View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

STOCK MARKET DISPERSION AND REAL
ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM
QUARTERLY DATA
Prakash Loungani, Mark Rush and William Tave
Working Paper Series
Macro Economic Issues
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
September, 1990 (WP-90-15)

Stock Market Dispersion and Real Economic Activity:
Evidence from Quarterly Data

Prakash Loungani
University of Florida
and
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Mark Rush
University of Florida
and
William Tave
Brown University

September 1990

Earlier drafts of this paper were presented at the NBER Summer
Institute, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and the University
of Florida. We thank James Adams, Herb Baer, Bill Bomberger, Steve
Davis, David Denslow, Martin Eichenbaum, Hesna Genay, Larry Kenny,
Ken Kuttner, David Lilien, Jim Moser, Richard Rogerson, Steve
Strongin, Mark Watson and other seminar participants for extensive
comments. The Financial Institutions Center at the University of
Florida supported this research.




ABSTRACT
We conduct an empirical investigation into the effects that
stock market dispersion has on real economic activity. The results
from fairly standard reduced-form equations
suggest that,
controlling for the effects of monetary and fiscal policy, stock
market dispersion leads to a significant increase in unemployment
and a decline in real GNP and investment. We also report results
from including our stock market measure and a Lilien-type
employment dispersion measure [see Lilien (1982)] in several VAR
systems in which unemployment is used as the indicator of real
economic activity. The performance of the employment-based measure
turns out to be very sensitive to the ordering of the variables in
the system. The stock market dispersion measure always explains a
larger fraction of the variance of unemployment than does the
employment dispersion measure, and the fraction explained is not
sensitive to the ordering of the variables. Even after the
inclusion of an interest rate variable and the Standard & Poor's
500 in the VAR system, stock market dispersion accounts for between
26% and 33% of the variance of unemployment at long horizons.
Prakash Loungani
Economic Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
230 S. LaSalle St.
Chicago, IL 60690
312-322-8203
Mark Rush
Department of Economics
University of Florida
Gainesville, FL 32611
904-392-0318
William Tave
Department of Economics
Brown University
Providence, RI 02912




1

1. Introduction
David Lilien's (1982) paper has sparked a debate on the extent
to which fluctuations in the aggregate unemployment rate may be
attributed

to

the

reallocation

of

labor

across

sectors.

The

voluminous literature that has followed Lilien can be divided into
two groups: (1) time-series studies which test whether proxies for
the amount of sectoral labor reallocation are correlated with the
aggregate unemployment

rate,

and

(2)

studies which attempt to

measure labor reallocation and its contribution to unemployment
directly by using panel data sets. While this paper belongs to the
first group, it is useful to briefly review the evidence from the
second group of studies.
Lilien appears to have had in mind a model— such as that of
Lucas

and Prescott

sectors

is

(1974)— where

fixed exogenously,

the

but

time

downturns

required to

switch

are marked by

an

increase in the number of workers who experience unemployment as
they switch between sectors. Using data from the Current Population
Survey, Murphy and Topel (1987) present evidence against this early
("search") version of the sectoral shifts hypothesis.
However, one can consider alternate models where the impact of
sectoral shocks is not just on the number of workers who experience
unemployment as they switch sectors, but also on the time it takes
workers to switch sectors. This feature is likely to emerge in
models

that

assign

a prominent

role

to

sector-specific

human

capital. For instance, Topel and Weiss (1985) present a model where
some periods— such as the 1970's and early 1980's— are marked by




2
increased uncertainty about the relative returns to sector-specific
human capital investment, leading to an increase in the time that
displaced workers take to switch sectors.

In Rogerson's

(1989)

model, the impact of sectoral shocks leads to very high durations
of unemployment among older workers who are displaced from their
jobs: The basic idea is that these workers are at an disadvantage
relative to younger workers in that they do not have as long to
reap the benefits of (new) human capital accumulation and hence
require higher wages than do otherwise identical younger workers.
Using the Michigan Panel Study of Income Dynamics, a longitudinal
data set that enables researchers to observe workers' mobility and
unemployment experience over several consecutive years, Loungani
and Rogerson
present

(1989a)

evidence

and Loungani,

consistent

with

Rogerson

these

and

broader

Sonn
views

(1989b)
of

the

sectoral shifts hypothesis that stress the importance of sectorspecific human capital accumulation.
Since most of the panel data sets start around the late 1960's
or early 1970's, they do not offer any evidence on the contribution
of sectoral reallocation to unemployment prior to that period.
Hence,

time-series

in d u stry

d isp e rsio n

studies— which

typically

construct

c r o s s ­

indices to proxy for the amount of sectoral

reallocation of resources— are a useful source of complementary
evidence.

As discussed in Davis

(1985,

p.32)

and Barro

(1986,

p.138), the use of a dispersion index offers some advantages to
researchers who are interested primarily in determining the impact
of sectoral shocks on broad macroeconomic aggregates such as the




3

aggregate unemployment rate. Barro states that the use of the
dispersion index circumvents "the need to isolate a detailed array
of

many— mostly

preferences
sectors."

unobservable— disturbances

(that)

motivate

reallocations

to
of

technology
resources

and

across

Davis points out that "allocative disturbances from any

particular source are likely to occur rather infrequently over
available sample sizes," which makes it difficult to explicitly
incorporate

variables

that

capture

the

effects

of

allocative

disturbances into an aggregate unemployment equation.
In this paper we construct a measure of the cross-industry
dispersion

in

stock price
of

growth
capital

to proxy

for the

and

undertaken

labor

amount
by

of

sectoral

reallocation

the

economy.

In a well-functioning stock market, the industry stock

price represents the present value of expected future industry
profits.

An increase in the dispersion of stock prices across

industries reflects the occurrence of shocks that are expected to
have differential impacts on industries' profits. If these shocks
are

expected

to be persistent,

productive

resources,

such

as

capital and labor, will be displaced from the industries that are
expected
resources

to

be

are

adversely
not

affected.

immediately

To the

absorbed

extent

into

more

that

these

profitable

industries, the dispersion in stock prices will be followed by a
decline in real economic activity. In Section 2 of the paper, we
present a brief theoretical framework along these lines. We also
present details on the construction of the stock market dispersion
index.




4

While previous studies have focused on the impact of labor
reallocation on unemployment, it is likely that the reallocation of
capital

across sectors is also fairly costly.

plausible

that

the

adjustment

costs

It is therefore

associated

with

capital

reallocation lead to declines in other macroeconomic aggregates. In
Section 3 we show, using quarterly data for the period 1947 to
1987, that an increase in stock market dispersion leads not only to
a statistically significant increase in unemployment but also to a
decline in output and investment.
The results for unemployment bolster our preliminary work on
the relationship between stock market dispersion and unemployment.
Loungani, Rush and Tave (1990) present evidence on the determinants
of U.S. unemployment over a long time period, 1929 to 1987. Using
annual data, we find that unemployment depends on up to three lags
of a stock market dispersion measure. Loungani and Rush

(1990)

construct a stock market dispersion measure using British data for
the period 1912 to 1938. This measure appears to reflect fairly
well the decline of the traditional export industries and the rise
of newer industries and turns out to explain a large fraction of
British interwar unemployment.
Our stock market dispersion index is clearly motivated by
Lilien's use of cross-industry

e m p lo y m e n t

dispersion to proxy for

the intersectoral flow of labor. Many researchers, most notably
Abraham and Katz

(1984,

1986), have questioned Lilien's use of

employment dispersion as a measure of labor reallocation. Their
basic point is that movements in employment dispersion may simply




5

be reflecting the well-known fact that the business cycle has non­
neutral effects across industries. The increase in the dispersion
of employment growth rates could reflect,
reallocation,

not

increased labor

but simply the uneven impact of aggregate demand

shocks on temporary layoffs in different industries. Hence there is
an

observational

equivalence

between

the

predictions

sectoral shifts hypothesis and the more traditional

of

the

"aggregate

demand hypothesis."
The main

advantage

of a

stock market

dispersion measure

relative to Lilien's measure is that stock prices respond more
strongly to disturbances that are perceived to be permanent than to
temporary

disturbances,

which

need not

be

true

of employment

changes. The industry stock price represents the present value of
expected profits over a long horizon. The impact of innovations in
industry profits on its stock price will therefore depend on how
long the shocks are expected to be persist.

If the shocks are

purely temporary, the innovations will have little impact on the
present value of expected profits and, hence, will have little
impact on industries'
shocks

are

fairly

stock prices.

persistent,

the

On the other hand,
innovations

will

if the
have

a

significant impact on expected future profits and will lead to
large changes in industries' stock prices. Furthermore, it is these
sorts of persistent shocks that will cause productive resources,
such as capital and labor,

to be displaced from the adversely

affected industries. Hence,

a dispersion index constructed from

industries'




sto c k

p r ic e s

automatically assigns greater weight to

6

permanent structural changes rather than temporary cyclical shocks.
We conjecture,

therefore,

that a stock market based dispersion

measure is less likely than an employment-based measure to reflect
changes in temporary layoffs; this implies that our stock market
dispersion variable is less sensitive than employment dispersion
measures to aggregate demand disturbances that result in large
swings in temporary layoffs.
Rather than rely solely on these conjectures, we put them to
the test

in Section

4 of the paper.

Abraham-Katz

suggest two

methods of resolving the observational equivalence problem that
they identify. The first is to test whether the correlation between
the dispersion index and the aggregate vacancy rate is positive or
negative. Abraham-Katz argue that if the dispersion index is a good
proxy for sectoral shifts this correlation should be positive,
since the reduced labor demand in some sectors will be matched by
increased hiring in other sectors. On the other hand, if dispersion
is attributable to aggregate demand shocks, then this correlation
should be negative since all sectors will reduce their hiring. The
empirical

relationship between dispersion and a proxy

for the

vacancy rate has been investigated in independent work by Brainard
and Cutler (1989) using a stock market dispersion index similar to
ours.1 They find that the impulse response of the vacancy rate
proxy to innovations in their stock market dispersion
consistently

of

one

sign,

and the

standard

errors

"is not

are

large

relative to the coefficients."
This method of resolving the observational equivalence problem




7

suffers from the lack of availability of adequate vacancy data for
the U.S. Instead, researchers are forced to use an index based on
help-wanted advertising in newspapers in 51 cities. An additional
problem is that recent work by Hosios (1988) implies that sectoral
shifts

models that

allow

for both

capital

and labor mobility

generate a negative correlation between dispersion and vacancy
rates. Hence in his model information on vacancy rates cannot be
used

to

distinguish the

aggregate

demand hypothesis

from the

sectoral shifts hypothesis.
The second method— which is essentially the one we follow in
this paper— involves "purging" the dispersion index of movements
that can be attributed to aggregate demand disturbances and then
testing

if

the

significantly

residual

correlated

measure

with

of

economic

dispersion
activity.

is
This

still
method

requires a careful specification of a list of regressors that
adequately capture aggregate demand. Recognizing that stock prices
are

forward-looking,

we include in our list not only standard

aggregate demand shifters

such as money growth and government

spending shocks, but also "information" variables, such as interest
rate spreads and mean stock returns, that have emerged in recent
studies as strong predictors of future economic activity. However,
even

after

controlling

for

the

effects

of these

current

and

potential aggregate demand shifts, innovations in our stock market
dispersion index explain nearly 33% of the variance of unemployment
at long horizons.
dispersion




measure

On the other hand,
explains

less

than

a Lilien-type
5%

of the

e m p lo y m e n t

variance

of

8
unemployment once the aggregate demand shifters are included. To
summarize, the empirical evidence strongly supports our conjecture
that the stock market dispersion index is less susceptible to the
Abraham-Katz critique than Lilien's measure.

2. Stock Market Dispersion and Economic Activity
A. Theoretical Framework
We

begin

by

presenting

a theoretical

framework

that

is

consistent with the key ideas in Lilien (1982), Black (1982) and
Davis

(1987) . For convenience we refer to this framework as the

costly sectoral mobility model.
Consider a n-sector economy with each sector producing a
distinct product using a vector of productive resources or inputs,
Zlt. Profits in each sector are given by,
(1)

7iit = JC(Zl t ) e it

where the ei 's are uncorrelated across sectors, with mean e and
t
(cross-sectional)

standard

deviation

a.

Not

much

significance

should be attached to the particular way in which we specify the
stochastic shocks to the profit function; this framework can be
modified to distinguish among shocks to the sectoral price ("taste
shocks"),

shocks

to

the

marginal

physical

product

of

inputs

("productivity shocks") and shocks to the cost function.
The sectoral stock price equals the sum of discounted expected
future profits over an infinite horizon,
(2)

S it =

(1/p) ( S E ^ J W )

where P is the discount factor and Et is the expectations operator
_x




9

conditional on information available in period t-1.
Long-run equilibrium is characterized by the equality of stock
returns across sectors,
(3)

Ri * = Rt
t
*

for all i

where Ri =log ( S Lt / S
t

i t _!)

and ^ is a weighted average of the sectoral

stock returns. We denote the allocation of inputs across sectors
associated with this long-run equilibrium by Zl * Note that this
t.
target allocation of resources changes over time in response to
realizations of the Bit's.
In the short-run, productive resources move across sectors

if

Zj.t-1

The

-

& i ( z it

~

(Z it

Z it - i) /

with

Z it

~

0

partial-adjustment

Hrt
1
*-»

Zj.t-1

Z it

-

CS3

towards this target allocation as follows:

<

if

a2

<

>
^ it - l

(Xi <

reflects

Z lt *

<

Z it*

1

the

assumption

that

both

capital and labor are partly specialized to a sector and hence the
reallocation process is costly and/or time-consuming. The role of
adjustment costs for capital is emphasized in early work by Eisner
and Strotz (1963), while the quasi-fixity of labor was highlighted
in seminal work by Oi
above

is

the

(1962)

assumption

asymmetric.2 In particular,
reach their

and Becker

that

the

(1964) . Also reflected

adjustment

mechanism

is

contracting sectors are assumed to

long-run equilibrium input levels

faster than the

expanding sectors, so that ax > a2.
Two recent empirical studies provide indirect evidence of the
sector-specificity of labor and capital. Topel (1990, p.17) states




10
that

"when human

capital

is

'general'

in the

sense

of being

portable among activities, a job loss should imply fairly minor and
transitory effects on earning capacity. But with specific capital,
initial losses may be large and persistent." Using data from the
PSID and the Displaced Worker Survey, Topel finds evidence of large
short-run

reductions

in

earnings— 40

percent

for

manufacturing worker— following job loss. Moreover,
change

industry

or

occupation

following

the

the

typical

workers who

job

loss

have

atypically large short run reductions in earnings.3 Grossman and
Levinsohn

(1989)

study the impact of exogenous

changes in the

prices of competing import goods on stock returns in six U.S.
industries. They state (p. 1065) that "when factors are mobile, ..
individual returns may respond little or even positively to adverse
shocks

to

the

particular

sectors

in

which

the

factors

are

employed." They find however that for five of the six industries in
their study, lower-than-expected import prices lead to substantial
declines

in

stock

returns,

suggesting

that

capital

is highly

immobile between sectors in the short run.
We next consider the
changes

in

realizations
Prescott

o,
of

the
the

(1974) model

impact on real economic activity of

(cross-section)
sector-specific
a

standard
shocks.

deviation
In the

of

the

Lucas

and

is assumed to be constant over time and

hence the reallocation of product demand across sectors leads to a
time-invariant natural rate of unemployment. In contrast, Lilien,
Black and Davis suggest that

a

may vary over time, depending on the

nature of the shocks to the economy. In the framework developed




11
above, an increase in a reflects the arrival of shocks that are
expected to have differential impacts on sectoral profits. This
leads to an increase in the stock prices of sectors that investors
believe are going to expand and a decline in the stock prices of
sectors that are expected to contract, thereby causing dispersion
in

the

realizations

of

the

stock

returns.

The

greater

the

difference foreseen in the sectors' prospects, the larger is the
dispersion in stock returns and the larger is the reallocation of
productive resources across sectors that is required to attain the
(new)

long-run

equilibrium.

adjustment mechanism,

Given

our

assumptions

about

the

this reallocation involves an increase in

unemployment, and a decline in aggregate output and investment. As
discussed

in

the

introduction,

the

evidence

from

panel

data

suggests that it is necessary to think of the reallocation process
not just in terms of the

am ount

sectors but also in terms of the

o f

resources that have to switch
it takes resources to switch

tim e

sectors.
Topel
relates
activity.

and Weiss

the

(1985)

dispersion

They assume,

sector-specific.

in

present
stock

as we do,

However,

they

an alternate theory which

market

returns

to

economic

that human capital is partly

interpret

an

increase

in

stock

market dispersion as reflecting an increase in uncertainty about
the relative returns to sector-specific human capital investment.
In the face of this increased uncertainty about which sectors are
going to prosper and which ones are going to decline, "individuals
with less experience and those with greater costs of acquiring




12
sector-specific

human

capital

will

rationally

and

optimally

postpone employment and human capital investment until uncertainty
has been resolved." We refer to the Topel-Weiss framework as the
sectoral uncertainty model.
While the theory underlying their work is distinct from the
costly sectoral mobility model outlined above,

Topel and Weiss

point out that it may be difficult to distinguish between the two
empirically (p. 348):
"In contrast to Lilien, who implies that the o c c u r r e n c e of a
sectoral shock that requires labor to be reallocated raises
unemployment, we argue that t h e p r o s p e c t o f f u t u r e s h o c k s is
a likely candidate for explaining the observed rise in
unemployment, especially among younger individuals. Of course,
to the extent that the occurrence of sectoral shocks is
correlated over time,
a sectoral shock may increase
expectations of future shocks, so it may be difficult to
completely separate the two theories empirically. In this
sense, models of costly sectoral mobility and sectoral
uncertainty
are
complementary
theories
of
rising
unemployment."

B. Construction and Properties of the Stock Market Dispersion Index
This section of the paper describes the construction of the
empirical analog to a. The basic data we used to construct our
measure of the dispersion of stock prices were monthly average
indices of various industries'
Standard and Poors

stock prices,

as constructed by

(1988). The industries, which are defined by

Standard and Poors, range in size from 2 firms to 31 firms and the
indices are computed by weighting each firm's stock price according
to the firm's market value.

Standard and Poors began compiling

these data in 1926; at various times additional industries have
been added (and others subtracted) so that currently Standard and




13

Poors compiles indices for about 85 industries. We used a sample of
60 indices, including most industries with a complete data series
from 1947 through 1987 as well as a few shorter series deemed
important. A list of the industries we used, together with their
starting date, ending date (if relevant), and weight in our index
is given in the appendix.
In calculating the index, we first deflated each index using
the GNP price deflator and then used quarterly averages of the
monthly data.

Then we calculated each indices'

growth rate and

defined our dispersion measure as
(5)

St = [£ wlt(ri - rt)2]12
t
/

where rl is the growth rate of industry i's stock at time t, rt is
t
the growth rate of Standard and Poor's composite listing, and wl
t
is a weight based on the industry's employment. Due to the changing
number

of

available,

industries
the

for which

wi weight
t

given

Standard
an

and Poor's

industry

changed

data

are

as

the

industries included in our dispersion index changed. wl equals the
t
over-all weight for industry i, based on its share of employment
from the entire sample,

(called W±; see the Appendix) divided by

the sum of the W± weights used in period t. Thus we compensated for
the varying number of industries in different years and so S is an
employment-weighted standard deviation of the growth rate of the
industries' stock prices.




14

3. Empirical Results from Reduced-Form Equations
To determine the role our dispersion index plays in affecting
aggregate

economic

activity,

we

start by specifying

a set

of

conventional reduced-form regressions of the type estimated by
Lilien (1982). Our hypothesis is that the greater the difference
foreseen in the industries'

prospects,

the larger will be the

divergence in their stock prices, which will be reflected in an
upward movement in the dispersion index. Moreover, the greater the
difference

foreseen

in

the

industries'

prospects,

the

more

resources must be moved and so the larger will be the resulting
unemployment and decline in real activity. Under both versions of
the sectoral shifts hypothesis, there is reason to expect that an
increase in dispersion will have a persistent impact on economic
activity, i.e., that

la g g e d

values of dispersion will be correlated

with economic activity. Under the costly sectoral mobility model,
this reflects the fact that the reallocation of resources will be
staggered over time due to adjustment costs. Under the sectoral
uncertainty model, the lag length reflects the time it takes for
the uncertainty about sectors' relative prospects to be resolved.
We use changes in government spending and money growth to
capture shocks to aggregate demand. To control for the effects of
changes

in

government

spending,

the

unemployment

regression

includes the ratio of federal government purchases of goods and
services to trend GNP, called GY, while the output and investment
equations include the log of federal purchases, called LF.4 We use
the actual growth rate of the base money supply, called DB, as the




15

monetary variable.5
Unemployment rates trended upwards during the late 1960's and
the 1970's and demographic changes are often thought of as an
important factor in accounting for this rise. To capture this we
include a variable DEMO, which equals the percentage of women in
the total labor force, in the unemployment equation. To account for
the trend growth in output and investment, we include a time trend,
T.6

For all the variables,

except the trend, we included lags.

Clearly there is no theoretical basis for the number of lags to be
included. The trade-off between more versus fewer lags hinges on
the point that including more lags than justified lowers efficiency
but including fewer biases the results. We expect that the relative
price effects for which we are searching will occur with a fairly
long lag, so at the risk of losing efficiency we included two years
worth of lags for S. We also used eight lags for DB, one lag for
the government spending variables and the demographic variable in
the unemployment equation and,

to capture any inertia that we

failed to explicitly model, two lags of the dependent variables in
each regression. Our main results are robust to several alternate
lag structures.7 In summary, we estimated the following reduced
form regressions:
8

8

1

2

LY = a x + Xb ( i ) DBt.i + I c U J S t . i + X d ( i ) L F t. i + eT + X f L Y ^ i
i=0
i=0
i=0
i=l
8

LI = m




8

+ p jjU JS ,.,

i
2
O
+ S tU JL F t.i + C T + X y L I ^
i=0
i=l

16

8
8
1
1
UN = (X + X p d JD B t.i + S y U J S t.i + X S d J L F t .i + I
i

i=0

i=0

i=0

2
kD O
EM ,...,^

i=0

+ SjlUNt.i

1

where UN = Log(U/[1—U ] ), with U being the unemployment rate, LY is
is

log

of

producers'

real

GNP

and

LI

is

the

log

of

real

investment

in

durable equipment and structures. We hypothesize that

the P's and S's generally should be negative and the b's, d's, £'s,
T's, and K's should be positive. More important,

though,

are the

c's, < ) s and y's which indicate the effect from dispersion. Since
J',
we expect increased dispersion will lower output and investment,
|'
while raising unemployment, the c's and < ) s should be negative and
the y's positive.

For two reasons,

though, we examine mainly the

lagged values of the dispersion variables. First,

the effects of

the more contemporaneous dispersion variables may be reflecting
effects

from

differentially

other,
affect

omitted,
industries.

aggregate
This is,

variables

of course,

that

the point

made by Abraham and Katz. Second, as discussed above, dispersion in
the stock market should lead movements in real economic activity.

Unconstrained Equations
We estimated these regressions for the period 1950-1 to 1987IV. The results from this are reported in Table 1.

[In the table,

S6 indicates the estimated coefficient for St
_6. The other variables
have similar interpretations.] The results from Table 1 show that
the effect of dispersion on output, investment and unemployment is
fairly clear cut. The stock dispersion variables are significantly




17

negative in the output regression at lags two,

six and eight,

in

the investment regression at lags one and eight, and significantly
positive in the unemployment equation at lags one, five, and seven.
The

only puzzle

positive

in

is that the contemporaneous

the

investment

regression

at

S is
the

significantly
10%

level

of

significance. The failure of more individual coefficients to attain
significance may well be because of collinearity because

in all

cases the sum of the coefficients is highly significant at over the
99% confidence level. These results, especially the significance of
the

longer

lagged variables,

provides

evidence

in

favor

of the

sectoral shifts hypothesis.

Constrained Regressions
Because multicollinearity amongst the variables is clearly a
problem,

we

re-estimated

our

regressions

constraining

the

coefficients for DB and S to lie along a second order polynomial.
The results from this estimation are reported in Table 2.
Although
coefficients

this
on

procedure

DB

and

S

does
by

interpretation of the regressions.

not

change

much,

it

the
does

For instance,

sums

of

sharpen

the
our

looking at the

effects from changes in the base money supply, we see that all the
coefficients the regressions have the expected sign and many are
now significantly different from zero. Moreover, all lags of S now
have the "correct" sign and most are significantly different from
zero even up to lags of two years.

It is particularly noteworthy

that in the investment and unemployment regressions, the cumulative




18
effect from S lagged six, seven and eight quarters are larger than
for any other three consecutive quarters.

This large impact

for

what seems ex ante to be quite long lags appears to us as strong
support for the sectoral shocks hypothesis.

4. Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Demand?
This section is devoted to determining the extent to which our
stock market dispersion index is subject to the same criticisms
that Abraham and Katz
work.

In

the

(1984,

interests

of

1986)

aimed at Lilien's

brevity

we

focus

empirical

largely

on

the

unemployment equation, though similar considerations would hold for
the output and investment equations.
Our empirical work thus far rests on the assumption that the
shocks

to

sectoral

uncorrelated across

profits— the
sectors.

eit's

Hence,

in

equation

movements

(1)— are

in the dispersion

index are assumed to be driven by sectoral shocks alone. However,
as

Abraham-Katz

satisfied

in

differential

point

out,

practice.
impacts

on

this

assumption

Aggregate
sectoral

demand
profits

is

unlikely

shocks
will

which

also

to

be

have

lead

to

movements in the dispersion index. Under certain conditions— which
are spelled out in their paper— aggregate demand shocks can also
lead to a positive correlation between the dispersion index and
aggregate unemployment.
The Abraham-Katz critique points out that treating movements
in dispersion as exogenously given— as was assumed in the reducedform equations estimated in the previous section— may be incorrect




19

under

certain

circumstances.

In

this

section

we

show

that

by

estimating VAR systems, and by imposing alternate orderings on the
contemporaneous innovations, we can gauge the extent to which their
critique is applicable in practice.

A. Comparison with Employment Dispersion
We begin by illustrating the Abraham-Katz critique in a VAR
framework. We construct an alternate measure of denoted SIG; the
difference between S and SIG is that the latter is a measure of the
dispersion of employment growth rates across sectors. We then add
SIG to a VAR system in which the other variables are unemployment
(UN)

and two

aggregate

demand proxies,

the

growth

rate

of the

monetary base (DB) and the ratio of federal government purchases to
trend GNP
(6)

(GY). That is we estimate a m-th order autoregression,

Xt = A * . ! + .....

+

+ et

where Xt is a vector of all the variables in the model

(4x1 in this

case) . As a first step, this allows us to ascertain if movements in
SIG are Granger-caused by other variables in the system.
The results of this estimation are contained in Table 3. The
sample period is 1951:2 to 1987:4. The lag length is picked to be
8 quarters, which is a more generous lag length than that used in
most VAR studies;

however,

pruning the lags does not affect our

results in this table. Panel A shows that lags of SIG are highly
significant in the unemployment equation. However,
case that

lags of the aggregate demand proxies,

it is also the
DB and GY,

are

fairly significant in the employment dispersion equation; the first




20

few lags

of unemployment

are also

significant

in this

equation

though the sum does not attain significance at conventional levels.
Hence,

there appears to be clear evidence of "reverse causality"

running

from

the

other

variables

in

the

system

would

be

to

employment

dispersion.
The

Granger-causality

tests

sufficient

in

detemrnining the extent of the "reverse causality" problem if the
contemporaneous innovations in different variables, i.e., the et's
in equation

(6) above, were independent.

However,

Panel B — which

reports the contemporaneous correlation matrix of the et's— shows
that there is that there is a strong, positive correlation between
innovations unemployment and innovations in SIG. In light of this,
Panel C reports results of the decomposition of variance for the
unemployment and employment dispersion equations using the standard
Choleski factorization under two alternate orderings.
places SIG first in the system,

Ordering 1

followed by GY, DB and UN.

(This,

of course, keeps SIG independent of the contemporaneous values of
UN, GY and DB but allows UN to be affected not only by lags of SIG,
GY,

and

DB

but

also

by

the

contemporaneous

values

of

these

variables.) Hence, with only minor modifications, this equation is
similar

to

the

reduced-form

equation

reported

earlier.

Not

surprisingly, the results support our earlier conclusions and the
views espoused by Lilien. Employment dispersion explains close to
20% of the variance of unemployment, whereas unemployment explains
only about 10% of the variance of dispersion.
This pattern is dramatically altered when SIG is placed last




21

in the system,

as shown in the results

for Ordering 2. Now the

results are closer to the Abraham-Katz view: SIG explains less than
5% of the variance of unemployment while nearly 25% of the variance
of SIG is attributable to unemployment. To summarize, these results
confirm

the

Abraham-Katz

argument

that

it

is

difficult

to

distinguish the view that exogenous sectoral shifts cause some part
of unemployment fluctuations from the view that unemployment causes
increases in dispersion.
Next, we consider the extent to which similar problems arise
when

our

stock

market

measure,

S,

is

used

as

the

measure

of

dispersion. Once again, the sample period is 1951:2 to 1987:4 and
eight lags of each variable are included. The results are reported
in

Table

4.

Panel

A

shows

that

the

sum

of

the

lags

of

S

is

significantly different from zero in the unemployment equation; as
we found in the reduced-from equations, it is the higher-order lags
of S, particularly

lags seven and eight

highly significant.

The evidence for "reverse causality" is much

weaker,

with

equation.

only

Panel

the
B

GY

shows

variable
that

in this

being

there

case,

significant

there

is

that

in

very

are

the

S

little

contemporaneous correlation between the residuals. Panel C presents
variance decompositions for two different orderings,

one in which

S is placed first in the system and one in which it is placed last.
The

key

finding

is

that

the

fraction

of

the

variance

of

unemployment explained by S is not very sensitive to the ordering:
S explains 32% of the variance

(at step 20) if placed last and 38%

if placed first in the system. Also,




less than 2% of the variance

22

of S is attributable to innovations in unemployment. These results
constitute preliminary evidence that S may be less vulnerable than
employment dispersion to the Abraham-Katz critique.

B. Results with Mean Stock Price Growth
Stock

prices

are

forward-looking

and

should

respond

to

expected changes in aggregate demand that may not be reflected in
current

money

growth

or

current

government

spending.

Hence

we

cannot rule out the possibility that the stock market dispersion
index is driven by imminent aggregate demand shocks that we have
omitted that differentially affect industries' fortunes. To explore
this possibility, we augment both our reduced form regressions and
the VAR systems discussed above to include the real growth rate of
the Standard & Poor's 500.
stock

market

dispersion

The idea is that if movements in the
index

are

largely

in

expectation

of

imminent aggregate shocks, then those expectations should also be
reflected in movements
omitted
index,

aggregate
the

in the mean stock price growth.

shocks

inclusion

of

are the
the

factor

mean

driving

stock

price

our

Thus,

if

dispersion

growth

should

eliminate the impact of stock dispersion on aggregate activity.
Table 5 presents the results
include
results,

mean

stock

price

growth,

from augmenting the system to
DSP.

Before

several points should be noted. First,

we

discuss

the

it turns out that

the government spending variable, GY, is no longer significant in
the unemployment

equation

in the

augmented system and hence we

exclude this variable from the system.




In any case,

including GY

23

does not affect our main conclusions.
brevity,

Second,

in the interest of

we only report the results for a system in which both S

and SIG are included simultaneously. Third, we continue to use the
monetary base as the measure of money whereas many VAR studies use
Ml; however, we obtain qualitatively similar results if we replace
the base by Ml (a change which also involves starting the sample in
1959

rather than

1948).

Hence the

estimated system consists

of

unemployment, UN, the monetary base, DB, mean stock price growth,
DSP, and the two dispersion measures, S and SIG. The lag length is
set

at

eight

for

the

S variable

and

four

for

all

the

other

variables.
Panel A shows that lags of stock market dispersion continue to
be

significant

inclusion

of

at

DSP

about
does

a

not

5%

level.

eliminate

Panel
the

B

shows

importance

that
of

S

the
for

unemployment. While the stock market mean is fairly important at
the shorter forecast horizons, stock market dispersion continues to
account for between 34% and 39% of the variance of unemployment at
the longer horizons.
Barro
between

mean

(1989)

has

recently

stock price

growth

investigated

the

and aggregate

relationship

investment

using

reduced-from equations similar to those we use in Section 3. He
finds that lagged stock price growth has strong explanatory value
for

the

(growth

rate

of)

investment

and,

moreover,

that

this

variable dominates other predictors of investment such as q and
measures of cash flow.8 In a companion paper,
provides




recent evidence

Barro

confirming the well-known

(1988b)

also

link between

2 4

mean

stock price

growth and subsequent movements

in output. In

light of these results, it is interesting to briefly return to the
reduced-form

framework

and

see

whether

the

inclusion

of

stock

market dispersion has any impact of Barro's findings for output and
investment.

Table

6 presents

the

results

from

augmenting

the

unconstrained reduced form regressions to include the growth rate
of the S&P 500; Table 7 presents similar results from a constrained
system, where the coefficients for DB, DSP, and S are constrained
to lie along a second order polynomial. In both Tables we see that
mean stock price growth has a strong effect on output,
and

unemployment:

Many

of

the

individual

investment

coefficients

significantly different from zero and, except for output,

are

so too

are the sums of the coefficients.
Including the growth rate of stock prices seemingly reduces
the impact of our dispersion variable. In particular, for both the
unconstrained investment and unemployment regressions the sum of
our dispersion variables is no longer significantly different from
zero at conventional levels.

However,

it is important to notice

that this reduction takes place among the contemporaneous and first
few lags of dispersion.

If we examine only the last four lagged

coefficients

find

we

again

that

the

sums

are

significantly

different from zero: In the investment regression, the F-statistic
for the sum of the last four dispersion coefficients is 2.43 and in
the

unemployment

regression the F-statistic

is 2.29.

Given

our

emphasis on the lagged coefficients,

we find the point that the

lags

Looking

remain




significant

reassuring.

now

to

the

output

25

regression,
well

as

we can see that the sum of all the coefficients— as

the

sum

of

just

the

last

four

coefficients— is

significantly different from zero. Moreover, when we constrain the
coefficients

in Table

7,

the

sums

as well

as

the

last

several

coefficients again emerge as significant.

C. The Role of Interest Rate Spreads
Following the work of Sims

(1980), who drew attention to the

strong predictive power of the commercial paper rate for output, it
has become customary to include some measure of interest rates in
VAR systems that attempt to test whether movements in money affect
real activity. Sims
interest

rates

(1982) and McCallum

rather than monetary

(1986) suggest that it is

growth

rates

that

properly

capture Federal Reserve actions, which may account for their being
informative about the future of the real economy. However, a flurry
of recent papers has shown that measures of interest rate spreads—
differences between interest rates on alternative financial assets-dominate

measures

of

the

level

of

interest

rates

as

robust

predictors of economic activity.9 While the measure of the spread
used differs across studies,

the measure that appears to perform

the best is the difference between the short-term commercial paper
rate and the short-term Treasury bill rate. In prediction equations
for real GNP, Friedman and Kuttner (1989) find that the sum of the
interest rate spread variables is significant at the .001 level or
better in all their specifications.

Stock and Watson

(1989)— who

examined the information contained in a wide array of variables in




26

constructing

a

new

index

of

leading

indicators— find

that

the

spread outperforms nearly every other variable in forecasting the
business cycle. Bernanke (1990) provides preliminary evidence that
the reason the spread works so well in predicting economic activity
is that it combines information about the stance of monetary policy
and, to a lesser extent, expected default risk.
To the extent that the stock market dispersion index is also
responding

to

information

about

the

future

course

of

monetary

policy, including the interest rate spread in the VAR system should
weaken its correlation with unemployment. Table 8 reports results
obtained by adding the measure of the spread used by Friedman and
Kuttner, the difference between the 4-to-6 month commercial paper
rate and the 3 month Treasury Bill rate, which we call IRS, to the
VAR system discussed earlier.
Panel A reports the F-tests for the unemployment equation. All
the variables included in the system are significant and,

as in

Friedman and Kuttner's work with output, the interest rate spread
is significant at better than a .001 level. Panel B reports the
variance decomposition of unemployment for two different orderings.
Ordering 1 places the employment dispersion first in the system and
the

stock

positions.

dispersion

last

whereas

Ordering

2

reverses

Several conclusions are apparent. First,

these

the interest

rate spread explains a much larger fraction of the variance than
the

monetary

base.

Second,

the

contribution

of

employment

dispersion is relatively modest, ranging from 3% to 9% at step 20.
The most important conclusion, from our perspective, is that stock




27

market dispersion continues to account for a large fraction of the
variance of unemployment; at step 20, for instance, between 25% and
33% of the variance is attributable to movements in S.

D. Have We Adequately Controlled for Aggregate Demand ?
In

the

preceding

monetary base growth
stock price growth

sections

we

have

used

four

variables—

(DB), government spending changes
(DSP)

and the interest rate spread

(GY), mean
(IRS)— to

capture the state of current and future aggregate demand.

In this

section we conduct some tests suggested by Abraham and Katz

(1984,

pp. 17-20) to detemine whether these variables adequately control
for the impact of aggregate demand fluctuations on sectoral stock
price growth.1
0
As before,

let Sl denote the stock price index for industry
t

i at time t and define rl = log
t

. We regress rl on the
t

aggregate demand variables:
(7 )

rl = Yo + YiDBt + Y2GYt + y 3D SPt + Y4 IR S t + T i
t
lt

where the T lt/s are residuals.
|

We then construct a stock market

index based on the residuals from equation
(8)

(x):

Sp
urged, = [Z wit( i t - T t)2]1 2
t
Tl
j
/

where T t is a weighted average of the “
]
Hit's.
We also estimate these equations allowing lagged values of the
aggregate

demand proxies— as

well

as

current

values— to

affect

sectoral stock price growth;
(9 )

We

r it = Yo + S y u D B t.i + SY2iGYt.i + ^ D S P ^

picked




two

alternate

lag

lengths,

4

+ EY4iIRSt_i + T i'it

and

8 . The

two

Spu g d
re

28

measures

corresponding

correlated
equation

with

the

(7) . This

to

one
is

these

lag

lengths

constructed

shown

using

in Panel

A

of

turn
the

to

be

highly

residuals

Table

9.

from

Hence

the

subsequent work only uses the estimated equations (7) and the Spu
rged
measure given in (8) .
If the four variables— GY, DB, DSP and IRS— do a good job of
capturing

the

common

factors

that

underlie variations

in

stock

market returns then the correlation among the T lt's should be much
|
lower than the correlation among the rit's. Whether or not this is
indeed the case is investigated in Panel B of Table 9.
The top number in each cell of the table gives the
correlation

between

the

r^'s

for

eight

industries

simple

which

were

randomly chosen from our set of 60 industries. The bottom number
gives the corresponding correlation between the T it's. As shown, the
)
correlation between the rit's is uniformly positive— the average
correlation is 0.42— which indicates that some common factors do
underlie the variations in sectoral stock price returns. However
the correlation between the T , ' s is almost always close to zero,
h.
suggesting that the four variables adequately control for aggregate
demand. The cases where the correlation between the elt's is non­
zero tend to be cases where the two industries belong to the same
broader industry group,

e.g.,

the

for

residual

returns

"Aluminum" and "Copper." Note that
"Auto"

and

"Oil"

are

negatively

correlated, as one might expect in a period dominated by strong oil
price shocks.
Finally,




we

present

results

obtained

from

including

Spu
rged

29

instead of S in the VAR system. Panel A of Table 10 shows that the
sum

of

the

lagged

values

of

the

"purged"

dispersion

index

is

significant at a 2% level of significance. Panel B shows that Sp r a
ugd
explains 22% of the variance of unemployment if placed last in the
system and 33% if placed first.
Figure

1

plots

the

impulse

response

of

unemployment

innovations in the other variables of the system. As shown,

to

Sp r e
ugd

has a strong impact on unemployment with the peak occurring around
lag 10. The impact is also fairly persistent; for instance, at lag
12 the impact of monetary base innovations is essentially zero but
the impact of Sp r e is still at half its peak effect.
ugd

V.

CONCLUSIONS
A multi-sector economy is subject to a variety of shocks that-

-initially at least— affect only one or a few sectors. Many recent
papers

investigate the impact of such sector-specific shocks,

prominent

example being Grossman and Levinsohn's

(1990)

empirical

study

in

the

capital

in

competing

of

import

the
goods

impact
on

of

variations

returns

to

a

careful

prices
six

of

U.S.

industries. Their study complements Grossman's (1987) earlier work
on

the

employment

competition.
sectoral

While

shocks,

and

wage

our

focus

our

goal

in

effects
is

also

this

of
on

paper

variations
the
is

in

impacts

different:

import
of
We

such
are

interested in determining the extent to which sectoral shocks can
lead to changes in broad macroeconomic aggregates such as real GNP,
aggregate investment and aggregate unemployment. Recent theoretical




30

work emphasizes two channels through which this can occur. First,
if physical

capital

reallocation

and human

of resources

affected by

sectoral

uncertainty

about

out

shocks
the

capital
of

are

sector-specific,

industries

can be costly.

relative

returns

that

are

Second,
to

the

adversely

if there

is

sector-specific

investment, firms and workers may delay making any investment until
the uncertainty is resolved.
Instead of explicitly modelling specific shocks,
Lilien's

we

follow

(1982) innovative use of a dispersion index to proxy for

the intensity of sector-specific shocks.

Unlike Lilien, however,

we use the dispersion in stock price growth across industries—
rather than employment growth dispersion— to measure the intensity
of sectoral shifts. The results from fairly standard reduced-form
equations

suggest that,

controlling for the effects

base growth and fiscal policy,

of monetary

stock market dispersion leads to a

significant increase in unemployment and a decline in real GNP and
investment.
While these initial results give strong support for a sectoral
shifts explanation of unemployment,
robustness,
1986)

particularly

critique

of

in light

Lilien's

it is necessary to test their
of Abraham and Katz's

employment

dispersion

(1984,

index.

Our

principal empirical findings are as follows:
(i)




Using

a

VAR

framework,

contemporaneous

we

correlation

find

that

between

there
the

is

a

strong

innovations

unemployment and innovations in employment dispersion.

in
This

makes it very difficult to distinguish empirically a model in

3 1

which

exogenous

unemployment

shifts

in

from a model

employment

dispersion

in which the

causality

cause

runs

the

other way. Hence we confirm the basic Abraham-Katz finding,
albeit in a different empirical framework.

stock

(ii) When

sectoral

market

dispersion

reallocation,

there

is

used

is

as

the

little

measure

evidence

of

that

unemployment Granger-causes movements in the stock dispersion
index. On the other hand, after controlling for the effects of
standard

aggregate

growth and changes

demand

shifters

such

as

in government purchases,

monetary

base

innovations

in

stock market dispersion account for between 32% to 38% of the
variance of unemployment at long horizons.
(iii) We recognize that stock prices are forward-looking and hence
our dispersion index may be influenced not only by the current
state of aggregate demand,

as reflected in money growth and

government spending, but also by the future state of aggregate
demand. This leads us to expand our VAR system to include two
"information" variables that have emerged in recent studies as
robust predictors of economic activity.
the mean return on the stock market
Fischer and Merton

(1984)]

These variables are

[see Barro

(1988,

1989) ,

and an interest rate spread— the

differential between the short-term commercial paper rate and
the

short-term month

Kuttner
Bernanke

(1989),
(1990),

Stock

Treasury bill
and Watson

rate
(1989)].

[see Friedman
As

the spread appears to reflect

discussed

and
in

largely the

stance of monetary policy. However, even after controlling for




32

the effects

of these additional variables

on unemployment,

innovations in stock market dispersion account for between 25%
and 33% of the variance of unemployment at long horizons.
(iv) The set of four variables— DB, GY, DSP and IRS— does a good
job of capturing the common
stock price movements.

factors that underlie sectoral

Regressions

of sectoral

stock price

growth on these variables yield residuals that are virtually
uncorrelated across industries.
(v)

Finally, we construct a proxy for sectoral shifts, Spurged that
is purged of the influence of aggregate demand. This measure
continues to account for between 22% and 31% of the variance
of unemployment.




33

REFERENCES
Abraham, Katharine and Lawrence Katz, 1984, Cyclical
Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Disturbances?,
NBER Working Paper no. 1410.
Abraham, Katharine and Lawrence Katz, 1986, Cyclical
Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Disturbances?,
Journal of Political Economy. 94, 507-22.
Aiyagari, Rao S., Lawrence Christiano and Martin Eichenbaum. "The
Output, Employment and Interest Rate Effects of Government
Consumption." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper
No. WP-90-10, June 1990.
Barro, Robert J. "Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in
the United States." American Economic Review. March 1977,
101-115.
Barro, Robert J. "Output Effects of Government Purchases."
Journal of Political Economy. December 1981, 1086-1121.
Barro, Robert J. Comment on "Do Equilibrium Real Business
Theories Explain Postwar U.S. Business Cycles" by Martin
Eichenbaum and Ken Singletion, NBER Macroeconomics Annual
1986.
Barro, Robert J. "The Neoclassical Approach to Fiscal Policy."
in Modern Business Cycle Theory, edited by Robert J. Barro.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1988. (1988a)
Barro, Robert J. "The Stock Market and the Macroeconomy:
Implications of the October 1987 Crash, Working Paper,
Harvard University, February 1988. (1988b)
Barro, Robert J. "The Stock Market and Investment." NBER Working
Paper No. 2925, April 1989.
Barro, Robert J. and Mark Rush. "Unanticipated Money and
Economic Activity." in Rational Expectations and Economic
Policy, edited by Stanley Fischer, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1980.
Becker, Gary. Human Capital. NBER, New York,

1964.

Bernanke, Ben. "On the Predictive Power of Interest Rates and
Interest Rate Spreads." Working Paper, Princeton University,
June 4, 1990.
Black, Fischer. Business Cycles and Equilibrium. New York, N.
Y.:Basil Blackwell, 1987.




34

Brainard, Lael and David Cutler. "Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical
Unemployment." Working Paper, December 1989.
Courtney, Hugh. "Asymmetric Responses in Factor Demands and the
Business Cycle." Working Paper, MIT, November 1989.
Davis, Steve. "Allocative Disturbances and Temporal Asymmetry in
Labor Market Fluctuations." Working Paper, Chicago GSB,
January 1985.
Davis, Steve. "Fluctuations in the Pace of Labor Reallocation."
Carneaie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 27,
Spring 1987, 335-402.
Denslow, Dave and Mark Rush. "Supply Shocks and the Interest
Rate." Economic Inquiry. July 1989.
Diebold, Francis and Glenn Rudebusch. "Long Memory and
Persistence in Aggregate Output." Journal of Monetary
Economics. 1989.
Eisner, Robert and Robert Strotz. "Determinants of Business
Investment," in Impacts of Monetary Policy. Commission on
Money and Credit, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, 60-338.
Estrella, Arturo and Gikas Hardouvelis. "The Term Structure as a
Predictor of Interest Rates." Working Paper, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, March 1989.
Fazzari, Stephen, Glenn Hubbard and Bruce Petersen. "Financing
Constraints and Corporate Investment." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity. 1988:1, 141-95.
Fischer, Stanley and Robert Merton. "Macroeconomics and Finance:
The Role of the Stock Market." Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, 21, 1984, 57-108.
Friedman, Benjamin and Kenneth Kuttner. "Money, Income and Prices
after the 1980's." NBER Working Paper No. 2852, February
1989.
Frydman, Roman and Peter Rappoport. "Is the Distinction Between
Anticipated and Unanticipated Money Growth Relevant in
Explaining Aggregate Output?" American Economic Review.
September 1987, 693-703.
Grossman, Gene and James Levinsohn. "Import Competition and the
Stock Market Return to Capital." American Economic Review.
79, December 1989, 1065-87.
Hamilton, James D. "A Neoclassical Model of Unemployment and the
Business Cycle." Journal of Political Economy. 96, 1988,




35

593-617.
Hosios, Arthur J. "Unemployment and Vacancies with Sectoral
Shifts." University of Toronto Working Paper, August 1988.
King, Robert and Charles Plosser. "Money, Credit and Prices in a
Real Business Cycle Model." American Economic Review. 1984.
Kowalczyk, Carsten and Prakash Loungani. "Energy Prices and
Sectoral Reallocation." Working Paper, October 1990.
Laurent, Robert D. "An Interest Rate-Based Predictor of Monetary
Policy." Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, January/February 1988, 3-14.
Laurent, Robert D. "Testing the 'Spread'." Economic Perspectives.
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, July/August 1989, 22-34.
Leban, R. and J. Lesourne. "The Firm's Investmant and Employment
Policy through a Business Cycle." European Economic Review.
13, 1980, 43-80.
Lilien, David. "Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment."
Journal of Political Economy. 90, 1982, 777-793.
Loungani, Prakash. "Oil Price Shocks and the Dispersion
Hypothesis." The Review of Economics and Statistics. August
1986, 536-539.
Loungani, Prakash and Richard Rogerson. "Cyclical Fluctuations
and the Sectoral Reallocation of Labor: Evidence From the
PSID." Journal of Monetary Economics. March 1989. (1989a)
Loungani, Prakash, Richard Rogerson, and Yang-Hoon Sonn. "Labor
Mobility, Unemployment and Sectoral Shifts: Evidence From
Micro Data." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper
No. 89-22, December 1989. (1989b)
Loungani, Prakash and Mark Rush. "Sectoral Shifts in Interwar
Britain." Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago Working Paper No. WP-90-7, June 1990. (1990a)
Loungani, Prakash, Mark Rush, and William Tave. "Stock Market
Dispersion and Unemployment." Forthcoming, Journal of
Monetary Economics. May 1990. (1990b)




36

Loungani, Prakash, Mark Rush and William Tave. "Stock Market
Dispersion and the Macroeconomy." Forthcoming, Economic
Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. (1990c)
Lucas, Robert and Edward Prescott. "Equilibrium Search and
Unemployment." Journal of Economic Theory. 1974, 188-209.
McCallum, Bennett T. "On 'Real' and 'Sticky-Price' Theories of
the Business Cycle." Journal of Money. Credit and Banking.
November 1986, 397-414.
Mishkin, Frederic S. "Does Anticipated Monetary Policy Matter?
An Econometric Investigation." Journal of Political Economy.
February, 1982, 22-51.
Murphy, Kevin M. and Robert Topel. "The Evolution of
Unemployment in the United States: 1968-85." in NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1987. edited by Stanley Fischer.
Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987.
Neumann, George and Robert Topel. "Employment Risk, Sectoral
Shifts and the Geographic Distribution of Unemployment."
Working Paper, 1985.
Nickell, Stephen. "Fixed Costs, Employment and Labor Demand over
the Business Cycle." Economica. 45, 1978, 327-345.
Oi, Walter. Comment on the Relationship between Unemployment and
Sectoral Shifts. Carneoie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy. 27, 403-406.
Oi, Walter. "Labor as a Quasi-Fixed Factor." Journal of Political
Economy. 70, 1962, 538-55.
Rissman, Ellen. "What is the Natural Rate of Unemployment?"
Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
September/October 1986, 3-17.
Rogerson, Richard. "Sectoral Shocks, Human Capital and Displaced
Workers." Working Paper, Stanford University, July 1989.
Rush, Mark. "Unexpected Money and Unemployment: 1920 to 1983."
Journal of Money. Credit, and Banking. August 1986, 259-274.
Sims, Christopher A. "Comparison of Interwar and Postwar Business
Cycles: Monetarism Reconsidered." American Economic Review.
May 1982, 250-257.
Sims, Christopher A. "Policy Analysis with Econometric Models"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1982, 107-152.




37

Stock, James and Mark Watson. "New Indexes of Coincident and
Leading Economic Indicators." NBER Macroeconomics Annual
1989. MIT Press.
Sims, Christopher A. "Policy Analysis with Econometric Models"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1982, 107-152.
Strongin, Steve. "Macroeconomic Models and the Term Structure of
Interest Rates." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working
Paper No. WP-90-14, September 1990.
Topel, Robert. "Specific Cpaital and Unemployment: Measuring the
Costs and Consequences of Job Loss." Working Paper,
University of Chicago, February 1990.
Topel, Robert and Laurence Weiss. "Sectoral Uncertainty and
Unemployment." Chapter 16 in Employment. Unemployment and
Labor Utilization, 1985.
Weiss, Laurence. "Asymmetric Adjustment Costs and Sectoral
Shifts," in Heller e t . a l . (eds.) Equilibrium Analysis:
Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Volume II, 1986,
Cambridge University Press.




38

Table 1: UNCONSTRAINED REGRESSIONS

O U T PU T

IN V E S T M E N T

UNEM PLO YM ENT

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
C
.83***
.16

STANDARD
COEFFICIENTERROR
C
-.88***
.26

DB
.15
DB1
.18
DB2 -.12
.11
DB3
DB4 -.05
.11
DB5
D B 6 -.02
DB7
.11
.13
DB8

.13
.13
.14
.14
.13
.12
.12
.12
.10

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB6
DB7
DB8

DB
-2.29***
DB1
-.58
DB2
2 .12***
DB3 -2.63***
-.14
DB4
.47
DB5
.62
DB6
DB7 -3.62***
DB 8
.80

.25

I

.30
.32
.33
.32
.31
.29
.29
.28
.25

-1.26***

•

.62**

I

-.01
1 .20***
-.88**
.15
.40
-.25
-.06
.96***
-.24

GO

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
C
.82***
.22

.09
.10
.11
.11
.11
.11
.11
.10
.09

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
SI
S8

.12
.46*
-.11
.21
-.18
.52*
-.19
.69**
.15

.24
.27
.29
.29
.29
.30
.29
.28
.24

.60***

.2 1

I

1.67***

.54

-.014
-.050
-.097**
.031
-.075
.034
-.078*
.001
-.066*

.037
.043
.045
.047
.046
.046
.045
.043
.038

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
SI
S8

I

-.312***

.086

I

LF
LF1
T

.057
LF
.014
.025
-.029
LF1
-.014
.056
-.035
.025
T .0012***
.0002
.0008***
.0002
1.14***
-.24***

R2 .9994
=

.09
.08

LI1
LI2

S E = .0091

- 5.25*** 1 .40

.16*
-.30***
.05
-.12
.05
-.12
-.06
-.06
-.19**

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

LY1
LY2

I

.81
.88
.86
.87
.84
.79
.80
.77
.66

1.30***
-.42***

.08
.08

R2 .997 6SE= .0217
=

GY
GY1

-•1.57
1.68

DEMO
.045**
DEMOl -.039**
UNI
1.48***
UN 2
-.66***

1 .14
1 .17
.020
.020
.07
.07

R:! 9708SE= .0584
=.

*** indicates significance at the 1% level; ** at the 5% level
and * at the 10% level.




39

Table 2: CONSTRAINED REGRESSIONS

O U T PU T

IN V E ST M E N T

UNEM PLO YM ENT

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
.21
.87***
C

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
94 * * * .17
C

STANDARD
COEFFICIENTERROR
•1.04***
.27
C

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB6
DB7
DB8

.16*
.10*
.05
.02
.02
.02
.05*
.09***
.15***

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB6
DB7
DB8

I

.66**

S

S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

-.047**
-.040**
-.035***
-.032**
-.030**
-.031**
-.034***
-.039***
-.046**

I

- .3 3 4 * * *

LF
LF1
T

LF
.017
-.089
.058
.023
LF1
.034
.024
.058
-.040*
.0002
T .0013***
.0003
.0008***

S3

1 .10***
-.20***

LY1
LY2
•

I
I

CM

9994

.19
.11
.07
.08
.09
.08
.07
.08
.14

DB
-•1.41***
DB1
-.91.***
DB2
-. 54***
DB3
-.31
DB4
-.22
DB5
-.26
D B 6 -.43**
DB7
-.75***
DB 8 -■
1.20

.52
.30
.21
.22
.25
.24
.21
.23
.38

I

1 .5 6 * * *

.51

I

- ■6.01***

1 .4 7

.024
.016
.013
.014
.014
.013
.012
.014
.022

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S8

-.061
-.052
-.049
-.052
-.061*
-.076**
-.098***
-.125***
-.159***

.063
.041
.033
.036
.037
.035
.031
.037
.059

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

.33**
.22**
.15***
.11
.11
.14
.22***
.33***
.48***

.16
.11
.09
.09
.09
.09
.08
.10
.16

.084

I

- .7 3 2 * * *

.2 1 9

2 .0 9 * * *

.5 6

C
M

SI
S2

.40**
.25**
.14*
.07
.04
.05
.10
.19**
.33**

.08
.05
.03
.03
.04
.03
.03
.03
.06

.08
.08

SE=.0091

SI

LI 1
LI2

1 .21***
- .

34

R2 .9970
=

***

.08
.08

SE= .0234

I
GY
GY1

- 1.57
1.75

1.16
1.19

DEMO
.029
DEMOl -.022
UNI
1.40***
UN 2
-.59***
R2 .9638
=

.020
.020
.07
.07

SE =.0621

*** indicates significance at the 1% level; ** at the 5% level;
and * at the 10% level.




40
Key:
SIG = employment dispersion
GY = govt, purchases/trend GNP
DB =: monetary base growth
UN =: unemployment rate

Table 3
VAR System: SI 6 6Y DB UN
Sample Period: 1951:1 to 1987 :4
F-TESTS : UN

Panel A
VARIABLE
SIG
GY
DB
UN

F-STAT.
4.70
1.94
3.75
189.45

F-TESTS: SIG

SIGN. : VL.
L
.00005
.05946
.00003
.00000

F-STAT.
3.18
2.71
2.63
1.62

SIGN. LVL.
.0027
.0089
.0110
.1275

Entries are F-statistic values and significance levels of the
hypothesis that 8 lags of the variable can be excluded. from the
unemployment and employment dispersion equations.
Panel B

CORRELATION MATRIX OF RESIDUALS

VARIABLE

1 . 000

SIG
GY
DB
UN

2
4
8
12
20

DB

UN

- 0.114
- 0.005

0.026

#
#

1.000

0.313
- 0.128
- 0.091

1.000

•

Panel . C
STEP

GYI

SIG

•

1.000

•

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 1
SIG

15.8
10.9
16.6
18.3
17.7

UN
GY
1.4
4.0
7.5
11.6
13.5

DB

UN

2.2
3.2
6.9
7.2
7.4

80.5
82.0
68.9
62.8
61.4

SIG
95.9
83.7
80.6
76.7
74.9

SIG
GY

DB

1.0
7.9
9.0
8.6
8.6

0.1
2.5
3.4
5.1
5.1

UN
3.0
5.9
7.0
9.5
11.3

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 2
STEP

GY

UN
DB

UN

SIG

2
4
8
12
20

1.2
3.6
6.9
10.9
13.0

3.7
4.6
9.3
9.8
9.9

94.2
91.4
80.7
74.8
72.7

SIG
0.8
0.3
3.1
4.5
4.6

GY
0.8
7.4
8.6
8.2
8.2

DB

UN

1.7
3.7
4.5
6.1
6.1

16.5
19.4
19.3
21.2
22.5

SIG
81.0
69.4
67.6
64.9
63.1

Entries show percentage of forecast variance of unemployment and
employment dispersion at different horizons attributable to
innovations in the variables of the system. Ordering is as shown




41
Key:
S =
GY =
DB =
UN =

Table 4
VAR System: S GY DB UN
Sample Period: 1951:2 to 1987:4

stock market dispersion
govt, purchases/trend GNP
monetary base growth
unemployment rate

F-TESTS: UN

Panel A

F-STAT.
2.61
1.24
3.04
165.29

VARIABLE
S
GY
DB
UN

F-TESTS : S
SIGN. L V L .
.0116
.2807
.0038
.0000

F-STAT.
4.31
3.21
0.69
0.98

SIGN. LVL.
.0001
.0025
.6942
.4522

Entries are: F-statistic: values and significance levels of the
hypothesis that 8 lags of the variable can be excluded from the
unemployment and stock dispersion equations.
panel B

CORRELATION MATRIX OF RESIDUALS

VARIABLE

1.000

S
GY
DB
UN
Panel C
STEP
2
4
8
12
20

GYI

S

- 0.022

#

1.000

DB

UN

0.046
- 0.044

0.101
- 0.131
- 0.085

1.000
•

•

1.000

•

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 1
S
4.9
11.5
25.1
37.5
36.7

UN
GY

1.0
1.6
1.9
3.9
7.5

DB
2.0
3.3
8.2
7.5
7.6

UN
92.1
87.8
64.8
51.1
48.1

S
97.5
92.9
84.6
80.9
75.2

S
GY
1.2
4.9
10.3
13.9
16.6

DB
0.8
1.7
3.0
3.9
6.7

UN
0.5
0.5
0.9
1.3
1.5

S
DB

UN

S

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 2
STEP
2
4
8
12
20

GY

1.0
1.8
2.2
4.4
8.1

UN
DB
1.7
2.8
7.0
6.2
6.4

UN
95.4
88.9
71.0
56.7
53.6

S
1.8
6.4
19.8
32.7
31.9

GY
1.5
5.0
10.4
14.0
16.5

0.7
1.7
2.7
3.8
6.2

0.9

1.0
1.2
1.7
1.8

97.0
92.3
85.6
80.6
75.5

Entries show percentage of forecast variance of unemployment and
stock market dispersion at different horizons attributable to
innovations in the variables of the system. Ordering is as shown.




42
Table 5
VAR System: S SI 6 DSP DB UN
Sample Period: 1951:2 to 1987:4
Key: S
SIG
DSP
DB
UN
Panel A
VARIABLE

s
SIG
DSP
DB
UN

=
=
=
=
=

stock market dispersion index
employment dispersion index
growth rate of S&P 500
monetary base growth
unemployment rate

P-TESTS: UN
F-STATISTIC
1 .96
4. 96
4. 05
2 .58
496. 57

SIGNIF. LEVEL
.0576
.0010
.0041
.0408
.0000

Entries are F-statistic values and significance levels of
hypothesis that 4 lags of the variable (8 in the! case of ;
be excluded from the unemployment equations.
Panel B
DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 1 (SIG DSP1 DB UN S)
STEP

S

SIG

2
4
8
12
20

1.7
4.4
11.4
27.1
33.8

12.0
5.3
5.7
6.2
5.6

DSP

DB

4.0
25.2
32.2
28.8
27.5

0.8
1.6
5.5
4.6
4.4

UN
81.5
69.9
45.2
33.3
28.6

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 2 (S DSP DB UN SIG)
STEP

S

SIG

DSP

DB

2
4
8
12
20

2.6
6.1
14.3
31.1
39.0

0.4
1.1
1.5
1.9
2.0

2.5
15.6
26.1
21.8
20.2

2.4
3.3
9.8
9.6
8.4

UN
92.2
73.8
48.3
35.5
30.4

Entries show percentage of forecast variance of unemployment at
different horizons attributable to innovations in the variables
of the system. Ordering is as shown in parenthesis (...).




43

Table 6: UNCONSTRAINED REGRESSIONS WITH STOCK PRICE GROWTH

OUTPUT

INVESTMENT

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
.23
.45**
C

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
.17
.74***
C

STANDARD
COEFFICIENTERROR
C
■ •07***
1
.26

.13
.13
.13
.13
.13
.12
.12
.11
.11

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB 6
DB7
DB 8

-.11
1 .22***
-.70**
.12
.36
-.24
-.02
1 .01***
-.16

.31
.31
.33
.31
.31
.29
.29
.28
.26

DB
2 .20**
DB1
-.98
DB2
1.96**
DB3 -•2.49***
DB4
-.44
DB5
.30
DB 6
.65
DB7 -•3.53***
DB 8
.42

.25

I

1.48***

.51

.004
DSP
DSP1 .032***
DSP2 .034***
DSP3 -.002
DSP4 .007
DSP5 -.007
DSP6 -.001
DSP7 -.012
DSP8 -.004

.011
.012
.012
.012
.012
.012
.012
.011
.012

DSP
-.019
DSP1
.035*
DSP2
.087***
.037
DSP3
DSP4
.023
DSP5
.033
.028
DSP6
DSP7
.032
DSP8
.018

- 6.31*** 1.61
.02
.07
DSP
DSP1 — .22 * * * .07
DSP2 -.18**
.08
DSP3 -.19**
.08
DSP4 -.09
.08
DSP5 -.11
.08
DSP6 -.03
.08
DSP7 -.10
.08
DSP8 -.08
.08

I

.050

.041

I

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

.006
-.060
-.093**
.015
-.063
.028
-.090**
.003
-.068*

.037
.042
.043
.046
.045
.045
.044
.043
.037

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
SI
S8

.208**
-.256**
.062
-.097
.079
-.056
-.073
-.040
-.166

I

-.323***

.094

I

-.340

LF
LF1
T

.036
-.061**
.0004*

.026
.026
.0002

LF
LF1
T

-.044
.058
-.001
.056
.0009***
.0003

DB
.01
.22*
DB1
DB2 -.12
.10
DB3
DB4 -.07
DB5
.11
.03
DB6
DB7
.06
.07
DB8
.39

I

R2 9995 SE=.0087
:
=.

LI1
LI2

1 .22***
-.32***

I

- 1 .00***

.30

.089
.101
.107
.107
.108
.107
.106
.101
.089

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
SI
S8

-.08
.41
-.19
.14
-.33
.34
-.17
.53**
.15

.24
.26
.28
.28
.28
.29
.29
.27
.24

.233

I

.59

.098

.09
.09

R‘ 9980SE= .0209
!
=.

GY
GY1

•

.09
.08

E

o

1.08***
-.12

.84
.86
.84
.85
.82
.77
.79
.75
.69

0
0

LY1
LY2

.275***

.027
.027
.028
.029
.029
.028
.029
.028
.029

UNEMPLOYMENT

-1.62
2.09*

DEMO
.042**
DEMOl -.034*
UNI
1.36***
UN 2
-.50***

1.13
1.16
.019
.019
.08
.08

R 2 .9755SE =.0555
:
=

*** indicates significance at the 1% level; ** at the 5% level;
and * at the 10% level.




4 4

Table 7: CONSTRAINED REGRESSIONS WITH STOCK PRICE GROWTH

INVESTMENT

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
.63***

STANDARD
COEFFICIENTERROR
-1.23***
.27
C

CM
CM
•

OUTPUT

STANDARD
COEFFICIENT ERROR
.92*** .17
C

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB6
DB7
DB8

.07
.04
.03
.03
.03
.05*
.08**

.2
1*

.08
.05
.03
.03
.04
.03
.03
.03
.06

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB 6
DB7
DB 8

I

.55**

.24

X

.018**
DSP
DSP1 .016**
DSP2 .014**
DSP3 .011*
DSP4 .007
DSP5 .003
DSP6 - . 0 0 2
DSP7 -.007
DSP8 -.013

.009
.006
.005
.006
.006
.005
.005
.006
.009

DSP
DSPl
DSP2
DSP3
DSP4
DSP5
DSP6
DSP7
DSP8

X

.041

c

.1 0

.046

.48***
.29**
.16**
.07
.04
.07
.15**
2 9* * *
.48***

.20
.11
.07
.08
.09
.08
.07
.09
.16

DB
DB1
DB2
DB3
DB4
DB5
DB6
DB7
DB 8

-1.79***
-1.16***
-.71***
-.43**
-.32
-.38
-.61***
-1 .01***
-1.59***

2.05***

.53

X

- 8 .00*** 1.67

.002
.022*
.038***
.048***
.053***
.053***
.047***
.036**
.020

.022
.015
.013
.014
.015
.015
.014
.017
.024

DSP
DSPl
DSP2
DSP3
DSP4
DSP5
DSP6
DSP7
DSP8

X

.32***

.10

-.017
-.006
-.002
-.006
-.019
-.039
-.067**
-.102***
-.146***

.062
.042
.036
.038
.039
.036
.032
.037
.057

X
s

.242

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

-.041*
-.036**
-.033**
-.031**
-.032**
-.033**
-.037***
-.042***
-.049**

.024
.016
.014
.014
.015
.014
.013
.014
. 0 2 2

S
SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
S7
S8

X

-.333***

.093

X

-.403*

LF
LF1
T

.026
-.051**
.0005**

.023
.024

LF
LF1
T

-.120** .057
.057
.064
.0011***
.0003

LY1
LY2

1.06***
-.12*

R2 .9994
=

. 0 0 0 2

.08
.08

SE= .0088

UNEMPLOYMENT

LI1
LI2

1 .11***
-.24***

.08
.07

R2 .9973SE=.0226
=

.56
.33
.21
.21
.24
.23
.21
.25
.43

-.08
-. 12***
-.14***
-.16***
-.16***
-.15***
— .14***
-.11**
-.07

.06
.04
.04
.04
.04
.04
.04
.05
.07

- 1 .1 1 ***

.30

SI
S2
S3
S4
S5
S6
SI
S8

.21
.08
.01
-.04
-.03
.02
.11
.25**
^44***

.16
.10
.09
.10
.10
.09
.09
.10
.15

X

1.06**

.62

GY
GY1

-1.29
1.70

.034*
DEMO
DEMO1-.024
UNI
1.27***
UN 2
-.46***

1.13
1.16
.019
.019
.08
.07

R2 9674SE=. 0596
=.

*** indicates significance at the 1% level; ** at the 5% level
and * at the 10% level.




45
Table 8
VAR System: S DSP SIG IRS DB UN
Sample Period: 1951:2 to 1987:4
Key: S
DSP
SIG
IRS
DB
UN
Panel A
VARIABLE
S
DSP
SIG
IRS
DB
UN

=
=
=
=
=
=

stock market dispersion index
growth rate of S&P 500
employment dispersion index
interest rate spread
monetary base growth
unemployment rate

F-TESTS: UN
F-STATISTIC
2.00
2.10
5.52
3.14
3.35
532.60

SIGNIF. LEVEL
.0520
.0838
.0004
.0171
.0122
.0000

Entries are F-statistic values and significance levels of the
hypothesis that 4 lags of the variable (8 lags in the case of S)
can be excluded from the unemployment equations.
Panel B
DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 1 (DSP SIG IRS DB UN S)
STEP
2
4
8
12
20

S
1.2
2.7
8.9
20.3
24.6

DSP
3.6
18.1
29.6
26.8
26.2

SIG
10.7
4.6
5.4
5.6
4.9

IRS
5.9
12.9
12.9
14.5
16.1

DB
0.7
1.8
5.8
14.5
16.1

UN
77.9
59.9
37.4
27.9
23.5

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 2 (S DSP IRS DB UN SIG)
STEP
2
4
8
12
20

S
2.0
4.9
12.8
27.0
33.1

DSP
3.1
16.4
26.1
22.5
21.5

SIG
0.4
0.7
1.2
1.8
1.9

IRS
4.5
10.7
9.7
9.6
10.4

DB
1.6
2.8
9.0
8.9
7.6

UN
88.3
64.4
41.1
30.3
25.5

Entries show percentage of forecast variance of unemployment at
different horizons attributable to innovations in the variables
of the system. Ordering is as shown in parenthesis (...).




46
Table 9
Panel A: Correlation matrix of alternate Spargsd measures
Spurged
(4 lags)

C
‘
-'purged

(8 lags)

c
‘
-'purged

0.936*

(no lags)

0.902*

C
‘
-'purged

(4 lags)

••

0.972*

)
Panel B : Correlation matrix of rlt's and T lt's
Entr.
Auto.

.47*
.01

Copp.

Alum.

Drug

.44*
-.01

.53*
.13

.21*
-.41*

.44*
-.09

.30*
-.07

.57*
.11

.40*
.05

.33*
-.11

.47*
.02

.39*
.07

.63*
.30*

.63*
.40*

.42*
.09

.52*
.25*

.23*
-.03

.47*
.11

.37*
-.06

.42*
.09

.24*
-.07

.43*
.00

.48*
.25*

.21*
-.11

.29*
-.20*

••

.26*
-.05

.47*
.05

Copp.
••
Alum.
••
•

#

•

•

••

••

•

•

•

Drug

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Media

••

••

Coal

Coal

.43*
.12

Entr.

Oil

Oil

.36*
-.01

* denotes that the null hypothesis that the correlation is zero
can be rejected at a significance level of .01
Kev to abbreviated industry names:
A u t o .= Automobiles; Entr.= Entertainment; Copp. = Copper;
Alum.= Aluminum; Oil = Domestic Oil; Media = Broadcast Media




47
Table 10
VAR System: Spurgad DSP SIG IRS DB UN
Sample Period: 1951:2 to 1987:4
Key: Spurged = "purged" stock market dispersion index
DSP = growth rate of S&P 500
SIG = employment dispersion index
IRS = interest rate spread
= monetary base growth
DB
= unemployment rate
UN

F-TESTS: O
N

Panel A
VARIABLE

Spurged
DSP
SIG
IRS
DB
UN

F-STATISTIC
2.39
3.30
5.52
2.78
5.16
426.53

SIGNIF. LEVEL
.0207
.0137
.0004
.0307
.0007

.0000

Entries are F-statistic values and significance levels of the
hypothesis that 4 lags of the variable (8 lags in the case of S)
can be excluded from the unemployment equations.
Panel B
DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 1 (DSP SIG IRS DB ON Sp r < l
ugK)

STEP
2
4
8
12
20

Spurqed
1.3
3.6
1 0 .6
20.5
2 2 .1

DSP
4.7
23.2
38.9
34.8
34.8

SIG
9.6
3.7
5.4
5.6
5.3

IRS
4.5
1 0 .0
8 .1
1 1 .0
1 2 .6

DB
3.1
5.3
9.5
7.7
6.9

UN

76.7
54.1
27.4
20.3
18.2

DECOMPOSITION OF VARIANCE: ORDERING 2 (SpU g < DSP IRS DB UN SIG)
rBj
STEP

Spurqed

2

2.4

4

6 .8

8
12
20

16.0
28.9
31.4

DSP
3.4
20.3
33.1
28.2
28.2

SIG
0.5
0.7
2.3
3.1
3.1

IRS
3.3
7.7
5.3
6.3
7.4

DB
5.1
7.2
13.7
11.9

UN
85.2
57.3
29.7

1 0 .6

19.3

2 1 .6

Entries show percentage of forecast variance of unemployment at
different horizons attributable to innovations in the variables
of the system. Ordering is as shown in parenthesis (...).




IMPULSE RESPONSE OF UN

-.0 7 5




48
APPENDIX I :

CONSTRUCTION OF THE D ISPE R SIO N INDEX

To assemble our measure of the dispersion of stock market
prices, we used 60 industrial indices compiled by Standard and
Poor's. The following listing, arranged by length of the data
series, gives the starting and, if relevant, ending dates as well
as the employment weight for each industry used:
INDUSTRY
OIL-COMPOSITE
MACHINERY (AGRICULTURAL)
AUTOMOBILES
COMPUTER SYSTEMS
ENTERTAINMENT
INVESTMENT COS (CLOSED END)
RETAIL STORES (DEPARTMENT STORES)
RETAIL STORES (FOOD CHAIN STORES)
COPPER
MACHINERY (CONSTRUCTION & MAT. HAND.)
OIL (CRUDE PRODUCERS)
BUILDING MATERIALS
COAL
DRUGS
FINANCIAL (PROPERTY-CASUALTY INSURANCE)
HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS
MACHINERY (DIVERSIFIED)
MONEY CENTER BANKS
PAPER
RETAIL STORES (COMPOSITE)
SHOES
STEEL
TIRES AND RUBBER GOODS
TRANSPORTATION (RAILROADS)
MACHINE TOOLS
CHEMICALS
CONTAINERS (METAL & GLASS)
FOODS
HEAVY DUTY TRUCKS & PARTS
TEXTILE PRODUCTS
TRANSPORTATION (AIRLINES)
UTILITIES (ELECTRIC POWER COMPANIES)
ELECTRONIC MAJOR COMPANIES
AEROSPACE/DEFENSE
BEVERAGES (SOFT DRINKS)
TEXTILES (APPAREL MANUFACTURERS)
BEVERAGES (DISTILLERS)
FINANCIAL (PERSONAL LOAN)
BEVERAGE S (
BREWERS)
ALUMINUM
DOMESTIC OILS
INTERNATIONAL OILS




STAR1’ END
YEAR YEAR. .
. w,
.004614
1926 —
1926 1985 .007786
1928 —
.048679
1930 —
.026044
1930 —
.008573
.001387
1930 —
.044414
1930
1930 —
.023748
1930 1986 .009005
1930 1985 .007786
1930 1985 .004614
1932 —
.009658
1932 -- .000850
1932 —
.032236
1932 —
.000669
1932 —
.032236
1932 —
.007786
1932 —
.021462
1932 —
.012355
1932 —
.044414
1932 —
.002114
1932 —
.009005
1932 —
.019075
1932 —
.017221
1933
.007786
1934 —
.032236
1934 —
.011508
.014427
1934
1934 —
.048679
1934 —
.010624
1934 —
.013094
1934
.013124
1934 1986 .026044
1936 —
.048679
.014427
1936 —
1936 —
.010188
1936 1986 .014427
1939 -- .001387
1940
.014427
1941 —
.009005
1943 —
.031571
.031571
1943 —
—

—

—

—

—

49

OIL WELL & EQUIPMENT SERVICE
ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT
GOLD MINING
HOUSEHOLD FURNISHINGS & APPLIANCES
MAJOR REGIONAL BANKS
METALS MISCELLANEOUS
NATURAL GAS PIPE LINES
PAPER CONTAINERS
NATURAL GAS DISTRIBUTORS
PUBLISHING
BROADCAST MEDIA
TRANSPORTATION (TRUCKERS)
FINANCIAL (SAVINGS & LOAN HOLD. COS.)
HOMEBUILDING
TRANSPORTATION (AIR FREIGHT)
ELECTRONICS (SEMICONDUCTORS)
COMPUTER SOFTWARE & SERVICES
HOSPITAL MANAGEMENT
The

1943 —
.007786
1945 —
.026044
1945
.004582
1945 —
.026044
—
1945
.021462
1945
.009005
1945
.013124
1945
.012355
1945 1984 .013124
1946
.011392
1947
.005688
1957 —
.011936
.001387
1959 —
1965 —
.001766
1965 —
.013094
1970 —
.026044
1978 —
.025904
1978
.020130
—

—

—
—

—

-

-

—

weights used to construct S were derived from the

Standard and Poor's Compustat II 1968-1987 Annual Aggregate
Industrial File computer data tape.

This tape lists, among other

data, annual employment for each industry.

The industries are

organized by four-digit codes similar to the SIC codes, though
the industry break-down is not exactly the same as in the
Standard and Poor's Security Price Index, from which the stock
data were obtained. However, the composition of these industries
were the same for two-digit industries. Thus, we needed to make
some approximations. We wanted weights based on data near the
center point of our sample period. Thus, we started by using the
four digit industries and calculated the industry's average
employment figure using data between 1968 to 1972. If all of
these years were missing data, we used the employment figure from
the year closest to 1972. These four-digit industry weights were
then grouped into the two-digit industry and the share of
employment accounted for by each two-digit industry was




calculated. Finally, to give our w1 this share was divided by
#
the number of our sixty industries that fell within each of the
two-digit categories. Thus, similar industries that fall within
the same two digit classification, eg FOOD and BEVERAGES, have
the same employment weight.




51

FOOTNOTES

1. Brainard and Cutler (1989) regress industry stock growth on mean
stock price growth and use the residuals from these regressions to
construct their stock market dispersion index. However, despite
this difference, the correlation between their index and ours is
high: 0.66 in levels and 0.74 in logs.
2. For a discussion of asymmetries in adjustment costs of quasifixed factors, see Nickell (1978), Leban and Lesourne (1980), Weiss
(1986) and Courtney (1989).
3. The losses are actually larger for occupational change than
industry change, which is consistent with the comments of
(1987) . See Loungani, Rogerson and Sonn for evidence on
contribution
of
occupational mobility
to total
weeks
unemployment.

for
Oi
the
of

4. Two points about our specification deserve mention. First,
since we include time trends in the output and investment
regressions, which is equivalent to detrending all the
independent variables, the specification of the government
spending variable is actually quite similar to that in the
unemployment regression. Second, the distinction between
permanent and temporary changes in spending is important in
theory [see Barro (1981 and 1988a), Denslow and Rush (1989) and
Aiyagari, Christiano and Eichenbaum (1990)] and empirical
applications that include major wars. However, our sample period
includes only the Korean and Vietnam wars; neither of these
seemed sufficiently important relative to total output to enable
us to distinguish between temporary and permanent government
spending.
5. Our choice of the base as the measure of money is motivated by
the possible endogeneity of broader monetary aggregates such as Ml.
See King and Plosser (1984) and Rush (1986) for a further
discussion of this issue. Studies that use quarterly data, starting
with Barro and Rush (1980) and up to the more recent Frydman and
Rappoport (1987), tend to find that all changes in the money
supply— not just unexpected changes— matter for real activity.
Hence we do not pursue a decomposition of base growth into expected
and unexpected components.
6. There is still a lot of dispute over whether macro aggregates
such as GNP are difference-stationary, as suggested by Nelson and
Plosser (1982), or trend stationary, as suggested in many other
studies such as Diebold and Rudebusch (1988). Faced with this
uncertainty, we opted for the traditional approach of assuming




52

trend stationarity.
7. For instance, we increased the number of lags for S and DB to
twelve and sixteen; increased the lags for government spending and
DEMO to four; and increased the lags for the dependent variable to
three and four. Individually and jointly the added lags rarely
attained standard levels of significance.
8. For alternate views of the investment process that stress the
role of cash flow variables, see Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen
(1988) .
9. In addition to the studies cited in the main text of the paper,
the role of interest rate spreads is investigated in Laurent (1988,
1989), Estrella and Hardouvelis (1989) and Strongin (1990).1
0
10. It is quite likely that variables such as DSP are responding to
events such as oil price shocks, which are not pure aggregate
demand shocks. In fact, Davis (1985), Loungani (1986), Hamilton
(1988) and Kowalczyk and Loungani (1990) provide theoretical and
empirical evidence on the impact of oil price shocks on the
sectoral reallocation of resources. However, in order to be as fair
as possible to the Abraham-Katz view, we prefer to "over-control"
for the effects of aggregate demand on sectoral stock returns by
treating all movements in DSP as being "aggregate-demand-driven."




Working Papers and Staff Memoranda
The following lists papers developed in recent years by the Bank’s research
staff. Copies of those materials that are currently available can be obtained by
contacting the Public Information Center (312) 322-5111.

W orking Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the
Seventh Federal Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
REGIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES
Taxation of Public Utilities Sales: State Practices
and the Illinois Experience

WP-86-1

D ia n e F . S ieg e l a n d W illia m A . T esta

Measuring Regional High Tech Activity with Occupational Data

WP-87-1

A len k a S . G iese a n d W illia m A . T esta

Alternative Approaches to Analysis of Total Factor Productivity
at the Plant Level

WP-87-2

R o b e rt H. S ch norbu s a n d P h ilip R . Isra ilev ic h

Industrial R&D An Analysis of the Chicago Area

WP-87-3

A len ka S. G iese a n d W illia m A . T esta

Metro Area Growth from 1976 to 1985: Theory and Evidence

WP-89-1

W illiam A . T esta

Unemployment Insurance: A State Economic Development Perspective

WP-89-2

W illiam A . T esta a n d N a ta lie A . D a v ila

A Window of Opportunity Opens for Regional Economic Analysis:
BEA Release Gross State Product Data

WP-89-3

A len ka S. G iese

Determining Manufacturing Output for States and Regions

WP-89-4

P h ilip R . Isra ile v ic h a n d W illia m A. T esta

The Opening of Midwest Manufacturing to Foreign Companies:
The Influx of Foreign Direct Investment

WP-89-5

A len ka S .G ie se




l

A New Approach to Regional Capital Stock Estimation:
Measurement and Performance
Alenka S. Giese and Robert H. Schnorbus

WP-89-6

Why has Illinois Manufacturing Fallen Behind the Region?
William A. Testa

WP-89-7

Regional Specialization and Technology in Manufacturing
Alenka S. Giese and William A. Testa

WP-89-8

Theory and Evidence of Two Competitive Price Mechanisms for Steel
Christopher Erceg, Philip R. Israilevich and Robert H. Schnorbus

WP-89-9

Regional Energy Costs and Business Siting Decisions:
An Illinois Perspective
David R. Allardice and William A. Testa
Manufacturing's Changeover to Services in the Great Lakes Economy
William A. Testa
Construction of Input-Output Coefficients
with Flexible Functional Forms
Philip R. Israilevich

WP-89-10

WP-89-12

WP-90-1

Regional Regulatory Effects on Bank Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoffand Philip R. Israilevich

WP-90-4

Regional Growth and Development Theory: Summary and Evaluation
Geoffrey JD. Hewings

WP-90-5

Institutional Rigidities as Barriers to Regional Growth:
A Midwest Perspective
Michael Kendix

WP-90-6

ISSUES IN FINANCIAL REGULATION
Technical Change, Regulation, and Economies of Scale for Large Commercial
Banks: An Application of a Modified Version of Shepard's Lemma
Douglas D. Evanoff, Philip R. Israilevich and Randall C. Merris




WP-89-11

2

Working paper series continued

Reserve Account Management Behavior: Impact of the Reserve Accounting
Scheme and Carry Forward Provision

W P-89-12

D o u g la s D . E v a n o ff

Are Some Banks too Large to Fail? Myth and Reality

WP-89-14

G eo rg e G . K au fm an

Variability and Stationarity of Term Premia

W P-89-16

R am o n P . D e G en n aro a n d J a m e s T. M o se r

A Model of Borrowing and Lending with Fixed and Variable Interest Rates

WP-89-17

T hom as M o n d sch ea n

Do ‘'Vulnerable" Economies Need Deposit Insurance?: Lessons from the
U.S. Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s

W P-89-18

C h a rle s W. C a lo m iris

The Savings and Loan Rescue of 1989: Causes and Perspective

WP-89-23

G eo rg e G. K au fm an

The Impact of Deposit Insurance on S&L Shareholders' Risk/Retum Trade-offs

WP-89-24

E lijah B r e w e r III

Payments System Risk Issues on a Global Economy

W P-90-12

H e rb e rt L . B a e r a n d D o u g la s D . E v a n o ff

MACRO ECONOMIC ISSUES
Back of the G-7 Pack: Public Investment and Productivity
Growth in the Group of Seven

WP-89-13

D a v id A . A sch a u e r

Monetary and Non-Monetary Sources of Inflation: An Error
Correction Analysis

W P-89-15

K en n eth N . K u ttn er

Trade Policy and Union Wage Dynamics

WP-89-19

E llen R . R issm a n




3

Working paper series continued

Investment Cyclicality in Manufacturing Industries

W P-89-20

B ru ce C. P e te rse n a n d W illia m A . S tra u ss

Labor Mobility, Unemployment and Sectoral Shifts:
Evidence from Micro Data

WP-89-22

P ra k a sh L ou n gan i, R ic h a rd R o g e rso n a n d Y ang-H oon Sonn

Unit Roots in Real GNP: Do We Know, and Do We Care?

WP-90-2

L a w re n c e J . C h ristia n o a n d M a rtin E ich en bau m

Money Supply Announcements and the Market's Perception
of Federal Reserve Policy

WP-90-3

S teven S tron gin a n d V efa T arhan

Sectoral Shifts in Interwar Britain

W P-90-7

P ra k a sh L o u n g a n i a n d M a rk R u sh

Money, Output, and Inflation: Testing the P-Star Restrictions

WP-90-8

K en n eth N . K u ttn e r

Current Real Business Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor
Market Fluctuations

WP-90-9

L a w re n c e J. C h ristia n o a n d M a rtin E ich en bau m

The Output, Employment, and Interest Rate Effects of
Government Consumption

WP-90-10

S. R a o A iy a g a ri, L a w re n c e J. C h ristia n o a n d M a rtin E ich en bau m

Money, Income, Prices and Interest Rates after the 1980s

WP-90-11

B en ja m in M . F ried m a n a n d K en n eth N . K u ttn er

Real Business Cycle Theory: Wisdom or Whimsy?

WP-90-13

M a rtin E ich en bau m

Macroeconomic Models and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

WP-90-14

S teven S tro n g in




4

Working paper series continued

Stock Market Dispersion and Real Economic Activity:
Evidence from Quarterly Data
P ra k a sh L o u n g a n i , M a rk R u sh a n d W illiam T ave
Term-Structure Spreads, The Money Supply Mechanism,
and Indicators of Monetary Policy
R o b e r t D . L a u ren t




WP-90-15

WP-90-16

Staff Memoranda
A series of research papers in draft form prepared by members of the
Research Department and distributed to the academic community for review
and comment. (Series discontinued in December, 1988. Later works appear in
working paper series).
Risks and Failures in Banking: Overview, History, and Evaluation
George J. Benston and George G. Kaufman

SM-86-1

The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal Policy
David Alan Aschauer

SM-86-2

Banking Risk in Historical Perspective
George G. Kaufman

SM-86-3

The Impact of Market, Industry, and Interest Rate Risks
on Bank Stock Returns
Elijah Brewer, III and Cheng Few Lee

SM-86-4

Wage Growth and Sectoral Shifts: New Evidence on the
Stability o f the Phillips Curve
Ellen R.Rissman

SM-87-1

Testing Stock-Adjustment Specifications and
Other Restrictions on Money Demand Equations
Randall C. Merris

SM-87-2

The Truth About Bank Runs

SM-87-3

G eo rg e G . K a u fm a n

On The Relationship Between Standby Letters of Credit and Bank Capital
Gary D. Koppenhaver and Roger Stover
Alternative Instruments for Hedging Inflation Risk in the
Banking Industry
Gary D. Koppenhaver and Cheng F. Lee

SM-87-4

SM-87-5

The Effects of Regulation on Bank Participation in the Market
Gary D. Koppenhaver

SM-87-6

Bank Stock Valuation: Does Maturity Gap Matter?
Vefa Tarhan

SM-87-7




6




Staff Memoranda continued

Finite Horizons, Intertemporal Substitution and Fiscal Policy

SM-87-8

D a v id A la n A sch a u e r

Reevaluation of the Structure-Conduct-Performance
Paradigm in Banking

SM-87-9

D o u g la s D . E v a n o ff a n d D ia n a L . F o rtie r

Net Private Investment and Public Expenditure in the
United States 1953-1984

SM-87-10

D a v id A la n A sch a u e r

Risk and Solvency Regulation of Depository Institutions:
Past Policies and Current Options

SM-88-1

G e o rg e J. B en sto n a n d G e o rg e G . K au fm an

Public Spending and the Return to Capital

SM-88-2

D a v id A sch a u e r

Is Government Spending Stimulative?

SM-88-3

D a v id A sch a u e r

Securities Activities of Commercial Banks: The Current
Economic and Legal Environment

SM-88-4

G eo rg e G. K au fm an a n d L a r r y R. M o te

A Note on the Relationship Between Bank Holding Company
Risks and Nonbank Activity

SM-88-5

E lija h B r e w e r , III

Duration Models: A Taxonomy

SM-88-6

G. O . B ie rw a g , G eo rg e G. K au fm an a n d C ynthia M . L a tta

Durations of Nondefault-Free Securities
G . 0 . B ie rw a g a n d G e o rg e G. K au fm an

Is Public Expenditure Productive?
D a v id A sch a u e r

SM-88-7

Staff Memoranda continued

Commercial Bank Capacity to Pay Interest on Demand Deposits:
Evidence from Large Weekly Reporting Banks

SM-88-8

E lija h B rew e r, III a n d T h om as H . M o n d sch ea n

Imperfect Information and the Permanent Income Hypothesis

SM-88-9

A b h ijit V. B a n e rje e a n d K en n eth N . K u ttn er

Does Public Capital Crowd out Private Capital?

SM-88-10

D a v id A sch a u e r

Imports, Trade Policy, and Union Wage Dynamics

SM-88-11

E llen R issm a n




8