
12153
21109
9154

See Data Appendix




.67
.94
.84
.81
.79
.97
.87
.80
.84
.72
.92
.93
.91

Estimated
Avg. size
Rate of
Asset
Shortfall
of Liq. Bks
Rel. to Susp. Shortfall

.83
.45
.09
.65
.50
.59
.44
.94
.80
.70
.57
.60
.45

.50
.40
.49
.53
.31
.42
.66
.56
.55
.57
.49
.49
.30

349
1,862
613
2,958
6,855
6,812
4,115
5,767
6,445
7,861
3,123
5,772
1,125

State-Chartered Banks_________________________________ All Banks
Total Bank Deposits Liq./ Size Rate of Estimated Total Bank Ratio of
Shortfal1
Shortfall Equity
Equity
of Sus.
Susp. Ratio Asset
to Equity
June 1930
Shortfall
June 1930 Banks
1921-30
3,815
13,776
39,064
4,612
35,750
69,387
9,999
26,063
9,210
41,251
11,665
8,477
4,819

15,056
12,187
46,318
9,185
138,995
80,634
31,361
78,093
45,199
38,986
50,970
91,619
7,536

.80
.95
.75
.85
.75
.77
.89
.85
.92
.79
.91
.77
.80

.06
.95
.70
.63
.66
.47
.47
1.04
1.05
.28
.58
1.00
.48

.09
.32
.56
.51
.46
.52
.48
.65
.83
.44
.34
.76
.46

65
3,520
13,618
2,509
31,649
15,174
6,297
44,872
36,240
3,794
9,147
53,615
1,331

8,496
10,273
39,805
4,983
74,935
38,417
9,94/
27,760
9,695
11,493
17,069
10,848
3,844

.03
.22
.18
.57
.35
.20
.52
.94
2,26
.22
,43
3,07
.28