View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Tenure Choice with Location Selection:
The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and
Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP 2003-05

TENURE CHOICE WITH LOCATION SELECTION:
THE CASE OF HISPANIC NEIGHBORHOODS IN CHICAGO

Maude Toussaint-Comeau
Sherrie L.W. Rhine
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Abstract

A notable feature of immigration into the U.S. is the high degree of spatial
concentration of different immigrant groups. We ask the question whether
residing in areas with a large proportion of a co-ethnic group influence the
decision to own a home for Hispanics in the Chicago Metropolitan area. The
results show that Hispanics choose to live in Hispanic enclaves based on
relatively homogeneous characteristics such as recent migration, less English
language fluency, and lower income. More years in the U.S., higher education
attainment and English language fluency remain strong predictors of
homeownership. Individuals are less likely to be homeowners in communities with
a larger co-ethnic concentration, foreign-born residents, or lower-income
families. (JEL C35, J1, R12)

TENURE CHOICE WITH LOCATION SELECTION:
THE CASE OF HISPANIC NEIGHBORHOODS IN CHICAGO
MAUDE TOUSSAINT-COMEAU and SHERRIE L.W.RHINE*

I.

INTRODUCTION
The tendency for immigrant groups to locate where other co-ethnic groups have already

settled (in ethnic enclaves) is a common process resulting from the need (or preference) to
reunify with family members and other co-ethnic members and from initial unfamiliarity with
the country's labor and housing markets (Bartel, 1989). Immigrants may also settle where they
have the best opportunities for employment or where they can best use their skills, which may or
may not be in an ethnic enclave. Evidence suggests that an immigrant’s location choice (whether
in or outside an enclave, within the destination country) depends on his/her human capital
characteristics. Specifically, immigrants who choose to live in enclaves tend to have less
education, shorter periods of residency in the U.S., less general experience in the destination
country, and lower English proficiency (Funkhouser and Ramos, 1993).
The implications of spatial concentration for immigrant groups on various aspects of their
economic adjustments have spurred much interest among researchers. The impact of spatial
concentration has been analyzed for the labor market earnings of immigrant groups, their
propensity to be self-employed (Light et al., 1993), their investment in post-migration human
capital (Chiswick and Miller, 2002), and their participation in the political process (Portes and
Mozo, 1985). Although less studied, homeownership is another important aspect of immigrant
financial assimilation and the social/economic adjustment process that deserves attention (Alba
and Logan, 1992).
Ethnic enclaves may influence homeownership attainment of immigrant groups in several
ways. Rising housing prices in increasingly dense neighborhoods can encourage homeownership

2

as an investment (Borjas, 2002). Ethnic enclaves may also foster homeownership to the extent
that ethnic networks within enclaves can more effectively channel information flows about
house-ownership opportunities (Krivo, 1995). Conversely, if an immigrant group is concentrated
in an ethnic neighborhood where the supply of housing is more limited and possibly where
housing stock is of poor quality, this will likely result in lower homeownership gains for the
group (Krivo, 1995). Or, if an immigrant group is concentrated in a central city where housing
prices are relatively higher, these residents may be less likely to own a home due to affordability
constraints (Coulson, 1999). In particular, the more recently an immigrant group has migrated
and the poorer the immigrants are who reside in enclaves, the greater are the affordability
constraints and difficulties faced in meeting down payment requirements (McArdle, 1995).
The impact of ethnic spatial concentration on homeownership is unclear and previous
empirical research has shown somewhat conflicting evidence. Comparing various ethnic/racial
groups, Alba and Logan (1992) find that, as the proportion of Mexicans and Cubans in a
metropolitan area becomes larger, the likelihood of homeownership increases; while for other
groups such as Puerto Ricans and Vietnamese, the likelihood of homeownership decreases.
Similarly, Krivo (1995) maintains that the “immigrant context” decreases the likelihood of
homeownership among Hispanics--although the negative effect is more subdued for Mexicans
than non-Mexicans. In contrast, Borjas (2002) finds that in several major American cities ethnic
clustering increases the probability that immigrant households own their homes.
These studies suggest that the ethnic enclave context will have a direct impact on the
determination of tenure choice. At the same time, it is reasonable to assume that the decision to
reside in an ethnic enclave is not a random process. A number of factors are likely to influence
an immigrant’s decision to choose an “enclave” rather than a location with only a sparse number

3

of residents from its co-ethnic group. Enclaves offer an alternative means of cushioning the
relatively higher cost of integration that some immigrants may face (Chiswick and Miller, 2002).
Immigrants with less human capital may have greater difficulty in adapting or assimilating to the
new culture and therefore may have a greater reliance on living in an ethnic enclave. For similar
reasons, older immigrants also may choose such a location. Immigrants with less incentive to
invest in learning to speak a new language, such as those who plan to repatriate at some point in
the future, would tend to prefer to live with others who speak their language and share a similar
culture. To summarize, location choice is likely to be a function of immigrant status and human
capital characteristics --factors that at the same time impact the tenure decision. An immigrant’s
location choice and tenure decision is likely to be simultaneously (or endogenously) determined.
This paper is concerned with the issue of spatial concentration, an immigrant’s decision
to reside in an ethnic enclave and the impact of these conditions on homeownership. We propose
a framework for testing the hypothesis of the potential joint relationship between ethnic enclave
location choice and tenure choice. Specifically, we ask the question whether residing in areas
with a large proportion of a co-ethnic group influences the decision to own a home.
The analysis is applied to Hispanic households in distinct communities in the Chicago
metropolitan area. Similar to the trend in several other major U.S. cities, Hispanics are one of the
fastest growing populations in the Chicago metropolitan area, with distinct and growing
neighborhood concentrations throughout the area. Yet they have the lowest rate of
homeownership of all other racial/ethnic groups. Our analysis determines the factors affecting
homeownership for this group and in particular looks at the influence of residential segregation
(ethnic concentration) on homeownership.

4

The Chicago MSA is divided into 47 Public Use Micro Areas (PUMAs). PUMAs are the
smallest geographical units defined by the 1990 U.S. Census Public Use Micro Statistics, public
version of the data. Within the Chicago metropolitan area, PUMAs that are heavily populated by
Hispanics are identified and compared with other PUMAs that have an intermediate proportion
of Hispanics, and others where there are only few Hispanic residents. These smaller geographical
units allow us to identify specific Hispanic areas and potentially to capture some ethnic enclave
or ethnic affinity effects. This is in contrast to previous studies that have typically considered
only cross-metropolitan variation effects in analyzing the tenure decision.
From a policy perspective, the stability and population growth in these neighborhoods is
of much concern because of the likely changes in housing prices, neighborhood amenities and
community development needs. An important objective of this research is to also identify
potential ways to help better serve the housing needs in these ethnic communities.
This study is organized as follows: Section 2 provides a discussion about the survey data
and a description of the sample analyzed. Section 3 suggests the theoretical/econometric model.
Section 4 reports the findings from the empirical investigation. In the final section, we discuss
the potential implications from the analysis.
II.

DATA AND SAMPLE DESCRIPTION
The data used in this analysis are drawn from the Public Use Micro Statistics (PUMS) of

the 1990 U.S. Census, which represent a sample of 5 percent of the U.S. population. The data is
advantageous because it provides a sample of Hispanics that is larger than other surveys such as
the American Housing Survey and the Current Population Survey. More importantly this data
includes a wealth of information on immigration status, mobility history and language
proficiency that are important for our analysis.

5

Table 1 provides the definition and means of variables used in the analysis. For this
study, we restrict the sample to cover Hispanic households living in the Chicago MSA, with
heads of household 18 to 64 years of age, who either own or rent their primary residence, and
who had positive income. Educational attainment for heads of households in the total sample was
rather low, as the majority (54 percent) had less than 12 years of schooling. Close to 30 percent
reported that they do not speak English well or very well. Close to 70 percent are foreign-born
(while about 30 percent are born U.S. citizens). Consistent with the nation, the homeownership
rate for Hispanics in the Chicago metropolitan area sample was 46 percent (Joint Center for
Housing Study, 1999).
Typical of immigrant groups and low-income households, mobility was fairly high (Kan,
2000). Forty-six percent moved from a different state in the U.S; 4 percent moved from a
different area within the State of Illinois; and 9 percent came from a foreign country. Households
in ethnic enclaves seem to be much less mobile than those in other locations; 45 percent of
households in ethnic enclaves were non-movers compared to 38 percent of those who resided in
other locations. In general, one expects non-movers to be more prone to homeownership. To the
extent that this is true, the longer-term (non-movers) residents in the Hispanic neighborhoods
might be a source of favorable prospect for homeownership gains in the Hispanic ethnic
enclaves.
Surprisingly, movement across PUMA locations within the Chicago metropolitan area
was a fairly uncommon occurrence –only 2 percent undertook such a move. Typically, looking at
movement or the mobility of households has been used as an approach to understand location
choice (Boehm et al., 1991). Mobility is viewed as reflective of households’ responses to
variations in local labor market opportunities or differences in neighborhood amenities (e.g.

6

school quality). The fact that individual Hispanic households experienced such little mobility
within the Chicago area precludes us from testing the determinants of these households’
movement within this urban area. This raises an important question. What are the factors that
drive the “initial” location choice of the Hispanics within the Chicago metropolitan area? And
how does this choice influence and interact with tenure choice? Some plausible explanations are
offered looking more closely at the pattern of location for the group.
While the Hispanic population in the sample made up 10 percent of the population in the
entire Chicago MSA, one of the total of 47 PUMAs had an 86 percent population of households
who were of Hispanic origin. (It combines South Lawndale, known as Little Village and the
neighboring Lower West Side, known as Pilsen; two communities located on the southwest side
of the City of Chicago). This PUMA can be considered as the primary location of Hispanics in
the Chicago MSA. Another PUMA had 58 percent of its household population of Hispanic
origin. (It includes Rogers Park and Uptown, two areas on the north side of the City of Chicago).
This PUMA was considered the secondary location for Hispanics in the Chicago MSA for that
decennial. We combine the primary and secondary locations as enclaves with a majority
Hispanic population, referred to as HISPLOC for Hispanic locations or ethnic enclaves.1 All the
remaining PUMAs had a population of less than 26 percent Hispanic with most having 10
percent or less Hispanic households --they are classified as other locations. The clear
concentration of Hispanic households in these specific locations, while being sparsely populated
in each of the remaining locations of the Chicago metropolitan area, is consistent with the pattern
of inside-enclave/outside-enclave choice observed for many other immigrant groups
(Funkhouser and Ramos, 1993).

7

Table 1 also reports the mean characteristics of Hispanics based on the two distinctly
different residential locations; the predominantly Hispanic locations, HISPLOC, and the other
locations. A striking result is that Hispanics with the most human capital tend to locate outside
the areas with the largest concentration of Hispanics. Specifically, households in the HISPLOC
locations have on average less education and less proficiency in English, and have been in the
U.S. for a shorter period of time. These households also tend to have less income and lower
homeownership rates. The larger household size reported in HISPLOC is consistent with
findings reported for Hispanics in the Los Angeles metropolitan area (Krivo, 1995).
In the next section, we examine the question of whether the deliberate choice of insideenclave/outside-enclave locations, as promulgated by individuals’ socioeconomic characteristics
and immigrant status, also affects the tenure choice or homeownership attainment for the group.
III.

THEORETICAL/ECONOMETRIC FRAMEWORK
Economic theory suggests that an individual maximizes utility through decisions made

based on marginal cost, marginal benefit calculations. Since the net benefit of the choice taken is
not directly observable, the resulting outcome of the choice is modeled as an unobservable
variable (y*). In the case of a tenure choice model, it is assumed that there is a latent variable
(y*) that measures the tendency of an individual toward ownership. Building from a consumer
choice theoretical framework, we propose to model the household’s decision of whether or not to
own a home with a binomial probit model.
Prob[own a home| x] = Φ(β’ x)
where Φ (t) denotes the CDF of the normal distribution and x denotes those covariates
that influence the choice made. The decision of owning is influenced by an individual’s
socioeconomic, demographic, and life-cycle covariates as well as the location choice. The

8

dependent variable, y1 = OWNHOME, is equal to one if the household owns his home and
equals zero otherwise.
An important consideration is the possibility that an individual’s initial decision to reside
in an enclave as opposed to outside an enclave influences tenure choice. Studies that focus on
native groups have used a multinomial/nested logit technique to model the location choices that
tend to span across many places (e.g. Deng et al, 2003). Our study draws upon the immigrant
location choice literature. We consider the choice of location to fall within an insideenclave/outside-enclave choice set. As such, the probit specification is appropriate to model this
binary decision. Specifically, the variable, y2 = HISPLOC, is equal to one if the household
chooses to reside in an enclave and equals zero otherwise.
The full model is
y1* = β′ x1 + γy2 + є1 ,

y1 = 1 if y1* > 0,

y2* = α′ x2 + є2 ,

y2 = 1 if y2* > 0, 0 otherwise,

0 otherwise,

(1)
(2)

where x1 includes the characteristics described by x and x2 represents the factors that influence
the location decision. The disturbances are jointly normally distributed with
E[є 1] = E[ є 2] = 0,
Var[є 1] = Var[є 2] = 1,
Corr[ є 1, є 2] = ρ,
The joint decision is described by the probability model,
Prob [y1 = 1, y2 = 1] = Prob [y1 = 1 | y2 = 1] × Prob [y2 = 1]
= {BVN(y1=1, y2 = 1)/Prob[y2 = 1]} × Prob[y2 = 1],

(3)

where BVN denotes the CDF of the bivariate normal distribution. If we insert the variables of
our model and include the two parameter vectors, the preceding can be rewritten as

9

Prob [y1 = 1, y2 = 1] = [BVN (β′ x1 + γ, α′ x2, ρ) / Φ(α′ x2)] × Φ (α′ x2 ).

(4)

After canceling terms, this produces the bivariate probability
Prob[y1=1, y2=1] = BVN(β′ x1 + γ, α′ x2 , ρ)
where β, γ, α, ρ are the parameters to be estimated. The three remaining cases are:
Prob [y1 = 1, y2 = 0] = BVN(β′ x1 , -α′ x2 , -ρ),
Prob [y1 = 0, y2 = 1] = BVN (-β′ x1 - γ, α′ x2, -ρ), and
Prob [y1 = 0, y2 = 0] = BVN (-β′ x1 - γ, -α′ x2, ρ).
Therefore, despite initial appearances, these terms enter the usual likelihood function for the
bivariate probit model. Contrary to what intuition might suggest, the result shows that the
presence of y2 in the first equation does not cause a “simultaneity” problem. The model can be
consistently and efficiently estimated as the bivariate probit model, as stated, by maximum
likelihood as if there were no joint determination in the first equation.2
The bivariate probit technique is estimated to ascertain whether the probability of
choosing a location (HISPLOC = 1) is jointly determined with tenure choice (OWNHOME). The
model includes a correlation between the latent (unobserved) effects in the HISPLOC and
OWNHOME equations. Should the correlation coefficient, ρ, be statistically different from zero,
we conclude that the tenure decision is not only directly affected by the location decision but also
is indirectly influenced through household effects (such as unmeasured preference, culture
effects, or neighborhood-specific effects) which are not explicit in the model. We do note that
our specification is an extension of the standard probit model where ρ = 0. However, even if ρ
equals 0, the two household’s decisions are not viewed as independent since y2 appears in the y1
equation. The next section explains the motivations behind inclusion of specific covariates in the
empirical estimate counterpart of the theoretical model and discusses the results.

10

IV.

EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION

Life-cycle and Demographic Variables
There is agreement in the literature that tenure choice depends on life-cycle (including
family structure) and demographic variables (Goodman, 1990). Following this convention,
marital status, MARRIED, size of the household, HHSIZE, and whether or not dependent
children are present, DEPENDENT, are included. They serve as indicator variables of the tastes
and preference for homeownership. Age of the head of household is controlled for in a nonlinear
fashion using a series of dummy variables for selected age groups. For example, AGE24 is equal
to 1 if the head of household is 18 to 24 years of age, zero otherwise. The remaining age
categories are defined in a similar way. Finally, the indicator variable, MEXICO, is equal to 1 if
the head of household’s place of birth is Mexico or zero otherwise. This characteristic controls
for differences in homeownership between those of Mexican and non-Mexican national origin.
Immigration, Assimilation, and Mobility Variables
The immigrant experience of Hispanics has important implications for homeownership
outcomes for several reasons. First, the intricacies of the home purchase process require a certain
level of financial acumen and mastery of the English language which may be more difficult for
some non-native English speaking immigrants (Cheney and Cheney, 1997; Ratner, 1997;
Hamilton and Cogswell, 1997). Acquired English language fluency is an important human
capital attribute for immigrants and is an indicator of potentially greater assimilation and
integration into the mainstream financial system. It might be expected that immigrants with
greater English language fluency are more likely to be a homeowner. Conversely, in a Hispanic
neighborhood context where transactions may be conducted in Spanish, a lack of English
language fluency may not necessarily hamper ownership. NOENGL, whether the head of

11

household reported that he/she speaks English “not well” or “not at all” is included to determine
the influence that this lack of human capital has on homeownership.
Second, unfamiliarity with the U.S. credit system may result in households being less
informed about opportunities that could increase their ability to purchase a home. It has been
suggested that a limited understanding of the U.S. credit system may also cause some immigrants
to be less willing to absorb the debt necessary in the home purchase process (Gerlin, 1996).
Therefore, the length of time a person has resided in the U.S. is important. From a lender's point
of view, the length of time a person has resided at a particular address in the U.S. can be
considered for lending qualification or underwriting purposes (Warren, 1995). Hence the longer
a person has lived in the U.S., the less his/her immigrant status should influence the likelihood of
homeownership. Length of time since migration is controlled for in a nonlinear fashion with
dummies for incremental years since migration. Numerical suffixes are used to denote the
number of years. For example, YSM5 is equal to 1 if the head migrated less than 5 years prior to
the survey. We also include an indicator variable for whether the head is an U.S. born citizen,
USCIT (note, in which case, years since migration is equal to zero). Whether the head of
household is a naturalized citizen, NATRL_CIT, is included as an indicator variable for
integration or assimilation potential.
Following previous research that has shown that mobility is important to the tenure
decision (Painter, 2000; Kan, 2000), the model also controls for geographic mobility by
including relevant indicator variables. MOVE_US indicates whether the head of household’s
residence 5 years earlier was in another state. MOVE_IL indicates whether the individual moved
from a different location within the state of Illinois to the Chicago metropolitan area, while,
MOVE_PUMA denotes whether a move was made across PUMAs in the Chicago metropolitan

12

area. The relationship between mobility and homeownership is expected to be negative given the
transactions and moving costs associated with selling a home (Boehm et al., 1991).
Socioeconomic Variables
Household income has been used as an indicator for the effects of nominal housing
affordability on household tenure choice. As is customary, both permanent and transitory
components of household income are included (Goodman and Kawai, 1982). Permanent income,
PERMANINC, is the predicted value of the measured income estimated by a regression on a set
of instrumental variables related to human capital and other characteristics, while transitory
income, TRANSINC, is the difference between the observed measured household income and
predicted income. Permanent income is expected to have a positive influence on homeownership.
Transitory income may be less important as the typical costs associated with the home purchase
process (i.e., transactions, search and moving costs) are so substantial that they may not be
covered by transitory income (Goodman, 1990).
Educational attainment is controlled for with a series of indicator variables reflecting
whether the head of household completed college or beyond, COLLEGE, or graduated from high
school, HIGHSCHOOL. Schooling level is viewed in the literature as one potential indicator of
wealth prospect and is used here as a proxy for wealth-related taste for homeownership.
Housing Prices
To the extent that homeownership is viewed as an investment, greater expectations for
future increases in housing value for a given area will induce an individual toward
homeownership in that area. As such, we might expect individuals located in areas with higher
housing values to have a greater propensity for owner-occupied housing than individuals who
reside in areas where housing values are lower. On the other hand, higher housing prices may

13

lead to greater affordability constraints, especially for lower-income and more recent immigrant
groups. Studies have shown that Hispanics have lower income levels relative to other
ethnic/racial groups. Therefore, home affordability is likely to be relevant for their tenure choice.
Gyourko and Linneman (1996) used the 25th percentile of the log housing value in an MSA as an
indicator variable to capture the costs of a typical inexpensive home and median rent value to
capture local housing prices. We follow their approach by including HOMEVAL, the 25th
percentile of the log housing value in each PUMA to control for local housing affordability. The
median rent in the PUMA, MEDRENT, also is included to control for the typical cost of renting
in the PUMA. Areas with relatively high housing values or low rents may be expected to
lengthen the transition to homeownership (Painter et al., 2000).
Location Variables
In the empirical analysis, HISPLOC, the indicator variable for Hispanic locations, is
included to measure the direct impact of residing in an ethnic enclave on the likelihood of
homeownership attainment.
An index of ethnic concentration is also developed to capture the effect of ethnic
clustering or ethnic networks within a location, independent of Hispanic location housing market
fixed effects. This variable, ETHNAFF, or ethnic affinity is defined by
ETHNAFF = Nlp / Np
Where Nlp is the total number of persons born in the same country of origin, ethnicity or
ancestry (l) as the householder and who live in his/her PUMA (p). Np is the total number of
persons who live in the PUMA (p) using the entire population of persons enumerated by the U.S.
Census as residing in the PUMA area. In essence, this variable is included to capture the extent
to which a higher proportion of people who share the same ethnic background within these
defined areas influence the likelihood of homeownership. ETHNAFF is similar to the Exposure
14

Index concept used in Borjas (2002) to measure ethnic clustering within metropolitan areas. The
index used in this study, however, is a more concise measure since it is defined at the PUMA
level.3 In addition, unlike previous studies we include a quadratic term to investigate potential
non-linearity in the relationship between ethnic concentration and homeownership.4
A priori, the directional influence of ETHNAFF on homeownership is uncertain. One
hypothesis is that the higher the value of the ETHNAFF index the greater the affinity or sense of
belonging and thereby a heightened potential for ethnic networks to help promote
homeownership. The potential benefits of ethnic affinity, however, may be somewhat offset by
the hampering effect of higher concentrations of individuals who face relatively greater
economic and financial constraints. If true, as ethnic concentration rises, there may be a lower
likelihood for homeownership (McArdle, 1995). To investigate these possibilities, we also add
indicator variables to control for resident-location characteristics including the percent of
households with low income (PCT_POOR), the percent of households who are foreign-born
(PCT_FORGN), and the percent of households who are not fluent in English (PCT_NOENGL).5
Empirical Results
The decision to locate in a predominantly Hispanic enclave, HISPLOC, is expected to
influence the household’s tenure choice (OWNHOME). The results from Table 2 for the
HISPLOC equation concur that life-cycle and demographic characteristics such as marital status
and the number of persons in the household significantly influence this decision for Hispanics. In
addition, assimilation indicator variables such as English language fluency and whether an
individual is a naturalized citizen influence where a household chooses to live. Socioeconomic
factors such as permanent income and transitory income also have a significant influence on the
location decision. Access to ethnic networks has a positive influence on the decision to reside in

15

a Hispanic enclave. Individuals who are more mobile, those who had moved from a different
location within the U.S, the State of Illinois, or PUMA have a decreased tendency to choose to
reside in Hispanic enclaves.
The bivariate probit model estimates for the tenure decision are reported in Table 3. We
develop these OWNHOME models by initially considering a simple specification that excludes
mobility. The first specification determines that the choice of location (HISPLOC) significantly
influences the homeownership decision. As expected, the second specification, which includes
controls for mobility shows that more mobile households are significantly less likely to be
homeowners than their less mobile or non-mover counterparts. Interestingly, the coefficient of
HISPLOC becomes statistically insignificant, suggesting that to a great extent the positive
influence of Hispanic location was promulgated by the ownership-prone, non-mover residents in
these locations.
We then introduce ethnic affinity and resident-location (neighborhood) effects into the
model to gain a clearer understanding about how these characteristics influence the Hispanic
enclave and homeownership decisions. This step-wise approach allows us to determine whether
these decisions are also affected by potential unmeasured household preference or other latent
effects not explicit in the model, yet captured by the correlation coefficient, ρ. In the third
specification, the estimated coefficients for ethnic networks and its square term have a significant
influence on the homeownership decision.
How important neighborhood characteristics are to the homeownership decision are
explored in the fourth model reported in Table 3. The findings from this model suggest that
homeownership is less likely for those who also choose to reside in a Hispanic enclave and when
the location is more heavily represented by lower-income (PCT_POOR) or foreign-born

16

(PCT_FORGN) individuals. Conversely, living in areas where there is a higher percentage of
residents who do not speak English well (PCT_NOENGL) increases the likelihood of
homeownership. Consistent with the ethnic enclave hypothesis, a higher concentration of
individuals who do speak English well does not directly impede the potential for
homeownership. After controlling for neighborhood effects, the estimated coefficient on ρ is
insignificant, suggesting that the model has aptly controlled for potential latent effects
influencing the enclave and homeownership decisions. A compelling result is that the effect of
ethnic affinity is largely offset (becomes statistically insignificant) when the model includes the
neighborhood characteristics, suggesting that part of the negative effect of ethnic affinity can be
explained by its interaction with a larger concentration of immigrant households with financial
constraints in ethnic enclaves. This result gives added insights into nuances in the dynamics of
neighborhood characteristics that are implicated in the treatment of ethnic concentration in the
analysis.
Marginal Effects
Marginal effects for the final model are computed to determine the magnitude of
influence that the covariants have on the probability that individuals who choose an enclave own
a home. The conditional probability, Prob[OWNHOME=1|HISPLOC=1], includes both a direct
and an indirect effect. From the model structure in equation (4), the probability is
Prob[OWNHOME=1|HISPLOC=1] = Prob [y1 = 1| y2 = 1]
= Prob [y1 = 1, y2 = 1] / Prob[y2 = 1].
A variable of interest can appear in both probabilities. The direct and indirect effects can be seen
by assuming that the variable is continuous and differentiating the probability. Denoting the
influence by z, we have

17

Prob [y1= 1,y2= 1] / ∂ z = ∂ Prob (y1= 1,y2= 1) / ∂ z (∂Prob (y2= 1) / ∂ z) Prob (y1= 1,y2= 1)
____________________ _ ________________________________
Prob (y2= 1)
[Prob (y2= 1)]2
= direct + indirect effect.
An attribute’s total marginal effect in the homeownership model is the sum of its direct
and indirect effects. The direct effect is produced by the attribute’s presence in the first equation,
OWNHOME. The indirect effect is also produced if this same attribute is included in the second
equation, HISPLOC. Accordingly, the total marginal effect on OWNHOME is the sum of the
direct and indirect effects for those attributes that are specified in both equations. Attributes that
are included in the second equation directly influence the probability of choosing a Hispanic
enclave. This effect is transmitted back to the first equation through the attribute, HISPLOC,
which appears in the OWNHOME equation, thus exerting the secondary, or indirect effect. For
the variables on the right-hand side of the OWHHOME equation that are binary, the marginal
effects are computed by evaluating the conditional probability with these set equal to one then
zero, with other variables fixed at the sample means, so the decomposition is implicit.
The total marginal effects reported in Table 4 are based on the condition that a
householder chooses a Hispanic enclave (HISPLOC = 1). For ease of interpretation, this
condition will not be repeated but holds nonetheless throughout the discussion in this section. As
shown in Table 4, homeownership increases by 12.6 percentage points due to higher educational
attainment, COLLEGE; and by 6.3 percentage points due to HIGHSCHOOL. The positive
influence of higher educational attainment, COLLEGE and HIGHSCHOOL, on homeownership
is somewhat lessened when we consider the indirect effect. Moreover, the negative effect of
English language deficiency on homeownership is less substantial (direct effect = -11.5; indirect

18

effect = 3.7; total effects –7.8 when we account for location selection’s indirect effect). Hence
these human capital factors exert a somewhat lessened impact on homeownership in the context
of an immigrant/ethnic enclave.
The influence of being in a particular age group reveals expected life-cycle effects. For
example, younger householders (AGE24 and AGE34) are less likely than those in the 35 to 44
age category (AGE44) to own a home. Conversely, older householders are more likely than
those in the 35 to 44 age group to own a home.
Years since migration show a similar cycle. The likelihood of being a homeowner for
those with shorter stays in the U.S. (YSM5 and YSM10) is less than for those who have lived in
the U.S. 11 to 20 years (YSM20). On the other hand, those who have remained in the U.S. from
21 to 40 years are more likely to be a homeowner than those who have been in the U.S. 11 to 20
years. Being a naturalized or U.S. born citizen increases the likelihood of owning a home by 1.5
and 4.4 percentage points, respectively. These results are consistent with the proposition that
more years residing in the U.S. or being a citizen signal a greater commitment and incentive to
invest in homeownership in this country.
An increase in permanent income significantly increases the probability of owning a
home by 2.7 percentage points. By comparison, an increase in average home prices in a PUMA
lowers the likelihood of homeownership for this Hispanic sample. Recalling that this variable is
defined as a proportion, an increase by 10 percent in home values in a PUMA decreases the
probability of homeownership by 2.4 percentage points.
Whether or not households are mobile plays a strong role in the decision to purchase a
home. Relative to non-movers, those who move from another part of the state of Illinois or from
another state in the U.S. are less likely to be homeowners by 14.7 and 32.9 percentage points,

19

respectively. This finding is consistent with Painter (2000) who determines that recent movers
are much less likely to own, while homeowners tend to be less mobile.
As for the neighborhood characteristics, the results show that a 10 percent increase in the
proportion of low-income or foreign-born families in the PUMA decreases the likelihood of
homeownership by 1.4 and 0.3 percentage points. Finally, an increase in the concentration of
individuals who do not speak English fluently increases the likelihood of homeownership, albeit
the influence is negligible.
The second alternative, Prob[OWNHOME=1|HISPLOC=0] was also considered.6
Generally, the estimated marginal effects mirror those reported in Table 3 where HISPLOC = 1.
This suggests that regardless of location choice, whether inside-enclaves or outside-enclaves,
these characteristics remain important to the homeownership decision.
V.

POLICY DISCUSSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Purchasing a home is one of the largest and most important financial investment

decisions made by a household. For many families, homeownership is a foundation for financial
asset building and future wealth accumulation. Increased homeownership also has been linked to
improved property maintenance, higher property values, greater community involvement and
enhanced neighborhood stability (Rohe and Stewart, 1996; Cox, 1982). The opportunity to
become a homeowner, therefore, contributes to a community’s overall economic stability and
growth.
Homeownership is an indication of immigrant integration into the U.S. labor, financial
and credit markets and shows a commitment to invest in a particular neighborhood. Although
Hispanics are the fastest growing minority group in the U.S., they are among those groups with
the lowest homeownership rates. This study determines that homeownership is less likely for

20

individuals if they are younger, lack English proficiency, are less educated, have resided in the
U.S. for shorter periods of time, or tend to be mobile. They are also less likely to be
homeowners in communities with larger proportions of co-ethnic, foreign-born residents or
lower-income families.
The findings point to the tendency for human capital attributes to exert a somewhat lower
impact on homeownership in the context of an ethnic enclave. A number of explanations could
support the results that not speaking English fluently or being an immigrant is somewhat less of
an impediment for Hispanics when a mostly Hispanic residential location is selected. Intuitively,
it is possible that individuals in Hispanic neighborhoods may have greater opportunities to
conduct home purchase transactions in Spanish. Also, financial service providers may be taking
steps (e.g., having Spanish-speaking loan officers) toward removing language barriers from the
home purchase or financial intermediation process in neighborhoods where there is a visibly
larger Hispanic market (Kelderhouse, 2002).
Notwithstanding, we found that limited education and language difficulties may serve as
serious constraints for this group in terms of becoming homeowners. In the short term, a
potentially important policy response might be to offer credit and home financing information in
Spanish so that individuals can make informed financial decisions concerning a home purchase.
Distributing product and information brochures in Spanish is becoming more a common practice
by some financial institutions and may help provide useful information to Hispanics. To help
bridge language/cultural differences, financial institutions also have become more proactive in
employing a culturally diverse staff (e.g., Spanish-speaking loan officers). Moreover, a greater
number of community leaders, government agencies and financial institutions are partnering to
create and offer financial education programs to Hispanic immigrants in their communities.7

21

Our analysis finds that the likelihood of homeownership is lower when housing
prices/values are higher. Given that housing prices affect the ability of these lower-income
Hispanic households to consider homeownership, this finding speaks to the need for policy
makers to continue to direct their efforts toward promoting affordable housing initiatives and
community economic development.8 Toward a longer-term remedy, the low-income Hispanic
communities in this metropolitan area could benefit from active community development and
housing development initiatives. According to a recent study for the Fannie Mae Foundation,
successful practices for promoting affordable homeownership include low downpayment,
absence of mortgage insurance, higher qualifying ratios, consideration of alternative or
nontraditional credit qualification proofs, latitude in proof of immigrant status, closing cost
assistance programs, and in-language homeownership education or counseling.9 There is also an
innovative sweat equity practice that has apparently created sustainable homeownership for verylow income immigrant buyers.10
The Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) of 1977 encourages financial institutions to
help meet the credit needs of their local communities, including low- and moderate-income
neighborhoods, consistent with the institutions’ safe and sound banking practices. According to a
study by Haag (2000), CRA has contributed to the recent gains in the rate of mortgage lending
among lower-income and minority households. In addition, greater availability of affordable
housing has resulted from various programs offering low down payment and/or governmentsecured mortgage loans (e.g., FHA lending and low-interest mortgage financing).
What can be said however of the specific case of Hispanic neighborhoods in the Chicago
area? First and foremost, community development opportunities to promote flexible home loan
programs have been an important strategy to increase homeownership for low-income Hispanics.

22

It is instructive to illustrate the actual experience of the South Lawndale area, one of the
Hispanic enclaves in the City of Chicago. In many ways, the actual experience in this
community’s housing market underscores the importance of developing clear targeted economic
development initiatives to meet the special needs of emerging Hispanic communities.
South Lawndale (commonly referred to as Little Village) is a relatively stable residential
and business community. The profusion of advertising signs that are written in Spanish along its
main business strip (26th street) mirrors the culture of that community. Eighty-three percent of
the community residents are Hispanic, primarily from Mexico. Thirty-seven percent of all
housing units are owner-occupied. The housing units are very old. For example, as of 1990,
more than half of the housing structures were built prior to 1940. While the total housing units in
Little Village remained virtually unchanged from its 1960 level, the population has substantially
increased (e.g., 33 percent between 1960 and 1990). Because the Hispanic population has
outpaced the creation of new housing stock, this created severe overcrowding in the area. This
community had in fact the highest rate of overcrowded housing among the communities in the
City of Chicago, with four times the rate experienced in the City as a whole in 1990 (Chicago
Fact Book Consortium, 1995). Because of very high increases in housing prices in the later part
of the 1990s and early 2000s, housing affordability remains a challenge.
Nonetheless, Little Village experienced a steady increase in the number of home sales
and mortgage-related loans in the 1990’s.11 The continued strength in home sales and mortgage
financing has contributed to this community’s vitality. The latest 2000 Census data shows that
homeowner housing units vacancy rate is only 1.5 percent, compared to 7 percent in 1990. What
has been done in this community to sustain its robust housing market? In 1994, Little Village
was designated as an empowerment zone to help meet its unique housing and economic

23

development. This spawned several innovative housing and economic development programs
and initiatives.12 Projects such as those led by non-profit organizations and or in partnerships
with banks typify initiatives that are being taken to address the housing and economic
development needs of the community. For example, the Resurrection Project, a non-profit
organization whose main service area is Little Village and neighboring Pilsen produced 160
housing units between 1992 and 1999 in these communities. Among ways they have approached
these projects include partnering with over 12 financial institutions to provide end financing at
low rates with down payments of as low as 5 percent.13 According to a report about the
Resurrection Project, 80 percent of the homeowners in those new units had previously lived in
the community and 63 percent are low-income. This fact is consistent with the study’s finding
that long-term residents in this primary Hispanic enclave in the Chicago area may serve as a
catalyst for homeownership gains in the community. Overall, while listing the scope of projects
that has been done and their impact is beyond the scope of the paper, it is nevertheless
encouraging that efforts are being made to successfully promote homeownership and community
development in a targeted fashion in the community.
In conclusion, the methodology developed in this paper could be applied to other
metropolitan areas. Indeed, it is hoped that this paper will encourage researchers to conduct
similar analyses for other areas, other racial/ethnic groups, and other time periods. Doing so will
not only test the robustness of our approach but will also help us to better understand the
determinants of immigrant homeownership in diverse settings. This study focuses on a single
metropolitan area. The fact that the actual choice of a primary Hispanic location is not
necessarily an impediment for homeownership possibly due to its long term-residents who
choose to own in that community may not be typical of other Hispanic neighborhoods in other

24

metropolitan areas. Nevertheless, our discussion of the actual activities in one of the Hispanic
areas illustrates the importance of targeted housing development projects to help increase access
to affordable housing in low-income Hispanic communities. This is likely to be relevant for
many other Hispanic neighborhoods across other metropolitan areas in the U.S.
As an additional consideration, we recognize that the financial integration of households
and whether households have a relationship with the formal financial sector (that is, have a
transaction accounts at a bank) will likely play an important role in determining whether
households have access to credit for a home mortgage. Given that Hispanic households are much
less likely to be banked, this may be a consideration for future immigrant homeownership.
Future research may also benefit from an investigation of other potential factors that may be
important toward addressing issues related to access to credit and financial services. These
include attitudes toward borrowing and preferences for or access to alternative and/or informal
credit sources.
The results show that an increase in ethnic concentration dampens the prospect of
homeownership. From an immigration policy perspective, do these findings suggest that ethnic
concentration should be discouraged? We propose that the answer to this question is no.
Concentrations of immigrants tend to be a first-generation or at most a second-generation
phenomenon. New data from the 2000 U.S. Census points to a strikingly large dispersion of
Hispanic communities across the Chicago metropolitan area. This suggests that Hispanic
immigrant populations are mobile over time. Gains in human capital such as English language
proficiency and education, socioeconomic integration and mobility outside of concentrated
enclaves are likely to occur naturally over time. As such, we expect future homeownership rates
to rise for Hispanics, potentially more so in locations outside of the traditional Hispanic enclave.

25

The most effective policy for Hispanics may be to allow the self-correcting mechanism already
underway to continue.
REFERENCES
Alba, R. D. and J. R. Logan. “Assimilation and Stratification in the Homeownership
Patterns of Racial and Ethnic Groups,” International Migration Review, Vol. XXVI, No. 4,
Winter, 1992, 1314-1341.
Bartel, A. “ Where Do the New Immigrant Live?” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 7,
No. 4, October 1989, 371-379.
Boehm, T. P., H. W. Herzog, Jr. and A. M. Schlottmann. "Intra Urban Mobility,
Migration, and Tenure Choice," The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. LXXII, No. 1,
February 1991, 59-68.
Borjas, J. G. “Homeownership in the Immigrant Population,” Working paper No. 02-01,
Research Institute for Housing America, March 2002.
Cheney, S.A. and C.C. Cheney. “Adaptation and Homebuying of Latin American and
Indian Immigrants in Montgomery County, Maryland,” The Journal of Policy Development and
Research, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Vol. 3 (1), March, 1997, 39-61.
Chicago Fact Book Consortium. Local Community Fact Book-Chicago Metropolitan
Area 1990, Chicago, Academy Chicago Publishers, 1995.
Chiswick, B. and P. W. Miller. “Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrant Adjustment?”
Unpublished paper, Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 2002.
Coulson, E. “Why are Hispanic- and Asian-American Homeownership Rates so Low?
Immigration and Other Factors,” Journal of Urban Economics 45, 1999, 209-227.

26

Cox, K. “Housing Tenure and Neighborhood Activism,” Urban Affairs Quarterly 18,
1982, 107-129.
Cutler, D., and E. L. Glaeser. “Are Ghettos Good or Bad?” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112, August 1997, 827-872.
Deng, Y; S. L. Ross and S. M. Wachter. “Racial Differences in Homeownership: The
Effect of Residential Location,” Regional Science and Urban Economics, Forthcoming, 2003.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. “What can Bankers eager to Capture this Market do?
Techniques for Reaching the Latino Immigrant Population,” Bridges, Community Affairs
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Autumn 2002, 4-5. www.stlouisfed.org.
Funkhouser, E. and F. A. Ramos. “The Choice of Migration Destination: Dominican and
Cuban Americans to the Mainland United States and Puerto Rico,” International Migration
Review, 27, 1993, 537-556.
Gerlin, A. “In This Texas Town Their Favorite Bank is Mattress Savings,” Wall Street
Journal, October 31, 1996, A1.
Goodman, A. C. “Demographics of Individual Housing Demand,” Regional Science and
Urban Economics 20, 1990, 83-102.
Goodman, A. C and M. Kawai. “Permanent Income, Hedonic Prices and Demand for
Housing: New Evidence,” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 23, 1982, 214-237.
Greene, W. H. Econometric Analysis, Fifth Edition, Prentice hall, New Jersey, 2003.
Gyourko, J. and P. Linneman. “Analysis of the Changing Influences on Traditional
Households’ Ownership Patterns,” Journal of Urban Economics 39, 1996, 318-341.
Haag, S. W. “Community Reinvestment and Cities: A Literature Review of CRA's
Impact and Future,“ A Discussion Paper, The Brooking Institution, March, 2000.

27

Hamilton, S. and S. J. H. Cogswell. “Barriers to Home Purchase for African-Americans
and Hispanics in Syracuse,“ The Journal of Policy Development and Research, U.S. Department
of Housing and Urban Development, Vol. 3, No. 1, March 1997, 91-130.
Joint Center for Housing Studies. The State of the Nation’s Housing, Joint Center for
Housing Studies of Harvard University, 1999.
Kan, K. “Dynamic Modeling of Housing Tenure Choice,” Journal of Urban Economics,
Vol. 48, No. 1, 2000, 46-69.
Kelderhouse, E. R. “Banking Latino Immigrants: A Lucrative New Market for
Progressive Financial Institutions,” Bridges, Community Affairs Department of the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Autumn 2002, www.stlouisfed.org.
Krivo, L. “Immigrant Characteristics and Hispanic-Anglo Housing Inequality,”
Demography, Vol. 32, Issue 4, November, 1995, 599-615.
Light, I., P. Bhachu, and S. Karageorgies. “Immigrant Networks and Entrepreneurship.”
In Immigration and Entrepreneurship, edited by Ivan Light and Parminder Bhachu, New
Brunswick NJ, 1993.
McArdle, N. and G. S. Masnick. “The Changing Face of America’s Homebuyers,”
Mortgage Banking, Vol. 56, December, 1995, 3-16.
Painter, G. “Tenure Choice with Sample Selection: Differences among Alternative
Samples,” Journal of Housing Economics 9, 2000, 1997-.
Painter, G., G. Stuart and D. Myers. “The Decision to Own: The Impact of Race,
Ethnicity and Immigrant Status,” Research Institute for Housing America, Working Paper, No.
00-02, June, 2000.

28

Portes A. and R. Mozo. “The Political Adaptation Process of Cubans and Other Ethnic
Minorities in the United States: A Preliminary Analysis,” International Migration Review, Vol.
XIX, No. 1, 35-63.
Ratner, M. “Ethnographic Studies of Homeownership and Home Mortgage Financing:
An Introduction,” The Journal of Policy Development and Research, U.S. Department of
Housing and Urban Development, Vol. 3, No. 1, March, 1997, 1-11.
Rohe, W. M., and L. Steward. “Homeownership and Neighborhood Stability,” Housing
Policy Debate, Vol. 7, 1996, 37-81.
Schill, M. H., S. Friedman and E. Rosembaum. “The Housing Conditions of Immigrants
in New York City,” Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 9, Issue 9, 1998, 201-235.
Schoenholtz A. I and K. Stanton. Reaching the Immigrant Market: Creating
Homeownership Opportunities for New Americans, Fannie Mae Foundation,
www.fanniemaefoundation.org, 2001.
Stegman, M. A. State and Local Affordable-Housing Programs: A Rich Tapestry, Urban
Land Institute, Washington D.C., 1999.
Warren, D. “Fair Lending and Credit Scoring,” Mortgage Banking, Vol. 56, November,
1995, 55-58.

29

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
Hispanics in the Chicago MSA
Variables
OWNHOME
PERMANINC
TRANSINC
MARRIED
AGE24
AGE34
AGE44
AGE54
AGE64
COLLEGE
HIGHSCHOOL
ENGLWELL
NOENGL
USCIT
NATRL_CIT
YSM5
YSM10
YSM20
YSM30
YSM40
YSM50
HHSIZE
DEPENDENT
MEXICO
HOMEVAL
MEDRENT
ETHNAFF
HISPLOC
MOVE_PUMA
MOVE_IL
MOVE_US
MOVE_FORGN
NON MOVERS
PCT_POOR
PCT_FORGN
PCT_NOENGL

Definition of Variables

Total
Sample

HISPLOC
Locations

Other
Locations

1 if owns with mortgage or own free and clear, = 0 if rent.
Predicted values of log of income.
Residuals of log of income.
1 if married, =0 otherwise.
1 if age is 18 to 24, = 0 otherwise.
1 if age is 25 to 34, = 0 otherwise.
1 if age is 35 to 44, = 0 otherwise.
1 if age is 45 to 54, = 0 otherwise.
1 if age is 55 to 64, = 0 otherwise.
1 if college degree and beyond, = 0 otherwise.
1 if HS diploma or equivalent, = 0 otherwise.
1 if speak English “well” or “very well,” = 0 otherwise.
1 if speak English “not well” or “not at all,” = 0 otherwise.
1 if born in U.S. or is of American parents, = 0 otherwise.
1 if was born abroad and is naturalized, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is 5 years or less, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is 6 to 10, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is 11 to 20, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is 21 to 30, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is 31 to 40, = 0 otherwise.
1 if years since migration is over 40, = 0 otherwise.
1 Number of persons in household.
1 if dependent children present, = 0 otherwise.
1 if place of birth is Mexico, = 0 otherwise.
25th quartile of log value of home in PUMA.
Median value of rent in PUMA.
Ratio of people in PUMA with same place of birth, ethnic
origin, or ancestry with respondent to total number of
population in the PUMA.
1 for PUMAs with 86 percent and 58 percent Hispanic,
respectively, = 0 for all other PUMAs.
1 if moved from within PUMAs, = 0 otherwise.
1 if moved from within Illinois, = 0 otherwise.
1 if moved from within U.S., = 0 otherwise.
1 if moved from a foreign country, = 0 otherwise.
1 if did not move in the last 5 years, = 0 otherwise.
Percent of family household in PUMA who have low
income (less than 80 percent of the MSA median income)
Percent of family household in PUMA who are foreign
born.
Percent of family households in PUMA who do not speak
“not well or not at all”.
Sample size

0.48
9.36

0.20

0.37
9.26
-0.06
0.54
0.25
0.33
0.25
0.12
0.05
0.01
0.37
0.58
0.36
0.23
0.16
0.14
0.32
0.43
0.04
0.06
0.01
4.96
0.20
0.56
5.78
393.2
0.27

0.53
9.40
0.02
0.59
0.23
0.35
0.25
0.11
0.06
0.03
0.45
0.60
0.24
0.34
0.18
0.12
0.25
0.53
0.04
0.05
0.01
4.55
0.20
0.45
5.96
517.5
0.18

0.27

1.0

---

0.02
0.46
0.04
0.10
46.41

0.00
0.42
0.03
0.10
0.45
56.30

0.02
0.47
0.05
0.09
0.38
42.12

59.50

60.35

59.19

30.09

39.17

26.81

14126

3752

10374

30

0.57
0.23
0.31
0.28
0.12
0.06
0.03
0.43
0.60
0.27
0.31
0.17
0.12
0.27
0.51
0.04
0.05
0.01
4.66
0.20
0.48
5.91

Table 2: Bivariate Probit Results of Ethnic Enclave Location Choice
Dependent variable, HISPLOC
Variables

Coefficient
Estimates
-0.66*

Standard
Errors
0.16

Socioeconomic Variables
PERMANINC

-0.07*

0.02

TRANSINC

-0.00*

0.00

COLLEGE

-0.36*

0.10

HIGHSCHOOL

-0.10*

0.03

Life-cycle and Demographic Variables
MARRIED

-0.20*

0.03

HHSIZE

0.01*

0.01

DEPENDENT

-0.01

0.03

AGE24

0.01

0.04

AGE34

0.01

0.03

AGE54

0.06

0.04

AGE64

-0.14**

0.06

Immigration, Assimilation and Mobility Variables
ENGLWELL

0.76*

0.04

NO_ENGL

0.94*

0.05

USCIT

-0.78*

0.03

NATRL_CIT

-0.13*

0.04

MOVE_PUMA

-0.85*

0.14

MOVE_IL

-0.18*

0.03

MOVE_US

-0.23*

0.07

MOVE_FORGN

-0.28*

0.05

ETHNAFF

2.09*

0.06

Intercept

* significant at less than 0.01. ** significant at less than 0.05.
Note: The omitted education category is less than high school level education; the omitted
age category is age44 (ages 35 to 44); the omitted language category is “speak only English
at home”; the omitted mobility category is NON_MOVERS.

31

Table 3: Bivariate Probit Models
Dependent variable, OWNHOME
Variables
Intercept
Socioeconomic Variables
PERMANINC
TRANSINC
COLLEGE
HIGHSCHOOL
Housing Prices Variables
HOMEVAL
MEDRENT
Life-cycle and Demographic Variables
MARRIED
HHSIZE
DEPENDENT
AGE24
AGE34
AGE54
AGE64
MEXICO
Immigration, Assimilation and Mobility Variables
NO_ENGL
USCIT
NATRL_CIT
YSM5
YSM10
YSM30
YSM40
YSM50

Simple
Model
2.93*
(0.43)

Mobility
Effects
3.18*
(0.44)

Ethnic Affinity
Effects
2.76*
(0.45)

Ethnic Affinity &
Neighborhood Effects
4.43*
(0.47)

0.09*
(0.01)
-0.00
(0.00)
0.26*
(0.07)
0.20*
(0.02)

0.09*
(0.01)
0.00
(0.00)
0.32*
(0.08)
0.20*
(0.03)

0.08*
(0.01)
0.00
(0.00)
0.33*
(0.08)
0.19*
(0.03)

0.08*
(0.02)
0.00
(0.00)
0.36*
(0.07)
0.17*
(0.03)

-0.94*
(0.08)
0.22*
(0.02)

-0.94*
(0.08)
0.24*
(0.02)

-0.83*
(0.08)
0.19*
(0.02)

-0.64*
(0.09)
0.01
(0.02)

0.21*
(0.02)
0.13*
(0.00)
0.04
(0.03)
-0.15*
(0.04)
-0.18*
(0.03)
0.25*
(0.03)
0.37*
(0.05)
0.01
(0.03)

0.21*
(0.03)
0.13*
(0.00)
0.04
(0.03)
-0.12*
(0.04)
-0.15*
(0.03)
0.22*
(0.04)
0.30*
(0.05)
0.02
(0.03)

0.21*
(0.03)
0.13*
(0.00)
0.04
(0.03)
-0.12*
(0.04)
-0.14*
(0.03)
0.22*
(0.04)
0.29*
(0.06)
0.12*
(0.03)

0.17*
(0.03)
0.13*
(0.00)
0.03
(0.03)
-0.14*
(0.04)
-0.15*
(0.03)
0.22*
(0.04)
0.30*
(0.06)
-0.04*
(0.03)

-0.36*
(0.03)
0.22*
(0.04)
0.15*
(0.03)
-0.83*
(0.05)
-0.44*
(0.03)
0.18*
(0.06)
0.26*
(0.06)
0.13
(0.15)

-0.32*
(0.03)
0.18*
(0.04)
0.12*
(0.03)
-0.70*
(0.06)
-0.42*
(0.03)
0.18*
(0.06)
0.26*
(0.06)
0.15
(0.15)
0.12
(0.09)
-0.32*
(0.03)
-0.79*
(0.06)
-0.46*
(0.06)

-0.32
(0.03)
0.21*
(0.05)
0.12*
(0.03)
-0.71*
(0.06)
-0.42*
(0.03)
0.19*
(0.06)
0.27*
(0.06)
0.16
(0.15)
0.04
(0.09)
-0.31*
(0.03)
-0.76*
(0.06)
-0.44*
(0.06)

-0.29
(0.03)
0.05*
(0.08)
0.12**
(0.06)
-0.69*
(0.06)
-0.40*
(0.03)
0.16*
(0.07)
0.22*
(0.06)
0.13
(0.16)
-0.01
(0.09)
-0.36*
(0.03)
-0.82*
(0.06)
-0.46*
(0.06)

MOVE_PUMA
MOVE_IL
MOVE_US
MOVE_FORGN

32

TABLE 3 continued
Variables
Location Variables
HISPLOC

Simple
Model

Mobility
Effects

Ethnic Affinity
Effects

Ethnic Affinity &
Neighborhood Effects

0.25*
(0.08)

-0.08
(0.09)

0.20
(0.14)
-2.44*
(0.29)
3.65*
(0.42)

-0.33*
(0.04)
-15,435.71

-0.14*
(0.05)
-15,304.33

-0.21*
(0.08)
-15,265,03

-0.20
(0.15)
-0.32
(0.32)
0.38
(0.45)
-0.04*
(0.00)
-0.041
(0.00)
0.01*
(0.00)
-0.13
(0.08)
-15,004.63

ETHNAFF
ETHNAFF**2
PCT_POOR
PCT_FORGN
PCT_NOENGL
ρ (1,2)
Log likelihood

*Significant at less than .01 level. ** Significant at less than .05 level. Standard errors are in parentheses

33

Table 4: Marginal Effects
PROBABILITY (OWNHOME = 1 | HISPLOC = 1)

PERMANINC
TRANSINC
HOMEVAL
MEDRENT
MARRIED
HHSIZE
DEPENDENT
AGE24
AGE34
AGE54
AGE64
COLLEGE
HIGHSCHOOL
NOENGL
USCIT
NATRL_CIT
YSM5
YSM10
YSM30
YSM40
YSM50
MEXICO
MOVE_PUMA
MOVE_IL
MOVE_US
MOVE_FORGN
ETHNAFF
ETHNAFF**2
PCT_POOR
PCT_FORGN
PCT_NOENGL

Direct
Effect
0.030
-0.000
-0.245
0.004
0.068
0.051
0.013
-0.054
-0.059
0.084
0.117
0.140
0.067
-0.115
0.046
0.049
-0.272
-0.152
0.062
0.087
0.053
-0.015
-0.002
-0.140
-0.320
-0.182
-0.026
0.148
-0.014
-0.003
0.003

Indirect
Effect
-0.003
-0.000
-----0.008
-0.000
-0.000
-0.000
-0.000
0.002
-0.005
-0.014
-0.004
0.037
-0.031
-0.005
------------0.033
-0.007
-0.009
-0.011
0.082
---------

Total
Effect
0.027*
0.000
-0.245*
0.004
0.060*
0.051*
0.013
-0.054*
-0.059*
0.082*
0.112*
0.126*
0.063*
-0.078
0.015*
0.044*
-0.272*
-0.152*
0.062*
0.087*
0.053
-0.015
0.031
-0.147*
-0.329*
-0.193*
0.056
0.148
-0.014*
-0.003*
0.003*

*Significant at less than .01 level.

34

* A final version of this paper is forthcoming in Contemporary Economic Policy. The views
expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
1

A beta test determined that the calculated proportions for the variables between these two
locations were not statistically different in most cases.
2

See Greene (2003), page 716, Chapter 21.

3

Also, see Cutler and Glaeser (1997) for similar measures of residential clustering.

4

This thoughtful suggestion was made by an anonymous referee.

5

Models that included interaction terms for the affinity index and other location-specific
characteristics were also estimated. We report the findings from the more parsimonious model
because the conclusions drawn from the specifications remained virtually the same.
6

The results are available upon request from senior author.

7

With the 2000 census data showing that the Hispanic population is one of the fastest growing
population, financial institutions have recognized that the population represents a potentially
lucrative, untapped market. A vast literature is providing advise on how to reach this market (e.g.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2002). Recently, there has been a number of forums or
workshops to bring together bank representatives, researchers and Hispanic community leaders
to discuss ways to reach the Hispanic market. An example is the Hispanic Banking Forum,
which was co-sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Office of the Comptroller
(OCC) and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) on June 2002. Information about
the Hispanic Banking Forum can be accessed by selecting "Banker Education" on the OCC
Internet home page, www.occ.treas.gov, and choosing "Conferences/Seminars." Another
example is the Lending Avenues for Latino Immigrants, a workshop cosponsored by the FDIC,
the OCC and the Small Business Administration, December 2002).
8

A comprehensive review of more than 100 state and local government-sponsored affordable
housing programs nationwide is provided and evaluated in Stegman (1999).

9

For a comprehensive guide to the specific ways by which homeownership opportunities can be
created for the immigrant market, see Shoenholtz and Stanton (2001), a study completed for the
Fannie Mae Foundation.
10

Sweat equity or mutual self-help housing programs bring together groups of families to help
build each other’s home under the supervision of a skilled construction supervisor. Typically, a
non-profit organization acts as developer, construction supervisor, loan facilitator, participant
screener, and educator (Schoenholtz and Stanton, 2001).
11

The trend in mortgage-related lending includes home purchase (conventional plus
government-insured, FHA/VA/FmHA-insured), refinance loans and home improvement loans
35

and is drawn from the Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act data, 1994-1999. The Chicago Association of Realtors provided us with the
1994-1999 trend in home sales for Little Village and the City of Chicago.
12

The Empowerment Zone/Enterprise Community program was established under the Federal
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act in 1994. The program was designed to empower people and
communities across the U.S to work together to develop a strategic plan designed to create jobs
and opportunities in the nation’s most impoverished urban and rural areas. For detail information
go to www.cichi.il.us/planandDevelopment/ …s/ EmpowermentZone/EmpowermentZone2.htm.
13

For more information, go to www.fanniemaefoundation.org/grants/sea/rp/recordshtml.

36

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Dynamic Monetary Equilibrium in a Random-Matching Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-00-1

The Effects of Health, Wealth, and Wages on Labor Supply and Retirement Behavior
Eric French

WP-00-2

Market Discipline in the Governance of U.S. Bank Holding Companies:
Monitoring vs. Influencing
Robert R. Bliss and Mark J. Flannery

WP-00-3

Using Market Valuation to Assess the Importance and Efficiency
of Public School Spending
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse
Employment Flows, Capital Mobility, and Policy Analysis
Marcelo Veracierto
Does the Community Reinvestment Act Influence Lending? An Analysis
of Changes in Bank Low-Income Mortgage Activity
Drew Dahl, Douglas D. Evanoff and Michael F. Spivey

WP-00-4

WP-00-5

WP-00-6

Subordinated Debt and Bank Capital Reform
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-00-7

The Labor Supply Response To (Mismeasured But) Predictable Wage Changes
Eric French

WP-00-8

For How Long Are Newly Chartered Banks Financially Fragile?
Robert DeYoung

WP-00-9

Bank Capital Regulation With and Without State-Contingent Penalties
David A. Marshall and Edward S. Prescott

WP-00-10

Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care?
Susanto Basu and John Fernald

WP-00-11

Oligopoly Banking and Capital Accumulation
Nicola Cetorelli and Pietro F. Peretto

WP-00-12

Puzzles in the Chinese Stock Market
John Fernald and John H. Rogers

WP-00-13

The Effects of Geographic Expansion on Bank Efficiency
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-00-14

Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Employment Dynamics
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-00-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Post-Resolution Treatment of Depositors at Failed Banks: Implications for the Severity
of Banking Crises, Systemic Risk, and Too-Big-To-Fail
George G. Kaufman and Steven A. Seelig

WP-00-16

The Double Play: Simultaneous Speculative Attacks on Currency and Equity Markets
Sujit Chakravorti and Subir Lall

WP-00-17

Capital Requirements and Competition in the Banking Industry
Peter J.G. Vlaar

WP-00-18

Financial-Intermediation Regime and Efficiency in a Boyd-Prescott Economy
Yeong-Yuh Chiang and Edward J. Green

WP-00-19

How Do Retail Prices React to Minimum Wage Increases?
James M. MacDonald and Daniel Aaronson

WP-00-20

Financial Signal Processing: A Self Calibrating Model
Robert J. Elliott, William C. Hunter and Barbara M. Jamieson

WP-00-21

An Empirical Examination of the Price-Dividend Relation with Dividend Management
Lucy F. Ackert and William C. Hunter

WP-00-22

Savings of Young Parents
Annamaria Lusardi, Ricardo Cossa, and Erin L. Krupka

WP-00-23

The Pitfalls in Inferring Risk from Financial Market Data
Robert R. Bliss

WP-00-24

What Can Account for Fluctuations in the Terms of Trade?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-00-25

Data Revisions and the Identification of Monetary Policy Shocks
Dean Croushore and Charles L. Evans

WP-00-26

Recent Evidence on the Relationship Between Unemployment and Wage Growth
Daniel Aaronson and Daniel Sullivan

WP-00-27

Supplier Relationships and Small Business Use of Trade Credit
Daniel Aaronson, Raphael Bostic, Paul Huck and Robert Townsend

WP-00-28

What are the Short-Run Effects of Increasing Labor Market Flexibility?
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-00-29

Equilibrium Lending Mechanism and Aggregate Activity
Cheng Wang and Ruilin Zhou

WP-00-30

Impact of Independent Directors and the Regulatory Environment on Bank Merger Prices:
Evidence from Takeover Activity in the 1990s
Elijah Brewer III, William E. Jackson III, and Julapa A. Jagtiani
Does Bank Concentration Lead to Concentration in Industrial Sectors?
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-00-31

WP-01-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
On the Fiscal Implications of Twin Crises
Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo

WP-01-02

Sub-Debt Yield Spreads as Bank Risk Measures
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-01-03

Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald and Matthew D. Shapiro

WP-01-04

Do Regulators Search for the Quiet Life? The Relationship Between Regulators and
The Regulated in Banking
Richard J. Rosen
Learning-by-Doing, Scale Efficiencies, and Financial Performance at Internet-Only Banks
Robert DeYoung
The Role of Real Wages, Productivity, and Fiscal Policy in Germany’s
Great Depression 1928-37
Jonas D. M. Fisher and Andreas Hornstein

WP-01-05

WP-01-06

WP-01-07

Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Charles L. Evans

WP-01-08

Outsourcing Business Service and the Scope of Local Markets
Yukako Ono

WP-01-09

The Effect of Market Size Structure on Competition: The Case of Small Business Lending
Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Rosen and Gregory F. Udell

WP-01-10

Deregulation, the Internet, and the Competitive Viability of Large Banks
and Community Banks
Robert DeYoung and William C. Hunter

WP-01-11

Price Ceilings as Focal Points for Tacit Collusion: Evidence from Credit Cards
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-01-12

Gaps and Triangles
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-01-13

A Real Explanation for Heterogeneous Investment Dynamics
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-01-14

Recovering Risk Aversion from Options
Robert R. Bliss and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou

WP-01-15

Economic Determinants of the Nominal Treasury Yield Curve
Charles L. Evans and David Marshall

WP-01-16

Price Level Uniformity in a Random Matching Model with Perfectly Patient Traders
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-01-17

Earnings Mobility in the US: A New Look at Intergenerational Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-18

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Effects of Health Insurance and Self-Insurance on Retirement Behavior
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-01-19

The Effect of Part-Time Work on Wages: Evidence from the Social Security Rules
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-01-20

Antidumping Policy Under Imperfect Competition
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-01-21

Is the United States an Optimum Currency Area?
An Empirical Analysis of Regional Business Cycles
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-01-22

A Note on the Estimation of Linear Regression Models with Heteroskedastic
Measurement Errors
Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-01-23

The Mis-Measurement of Permanent Earnings: New Evidence from Social
Security Earnings Data
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-24

Pricing IPOs of Mutual Thrift Conversions: The Joint Effect of Regulation
and Market Discipline
Elijah Brewer III, Douglas D. Evanoff and Jacky So

WP-01-25

Opportunity Cost and Prudentiality: An Analysis of Collateral Decisions in
Bilateral and Multilateral Settings
Herbert L. Baer, Virginia G. France and James T. Moser

WP-01-26

Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg
Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-06

WP-02-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

6