View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Sticky Prices: New Evidence
from Retail Catalogs
Anil K. Kashyap

Working Papers Series
Issues in Macroeconomics
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
December 1991 (WP-91-26)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

Sticky Prices: New Evidence from Retail Catalogs

Anil K Kashyap
Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago
February 1990
(revised October 1991)

This paper was inspired by a conversation with Julio Rotemberg; he, Olivier
Blanchard, Ricardo Caballero, Stanley Fischer and David Romer deserve more than
the usual credit for helpful comments and conversations. I also benefitted from
many insightful suggestions from Larry Ball, Samuel Bentolila, Giuseppe Bertola,
Andrew Caplin, Ben Hermalin, Takeo Hoshi, Gary Loveman, Katie Merrell, Jim
Symanowski and three anonymous referees. I thank Chris Geczy for outstanding
research assistance. The project would not have been possible without the
permission and help of L.L. Bean Inc., The Orvis Company, Inc. and Recreational
Equipment Inc. Among the many people from these companies who helped me I
would like to thank, Kilt Andrew, Michael Collins, Michael Crenshaw, Catherine
Hartnett, Maurice Hilton, Byron Ives, Dave Kashner, Bonnie Miller, Les Noelk, Leigh
Perkins Jr., Leigh Perkins Sr., Tom Rosenbauer and Lea Talcott. The opinions here
do not reflect the views of these companies and of course any remaining errors are
my own.




Federal Reserve Board
FEDS Working Paper 112
revised September 1991

Sticky Prices: New Evidence from Retail Catalogs
Abstract
Despite the central importance of the debate in macroeconomics over
whether prices are flexible, there is almost no evidence on the time series
movements of actual transaction prices. This paper presents new results on the
size, frequency, and synchronization of price changes for twelve selected retail
goods over the past 35 years. Three basic facts about the data are uncovered:
first, that nominal prices are typically fixed for more than one year and that the
time between changes is very irregular; second, prices change more often during
periods of high overall inflation; third, when prices do change, the sizes of the
changes are widely dispersed. Both "large" and "small" changes occur for the
same item and the sizes of these changes do not closely depend on overall
inflation.
These findings are then used to critique standard models of price-setting.
Simple versions of both target/threshold models and fixed timing models are
strongly rejected. Modifications of the target/threshold models that introduce timevarying costs or benefits to price changes seem more promising. Similarly, models
focussing on customer markets receive some support from these data.

JEL Classification Code: E31
Keywords: inflation, price-setting, menu-costs

Anil Kashyap
University of Chicago
Graduate School of Business
1101 East 58th Street
Chicago, IL 60637
(312) 702-7260




Introduction
Despite the central importance of the debate in macroeconomics over
whether prices are flexible, there is very little direct evidence on how actual
transaction prices evolve over time. For instance, in Gordon's [1990] recent
survey of "New Keynesian Economics", he is only able to identify three other time
series studies on price flexibility. This paper contributes to the small empirical
literature on price rigidity by describing the evolution of twelve selected retail
goods prices over the past 35 years.
One factor that has inhibited the empirical literature in this area is the lack of
clear guidance from many of the competing theories of price rigidity about how
testing should proceed. As Blinder [1991] points out, "what we mean when we
say that a theory predicts that prices are 'sticky': Often nothing more than that
prices adjust less rapidly the Walrasian market clearing prices." Given this
amorphous benchmark, in many cases it is not obvious what one can do to "test"
whether prices are or are not flexible. The goal of this paper is to document the
characteristics of the prices that I have collected and then discuss how these
characteristics cohere with the various competing theories of price rigidity.
The evidence can be summarized in terms of the size, frequency and
synchronization of price changes. I find three basic facts about these data: first
that nominal prices are typically fixed for more than one year and that the time
between changes is very irregular; second, prices change more often during
periods of high overall inflation; third, when prices do change, the sizes of the




changes are widely dispersed. Both "large" and "small" changes occur for the
same item and the sizes of these changes do not closely depend on overall
inflation. Below, I argue that these facts challenge many of the recent theories put
forward to explain price rigidities and suggest certain directions in which to extend
existing models.
The remainder of the paper is separated into 5 sections. In the next section,
I explain why these data are particularly appropriate for testing many of the leading
theories of price rigidity. In the following section, I describe the method of data
collection and items in the study. The third section of the paper documents the
facts mentioned above. The fourth section of the paper discusses how these facts
bear on the leading theories of price setting. The final section summarizes my
findings and suggests several promising directions for future research.
I The Relevance of Catalog Data
The data were collected from the mail-order catalogs of L.L. Bean, Inc., The
Orvis Company, Inc., and Recreational Equipment, Inc. (REI). There are a number
of reasons why the data are well-suited to testing certain theories of price rigidity.
For instance on theoretical grounds, Sheshinski and Weiss, in their classic 1977
article on price setting, motivate their model by describing the pricing problem
facing a mail-order retailer. Similarly, the data provide a natural benchmark to
which models based on fixed timing between price changes can be compared.
Since elements of these tw o types of models are the major components of much
of the literature, a priori, one should expect the data to be informative.




2

In addition to being relevant to certain theoretical models, retail catalog data
are valuable because they can be used to: 1) track items which have been available
and unchanged for long periods of time; 2) examine both big and small ticket
items; and 3) draw inference about retail goods in general. The goods analyzed
below have a number of these desirable features. For instance, although they vary
considerably in price and potential clientele, they all can be purchased in retail
stores and for the most part are high volume items. Likewise there is a
presumption that the behavior of these prices can be extrapolated beyond just the
mail-order industry.1 Rees [1961] has shown that for these types of unchanging
items, broad movements in catalog prices closely track price movements in
conventional retail stores.2 And indeed the management of one of these
companies regularly draws up a formal list of competitors which includes many
non-mail-order firms and checks to see that their own prices are comparable to this
reference group's prices.
The goods in this study were chosen for several reasons: first, I wanted
items which are popular and representative of the goods that a firm sells; second, I
wanted high-volume goods so that an incremental price increase would produce a
non-trivial amount of revenue; third, I wanted only items that underwent minimal
quality changes.3 By considering items that are representative of the firm's
product line I can abstract from any pricing behavior that may occur when a firm is
trying to break into a new market. By studying large revenue items, I insure that
firms have incentives to carefully scrutinize the prices. Finally, by studying staple




3

items that have undergone very little quality change, I can focus on pure pricing
behavior.4 Obviously, these considerations limit the number of goods that can be
studied and the types of questions that can be analyzed.
Another potential drawback of the data is that by their very nature, prices
advertised in catalogs might be suspected of being artificially rigid. Indeed, to be
useful the prices appearing any given catalog must be applicable over some non­
trivial time horizon. Of course, this does not mean that the same nominal price
must be operative at all times; it would be straightforward to index the prices in
the catalog. As a practical matter, however, index prices are rarely used, at least
in the U.S. Thus a key issue is how much is lost by studying the flexibility of
these prices, which necessarily have to be posted for non-trivial periods of time.
All three of the companies in this study fix their prices for six month
intervals. One interesting question that I do not study is why the companies
choose this particular interval over which to quote fixed nominal prices.
Nevertheless, as a result of this choice, only tw o price changes per year that could
be observed using these data. Recent evidence presented by Blinder [1991]
suggests that a built-in rigidity of this form may not be as serious a problem as
might first be expected. Blinder finds that 55% of the firms he surveyed change
prices either once or not at all year during a typical year. So during "normal"
periods the catalog prices are not obviously more rigid than other prices.
Furthermore, given that firms have the option of resetting the nominal price
twice a year, there is presumably information implicit in the decision not to reset




4

the price. Since I find that for all the items in this study there are sometimes long
spells, say longer than 4 years, of fixed nominal prices, I do not believe that the
marketing considerations that seem to prevent very high frequency price revisions
render these prices uninteresting-particularly for students of business cycles. Of
course there are a number of other issues regarding seasonal pricing that are
masked--see Barsky and Warner [1990] for recent work in this area.
In my view, a more serious concern about these data is that in these type of
retail markets, prices are effectively the sole determinant of allocations.5 Most of
the existing empirical work on prices focuses on intermediate goods transactions
between buyers and sellers who have long-term relationships. Carlton [1986], in a
careful study of such transactions, shows that these prices are quite sticky. As he
points out, however, this need not imply any inefficiency because, in this situation,
price is only one of the instruments which can be used to allocate goods. Blinder's
[1991] survey results reinforce the view that this flexibility is important: survey
participants often cite the ability to vary the non-price attributes of a good as a
reason for price rigidity. Since most of the goods in my sample are quite popular,
and have been carried by the companies for a long time, stock-outs are uncommon
and delivery lags are not too variable. This line of argument suggests that prices
may have to do more of the work in adjusting to clear these markets than in other
situations. In this case, one might suspect that these prices might be more flexible
than the prices involved in many other transactions.
On balance, it seems fair to conclude that although these prices are not




5

ideal for studying all issues concerning rigidity, they should be relatively'
informative for many important questions.
II Data Collection and Description
Given the general goals for choosing the types of items to be analyzed, there
were several additional conventions that I adopted in the process of collecting the
prices. The prices were assembled by directly copying prices from old catalogs. I
collected the information from Bean and Orvis, while the REI data were processed
by a member of their staff.
As mentioned above, although these companies issue many catalogs per
year, the prices advertised in the Spring and Fall catalogs for each company
effectively cover the next six months.6 One major convention is to use the last
advertised price for an item if it does not appear in a particular catalog. This is
sensible because all three companies will sell an item at its last advertised price if it
does not appear in the current catalog. The majority of the items studied appear in
both the Spring and Fall catalogs each year, so that this issue is somewhat
academic.7 However, the Orvis fishing items are often advertised only in the
Spring catalog. Accordingly, the duration between price changes for these items
must be interpreted appropriately.
A second caveat is that the prices discussed below refer only to the list
prices in the standard catalogs for one unit of an item. Hence, I ignore the very
slight discounts for bulk purchases which have been offered occasionally by each
of the companies. I also ignore sale prices which may have been available for very




6

short periods. Each of the companies from time to time offers discounts if an item
is over-stocked or a particular model is being discontinued. Similarly, each of these
firms operate retail outlets where the goods in the catalogs can be purchased in
person at the catalog prices.8 Again, the retail outlets sometimes offer short-lived
sales that are not available to catalog customers. For the items in this study, sales
are very infrequent.
In using only stated catalog prices I am also ignoring any postage and
handling charges. This can be justified for at least three reasons. First, all Bean
prices include these charges and the Bean prices can be used to establish
essentially all of the claims made below. Second, the Orvis and REI prices also
apply for goods bought through their retail stores and as such, do represent
transaction prices for some customers. Lastly, Bean management reports that
numerous customer surveys have indicated that most customers are insensitive to
shipping charges. Again, this last claim would be interesting to document and
study for its own sake, but it is beyond the scope of this paper.
REI is a consumer cooperative, so once per year REI members are given
rebates for purchases made in the preceding year. The last implication of using
stated catalog prices in our calculations is that I ignore any rebates that members
may subsequently receive for buying through REI.
Finally, I limit my analysis to the post-Korean war period. Many of the items
did not exist prior to 1953. But for some of the items early data are available. I
exclude them here because of the price controls and rationing that prevailed during




7

the Korean War and World War Two. In many cases, goods completely
disappeared from the market. In other cases, quantities were limited and often
only available if the buyer had a ration coupon.
Turning to the actual products, I study five items from Bean--a more
complete description is given in the appendix of my 1990 working paper. Together
these items cover Bean's traditional product areas: footwear, clothing, hunting and
fishing gear and hand-sewn canvas and leather specialty items. More specifically I
study the prices for tw o shoes, a shirt, a blanket and a duffel bag. Of the tw o
shoes, one is a moccasin and the other a hunting boot. The shirt is a cotton
"chamois" shirt. The duffel bag is made from canvas and the blanket is made of
wool. Bean manufactures the duffel bag and the shoes. The chamois shirts are
contracted out and the manufacturer changes from time to time. The blanket is a
Hudson's Bay Blanket that Bean imports from England. All of these items are
studied over the entire 1953-1987 period.
The items I track from Orvis reflect the fact that it began as a fishing tackle
supplier and has expanded over the last 25 years to now offer a wider variety of
products. The earliest Orvis items are a bamboo fly rod and a fly. Both are
individually made, although the fly-tying is contracted out and the bamboo rods are
made in-house by Orvis craftsmen. The popularity of the bamboo rod declined
with the invention of graphite, and the rod was discontinued in 1985. The fly is
available over the entire 1953-1987 period. I also analyze a poplin fishing hat that
Orvis has sold since 1963.




8

The non-fishing items have a shorter lifetime. The hunting item that I follow is
a pair of binoculars which Orvis sold from 1966 until 1986. After 1986 the case
for these binoculars was changed, so I dropped the item. The binoculars are made
for Orvis in West Germany. The last two Orvis items were selected because of
their comparability with Bean goods. I track the Orvis chamois shirt, which the
company introduced in 1974 and the Hudson's Bay Blanket during the twelve
years that Orvis carried it. The Orvis and Bean chamois shirts are close substitutes
for each other and the Hudson's Bay Blanket that the two companies offered were
identical.
The data from REI were restricted by the availability of past catalogs.
Complete catalogs prior to 1969 were not available. Given that I was limited to
less than 20 years of data I chose to use only one REI item: the REI chamois shirt.
This shirt is manufactured for REI and is very similar to the Bean and Orvis shirts.
Ill NOMINAL PRICE CHARACTERISTICS
I

begin with an examination of the frequency of price changes. Table 1

introduces the mnemonics used throughout the remainder of the paper and
presents the first basic finding: that nominal prices typically stay fixed for periods
of longer than one year. As mentioned in the last section, it is the nature of the
catalog business that prices listed in a catalog do not expire immediately. But
there is no a priori reason why price schedules could not be included in the
catalogs. In principle, the schedule could depend on time or more exotic factors
such as the consumer price index. Similarly, the companies could issue catalogs




9

with prices that expired more frequently (say every three months). However, given
conventions followed by these firms, this fact should be interpreted as saying that
over half the time when the firms consider adjusting their price they choose to
leave it alone; more often than not the firms prefer not to adjust their current price.
Turning to specific entries in Table 1 it is important to remember that the
Orvis Fishing Hat and Light Cahill Fly are often only advertised once per year. Note
also that the statistics on the time between price changes were calculated using
the conservative assumption that all prices prevailing in Fall 1987 would change in
the Spring 1988. Even so the average time between price changes is about 15
months.
The last four columns in the Table provide further information on the
duration of long spells. These columns reveal that none of the items had their
longest spell during the mid- to late-1970's. This is the first of many indicators
that will show that during times of higher inflation long spells of constant prices
are less common. The table shows that long spells have not disappeared. Periods
of more than 2 years of unchanging prices still occur.
With the information on durations in hand, I now turn to analyzing the size
of the price changes. The tw o panels in Figure 1 give a variety of statistics
concerning the size of price changes. For each item, the top panel shows the
average (absolute) size of the price changes. The lower panel provides information
on the distribution of the size of the changes. For example, for the Orvis
binoculars roughly five percent of the changes were less than one percent in




10

magnitude, while roughly 14 percent were between one and tw o percent and
another 14 percent were between tw o and three percent. Thus about one third of
all of the changes were less than three percent in magnitude. Nevertheless, about
one fifth of the changes for the Orvis binoculars were more than 15 percent in
magnitude.
Overall the heterogeneity in the size of the changes, both across time and
items, is striking. As the top portion of the Figure shows, the mean change for
each of the various items is between 4 and 18 percent, with the average over all
items being about 9 percent. However, as the bottom panel shows there also tend
to be both large and small changes for the same item at different times. Price
changes of less than a dollar for a thirty dollar item are quite common, yet as Table
1 shows this same type of item would be prone to spells of no change at all for
periods exceeding a year. Conversely, prices also regularly change by more than
15 percent between periods.
To further investigate the nature of the changes, I next study the extent to
which changes across items are synchronized. Figure 2 shows the timing of price
changes. Each symbol in the figure marks the periods when a price changed. The
figure highlights the fact that price changes were much more frequent from the
late sixties to early eighties; during periods of higher average inflation, price
changes were more common.
The figure also supports the evidence in Table 1 that as inflation has
subsided during the mid-eighties, the frequency of price changes has slowed as




11

well. A t this point, it is too early to tell whether prices before and after the
seventies are equally rigid. The figure also suggests that the timing of price
changes across items is not particularly highly synchronized. Formalizing this
impression is a bit difficult: Given the discrete nature of changes, standard
correlation statistics are uninformative. Accordingly, I use a measure of
association described by Fleiss ([1973] pp. 42-43) that accounts for this
discontinuity. Intuitively, this association measure is derived by checking whether
changes and non-changes for one series are sufficiently aligned with changes and
non-changes for the second series so as to reject the hypothesis that the tw o sets
of change series are independent. Therefore, in addition to providing a measure of
association that is scaled between -1 and 1, the statistic also facilitates testing
whether price changes for any pair of series are independent. I view lack of
independence as a very weak benchmark since with semi-annual data I would
expect business cycle factors to induce some common movements across most
items.
Surprisingly, using the changes of the raw semi-annual data it is not possible
to reject the hypothesis of independence among most of the series-only 12 of the
66 potential pairwise comparisons were sufficiently correlated so that the
hypothesis of independence could be rejected. (To save space these results are
omitted). One possible explanation for this finding may be that changes are indeed
synchronized but not contemporaneously timed; for instance, changes for similar
items may regularly occur within a year but not coincide exactly. Moreover, for




12

some of the more seasonal goods comparisons using semi-annual data may be
slightly misleading. To investigate these suspicions, I annualized the data so that
changes that occur within the same year will be treated as identical (i.e., if any
price change occurred within a given year, the observation for the year is coded as
a one, otherwise it is coded as zero.) Since there are tw o ways to group adjacent
Fall and Spring seasons, I used tw o different definitions of a year: one
corresponding to the standard calendar year, the other corresponding to the
fashion cycle that runs from Fall of one year through the Spring of the following
year.
Table 2 reports the correlations, with the entries above the diagonal
corresponding to the fashion year calculations and entries below the diagonal
pertaining to calendar years. Cases where the hypothesis of independence can be
rejected are highlighted with boldfaced-type. Even with these annualized data,
where the importance on common macroeconomic shocks for price changes should
be magnified, there is surprisingly little correlation between most of the goods;
depending on the convention used to group the observations, there are either 6 or
9 significant associations between the 66 pairwise comparisons.
In some cases, the short length of the sample and the associated lack of
precision may be responsible for the insignificance of the correlations. However,
the lack of synchronization is evident for many of the items where synchronization
might have been most expected. (The correlations among the items that one
might naturally group together are highlighted by boxes in the table.) For example,




13

one cannot reject the hypothesis that the price changes for the identical blankets
being sold by Orvis and Bean are independent. The same conclusion follows for
the associations among the three chamois shirts and for the connections between
the fishing gear. Collectively, these results suggest that there is very little
synchronization between the price changes across items.
At this point I have established the three basic facts mentioned in the
introduction: that prices are adjusted infrequently, by differing amounts, and
although prices are more likely to change during periods of high overall inflation,
the synchronization of changes across goods is generally low. These findings
should not be surprising since they are implicit in the only other empirical work
using U.S. data, Cecchetti [1985,86]~although Cecchetti did not emphasize the
presence of many small changes.9 His results are for magazine newsstand prices,
which some skeptics have argued may be atypical because subscriptions and
advertising, not newsstand sales, produce the majority of magazine revenue and
magazines on the whole are a small ticket item. My data are immune to these
criticisms and reaffirm Cecchetti's findings.
IV Interpreting the Facts in Light of Existing Models
I now relate these basic findings to the standard models of price-setting.
One difficulty in the exercise is that there is no consensus, baseline model from
which to start; in contrast to say the consumption literature, where the permanentincome/life-cycle model is generally accepted as a benchmark, there is no widely
accepted canonical model of dynamic price-setting in a uncertain environment.




14

Thus, the embryonic state of the theory concerning price rigidity forces me to
consider a host of models rather than intensively testing a specific model.
In some cases, these models are sufficiently well-developed that they
contain parameters which could in principle be estimated using the catalog data.
However, in these cases the models could almost always be rejected without the
need for any estimation. Accordingly, I have expanded the set of theories under
consideration to include some explanations for price rigidity which are not wellenough specified to cleanly formalize. This choice means that it is not possible to
proceed with a complete set of tight hypothesis tests. While this is an uneasy
compromise, I view it as the only productive approach, since it would serve little
purpose to focus exclusively on the glaring empirical deficiencies in the few models
that are tractable enough to rigorously analyze.
A short-hand description of the collection of theories I consider is given in
Table 3. As a starting point, it is useful to make a distinction between theories
explicitly aimed at explaining nominal price rigidity and theories which apply to real
price rigidity.

As McCallum [1986] and Ball and Romer [1990] emphasize, many

commonly cited reasons for rigidity in fact apply to real price rigidity rather than
nominal price rigidity. As a crude rule of thumb, the tw o types of theories can be
distinguished by those which can and cannot explain why prices are not indexed.
However, as Ball and Romer [1990] demonstrate, if there is rigidity in real prices,
then only a small amount of nominal rigidity may be needed for the nominal
sluggishness to be important. Thus while much of my discussion will focus on




15

nominal rigidity, there are goods reasons to also consider models of real rigidities.
The theories that clearly apply to nominal rigidity generally posit a direct cost
to changing prices-thereby making indexing prohibitively expensive. One issue
highlighted by these catalog data is the difficulty of identifying the costs which
inhibit adjustment. For instance, since the catalog layouts are typically redesigned
between seasons, there would appear to be no additional costs to changing the
prices each season; similarly, the key decision makers at each company claim to
review their prices at least every season, so that the fixed cost of reviewing the
prices is incurred each period. Moreover, even if these reviewing costs were
significant and not borne every six months, it would still be difficult to explain why
price-setters do not adopt an indexing strategy as a rule of thumb. I see no a priori
reason why the firms could not find some sort of price index for each item and
make the default price change from period to period be linked to that index.
Apparently, this hypothetical alternative pricing strategy is dominated by a strategy
that calls for absolutely no indexing.
One potential resolution to these puzzles is given by Mankiw [1985] and
Akerlof and Yellen [1985]. These authors observe that the cost to a
monopolistically competitive firm of a slightly miss-set price is second-order. So, if
there are small relabelling or "menu" costs involved in revising prices they may be
enough to inhibit continuous adjustment of prices. While this explanation is
appealing, the difficulty of identifying these menu costs (or in Akerlof and Yellen's
terms, explaining why nominal rules of thumb dominate simple indexing schemes)




16

is still disturbing.
Nevertheless, assuming that price adjustment is indeed costly, there are two
branches of the literature that can be pursued. The first class of explanations,
which I will call target/threshold or (S,s) models, posit that a firm trades off the
costs of letting inflation erode its optimal price with the cost of changing prices.
With a fixed cost of changing prices and a predictable amount of inflation, the firm
will not adjust it nominal prices until the accumulated inflation drives the real price
below a (pre-specified) lower limit. Once the limit is crossed, the nominal price will
be reset to a higher level. Allowing for cost and demand shocks will imply that
nominal prices should be set to be keep the real price within a range that varies
over time.
The usual motivation for these type of models is that they are plausible and
sometimes even optimal (depending on the exact specification of the model);
ironically, the Sheshinski and Weiss [1977] paper, which is responsible for much of
this literature, began with a quote describing the pricing problem facing mail-order
catalog companies to motivate the usefulness of this class of models. My data
strongly contradict many of the key implications of the simpler versions of these
models.
For instance, the simplest target/threshold models operate under the
assumption that price adjustments should occur only in one direction and should all
be of the same size. These one-sided (S,s) models therefore can be trivially
rejected since about 8 percent of the price changes are decreases. A further




17

problem is the substantial differences in the sizes of the changes. A slightly more
realistic version of the model would allow for both increases and decreases but
keep the size of changes in each direction fixed. Again, such two-sided (S,s)
models can be overwhelmingly rejected due to the variations in the size of the
changes. Unfortunately, finding closed form solutions for more general
target/threshold models where both the limit prices and the return price are time
varying is very difficult.
Assuming one was going to move towards an (S,s) model with time-varying
thresholds and target points, what would it need to do to fit the data? The most
straightforward approach would be to try to approximate the data using a
sequence of (S,s) models with fixed band widths. For instance, if some periods
were characterized by mostly large price changes, while others were well-described
as having mostly small price changes, then combining models that alternated
between having a wide and narrow set of bands might work. The logic of the (S,s)
model suggests that the band width operative at any particular time should be
related to the overall expected level of inflation.
To see the intuitive link between the size of price changes implied by a
target/threshold model and the expected level of inflation, suppose that a firm had
an equilibrium policy in place that was optimal given the cost of changing prices
and the prevailing, expected inflation rate. The optimality of this policy would
imply that the firm would be indifferent between more frequent adjustments and
more time away from its instantaneously optimal price. If the underlying inflation




18

rate is expected to increase, the old price rule will no longer be optimal: holding the
previous price bands fixed, the new higher expected inflation rate will necessitate
more frequent (costly) price adjustments. In this situation the firm would always
want to readjust its trigger prices so that it increases both the expected deviation
from the optimal price and the frequency with which it must adjust prices. Hence
when expected inflation increases, the average size of its price changes should
increase (see Tsiddon [1987] for a formal argument along these lines).
This implication is investigated in Figures 3a-3c, which display both the size
and timing of the price changes. Specifically, the figures simultaneously show the
time between changes for each item and the size of any changes when they occur.
The scaling across the figures and the items is uniform so that all changes are
directly comparable; price decreases are represented by downward bars.
The data from figures suggest that the size of price changes is not very
closely tied to the overall (observed) level of inflation: changes are more frequent
during the 1970s but not systematically larger when compared to the 1950s,
1960s or late 1980s. Indeed, for most of the items, the average price change
during the 1968 to 1982 period, when CPI inflation averaged about 7.5 percent
per year, appears to be about the same as the average price increase over the
pre-1968 and post 1982 period, when average inflation was about 2.5 percent.10
Since realized inflation in the U.S. is well-approximated by a random walk (Ball and
Cecchetti [1990]), lagged inflation and expected inflation should coincide, so that
this result is another troubling for simple (S,s) models.




19

The links between the between the avetage sizes o f price changes and the
actual rate of inflation are further pursued in Table 4. The table contrasts the
average size of the price changes for each item during the 1968 to 1982 "high
inflation" period and with those from the remaining "low inflation" periods--the
comparisons are informative so longs as one accepts the premise that the expected
or core rate of inflation differed across the tw o periods. The numbers in
parentheses below each of the entries in the table represent the number of
changes included in the averages. Obviously, for the items that entered the study
in the late sixties and early seventies there is limited information available
concerning pricing patterns in a low-inflation environment. Nevertheless, the table
demonstrates that the average magnitude of the price changes between the tw o
periods is approximately equal. A formal Wilcoxon ranks test for equality of the
median change between the tw o periods confirms this claim. (I use a nonparametric test since the distribution of price changes appears to be very non­
normal.) The last column of Table 4 shows the probability that the median change
in the tw o periods is equal. For none of the items is it possible to reject the
assumption of equality at any of the usual significance levels. For the joint test
that the median change across all goods is equal in the tw o periods, I fail to reject
at the 75 percent significance level.
The lack of association between the average size of the price changes and
core inflation strongly challenges the simple, tractable versions of the (S,s) theory.
The most obvious challenge will be to explain the interspersing of the large and




20

small price changes that occur even during periods of high inflation. There are
several ways that this might be handled within the context of more complicated
(S,s) models.
One possibility is to assume that demand conditions shift to make the
desired band width narrower, so that an immediate small price change has a large
benefit. I am unaware of any work that has taken this approach. However, in
principle, any shift in the demand or cost environment that periodically reduced the
desired band width could give rise to small adjustments.
Alternatively, the variations in the sizes of the price changes could be
handled by introducing a time-varying cost to changing prices. This approach
seems to be the direction in which the literature is heading. For instance, Benabou
[1990], expanding on his 1988 model, has made some progress with this type of
setup. He considers how consumers' search behavior interacts with the level of
inflation to generate endogenous fluctuations in the degree of competitiveness. In
his model, shocks which increase competition decrease price dispersion and thus
can generate a motive for small price adjustments, even at high levels of inflation.
Unfortunately, the Benabou model is sufficiently complex that it can only be
analyzed using simulations; "testing" the model does not seem possible at this
point. Hopefully, further work along these lines will yield an enhanced (S,s) model
that can fit these data.
The other leading alternatives to the target/threshold model are models
where prices are assumed to adjust at fixed intervals. Under this view, prices are




21

not continuously reset because either the necessary information is not available or
the costs of high frequency changes are prohibitive. Given that these companies
are now issuing many catalogs per year (Bean was sending out over 20 per year by
the end of the sample) it would be unrealistic to assume that prices could be
intelligently readjusted with each catalog. Even leaving aside the confusion it
would create for customers, it is probably difficult to process sales data quickly
enough to justify continually fine-tuning prices. So this model explains why prices
are posted for non-trivial periods of time. However, it does not explain why the
actual period of time between changes for the same good is so variable. From
Table 1, the large standard deviations for the number of months between price
changes present a strong challenge to the simplest timing model.
A more sophisticated timing based model would relax the assumption that all
prices for every item are revised in tandem. Presumably a natural extension would
focus on the synchronization of changes for similar items. In particular, a robust
implication of the timing model seems to be that for items where either information
(about costs or demand) or characteristics of the consumers and suppliers is
similar, price changes should be correlated. In my sample there are four natural
groupings of items where these conditions are likely to hold: the tw o identical
blankets, the three nearly identical shirts, the tw o types of leather shoes and the
three fishing items. As mentioned in the last section, it does not appear that
changes among these goods are tightly synchronized even at the annual frequency.
Only for the tw o types of shoes is it possible to reject the hypothesis that the price




22

changes are independent.
The asynchronization of the changes is even more surprising given that the
price levels for comparable items tend to be aligned. For instance, the Orvis pricesetters explicitly stated that they were matching Bean's price moves for the
Hudson Bay blankets. Figure 4 verifies this claim and also highlights the peculiar
nature of many of the price changes. Between the Spring of 1980 and the Fall of
1982, Bean's price for the Hudson Bay Blanket moved from $110 to $111 to
$112 to $131 to $132 to $145. After the Fall of 1982, the price remained at
$145 for another 18 months. The corresponding Orvis prices were $110, $110,
$131, $136, $136 and $136--the price stayed at $136 for another tw o years.
Clearly this sequence of changes will be difficult to explain using a standard timing
model.
The remaining explanations I discuss tend to be incomplete "models" for
rigidity. For instance, most of these explanations are not completely enough
developed to identify parameters that could be estimated. Similarly, many of these
explanations have a difficult time explaining why nominal rather than real prices are
slow moving. On the other hand, as Blinder [1991] points out, these explanations
are often mentioned in informal discussions about rigidity. Moreover in light of the
Ball and Romer [1990] result of the interactions between real and nominal price
rigidity, any evidence related to real price rigidity can be thought of as
complementary to the investigation of nominal rigidities.
Again, there are tw o general classes of theories. The first set are based on




23

differing assumptions regarding costs and markups. The simplest model posits
that marginal cost is flat and that markups are acyclical, so that markup pricing
generates rigid prices. A competing theory assumes that marginal cost is
increasing in output, but markups are procyclical so that prices are acyclical. (See
Rotemberg and Woodford [1991] for a survey.) Finally, a third possibility is that
prices are marked up on the basis of the historical acquisition costs, rather than the
prevailing cost of obtaining goods. Unfortunately, the bottom line is that each of
the theories implies that prices should be rigid, so to distinguish among the
theories, one must make some additional assumptions about costs or demand.
Given that I have no reliable quantitative data on costs or demand, catalog data are
not particularly well-suited to distinguishing among these theories.11
If we are willing to assume that costs are similar for the identical and nearly
identical items in the sample, the blankets and shirts, then the lack of
synchronization of price changes suggests that markups cannot be constant; if
cost movements are synchronized but price movements are not, there must be
variation in markups. This asynchronization could be explained if the firms are
slow to pass through cost changes or if markups are time-varying. Making any
further inferences to distinguish between the remaining tw o explanations would
require stronger assumptions.
The final set of explanations for price rigidity which I consider are based on
customer-market considerations. The first candidate theory, typically associated
with Okun [1981], holds that firms have implicit agreements with their customers




24

that lead the firms to moderate price increases. (Again, this theory presumably
should apply to real, rather than nominal prices.) While this theory is difficult to
test without precise data on costs and demand, there are several aspects of the
price change statistics that seem at least weakly supportive.
First, if firms were raising prices when demand increased, one might expect
more price increases in business cycle booms than in business cycle downturns.
Okun argues that firms' desire to encourage continuing relationships mitigates the
tendency to exploit surges in demand. For these data, there is no tendency for
prices to change more often during (NBER) business cycle expansions than
contractions--price changes occur about 30 percent of the time during expansions
and about 34 percent of the time during contractions.
Second, Okun talks at length about the importance of "fairness" in pricing
and why price increases which are attributable to cost increases are easier to
justify. If one assumes that cost increases are more common when inflation is
high (or can be more credibly cited as having occurred), this reasoning might
predict that price changes should increase with the level of inflation. The notion
that high inflation periods are periods of many price increases, rather than larger
price increases, is one of my basic findings. I conclude that to the extent that
these data are relevant to the Okun customer market hypothesis, they seem to
support it.
A second customer market explanation for rigidity focuses on the strategic
aspects of the pricing decision. With such a small sample of overlapping items,




25

this data set is not the best one to use in studying the "coordination failures"
hypothesis. As already mentioned, in the case of the blankets, the Orvis prices
were being set to keep them aligned with the Bean prices. However, this
description of the pricing strategy is incomplete since the gap between the tw o
prices fluctuated. Figure 5 graphs the prices of the three chamois shirts. Again
there is some support for the existence of a strategic element to the price patterns.
On the one hand, the price levels of the three shirts tend to systematically be
ranked with the Orvis shirt being most expensive and the Bean shirt being least
expensive. This pattern likely reflects a conscious marketing decision by the firms-notice also that the Orvis price for the blanket tended to systematically exceed the
Bean price. On the other hand, the timing of the price changes are not coordinated
and the gaps between the prices fluctuate. Overall, the evidence is mixed. There
is no simple strategic model that captures the price dynamics, yet there are some
clear patterns in the data. A more complete evaluation will require a larger data
set.
The final customer based explanation I consider was proposed by the pricesetters at Orvis and REI. They suggested that there are certain nominal thresholds,
price points, which firms are reluctant to exceed because doing so would lead to a
considerable loss in sales. More formally, a price point is a price where a firm
believes its marginal revenue curve is discontinuous because its customers care
about nominal magnitudes. This explanation is different from the standard kinked
demand story of price stickiness. The firm may be reluctant to exceed a threshold




26

even if there is no strong competition. For instance, for a monopolist, a price
increase from 19.95 to 20.25 might have a very different effect than an increase
from 20.50 to 20.85. The presence of a competitor is likely only to reinforce a
firm's reluctance to change a price.
There is no tight theoretical justification for this story, although it is similar in
spirit to the explanation for rigidities posited by McCallum [1986]. McCallum
suggested that the use of non-indexed prices is done for convenience. He argues
that inflation uncertainty in the U.S. has generally been low, so that the gains from
indexation would be low enough that the mere cost of continually calculating real
prices is sufficient to deter firms from indexing. The analogy here is that buyers
may use rules of thumb when searching for items and comparing prices.
McCallum's convenience argument can be used to explain why the rules would
likely be formulated using nominal prices. If firms are aware of this practice they
may set prices so as to exploit the use of the rules; if a firm know some customers
do not even consider buying a shirt that costs more than $20, then if the firm has
any discretion in setting the price it will prefer to charge $19.95 instead of
$20.05.
Having described these pricing points, the natural question is whether they
are observable and empirically significant. In the working paper version of the
paper, Kashyap [1990], I provided a number of calculations to assess this
question. The results were mixed and for brevity sake, I merely summarize the
main findings. I begin by noting that the static distribution of prices is not uniform.




27

Prices endings between 41 to 50 cents or 75 to 00 cents are much more common
than prices ending between 01 to 40 or 51 to 74. (This is a widely documented
finding, see Friedman [1967]). The bunching of price endings is also more
pronounced during low inflation periods than high inflation periods. These facts
about the static distribution, however, are irrelevant for macroeconomists unless
they have dynamic implications.
To investigate the dynamic consequences of the price points, one needs to
be more specific about how to define a price point. This is difficult since there is
clear danger of circularity in using the data to learn about the price points and then
testing the model with the same data. Ideally, one would use different data sets to
identify the price points and to study their consequences. With only one data set
and a presumption that the high and low inflation periods may differ, my options
are limited. My approach was to use very simple rules to identify the price points,
with the hope that these rules were sufficiently straightforward that it would be
clear that the results have not been rigged.
The rules on which I settled assigned thresholds every fifty cents for the low
price items (the hat and the shoe) and every dollar for the more expensive
items.12 Operationally, this meant that prices in certain ranges were considered
to be at price points. The fifty cent price range was defined as all prices which
end between 40 and 50 cents. For instance, prices of $12.45 and $4.50 would
both considered to be at a fifty cent threshold. The dollar price point encompasses
only those prices which end between 75 and 100 cents. Given these admittedly




28

ad hoc cutoffs several tests were carried out. (See Kashyap [1990] for a more
extended discussion of what follows).
First, if pricing points inhibit price changes, then they might also be
expected to affect the sizes of price increases. Specifically, if prices which are at
price points are fixed longer than other prices, then any subsequent price
adjustments might be expected to be larger than average. There was weak
evidence in this direction. On an item by basis there was a slight tendency for the
changes after price points to be larger (but not significantly so) than usual.
Collectively, across all items this pattern was also statistically significant.
A more direct test I considered was to check whether price changes that
were predicted by competitors' price movements and cost shocks were less likely
to occur when prices were near price points. To do this, I estimated the
probability of a price change given cost changes, movements in competitors prices
and an indicator of whether the firm was near a price point. The lack of reliable
cost and competitors' price information means that these results should merely be
considered suggestive.
Given these caveats, the results were reasonable. The models successfully
predict the decision to change or not roughly 70 percent of the time. The
coefficients on the cost proxies tended to be positive and marginally significant,
indicating that an increase in costs increases the likelihood of a price change.
Conversely, for seven of the eight items, the price points indicators have negative
coefficients. The cumulative increases in the price of substitute goods, over the




29

period when a firm has its own price fixed, seemed to have a mixed effect on the
likelihood of a price change--with the only significant results coming for the shirts.
However, the bottom line was that while the price points seemed to work in the
expected direction the size of the effects were insignificant.
This conclusion was partially reversed when I allowed the importance of the
price point effects to shift with the level of inflation. Specifically, I split up the
price threshold proxy so that there were separate regressors for the high and low
inflation regimes.13 The period 1968-1982 was chosen as the high inflation
period.14 The results were then somewhat more impressive: for all of the goods,
being near a price point in the low inflation period reduced the probability of a price
change, while in most cases price points were of no importance during the high
inflation period. Furthermore, the importance of the price points was much more
pronounced for the shirts, cap and fly. It appears that the designation of price
points that I used for the three $40+ items was too liberal: the data suggest that
adjacent one dollar barriers are not nearly as important for these more expensive
items.
The overall evidence on price points suggests that they may influence price
adjustment, but the results are inconclusive. With more theoretical work aimed at
describing the determination of the price points and a broader data set this
question can be explored much more carefully.
More generally, the customer market explanations do relatively well at
explaining certain aspects of the data. Unfortunately, this conclusion must be




30

tempered by the observation that the data are not particularly well-suited to testing
these hypotheses. Furthermore, aside from the price point explanation, which is
explicitly about nominal prices, these theories tend to incapable of explaining
nominal rigidities.
V CONCLUSIONS
What does on learn from this paper? The results in section 3 show that
nominal prices are rigid. Starting from first principles, this fact is difficult to
explain. Profit-maximizing firms would like to sell enough goods so that the
marginal cost of producing the last unit of a good is just equal to the marginal
revenue received from the sale of that last unit. The presence of inflation alone
makes it seem unlikely that fixing a nominal price is optimal in this situation.
Presumably the firm would want to continuously adjust its prices.
One way out of this puzzle is to assume that firms adjust some other nonprice aspect of their product. The leading possibility is that delivery lags are varied
to introduce flexibility. In the case of these standard, flagship-type catalog items,
this seems less likely than usual. But more work on the importance of delivery lags
and other non-price attributes seems to be called for.
The more standard response to evidence on nominal rigidities is that it is
unreasonable to assume prices can be continuously readjusted for free. In this
case prices can easily stay fixed. Optimizing firms will not constantly reset prices
if changing prices is costly. Of course this sidesteps an important issue: why is it
costly to change prices? Given that catalogs are reprinted every 6 months why




31

not have a rule that says prices automatically rise to cover cost increases? Even if
we do not understand the fundamental reason for these costs, we can describe
what they must look like. In other words, if the firms are behaving optimally in
light of the constraints they face, then by observing their behavior we can infer
something about these constraints.
The length of spells in these data vary considerably. Hence, the simple
restrictions that lead to fixed timing of price changes do not appear to be
important. In addition, the sizes of the price changes are quite different. In
particular, small price changes are quite common. The combination of many
periods of no change and many small changes, suggests that sometimes when
small price changes do occur, the costs of changing prices must be small (or the
benefits of the change must be large). At other times these costs must be larger
or benefits must be smaller. Models that generate price rigidity by assuming a
constant cost of changing prices in an otherwise stationary environment can not
explain these data. Subsequent work in this area should involve models where
either the costs of changing prices differ from period to period or the benefits are
time-varying.
Models where the cost of changing prices is time varying can be derived in a
number of ways. The search model proposed by Benabou [1990] seems like one
promising, albeit complicated approach. Alternatively, the price point model can be
pursued. It is too early to tell if either of these strategies will succeed in producing
a testable model that fits the data.




32

fieferfinCfig

Akerlof, G. A. and J. Yellen [1985], "Can Small Deviations from Rationality Make
Significant Differences to Economic Equilibria," American Economic Review.
75, pp. 708-720.
Ball, L. and S. G. Cecchetti [1990], "Inflation and Uncertainty as Short and Long
Horizons." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1990:1. pp. 215-245.
Ball, L. and D. Romer [1990], "Real Rigidities and the Non-Neutrality of Money",
forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies.
Barsky, R. B. and E. J. Warner [1990], "The Timing and Magnitude of Retail Store
Markdowns with Reference to Weekends, Holidays and Business Cycle
Fluctuations," unprocessed mimeo.
Benabou, R. [1988], "Search Price Setting and Inflation," Review of Economic
Studies. 55, pp. 353-376.
Benabou, R. [1990], "Inflation and Efficiency in Search Markets", unprocessed
mimeo.
Blanchard, O.J. [1983], "Wages, Prices and Inflation Stabilization," in Inflation.
Debt and Indexation, edited by R. Dornbusch and M.H. Simonsen, MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA.
Blinder, A. S. [1991], "Why are Prices Sticky? Preliminary Results from an
Interview Study," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. 81,
pp. 89-96.
Carlton, D. [1986], "The Rigidity of Prices," American Economic Review. 76, pp.
637-658.
Cecchetti, S. G. [1985], "Staggered Contracts and the Frequency of Price
Adjustment," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 100, pp. 935-959.
Cecchetti, S. G. [1986], "The Frequency of Price Adjustment: A Study of the
Newsstand Prices of Magazines," Journal of Econometrics. 31, pp.
255-274.
Danziger, L. [1987], "Inflation, Fixed Cost of Price Adjustment and the
Measurement of Relative Price Variability: Theory and Evidence," American
Economic Review. 77, pp. 704-713.




33

Friedman, L. [1967], "Psychological Pricing in the Food Industry," in Prices: Issues
in Theory. Practice and Public Policy, edited by A. Phillips and O.E.
Williamson, University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia.
Fleiss, J. L. [1973], Statistical Methods for Rates and Proportions. John Wiley and
Sons, New York.
Gordon, R. J. [1990], "What is New Keynesian Economics," Journal of Economic
Literature. 28, pp. 1115-1171.
Hogan, A and P. Schullery [1981], The Orvis Storv. The Orvis Company Inc.,
Manchester, VT.
Mankiw, N.G. [1985], "Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A
Macroeconomic Model," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 100, pp. 529-538.
McCallum, B. T. [1986], "On 'Real' and 'Sticky-Price' Theories of the usiness
Cycle", Journal of Money. Credit and Banking, vol. 18, no 4, pp. 397-414.
Montgomery, M.R. [1984], In Search of L.L.Bean. Plume Books, New York.
Okun, A. [1981], Prices and Quantities: A Macroeconomic Analysis. The Brookings
Institution, Washington D.C.
Progressive Grocer [1964], "How Much Do Customers Know About Retail Prices?,"
pp. c104-c106.
Rees, A. [1961], "Alternative Retail Price Indexes for Selected Non-Durable Goods,
1947-59," in The Price Statistics of the Federal Government: Review.
Appraisal and Recommendations, edited by G. Stigler, National Bureau of
Economic Research, New York.
Rotemberg, J. [1987], "The New Keynesian Microfoundations," in NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1987. edited by S. Fischer, MIT Press, Cambridge,
MA., pp. 69-104.
Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford [1991], "Markups and the Business Cycle," in
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991. edited by 0. Blanchard and S. Fischer,
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA., forthcoming.
Sharpe, S.A. [1987], "Price Rigidity in Imperfectly Competitive Markets: A Survey
of Theoretical Approaches," Special Studies Paper 203, Federal Reserve
Board, Washington D.C.




34

Sheshinski, E., and Y. Weiss [1977], "Inflation and Costs of Price Adjustment",
Review of Economic Studies. 44, pp. 287-303.
Sheshinski, E., A. Tishler and Y. Weiss [1981], "Inflation, Costs of Adjustment,
and Amplitude of Real Price Changes: An Empirical Analysis," in
Development in an Inflationary World. Academic Press.
Tsiddon, D. [1987], "The (Mis)Behavior of the Aggregate Price Level",
unprocessed mimeo.




35

1. The mail-order business itself is now estimated to be a 50 billion dollar
industry which is growing at ten percent per year. Thus, these prices would
be of some interest even if they only tracked overall catalog prices.
2. Specifically, he shows that a CPI based on a collection of catalog items closely
tracks the BLS CPI (as long as the goods are not undergoing big changes in quality).
3. Obviously changes in tastes can imply that the same physical good is not identical
at two different times.
4. Of course not changing quality may be endogenous decision. Implicitly we assume
that for these goods, quality changes are driven by exogenous forces.
5. The claim that orders are literally never backlogged is incorrect. But for these
items, which the companies have carried for many years, the companies have a fairly
good idea about their demand curves and stockouts are unlikely. Actual inventory
data from Orvis confirm this.
6. If an item does not appear in the Orvis Fall or Spring Catalog then they may
change the price in the first catalog in which it reappears, regardless of season.
7. If a customer uses an old catalog to place an order, all three companies fill the
order and bill the customer for the difference.
8. The equivalence between the store and catalog prices is reassuring since Orvis and
REI are expanding the number of outlets they operate and thus the percentage of total
sales accruing from catalogs is falling. At the end of my sample, mail order sales
accounted for over 80 percent of Beans and Orvis's total sales and roughly 20 percent
of REI's total sales.
9. Danziger [1987] analyzes Israeli data for Kosher salami. However, his data are not
continuously sampled through time or across sellers. Sheshinski, Tisler and Weiss
[1981] study the price of noodles and instant coffee in Israel but these prices are
regulated.




36

10. An additional visual impression that comes out of Figures 3a-3c is that during the
high inflation period the variance of the size of the changes increases for some of the
items. For instance, for the Orvis binoculars and the Bean chamois shirt, the 1970s
and early 1980s seem to be characterized by an increase in both the number of very
small and very large changes. However, across all the items where meaningful
comparisons between the two inflation regimes can be made, the standard deviation
of the price changes only rises during the high inflation period in five of the nine
cases.
11. I did uncover the following anecdotal evidence on costs in the course of talking
with the price-setters at each of the three companies. These price-setters identified
cost factors as one of many factors that they considered in making their pricing
decisions. However, their notion of "costs" requires some explanation. For fairly
generic items, the catalog company will obtain a per-unit price quote from a wholesale
vendor for an unlimited quantity of the good. This price quote would be expected to
be honored by the vender over the life of the catalog, so that the retailer would be
able to have orders for additional units filled quickly at a pre-determined price. Most
of the items in this study fit this description. For more specialized items, vendors tend
to require a minimum order size from the retailer. In some cases, the minimums are
sufficiently small that they pose no problem: a price per order of a given size will be
determined and if additional units are required then they can be purchased by the
retailer provided that the re-order is sufficiently large. In this case, the only difficulty
is the possible delivery lag that arises if re-orders are necessary. In some cases,
however, the minimum order size is sufficiently large that if the retailer stocks out,
reorders are prohibitively expensive. In these cases, the catalog company will turn
customers away. This scenario is most common for unusual items that have not
previously appeared in the catalog.
12. Some of the items were excluded because cost proxies could not be found. For
instance, no reliable producer price indices are available for bamboo and it is known
that bamboo shortages have been a key factor in shifting the price of the fly rod.
Similarly cost information is difficult to obtain for the binoculars. Since the binoculars
have always been produced by a single West German firm, I suspect that
approximating costs for this item may be particularly difficult. Finally, for the blankets
(British) labor cost data were not readily available. In the case of the blankets, we
have already see that competitive factors are very important and that the pricing point
story may not be relevant.
13. Making this type of distinction can be justified for several reasons. First,
consumer search activity, which undoubtedly influences these thresholds, is unlikely
to be constant. Pursuing the analogy with the McCallum explanation, if rules of
thumb are responsible for thresholds then rules of thumb may be abandoned during




37

periods of high inflation. Similarly, changes in the sizes of cost shocks could
undermine the importance price points. If costs grow more rapidly during periods of
high inflation, then retailers may choose to jump from price point to price point.
Finally, because prices are adjusted more frequently during periods of high inflation,
a firm might expect its competitors to be more inclined to follow a price move.
Hence, strategic considerations that reinforce being at a particular price point may be
less relevant during high inflation periods.
14. I experimented with other definitions of the high inflation period and found that
these results were robust.




38

T a b le 1
Frequency of Price Changes

Ave. Months
Between Price
Changes
6

Mnemonic

Item

Dates

LLB_Shoe

Bean
Hunting
Shoe

53:1-87:2

Bean
Camp
Moccasin

53:1-87:2

LLB_Mocc

LLB_Blnk

ORV-Blnk

I,LB_Dbag

Bean
Hudson
Bay
Blanket
Orvis
Hudson
Bay
Blanket
Bean
Zipper
Duffle
Blanket

(Std. Dev.)

Longest Spell
Overall:
Since 1980:
Number of
Changes

Dates &

Duration
(months)

Dates &

Duration
(months)

36

59:2-63:2

54

85:2-86:2

18

11.5
(1 2 .8 )

37

59:2-65:1

78

81:1-82:1

18

53:1-87:2

17.8
(15.0)

24

58:1-62:2

60

84:2-87:1

36

72:1-84:2

14.2
(1 0 .8 )

1 1

81:2-84:2

42

81:2-84:2

42

53:1-87:2

12.9
(9.6)

33

61:2-65:1

48

80:2-81:2

18

34

59:1-65:2

84

85:1-87:1

30

1 1

83:2-87:2

54

83:2-87:2 ‘ 54

1 1 . 8

(10.9)

LLB_Shrt

Bean
Chamois
Shirt

53:1-87:2

12.5
(14.2)

ORV_Shrt

Orvis
Chamois
Shirt

74:2-87:2

14.7
(14.3)

REI_Shrt

RE I
Chamois
Shirt

72:1-87:2

14.8
(19.7)

13

81:1-87:1

78

81:1-87:1

78

ORV_Hat

Orvis
Fishing
Hat

63:1-87:2

18.8
(15.0)

16

63:1-68:2

72

81:1-82:2

24

ORV_Brod

Orvis
Bamboo
Fly Rod

53:1-85:1

18.0
(14.9)

2 2

69:2-73:2

54

81:1-82:1

18

ORVJFly

Orvis
Fishing
Fly

53:1-87:2

30.4
(31.6)

14

54:1-64:2

132

'82:1-84:2

36

ORV_Binc

Orvis
7 inch
Binocs.

6 6

2 2

68:1-71:1

42

80:1-81:2

24

All

All Items




:1 -8

6 : 1

1 1 . 2

(9.1)
53:1-87:2

14.7
(15.0)

273

T a b le 2
Correlation and Tests of Independence for Annual Price Changes1 '

2

(changes are aggregated to annual frequency: correlations above the diagonal apply to years starting in the
Fall running through the Spring, correlations below the diagonal apply to standard calendar years)..

t.
t.
r

Mnemonic

Shoe

t.
t.
r
Mocc

t.
t.
r
Blnk

Orv
Blnk

t.
t.
r
Dbag

T.T.R
Shrt

Orv
Shrt

Rei_
Shrt

Orv
Hat

Orv_
Brob

Orv_
Fly

Orv_
Bine

1.0

.396

.144

.365

.215

.171

.320

-.333

.089

.325

.499

.145

LLB Mocc

.525

1.0

.090

-.228

.262

.351

.059

.048

.535

.398

.079

-.150

LLB_Blnk

. 1 2 0

.308

1.0

.158

.023

.197

-.043

.098

.033

.399

.447

-.154

OryJBlnk

. 1 0 1

.501

1.0

♦

.386

.350

-.337

.101

.675

.101

LLBJDbag

.253

.160

- . 2 0 0

-.228

1.0

.298

.204

.258

. 1 2 2

.336

LLB_Shrt

.470

.662

. 1 2 0

.539

.253

1.0

.251

.073

.115

.590

.286

-.275

Orv_Shrt

.365

.365

.025

.612

-.228

.318

1.0

.289

.251

-.194

.289

.158

Rei-Shrt

. 2 2 2

.293

.618

.675

-.228

. 2 2 2

.537

1.0

.073

-.337

.126

.048

Orv_Hat

. 0 0 0

.535

.167

. 1 0 1

.115

.306

.318

.545

1 . 0

.018

-.196

.059

Orv_Brob

.416

.495

.332

.158

. 0 2 0

.284

.241

.411

.452

1 . 0

.362

.269

Orv_Fly

.520

.224

-.007

.537

.355

.393

. 2 2 0

.126

-.196

.038

1 . 0

.066

OrvJBinc

.230 -.141

- . 1 2 2

. 1 0 1

.499

-.258

-.213

.026

.224

.206

.030

1 . 0

Orv
Blnk

T.T.R
Dbag

LLB_
Shrt

Orv_
Shrt

Orv_
Brob

Orv
Fly

LLB_
Shoe

♦

T.T.R
Mocc

T.T.R
Blnk

. 1 0 1

♦

♦

Rei_
Shrt

o as

LLB__Shoe

Orv_
Bine

1. Correlations between items whose changes are sufficiently synchronized to reject the hypothesis of
independence are indicated in bold.
2. Note that for some of the shorter series a price change occurs every year so that the correlation is
defined to be 0. Such cases are identified by +'s in the table.




Table 3

G eneric M od els/E xp lan ations fo r P r ic e R ig id it y
E x p lic it C osts o f Changing P r ic e s :
T arget/T h resh o ld " ( S , s ) " Models
i)
O n e-sid ed — f ix e d band w idth
ii)
Tw o-sided — f ix e d band w idth
i i i ) Tw o-sided — v a r ia b le band w idth
Time Dependent Models
i)
ii)

F ixed in t e r v a ls a l l goods
F ixed in t e r v a ls fo r c l o s e l y r e la t e d goods

Markup Based E x p la n a tio n s:
i)
P r ic e s are marked up over slow moving h i s t o r i c a l c o s t s
ii)
M arginal c o s t s and markups are c o n sta n t
i i i ) P r o c y c lic a l markups o f f s e t r i s i n g m arginal c o s t s
Customer Based E xp lan ation s:
i)
ii)
iii)




I m p lic it agreem ents w ith custom ers i n h i b i t gouging
C oord in ation d i f f i c u l t i e s in sy n ch ro n izin g changes
a c r o ss com peting firm s
P r ic e p o in ts : nominal r u le s o f thumb used by custom ers

T a b le 4
Average Size of Price Change by Period

Average Absolute Percentage Price Change
High
Low
Inflation
Inflation
Period
Period
Complete
(1968-1982) pre-6 8 , post-82
Sample
(# Changes)
(# Changes)
(# Changes)

Mnemonic

Item

Dates

LLB_Shoe

Bean
Hunting
Shoe

53:l-87;2

5.5
(35)

LLBJiOCC

Bean
Camp
Moccasin

53:1-87:2

5.7
(36)

53:1-87:2

LLB_Blnk

ORV-Blnk

LLB_Dbag

Bean
Hudson
Bay
Blanket
Orvis
Hudson
Bay
Blanket
Bean
Zipper
Duffle
Blanket

4.9
(2 1 )

6.4
(14)

0.18

5.4
(23)

6.4
(13)

0.72

9.0
(23)

11.9
(13)

5.4
(1 0 )

0.34

72:1-84:2

13.7
(1 0 )

13.7
(1 0 )

53:1-87:2

7.1
(32)

7.6
(15)

0.78

(17)

0.89

6 . 6

n.a.

LLB_Shrt

Bean
Chamois
Shirt

53:1-87:2

4.8
(33)

5.1
(2 2 )

4.4
(1 1 )

ORV_Shrt

Orvis
Chamois
Shirt

74:2-87:2

5.3
(13)

5.0
(9)

8 . 0

REI
Chamois
Shirt

72:1-87:2

ORV_Hat

Orvis
Fishing
Hat

ORV_Brod

RBI_Shrt

Wilcoxen
Ranks Test:
Probability of
Equal Medians

1 0 . 0

1 0 . 0

n.a.

n.a.

(1 )

1 0 . 0

n.a.

(1 2 )

(ID

63:1-87:2

17.1
(15)

18.2
(1 1 )

14.0
(4)

0.99

Orvis
Bamboo
Fly Rod

53:1-85:1

11.7
(2 1 )

13.2
(1 2 )

9.8
(9)

0.48

ORV_Fly

Orvis
Fishing
Fly

53:1-87:2

10.3
(13)

9.9
(9)

11.3
(4)

0.82

ORV_Binc

Orvis
7 inch
Binocs•

6 6

:1 -8

8.4
(2 1 )

7.6
(16)

8.5
(261)

8.4
(174)

All

All Items




6 : 1

53:1-87:2

(1 )

1 1 . 2

0.15

(5)
7.5
(87)

0.75

Figure 1A
Sizes

of Price C h a n g e s
AverageAbsolute% Change*

10
101710
15
1413.
12
11
10

2
1
0
SHOE

MOCG

BLNK

ORV
BLNK

OBAQ

SHRT

ORV
SHRT

REI
8HRT

ORV
HAT

ORV
BROD

ORV

ORV
BING

ORV
FLY

ORV
BINC
X>16

FLY

Figure 1B
Distribution

of

Price

C h a n g e s

Percam

LLB
8HOe

LLB
MOCC

LEGENO




LLB
BLNK

X<1

ORV
BLNK

UJB
OBAQ

UJB
SHRT
1<X<2

ORV
SHRT

RS
SHRT
2<X<S

ORV
HAT

ORV
BROO
3<X<1«

ALL

Figure 2

Timing of Price Changes
First Symbol Per Item Shows First Observation

X X X
X

X

x

X

X X
XX
4

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X X X
X
Orvis Fishing Hat
X

X XXX
Orvis Bamboo Fly Rod

X XX XX

AA AA AA AA AA A

A

X
Orvis Light Cahill Fly

A

A AA A A
Orvis 7-inch Binoculars
Orvis Chamois Shirt

•

• • • • • •

•

REI Chamois Shirt
•

•

•

•

•

• •• •

• • • • • •

♦

♦

• • • • • •
♦

♦ ♦♦

♦ ♦

•• •• ••
•
•
Bean Chamois Shirt
♦♦
Orvis Hudson Bay Blanket

♦♦♦♦♦♦•♦♦♦

o o

o o o o
a
o

5
2

5
3

oa a

oo
o

a

5
4

5
5




5
6

5
7

5
8

5
9

6
o

6
1

6
2

6
3

6
4

o

a o

11 1
6 6
5 6

6
7

o o o o o o o o o o o o o
oo ao a

do

6
9

1■
7
O

T im e

7
1

oo aa a
aa aa aa

oa ao

o

6
8

oa a

7
2

11 1
7 7
3 4

7
5

aa

o oa a

a ao aa

♦
♦
Bean Hudson Bay Blanket

o o o o o o o o o
Bean Zipper DuffleBag
o

o o ao a
a
Bean Camp Moccasin

a aa aa a aa aa
a
Maine Hunting Shoe




Figure 3 A

Size and Timing of Price Changes

Tlnw




Figure 3 B

Size and Timing of Price Changes

Time

Figure 3 C

Size and Timing of Price Changes
RDATNC92CS
_ -U

0-3*

0 -10*
. 0 0 =

D

o

D

□

□

D

. o

o

□

o

o

□ 0

0

o

o O q
Orvia Fishing Ha!

□ □ □

□
Orvia LightCahillFly

n
a

a

D

□

0

□

dJ

□

a

□ □ 0 Qd

ocOD

cd

Orvia Bamboo FlyRod

□

□

o

JDo-

cl

co — D D

_

D

q

0

Orvia 7-Inch Binoculars

52 53 54 55 56 57 58 50 00 61 82 83 64 86 66 67 88 09 70 71 7 2 7 3




Time

74 75 76 7 7 7 8 7 9 8 0

81 8 2 8 3 8 4 8 5 8 6 8 7 8 8




Figure 4

Hudson

Bay

Solid = Bean

B l a n k e t Prices

Dashes = Orvis

Figure 5
Chamois

Solid — Bean

Shirt P r i c e s

Dashes = Orvis

Time

Dots — REI