View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series



Seasonal Solow Residuals and
Christmas: A Case for Labor Hoarding
and Increasing Returns
R. Anton Braun and Charles L. Evans

Working Papers Series
Issues in Macroeconomics
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
October 1991 (W P -91-20)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

Seasonal Solov Residuals and Christmas:

A Case for Labor Hoarding and Increasing Returns

*
R. Anton Braun
_
,
**
Charles L. Evans

Revised October 1991

Abstract
In aggregate unadjusted data, measured Solov residuals exhibit large seasonal
variations.
Total Factor Productivity grows rapidly in the fourth quarter at
an annual rate of 24% and regresses sharply in the first quarter at an annual
rate of -30%. This paper
considers two potential explanations for the
measured seasonal variation in the Solow residual: labor hoarding and
increasing returns to scale. Using a specification that allows for no
exogenous seasonal variation in technology and a single seasonal demand shift
in the fourth quarter, we ask the following question: How much of the total
seasonal variation in the measured Solow residual can be explained by
Christmas?
The answer to this question is surprising.
With increasing
returns and time varying labor effort, Christmas is sufficient to explain the
seasonal variation in the Solow residual, consumption, average productivity
and output in all four quarters.
Our analysis of seasonally unadjusted data
uncovers important roles for labor hoarding and increasing returns which are
difficult to identify in adjusted data.

JEL Classification(s):
★

131, 023

Department of Economics
Rouss Hall
University of Virginia
Charlottesville, VA 22901
(804) 924-7845

Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
P.0. Box 834
Chicago, IL 60690-0834
(312) 322-5812

Ve thank Marty Eichenbaum, Jim Hamilton, Bob Chirinko and seminar participants
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago for helpful comments.
All opinions
expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, or the Federal Reserve System.







1.

Introduction

Prescott [1986] has argued that the variability of Solow's residual is a
reasonable estimate of the variability of exogenous technology shocks.

When

Solow's residual is measured using seasonally unadjusted data for the postwar
U.S. economy,

it exhibits large seasonal variations,

growing rapidly in the

fourth quarter at an annual rate of 24% and falling sharply in the

first

quarter at an annual rate of -30%. This paper starts from the premise that it
is implausible to attribute seasonal variation of this magnitude to changes in
the

state

of

technology.^

We

present

a

model

in

which

fluctuations arise from a single demand shift, Christmas.

all

seasonal

This demand shift

together with misspecification of the traditional production function leads to
large seasonal variation in the Solow residual.
for misspecification,
scale.

Even

when

labor hoarding

technological

growth

and
is

We consider two candidates

external

increasing

aseasonal,

either

returns

to

candidate

in

isolation can induce spurious seasonality in the Solow residual. Our general
equilibrium analysis indicates that:

(1) the economy's seasonal patterns in

all four quarters may be a response simply to a fourth quarter consumption
demand shift, and (2) a combination of labor hoarding and external increasing
returns are important for replicating these patterns
variables

for

the

postwar

U.S.

economy.

Since

in aggregate

our

analysis

quantity

identifies

important roles for labor hoarding and increasing returns, these results have
implications for nonseasonal macroeconomic models.
By focusing on seasonal fluctuations we are able to exploit information

Beaulieu
the first
Argentina
no reason




and Miron [1991] cast doubt on weather explanations by showing that
quarter is a period of negative output growth in Australia and
as well as the United States.
In the Southern Hemisphere, there is
to expect a negative technology seasonal in the first quarter.

2

that

is

typically

ignored

in empirical

macroeconomic

research,

2

This

is

important because the research strategy of selecting a macroeconomic theory
based upon its ability to match certain statistical moments
adjusted data
example,

often

fails

to discriminate

Murphy-Shleifer-Vishny

[1989]

among competing

in seasonally
theories.

survey the many similarities between

technology shock-driven and increasing returns equilibrium theories.
seasonality,

For

Ignoring

they conclude that both theories can be modified in plausible

ways to generate the same implications for aggregate quantity variables.

In a

similar vein, Cooper and Haltiwanger [1989] conclude that production bunching
may

arise

due

to

either

nonconvexities

in production

or

the

arrival

of

3
technology

shocks

in

bunches.

The

literature

on

procyclical productivity also produces mixed results.

labor

hoarding

and

Rotemberg and Summers

[1990] show that the combination of labor hoarding and price inflexibility can
generate procyclical total factor productivity without appealing to technology
shocks. On the other hand, Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo [1990] find that
labor hoarding, price flexibility, and relatively small exogenous technology
shocks can generate procyclical total factor productivity.
The principal difficulty in selecting one theory, of course, is that each
school of thought interprets the postwar period as being dominated by either
supply shocks

(RBC)

or demand shocks

(Keynesian labor hoarding,

increasing

2
Other researchers have noted this also.
Barsky and Miron [1989] argue that
the seasonal cycle facts for the U.S. contain information for evaluating
alternative macroeconomic theories.
Ghysels [1991] disputes the claim that
the seasonal cycle is like the business cycle, but agrees that seasonally
unadjusted data contain useful information for identifying propagation
mechanisms.
3
Evidence favoring increasing returns is uncovered by Hall [1989], Ramey
[1991], and Caballero and Lyons [1990]. Their conclusions rely on the assumed
exogeneity of their instruments, which is controversial.
Further evidence of
increasing returns which does not rely on these instruments would strengthen
their case.
Chirinko [1991] concludes that increasing returns is more
important than either labor hoarding or technology shocks.




3

returns)-- but not both.

If economists could identify demand shocks, however,

the predicted countercyclical response of labor productivity in RBC models
could

be

compared

with

the

predicted

returns and labor hoarding theories.
is difficult

procyclical

response

in

increasing

Needless to say, such an identification

to achieve unambiguously

in postwar

seasonally

adjusted

time

series data.
Seasonal

fluctuations

offer

valuable

identifying

restrictions.

For

instance, few economists would dispute that Christmas is an important seasonal
event which produces
fourth quarter.

an

increased demand

On the other hand,

seasonal shifters of technology.
seasonal
finding

impulse
that

is weakened

seasonal

patterns in the U.S.
and

that

Christmas

for

it is difficult

in

by

Southern

Beaulieu
Hemisphere

[1990]

in the

identify bonafide

and

Miron's

countries

[1991]

resemble

Together our assumptions that technology is aseasonal
is

an

important

shift

in

demand

restrictions that have strong discriminatory power.
Evans

to

services

The contention that weather is an important

considerably

patterns

consumption

4

provide

identifying

For instance, Braun and

find that seasonal Real Business Cycle models predict totally

aseasonal patterns in output under these identifying assumptions.
transient and anticipated nature of Christmas,

households

Due to the

simply draw down

their savings and increase consumption by equal amounts in the fourth quarter
leaving the level of output unchanged.

RBC models require implausibly large

seasonal variations in technology to explain the seasonal pattern in output.
Thus,

our

identifying

assumptions

offer

strong

explanation for the seasonal pattern in output.

4

evidence

against

one

In this paper we demonstrate4

Our use of seasonal identifying restrictions is similar to Bernanke and
Parkinson's analysis.
Using interwar data, Bernanke and Parkinson [1991]
investigate procyclical productivity in industrial markets.
Under the
plausible identifying assumption that the Great Depression was not caused by a
series of large technology shocks, they find evidence in favor of increasing
returns and labor hoarding.




4

that labor hoarding in conjuction with increasing returns can generate many of
the observed patterns in output, consumption, and the measured Solow residual.
Modeling

seasonal

fluctuations

with

a

single

Christmas

demand

shift

requires us to model economic agents' responses to anticipated and transitory
impulses.

First, the anticipated nature of the Christmas seasonal shift leads

us to model variations in labor effort as driven by convex costs of adjusting
employment.

Burnside, Eichenbaum and Rebelo

[1990] model labor hoarding by

assuming that employment is fixed at the beginning of the period and only
labor effort can respond within a period to shocks.
effort

responds

persistence."*

only
To

to

induce

unanticipated
seasonal

shocks,

In their framework labor
exhibiting

labor hoarding,

quasi-fixed factors must be modeled explicitly.

the

costs

no
of

noticeable
adjusting

Second, the transitory nature

of seasonal shifts leads us to consider convex costs of adjusting capital.

In

an economy with external increasing returns, Baxter and King [1990] found a
negligible response of output to a purely transitory increase in consumption
demand:

consumption rose but investment fell,

leaving output unchanged.

In

the absence of adjustment costs, a similar result is to be expected for the
case of a fourth quarter Christmas seasonal.

If increasing returns is to have

a chance, it must be costly to adjust investment. Third, the nontime-separable
preferences emphasized by Kydland and Prescott [1982], Eichenbaum, Hansen, and
Singleton

[1988],

and others

for business

cycle variability

also play

an

important role in propagating the Christmas demand shock beyond simply the
fourth quarter.

Thus, modeling seasonal fluctuations leads to a specification

that incorporates the same propagation mechanisms that receive wide attention
in models of the business cycle.

In Burnside-Eichenbaum-Rebelo [1990], the impulse response functions of labor
effort to innovations in technology and government purchases appear to be zero
after the initial period's response.




5

Many of the model's parameters governing returns to scale, the magnitude
of adjustment costs and elasticities for work effort are difficult to pin down
on

a

priori

grounds.

A

Generalized

Method

of

Moments

(GMM)

estimation

strategy is used to produce estimates of these parameters. These estimates are
then used to evaluate the seasonal growth rates implied by the model. We find
that both labor hoarding and increasing returns mechanisms are important for
capturing the U.S.
variables

in

the

economy's seasonal fluctuations.
model,

the

hypothesis

that

For each of the real
the

predicted

fluctuations match the data's seasonals cannot be rejected.

seasonal

The estimated

parameterization proves to be remarkably successful at capturing the seasonal
pattern in the measured Solow residual as well as the seasonal pattern in
output, consumption, and
suggest

further

that

average productivity.

labor

hoarding

and

Results reported in section 4

nontime-separabilities

biggest role in propagating the Christmas demand shock.

play

the

Increasing returns

prove to be important for amplifying the seasonal patterns generated by the
other features of the model.
Finally, this model also offers an explanation for the similar seasonal
patterns across countries which Beaulieu and Miron
Christmas-like

celebrations

induce

fourth

quarter

[1991]

have documented.

preference

shifts

consumption demand in many Northern and Southern Hemisphere countries.
extent

that

increasing

returns

to

scale

and

labor hoarding

are

in

To the

important

features of these other economies as well, then our model predicts a seasonal
pattern similar to that found in the U.S.
An outline of the remainder of the paper follows. In section 2 the model
is

described and the seasonal equilibrium

growth path is defined. Section 3

contains a description of the data, the estimation strategy and a summary of
the estimation results. Section 4 evaluates the seasonal implications of the
estimated parameterization and explores the role of the various components of




6

th e

m o d e l.

I n

s e c t io n

5

w e

2.

c o n c lu d e

b y

s u m m a r iz in g

o u r

r e s u lt s .

The Economic Model

In this section we describe the model economy. The presentation of the
economy

leads naturally

competitive equilibrium

to an optimization problem whose
allocation.

to a productive externality.
take account of

solution

is

the

This solution is not Pareto optimal due

As we pose the problem,

the planner does not

the externality. A benevolent social planner could do better

by allowing agents to coordinate. This strategy for calculating competitive
allocations in distorted economies is discussed at length in Romer[1988].

Preferences
The household's period preferences depend upon consumption services c^,
leisure services 1^, and (negatively upon) the intensity of labor effort v .
The period utility function is:
rt log c*
where r

+

a log 1*

-

( v t - v )2

is a seasonal preference shifter.

,

£ > 0, a > 0

[1]

The preference shifter captures

the household's increased desire to consume during the Christmas season:
rt *
where

\

' Q lt + 7 Q 2t + 7 Q3t + '4 Q4 f

> 7 > 0

121

is a quarterly seasonal dummy variable taking on the value of 1 when

period t corresponds to season i and zero otherwise.

Consumption and leisure

services are defined as follows:
•fa

ct -

1* where

cpt + a cpt l ,

T - nt + b ( T -

cpt

allocation.

are

consumption

Ia 1 < 1

nt l

)

|b | < 1

,

expenditures

and

T

[3]

[4 ]

represents

the

total

time

If a > 0 consumption expenditures have a durable quality and are

substitutable across adjacent periods.

If a < 0 consumption expenditures are

complements across adjacent periods, and consumption preferences exhibit habit




7

p e r s is t e n c e .

T he

sam e

in t e r p r e t a t io n s

h o ld

fo r

b

an d

le is u r e

The interpretation of labor effort in the period utility function depends
upon the value of v.

If v>0, v is a bliss point for labor effort.

case, deviations from v provide disutility for the household.
interpreted as

a normal

level

of

labor

effort:

workers

In this

Here v can be

view periods

of

inactivity on the job with the same dissatisfaction as comparable periods of
overactivity.

If v<0, labor effort provides increasing disutility.

In this

case, less work effort is strictly preferred to more.

Production
The representative household has access to a technology which produces
goods (y) using capital (k), labor hours (n), and labor intensity (v):
0 < $ < 1
zt -

z

t

l

[5]

exp( A + ct )

[6]

4t “ *1 < V Zt / 2 ’ *1* *2 > 0
>
Aside from the choice of factor inputs k, n, and v, the level of production is
influenced by three additional factors:

exogenous variation in the state of

technology z^, a productive externality 0 , and convex adjustment costs J
capital and labor (with the specification described below).

on

Each of these

factors will now be discussed separately.
The technology variable z^ is a random walk process in logarithms with
constant drift A.
random variable.
noteworthy.

The impulse

is an independent,

serially uncorrelated

Three observations on the role of z^ in our analysis are

First,

the constant drift term A is nonseasonal-- this is our

identifying restriction that the true technology is aseasonal.
growth

in this economy originates with

z^ since

our

Second,

all

specification of

the

productive externality exhibits local increasing returns
In the balanced growth equilibrium that we analyze,




8

(discussed below).

therefore,

all trending

p r e

variables share the same trend as zf .
c
role

in our analysis

of perfect

Third, the variability of c

foresight seasonal

growth paths,

plays no
but

its

presence satisfies a necessary condition for our econometric relationships to
be well-posed in Section 3.
Increasing

returns

externality variable
capita output.
Murphy,

production

where y

are

captured

by

Marshallian

represents the economy-wide level of per

Shleifer, and Vishny [1989], Caballero and Lyons

influence

the

Marshallian productive externalities have been considered by

and King [1990],
to

in

[1990],

and Baxter

In our framework, the representative household is too small

the

economy-wide

household's control.

output,

so

^

is

taken

to

be

beyond

the

Since the externality is expressed relative to the level

of technology z^, this specification embodies local increasing returns--

as

aggregate economic activity rises relative to trend, the economy becomes more
productive.^
The variable

is a factor which

relates

to

the

cost

of

adjusting

capital and labor hours in terms of lost output:

kt+i - k texp(A+et) \2
exp
{
where ^

-

and ^

)2 -

M

4

-

(

^

[8 ]

n

are positive, and A is the average growth rate of capital as

well as the technology z^. The first term states that it is costly to increase
the capital stock at a rate other than its growth rate.

^Alternatively,

if z

The firm has in place

were deleted from the specification of

in [7], the

externality would grow with economy-wide output, and this would be global
increasing returns. Given our econometric methodology in Section 3, these two
specifications are observationally equivalent. Specifically, for local IR all
growth is exogenous; whereas for global IR the exogenous growth is magnified
by the
process so that some growth is endogenous.
In the global case,
there is a lower value of X which interacts with the same value of ^

as

the local case to produce the same equilibrium as we report in Section 4.
Applying our estimation procedure to the global case would produce this lower
value of A.



9

a technology for assimilating new capital into the production process. This
technology costlessly accepts the normal level of new investment, but other
levels create congestion in the production process.

Likewise, the second term

states that it is costly to increase labor hours at a rate other than its
unconditional

growth

rate,

adjustment cost factor

which

is

zero.

For

this

specification,

the

is in the interval (0,1] and in a nonseasonal steady

state J^-l.^

Period Budget Constraint
The household's period budget constraint is given by:

k t ^ t V V 1 ** J t “ cp t + kt + i * a ' 6) kt

[9]

where S is the rate of capital depreciation per quarter.
be

introduced

into

the

model

and

constraint

[9]

(as

Fiscal policy could
in

Braun

and

Evans

[1991]), but our focus in this paper is the single demand seasonal Christmas
since that is a relative constant across countries.

Planner's Problem
The competitive equilibrium allocations

in a decentralized version of

this

economy are identical to the solution of the following optimization
g
problem.
At time 0, choose a sequence of contingencies { cpt , n^, v , k
t^O } to solve the following:

Due to the inclusion of the growth term in J^, the nonseasonal steady state
of this economy will be the same as an economy which omits adjustment costs.
Besides being plausible, the growth term allows greater comparability with
previous studies.

g
This is a solution strategy previously employed by Romer [1986].




10

max E0£

^t|rtlog(cpt+acpt l ) + alog(T-nt+b(T-nt l )) - |-(vt-v)2
-

t-0

+

where
are

• cpc • V i

] }

+

i9
10i

is a Lagrange multiplier, and the initial values k^, cp
given.

treating

Notice

that

as given:

the

planner

ignores

the

allocations

externality,

while this is suboptimal, it is the analagous problem

to the one faced by small households and firms.
optimal

productive

and n ^

which

solve this

problem

It is well-known that the
are characterized

by

the

first-order conditions for cpt , nt> v , kt+^, and a transversality condition
related to capital (for an example, see Braun and

Evans [1991]).

Furthermore,

assets can be pricedusing intertemporal marginal

rates of substitution in the

usual way.

4

Perfect Foresight Seasonal Equilibrium Growth Path
This

economy

grows

over

time

at

the

progress which is given by A per period.
calendar year, however,
foresight

seasonal

rate

of exogenous

technological

Since preferences shift over the

these growth rates may vary seasonally.

equilibrium growth

path

for this

A perfect

economy

is

a

9

generalization of the standard definition of

a balanced growth path.

The

relevant new feature is that the seasonal growth path is indexed by season.
Thus, consumption in year t and quarter i is linked to consumption in year t+1
quarter

i by

the

following

relationship:

ct+i i “

4A
e ct i*

Along

the

seasonal growth path, consumption will always grow x^% in the winter, Xj% in

9
For example, see King, Plosser, and Rebelo [1988] for a standard definition
of a balanced growth path.




11

th e

s p r in g ,

x^%

in

th e

su m m er,

an d

x^%

in

th e

f a l l . ^

Seasonality 1b Measured golow Res,iduals
Suppose that a researcher attempts to measure Solow residuals for this
economy as Prescott [1986] does.

Armed with the precise knowledge of 0, the

measured Solow residual will b e : ^
St ■ [ A lo g yt - 0 A log kt - (1-0) A log nt ] / (1-0)
- [ (l-0 -^2)
Assuming that

A l o 8

zt +

^ 2

Alog yt *

the deterministic

Alog v t + Alog Jt ^ / C1**)

component of technological

aseasonal, then seasonality in S^ can arise from:
output is seasonal,
seasonal,

[11]

growth

(z^)

is

(1 ) increasing returns if

(2 ) labor hoarding if variations

in labor effort are

and (3) seasonal adjustments in capital and labor hours.

If the

fourth quarter increased desire to consume is strong enough to generate a
seasonal increase in fourth quarter output, then measured Solow residuals will
be proseasonal due to the productive externality.
achieved by a seasonal

increase

in work effort

If the higher output is
(without

a correspondingly

large increase in adjustment costs), then the demand effect is reinforced.
Whether

or

not

a

single

Christmas

seasonal

in

preferences

can

12

explain

seasonality in Solow residuals, in all four quarters, depends upon the model's
ability to generate seasonality in output and labor effort across the entire
calendar year.*
2
1

^ F o r an explicit characterization of this type of seasonal equilibrium path,
see Braun and Evans or Chatterjee and Ravikumar [1989].
X1Ve assume that S^ is an attempt to measure Alog z^ rather than (l-0)Alog z^.

12

Evans [1991] documents that Prescott's measure of the Solow residual is not
exogenous when seasonally adjusted data is used.
The finding that money,
interest rates, and government spending Granger-cause Prescott's residual
could be due to increasing returns or unobserved variations in labor effort of
the form modeled here.




12

3.

Econometric Estimation of the Model's Structural Parameters

The vector of structural parameters $ contains 16 elements:
* - ( 6, 0, T, r, r4 , a, a, b, £, v, 6,

A,

).

In assigning parameter values, there are three categories of parameters:
parameters which can be normalized a priori because
influence upon the analysis;

(2 ) parameters which

their values
are

parameters
Moments.
Since

which
First,

utility

are

econometrically

the parameters

is

ordinal,

we

estimated

(a, T,

a«l

and

estimate

whose

level

and
Method

a

(3)
of

the

consumption

The time allocation is set to T-1369 hours

per quarter (as in Christiano and Eichenbaum [1991]).
index variable

Generalized

set

v) are inherently unidentified.

normalize

preference parameters r and r^.

by

have no

customarily

priori because their values are not well-identified in the data;

(1)

depends

upon v:

we

guarantees that average labor effort will be 1.

13

Labor effort v

set v

at

a

level

is an
which

The parameter < simply
f
>^

defines the units of measure for commodities (thousands of dollars, billions
of yen,

etc.):

analysis.

its value can be selected arbitrarily without affecting the

Second, the discount factor 0 is not well-identified in aggregate

time series data.

We set 0 equal to 1.03

- 25

as in Christiano and Eichenbaum.

Third, the lack of seasonally unadjusted quarterly data on the capital stock
leads

us

to

depreciation

construct
rate

S

is

capital
2.5%

from

per

investment

quarter.

The

flows

assuming

remaining

that

the

parameters

are

econometrically estimated by Generalized Method of Moments.

3.1

GMM estimation
The parameters

a * b,

( 0, r, r^,

13

^ ^ are estimated by1
3

This normalization ensures that the average labor input
corresponds to the average level of labor hours in the data.



13

in

the

model

imposing jointly two sets of moment conditions:
based

upon

the

household's

consumption and leisure;

intratemporal

(1 ) orthogonality conditions
Euler

equation

for

choosing

and (2 ) explicitly equating a set of first moments

in the data with the model's predictions for these moments.

For the first set

of moments, the Euler equation can be written (in terms of observables) as:

where

- ^/(cp^ + a cp^ ^).

a valid

instrument

instrument

set

Xt l^Xt-2 ^

for

includes

Any variable in the time t information set is

estimating
the

time

the
t

parameters
and

t-

in

this

growth

1

equation.

rates

(x^/x^ ^

The
and

^ak°r hours, capital, consumption, and output, as well as four

seasonal dummy variables.
To describe the second set of moment restrictions, let H(x^) refer to the
following transformations of the data:
cpt)qt

(Alog yt/nt)qt

(Alog kt)qt

/
(Alog (l+rt))qt
where

kt/yt

is a 4x1 vector of seasonal dummies, r

]
is a real interest rate, and

the symbol ' denotes transposition, so H(xt) is a 22x1 vector.
the first
rates

of

2 0

elements of the expected value of H(xt> are the seasonal growth

output,

consumption,

labor

productivity,

seasonal change in the real interest rate.
to the average

capital-output ratio

H(xt) -

h(¥) +

ut

14

and

capital,

and

the

The last two elements correspond

and average

definition, the model predicts that




Accordingly,

labor hours.

Given

this

where MU') corresponds to the model's predicted first moments of H(xt) and
is a vector mean zero, serially correlated random variable.

Based upon these

moment restrictions, our estimator of V attempts to set the sample mean of u^
to zero, as well as the sample moments based upon equation [1

2

].

Our choice of moment restrictions is motivated by two concerns.

First,

since labor effort is unobserved, the parameter £ cannot be estimated by Euler
equation methods.

Second, estimating ^

from production function residuals

seems hopeless due to the presence of unobserved variations in labor effort:
no exogenous instruments are available.

14

However,

these parameters can be

estimated by forcing the model to confront the seasonal growth rates in the
data by choosing
Finally,

^

Sims

an<* £, as well as the other parameters.
[1990]

and Hansen and

Sargent

[1991]

have

argued

that

econometricians who use seasonally unadjusted data and misspecify the seasonal
mechanisms may do much worse than econometricians who discard the potential
information content at seasonal frequencies and simply use seasonally adjusted
data.

On the other hand, Ghysels [1991] has pointed out that great efficiency

gains may be possible if seasonally unadjusted data is used.

Thus, there is a

potential trade-off involved in using seasonally unadjusted data, efficiency
gains versus misspecification bias.

Ue

try to address

the bias

issue by

comparing our parameter estimates with other econometric studies which used
seasonally adjusted or annual data.^ 1
4

14
Hall [1988] has noted that his set of instruments would fail to be exogenous
in this setting.
^Another interesting statistical issue is whether the unadjusted time series
data are better characterized by purely indeterministic seasonality, purely
deterministic seasonality, or a mixture of both.
Ve identify Christmas
effects with a fourth quarter mean of r which is larger than the other three
quarters. This single nonzero seasonal mean induces nonzero seasonal means in
other economic aggregates.
Even if r
is stochastic, our economic theory
predicts that economic time series will possess some deterministically
seasonal components.
This argues against purely indeterministic models of




15

3 .2

D a ta
The original data set employed in this study is the Barsky-Miron [1989]

data for the sample period 1964-1985:
adjusted

for

theoretical

seasonality.
constructs

of

U.S. quarterly data which has not been

For

the

empirical

our

model,

analysis

however,

we

to

conform

redefine

to
of

some

the
the

variables as follows (and convert to per capita values).

Output (y) is Gross

National Product per capita.

is nondurables plus

Private consumption (cp)

services consumption expenditures per capita.
Fixed

Investment

plus

Durable

consumption

Investment (i) is the sum of

expenditures,

per

capita.

The

capital stock is computed using the flow investment expenditures, a quarterly
depreciation rate of 2.5%, and an initial capital stock value for 1950.

Labor

hours are computed as the product of total nonagricultural employment times
average hours per week of nonagricultural production workers times 13 weeks
per quarter (per capita).

The real interest rate is the ex post return on

three-month Treasury Bills, not seasonally adjusted as reported in Citibase.
The data is converted to per capita values by using the civilian population,
16 years and older.

3.3

Estimation Results
Table

1 presents

moment restrictions

our

estimation results.

in estimating

1 0

The

estimation

structural parameters;

imposes

34

in principle,

there are 24 overidentifying restrictions which are tested by Hansen's [1982]
J-statistic.

The

statistic

is

20.86

with

a

probability

uncovering no evidence against these restrictions.
restrictions

involve matching the model's

seasonality.




16

value

of

0.65,

Recall that 20 of the 34

seasonal predictions

against

the

data's seasonal growth rates.

Informally, this test suggests that the model

successfully captures the data's seasonal properties.

This claim is examined

in more detail in Section 4 where we consider a variety of other tests that
focus

explicitly
Turning

to

on

the

the

model's

individual

seasonal

predictions.

parameters,

our

estimates

using

seasonally

unadjusted data are similar to other estimates in the literature which have
employed seasonally adjusted data.

Our estimate of 0 is .279 which is close

to Prescott's [1986] value of .25 (when output is identified with GNP and does
not include the services of durable consumption goods).
value

of r and

is

.2363.

The

inverse

1/r

The weighted average

corresponds

to

preference parameters estimated by Christiano and Eichenbaum;
4.23

falls

within

the

range

3.92

and

5.15

consumption effect is estimated to be r^/r "

they
1

.0

2 2

report.
;

the

leisure

our value of
The

Christmas

this is the percentage

increase in the marginal utility of consumption services, holding consumption
services fixed.

This value does not seem to be implausibly large.
A
A

The

unusual

precision

of

A

0,

r,

and

is

due

to

the

two

moment

restrictions in H(x^) which are related to the capital-output ratio and the
level of labor hours.
re-estimated,

the

If these two moment conditions are dropped and ¥ is

parameter

estimates

are

essentially

unchanged,

but

the

A
A

standard

errors

respectively.

for

0,

A

r,

and

rise

to

.0352,

.0105,

and

.0107,

Therefore, the unusual precision of these parameter estimates

is due to the inclusion of strong identifying restrictions from the model's
equilibrium predictions.
The

nontime-separability

parameters

a

and

b

are

similar

to

other

researchers' estimates.

The value of a-.445 indicates that consumption goods

have a durable quality:

in seasonally adjusted data, this has been found by




17

The

Eicheribaum, Hansen, and Singleton [1988] and Gallant and Tauchen [1990].^

value of b--.517 indicates that leisure preferences exhibit habit-persistence:
in seasonally adjusted data, this has been found by Eichenbaum, Hansen,
Singleton as well as Braun [1990].
relatively

smooth;

habit-persistence

in

and

This feature makes leisure and labor hours

addition

to

in leisure will

adjustment

smooth

costs

labor hours

for

and

labor

lead

to

hours,
greater

variations in labor effort in response to exogenous shocks.
The adjustment cost parameters are significantly different from zero.^
The capital and labor estimates are 28.45 and 0.258, but these numbers are a
poor indication of their relative effects.

On a quarterly basis, the standard

deviations for the growth rates of capital and labor are 0.35% and 2.21%.
percentage

reduction

in output

due

to

adjusting

capital

(only)

and

(only) by one standard deviation above average is -0.018% and -0.006%.
capital
penalty.

adjustment
Also,

penalty

is

only

about

3

times

larger

than

the

The
labor

So the
labor

these numbers indicate that the direct effect of adjustment

costs on measured Solow residuals is negligible. That is, the effects of Alog
in equation

[11]

are small.

indirect effect may be

large:

As was noted
in response

in Section 2, however,

to a consumption

demand

the

shock,

reducing investment may now be costly enough to induce a large response in
output.
Our estimate of the output elasticity with respect to external increasing
returns is ^

“ .2389.

The elasticity is significantly different from zero.

This value is within the range of estimates reported by Caballero and Lyons

On the other hand, Constantinides and Ferson [1990] find evidence of
habit-persistence in consumption goods preferences (a<0). In simulations of
an equilibrium business cycle model with seasonality, Braun and Evans [1990]
found that durability in consumption (a>0 ) helped the model match key business
cycle moments better than habit-persistence.
^Ghysels [1988] observes that there is a lot of spectral power at seasonal
frequencies for identifying adjustment cost parameters.




18

[1989] and Baxter and King [1990], although Baxter and King use a larger value
of ,33 in their model evaluation.
our

estimate

provides

some

The size and statistical significance of

evidence

that

external

important for explaining seasonal fluctuations;
offered
differ

in Section 4.
from

those

estimate of ^

Nevertheless,

of

provides

are

our

identifying

restrictions

and

[1990]

evidence which

returns

a quantitative assessment is

since

Caballero-Lyons

increasing

Baxter-King

[1990],

our

theirs

and

is both

independent

of

complementary.
Our estimate of £ is 0.0241, so the disutility of labor effort deviations
may in fact be small enough to induce sizable variations.
is .0348, so the estimate is reasonably imprecise.

The standard error

It is important to note

that the hypothesis that variations in labor effort are small would imply that
? is large:

the point estimate and standard error do not support this.

As we

will see in Section 4, estimates of f in the range reported are capable of
yielding

substantial

variations

in

work

habit-persistence

in leisure preferences,

relatively

disutility

effort.

small

associated

costly

with

adjustment

varying

provide evidence for the labor hoarding hypothesis.
implied by the estimates and

Thus,

labor

Finally,

normalization is negative.

the
of

estimated
labor,

effort

and

jointly

the value of v

Thus,

utility

is

strictly decreasing in work effort.
Overall, the estimated parameterization seems reasonable.

The similarity

of many estimates with previous studies suggests that if we had chosen to
"calibrate"

our

parameterization

model
would

using
not

these

have

been

other
very

studies,
different.

the

resulting

Finally,

the

overidentifying restrictions cannot be rejected.

4 .
In




t h is

E v a lu a tin g
s e c t io n

w e

th e

M o d e l's

e v a lu a te

19

th e

S e a so n a l
s e a s o n a l

I m p lic a tio n s
p r o p e r tie s

o f

t

parameterization

and

offer

evidence

on

the

relative

importance

of

hoarding and increasing returns in explaining the seasonal patterns
data. Two criteria
First,

a series

labor
in the

are used to evaluate the model's seasonal predictions.

of hypothesis

tests

are

reported.

These

tests

have

the

benefit of taking into consideration sampling error in the summary statistics
for the data and sampling error in the estimated parameterization. Second, the
seasonal growth rates of the data and the model are simply plotted together.
This latter approach provides a visual summary of the seasonal properties of
the model relative to the data.
Table 2 contains results from a series of hypothesis tests. The results
in

table

questions:
predict

are

2

aimed

providing

information

on

the

Is there evidence of seasonality in the data?

significant

patterns

at

seasonality?

Does

the model predict

following
Does

the

the model

same

found in the data? Column one reports Wald statistics

three

seasonal

that offer

evidence on the first question for each variable individually. The maintained
null underlying the column one results is that the four seasonal dummies for a
particular time series are equal (equation (1), Table 2). These statistics are
constructed from GMM estimates of the average seasonal growth rates in the
data

and

statistic

use

a

Newey-West

indicate

that

covariance

the

null

estimator.
hypothesis

The
of

p-values
no

for

each

seasonality

is

overwhelmingly rejected for each time series. These results are representative
of findings reported by Barsky and Miron [1989]

18

.

Column two reports Wald

statistics that offer evidence on the second question.

The maintained null

hypothesis is that the model's predicted seasonal growth rates are equal.

19

18

Barsky and Miron also find that there is statistically significant
seasonality in the real interest rate although the magnitude of the estimated
seasonals (in levels) is small.

19

The model's predicted seasonal growth rates are a highly nonlinear function




20

The null hypothesis of no seasonality is also sharply rejected for each of the
time-series that the model offers predictions for. On the basis of the results
from these two tests,

we conclude that both the model

and the data offer

strong refutable predictions at seasonal frequencies.
Certainly the most important question is the third one:
predict the seasonal patterns in the data?

Does the model

Column three of Table 2 provides

one metric for evaluating the model 1 s "fit" at seasonal

frequencies.

maintained null hypothesis

model's

in column three

is

that

the

The

predicted

seasonal growth rates for the jth time-series equal the corresponding values
in the data in each of the four seasons. This LaGrange multiplier (or LM) test
is formally a test of particular moment restrictions that were imposed in the
course

of estimation.

statistics were

For hours,

the

Solow residual,

and

calculated using

the

fact

time

that

these

investment,
series

the

can be

expressed as (log) linear combinations of other time series that were included
in the estimation. Eichenbaum, Hansen and Singleton [1984] and Newey and West
[1987b] describe the details of implementing LM tests in the context of GMM
estimation.

Column three contains

surprisingly

null of a common seasonal pattern in all

little

instances.

evidence
As

against

a check we

the
also

calculated a GMM analog to the likelihood ratio statistic and found that the
two statistics were virtually identical.
This collection of statistics provides two important conclusions. First,
the tests reported in columns one and two demonstrate that the statistics have
sufficient power to reject the null hypothesis of no seasonality for the model
and the data. Second, the column three results find no evidence against the
hypothesis that the model correctly predicts the pattern of seasonality found

of the estimated structural parameter vector 4. The asymptotic covariance of
the predicted seasonals is computed using the covariance estimator of ¥ and
the gradient of the nonlinear function.
The Wald statistics are constructed
from these objects in the usual way.




21

in

th e

d a ta .

Turning to the specific predictions of the model, we report plots of the
seasonal

growth rates

for

the data and model

numbers are presented in Table 3).

in figures

These diagrams

1-3

complement

(the

actual

the previous

hypothesis tests in that they offer summary information on the ability of the
estimated parameterization

to

capture

particular

aspects

of

the

seasonal

pattern in the data. We will focus on two aspects of the seasonal pattern: the
magnitude of the model's predicted seasonal in a particular quarter relative
to the data and the ability of the model to mimic the sequential relationship
of

seasons

found

in

the

data.

The

Solow

residuals

labeled

"data"

are

calculated using 0«.28. As was noted in section 3 this number is qualitatively
close to the value of .25 used by Prescott [1986].
One of the principal aims of this paper is to investigate the possibility
that increasing returns and/or time-varying labor effort can explain the large
seasonal variation
reported

in table

in the
2:

Solow Residual.

the model

is

quite

Figure

1 confirms

successful

in

this

predicted Solow residual has the same sequential pattern
magnitudes

found in the data.

These

results

offer

strong

the

results

respect.

The

and captures

the

support

for our

contention that the observed seasonal pattern in the Solow residual is

driven

largely by demand shocks.
In addition to capturing the seasonal pattern in the Solow residual, the
model also mimics important features of seasonality in output, consumption and
average productivity. In all of these instances the model correctly predicts
the sequential seasonal pattern

of the data.

For consumption we do see a

tendency for the model to understate the third quarter deceleration found in
the

data

and

for

output

the

model

understates

the

second

quarter

rise.

However, the hypothesis tests indicate that both of these disparities can be
attributed to sampling error. These




successes across the entire calendar year

22

are particularly striking given that the only seasonal shifter is a fourth
quarter shift in preferences.
Figure 3 displays the seasonal patterns in labor effort.
an unobservable, the data's seasonals cannot be
output

rises

on

the

strength

of

higher

combination with increasing returns,

than

reported.
normal

work

in

the

first

quarter.

Fourth quarter

labor

effort.

In

fourth quarter effort is only 3% above

normal in generating an annualized output growth of 18%.
at

Since this is

These

variations

20

in

Opposing forces are
effort

do

not

seem

implausible.
If we ignore sampling error, the figures suggest that the model fails to
account for some aspects of the seasonal pattern in other variables. For hours
and investment the magnitudes are off in all four quarters,

for the capital

stock they are off in three quarters and for interest rates they are off in
two quarters.

However,

even for these time series

the model

captures many

features of the sequential pattern in the data. The fact that the hypothesis
tests in table

2

fail to reject a common seasonal pattern in individual time

series suggests that there may be considerable sampling error. The most likely
A

sources

for this

sampling error are

A

in £ and

parameters which

govern

respectively the roles of time-varying labor effort and increasing returns.
Both

parameters

are

estimated

with

sizable

standard

errors.

The

case

analyses below demonstrate that variations in these two paramters lead to a
deterioration in the model's seasonal predictions relative to the data.
It is also interesting to examine the role of the various features of the
model

in

explaining

these

seasonal

patterns.

increasing returns can be shut down by setting ^
in work effort can be ruled out by setting

20

Notice
"0 •

and

first,

23

the

Second, time variation
F°r t* 1 6 8 6 values of

The fourth quarter growth rate of labor effort is only 3.8%.




that

£ and ^
adjust

it is never

labor

desirable to vary effort, while

in production.

By

examining

these

two

it is costless to

special

cases

of

the

estimated paramterization we can get some feel for the contributions of labor
hoarding and increasing returns to scale.
The results from these exercises are displayed in Figures 4, 5, and

6

along with the data for purposes of comparison. Consider first output and the
Solow residual. With only increasing returns the Solow residual and output are
essentially flat across all four seasons.

Labor hoarding, on the other hand,

does in isolation produce the correct sequential pattern for these two series
while dramatically understating the magnitudes. On the basis of these diagrams
it would appear that labor hoarding plays a crucial role in generating the
correct seasonal pattern in output and the Solow residual. The primary role of
increasing

returns

then

is

to

magnify

these

patterns.

In

our

estimated

parameterization increasing returns and labor hoarding are clearly interacting
to deliver the seasonal patterns in output and the Solow Residual.
Consumption and investment, on the other hand, continue to display some
seasonality with
properties

only

increasing

of the model.

The

returns.

This

fourth quarter

can

be

seasonal

attributed
demand

to

two

shift helps

explain the fluctuations in the fourth and first quarters. In the second and
third quarters investment and consumption are adjusting endogenously via the
nontime-separabilities in consumption which imply that consumption in adjacent
periods are substitutes.5

5.
This

paper

demonstrates

Conclusion

that

the

seasonal

cycle

contains

valuable

information for uncovering the roles of labor hoarding and increasing returns.
In contrast to business cycles which are arguably induced by both demand and
technology




shocks

of

varying

persistence,

24

seasonal

fluctuations

are

anticipated,
Christmas.

transient,

and

easily

identified with

calendar

events

like

Our findings indicate that increasing returns to scale alone does

not directly explain the seasonality in measured Solow residuals.

However, it

plays an important role in magnifying small variations in work effort. Hall
[1988] has argued that labor hoarding requires implausibly large variations in
work effort to explain cyclical fluctuations in Solow residuals.
fluctuations

this

labor effort

variation of no more

increasing
fluctuations

is not

returns

these

in total

observed in the data.

the

case.

Our

than

variations

estimated parameterization

5.5%
are

factor productivity

on a

labor hoarding--

quarterly basis.

magnified,
that are

of

thereby
the

same

With

producing
magnitude

this

model

offers

an

productive externalities,

explanation

for

the

similar

cross-country seasonal patterns documented by Beaulieu and Miron [1991].




implies

Finally, since our explanation rests on phenomena which

are not country-specific-- Christmas celebrations,
and

For seasonal

25

R e fe r e n c e s
Barsky, R. and J. Miron, 1989, The Seasonal Cycle and the Business
Cycle, Journal of Political Economy.
Baxter, M . , and R. King, 1990, Productive Externalities and Cyclical
Volatility, Rochester Center for Economic Research Working
Paper #245.
Beaulieu, J . 9 and J. Miron, 1991, A Cross Country Comparison of
Seasonal Cycles and Business Cycles, manuscript, Boston University.
Braun, R . , 1990, The Dynamic Interaction of Distortionary Taxes and
Aggregate Variables in Postwar U.S. Data, unpublished Ph.D.
thesis, Carnegie Mellon University.
Braun, R . , and C. Evans, 1991, Seasonality and Equilibrium Business
Cycle Theories, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics,
Discussion Paper #45.
Burnside, C., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo, 1990, Labor Hoarding and
the Business Cycle, NBER working paper #3556.
Caballero, R . , and R. Lyons, 1989, The Role of External Economies in U.S.
Manufacturing, manuscript, Columbia University.
Chatterjee, S. and B. Ravikumar, 1989, A Neoclassical Model of
Seasonal Fluctuations, manuscript, University of Iowa.
Christiano, L. and M. Eichenbaum, 1990, Current Real Business
Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations,
unpublished manuscript, Institute for Empirical
Macroeconomics, Discussion Paper #24.
Chirinko, R . , 1991, Non-Convexities, Labor Hoarding, Technology Shocks,
Procyclical Productivity: A Structural Econometric Approach,
manuscript, University of Chicago.
Constantinides, G. and W. Ferson, 1990, Habit Persistence and Durability
in Aggregate Consumption: Empirical Tests, unpublished
manuscript, University of Chicago.
Cooper, R . , and J. Haltiwanger, 1989, Macroeconomic Implications of
Production Bunching: Factor and Final Demand Linkages,
NBER Working Paper #2976.
Eichenbaum, M. and L. Hansen, 1990, Estimating Models with
Intertemporal Substitution Using Aggregate Time Series Data,
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.
Eichenbaum, M . , L. Hansen, and K. Singleton, 1989, A Time Series
Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and
Leisure Choice Under Uncertainty, Quarterly Journal of
Economics.




26

Eichenbaum, M . , L. Hansen, and K. Singleton, 1984, Appendix to: A Time
Series Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and
Leisure Choice Under Uncertainty, manuscript,
Carnegie-Mellon University.
Evans, C., 1991, Productivity Shocks and Real Business Cycles, manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Gallant, R . , L. Hansen, and G. Tauchen, 1990, Using Conditional
Moments of Asset Payoffs to infer the Volatility of
Intertemporal Marginal Rates of Substitution,
Journal of Econometrics.
Gallant, R. and G. Tauchen, 1989, Seminonparametric Estimation of
Conditionally Constrained Heterogeneous Processes: Asset
Pricing Applications, Econometrics 57, 1091-1120.
Ghysels, E., 1988, A Study Toward a Dynamic Theory of Seasonality
for Economic Time Series, Journal of American Statistical
Association, 83, 168-172.
Ghysels, E., 1991, On the Economics and Econometrics of Seasonality,
manuscript, University of Montreal.
Hall, R . , 1988, The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in
U.S. Industry, Journal of Political Economy 96, pp. 921-947.
Hall, R. , 1989, Temporal Agglomeration, NBER Working Paper #3143.
Hansen, L . , 1982, Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments
Estimators, Econometrics 50, 1029-1054.
Hansen, L., and T. Sargent 1991, Seasonality and Approxiamation Errors
Rational Expectations Models, manuscript, Hoover Institute.
Hansen, L. and K. Singleton, 1982, Generalized Instrumental Variables
Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models,
Econometrica 50, 1269-1286.
Heaton, J., 1988, The Interaction between Time-Nonseparable Preferences
and Time Aggregation, unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago.
Kydland, F. and E. Prescott, 1982, Time to Build and Aggregate
Fluctuations, Econometrica 50, 1345-1370.
Murphy, K . , A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, Building Blocks of Market
Clearing Business Cycle Models, NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989,
pp. 247-287.
Newey, W. and K. West, 1987a, A Simple, Positive Definite,
Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance
Matrix, Econometrica 55, pp. 703-708.
Newey, W. and K. West, 1987b, Hypothesis Testing with Efficient
Method of Moments Estimators, International Economic Review 28,
pp. 777-788.




27

in

Prescott, E., 1986, Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement,
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 27
(Autumn), 11-44.
Ramey, V., 1991, Nonconvex Costs and the Behavior of Inventories,
Journal of Political Economy.
Sims, C., 1990, Rational Expectations Modeling With Seasonally Adjusted Data.
Institute for Emprical Macroeconomics Discussion Paper 35.
Singleton, K . , 1988, Econometric Issues in the Analysis of
Equilibrium Business Cycle Models, Journal of Monetary Economics.




28

T a b le

Parameter

1 :

Estimate

GMM P a r a m e t e r

E s tim a te s

Standard Error

6

.2790

0.00091

r

.2350

0.00045

.2402

0.00047

. 0 0 2 1

0.00005

r4

X

28.448

3.64360

.2576

0.05645

a

.4453

0.01123

b

-.5173

0.00854

.2389

0.09240

.0241

0.03481

*1
* 2

CM

J-statistic
Degrees of Freedom
P-value

2 0 . 8 6

24
.6469

21

A Newey-West procedure [1987a] with four lags was used to compute the optimal
GMM weighting matrix.




29

T a b le

(1)

4 x

X
<

f(») - d,

1

>✓
*

CM

(3)

Variable X

f(*)'q

L

+ w

L

T e s t

R e s u lts

f
22
Hn : The model does NOT exhibit deterministic
seasonality . The elements of f(40 are equal.
h 1:

„d
Ho

H y p o th e s is

H q : The data do NOT exhibit deterministic
seasonality
The elements of d are equal.

— d'q t + w t ,

t

2 :

The model's predicted seasonality equals
the data's seasonality.

23

Hj
Ho

4

Solow

303.64
(.000)

437.74
(.000)

0.125
(.998)

Output

413.90
(.000)

348.08
(.000)

0.201
(.995)

Consumption

715.28
(.000)

197.32
(.000)

0.058
(.999)

Investment

1097.45
(.000)

27.35
(.000)

0.137
(.997)

Capital

280.26
(.000)

31.21
(.000)

0.301
(.989)

Labor Hours

831.49
(.000)

112.31
(.000)

24

0.216
(.994)

615.61
(.000)
Labor Prod

227.14
(.000)

391.25
(.000)

0.167
(.996)

Real Rate

31.06
(.000)

54.03
(.000)

0.034
(.999)

22

Equation (2) is predicted by our theoretical model, but our test is not
regression-based. See the text for a description.
23
For both columns 1 and 2, the Wald test statistics are asymptotically
distributed x with four degrees of freedom.
The numbers in parentheses are
probability values of the test statistic.
24
2
The Lagrange Multiplier test statistic is asymptotically distributed x with
four degrees of freedom.




30

T a b le

3 :

S e a s o n a l

25
G r o w th

Variable

Season

Model

Solow Residual

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-7.451
3.512
- .703
5.466

-7.323
3.889
-2.019
5.889

Output

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-6.501
2.924
- .345
4.746

-7.356
4.623
- .674
4.529

Consumption

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-6.744
3.500
-1.322
5.390

-6.876
3.015
.461
4.767

Investment

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-5.637
.854
3.141
2.465

-14.065
12.365
-1.578
4.896

Capital

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

.297
.136
.155
.235

.640
.219
.572
.506

Labor Hours

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-1.681
0.491
.165
1.025

-3.126
2.438
.863
.197

Labor Prod.

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

-4.821
2.433
- .510
3.721

-4.229
2.186
-1.537
4.332

Real Rate

Winter
Spring
Summer
Fall

2.901
0.812
0.409
-4.122

R a te s

.701
1.247
- .397
-1.162

25

Data

Quarterly rates of growth in percentages, except for the real interest rate
which is the quarterly change in annualized yields (i.e., Alog (l+rt), with r
at annual rates).




31

SOLOW RESIDUAL

OUTPUT

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

50
.

25
.

PERCENT

PERCENT

0.0

-.
25

-.
50

-.
75
2

3

CONSUMPTION

4

QUARTERLY SEASONS

INVESTMENT

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

15

10

PERCENT

PERCENT

5

0

5

-10

-5
1

1




2

3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

4

1

4

QUARTERLY SEASONS

Figure

1
QUARTERLY SEASONS

CAPITAL STOCK
QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

PERCENT

LABOR HOURS
Q UARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

QUARTERLY SEASONS

REAL INTEREST RATE

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

CHANGE IN ANNUALIZED YIELDS

PERCENT

LABOR PRODUCTIVITY

1



2

3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

4




3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

F ig u r e

OUTPUT

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

PERCENT

PERCENT

SOLOW RESIDUAL

QUARTERLY SEASONS

INVESTMENT

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

PERCENT

PERCENT

CONSUMPTION

1



Figure 4

QUARTERLY SEASONS

2

3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

4

1

2

3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

4

CAPITAL STOCK
QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

PERCENT

PERCENT

LABOR HOURS
QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

REAL INTEREST RATE

QUARTERLY RATES O F GROWTH

CHANGE IN ANNUALIZED YIELDS

PERCENT

PERCENTAGE POINTS

QUARTERLY SEASONS

LABOR PRODUCTIVITY

Figure 5

QUARTERLY SEASONS

1




4

QUARTERLY SEASONS

1

2

3

QUARTERLY SEASONS

4




6

QUARTERLY SEASONS

F ig u r e

130333 dO B V 73 0 X30NI