View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP 2009-04

1

Stochastic Volatility1
Torben G. Andersena and Luca Benzonib
a

Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL; NBER, Cambridge, MA;
and CREATES, Aarhus, Denmark.
b Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois, USA.

Article Outline
Glossary
I

Definition of the Subject and its Importance

II

Introduction

III

Model Specification

IV

Realized Volatility

V

Applications

VI

Estimation Methods

VII

Future Directions

VIII References

Glossary
Implied volatility The value of asset return volatility which equates a model-implied derivative
price to the observed market price. Most notably, the term is used to identify the volatility
implied by the Black and Scholes [63] option pricing formula.
Quadratic return variation The ex-post sample-path return variation over a fixed time interval.
Realized volatility The sum of finely sampled squared asset return realizations over a fixed time
interval. It is an estimate of the quadratic return variation over such time interval.
Stochastic volatility A process in which the return variation dynamics include an unobservable
shock which cannot be predicted using current available information.
1

This version: June 15, 2008. Chapter prepared for the Encyclopedia of Complexity and System Science, Springer.
We are grateful to Olena Chyruk, Bruce Mizrach (the Editor), and Neil Shephard for helpful comments and suggestions.
Of course, all errors remain our sole responsibility. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. The work of Andersen is supported by a
grant from the NSF to the NBER and support from CREATES funded by the Danish National Research Foundation.

2

I. Definition of the Subject and its Importance
Given the importance of return volatility on a number of practical financial management decisions,
the efforts to provide good real-time estimates and forecasts of current and future volatility have
been extensive. The main framework used in this context involves stochastic volatility models. In a
broad sense, this model class includes GARCH, but we focus on a narrower set of specifications in
which volatility follows its own random process, as is common in models originating within financial
economics. The distinguishing feature of these specifications is that volatility, being inherently unobservable and subject to independent random shocks, is not measurable with respect to observable
information. In what follows, we refer to these models as genuine stochastic volatility models.
Much modern asset pricing theory is built on continuous-time models. The natural concept of
volatility within this setting is that of genuine stochastic volatility. For example, stochastic-volatility
(jump-)diffusions have provided a useful tool for a wide range of applications, including the pricing of
options and other derivatives, the modeling of the term structure of risk-free interest rates, and the
pricing of foreign currencies and defaultable bonds. The increased use of intraday transaction data
for construction of so-called realized volatility measures provides additional impetus for considering
genuine stochastic volatility models. As we demonstrate below, the realized volatility approach is
closely associated with the continuous-time stochastic volatility framework of financial economics.
There are some unique challenges in dealing with genuine stochastic volatility models. For example,
volatility is truly latent and this feature complicates estimation and inference. Further, the presence of
an additional state variable—volatility—renders the model less tractable from an analytic perspective.
We review how such challenges have been addressed through development of new estimation methods
and imposition of model restrictions allowing for closed-form solutions while remaining consistent with
the dominant empirical features of the data.

II. Introduction
The label Stochastic Volatility is applied in two distinct ways in the literature. For one, it is used
to signify that the (absolute) size of the innovations of a time series displays random fluctuations
over time. Descriptive models of financial time series almost invariably embed this feature nowadays
as asset return series tend to display alternating quiet and turbulent periods of varying length and
intensity. To distinguish this feature from models that operate with an a priori known or deterministic path for the volatility process, the random evolution of the conditional return variance is termed
stochastic volatility. The simplest case of deterministic volatility is the constant variance assumption
invoked in, e.g., the Black and Scholes [63] framework. Another example is modeling the variance
purely as a given function of calendar time, allowing only for effects such as time-of-year (seasonals),
day-of-week (institutional and announcement driven) or time-of-day (diurnal effects due to, e.g., market microstructure features). Any model not falling within this class is then a stochastic volatility
model. For example, in the one-factor continuous-time Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross [113] (CIR) model
the (stochastic) level of the short term interest rate governs the dynamics of the (instantaneous) drift
and diffusion term of all zero-coupon yields. Likewise, in GARCH models the past return innovations
govern the one-period ahead conditional mean and variance. In both models, the volatility is known,

3
or deterministic, at a given point in time, but the random evolution of the processes renders volatility
stochastic for any horizon beyond the present period.
The second notion of stochastic volatility, which we adopt henceforth, refers to models in which
the return variation dynamics is subject to an unobserved random shock so that the volatility is
inherently latent. That is, the current volatility state is not known for sure, conditional on the true
data generating process and the past history of all available discretely sampled data. Since the CIR
and GARCH models described above do render the current (conditional) volatility known, they are
not stochastic volatility models in this sense. In order to make the distinction clear cut, we follow
Andersen [10] and label this second, more restrictive, set genuine stochastic volatility (SV) models.
There are two main advantages to focusing on SV models. First, much asset pricing theory is
built on continuous-time models. Within this class, SV models tend to fit more naturally with a wide
array of applications, including the pricing of currencies, options, and other derivatives, as well as
the modeling of the term structure of interest rates. Second, the increasing use of high-frequency
intraday data for construction of so-called realized volatility measures is also starting to push the
GARCH models out of the limelight as the realized volatility approach is naturally linked to the
continuous-time SV framework of financial economics.
One drawback is that volatility is not measurable with respect to observable (past) information in
the SV setting. As such, an estimate of the current volatility state must be filtered out from a noisy
environment and the estimate will change as future observations become available. Hence, in-sample
estimation typically involves smoothing techniques, not just filtering. In contrast, the conditional
variance in GARCH is observable given past information, which renders (quasi-)maximum likelihood
techniques for inference quite straightforward while smoothing techniques have no role. As such,
GARCH models are easier to estimate and practitioners often rely on them for time-series forecasts of
volatility. However, the development of powerful method of simulated moments, Markov Chain Monte
Carlo (MCMC) and other simulation based procedures for estimation and forecasting of SV models
may well render them competitive with ARCH over time on that dimension.
Direct indications of the relations between SV and GARCH models are evident in the sequence of
papers by Dan Nelson and Dean Foster exploring the SV diffusion limits of ARCH models as the case of
continuous sampling is approached, see, e.g., Nelson and Foster [219]. Moreover, as explained in further
detail in the estimation section below, it can be useful to summarize the dynamic features of asset
returns by tractable pseudo-likelihood scores obtained from GARCH-style models when performing
simulation based inference for SV models. As such, the SV and GARCH frameworks are closely related
and should be viewed as complements. Despite these connections we focus, for the sake of brevity,
almost exclusively on SV models and refer the interested reader to the GARCH chapter for further
information.
The literature on SV models is vast and rapidly growing, and excellent surveys are available, e.g.,
Ghysels et al. [158] and Shephard [239, 240]. Consequently, we focus on providing an overview of the
main approaches with illustrations of the scope for applications of these models to practical finance
problems.

4

III. Model Specification
The original econometric studies of SV models were invariably cast in discrete time and they were quite
similar in structure to ARCH models, although endowed with a more explicit structural interpretation.
Recent work in the area has been mostly directly towards a continuous time setting and motivated
by the typical specifications in financial economics. This section briefly reviews the two alternative
approaches to specification of SV models.

III.1. Discrete-Time SV Models and the Mixture-of-Distributions Hypothesis
Asset pricing theory contends that financial asset prices reflect the discounted value of future expected
cash flows, implying that all news relevant for either discount rates or cash flows should induce a shift
in market prices. Since economic news items appear almost continuously in real time, this perspective
rationalizes the ever-changing nature of prices observed in financial markets. The process linking
news arrivals to price changes may be complex, but if it is stationary in the statistical sense it will
nonetheless produce a robust theoretical association between news arrivals, market activity and return
volatility. In fact, if the number of news arrival is very large, standard central limit theory will tend to
imply that asset returns are approximately normally distributed conditional on the news count. More
generally, variables such as the trading volume, the number of transactions or the number of price
quotes are also naturally related to the intensity of the information flow. This line of reasoning has
motivated specifications such as,
yt |st ; N (µy st , σ 2 st )
(1)
y
where yt is an “activity” variable related to the information flow, st is a positive intensity process
reflecting the rate of news arrivals, µy represents the mean response to an information event, and σ y
is a pure scaling parameter.
This is a normal mixture model, where the st process governs or “mixes” the scale of the distribution
across the periods. If st is constant, this is simply an i.i.d. Gaussian process for returns and possible
other related variables. However, this is clearly at odds with the empirical evidence for, e.g., return
volatility and trading volume. Therefore, st is typically stipulated to follow a separate stochastic
process with random innovations. Hence, each period the return series is subject to two separate
shocks, namely the usual idiosyncratic error term associated with the (normal) return distribution,
but also a shock to the variance or volatility process, st . This endows the return process with genuine
stochastic volatility, reflecting the random intensity of news arrivals. Moreover, it is typically assumed
that only returns, transactions and quotes are observable, but not the actual value of st itself, implying
that σ y cannot be separately identified. Hence, we simply fix this parameter at unity.
The time variation in the information flow series induces a fat-tailed unconditional distribution,
consistent with stylized facts for financial return and, e.g., trading volume series. Intuitively, days
with a lot of news display more rapid price fluctuations and trading activity than days with a low
news count. In addition, if the st process is positively correlated, then shocks to the conditional mean
and variance processes for yt will be persistent. This is consistent with the observed clustering in
financial markets, where return volatility and trading activity are contemporaneously correlated and
each display pronounced positive serial dependence.

5
The inherent randomness and unobserved nature of the news arrival process, even during period
t, renders the true mean and variance series latent. This property is the major difference with the
GARCH model class, in which the one-step-ahead conditional mean and variance are a known function
of observed variables at time t − 1. As such, for genuine SV models, we must distinguish the full, but
infeasible, information set (st ∈ Ft ) and the observable information set (st ∈ It ). This basic latency of
/
the mixing variable (state vector) of the SV model complicates inference and forecasting procedures
as discussed below.
For short horizon returns, µy is nearly negligible and can reasonably be ignored or simply fixed
at a small constant value, and the series can then be demeaned. This simplification produces the
following return (innovation) model,
√
rt = st zt ,
(2)
Where zt is an i.i.d. standard normal variable, implying a simple normal-mixture representation,
rt |st ; N (0, st ) .

(3)

Univariate return models of the form (3) as well as multivariate systems including a return variable
along with other related market activity variables, such as the transactions count, the quote intensity
or the aggregate trading volume, stem from the Mixture-of-Distributions Hypothesis (MDH).
Actual implementation of the MDH hinges on a particular representation of the informationarrival process st . Clark [102] uses trading volume as a proxy for the activity variable, a choice
motivated by the high contemporaneous correlation between return volatility and volume. Tauchen
and Pitts [247] follow a structural approach to characterize the joint distribution of the daily return
and volume relation governed by the underlying latent information flow st . However, both these
models assume temporal independence of the information flow, thus failing to capture the clustering
in these series. Partly in response, Gallant et al. [153] examine the joint conditional return-volume
distribution without imposing any structural MDH restrictions. Nonetheless, many of the original
discrete-time SV specifications are compatible with the MDH framework, including Taylor [249],2 who
proposes an autoregressive parameterization of the latent log-volatility (or information flow) variable
log(st+1 ) = η 0 + η 1 log(st ) + ut , ut ; i.i.d(0, σ 2 ) ,
u

(4)

where the error term, ut , may be correlated with the disturbance term, zt , in the return equation (2)
so that ρ = corr(ut , zt ) = 0. If ρ < 0, downward movements in asset prices result in higher future
volatility as also predicted by the so-called ‘leverage effect’ in the exponential GARCH, or EGARCH,
form of Nelson [218] and the asymmetric GARCH model of Glosten et al. [160].
Early tests of the MDH include Lamoureux and Lastrapes [194] and Richardson and Smith [231].
Subsequently, Andersen [11] studies a modified version of the MDH that provides a much improved
fit to the data. Further refinements of the MDH specification have been pursued by, e.g., Liesenfeld
[198, 199] and Bollerslev and Jubinsky [67]. Among the first empirical studies of the related approach
of stochastic time changes are An´ and Geman [29], who focus on stock returns, and Conley et al.
e
[109], who focus on the short-term risk-free interest rate.
2

Discrete-time SV models go farther back in time, at least to the early paper by Rosenberg [232] recently reprinted
in Shephard [240].

6

III.2. Continuous-Time Stochastic Volatility Models
Asset returns typically contain a predictable component, which compensates the investor for the risk
of holding the security, and an unobservable shock term, which cannot be predicted using current
available information. The conditional asset return variance pertains to the variability of the unobservable shock term. As such, over a non-infinitesimal horizon it is necessary to first specify the
conditional mean return (e.g., through an asset pricing model) in order to identify the conditional
return variation. In contrast, over an infinitesimal time interval this is not necessary because the
requirement that market prices do not admit arbitrage opportunities implies that return innovations
are an order of magnitude larger than the mean return. This result has important implications for
the approach we use to model and measure volatility in continuous time.
Consider an asset with log-price process {p(t) , t ∈ [0 , T ]} defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P ).
Following Andersen et al. [19] we define the continuously compounded asset return over a time interval
from t − h to t, 0 ≤ h ≤ t ≤ T , to be
r(t, h) = p(t) − p(t − h) .

(5)

A special case of (5) is the cumulative return up to time t, which we denote r(t) ≡ r(t, t) = p(t) − p(0),
0 ≤ t ≤ T . Assume the asset trades in a frictionless market void of arbitrage opportunities and the
number of potential discontinuities (jumps) in the price process per unit time is finite. Then the logprice process p is a semi-martingale (e.g., Back [33]) and therefore the cumulative return r(t) admits
the decomposition (e.g., Protter [229])
r(t) = µ(t) + M C (t) + M J (t) ,

(6)

where µ(t) is a predictable and finite variation process, M c (t) a continuous-path infinite-variation
martingale, and M J (t) is a compensated finite activity jump martingale. Over a discrete time interval
the decomposition (6) becomes
r(t, h) = µ(t, h) + M C (t, h) + M J (t, h) ,

(7)

where µ(t, h) = µ(t) − µ(t − h), M C (t, h) = M C (t) − M C (t − h), and M J (t, h) = M J (t) − M J (t − h).
Denote now with [r, r] the quadratic variation of the semi-martingale process r, where (Protter
[229])
[r, r]t = r(t)2 − 2

r(s−)dr(s) ,

(8)

and r(t−) = lims↑t r(s). If the finite variation process µ is continuous, then its quadratic variation is
identically zero and the predictable component µ in decomposition (7) does not affect the quadratic
variation of the return r. Thus, we obtain an expression for the quadratic return variation over the
time interval from t − h to t, 0 ≤ h ≤ t ≤ T (e.g., Andersen et al. [21] and Barndorff-Nielsen and
Shephard [51, 52]):
QV (t, h) = [r, r]t − [r, r]t−h = [M C , M C ]t − [M C , M C ]t−h +

∆M 2 (s)
t−h<s≤t

C

C

C

C

∆r2 (s) .

= [M , M ]t − [M , M ]t−h +
t−h<s≤t

(9)

7
Most continuous-time models for asset returns can be cast within the general setting of equation
(7), and equation (9) provides a framework to study the model-implied return variance. For instance,
the Black and Scholes [63] model is a special case of the setting described by equation (7) in which
the conditional mean process µ is constant, the continuous martingale M C is a standard Brownian
motion process, and the jump martingale M J is identically zero:
dp(t) = µdt + σdW (t) .

(10)

In this case, the quadratic return variation over the time interval from t − h to t, 0 ≤ h ≤ t ≤ T ,
simplifies to
t

σ 2 ds = σ 2 h ,

QV (t, h) =

(11)

t−h

that is, return volatility is constant over any time interval of length h.
A second notable example is the jump-diffusion model of Merton [214],
dp(t) = (µ − λξ )dt + σdW (t) + ξ(t) dqt ,

(12)

where q is a Poisson process uncorrelated with W and governed by the constant jump intensity λ, i.e.,
Prob(dqt = 1) = λ dt. The scaling factor ξ(t) denotes the magnitude of the jump in the return process
if a jump occurs at time t. It is assumed to be normally distributed,
ξ(t) ; N ( ξ, σ 2 ) .
ξ

(13)

In this case, the quadratic return variation process over the time interval from t−h to t, 0 ≤ h ≤ t ≤ T
becomes
t

QV (t, h) =
t−h

J(s)2 ,

J(s)2 = σ 2 h +

σ 2 ds +

(14)

t−h≤s≤t

t−h≤s≤t

where J(t) ≡ ξ(t)dq(t) is non-zero only if a jump actually occurs.
Finally, a broad class of stochastic volatility models is defined by
dp(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t)dW (t) + ξ(t) dqt ,

(15)

where q is a constant-intensity Poisson process with log-normal jump amplitude (13). Equation (15)
is also a special case of (7) and the associated quadratic return variation over the time interval from
t − h to t, 0 ≤ h ≤ t ≤ T , is
t

QV (t, h) =

σ(s)2 ds +

t−h

J(s)2
t−h≤s≤t

J(s)2 .

≡ IV (t, h) +

(16)

t−h≤s≤t

As in the general case of equation (9), equation (16) identifies the contribution of diffusive volatility,
termed ‘integrated variance’ (IV), and cumulative squared jumps to the total quadratic variation.
Early applications typically ignored jumps and focused exclusively on the integrated variance
component. For instance, IV plays a key role in Hull and White’s [174] SV option pricing model,

8
which we discuss in Section V.1 below along with other option pricing applications. For illustration,
we focus here on the SV model specification by Wiggins [256]:
dp(t) = µdt + σ(t) dWp (t)

(17)

dσ(t) = f (σ(t))dt + η σ(t) dWσ (t) ,

(18)

where the innovations to the return dp and volatility σ, Wp and Wσ , are standard Brownian motions.
If we define y = log(σ) and apply Itˆ’s formula we obtain
o
1
f (σ(t))
dt + η dWσ (t) .
dy(t) = d log(σ(t)) = − η 2 +
2
σ(t)

(19)

Wiggins approximates the drift term f (σ(t)) ≈ {α + κ[ log(σ) − log(σ(t)) ]}σ(t). Substitution in
equation (19) yields
d log(σ(t)) = [ α − κ log(σ(t)) ] dt + η dWσ (t) ,
(20)
where α = α + κ log(σ) − 1 η 2 . As such, the logarithmic standard deviation process in Wiggins has
2
diffusion dynamics similar in spirit to Taylor’s discrete time AR(1) model for the logarithmic information process, equation (4). As in Taylor’s model, negative correlation between return and volatility
innovations, ρ = corr(Wp , Wσ ) < 0, generates an asymmetric response of volatility to return shocks
similar to the leverage effect in discrete-time EGARCH models.
More recently, several authors have imposed restrictions on the continuous-time SV jump-diffusion
(15) that render the model more tractable while remaining consistent with the empirical features of
the data. We return to these models in Section V.1 below.

IV. Realized Volatility
Model-free measures of return variation constructed only from concurrent return realizations have
been considered at least since Merton [215]. French et al. [148] construct monthly historical volatility
estimates from daily return observations. More recently, the increased availability of transaction
data has made it possible to refine early measures of historical volatility into the notion of ‘realized
volatility,’ which is endowed with a formal theoretical justification as an estimator of the quadratic
return variation as first noted in Andersen and Bollerslev [18]. The realized volatility of an asset
return r over the time interval from t − h to t is
n

RV (t, h; n) =

r t−h+
i=1

ih h
,
n n

2

.

(21)

Semi-martingale theory ensures that the realized volatility measure RV converges to the return quadratic
variation QV, previously defined in equation (9), when the sampling frequency n increases. We point
the interested reader to, e.g., Andersen et al. [19] to find formal arguments in support of this claim.
Here we convey intuition for this result by considering the special case in which the asset return follows
a continuous-time diffusion without jumps,
dp(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t) dW (t) .

(22)

9
As in equation (21), consider a partition of the [t − h, t] interval with mesh h/n. A discretization
of the diffusion (22) over a sub-interval from t − h + (i−1)h to t − h + ih , i = 1, . . . , n, yields
n
n
r t−h+

ih h
,
n n

where ∆W t − h +

≈µ t−h+
ih
n

(i − 1)h
n

=W t−h+

ih
n

h
(i − 1)h
+σ t−h+
n
n

−W t−h+

Suppressing time indices, the squared return
2

2

r =µ

h
n

r2

(i−1)h
n

∆W

t−h+

ih
n

,

(23)

.

over the time interval of length h/n is therefore:

2

+ 2 µ σ ∆W

h
n

+ σ 2 (∆W )2 .

(24)

As n → ∞ the first two terms vanish at a rate higher than the last one. In particular, to a first order
approximation the squared return equals the squared return innovation and therefore the squared
return conditional mean and variance are
E r2 |Ft
Var r2 |Ft

≈ σ2

h
n

≈ 2 σ4

(25)
2

h
n

.

(26)

The no-arbitrage condition implies that return innovations are serially uncorrelated. Thus, summing over i = 1, . . . , n we obtain
n

E RV (t, h, n)| Ft =

E r t−h+
i=1

ih h
,
n n

n

2

| Ft

≈

σ t−h+
i=1
t

n

Var r t − h +
i=1

ih h
,
n n

| Ft

≈

2σ t − h +
i=1

≈ 2

h
n
(27)

t−h
n

2

2

σ(s)2 ds

≈
Var RV (t, h, n)| Ft =

(i − 1)h
n

h
n

t

(i − 1)h
n

σ(s)4 ds .

4

h
n

2

(28)

t−h

Equation (27) illustrates that realized volatility is an unbiased estimator of the return quadratic
variation, while equation (28) shows that the estimator is consistent as its variance shrinks to zero
when we increase the sampling frequency n and keep the time interval h fixed. Taken together,
these results suggest that RV is a powerful and model-free measure of the return quadratic variation.
Effectively, RV gives practical empirical content to the latent volatility state variable underlying the
models previously discussed in Section III.2.
Two issues complicate the practical application of the convergence results illustrated in equations
(27) and (28). First, a continuum of instantaneous return observations must be used for the conditional
variance in equation (28) to vanish. In practice, only a discrete price record is observed, and thus an
inevitable discretization error is present. Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [52] develop an asymptotic
theory to assess the effect of this error on the RV estimate (see also Meddahi [209]). Second, market
microstructure effects (e.g., price discreteness, bid-ask spread positioning due to dealer inventory control, and bid-ask bounce) contaminate the return observations, especially at the ultra-high frequency.

10
These effects tend to generate spurious correlations in the return series which can be partially eliminated by filtering the data prior to forming the RV estimates. However, this strategy is not a panacea
and much current work studies the optimal sampling scheme and the construction of improved realized
volatility in the presence of microstructure noise. This growing literature is surveyed by Hansen and
Lunde [165], Bandi and Russell [46], McAleer and Medeiros [205], and Andersen and Benzoni [14].
Recent notable contributions to this literature include Bandi and Russell [45], Barndorff-Nielsen et
al. [49], Diebold and Strasser [121], and Zhang, Mykland, and A¨
ıt-Sahalia [262]. Related, there is the
issue of how to construct RV measures when the market is rather illiquid. One approach is to use a
lower sampling frequency and focus on longer-horizon RV measure. Alternatively the literature has
explored volatility measures that are more robust to situations in which the noise-to-signal ratio is
high, e.g., Alizadeh et al. [8], Brandt and Diebold [72], Brandt and Jones [73], Gallant et al. [151],
Garman and Klass [157], Parkinson [221], Schwert [237], and Yang and Zhang [259] consider the highlow price range measure. Dobrev [122] generalizes the range estimator to high-frequency data and
shows its link with RV measures.
Equations (27) and (28) also underscore an important difference between RV and other volatility
measures. RV is an ex-post model-free estimate of the quadratic variation process. This is in contrast
to ex-ante measures which attempt to forecast future quadratic variation using information up to
current time. The latter class includes parametric GARCH-type volatility forecasts as well as forecasts
built from stochastic volatility models through, e.g., the Kalman filter (e.g., Harvey and Shephard
[168], Harvey et al. [167]), the particle filter (e.g., Johannes and Polson [185, 186]) or the reprojection
method (e.g., Gallant and Long [152] and Gallant and Tauchen [155]).
More recently, other studies have pursued more direct time-series modeling of volatility to obtain
alternative ex-ante forecasts. For instance, Andersen et al. [21] follow an ARMA-style approach,
extended to allow for long memory features, to model the logarithmic foreign exchange rate realized
volatility. They find the fit to dominate that of traditional GARCH-type models estimated from daily
data. In a related development, Andersen, Bollerslev, and Meddahi [24, 25] exploit the general class
of Eigenfunction Stochastic Volatility (ESV) models introduced by Meddahi [208] to provide optimal
analytic forecast formulas for realized volatility as a function of past realized volatility. Other scholars
have pursued more general model specifications to improve forecasting performance. Ghysels et al.
[159] consider Mixed Data Sampling (MIDAS) regressions that use a combination of volatility measures
estimates at different frequencies and horizons. Related, Engle and Gallo [137] exploit the information
in different volatility measures, captured by a multivariate extension of the multiplicative error model
suggested by Engle [136], to predict multi-step volatility. Finally, Andersen et al. [20] build on the
Heterogeneous AutoRegressive (HAR) model by Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [50] and Corsi [110]
and propose a HAR-RV component-based regression to forecast the h-steps ahead quadratic variation:
RV (t + h, h) = β 0 + β D RV (t, 1) + β W RV (t, 5) + β M RV (t, 21) + ε(t + h) .

(29)

Here the lagged volatility components RV (t, 1), RV (t, 5), and RV (t, 21) combine to provide a parsimonious approximation to the long-memory type behavior of the realized volatility series, which
has been documented in several studies (e.g., Andersen et al. [19]). Simple OLS estimation yields
consistent estimates for the coefficients in the regression (29), which can be used to forecast volatility
out of sample.

11
As mentioned previously, the convergence results illustrated in equations (27) and (28) stem from
the theory of semi-martingales under conditions more general than those underlying the continuoustime diffusion in equation (22). For instance, these results are robust to the presence of discontinuities
in the return path as in the jump-diffusion SV model (15). In this case the realized volatility measure
(21) still converges to the return quadratic variation, which is now the sum of the diffusive integrated
volatility IV and the cumulative squared jump component:
J(s)2 .

QV (t, h) = IV (t, h) +

(30)

t−h≤s≤t

The decomposition in equation (30) motivates the quest for separate estimates of the two quadratic
variation components, IV and squared jumps. This is a fruitful exercise in forecasting applications,
since separate estimation of the two components increases predictive accuracy (e.g., Andersen et al.
[20]). Further, this decomposition is relevant for derivatives pricing, e.g., options are highly sensitive
to jumps as well as large moves in volatility (e.g., Pan [220] and Eraker [141]).
A consistent estimate of integrated volatility is the k-skip bipower variation, BV (e.g., BarndorffNielsen and Shephard [53]),
π
BV (t, h; k, n) =
2

n

|r t − h +
i=k+1

ih h
,
n n

||r t − h +

(i − k)h h
,
n
n

|.

(31)

Liu and Maheu [202] and Forsberg and Ghysels [147] show that realized power variation, which is
robust to the presence of jumps, can improve volatility forecasts. A well-known special case of (31)
is the ‘realized bipower variation,’ which has k = 1 and is denoted BV (t, h; n) ≡ BV (t, h; 1, n). We
can combine bipower variation with the realized volatility RV to obtain a consistent estimate of the
squared jump component, i.e.,
J(s)2 .

RV (t, h; n) − BV (t, h; n) −→ QV (t, h) − IV (t, h) =
n→∞

(32)

t−h≤s≤t

The result in equation (32) are useful to design tests for the presence of jumps in volatility, e.g.,
Andersen et al. [20], Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [53, 54], Huang and Tauchen [172], and Mizrach
[217]. More recently, alternative approaches to test for jumps have been developed by A¨
ıt-Sahalia and
Jacod [6], Andersen et al. [23], Lee and Mykland [195], and Zhang [261].

V. Applications
The power of the continuous-time paradigm has been evident ever since the work by Merton [212] on
intertemporal portfolio choice, Black and Scholes [63] on option pricing, and Vasicek [255] on bond
valuation. However, the idea of casting these problems in a continuous-time diffusion context goes
back all the way to the work in 1900 by Bachelier [32].
Merton [213] develops a continuous-time general-equilibrium intertemporal asset pricing model
which is later extended by Cox et al. [112] to a production economy. Because of its flexibility and
analytical tractability, the Cox et al. [112] framework has become a key tool used in several financial

12
applications, including the valuation of options and other derivative securities, the modeling of the
term structure of risk-free interest rates, the pricing of foreign currencies and defaultable bonds.
Volatility has played a central role in these applications. For instance, an option’s payoff is nonlinear in the price of the underlying asset and this feature renders the option value highly sensitive
to the volatility of underlying returns. Further, derivatives markets have grown rapidly in size and
complexity and financial institutions have been facing the challenge to manage intricate portfolios
exposed to multiple risk sources. Risk management of these sophisticated positions hinges on volatility
modeling. More recently, the markets have responded to the increasing hedging demands of investors
by offering a menu of new products including, e.g., volatility swaps and derivatives on implied volatility
indices like the VIX. These innovations have spurred an even more pressing need to accurately measure
and forecast volatility in financial markets.
Research has responded to these market developments. We next provide a brief illustrative overview
of the recent literature dealing with option pricing and term structure modeling, with an emphasis on
the role that volatility modeling has played in these two key applications.

V.1. Options
Rubinstein [233] and Bates [55], among others, note that prior to the 1987 market crash the Black and
Scholes [63] (BS) formula priced option contracts quite accurately whereas after the crash it has been
systematically underpricing out-of-the-money equity-index put contracts. This feature is evident from
Figure 1, which is constructed from options on the S&P 500 futures. It shows the implied volatility
function for near-maturity contracts traded both before and after October 19, 1987 (‘Black Monday’).
The mild u-shaped pattern prevailing in the pre-crash implied volatilities is labeled a ‘volatility smile,’
in contrast to the asymmetric post-1987 ‘volatility smirk.’ Importantly, while the steepness and level
of the implied volatility curve fluctuate day to day depending on market conditions, the curve has been
asymmetric and upward sloping ever since 1987, so the smirk remains in place to the current date,
e.g., Benzoni et al. [60]. In contrast, before the crash the implied volatility curve was invariably flat
or mildly u-shaped as documented in, e.g., Bates [57]. Finally, we note that the post-1987 asymmetric
smirk for index options contrasts sharply with the pattern for individual equity options, which possess
flat or mildly u-shaped implied volatility curves (e.g., Bakshi et al. [37] and Bollen and Whaley [65]).
Given the failures of the BS formula, much research has gone into relaxing the underlying assumptions. A natural starting point is to allow volatility to evolve randomly, inspiring numerous studies
that examine the option pricing implications of SV models. The list of early contributions includes
Hull and White [174], Johnson and Shanno [187], Melino and Turnbull [211], Scott [238], Stein [244],
Stein and Stein [245], and Wiggins [256]. Here we focus in particular on the Hull and White [174]
model,
dp(t) = µp dt + V (t) dWp (t)
dV (t)
= µV dt + σ V dWV (t) ,
V (t)

(33)
(34)

where Wp and WV are standard Brownian motions. In general, shocks to returns and volatility may
be (negatively) correlated, however for tractability Hull and White assume ρ = corr(dWp , dWV ) = 0.

13

14−Oct−1987

12−Oct−1988

27

27
Put IVs
Call IVs

Put IVs
Call IVs
26

25

25

24

24

23

23

22

22

21

21

20

20

19

19

18

Black−Scholes IV (percent per year)

26

18

17
−0.15

−0.1

−0.05

0
0.05
K/S−1

0.1

17
−0.15

0.15

−0.1

−0.05

0
0.05
K/S−1

0.1

0.15

Figure 1: Pre- and Post-1987 Crash Implied Volatilities. The plots depict Black-Scholes implied
volatilities computed from near-maturity options on the S&P500 futures on October 14, 1986 (the
week before the 1987 market crash) and a year later.
Under this assumption they show that, in a risk-neutral world, the premium C HW on a European call
option is the Black and Scholes price C BS evaluated at the average integrated variance V ,
V =

1
T −t

T

V (s)ds ,

(35)

t

integrated over the distribution h(V |V (t)) of V :
C HW ( p(t), V (t) ) =

C BS (V )h(V |V (t))dV .

(36)

The early efforts to identify a more realistic probabilistic model for the underlying return were
slowed by the analytical and computational complexity of the option pricing problem. Unlike the BS
setting, the early SV specifications do not admit closed-form solutions. Thus, the evaluation of the
option price requires time-consuming computations through, e.g., simulation methods or numerical
solution of the pricing partial differential equation by finite difference methods. Further, the presence of
a latent factor, volatility, and the lack of closed-form expressions for the likelihood function complicate
the estimation problem.
Consequently, much effort has gone into developing restrictions for the distribution of the underlying return process that allow for (semi) closed-form solutions and are consistent with the empirical
properties of the data. The ‘affine’ class of continuous-time models has proven particularly useful

14
in providing a flexible, yet analytically tractable, setting. Roughly speaking, the defining feature of
affine jump-diffusions is that the drift term, the conditional covariance term, and the jump intensity
are all a linear-plus-constant (affine) function of the state vector. The Vasicek [255] bond valuation
model and the Cox et al. [112] intertemporal asset pricing model provide powerful examples of the
advantages of the affine paradigm.
To illustrate the progress in option pricing applications built on affine models, consider the return
dynamics
dp(t) = µ dt +

V (t) dWp (t) + ξ p (t) dq(t)

dV (t) = κ(V − V (t)) dt + σ V

V (t) dWV (t) + ξ V (t) dq(t) ,

(37)
(38)

where Wp and WV are standard Brownian motions with non-zero correlation ρ = corr(dWp , dWV ), q
is a Poisson process, uncorrelated with Wp and WV , with jump intensity
λ(t) = λ0 + λ1 V (t) ,

(39)

that is, Prob(dqt = 1) = λ(t) dt. The jump amplitudes variables ξ p and ξ V have distributions
ξ V (t) ; exp(ξ V )
ξ p (t) | ξ V (t) ; N (ξ p + ρξ ξ V (t), σ 2 ) .
p

(40)
(41)

Here volatility is not only stochastic but also subject to jumps which occur simultaneously with jumps
in the underlying return process. The Black and Scholes model is a special case of (37)-(41) for
constant volatility, V (t) = σ 2 , 0 ≤ t ≤ T , and no jumps, λ(t) = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T . The Merton [214] model
arises from (37)-(41) if volatility is constant but we allow for jumps in returns.
More recently, Heston [170] has considered a special case of (37)-(41) with stochastic volatility but
without jumps. Using transform methods he derives a European option pricing formula which may be
evaluated readily through simple numerical integration. His SV model has GARCH-type features, in
that the variance is persistent and mean reverts at a rate κ to the long-run mean V . Compared to Hull
and White’s [174] setting, Heston’s model allows for shocks to returns and volatility to be negatively
correlated, i.e., ρ < 0, which creates a leverage-type effect and skews the return distribution. This
feature is consistent with the properties of equity index returns. Further, a fatter left tail in the
return distribution results in a higher cost for crash insurance and therefore makes out-of-the-money
put options more expensive. This is qualitatively consistent with the patterns in implied volatilities
observed after the 1987 market crash and discussed above.
Bates [56] has subsequently extended Heston’s approach to allow for jumps in returns and using
similar transform methods he has obtained a semi-closed form solution for the option price. The
addition of jumps provides a more realistic description of equity returns and has important option
pricing implications. With diffusive shocks (e.g., stochastic volatility) alone a large drop in the value of
the underlying asset over a short time span is very unlikely whereas a market crash is always possible
as long as large negative jumps can occur. This feature increases the value of a short-dated put option,
which offers downside protection to a long position in the underlying asset.
Finally, Duffie et al. [130] have introduced a general model with jumps to volatility which embeds
the dynamics (37)-(41). In model (37)-(41), the likelihood of a jump to occur increases when volatility

15
is high (λ1 > 0) and a jump in returns is accompanied by an outburst of volatility. This is consistent
with what is typically observed during times of market stress. As in the Heston case, variance is
persistent with a mean reversion coefficient κ towards its diffusive long-run mean V , while the total
long-run variance mean is the sum of the diffusive and jump components. In the special case of constant
jump intensity, i.e., λ1 = 0, the total long-run mean is V +ξ V λ0 /κ. The jump term (ξ V (t) dq(t)) fattens
the right tail of the variance distribution, which induces leptokurtosis in the return distribution. Two
effects generate asymmetrically distributed returns. The first channel is the diffusive leverage effect,
i.e., ρ < 0, the second is the correlation between the volatility and the jump amplitude of returns
generated through the coefficient ρξ . Taken together, these effects increase model-implied option
prices and help produce a realistic volatility smirk.
Several empirical studies rely on models of the form (37)-(41) in option-pricing applications. For
instance, Bates [56] uses Deutsche Mark options to estimate a model with stochastic volatility and
constant-intensity jumps to returns, while Bates [57] fits a jump-diffusion model with two SV factors
to options on S&P 500 futures. In the latter case, the two SV factors combine to help capture features
of the long-run memory in volatility while retaining the analytical tractability of the affine setting
(see, e.g., Christoffersen et al. [101] for another model with similar features). Alternative approaches
to model long memory in continuous-time SV models rely on the fractional Brownian motion process,
e.g., Comte and Renault [108] and Comte et al. [107], while Breidt et al. [76], Harvey [166] and Deo et
al. [118] consider discrete-time SV models (see Hurvich et al. [175] for a review). Bakshi et al. [34, 37]
estimate a model similar to the one introduced by Bates [56] using S&P 500 options.
Other scholars rely on underlying asset return data alone for estimation. For instance, Andersen et
al. [15] and Chernov et al. [95] use equity-index returns to estimate jump-diffusion SV models within
and outside the affine (37)-(41) class. Eraker et al. [142] extend this analysis and fit a model that
includes constant-intensity jumps to returns and volatility.
Finally, another stream of work examines the empirical implications of SV jump-diffusions using a
joint sample of S&P 500 options and index returns. For example, Benzoni [59], Chernov and Ghysels
[93], and Jones [189] estimate different flavors of the SV model without jumps. Pan [220] fits a model
that has jumps in returns with time-varying intensity, while Eraker [141] extends Pan’s work by adding
jumps in volatility.
Overall, this literature has established that the SV jump-diffusion model dramatically improves
the fit of underlying index returns and options prices compared to the Black and Scholes model.
Stochastic volatility alone has a first-order effect and jumps further enhance model performance by
generating fatter tails in the return distribution and reducing the pricing error for short-dated options.
The benefits of the SV setting are also significant in hedging applications.
Another aspect related to the specification of SV models concerns the pricing of volatility and
jump risks. Stochastic volatility and jumps are sources of uncertainty. It is an empirical issue to
determine whether investors demand to be compensated for bearing such risks and, if so, what the
magnitude of the risk premium is. To examine this issue it is useful to write model (37)-(41) in socalled risk-neutral form. It is common to assume that the volatility risk premium is proportional to
the instantaneous variance, η(t) = η V V (t). Further, the adjustment for jump risk is accomplished by
ξ
assuming that the amplitude ˜p (t) of jumps to returns has mean ˜p = ξ p + η p . These specifications
ξ
are consistent with an arbitrage-free economy. More general specifications can also be supported in a

16
general equilibrium setting, e.g., a risk adjustment may apply to the jump intensity λ(t). However, the
coefficients associated to these risk adjustments are difficult to estimate and to facilitate identification
they typically are fixed at zero. Incorporating such risk premia in model (37)-(41) yields the following
risk-neutral return dynamics (e.g., Pan [220] and Eraker [141]):
dp(t) = (r − µ∗ ) dt +

V (t) dWp (t) + ˜p (t) dq(t)
ξ

dV (t) = [ κ(V − V (t)) + η V V (t) ] dt + σ V

V (t) dWV (t) + ξ V (t) dq(t) ,

(42)
(43)

where r is the risk-free rate, µ∗ a jump compensator term, Wp and WV are standard Brownian motions
under this so-called Q measure, and the risk-adjusted jump amplitude variable ˜p is assumed to follow
ξ
the distribution,
˜ (t) | ξ (t) ; N (˜ + ρ ξ (t), σ 2 ) .
ξp
ξp
(44)
V
ξ V
p
Several studies estimate the risk-adjustment coefficients η V and η p for different specifications of
model (37)-(44); see, e.g., Benzoni [59], Broadie et al. [78], Chernov and Ghysels [93], Eraker [141],
Jones [189], and Pan [220]. It is found that investors demand compensation for volatility and jump
risks and these risk premia are important for the pricing of index options. This evidence is reinforced
by other studies examining the pricing of volatility risk using less structured but equally compelling
procedures. For instance, Coval and Shumway [111] find that the returns on zero-beta index option
straddles (i.e., combinations of calls and puts that have offsetting covariances with the index) are
significantly lower than the risk-free return. This evidence suggests that in addition to market risk at
least a second factor (likely, volatility) is priced in the index option market. Similar conclusions are
obtained by Bakshi and Kapadia [36], Buraschi and Jackwerth [79], and Broadie et al. [78].

V.2. Risk-Free Bonds and their Derivatives
The market for (essentially) risk-free Treasury bonds is liquid across a wide maturity spectrum. It
turns out that no-arbitrage restrictions constrain the allowable dynamics in the cross-section of bond
yields. Much work has gone into the development of tractable dynamic term structure models capable
of capturing the salient time-series properties of interest rates while respecting such cross-sectional noarbitrage conditions. The class of so-called ‘affine’ dynamic term structure models provides a flexible
and arbitrage-free, yet analytically tractable, setting for capturing the dynamics of the term structure
of interest rates. Following Duffie and Kan [129], Dai and Singleton [114, 115], and Piazzesi [227],
the short term interest rate, y0 (t), is an affine (i.e., linear-plus-constant) function of a vector of state
variables, X(t) = {xi (t), i = 1, . . . , N }:
N

y0 (t) = δ 0 +

δ i xi (t) = δ 0 + δ X X(t) ,

(45)

i=1

where the state-vector X has risk-neutral dynamics
˜ ˜
dX(t) = K(Θ − X(t))dt + Σ S(t)dW (t) .

(46)

˜
˜
In equation (46), W is an N -dimensional Brownian motion under the so-called Q-measure, K and Θ
are N × N matrices, and S(t) is a diagonal matrix with the ith diagonal element given by [S(t)]ii =

17
αi + β i X(t). Within this setting, the time-t price of a zero-coupon bond with time-to-maturity τ is
given by
P (t, τ ) = eA(τ )−B(τ ) X(t) ,
(47)
where the functions A(τ ) and B(τ ) solve a system of ordinary differential equations (ODEs); see, e.g.,
Duffie and Kan [129]. Semi-closed form solutions are also available for bond derivatives, e.g., bond
options as well as caps and floors (e.g., Duffie et al. [130]).
In empirical applications it is important to also establish the evolution of the state vector X under
the physical probability measure P, which is linked to the Q-dynamics (46) through a market price of
risk, Λ(t). Following Dai and Singleton [114] the market price of risk is often given by
Λ(t) =

S(t)λ ,

(48)

where λ is an N × 1 vector of constants. More recently, Duffee [127] proposed a broader ‘essentially
affine’ class, which retains the tractability of standard models but, in contrast to the specification in
equation (48), allows compensation for interest rate risk to vary independently of interest rate volatility.
This additional flexibility proves useful in forecasting future yields. Subsequent generalization are in
Duarte [124] and Cheridito et al. [92].
Litterman and Scheinkman [201] demonstrate that virtually all variation in U.S. Treasury rates
is captured by three factors, interpreted as changes in ‘level,’ ‘steepness,’ and ‘curvature.’ Consistent
with this evidence, much of the term-structure literature has focused on three-factor models. One
problem with these models, however, is that the factors are latent variables void of immediate economic interpretation. As such, it is challenging to impose appropriate identifying conditions for the
model coefficients and in particular to find the ideal representation for the ‘most flexible’ model, i.e.,
the model with the highest number of identifiable coefficients. Dai and Singleton [114] conduct an extensive specification analysis of multi-factor affine term structure models. They classify these models
into subfamilies according to the number of (independent linear combination of) state variables that
determine the conditional variance matrix of the state vector. Within each subfamily, they proceed
to identify the models that lead to well-defined bond prices (a condition they label ‘admissibility’)
and among the admissible specifications they identify a ‘maximal’ model that nests econometrically
all others in the subfamily. Joslin [190] builds on Dai and Singleton’s [114] work by pursuing identification through a normalization of the drift term in the state vector dynamics (instead of the diffusion
term, as in Dai and Singleton [114]). Duffie and Kan [129] follow an alternative approach to obtain an
identifiable model by rotating from a set of latent state variables to a set of observable zero-coupon
yields. Collin-Dufresne et al. [104] build on the insights of both Dai and Singleton [114] and Duffie
and Kan [129]. They perform a rotation of the state vector into a vector that contains the first few
components in the Taylor series expansion of the yield curve around a maturity of zero and their
quadratic variation. One advantage is that the elements of the rotated state vector have an intuitive
and unique economic interpretation (such as level, slope, and curvature of the yield curve) and therefore the model coefficients in this representation are identifiable. Further, it is easy to construct a
model-independent proxy for the rotated state vector, which facilitates model estimation as well as
interpretation of the estimated coefficients across models and sample periods.
This discussion underscores an important feature of affine term structure models. The dependence
of the conditional factor variance S(t) on one or more of the elements in X introduces stochastic

18
volatility in the yields. However, when a square-root factor is present parametric restrictions (admissibility conditions) need to be imposed so that the conditional variance S(t) is positive over the range
of X. These restrictions affect the correlations among the factors which, in turn, tend to worsen the
cross-sectional fit of the model. Specifically, CIR models in which S(t) depends on all the elements of
X require the conditional correlation among the factors to be zero, while the admissibility conditions
imposed on the matrix K renders the unconditional correlations non-negative. These restrictions are
not supported by the data. In contrast, constant-volatility Gaussian models with no square-root factors do not restrict the signs and magnitude of the conditional and unconditional correlations among
the factors but they do, of course, not accommodate the pronounced and persistent volatility fluctuations observed in bond yields. The class of models introduced by Dai and Singleton [114] falls between
these two extremes. By including both Gaussian and square-root factors they allow for time-varying
conditional volatilities of the state variables and yet they do not constrain the signs of some of their
correlations. This flexibility helps to address the trade off between generating realistic correlations
among the factors while capturing the time-series properties of the yields’ volatility.
A related aspect of (unconstrained) affine models concerns the dual role that square-root factors play in driving the time-series properties of yields’ volatility and the term structure of yields.
Specifically, the time-t yield yτ (t) on a zero-coupon bond with time-to-maturity τ is given by
P (t, τ ) = e−τ yτ (t) .

(49)

Thus, we have
A(τ ) B(τ )
+
X(t) .
(50)
τ
τ
It is typically assumed that the B matrix has full rank and therefore equation (50) provides a direct
link between the state-vector X(t) and the term-structure of bond yields. Further, Itˆ’s Lemma implies
o
that the yield yτ also follows a diffusion process:
yτ (t) = −

dyτ (t) = µyτ (X(t), t) dt +

B(τ )
Σ
τ

S(t)dW (t) .

(51)

Consequently, the (instantaneous) quadratic variation of the yield given as the squared yield volatility
coefficient for yτ is
B(τ )
B(τ )
Vyτ (t) =
Σ S(t) Σ
.
(52)
τ
τ
The elements of the S(t) matrix are affine in the state vector X(t), i.e., [S(t)]ii = αi +β i X(t). Further,
invoking the full rank condition on B(τ ), equation (50) implies that each state variable in the vector
X(t) is an affine function of the bond yields Y (t) = {yτ j (t), j = 1, . . . , J }. Thus, for any τ there is a
set of constants aτ , j , j = 0, . . . , J, so that
J

Vyτ (t) = aτ ,0 +

aτ , j yτ j (t) .

(53)

j=1

Hence, the current quadratic yield variation for bonds at any maturity is a linear combination of the
term structure of yields. As such, the market is complete, i.e., volatility is perfectly spanned by a
portfolio of bonds.

19
Collin-Dufresne and Goldstein [103] note that this spanning condition is unnecessarily restrictive
and propose conditions which ensures that volatility no longer directly enters the main bond pricing
equation (47). This restriction, which they term ‘unspanned stochastic volatility’ (USV), effectively
breaks the link between the yields’ quadratic variation and the level of the term structure by imposing
a reduced rank condition on the B(τ ) matrix. Further, since their model is a special (nested) case of
the affine class it retains the analytical tractability of the affine model class. Recently Joslin [190] has
derived more general conditions for affine term structure models to exhibit USV. His restrictions also
produce a market incompleteness (i.e., volatility cannot be hedged using a portfolio of bonds) but do
not constrain the degree of mean reversion of the other state variables so that his specification allows
for more flexibility in capturing the persistence in interest rate series. (See also the USV conditions
in the work by Trolle and Schwartz [253]).
There is conflicting evidence on the volatility spanning condition in fixed income markets. CollinDufresne and Goldstein (2002) find that swap rates have limited explanatory power for returns on atthe-money ‘straddles,’ i.e., portfolios mainly exposed to volatility risk. Similar findings are in Heidari
and Wu [169], who show that the common factors in LIBOR and swap rates explain only a limited
part of the variation in the swaption implied volatilities. Moreover, Li and Zhao [197] conclude that
some of the most sophisticated multi-factor dynamic term structure models have serious difficulties
in hedging caps and cap straddles, even though they capture bond yields well. In contrast, Fan et al.
[143] argue that swaptions and even swaption straddles can be well hedged with LIBOR bonds alone,
supporting the notion that bond markets are complete.
More recently other studies have examined several versions of the USV restriction, again coming
to different conclusions. A direct comparison of these results, however, is complicated by differences in
the model specification, the estimation method, and the data and sample period used in the estimation.
Collin-Dufresne et al. [105] consider swap rates data and fit the model using a Bayesian Markov Chain
Monte Carlo method. They find that a standard three-factor model generates a time series for the
variance state variable that is essentially unrelated to GARCH estimates of the quadratic variation of
the spot rate process or to implied variances from options, while a four-factor USV model generates
both realistic volatility estimates and a good cross-sectional fit. In contrast, Jacobs and Karoui [177]
consider a longer data set of U.S. Treasury yields and pursue quasi-maximum likelihood estimation.
They find the correlation between model-implied and GARCH volatility estimates to be high. However,
when estimating the model with a shorter sample of swap rates, they find such correlations to be small
or negative. Thompson [250] explicitly tests the Collin-Dufresne and Goldstein [103] USV restriction
and rejects it using swap rates data. Bikbov and Chernov [62], Han [164], Jarrow et al. [182], Joslin
[191], and Trolle and Schwartz [254] rely on data sets of derivatives prices and underlying interest
rates to better identify the volatility dynamics.
Andersen and Benzoni [12] directly relate model-free realized volatility measures (constructed from
high-frequency U.S. Treasury data) to the cross-section of contemporaneous bond yields. They find
that the explanatory power of such regressions is very limited, which indicates that volatility is not
spanned by a portfolio of bonds. The evidence in Andersen and Benzoni [12] is consistent with the
USV models of Collin-Dufresne et al. [105] and Joslin [190], as well as with a model that embeds weak
dependence between the yields and volatility as in Joslin [191]. Moreover, Duarte [125] argues that the
effects of mortgage-backed security hedging activity affects both the interest rate volatility implied by

20
options and the actual interest rate volatility. This evidence suggests that variables that are not in the
span of the term structure of yields and forward rates contribute to explain volatility in fixed income
markets. Also related, Wright and Zhou [258] find that adding a measure of market jump volatility
risk to a regression of excess bond returns on the term structure of forward rates nearly doubles the
R2 of the regression. Taken together, these findings suggest more generally that genuine SV models
are critical for appropriately capturing the dynamic evolution of the term structure.

VI. Estimation Methods
There are a very large number of alternative approaches to estimation and inference for parametric
SV models and we abstain from a thorough review. Instead, we point to the basic challenges that
exist for different types of specifications, how some of these were addressed in the early literature and
finally provide examples of methods that have been used extensively in recent years. Our exposition
continues to focus on applications to equity returns, interest rates, and associated derivatives.
Many of the original SV models were cast in discrete time, inspired by the popular GARCH
paradigm. In that case, the distinct challenge for SV models is the presence of a strongly persistent
latent state variable. However, more theoretically oriented models, focusing on derivatives applications, were often formulated in continuous time. Hence, it is natural that the econometrically-oriented
literature has moved in this direction in recent years as well. This development provides an added
complication as the continuous-time parameters must be estimated from discrete return data and
without direct observations on volatility. For illustration, consider a fully parametric continuous-time
SV model for the asset return r with conditional variance V and coefficient vector Ψ. Most methods
to estimate Ψ rely on the conditional density f for the data generating process,
f (r(t), V (t) | I(t − 1), Ψ) = fr|V (r(t) | V (t), I(t − 1), Ψ) × fV (V (t) | I(t − 1), Ψ) ,

(54)

where I(t − 1) is the available information set at time t − 1. The main complications are readily
identified. First, analytic expressions for the discrete-time transition (conditional) density, f , or the
discrete-time moments implied by the data generating process operating in continuous time, are often
unavailable. Second, volatility is latent in SV models, so that even if a closed-form expression for f is
known, direct evaluation of the above expression is infeasible due to the absence of explicit volatility
measures. The marginal likelihood with respect to the observable return process alone is obtained
by integrating over all possible paths for the volatility process, but this integral has a dimension
corresponding to sample size, rendering the approach infeasible in general.
Similar issues are present when estimating continuous-time dynamic term structure models. Following Piazzesi [228], a change of variable gives the conditional density for a zero-coupon yield y on a
bond with time to maturity τ :
f (yτ (t) | I(t − 1), Ψ) = fX (g(yτ (t), Ψ) | I(t − 1), Ψ) × |

y

g(yτ (t), Ψ) | .

(55)

Here the latent state vector X has conditional density fX , the function g(·, Ψ) maps the observable
yield y into X, X(t) = g(yτ (t), Ψ), and y g(yτ (t), Ψ) is the Jacobian determinant of the transformation. Unfortunately, analytic expressions for the conditional density fX are known only in some special

21
cases. Further, the mapping X(t) = g(yτ (t), Ψ) holds only if the model provides an exact fit to the
yields, while in practice different sources of error (e.g., model mis-specification, microstructure effects,
measurement errors) inject a considerable degree of noise into this otherwise deterministic linkage (for
correct model specification) between the state vector and the yields. As such, a good measure of X
might not be available to evaluate the conditional density (55).

VI.1. Estimation via Discrete-Time Model Specification or Approximation
The first empirical studies have estimated discrete-time SV models via a (Generalized) Method of
Moments procedure by matching a number of theoretical and sample moments, e.g., Chan et al.
[89], Ho et al. [171], Longstaff and Schwartz [204], and Melino and Turnbull [211]. These models
were either explicitly cast in discrete time or were seen as approximate versions of the continuoustime process of interest. Similarly, several authors estimate diffusive affine dynamic term structure
models by approximating the continuous-time dynamics with a discrete-time process. If the error
terms are stipulated to be normally distributed, the transition density of the discretized process is
multivariate normal and computation of unconditional moments then only requires knowledge of the
first two moments of the state vector. This result facilitates quasi-maximum likelihood estimation. In
evaluating the likelihood function, some studies suggest using closed-form expressions for the first two
moments of the continuous-time process instead of the moments of the discretized process (e.g., Fisher
and Gilles [145] and Duffee [127]), thus avoiding the associated discretization bias. This approach
typically requires some knowledge of the state of the system which may be obtained, imperfectly,
through matching the system, given the estimated parameter vector, to a set of observed zero-coupon
yields to infer the state vector X. A modern alternative is to use the so-called particle filter as an
efficient filtering procedure for the unobserved state variables given the estimated parameter vector.
We provide more detailed accounts of both of these procedures later in this section.
Finally, a number of authors develop a simulated maximum likelihood method that exploit the
specific structure of the discrete-time SV model. Early examples are Danielsson and Richard [117] and
Danielsson [116] who exploit the Accelerated Gaussian Importance Sampler for efficient Monte Carlo
evaluation of the likelihood. Subsequent improvements were provided by Fridman and Harris [149]
and Liesenfeld and Richard [200], with the latter relying on Efficient Importance Sampling (EIS).
In a second step, EIS can also be used for filtering the latent volatility state vector. In general,
these inference techniques provide quite impressive efficiency but the methodology is not always easy
to generalize beyond the structure of the basic discrete-time SV asset return model. We discuss the
general inference problem for continuous-time SV models for which the lack of a closed-form expression
for the transition density is an additional complicating factor in a later section.

VI.2. Filtering the Latent State Variable Directly During Estimation
Some early studies focused on direct ways to extract estimates of the latent volatility state variable in
discrete-time SV asset return models. The initial approach was based on quasi-maximum likelihood
(QML) methods exploiting the Kalman filter. This method requires a transformation of the SV model
to a linear state-space form. For instance, Harvey and Shephard [168] consider a version of the Taylor’s

22
[249] discrete-time SV model,
p(t) = p(t − 1) + β +

V (t)ε(t)

log(V (t)) = α + φ log(V (t − 1)) + η(t) ,

(56)
(57)

where p is the logarithmic price, ε is a zero-mean error term with unit variance, and η is an independentlydistributed error term with zero mean and variance σ 2 .
η
Define y(t) = p(t) − p(t − 1) − β, square the observations in equation (56), and take logarithms to
obtain the measurement equation,
(t) = ω + h(t) + ξ(t) ,
(58)
where (t) ≡ log y(t)2 , h(t) ≡ log(V (t)). Further, ξ is a zero-mean disturbance term given by ξ(t) =
log(ε(t)2 ) − E[ log(ε(t)2 ) ], ω = log(σ 2 ) + E[ log(ε(t)2 ) ], and σ is a scale constant which subsumes the
effect of the drift term α in equation (57). The autoregression (57) yields the transition equation,
h(t) = φh(t − 1) + η(t) ,

(59)

Taken together, equations (58) and (59) are the linear state-space transformation of the SV model (56)(57). If the joint distribution of ε and η is symmetric, i.e., f (ε, η) = f (−ε, −η), then the disturbance
terms in the state-space form are uncorrelated even if η and ε are not. A possible dependence between
ε and η allows the model to pick up some of the asymmetric behavior often observed in stock returns.
Projection of [ h(t) − Et−1 h(t) ] over [ (t) − Et−1 (t) ] yields the Kalman filter estimate of the latent
(logarithmic) variance process:
Et h(t) = Et−1 h(t) +

E{ [ h(t) − Et−1 h(t) ] × [ (t) − Et−1 (t) ] }
× [ (t) − Et−1 (t) ] ,
E{ [ (t) − Et−1 (t) ]2 }

(60)

where the conditional expectations Et−1 (t) and Et−1 h(t) are given by:
Et−1 (t) = ω + Et−1 h(t)

(61)

Et−1 h(t) = φ Et−1 h(t − 1) .

(62)

To start the recursion (60)-(62), the initial value E0 h(0) is fixed at the long-run mean log(V ).
Harvey and Shephard [168] estimate the model coefficients via quasi-maximum likelihood, i.e.
by treating the errors ξ and η as though they were normal and maximizing the prediction-error
decomposition form of the likelihood function obtained via the Kalman filter. Inference is valid as
long as the standard errors are appropriately adjusted. In their application they rely on daily returns
on the value-weighted U.S. market index over 1967-1987 and daily returns for 30 individual stocks over
1974-1983. Harvey et al. [167] pursue a similar approach to fit a multivariate SV model to a sample
of four exchange rate series from 1981 to 1985. One major drawback of the Kalman filter approach is
that the finite sample properties can be quite poor because the error term, ξ, is highly non-Gaussian,
see, e.g., Andersen, Chung, and Sørensen [27]. The method may be extended to accommodate various
generalizations including long memory persistence in volatility as detailed in Ghysels, Harvey, and
Renault [158].
A related literature, often exploited in multivariate settings, specifies latent GARCH-style dynamics for a state vector which governs the systematic evolution of a higher dimensional set of asset

23
returns. An early representative of these specifications is in Diebold and Nerlove [120], who exploit
the Kalman filter for estimation, while Fiorentina et al. [144] provide a likelihood-based estimation
procedure using MCMC techniques. We later review the MCMC approach in some detail.
The state-space form is also useful to characterize the dynamics of interest rates. Following, e.g.,
Piazzesi [227], for a discrete-time dynamic term structure model the measurement and transition
equations are
A(τ ) B(τ )
+
X(t) + ξ τ (t)
τ
τ
X(t) = µ + ΦX(t − 1) + Σ S(t)ε(t) ,

yτ (t) = −

(63)
(64)

where S(t) is a matrix whose elements are affine functions of the state vector X, and A and B
solve a system of difference equations. When all the yields are observed with error (i.e., ξ τ = 0 ∀τ ,
0 ≤ τ ≤ T ), QML estimation of the system (63)-(64) via the extended Kalman filter method yields
an estimate of the coefficient vector. Applications of this approach for the U.S. term structure data
include Campbell and Viceira [81], Gong and Remolona [161], and Pennacchi [225]. The extended
Kalman filter involves a linear approximation of the relation between the observed data and the state
variables, and the associated approximation error will produce biased estimates. Christoffersen et al.
[99] raise this concern and recommend the use of the so-called unscented Kalman filter for estimation
of systems in which the relation between data and state variables is highly non-linear, e.g., options
data.

VI.3. Methods Accommodating the Lack of a Closed-Form Transition Density
We have so far mostly discussed estimation techniques for models with either a known transition
density or one that is approximated by a discrete-time system. However, the majority of empiricallyrelevant continuous-time models do not possess explicit transition densities and alternative approaches
are necessary. This problem leads us naturally towards the large statistics and econometric literature
on estimation of diffusions from discretely-observed data. The vast majority of these studies assume
that all relevant variables are observed so the latent volatility or yield curve state variables, integral to
SV models, are not accounted for. Nonetheless, it may be feasible to extract the requisite estimates of
the state variable by alternate means, thus restoring the feasibility, albeit not efficiency, of the basic
approach. Since the literature is large and not directly geared towards genuine SV models, we focus
on methods that have seen use in applications involving latent state variables.
A popular approach is to invert the map between the state vector and a subset of the observables
assuming that the model prices specific securities exactly. In applications to equity markets this is
done, e.g., by assuming that one option contract is priced without error, which implies a specific value
(estimate) of the variance process given the model parameters Ψ. For instance, Pan [220] follows this
approach in her study of S&P 500 options and returns, which we review in more detail in Section VI.5.
In applications to fixed income markets it is likewise stipulated that certain bonds are priced without
error, i.e., in equation (63) the error term ξ τ i (t) is fixed at zero for a set of maturities τ 1 , . . . , τ N ,
where N matches the dimension of the state vector X. This approach yields an estimate for the latent
variables through the inverse-map X(t) = g(yτ (t), Ψ).

24
One criticism of the state vector inversion procedure is that it requires ad hoc assumptions regarding the choice of the securities that are error-free (those used to compute model-implied measures
of the state vector) vis-a-vis those observed with error (used either for estimation or to assess model
performance in an ‘out-of-sample’ cross-sectional check). In fact, the extracted state vector can be
quite sensitive to the choice of derivatives (or yields) used. Nevertheless, this approach has intuitive
appeal. Model-implied measures of the state vector, in combination with a closed-form expression
for the conditional density (55), allow for efficient estimation of the coefficient vector Ψ via maximum likelihood. Analytic expressions for fX in equation (55) exist in a limited number of cases. For
instance, if X is Gaussian then fX is multivariate normal, while if X follows a square-root process
then fX can be expressed in terms of the modified Bessel function (e.g., Cox et al. [113]). Different
flavors of these continuous-time models are estimated in, e.g., Chen and Scott [91], Collin-Dufresne
and Solnik [106], Duffie and Singleton [132], Jagannathan et al. [181], and Pearson and Sun [223]. In
more general cases, including affine processes that combine Gaussian and square-root state variables,
closed-form expressions for fX are no longer available. In the rest of this section we briefly review
different methods to overcome this problem. The interested reader may consult, e.g., Piazzesi [227]
for more details.
Lo [203] warns that the common approach of estimating parameters of an Itˆ process by applyo
ing maximum likelihood to a discretization of the stochastic differential equation yields inconsistent
estimators. In contrast, he characterizes the likelihood function as a solution to a partial differential
equation. The method is very general, e.g., it applies not only to continuous-time diffusions but also
to jump processes. In practice, however, analytic solutions to the partial differential equations (via,
e.g., Fourier transforms) are available only for a small class of models so computationally-intensive
methods (e.g., finite differencing or simulations) are generally required to solve the problem. This is
a severe limitation in the case of multivariate systems like SV models.
For general Markov processes, where the above solution is infeasible, a variety of procedures have
been advocated in recent years. Three excellent surveys provide different perspectives on the issue. A¨
ıtSahalia, Hansen, and Scheinkman [5] discuss operator methods and mention the potential of applying
a time deformation technique to account for genuine SV features of the process, as in Conley, Hansen,
Luttmer, and Scheinkman [109]. In addition, the A¨
ıt-Sahalia [3, 4] closed-form polynomial expansions
for discretely-sampled diffusions are reviewed along with the Schaumburg [235] extension to a general
class of Markov processes with L´vy-type generators. Meanwhile, Bibby, Jacobsen, and Sørensen [61]
e
survey the extensive statistics literature on estimating functions for diffusion-type models and Bandi
and Phillips [42] explicitly consider dealing with nonstationary processes (see also the work of Bandi
[39], Bandi and Nguyen [41], and Bandi and Phillips [43, 44]).
The characteristic function based inference technique has been particularly widely adopted due to
the natural fit with the exponentially affine model class which provides essentially closed-form solutions
for many pricing applications. Consequently, we dedicate a separate section to this approach.

25
VI.3.1. Characteristic Functions
Singleton [242] proposes to exploit the information contained in the conditional characteristic function
of the state vector X,
φ(iu, X(t), Ψ) = E eiu X(t+1) X(t) ,
(65)
to pursue maximum likelihood estimation of affine term structure models. In equation (65) we highlight
the dependence of the characteristic function on the unknown parameter vector Ψ. When X is an
affine (jump-)diffusion process, φ has the exponential affine form,
φ(iu, X(t), Ψ) = eαt (u)+β t (u) X(t) ,

(66)

where the functions α and β solve a system of ODEs. As such, the transition density fX is known
explicitly up to an inverse-Fourier transformation of the characteristic function (65),
fX (X(t + 1) X(t); Ψ) =

1
πN

RN
+

Re e−iu X(t+1) φ(iu, X(t), Ψ) du .

(67)

Singleton shows that Gauss-Legendre quadrature with a relatively small number of quadrature points
allows to accurately evaluate the integral in equation (67) when X is univariate. As such, the method
readily delivers efficient estimates of the parameter vector, Ψ, subject to an auxiliary assumption,
namely that the state vector may be extracted by assuming that a pre-specified set of security prices
is observed without error while the remainder have non-trivial error terms.
When X is multivariate the Fourier inversion in equation (67) is computationally more demanding. Thus, when estimating multi-dimensional systems Singleton suggests focusing on the conditional
density function of the individual elements of X, but conditioned on the full state vector,
fXj (Xj (t + 1)|X(t); Ψ) =

1
2π

R

e−iωIj X(t+1) φ(iω Ij , X(t), Ψ)dω ,

(68)

where the vector Ij has 1 in the jth element and zero elsewhere so that the jth element of X is
Xj (t + 1) = Ij X(t + 1). Maximization of the likelihood function obtained from fXj , for a fixed j,
will often suffice to obtain a consistent estimate of Ψ. Exploiting more than one of the conditional
densities (68) will result in more efficient Ψ estimate. For instance, the scores of multiple univariate
log-likelihood functions, stacked in a vector, yield moment conditions that allow for generalized method
of moment (GMM) estimation of the system. Alternatively, Joslin [191] proposes a change-of-measure
transformation which reduces the oscillatory behavior of the integrand in equation (67). When using
this transformation, Gauss-Hermite quadrature more readily provides a solution to the integral in (67)
even if the state vector X is multi-dimensional, thus facilitating full ML estimation of the system.
Related, several studies have pursued GMM estimation of affine processes using characteristic
functions. Definition (65) yields the moment condition
E (φ(iu, X(t), Ψ) − eiu X(t+1) )z(u, X(t)) = 0 ,

(69)

where X is an N -dimensional (jump-)diffusion, u ∈ RN , and z is an instrument function. When X is
affine, the characteristic function takes the exponential form (66). Different choices of u and z yield a
set of moment conditions that can be used for GMM estimation and inference. Singleton [242] derives

26
the optimal instrument in terms of delivering efficient estimates. Carrasco et al. [86] approximate the
optimal instrument with a set of basis functions that do not require the knowledge of the conditional
likelihood function, thus avoiding one of the assumptions invoked by Singleton. Further, they build on
Carrasco and Florens [87] to implement estimation using a continuum of moment conditions, which
yields maximum-likelihood efficiency. Other applications of GMM-characteristic function methods to
affine (jump-) diffusions for equity index returns are in Chacko and Viceira [88] and Jiang and Knight
[183].
In some cases the lack of closed-form expressions for the moment condition in equation (69) can
hinder GMM estimation. In these cases the expectation in equation (69) can be evaluated by Monte
Carlo integration. This is accomplished by simulating a long sample from the discretized process for a
given value of the coefficient vector Ψ. The parameter Ψ is then estimated via the simulated method
of moments (SMM) of McFadden [206] and Duffie and Singleton [131]. Singleton [242] proposes SMM
characteristic function estimators that exploit the special structure of affine term structure models.

VI.4. Efficient Estimation of General Continuous-Time Processes
A number of recent approaches offer excellent flexibility in terms of avoiding approximations to the
continuous-time model-implied transition density while still facilitating efficient estimation of the
evolution of the latent state vector for the system.
VI.4.1. Maximum Likelihood with Characteristic Functions
Bates [58] develops a filtration-based maximum likelihood estimation method for affine processes. His
approach relies on Bayes’ rule to recursively update the joint characteristic function of latent variables
and data conditional on past data. He then obtains the transition density by Fourier inversion of the
updated characteristic function.
Denote with y(t) and X(t) the time-t values of the observable variable and the state vector,
respectively, and let Y (t) ≡ {y(1), . . . , y(t)} be the data observed up to time t. Consider the case in
which the characteristic function of z(t + 1) ≡ (y(t + 1), X(t + 1)) conditional on z(t) ≡ (y(t), X(t)),
is an exponential affine function of X(t):
φ(is, iu, z(t), Ψ) = E eis y(t+1)+iu X(t+1) z(t)
= eα(is,iu,y(t))+β(is,iu,y(t)) X(t) ,

(70)

Next, determine the value of the characteristic function conditional on the observed data Y (t):
φ(is, iu, Y (t), Ψ) = E E eis y(t+1)+iu X(t+1) z(t)

Y (t)

= E eα(is,iu,y(t))+β(is,iu,y(t)) X(t) Y (t)
= eα(is,iu,y(t)) ψ(β(is, iu, y(t)), Y (t), Ψ) ,

(71)

where ψ(iu, Y (t), Ψ) ≡ E eiu X(t) Y (t) denotes the (marginal) characteristic function for the state
vector conditional on the observed data. Fourier inversion then yields the conditional density for the

27
observation y(t + 1) conditional on Y (t):
fy (y(t + 1) | Y (t); Ψ) =

1
2π

e−is y(t+1) φ(is, 0, Y (t), Ψ)ds .

(72)

R

The next step updates the characteristic function ψ (Bartlett [48]):
ψ(iu, Y (t + 1), Ψ) =

1
2πfy (y(t + 1) | Y (t); Ψ)

e−is y(t+1) φ(is, iu, Y (t), Ψ)ds .

(73)

R

To start the recursion, Bates initializes ψ at the unconditional characteristic function of the latent
variable X. The log-likelihood function is then given by
T

log L(Y (T ); Ψ) = log(fy (y(1); Ψ) +

log(fy (y(t) | Y (t − 1); Ψ)) .

(74)

t=2

A nice feature is that the method provides a natural solution to the filtering problem. The filtered
estimate of the latent state X and its variance are computed from the first and second derivatives of
the moment generating function ψ(u, Y (t); Ψ) in equation (73), evaluated at u = 0:
E[ X(t + 1) | Y (t + 1); Ψ ] =
Var[ X(t + 1) | Y (t + 1); Ψ ] =

1
2πfy (y(t + 1) | Y (t); Ψ)
1
2πfy (y(t + 1) | Y (t); Ψ)

R

R

e−is y(t+1) φu (is, 0, Y (t); Ψ)ds

(75)

e−is y(t+1) φuu (is, 0, Y (t); Ψ)ds

− {E[ X(t + 1) | Y (t + 1) ]}2 .

(76)

A drawback is that at each step t of the iteration the method requires storage of the entire
characteristic function ψ(iu, Y (t); Ψ). To deal with this issue Bates recommends to approximate the
true ψ with the characteristic function of a variable with a two-parameter distribution. The choice
of the distribution depends on the X-dynamics while the two parameters of the distribution are
determined by the conditional mean E[ X(t + 1) | Y (t + 1); Ψ ] and variance Var[ X(t + 1) | Y (t + 1); Ψ ]
given in equations (75)-(76).
In his application Bates finds that the method is successful in estimating different flavors of the
SV jump-diffusion for a univariate series of daily 1953-1996 S&P 500 returns. In particular, he shows
that the method obtains estimates that are equally, if not more, efficient compared to the efficient
method of moments and Markov Chain Monte Carlo methods described below. Extensions of the
method to multivariate processes are theoretically possible, but they require numerical integration of
multi-dimensional functions, which is computationally demanding.
VI.4.2. Simulated Maximum Likelihood
In Section VI.2 we discussed methods for simulated ML estimation and inference in discrete-time SV
models. Pedersen [224] and Santa-Clara [234] independently develop a simulated maximum likelihood
(SML) method to estimate continuous-time diffusion models. They divide each interval in between
two consecutive data points Xt+1 and Xt into M sub-intervals of length ∆ = 1/M and they discretize
the X proces using the Euler scheme,
√
(77)
Xt+(i+1)∆ = Xt+i∆ + µ(Xt+i∆ )∆ + Σ(Xt+i∆ ) ∆ εt+(i+1)∆ , i = 0, . . . , M − 1 ,

28
where µ and Σ are the drift and diffusion terms of the X process and ε is multivariate normal with mean
zero and identity variance matrix. The transition density of the discretized process is multivariate
normal with mean µ and variance matrix ΣΣ . As ∆ goes to zero, this density converges to that of
the continuous-time process X. As such, the transition density from Xt to Xt+1 is given by
fX (Xt+1 |Xt ; Ψ) =

fX (Xt+1 |Xt+1−∆ ; Ψ)fX (Xt+1−∆ |Xt ; Ψ)dXt+1−∆ .

(78)

For sufficiently small values of ∆ the first term in the integrand, fX (Xt+1 |Xt+1−∆ ; Ψ), is approximated
by the transition density of the discretized process, while the second term, fX (Xt+1−∆ |Xt ; Ψ), is a
multi-step-ahead transition density that can be computed from the recursion from Xt to Xt+1−∆ .
Writing the right-hand side of equation (78) as a conditional expectation yields
fX (Xt+1 |Xt ; Ψ) = EXt+1−∆ |Xt fX (Xt+1 |Xt+1−∆ ; Ψ) .

(79)

The expectation in equation (79) can be computed by Monte Carlo integration over a large number
of paths for the process X, simulated via the Euler scheme (77). As ∆ vanishes, the Euler scheme is
consistent. Thus, when the size of the simulated sample increases the sample average of the function
fX , evaluated at the random draws of Xt+1−∆ , converges to the true transition density. Application
of the principles in Bladt and Sørensen [64] may well be useful in enhancing the efficiency of the
simulation scheme and hence the actual efficiency of the inference procedure in practice.
Brandt and Santa-Clara [75] apply the SML method to estimate a continuous-time model of the
joint dynamics of interest rates in two countries and the exchange rate between the two currencies.
Piazzesi [228] extends the SML approach for jump-diffusion processes with time-varying jump intensity.
She considers a high-frequency policy rule based on yield curve information and an arbitrage-free bond
market and estimates the model using 1994-1998 data on the Federal Reserve target rate, the six-month
LIBOR rate, and swap yields.
An important issue is how to initialize any unobserved component of the state vector, X(t), such as
the volatility state at each observation to provide a starting point for next Monte Carlo integration step.
This may be remedied through application of the particle filter, as mentioned earlier and discussed
below in connection with MCMC estimation. Another possibility is, as also indicated previously, to
extract the state variable through inversion from derivatives prices or yields assumed observed without
pricing errors.
VI.4.3. Indirect inference
There are also other method-of-moments strategies to estimate finitely-sampled continuous-time processes of a general type. One prominent approach approximates the unknown transition density for
the continuous-time process with the density of a semi-nonparametric (SNP) auxiliary model. Then
one can use the score function of the auxiliary model to form moment conditions for the parameter
vector Ψ of the continuous-time model. This approach yields the efficient method of moments estimator (EMM) of Gallant and Tauchen [154], Gallant et al. [150], and Gallant and Long [152], and the
indirect inference estimator of Gouri´roux et al. [162] and Smith [243].
e
To fix ideas, suppose that the conditional density for a continuous-time return process r (the
‘structural’ model) is unknown. We intend to approximate the unknown density with a discretetime model (the ‘auxiliary’ model) that is tractable and yet sufficiently flexible to accommodate the

29
systematic features of the actual data sample well. A parsimonious auxiliary density for r embeds
ARMA and EGARCH leading terms to capture the conditional mean and variance dynamics. There
may be residual excess skewness and kurtosis that elude the ARMA and EGARCH forms. As such,
the auxiliary density is rescaled using a nonparametric polynomial expansion of order K, which yields
gK (r(t)|x(t); ξ) =

[PK (z(t), x(t))]2
2
R [PK (z(t), x(t))] φ(u)du

ν + (1 − ν ) ×

φ(z(t))
√
,
h(t)

(80)

where ν is a small constant, φ(.) is the standard normal density, x(t) contains lagged return observations, and
z(t) =

r(t) − µ(t)
h(t)

,

(81)
s

u

µ(t) = φ0 + c h(t) +

φi r(t − 1) +
i=1

δ i ε(t − 1) ,

(82)

i=1

p

log h(t) = ω +

β i log h(t − 1) +
i=1

(1 + α1 L + ... + αq Lq ) [ θ1 z(t − 1) + θ2 (b(z(t − 1)) −


Kz

Kz

i

PK (z, x) =

ai (x)z =
i=0



i=0

Kx

aij xj  z i ,

a00 = 1 ,

2/π) ] ,

(83)
(84)

|j|=0

Here j is a multi-index vector, xj ≡ (xj1 , . . . , xjM ), and |j | ≡ M jm . The term b(z) is a smooth
1
m=1
M
(twice-differentiable) function that closely approximates the absolute value operator in the EGARCH
variance equation.
In practice, the representation of PK is given by Hermite orthogonal polynomials. When the order
K of the expansion increases, the auxiliary density will approximate the data arbitrarily well. If the
structural model is indeed the true data generating process, then the auxiliary density will converge to
that of the structural model. For a given K, the QML estimator ˆ for the auxiliary model coefficient
ξ
satisfies the score condition
T
1
∂ log gK (r(t) | x(t); ˆ
ξ)
= 0.
(85)
T
∂ξ
t=1

Suppose now that the structural model is correct and Ψ0 is the true value of its coefficient vector.
Consider a series {r(t; Ψ), x(t; Ψ)}, t = 1, . . . , T (T ), simulated from the structural model. Then we
expect that the score condition (85) holds when evaluated by averaging over the simulated returns
rather than over the actual data:
mT (T ) (Ψ0 , ˆ =
ξ)

1
T (T )

T (T )
t=1

∂ log gK (r(t, Ψ0 ) | x(t, Ψ0 ); ˆ
ξ)
≈ 0.
∂ξ

(86)

When T and T (T ) tend to infinity, condition (86) holds exactly.
ˆ
Gallant and Tauchen [154] propose the EMM estimator Ψ defined via
ˆ
Ψ = arg min mT (T ) (Ψ, ˆ WT mT (T ) (Ψ, ˆ ,
ξ) ˆ
ξ)
Ψ

(87)

30
ˆ
where the weighting matrix WT is a consistent estimate of the inverse asymptotic covariance matrix
of the auxiliary score function, e.g., the inverse outer product of the SNP gradient:
1
ˆ −1
WT =
T

T
t=1

∂ log gK (r(t) | x(t); ˆ
ξ)
∂ξ

∂ log gK (r(t) | x(t); ˆ
ξ)
∂ξ

.

(88)

An important advantages of the technique is that EMM estimates achieve the same degree of
efficiency as the ML procedure, when the score of the auxiliary model asymptotically spans the score
of the true model. It also delivers powerful specification diagnostics that provide guidance in the model
selection. Gallant and Tauchen [154] show that the EMM estimator is asymptotically normal. Further,
under the assumption that the structural model is correctly specified, they derive a χ2 statistic for
ˆ ξ)
the test of over-identifying restrictions. Gallant et al. [150] normalize the vector mT (T ) (Ψ, ˆ by its
standard error to obtain a vector of score t-ratios. The significance of the individual score elements is
often informative of the source of model mis-specification, with the usual caveat that failure to capture
one characteristic of the data may result in the significance of a moment condition that pertains to
a coefficient not directly related to that characteristic (due to correlation in the moment conditions).
Finally, EMM provides a straightforward solution to the problem of filtering and forecasting the latent
return variance process V , i.e., determining the conditional densities f (V (t) | x(t), Ψ) and f (V (t +
j) | x(t), Ψ), j ≥ 0. This is accomplished through the reprojection method discussed in, e.g., Gallant
and Long [152] and Gallant and Tauchen [155]. In applications to dynamic term structure models,
the same method yields filtered and forecasted values for the latent state variables.
The reprojection method assumes that the coefficient vector Ψ is known. In practice, Ψ is fixed at
ˆ
the EMM estimate Ψ. Then one simulates a sample of returns and latent variables from the structural
model and fits the auxiliary model on the simulated data. This is equivalent to the first step of
the EMM procedure except that, in the reprojection step, we fit the auxiliary model assuming the
structural model is correct, rather than using actual data. The conditional density of the auxiliary
model, estimated under the null, approximates the unknown density of the structural model:
ˆ
gK (r(t + j)|x(t); ˜ ≈ f (r(t + j)|x(t); Ψ), j ≥ 0 ,
ξ)

(89)

where ˜ is the QML estimate of the auxiliary model coefficients obtained by fitting the model on
ξ
simulated data. This approach yields filtered estimates and forecasts for the conditional mean and
variance of the return via
ˆ
E r(t + j) | x(t); Ψ

=

ˆ
V ar r(t + j) | x(t); Ψ

=

y gK (y|x(t); ˜ dy ,
ξ)
ˆ
y − E r(t + j) | x(t); Ψ

(90)
2

gK (y|x(t); ˜ dy .
ξ)

(91)

An alternative approach consists in fitting an auxiliary model for the latent variable (e.g., the return
conditional variance) as a function of current and lagged returns. It is straightforward to estimate
such model using data on the latent variable and the associated returns simulated from the structural
ˆ
model with the EMM coefficient Ψ. Also in this case the auxiliary model density approximates the
true one, i.e.,
V
ˆ
gK (V (t + j)|x(t); ˜ ≈ f V (V (t + j)|x(t); ψ), j ≥ 0 .
ξ)
(92)

31
This approach yields a forecast for the conditional variance process,
ˆ
E V (t + j) | x(t); Ψ

=

V
v gK (v|x(t); ˜ dv .
ξ)

(93)

In sum, reprojection is a simulation approach to implement a non-linear Kalman-filter-type technique,
which yields effective forecasts for the unobservable state vector.
The indirect inference estimator by Gouri´roux et al. [162] and Smith [243] is closely related to the
e
EMM estimator. Indirect inference exploits that the following two quantities should be close when
the structural model is correct and the data are simulated at the true parameter Ψ0 : (i) the QML
estimator ˆ for the auxiliary model computed from actual data; (ii) the QML estimator ˆ
ξ
ξ(Ψ) for the
auxiliary model fitted on simulations from the structural model. Minimizing the distance between ˆ
ξ
ˆ
and ξ(Ψ) in an appropriate metric yields the indirect inference estimator for Ψ. Similar to EMM,
asymptotic normality holds and a χ2 test for over-identifying restrictions is available. However, the
indirect inference approach is computationally more demanding, because finding the value of Ψ that
minimizes the distance function requires re-estimating the auxiliary model on a different simulated
sample for each iteration of the optimization routine. EMM does not have this drawback, since the
EMM objective function is evaluated at the same fitted score at each iteration. Nonetheless, there
may well be circumstances where particular auxiliary models are of primary economic interest and
estimation based on the corresponding moment conditions may serve as a useful diagnostic tool for
model performance in such directions.
Several studies have used EMM to fit continuous-time SV jump-diffusion models for equity index
returns, e.g., Andersen et al. [15], Benzoni [59], Chernov and Ghysels [93], and Chernov et al. [94, 95].
Andersen and Lund [28] and Andersen et al. [16] use EMM to estimate SV jump-diffusion models for
the short-term interest rate. Ahn et al. [1, 2], Brandt and Chapman [71], and Dai and Singleton [114]
fit different flavors of multi-factor dynamic term structure models. Andersen et al. [27] document the
small-sample properties of the efficient method of moments estimator for stationary processes, while
Duffee and Stanton [128] study its properties for near unit-root processes.
A. Ronald Gallant and George E. Tauchen at Duke University have prepared well-documented
general-purpose EMM and SNP packages, available for download at the web address ftp.econ.duke.edu
in the directories pub/get/emm and pub/get/snp. In applications it is often useful to customize the
SNP density to allow for a more parsimonious fit of the data under investigation. For instance,
Andersen et al. [15, 16], Andersen and Lund [28], and Benzoni [59] rely on the SNP density (80)-(84).
VI.4.4. Markov Chain Monte Carlo
The MCMC method provides a Bayesian solution to the inference problem for a dynamic asset pricing
model. The approach treats the model coefficient Ψ as well as the vector of latent state variables
X as random variables and computes the posterior distribution f (Ψ, X|Y ), conditional on certain
observable variables Y , predicted by the model. The setting is sufficiently general to deal with a
wide range of situations. For instance, X and Y can be the (latent) volatility and (observable) return
processes as is the case of an SV model for asset returns. Or X and Y can be the latent state vector
and observable yields in a dynamic term structure model.

32
The posterior distribution f (Ψ, X|Y ) is the main tool to draw inference not only on the coefficient
Ψ but also on the latent vector X. Since f (Ψ, X|Y ) is unknown in closed-form in relevant applications,
MCMC relies on a simulation (a Markov Chain) from the conditional density f (Ψ, X|Y ) to compute
mode, mean, and standard deviations for the model coefficients and state variables via the Monte
Carlo method.
The posterior f (Ψ, X|Y ) is analytically untractable and extremely high-dimensional, so that simulation directly from f (Ψ, X|Y ) is typically infeasible. The MCMC approach hinges on the CliffordHammersley theorem, which determines conditions under which the posterior f (Ψ, X|Y ) is uniquely
determined by the marginal posterior distributions f (Ψ|X, Y ) and f (X|Ψ, Y ). In turn, the posteriors
f (Ψ|X, Y ) and f (X|Ψ, Y ) are determined by a set or univariate posterior distributions. Specifically,
denote with Ψ(i) the ith element of the coefficient Ψ, i = 1, . . . , K, and with Ψ(−i) the vector consisting of all elements in Ψ except for the ith one. Similarly denote with X(t) the tth row of the state
vector, t = 1, . . . , T , and with X(−t) the rest of the vector. Then the Clifford-Hammersley theorem
allows to characterize the posterior f (Ψ, X|Y ) via K + T univariate posteriors,
f (Ψ(i)|Ψ(−i), X, Y ),

i = 1, . . . , K

(94)

f (X(t)|X(−t), Ψ, Y ),

t = 1, . . . , T .

(95)

The construction of the Markov Chain relies on the so-called Gibbs sampler. The first step of
the algorithm consists in choosing initial values for the coefficient and the state, Ψ0 and X0 . When
(one of or both) the multi-dimensional posteriors are tractable, the Gibbs sampler generates values
Ψ1 and X1 directly from f (Ψ|X, Y ) and f (X|Ψ, Y ). Alternatively, each element of Ψ1 and X1 is
drawn from the univariate posteriors (94)-(95). Some of these posteriors may also be analytically
intractable or efficient algorithms to draw from these posteriors may not exist. In such cases the
Metropolis-Hastings algorithm ensures that the simulated sample is consistent with the posterior
target distribution. Metropolis-Hastings sampling consists of an accept-reject procedure of the draws
from a ‘proposal’ or ‘candidate’ tractable density, which is used to approximate the unknown posterior
(see, e.g., Johannes and Polson [186]).
Subsequent iterations of Gibbs sampling, possibly in combination with the Metropolis-Hastings
sampling, yield a series of ‘sweeps’ {Ψs , Xs }, s = 1, . . . , S, with limiting distribution f (Ψ, X|Y ).
A long number of sweeps may be necessary to ‘span’ the whole posterior distribution and obtain
convergence due to the serial dependence of subsequent draws of coefficients and state variables.
When the algorithm has converged, additional simulations provide a sample from the joint posterior
distribution.
The MCMC approach has several advantages. First, the inference automatically accounts for
parameter uncertainty. Further, the Markov Chain provides a direct and elegant solution to the
smoothing problem, i.e., the problem of determining the posterior distribution for the state vector X
conditional on the entire data sample, f (X(t) | Y (1), . . . , Y (T ), Ψ), t = 1, . . . , T . The limitation on the
approach is largely that efficient sampling schemes for the posterior distribution must be constructed
for each specific problem at hand which by nature is case specific and potentially cumbersome or
inefficient. Nonetheless, following the development of more general simulation algorithms, the method
has proven flexible for efficient estimation of a broad class of important models.

33
One drawback is that MCMC does not deliver an immediate solution to the filtering problem,
i.e., determining f (X(t) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ), and the forecasting problem, i.e., determining f (X(t +
j) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ), j > 0. However, recent research is overcoming this limitation through the use
of the ‘particle filter.’ Bayes rule implies
f (X(t + 1) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t + 1), Ψ) ∝ f (Y (t + 1) | X(t + 1), Ψ) f (X(t + 1) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ) , (96)
where the symbol ∝ denotes ‘proportional to.’ The first density on the right-hand side of equation
(96) is determined by the SV model and it is often known in closed form. In contrast, the second
density at the far-right end of the equation is given by an integral that involves the unknown filtering
density at the prior period, f (X(t) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ):
f (X(t + 1) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ) =

f (X(t + 1) | X(t), Ψ) f (X(t) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ) dX(t) .

(97)

The particle method relies on simulations to construct a finite set of weights wi (t) and particles X i (t),
i = 1, . . . , N , that approximate the unknown density with a finite sum,
N

wi (t)δ X i (t) .

f (X(t) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ) ≈

(98)

i=1

where the Dirac function δ X i (t) assigns mass one to the particle X i (t). Once the set of weights and
particles are determined, it is possible to re-sample from the discretized distribution. This step yields
a simulated sample {X s (t)}S which can be used to evaluate the density in equation (97) via Monte
s=1
Carlo integration:
f (X(t + 1) | Y (1), . . . , Y (t), Ψ) ≈

1
S

S

f (X(t + 1) | X s (t), Ψ) .

(99)

s=1

Equation (99) solves the forecasting problem while combining formulas (96) and (99) solves the filtering
problem. The challenge in practical application of the particle filter is to identify an accurate and
efficient algorithm to construct the set of particles and weights. We point the interested reader to
Kim et al. [193], Pitt and Shephard [226], and Johannes and Polson [186] for a discussion on how to
approach this problem.
The usefulness of the MCMC method to solve the inference problem for SV models has been evident
since the early work by Jacquier et al. [179], who develop an MCMC algorithm for the logarithmic SV
model. Jacquier et al. [180] provide extensions to correlated and non-normal error distributions. Kim
et al. [193] and Chib et al. [96] develop simulation-based methods to solve the filtering problem, while
Chib et al. [97] use the MCMC approach to estimate a multivariate SV model. Elerian et al. [135] and
Eraker [140] discuss how to extend the MCMC inference method to a continuous-time setting. Eraker
[140] uses the MCMC approach to estimate an SV diffusion process for interest rates, while Jones [188]
estimates a continuous-time model for the spot rate with non-linear drift function. Eraker et al. [142]
estimate an SV jump-diffusion process using data on S&P 500 return while Eraker [141] estimates a
similar model using joint data on options and underlying S&P 500 returns. Li et al. [196] allow for
L´vy-type jumps in their model. Collin-Dufresne et al. [104] use the MCMC approach to estimate
e
multi-factor affine dynamic term structure model using swap rates data. Johannes and Polson [185]
give a comprehensive survey of the still ongoing research on the use of the MCMC approach in the
general nonlinear jump-diffusion SV setting.

34

VI.5. Estimation from Option Data
Options’ payoffs are non-linear functions of the underlying security price. This feature renders options
highly sensitive to jumps in the underlying price and to return volatility, which makes option data
particularly useful to identify return dynamics. As such, several studies have taken advantage of
the information contained in option prices, possibly in combination with underlying return data, to
estimate SV models with or without discontinuities in returns and volatility.
Applications to derivatives data typically require a model for the pricing errors. A common
approach is to posit that the market price of an option, O∗ , normalized by the underlying observed
security price S ∗ , is the sum of the normalized model-implied option price, O/S ∗ , and a disturbance
term ε (e.g., Renault [230]):
O(S ∗ , V, K, τ , Ψ)
O∗
=
+ ε,
(100)
S∗
S∗
where V is the latent volatility state, K is the option strike price, τ is time to maturity, and Ψ is
the vector with the model coefficients. A pricing error ε could arise for several reasons, including
measurement error (e.g., price discreteness), asynchroneity between the derivatives and underlying
price observations, microstructure effects, and perhaps most importantly specification error. The
structure imposed on ε depends on the choice of a specific ‘loss function’ used for estimation (e.g.,
Christoffersen and Jacobs [98]). Several studies have estimated the coefficient vector Ψ by minimizing
the sum of the squared option pricing errors normalized by the underlying price S ∗ , as in equation
(100). Others have focused on either squared dollar pricing errors, or squared errors normalized by
the options market price (instead of S ∗ ). The latter approach has the advantage that a $1 error on
an expensive in-the-money option carries less weight than the same error on a cheaper out-of-themoney contract. The drawback is that giving a lot of weight to the pricing errors on short-maturity
deep-out-of-the-money options could bias the estimation results. Finally, the common practice of
expressing option prices in terms of their Black-Scholes implied volatilities has inspired other scholars
to minimize the deviations between Black-Scholes implied volatilities inferred from model and market
prices (e.g., Mizrach [216]). An alternative course is to form a moment-based loss function and follow a
GMM- or SMM-type approach to estimate Ψ. To this end moment conditions stem from distributional
assumptions on the pricing error ε (e.g., E[ε] = 0) or from the scores of a reduced-form model that
approximates the data.
In estimating the model, some researchers have opted to use a panel of options consisting of
contracts with multiple strikes and maturities across dates in the sample period. This choice brings
a wealth of information on the cross-sectional and term-structure properties of the implied volatility
smirk into the analysis. Others rely on only one option price observation per time period, which shifts
the focus to the time-series dimension of the data. Some studies re-estimate the model on a daily
basis rather than seeking a single point estimate for the coefficient Ψ across the entire sample period.
This ad hoc approach produces smaller in-sample pricing errors, which can be useful to practitioners,
but at the cost of concealing specification flaws by over-fitting the model, which tends to hurt outof-sample performance. The different approaches are in part dictated by the intended use of the
estimated system as practitioners often are concerned with market making and short-term hedging
while academics tend to value stable relations that may form the basis for consistent modeling of the
dominant features of the system over time.

35
Early contributions focus on loss functions based on the sum of squared option pricing errors and
rely entirely on option data for estimation. This approach typically yields an estimate of the model
coefficient Ψ that embeds an adjustment for risk, i.e., return and volatility dynamics are identified
under the risk-neutral rather than the physical probability measure. For instance, Bates [56] considers
an SV jump-diffusion model for Deutsche Mark foreign currency options and estimates its coefficient
vector Ψ via nonlinear generalized least squares of the normalized pricing errors with daily option data
from January 1984 to June 1991. A similar approach is followed by Bates [57] who fits an SV model
with two latent volatility factors and jumps using daily data on options on the S&P 500 futures from
January 1988 to December 1993. Bakshi et al. [34] focus on the pricing and hedging of daily S&P
500 index options from June 1988 to May 1991. In their application they re-calibrate the model on
a daily basis by minimizing the sum of the squared dollar pricing errors across options with different
maturities and strikes. Huang and Wu [173] explore the pricing implications of the time-changed
L´vy process by Carr and Wu [84] for daily S&P 500 index options from April 1999 to May 2000.
e
Their L´vy return process allows for discontinuities that exhibit higher jump frequencies compared
e
to the finite-intensity Poisson jump processes in equations (37)-(41). Further, their model allows for
a random time change, i.e., a monotonic transformation of the time variable which generates SV in
the diffusion and jump components of returns. In contrast, Bakshi et al. [35] fit an SV jump-diffusion
model by SMM using daily data on long-maturity S&P 500 options (LEAPS).
More recent studies have relied on joint data on S&P 500 option prices and underlying index
returns, spanning different periods, to estimate the model. This approach forces the same model to
price securities in two different markets and relies on information from the derivatives and underlying
securities to better pin down model coefficients and risk premia. For instance, Eraker [141] and Jones
[189] fit different flavors of the SV model (with and without jumps, respectively) by MCMC. Pan
[220] follows a GMM approach to estimate an SV jump-diffusion model using weekly data. She relies
on a single at-the-money option price observation each week, which identifies the level of the latent
volatility state variable (i.e., at each date she fixes the error term ε at zero and solves equation (100) for
V ). A¨
ıt-Sahalia and Kimmel [7] apply A¨
ıt-Sahalia’s [4] method to approximate the likelihood function
for a joint sample of options and underlying prices. Chernov and Ghysels [93] and Benzoni [59] obtain
moment conditions from the scores of a SNP auxiliary model. Similarly, other recent studies have
found it useful to use joint derivatives and interest rate data to fit dynamic term structure models,
e.g., Almeida et al. [9], and Bikbov and Chernov [62].
Finally, a different literature has studied the option pricing implications of a model in which asset
return volatility is a deterministic function of the asset price and time, e.g., Derman and Kani [119],
Dupire [134], Rubinstein [233], and Jackwerth and Rubinstein [176]. Since volatility is not stochastic
in this setting, we do not review these models here and point the interested reader to, e.g., Dumas et
al. [133] for an empirical analysis of their performance.

VII. Future Directions
In spite of much progress in our understanding of volatility new challenges lie ahead. In recent years
a wide array of volatility-sensitive products has been introduced. The market for these derivatives
has rapidly grown in size and complexity. Research faces the challenge to price and hedge these new

36
products. Moreover, the recent developments in model-free volatility modeling have effectively given
empirical content to the latent volatility variable, which opens the way for a new class of estimation
methods and specification tests for SV systems. Related, improved volatility measures enable us to
shed new light on the properties and implications of the volatility risk premium. Finally, more work
is needed to better understand the linkage between fluctuations in economic fundamentals and lowand high-frequency volatility movements. We conclude this chapter by briefly reviewing some open
issues in these four areas of research.

VII.1. Volatility and Financial Markets Innovation
Volatility is a fundamental input to any financial and real investment decision. Markets have responded
to investors’ needs by offering an array of volatility-linked instruments. In 1993 the Chicago Board
Option Exchange (CBOE) has introduced the VIX index, which measures the market expectations of
near-term volatility conveyed by equity-index options. The index was originally computed using the
Black-Scholes implied volatilities of eight different S&P 100 option (OEX) series so that, at any given
time, it represented the implied volatility of a hypothetical at-the-money OEX option with exactly 30
days to expiration (see Whaley [257]). On September 22, 2003, the CBOE began disseminating price
level information using a revised ‘model-free’ method for the VIX index. The new VIX is given by the
price of a portfolio of S&P 500 index options and incorporates information from the volatility smirk
by using a wider range of strike prices rather than just at-the-money series (see Britten-Jones and
Neuberger [77]). On March 26, 2004, trading in futures on the VIX Index started on the CBOE Futures
Exchange (CFE) while on February 24, 2006, options on the VIX began trading on the Chicago Board
Options Exchange. These developments have opened the way for investors to trade on option-implied
measures of market volatility. The popularity of the VIX prompted the CBOE to introduce similar
indices for other markets, e.g., the VXN NASDAQ 100 Volatility Index.
Along the way, a new over-the-counter market for volatility derivatives has also rapidly grown in
size and liquidity. Volatility derivatives are contracts whose payments are expressed as functions of
realized variance. Popular examples are variance swaps, which at maturity pay the difference between
realized variance and a fixed strike price. According to estimates by BNP Paribas reported by the
Risk [192] magazine, the daily trading volume for variance swaps on indices reached $4-5 million in
vega notional (measured in dollars per volatility point) in 2006, which corresponds to payments in
excess of $1 billion per percentage point of volatility on an annual basis (Carr and Lee [82]). Using
variance swaps hedge fund managers and proprietary traders can easily place huge bets on market
volatility.
Finally, in recent years credit derivatives markets have evolved in complexity and grown in size.
Among the most popular credit derivatives are the credit default swaps (CDS), which provide insurance
against the risk of default by a particular company. The buyer of a single-name CDS acquires the
right to sell bonds issued by the company at face value when a credit event occurs. Multiple-name
contracts can be purchased simultaneously through credit indices. For instance, the CDX indices
track the credit spreads for different portfolios of North American companies while the iTraxx Europe
indices track the spreads for portfolios of European companies. At the end of 2006 the notional amount
of outstanding over-the-counter single- and multi-name CDS contracts stood at $19 and $10 trillion,

37
respectively, according to the September 2007 Bank for International Settlements Quarterly Review.
These market developments have raised new interesting issues for research to tackle. The VIX
computations based on the new model-free definition of implied volatility used by the CBOE requires
the use of options with strike prices that cover the entire support of the return distribution. In
practice, liquid options satisfying this requirement often do not exist and the CBOE implementation
introduces random noise and systematic error into the index (Jiang and Tian [184]). Related, the VIX
implementation entails a truncation, i.e., the CBOE discards illiquid option prices with strikes lying
in the tails of the return distribution. As such, the notion of the VIX is more directly linked to that
of corridor volatility (Andersen and Bondarenko [26]). In sum, robust implementation of a model free
measure of implied volatility is still an open area of research. Future developments in this direction
will also have important repercussions on the hedging practices for implied-volatility derivatives.
Pricing and hedging of variance derivatives is another active area of research. Variance swaps
admit a simple replication strategy via static positions in call and put options on the underlying asset,
similar to model-free implied volatility measures (e.g., Britten-Jones and Neuberger [77] and Carr and
Madan [83]). In contrast, it is still an open area of research to determine the replication strategy for
derivatives whose payoffs are non-linear function of realized variance, e.g., volatility swaps, which pay
the square-root of realized variance, or call and put options on realized variance. Carr and Lee [82] is
an interesting paper in this direction.
Limited liability gives shareholders the option to default on the firm’s debt obligation. As such,
a debt claim has features similar to a short position in a put option. The pricing of corporate debt
is therefore sensitive to the volatility of the firms’ assets: higher volatility increases the probability
of default and therefore reduces the price of debt and increases credit spreads. The insights and
techniques developed in the SV literature could prove useful in credit risk modeling and applications
(e.g., Jacobs and Li [178], Tauchen and Zhou [248] and Zhang et al. [260]).

VII.2. The Use of Realized Volatility for Estimation of SV Models
Another promising line of research aims at extracting the information in RV measures for the estimation of dynamic asset pricing models. Early work along these lines includes Barndorff-Nielsen and
Shephard [51], who decompose RV into actual volatility and realized volatility error. They consider
a state-space representation for this decomposition and apply the Kalman filter to estimate different
flavors of the SV model. Moreover, Bollerslev and Zhou [68] and Garcia et al. [156] build on the
insights of Meddahi [210] to estimate SV diffusion models using conditional moments of integrated
volatility. More recently, Todorov [252] generalizes the analysis for the presence of jumps.
Related, recent studies have started to use RV measures to test the implications of models previously estimated with lower-frequency data. Since RV gives empirical content to the latent quadratic
variation process, this approach allows for a direct test of the model-implied restrictions on the latent volatility factor. Recent work along these lines includes Andersen and Benzoni [12], who use
model-free RV measures to show that the volatility spanning condition embedded in some affine term
structure models is violated in the U.S. Treasury market. Christoffersen et al. [100] note that the
Heston square-root SV model implies that the dynamics for the standard deviation process are conditionally Gaussian. They reject this condition by examining the distribution of the changes in the

38
square-root RV measure for S&P 500 returns.

VII.3. Volatility Risk Premium
More work is needed to better understand the link between asset return volatility and model risk
premia. Also in this case, RV measures are a fruitful source of information to shed new light on the
issue. Among the recent studies that pursue this venue is Bollerslev et al. [66], who exploit the moments
of RV and option-implied volatility to gauge a measure of the volatility risk premium. Todorov [251]
explores the variance risk premium dynamics using high-frequency S&P 500 index futures data and
data on the VIX index. He finds the variance risk premium to vary significantly over time and to
increase during periods of high volatility and immediately after big jumps in underlying returns. Carr
and Wu [85] provide a broader analysis of the variance risk premium for five equity indices and 35
individual stocks. They find the premium to be large and negative for the indices while it is much
smaller for the individual stocks. Further, they also find the premium to increase (in absolute value)
with the level of volatility. Additional work on the volatility risk premium embedded in individual
stock options is in Bakshi and Kapadia [36], Driessen et al. [123], and Duarte and Jones [126]. Other
studies have examined the linkage between volatility risk premia and equity returns (e.g., Bollerslev
and Zhou [69]) and hedge-fund performance (e.g., Bondarenko [70]). New research is also examining
the pricing of aggregate volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns. For instance, Ang et al. [30]
find that average returns are lower on stocks that have high sensitivities to innovations in aggregate
volatility and high idiosyncratic volatility (see also the related work by Ang et al. [31], Bandi et al.
[?], Chen [90], and Guo et al. [163]). This evidence is consistent with the findings of the empirical
option pricing literature, which suggests that there is a negative risk premium for volatility risk.
Intuitively, periods of high market volatility are associated to worsened investment opportunities and
tend to coincide with negative stock market returns (the so-callled leverage effect). As such, investors
are willing to pay higher prices (i.e., accept lower expected returns) to hold stocks that do well in
high-volatility conditions.

VII.4. Determinants of Volatility
Finally, an important area of future research concerns the linkage between asset return volatility and
economic uncertainty. Recent studies have proposed general equilibrium models that produce lowfrequency fluctuations in conditional volatility, e.g., Campbell and Cochrane [80], Bansal and Yaron
[47], McQueen and Vorkink [207], and Tauchen [246]. Related, Engle and Rangel [139] and Engle et
al. [138] link macroeconomic variables and long-run volatility movements. It is still an open issue,
however, to determine the process through which news about economic fundamentals are embedded
into prices to generate high-frequency volatility fluctuations. Early research by Schwert [236] and
Shiller [241] has concluded that the amplitude of the fluctuations in aggregate stock volatility is difficult
to explain using simple models of stock valuation. Further, Schwert [236] notes that while aggregate
leverage is significantly correlated with volatility, it explains a relatively small part of the movements
in stock volatility. Moreover, he finds little evidence that macroeconomic volatility (measured by
inflation and industrial production volatility) helps predict future asset return volatility. Model-free
realized volatility measures are a useful tool to further investigate this issue. Recent work in this

39
direction includes Andersen et al. [22] and Andersen and Bollerslev [17], who explore the linkage
between news arrivals and exchange rates volatility, and Andersen and Benzoni [13], who investigate
the determinants of bond yields volatility in the U.S. Treasury market. Related, Balduzzi et al.
[38] and Fleming and Remolona [146] study the reaction of trading volume, bid-ask spread, and price
volatility to macroeconomic surprises in the U.S. Treasury market, while Brandt and Kavajecz [74] and
Pasquariello and Vega [222] focus instead on the price discovery process and explore the implications
of order flow imbalances (excess buying or selling pressure) on day-to-day variation in yields.

VIII. References
Primary Literature
1. Ahn DH, Dittmar RF, Gallant AR (2002) Quadratic Term Structure Models: Theory and
Evidence. Review of Financial Studies 15:243–288
2. Ahn DH, Dittmar RF, Gallant AR, Gao B (2003) Purebred or hybrid?: Reproducing the volatility in term structure dynamics. Journal of Econometrics 116:147–180
3. A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (2002) Maximum-Likelihood Estimation of Discretely-Sampled Diffusions: A
Closed-Form Approximation Approach. Econometrica 70:223–262
4. A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (2007) Closed-Form Likelihood Expansions for Multivariate Diffusions, forthcoming in the Annals of Statistics. Annals of Statistics, forthcoming
ıt-Sahalia Y, Hansen LP, Scheinkman J (2004) Operator Methods for Continuous-Time Markov
5. A¨
Processes. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, NorthHolland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
6. A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y, Jacod J (2007) Testing for Jumps in a Discretely Observed Process. Annals of
Statistics, forthcoming
7. A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y, Kimmel R (2007) Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models
Journal of Financial Economics 83:413–452
8. Alizadeh S, Brandt MW, Diebold FX (2002) Range-Based Estimation of Stochastic Volatility
Models. Journal of Finance 57:1047–1091
9. Almeida CIR, Graveline JJ, Joslin S (2006) Do Options Contain Information About Excess Bond
Returns?. Working Paper, UMN, Funda¸˜o Getulio Vargas, MIT
ca
10. Andersen TG (1994) Stochastic Autoregressive Volatility: A Framework for Volatility Modeling.
Mathematical Finance 4:75–102
11. Andersen TG (1996) Return Volatility and Trading Volume: An Information Flow Interpretation
of Stochastic Volatility. Journal of Finance 51:169–204
12. Andersen TG, Benzoni L (2006) Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market? A
Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models. Working Paper, KGSM and Chicago FED

40
13. Andersen TG, Benzoni L (2007a) The Determinants of Volatility in the U.S. Treasury market.
Working Paper, KGSM and Chicago FED
14. Andersen TG, Benzoni L (2007b) Realized Volatility. In: Andersen TG, Davis RA, Kreiss JP,
Mikosch T (Eds) Handbook of Financial Time Series, Springer Verlag
15. Andersen TG, Benzoni L, Lund J (2002) An Empirical Investigation of Continuous-Time Equity
Return Models. Journal of Finance 57:1239–1284
16. Andersen TG, Benzoni L, Lund J (2004) Stochastic Volatility, Mean Drift and Jumps in the
Short Term Interest Rate. Working Paper, Northwestern University, University of Minnesota,
and Nykredit Bank
17. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T (1998a) Deutsche Mark-Dollar Volatility: Intraday Activity Patterns,
Macroeconomic Announcements, and Longer Run Dependencies. Journal of Finance 53:219–265
18. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T (1998b) Answering the Skeptics: Yes, Standard Volatility Models
Do Provide Accurate Forecasts. International Economic Review 39:885–905
19. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Diebold FX (2004) Parametric and nonparametric volatility measurement. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, NorthHolland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
20. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Diebold FX (2007) Roughing It Up: Including Jump Components
in Measuring, Modeling and Forecasting Asset Return Volatility. Review of Economics and
Statistics, forthcoming
21. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Diebold FX, Labys P (2003) Modeling and Forecasting Realized
Volatility. Econometrica 71:579–625
22. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Diebold FX, Vega C (2003) Micro Effects of Macro Announcements:
Real-Time Price Discovery in Foreign Exchange. American Economic Review 93:38–62
23. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Dobrev D (2007) No-arbitrage semi-martingale restrictions for
continuous-time volatility models subject to leverage effects, jumps and i.i.d. noise: Theory
and testable distributional implications. Journal of Econometrics 138:125–180
24. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Meddahi N (2004) Analytic Evaluation of Volatility Forecasts. International Economic Review 45:1079–1110
25. Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Meddahi N (2005) Correcting the Errors: Volatility Forecast Evaluation Using High-Frequency Data and Realized Volatilities. Econometrica 73:279–296
26. Andersen TG, Bondarenko O (2007) Construction and Interpretation of Model-Free Implied
Volatility. Working Paper, KGSM and UIC
27. Andersen TG, Chung HJ, Sørensen BE (1999) Efficient Method of Moments Estimation of a
Stochastic Volatility Model: A Monte Carlo Study, Journal of Econometrics 91:61–87

41
28. Andersen TG, Lund J (1997) Estimating continuous-time stochastic volatility models of the
short term interest rate diffusion. Journal of Econometrics 77:343–377
29. An´ T, Geman H (2000) Order Flow, Transaction Clock, and Normality of Asset Returns.
e
Journal of Finance 55:2259–2284
30. Ang A, Hodrick RJ, Xing Y, Zhang X (2006) The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected
Returns. Journal of Finance 51:259–299
31. Ang A, Hodrick RJ, Xing Y, Zhang X (2008) High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns:
international and further U.S. evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming
´
32. Bachelier L (1900) Th´orie de la Sp´culation. Annales de l’Ecole Normale Sup´rieure 3, Gauthiere
e
e
Villars, Paris, France. English translation in Cootner PH (Ed) (1964) The Random Character
of Stock Market Prices, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.
33. Back K (1991) Asset Prices for General Processes. Journal of Mathematical Economics 20:371–
395
34. Bakshi G, Cao C, Chen Z (1997) Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models.
Journal of Finance 52:2003–2049
35. Bakshi G, Cao C, Chen Z (2002) Pricing and hedging long-term options. Journal of Econometrics
94:277–318
36. Bakshi G, Kapadia N (2003) Delta-Hedged Gains and the Negative Market Volatility Risk
Premium. Review of Financial Studies 16:527–566
37. Bakshi G, Kapadia N, Madan D (2003) Stock Return Characteristics, Skew Laws, and the
Differential Pricing of Individual Equity Options. Review of Financial Studies 16:101–143
38. Balduzzi P, Elton EJ, Green TC (2001) Economic News and Bond Prices: Evidence from the
U.S. Treasury Market. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36:523–543
39. Bandi FM (2002) Short-term interest rate dynamics: a spatial approach. Journal of Financial
Economics 65:73–110
40. Bandi F, Moise CE, Russell JR (2008) Market volatility, market frictions, and the cross section
of stock returns. Working Paper, University of Chicago and Case Western Reserve University.
41. Bandi FM, Nguyen T (2003) On the functional estimation of jump-diffusion models. Journal of
Econometrics 116:293–328
42. Bandi FM, Phillips PCB (2002) Nonstationary Continuous-Time Processes. In: Hansen LP,
A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland,
forthcoming
43. Bandi FM, Phillips PCB (2003) Fully nonparametric estimation of scalar diffusion models.
Econometrica 71:241–283

42
44. Bandi FM, Phillips PCB (2007) A simple approach to the parametric estimation of potentially
nonstationary diffusions. Journal of Econometrics 137:354–395
45. Bandi FM, Russell J (2006a) Separating Microstructure Noise from Volatility. Journal of Financial Economics 79:655–692
46. Bandi FM, Russell J (2006b) Volatility. In: Birge J and Linetsky V (Eds) Handbook of Financial
Engineering, Elsevier
47. Bansal R, Yaron A (2004) Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing
Puzzles. Journal of Finance 59:1481–1509
48. Bartlett MS (1938) The Characteristic Function of a Conditional Statistic. Journal of the London
Mathematical Society 13:63–67
49. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Hansen P, Lunde A, Shephard N (2007) Designing Realized Kernels
to Measure the Ex-Post Variation of Equity Prices in the Presence of Noise. Working Paper,
University of Aarhus, Denmark; Stanford University; Nuffield College, Oxford, UK
50. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2001) Non-Gaussian OrnsteinUhlenbeckbased models and
some of their uses in financial economics. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B
63:167–241
51. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2002a) Econometric Analysis of Realised Volatility and its
Use in Estimating Stochastic Volatility Models. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series
B 64:253–280
52. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2002b) Estimating quadratic variation using realized variance. Journal of Applied Econometrics 17:457–477
53. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2004) Power and bipower variation with stochastic volatility
and jumps. Journal of Financial Econometrics 2:1-37
54. Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2006) Econometrics of testing for jumps in financial economics using bipower variation. Journal of Financial Econometrics 4:1–30
55. Bates DS (1991) The Crash of ’87: Was It Expected? The Evidence from Options Markets
Journal of Finance 46:1009–1044
56. Bates DS (1996) Jumps and stochastic volatility: exchange rate processes implicit in deutsche
mark options. Review of Financial Studies 9:69–107
57. Bates DS (2000) Post-’87 crash fears in the S&P 500 futures option market. Journal of Econometrics 94:181–238
58. Bates DS (2006) Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Latent Affine Processes. Review of Financial Studies 19:909–965

43
59. Benzoni L (2002) Pricing Options under Stochastic Volatility: An Empirical Investigation. Working Paper, Chicago FED
60. Benzoni L, Collin-Dufresne P, Goldstein RS (2007) Explaining Pre- and Post-1987 Crash Prices
of Equity and Options within a Unified General Equilibrium Framework. Working Paper,
Chicago FED, UCB, and UMN
61. Bibby BM, Jacobsen M, Sorensen M (2004) Estimating Functions for Discretely Sampled
Diffusion-Type Models. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
62. Bikbov R, Chernov M (2005) Term Structure and Volatility: Lessons from the Eurodollar Markets. Working Paper, LBS, Deutsche Bank
63. Black F, Scholes M (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political
Economy 81:637–654
64. Bladt M, Sørensen M (2007) Simple Simulation of Diffusion Bridges with Application to Likelihood Inference for Diffusions. Working Paper, University of Copenhagen, Denmark.
65. Bollen NPB, Whaley RE (2004) Does Net Buying Pressure Affect the Shape of Implied Volatility
Functions?. Journal of Finance 59:711–753
66. Bollerslev T, Gibson M, Zhou H (2004) Dynamic Estimation of Volatility Risk Premia and
Investor Risk Aversion from Option-Implied and Realized Volatilities. Working Paper, Duke,
Federal Reserve Board
67. Bollerslev T, Jubinsky PD (1999) Equity Trading Volume and Volatility: Latent Information
Arrivals and Common Long-Run Dependencies. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 17:9–
21
68. Bollerslev T, Zhou H (2002) Estimating stochastic volatility diffusion using conditional moments
of integrated volatility. Journal of Econometrics 109:33–65
69. Bollerslev T, Zhou H (2007) Expected Stock Returns and Variance Risk Premia. Working Paper,
Duke University and Federal Reserve Board
70. Bondarenko O (2004) Market price of variance risk and performance of hedge funds. Working
Paper, UIC
71. Brandt MW, Chapman DA (2003) Comparing Multifactor Models of the Term Structure. Working Paper, Duke and Boston College
72. Brandt MW, Diebold FX (2006) A No-Arbitrage Approach to Range-Based Estimation of Return
Covariances and Correlations. Journal of Business 79:61–73
73. Brandt MW, Jones CS (2006) Volatility Forecasting with Range-Based EGARCH Models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 24:470–486

44
74. Brandt MW, Kavajecz KA Price Discovery in the U.S. Treasury Market: The Impact of Orderflow and Liquidity on the Yield Curve. Journal of Finance 59:2623–2654
75. Brandt MW, Santa-Clara P (2002) Simulated likelihood estimation of diffusions with an application to exchange rate dynamics in incomplete markets. Journal of Financial Economics
63:161–210
76. Breidt FJ, Crato N, de Lima P (1998) The detection and estimation of long memory in stochastic
volatility Journal of Econometrics 83:325-348
77. Britten-Jones M, Neuberger A (2000) Option Prices, Implied Price Processes, and Stochastic
Volatility. Journal of Finance 55:839–866
78. Broadie M, Chernov M, Johannes MJ (2007) Model Specification and Risk Premia: Evidence
from Futures Options. Journal of Finance 62:1453–1490
79. Buraschi A, Jackwerth J (2001) The price of a smile: hedging and spanning in option markets.
Review of Financial Studies 14:495–527
80. Campbell JY, Cochrane JH (1999) By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of
Aggregate Stock Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy 107:205–251
81. Campbell JY, Viceira LM (2001) Who Should Buy Long-Term Bonds? American Economic
Review 91:99–127
82. Carr P, Lee R (2007) Robust Replication of Volatility Derivatives. Working Paper, NYU and
UofC
83. Carr P, Madan D (1998) Towards a theory of volatility trading. In: Jarrow R (Ed) Volatility,
Risk Publications
84. Carr P, Wu L (2004) Time-changed Lvy processes and option pricing. Journal of Financial
Economics 71:113–141
85. Carr P, Wu L (2007) Variance Risk Premia. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming
86. Carrasco M, Chernov M, Florens JP, Ghysels E (2007) Efficient estimation of general dynamic
models with a continuum of moment conditions. Journal of Econometrics 140:529–573
87. Carrasco M, Florens JP (2000) Generalization of GMM to a continuum of moment conditions.
Econometric Theory 16:797–834
88. Chacko G, Viceira LM (2003) Spectral GMM estimation of continuous-time processes. Journal
of Econometrics 116:259–292
89. Chan KC, Karolyi GA, Longstaff FA, Sanders AB (1992) An Empirical Comparison of Alternative Models of the Short-Term Interest Rate. The Journal of Finance 47:1209–1227

45
90. Chen J (2003) Intertemporal CAPM and the Cross-Section of Stock Return. Working Paper,
USC
91. Chen RR, Scott L (1993) Maximum likelihood estimation for a multifactor equilibrium model
of the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Fixed Income 3:14–31
92. Cheridito P, Filipovi´ D, Kimmel RL (2005) Market Price of Risk Specifications for Affine
c
Models: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming
93. Chernov M, Ghysels E (2002) A study towards a unified approach to the joint estimation of
objective and risk neutral measures for the purpose of options valuation. Journal of Financial
Economics 56:407–458
94. Chernov M, Gallant AR, Ghysels E, Tauchen G (1999) A New Class of Stochastic Volatility
Models with Jumps: Theory and Estimation. Working Paper, London Business School, Duke
University, University of Northern Carolina
95. Chernov M, Gallant AR, Ghysels E, Tauchen G (2003) Alternative models for stock price dynamics. Journal of Econometrics 116:225–257
96. Chib S, Nardari F, Shephard N (2002) Markov chain Monte Carlo methods for stochastic volatility models. Journal of Econometrics 108:281–316
97. Chib S, Nardari F, Shephard N (2006) Analysis of high dimensional multivariate stochastic
volatility models. Journal of Econometrics 134:341–371
98. Christoffersen PF, Jacobs K (2004) The importance of the loss function in option valuation.
Journal of Financial Economics 72:291–318
99. Christoffersen PF, Jacobs K, Karoui L, Mimouni K (2007) Estimating Term Structure Models
Using Swap Rates. Working Paper, McGill University
100. Christoffersen PF, Jacobs K, Mimouni K (2006a) Models for S&P 500 Dynamics: Evidence from
Realized Volatility, Daily Returns, and Option Prices. Working Paper, Mcgill University
101. Christoffersen PF, Jacobs K, Wang Y (2006b) Option Valuation with Long-run and Short-run
Volatility Components Working Paper, Mcgill University
102. Clark PK (1973) A Subordinated Stochastic Process Model with Finite Variance for Speculative
Prices. Econometrica 41:135–156
103. Collin-Dufresne P, Goldstein RS (2002) Do Bonds Span the Fixed Income Markets? Theory and
Evidence for Unspanned Stochastic Volatility. Journal of Finance 57:1685–1730
104. Collin-Dufresne P, Goldstein R, Jones CS (2007a) Identification of Maximal Affine Term Structure Models. Journal of Finance, forthcoming

46
105. Collin-Dufresne P, Goldstein R, Jones CS (2007b) Can Interest Rate Volatility be Extracted
from the Cross Section of Bond Yields? An Investigation of Unspanned Stochastic Volatility.
Working Paper, UCB, USC, UMN
106. Collin-Dufresne P, Solnik B (2001) On the Term Structure of Default Premia in the Swap and
LIBOR Markets Journal of Finance 56:1095–1115
107. Comte F, Coutin L, Renault E (2003) Affine Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models with Application to Option Pricing. Working Paper, CIRANO
108. Comte F, Renault E (1998) Long memory in continuous-time stochastic volatility models. Mathematical Finance 8:291–323
109. Conley TG, Hansen LP, Luttmer EGJ, Scheinkman JA (1997) Short-term interest rates as
subordinated diffusions. Review of Financial Studies 10:525–577
110. Corsi F (2003) A Simple Long Memory Model of realized Volatility. Working paper, University
of Southern Switzerland
111. Coval JD, Shumway T (2001) Expected Option Returns. Journal of Finance 56:983–1009
112. Cox JC, Ingersoll JE, Ross SA (1985a) An Intertemporal General Equilibrium Model of Asset
Prices. Econometrica 53:363–384
113. Cox JC, Ingersoll JE, Ross SA (1985b) A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.
Econometrica 53:385–407
114. Dai Q, Singleton KJ (2000) Specification Analysis of Affine Term Structure Models. Journal of
Finance 55:1943–1978
115. Dai Q, Singleton KJ (2003) Term Structure Dynamics in Theory and Reality. Review of Financial
Studies 16:631–678
116. Danielsson, J (1994) Stochastic Volatility in Asset Prices: Estimation by Simulated Maximum
Likelihood. Journal of Econometrics 64:375–400
117. Danielsson J, Richard, J-F (1993) Accelerated Gaussian Importance Sampler with Application
to Dynamic Latent Variable Models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 8:S153–S173
118. Deo, R, Hurvich C (2001) On the Log Periodogram Regression Estimator of the Memory Parameter in Long Memory Stochastic Volatility Models. Econometric Theory 17:686–710
119. Derman E, Kani I (1994) The volatility smile and its implied tree. Quantitative Strategies
Research Notes, Goldman Sachs, New York.
120. Diebold FX, Nerlove M (1989) The Dynamics of Exchange Rate Volatility: A Multivariate
Latent Factor ARCH Model. Journal of Applied Econometrics 4:1–21

47
121. Diebold FX, Strasser G (2007) On the Correlation Structure of Microstructure Noise in Theory
and Practice. Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania,
122. Dobrev D (2007) Capturing Volatility from Large Price Moves: Generalized Range Theory and
Applications. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Board
123. Driessen J, Maenhout P, Vilkov G (2006) Option-Implied Correlations and the Price of Correlation Risk. Working Paper, University of Amsterdam and INSEAD
124. Duarte J (2004) Evaluating An Alternative Risk Preference in Affine Term Structure Models.
Review of Financial Studies 17:370–404
125. Duarte J (2007) The Causal Effect of Mortgage Refinancing on Interest-Rate Volatility: Empirical Evidence and Theoretical Implications. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming
126. Duarte J, Jones CS (2007) The Price of Market Volatility Risk. Working Paper, University of
Washington and USC
127. Duffee GR (2002) Term Premia and Interest Rate Forecasts in Affine Models. Journal of Finance
57:405–443
128. Duffee G, Stanton R (2007) Evidence on simulation inference for near unit-root processes with
implications for term structure estimation. Journal of Financial Econometrics, forthcoming.
129. Duffie D, Kan R (1996) A yield-factor model of interest rates. Mathematical Finance 6:379–406
130. Duffie D, Pan J, Singleton KJ (2000) Transform Analysis and Asset Pricing for Affine JumpDiffusions Econometrica 68:1343–1376
131. Duffie D, Singleton KJ (1993) Simulated Moments Estimation of Markov Models of Asset Prices.
Econometrica 61:929–952
132. Duffie D, Singleton KJ (1997) An Econometric Model of the Term Structure of Interest-Rate
Swap Yields. Journal of Finance 52:1287–1321
133. Dumas B, Fleming J, Whaley RE (1996) Implied Volatility Functions: Empirical Tests. Journal
of Finance 53:2059–2106
134. Dupire B (1994) Pricing with a smile. Risk 7:18–20
135. Elerian O, Chib S, Shephard N (2001) Likelihood Inference for Discretely Observed Nonlinear
Diffusions. Econometrica 69:959–994
136. Engle RF (2002) New frontiers for ARCH models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 17:425–446
137. Engle RF, Gallo GM (2006) A multiple indicators model for volatility using intra-daily data.
Journal of Econometrics 131:3–27
138. Engle RF, Ghysels E, Sohn B (2006) On the Economic Sources of Stock Market Volatility.
Working Paper, NYU and UNC

48
139. Engle RF, Rangel JG (2006) The Spline-GARCH Model for Low Frequency Volatility and Its
Global Macroeconomic Causes. Working Paper, NYU
140. Eraker B (2001) MCMC Analysis of Diffusions with Applications to Finance. Journal of Business
& Economic Statistics 19:177–191
141. Eraker B (2004) Do Stock Prices and Volatility Jump? Reconciling Evidence from Spot and
Option Prices. Journal of Finance 59: 1367–1404
142. Eraker B, Johannes MS, Polson N (2003) The Impact of Jumps in Volatility and Returns. Journal
of Finance 58: 1269–1300
143. Fan R, Gupta A, Ritchken P (2003) Hedging in the Possible Presence of Unspanned Stochastic
Volatility: Evidence from Swaption Markets. Journal of Finance 58:2219–2248
144. Fiorentina G, Sentana E, Shephard N (2004) Likelihood-Based Estimation of Latent Generalized
ARCH Structures. Econometrica 72:1481–1517
145. Fisher M, Gilles C (1996) Estimating exponential-affine models of the term structure. Working
Paper, Atlanta FED
146. Fleming MJ, Remolona EM (1999) Price Formation and Liquidity in the U.S. Treasury Market:
The Response to Public Information. Journal of Finance 54:1901–1915
147. Forsberg L, Ghysels E (2007) Why Do Absolute Returns Predict Volatility So Well? Journal of
Financial Econometrics 5:31–67
148. French KR, Schwert GW, Stambaugh RF (1987) Expected stock returns and volatility. Journal
of Financial Economics 19:3–29
149. Fridman M, Harris L (1998) A Maximum Likelihood Approach for Non-Gaussian Stochastic
Volatility Models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 16:284–291
150. Gallant AR, Hsieh DA, Tauchen GE (1997) Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models with
Diagnostics. Journal of Econometrics 81:159–192
151. Gallant AR, Hsu C, Tauchen GE (1999) Using Daily Range Data to Calibrate Volatility Diffusions and Extract the Forward Integrated Variance. Review of Economics and Statistics 81:617–
631
152. Gallant AR, Long JR (1997) Estimating stochastic differential equations efficiently by minimum
chi-squared. Biometrika 84:125–141
153. Gallant AR, Rossi PE, Tauchen GE (1992) Stock Prices and Volume. Review of Financial Studies
5:199–242
154. Gallant AR, Tauchen GE (1996) Which Moments to Match. Econometric Theory 12:657–681

49
155. Gallant AR, Tauchen G (1998) Reprojecting Partially Observed Systems With Application to
Interest Rate Diffusions. Journal of the American Statistical Association 93:10–24
156. Garcia R, Lewis MA, Pastorello S, Renault E (2001) Estimation of Objective and Risk-neutral
Distributions based on Moments of Integrated Volatility Working Paper, Universit´ de Montr´al,
e
e
Banque Nationale du Canada, Universit` di Bologna, UNC
a
157. Garman MB, Klass MJ (1980) On the Estimation of Price Volatility From Historical Data.
Journal of Business 53:67–78
158. Ghysels E, Harvey AC, Renault E (1996) Stochastic Volatility. In: Maddala GS and Rao CR
(Eds) Handbook of Statistics, Volume 14, North Holland, Amsterdam, Holland
159. Ghysels E, Santa-Clara P, Valkanov R (2006) Predicting Volatility: How to Get the Most Out
of Returns Data Sampled at Different Frequencies. Journal of Econometrics 131:59–95
160. Glosten LR, Jagannathan R, Runkle D (1993) On the Relation Between the Expected Value
and the Volatility of the Nominal Excess Return on Stocks. Journal of Finance 48:1779–1801
161. Gong FF, Remolona EM (1996) A three-factor econometric model of the U.S. term structure.
Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
e
162. Gouri´roux C, Monfort A, Renault E (1993) Indirect Inference. Journal of Applied Econometrics
8:S85–S118
163. Guo H, Neely CJ, Higbee J (2007) Foreign Exchange Volatility Is Priced in Equities. Financial
Management, forthcoming
164. Han B (2007) Stochastic Volatilities and Correlations of Bond Yields. Journal of Finance
62:1491–1524
165. Hansen PR, Lunde A (2006) Realized Variance and Market Microstructure Noise. Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics 24:127–161
166. Harvey AC (1998) Long memory in stochastic volatility. In: Knight J, Satchell S (Eds) Forecasting Volatility in Financial Markets, Butterworth-Heinemann, London.
167. Harvey AC, Ruiz E, Shephard N (1994) Multivariate Stochastic Variance Models. Review of
Economic Studies 61:247–264
168. Harvey AC, Shephard N (1996) Estimation of an Asymmetric Stochastic Volatility Model for
Asset Returns. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 14:429–434
169. Heidari M, Wu L (2003) Are Interest Rate Derivatives Spanned by the Term Structure of Interest
Rates? Journal of Fixed Income 13:75–86
170. Heston SL (1993) A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications
to bond and currency options. Review of Financial Studies 6:327–343

50
171. Ho M, Perraudin W, Sørensen BE (1996) A Continuous Time Arbitrage Pricing Model with
Stochastic Volatility and Jumps. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 14:31–43
172. Huang X, Tauchen G (2005) The relative contribution of jumps to total price variation. Journal
of Financial Econometrics 3:456–499
173. Huang J, Wu L (2004) Specification Analysis of Option Pricing Models Based on Time-Changed
Levy Processes. Journal of Finance 59:1405–1440
174. Hull J, White A (1987) The Pricing of Options on Assets with Stochastic Volatilities. Journal
of Finance 42:281–300
175. Hurvich CM, Soulier P (2007) Stochastic Volatility Models with Long Memory. In: Andersen
TG, Davis RA, Kreiss JP, Mikosch T (Eds) Handbook of Financial Time Series, Springer Verlag.
176. Jackwerth JC, Rubinstein M (1996) Recovering Probability Distributions from Option Prices.
Journal of Finance 51:1611–1631
177. Jacobs K, Karoui L (2007) Conditional Volatility in Affine Term Structure Models: Evidence
from Treasury and Swap Markets. Working Paper, McGill University
178. Jacobs K, Li X (2007) Modeling the Dynamics of Credit Spreads with Stochastic Volatility.
Management Science, forthcoming
179. Jacquier E, Polson NG, Rossi PE (1994) Bayesian Analysis of Stochastic Volatility Models.
Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 12:371–389
180. Jacquier E, Polson NG, Rossi PE (2004) Bayesian analysis of stochastic volatility models with
fat-tails and correlated errors. Journal of Econometrics 122:185–212
181. Jagannathan R, Kaplin A, Sun S (2003) An evaluation of multi-factor CIR models using LIBOR,
swap rates, and cap and swaption prices. Journal of Econometrics 116:113–146
182. Jarrow R, Li H, Zhao F (2007) Interest Rate Caps “Smile” Too! But Can the LIBOR Market
Models Capture the Smile? Journal of Finance 62:345–382
183. Jiang GJ, Knight JL (2002) Efficient Estimation of the Continuous Time Stochastic Volatility
Model via the Empirical Characteristic Function. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics
20:198–212
184. Jiang GJ, Tian YS (2005) The Model-Free Implied Volatility and Its Information Content.
Review of Financial Studies 18:1305–1342.
185. Johannes MS, Polson N (2003) MCMC Methods for Continuous-Time Financial Econometrics.
In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia I (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
186. Johannes MS, Polson N (2006) Particle Filtering. In: Andersen TG, Davis RA, Kreiss JP,
Mikosch T (Eds) Handbook of Financial Time Series, Springer Verlag.

51
187. Johnson H, Shanno D (1987) Option Pricing when the Variance Is Changing. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis 22:143–152.
188. Jones CS (2003a) Nonlinear Mean Reversion in the Short-Term Interest Rate Review of Financial
Studies 16:793–843
189. Jones C (2003b) The dynamics of stochastic volatility: evidence from underlying and options
markets. Journal of Econometrics 116:181–224
190. Joslin S (2006) Can Unspanned Stochastic Volatility Models Explain the Cross Section of Bond
Volatilities?. Working Paper, MIT
191. Joslin S (2007) Pricing and Hedging Volatility Risk in Fixed Income Markets. Working Paper,
MIT
192. Jung J (2006) Vexed by variance. Risk
193. Kim SN, Shephard N, Chib S (1998) Stochastic Volatility: Likelihood Inference and Comparison
with ARCH Models. Review of Economic Studies 65:361–393
194. Lamoureux CG, Lastrapes WD (1994) Endogenous Trading Volume and Momentum in StockReturn Volatility. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 14:253–260
195. Lee SS, Mykland PA (2006) Jumps in Financial Markets: A New Nonparametric Test and Jump
Dynamics. Working Paper, Georgia Institute of Technology and University of Chicago
196. Li H, Wells MT, Yu CL (2006) A Bayesian Analysis of Return Dynamics with L´vy Jumps
e
Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming
197. Li H, Zhao F (2006) Unspanned Stochastic Volatility: Evidence from Hedging Interest Rate
Derivatives. Journal of Finance 61:341–378
198. Liesenfeld R (1998) Dynamic Bivariate Mixture Models: Modeling the Behavior of Prices and
Trading Volume. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 16, 101–109
199. Liesenfeld R (2001) A Generalized Bivariate Mixture Model for Stock Price Volatility and Trading Volume. Journal of Econometrics 104:141–178
200. Liesenfeld R, Richard, J-F (2003) Univariate and Multivariate Stochastic Volatility Models:
Estimation and Diagnostics. Journal of Empirical Finance 10:505–531
201. Litterman R, Scheinkman JA (1991) Common Factors Affecting Bond Returns. Journal of Fixed
Income 1:54–61
202. Liu C, Maheu JM (2007) Forecasting Realized Volatility: A Bayesian Model Averaging Approach. Working Paper, University of Toronto
o
203. Lo AW (1988) Maximum likelihood estimation of generalized Itˆ processes with discretelysampled data. Econometric Theory 4:231–247

52
204. Longstaff FA, Schwartz ES (1992) Interest Rate Volatility and the Term Structure: A TwoFactor General Equilibrium Model. Journal of Finance 47:1259–1282
205. McAleer M, Medeiros MC (2007) Realized Volatility: A Review. Econometric Reviews, forthcoming
206. McFadden D (1989) A Method of Simulated Moments for Estimation of Discrete Response
Models Without Numerical Integration. Econometrica 57:995–1026
207. McQueen G, Vorkink K (2004) Whence GARCH? A Preference-Based Explanation for Conditional Volatility. Review of Financial Studies 17:915–949
208. Meddahi N (2001) An Eigenfunction Approach for Volatility Modeling. Working Paper, Imperial
College
209. Meddahi N (2002) A Theoretical Comparison Between Integrated and Realized Volatility. Journal of Applied Econometrics 17:475–508
210. Meddahi N (2002) Moments of Continuous Time Stochastic Volatility Models. Working Paper,
Imperial College
211. Melino A, Turnbull SM (1990) Pricing foreign currency options with stochastic volatility. Journal
of Econometrics 45:239–265
212. Merton RC (1969) Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the continuous-time case.
Review of Economics and Statistics 51:247–257
213. Merton RC (1973) An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model. Econometrica 41:867–887
214. Merton RC (1976) Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. Journal of
Financial Economics 3:125–144
215. Merton RC (1980) On estimating the expected return on the market: An exploratory investigation. Journal of Financial Economics 8:323–361
216. Mizrach B (2006) The Enron Bankruptcy: When Did The Options Market Lose Its Smirk.
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 27:365–382
217. Mizrach B (2007) Recovering Probabilistic Information From Options Prices and the Underlying.
In Lee C, Lee AC (eds), Handbook of Quantitative Finance, Springer-Verlag, New York
218. Nelson DB (1991) Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach. Econometrica 59:347–370
219. Nelson DB, Foster DP (1994) Asymptotic Filtering Theory for Univariate ARCH Models. Econometrica 62:1–41
220. Pan J (2002) The jump-risk premia implicit in options: evidence from an integrated time-series
study. Journal of Financial Economics 63:3–50

53
221. Parkinson M (1980) The Extreme ValueMethod for Estimating the Variance of the Rate of
Return. Journal of Business 53:61-65
222. Pasquariello P, Vega C (2006) Informed and Strategic Order Flow in the Bond Markets. Review
of Financial Studies, forthcoming
223. Pearson ND, Sun TS (1994) Exploiting the Conditional Density in Estimating the Term Structure: An Application to the Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross Model. Journal of Finance 49:1279–1304
224. Pedersen AR (1995) A new approach to maximum likelihood estimation for stochastic differential
equations based on discrete observations. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics 22:55–71
225. Pennacchi GG (1991) Identifying the Dynamics of Real Interest Rates and Inflation: Evidence
Using Survey Data. Review of Financial Studies 4:53–86
226. Pitt MK, Shephard N (1999) Filtering via simulation: auxiliary particle filter. Journal of the
American Statistical Association 94:590–599
227. Piazzesi M (2003) Affine Term Structure Models. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia I (Eds) Handbook
of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
228. Piazzesi M (2005) Bond Yields and the Federal Reserve. Journal of Political Economy 113:311–
344
229. Protter P (1992) Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations: A New Approach. SpringerVerlag, New York, New York, U.S.
230. Renault E (1997) Econometric models of option pricing errors. In: Kreps D, Wallis K (Eds), Advances in Economics and Econometrics. Seventh World Congress. Cambridge University Press,
New York and Melbourne, 223-278.
231. Richardson M, Smith T (1994) A Direct Test of the Mixture of Distributions Hypothesis: Measuring the Daily Flow of Information. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 29:101–116
232. Rosenberg B (1972). The Behavior of Random Variables with Nonstationary Variance and the
Distribution of Security Prices. Working Paper, UCB, Berkeley
233. Rubinstein M (1994) Implied Binomial Trees. Journal of Finance 49:771–818
234. Santa-Clara P (1995) Simulated likelihood estimation of diffusions with an application to the
short term interest rate. Ph.D. Dissertation, INSEAD
235. Schaumburg E (2005) Estimation of Markov processes with Levy type generators. Working
Paper, KGSM
236. Schwert GW (1989) Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time? Journal of Finance
44:1115–1153
237. Schwert GW (1990) Stock Volatility and the Crash of ’87. Review of Financial Studies 3:77-102

54
238. Scott LO (1987) Option Pricing when the Variance Changes Randomly: Theory, Estimation
and an Application. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22:419–438
239. Shephard N (1996) Statistical Aspects of ARCH and Stochastic Volatility Models. In: Cox DR,
Hinkley DV, Barndorff-Nielsen OE (Eds) Time Series Models in Econometrics, Finance and
Other Fields, Chapman & Hall, London, UK, pp. 1–67
240. Shephard N (2004) Stochastic Volatility: Selected Readings. Oxford University Press, Oxford,
UK
241. Shiller RJ (1981) Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in
Dividends? American Economic Review 71:421–436
242. Singleton KJ (2001) Estimation of affine asset pricing models using the empirical characteristic
function. Journal of Econometrics 102:111–141
243. Smith, Jr., AA (1993) Estimating Nonlinear Time-series Models using Simulated Vector Autoregressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics 8:S63–S84
244. Stein JC (1989) Overreactions in the Options Market. Journal of Finance 44:1011–1023
245. Stein EM, Stein JC (1991) Stock price distributions with stochastic volatility: an analytic approach. Review of Financial Studies 4:727–752
246. Tauchen GE (2005) Stochastic Volatility in General Equilibrium. Working Paper, Duke
247. Tauchen GE, Pitts M (1983) The Price Variability-Volume Relationship on Speculative Markets.
Econometrica 51:485–505
248. Tauchen GE, Zhou H (2007) Realized Jumps on Financial Markets and Predicting Credit
Spreads. Working Paper, Duke and Board of Governors
249. Taylor SJ (1986) Modeling Financial Time Series. John Wiley and Sons, Chichester, UK
250. Thompson S (2004) Identifying Term Structure Volatility from the LIBOR-Swap Curve. Working
Paper, Harvard University
251. Todorov V (2006a) Variance Risk Premium Dynamics. Working Paper, KGSM
252. Todorov V (2006b) Estimation of Continuous-time Stochastic Volatility Models with Jumps
using High-Frequency Data. Working Paper, KGSM
253. Trolle AB, Schwartz ES (2007a) Unspanned stochastic volatility and the pricing of commodity
derivatives. Working Paper, Copenhagen Business School and UCLA
254. Trolle AB, Schwartz ES (2007b) A general stochastic volatility model for the pricing of interest
rate derivatives. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming
255. Vasicek OA (1977) An equilibrium characterization of the term structure. Journal of Financial
Economics 5:177–188

55
256. Wiggins JB (1987) Option Values under Stochastic Volatility: Theory and Empirical Estimates.
Journal of Financial Economics 19:351–372
257. Whaley RE (1993) Derivatives on Market Volatility: Hedging Tools Long Overdue. Journal of
Derivatives 1:71–84
258. Wright J, Zhou H (2007) Bond Risk Premia and Realized Jump Volatility. Working Paper, Board
of Governors
259. Yang D, Zhang Q (2000) Drift-Independent Volatility Estimation Based on High, Low, Open,
and Close Prices. Journal of Business 73:477-491
260. Zhang BY, Zhou H, Zhu H (2005) Explaining Credit Default Swap Spreads with the Equity
Volatility and Jump Risks of Individual Firms. Working Paper, Fitch Ratings, Federal Reserve
Board, BIS
261. Zhang L (2007) What you don’t know cannot hurt you: On the detection of small jumps.
Working Paper, UIC
262. Zhang L, Mykland PA, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (2005) A Tale of Two Time Scales: Determining Integrated
Volatility with Noisy High Frequency Data. Journal of the American Statistical Association
100:1394–1411

Books and Reviews
Asai M, McAleer M, Yu J (2006) Multivariate Stochastic Volatility: A Review. Econometric Reviews
25:145-175
Bates DS (2003) Empirical option pricing: a retrospection, Journal of Econometrics 116:387–404
Campbell JY, Lo AW, MacKinlay AC (1996) The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton
University Press, Princeton, NJ, US
Chib S, Omori Y, Asai M (2007) Multivariate Stochastic Volatility. Working Paper, Washington
University
Duffie D (2001) Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, US
Gallant AR, Tauchen G (2002) Simulated Score Methods and Indirect Inference for Continuous-time
Models. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, NorthHolland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
Garcia R, Ghysels E, Renault E (2003) The Econometrics of Option Pricing. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıtSahalia Y (Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland,
forthcoming
Gouri´roux C, Jasiak J (2001) Financial Econometrics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ,
e
US

56
Johannes MS, Polson N (2006) Markov Chain Monte Carlo. In: Andersen TG, Davis RA, Kreiss JP,
Mikosch T (Eds) Handbook of Financial Time Series, Springer Verlag
Jungbacker B, Koopman SJ (2007) Parameter Estimation and Practical Aspect of Modeling Stochastic Volatility. Working Paper, Vrije Universiteit
Mykland PA (2003) Option Pricing Bounds and Statistical Uncertainty. In: Hansen LP, A¨
ıt-Sahalia Y
(Eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, Holland, forthcoming
Renault E (2007) Moment-Based Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models. In: Andersen TG,
Davis RA, Kreiss JP, Mikosch T (Eds) Handbook of Financial Time Series, Springer Verlag
Singleton KJ (2006) Empirical Dynamic Asset Pricing: Model Specification and Econometric Assessment. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, US

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan
Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-18

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

6