View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Scale and the Origins of Structural
Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP 2008-06

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change∗
Francisco J. Buera†and Joseph P. Kaboski‡
February 4, 2008

Abstract
Structural change involves a broad set of trends: (i) sectoral reallocations, (ii) rich movements of productive activities between home and
market, and (iii) an increase in the scale of productive units. After extending these facts, we develop a model to explain them within a unified
framework. The crucial distinction between manufacturing, services, and
home production is the scale of the productive unit. Scale technologies
give rise to industrialization and the marketization of previously home
produced activities. The rise of mass consumption leads to an expansion
of manufacturing, but a reversal of the marketization process for service
industries. Finally, the later growth in the scale of services leads to a
decline in industry and a rise in services.
∗ We have benefited from helpful comments from Gary Becker, Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu
Midrigan, Ellen McGrattan, Enrique Martinez-Garcia, Joel Mokyr, Chiaki Moriguchi, Ed
Prescott, Richard Rogerson and participants in presentations at the AEA 2007 meetings,
Northwestern University, the FRB of Chicago, the FRB of Minneapolis, the NBER Summer
Institure, the University of Wisconsin, and the University of Chicago.
† Northwestern University, f-buera@northwestern.edu
‡ Ohio State University, kaboski.1@osu.edu

1

The rise of large scale technologies is a central aspect of the process of
development. Industrialization involves the implementation of technologies with
high and rapidly growing productivity. These technologies are not only more
productive but also involve a dramatic increase in the optimal scale of productive
units. For example, in the United States, the workers per manufacturing firm
increased seven fold between 1850 to 1950, from nine to sixty-three workers.
During the same period, real income per capita had risen only five-fold.1
The emergence of scale technologies is a central theme in the modern literature on industrialization.2 This literature, in examining the potential obstacles
to development stemming from scale technologies, has focused on the transition
from traditional, small-scale, cottage industry technologies to large-scale manufacturing during development. The sole emphasis on the rise of the manufacturing sector ignores a broader set of changes taking place during the transition
to a modern economy. Indeed, at its peak, industry constitutes less than half of
an economy’s measured output. A broader view of the process of development,
dating back to Kuznets (1973), includes the changes in the relative importance
of broadly defined sectors, (e.g.,agriculture, manufacturing and services), the
marketization of home production, and the introduction of modern technologies
into the household.
In this paper, we document facts on scale patterns, sectoral trends, and
home vs. market decisions, and provide a unified theory for them. In our theory, scale technologies are the origin of structural change. That is, a model
designed to be consistent with cross-sectoral and secular evidence on the scale
of productive units delivers strong predictions for the movement of production
between sectors and between home and the market. These predictions are consistent with the data. In particular, large-scale technologies drive production
out of the home and into the market, but these patterns reverse when households begin directly purchasing productive intermediates en masse, and much
modern service production moves back into the home. This drives an expansion
of the manufacturing sector at the expense of agriculture and services. Finally,
large-scale technologies may play a role in the more recent counter-reversal, in
which home production has declined relative to market labor and services.
We model the role of scale in a dynamic economy with two technologies, a
high-growth, modern technology and a stagnant, traditional, subsistence technology. The modern is a multi-stage technology with product units of three
different scales: home production, services, and manufacturing. The optimal
scales of these units arise because of specialized and indivisible manufactured
(intermediate/capital) goods needed for modern production.
• Home production using the modern technology involves production only
for (very customized) self-consumption. It is therefore the smallest scale
1 The historical importance of the growth in scale has been well-documented, e.g., Atack,
1985, Broadberry, 2006, Chandler, 1990, Goldin and Katz, 1995, Mokyr, 2001, and Sokoloff,
1984, There is also empirical work on currently less developed countries, e.g., Banerjee and
Duflo, 2005, and Buera, Kaboski, and Shin, 2007.
2 See, for example, important contributions by Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989a, 1989b),
Matsuyama (1992), and Banerjee and Newman (1993).

2

and most costly to produce, but its output is customized and therefore
has utility benefits.
• Services production is a substitute for home production. It has an intermediate optimal scale, and its productive efficiencies may or may not
outweigh its lower utility from limited customization.
• Manufacturing requires the largest fixed intermediates/capital and therefore operates at the largest scale. Given the large fixed costs and efficient
scale in manufacturing, home production of manufactured goods is not a
revelant alternative.
In contrast to the modern technologies, traditional production requires no
intermediate/capital goods and offers no advantages of scale. Hence all production occurs in the home.
On the consumption side, agents hold a continuum of satiable wants ordered
by the cost of producing output to satisfy them. Wants are symmetric. That
is, although there is a difference in utility between home and market produced
output, all wants are subject to this choice and so offer the same potential utility
The model identifies two forces at work that determine the relative growth of
the manufacturing, service, and home production over the development process.
The first force (“marketization”) leads to a relative increase in both industry
and market services at the expense of the traditional home technology. The
modern technology experiences technological progress, which the home is not
able to fully replicate because of its necessary small-scale of operation. It is
the large-scale of production of new technologies that draws production out of
the home and into the market place. These modern scale technologies involve
both industry and services, however, and this marketization force leads to an
expansion of both, and a decline in traditional home production. This force
is most important early in industrialization, when traditional home production
is prevalent, and marketization is strongest for technologies with large optimal
scales, high fixed intermediate/capital costs, and low utilization rates in the
home (e.g. railroad production and rail travel).
The second force (“mass consumption”) further drives the growth of manufacturing, but involves the choice to operate the modern technology at home
rather than purchase market services. We call this force “mass consumption”
because the choice of modern home production requires that consumers directly
purchase manufacturing inputs, and generally requires more manufacturing inputs per unit of output (e.g. commuting separately in cars rather than riding
otgether in a bus). Relative to modern market production of services, modern home production therefore yields less market production of services, but
requires more manufactured goods production. Mass consumption often occurs
later than marketization, as the costs of intermediates fall relative to income,
but may occur immediately if disutility of market consumption is high, utilization is high, or the cost of intermediate goods are small (e.g., food and clothing
services).

3

With sufficient heterogeneity in scale or the size of intermediate goods requirements, the model yields rich product cycles between the home and market.
The production of goods is large scale and has a single transition from home to
the market. Services for which scale is intermediate (e.g., local transportation,
laundering) may move from the home (traditional) to the market, and back to
the home (modern) over the course of development, while the smallest scale services may simply transition from traditional home to modern home production
(e.g. cooking with a wood-burning stove to cooking with a gas/electric range).
Our emphasis on the link between scale technologies, sectoral allocations,
and the home production margin is consistent with several additional empirical
facts. First, the increase (and peak) in manufacturing’s share in value-added
coincides with an increase (and peak) in the share of non-food goods in consumption, which is consistent with the mass consumption force. Second, the
peak in manufacturing in the U.S. also corresponds to a peak in the amount of
time spent in home production (Ramey and Francis, 2007). Market labor supply is known to be U-shaped over development (Goldin, 1994, Schultz, 1991),
and the trough in labor supply in the U.S. also corresponds to the peak in home
production. Finally, the post-1950 decline in industry relative to services is associated with growth in the scale of services, a decline in home production, and
an increase in labor supply.
We conclude the introduction by reviewing related literature, in order to delineate our relative contribution, and underscore that our emphasis on scale and
a broader view of structural change is important for policy and measurement.
After this literature review, Section 2 develops the broad facts of structural
change that motivate the paper. Section 3 introduces the model while Section 4
presents the main results. Section 5 discusses two extension of the basic model:
(i) the case with heterogeneity in the scale of services; and (ii) a model with
explicit durability of intermediate manufacturing inputs (capital). Section 6
compares some testable implications of our model with the data, and Section 7
concludes.
Related Literature Our empirical work extends and complements that of
Kuznets (1957), Chenery and Syrquin, (1975), and Kravis et. al, (1984) by using
updated sources and broadening the data in terms of number of countries and
panel length. We use broadly comparable sources, and use our theory to make
classification decisions for areas where discrepancies hold across methodologies.
Indeed, our theory of scale as a sectoral distinction gives guidance to empirical work, which has debated how to best classify handicrafts/cottage industries,
which are particularly prevalent in less developed countries.3 Given their smallscale, we classify them as services. In our view, the scale of a productive unit
3 Dean and Cole (1967, pp. 138-139) describe the problems of classification that arose
from the “radical transformation” of the structure of the British economy. Many occupations
were classified in “retail trade and handicraft” in the 1831 census (e.g., wood and furniture,
shipbuilding, printing, fur and leather, dressmaking, watches, toys and musical instruments,
food/drink and also iron founders, weavers, dyers, and paper) were classified as manufacturing
in later censuses.

4

reflects the extent of customization, with manufactured goods offering the least,
home production offering the most, and services being intermediate. In this
way, our paper is related to the view of Reid (1935) that manufacturing produces objects while services produce “circumstance” (location, condition, etc.),
and Locay’s (1990) view that more customized activities are produced in the
household.4
An existing theoretical literature (e.g., Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny, 1989a,
1989b, Matsuyama, 1992, and Banerjee and Newman, 1993) has examined the
role of scale in development, but in a different context. They showed how fixed
costs involved with large scale technologies can lead to poverty traps in the
presence of frictions, but focused on a single modern sector. In our broader
view, where scale differs across sectors, frictions can have differential impacts
across sectors as in Buera, Kaboski, and Shin (2007), Erosa and Hidalgo (2007),
or Rajan and Zingales (1998).5 Differential effects on services and industry can
be important since the sectors differ in their tradability and their contribution
to investment.
Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989b) and Matsuyama (2002) also demonstrate the importance of mass consumer demand of manufactured goods in development. Katona (1964) emphasizes household investment in durables an important characteristic of “mass consumption”, however, and we draw a unique
link between these durables and the growth of household production and manufacturing relative to services. Lagakos (2007) studies retailing and automobiles,
a particular example of this link. Given the role of scale, frictions in consumer
credit markets and the distribution of income may also play a role in industrialization.
Our model also underscores the measurement problems of home production
and home labor, and so is related to recent work on the growth of the service
sector and labor supply (Ngai and Pissarides, 2007, Rogerson, 2007). This approach diverges the recent literature on balanced growth and structural change
(e.g., Acemoglu and Guerrieri, 2007, Ngai and Pissarides, 2007, and Kongsamut,
Rebelo, and Xie, 2001, Foellmi and Zweimueller, 2006). Instead, we model a
transition from stagnation to modern growth as in Galor (2005), Galor and Weil
(2000), Gollin, Parente, and Rogerson (2007), and Hansen and Prescott (2005).
4 Statistical agencies uses various categories to group industries according to their type of
products. For example, according to the NIPA "goods are tangible products that can be stored
or inventoried, services are products that cannot be stored and are consumed at the place and
time of their purchase." Within goods, manucturing establishments are defined, according
to the NAICS, as those "engaged in the mechanical, physical, or chemical transformation
of materials, substances, or components into new products." Such definitions are problematic
practically (many classifications do not adhere to the definition) and conceptually (distinctions
are not economically meaningful).
5 The scale-dependent policies as emphasized by Guner, Ventura, and Yi (2006) can also
affect sectors differentially.

5

1

Facts of Structural Change
“The rate of structural transformation of the economy is high.
Major aspects of structural change include the shift away from agriculture to non-agriculture pursuits, and, recently, away from industry to services; a change of the scale of productive units, and a
related shift from personal enterprise to impersonal organization of
economic firms, with a corresponding change in the occupational
status of labor.” (Kuznets, 1971, 2)

This section documents key facts on three aspects of structural change:
growth in the scale of productive establishments, sectoral reallocations of production, and rich dynamics between home and market production.

1.1

Large Scale Technologies

In the model of the next section, scale is a proxy for the cost differential between
home-scale and market-scale production. In the data, we will focus on workers
per establishment as our preferred metric of scale in the market.6 Workers per
enterprise is another alternative, but firms are often driven by contracting rather
than technological considerations.7 The facts we present hold for either metric,
however.
The first fact is that the growth process involves the introduction of large
scale technologies in both industry and services. The industrial revolution involved the gradual spread of the factory system, characterized by the staggered
arrival of a series of large-scale technologies (Mokyr, 2001, Scranton, 1997).
Advances in agriculture in the early 18th century (e.g., seed drills, iron plows,
threshing machines, and most importantly, enclosures) were a precursor, but the
industrial revolution took off as technologies such as textile milling, iron production, mining, and steam power became increasingly economically viable.8 All led
to increases in the scale of production, and required large capital investments.
Similarly, the technologies of the second industrial revolution in the late 19th
and early 20th century, such as steel, concrete, paper and chemicals, internal
combustion engines, electricity, and food processing, led to even larger scales
of efficient production, as did increased mechanization in agriculture (tractors,
harvesters, etc.).9
6 In

the model, output or capital would be related measures.
some cases, however, the firm is the appropriate level that a technology is operated
(e.g., Walmart and inventory management).
8 Textiles provide an example of the staggered arrival of technologies, which took over a
century to fully move to large scale production. As Mokyr (2001) describes, cotton spinning,
carding, bleaching, and printing were mechanized relatively early and moved to factory production, while weaving production remained in the home until the power looms arrival in the
1820s. Combed wool spinning was mechanized early, but the combing process itself was not
mechanized until the mid-19th century. Hand production of worsted wool and linen lasted
even longer.
9 Berg (1994) provides an excellent description of the early development of the factory
system. Mokyr (1990) and Chandler (1990) give detailed accounts of technological innovations
7 In

6

The 19th century U.S. censuses of manufacturing made available by Atack
and Bateman (1999) support the narrative history.10 Most manufacturers were
still small-scale, with the median establishment employing just three workers
in 1850, but the larger means indicate some larger scale producers in 1850.
Scale grew in most industries between 1850 and 1870. The scales of industries
associated with the new technologies (steel, textiles, paper, engines, farming
machinery) were an order of magnitude larger, and had the largest increases in
scale from 1850 to 1870. Appendix A presents these data from the 1850 and
1870 census of manufacturers for the major industries that can be compared
over time.
Scale technologies were not particular only to goods production, but required
services in their delivery (Chandler, 1990). Services, transportation, retail trade,
and wholesale trade, in particular, were important elements even in early industrialization (Mokyr, 1990, Chandler, 1990). Canals, steam power, adding
machines and cash registers, and other new office technologies led to an increase
in the scale of services (Broadberry, 2006).
The second fact is that although modern services involved scale technologies,
manufacturing technologies operate on a much larger scale. Even in the census of
manufacturers, the smallest scale industries are those most commonly associated
with services (dairy, bakeries, crop services, repair shops). For example, there
was a large increase in the scale of meat products from 1850 to 1870 that may
reflect a transformation of this industry from butchers to meat packers.11
The histograms of establishment size in Figure 1 show more generally that
services are overwhelmingly small scale relative to industry. The vertical bar
indicates the average scales of 47 and 14 for 4-digit (SIC) manufacturing and
services, respectively. Despite the wide variance of scale in industry, the distributions overlap very little with most of the mass in services being below ten,
and most of the mass of manufacturers being greater than ten. The difference is
scale is true across each broad industry in the goods sector (including agriculture, mining, utilities, and manufacturing) and services sectors (transportation,
services, public administration) with the exception of construction, which is typically in the industrial sector, but has many service-like characteristics.12 The
identical patterns hold for enterprise size rather than establishment size with
average scales of 57 and 18, respectively.
in the second industrial revolution and how they lead to large scale production .
1 0 Atack (1985) provides further evidence for the U.S., while Sokoloff (1984) and Sicsic
(1994) provide evidence for early 19th century northeastern U.S. and 19th century France,
respectively.
1 1 At times, scale has been used as an explicit basis for classification. For example, in
the 1927 census, producers of confectionaries, ice cream and sheet iron were deemed to be
manufacturers (as opposed to services) if annual production was at least $20,000.
1 2 For example, construction is non-tradable, and much of construction consists of small-scale
contract work for which home production is a viable alternative.

7

0.6
0.4

Manufactures

0.2
0
0

20

40

60

80

100

40
60
80
Employment per Establishment

100

0.6
0.4

Services

0.2
0
0

20

Figure 1: Histogram of Average Size per Establishment (4-digit SIC), US 1997

1.2

Sectoral Reallocations

We extend Kuznets’ stylized development patterns for reallocations across industry, services and manufacturing with longer time series and a wider set of
countries. Utilizing recent independent work by economic historians, we have
assembled reliable extended time series of current price value-added share data
for 30 countries, covering six continents and different levels of current development. (See documentation and data at
http://faculty.wcas.northwestern.edu/~fjb913/BK2_DataAppendix.zip for details.)13
The data series are summarized Figure ??, which shows value-added shares
vs. real income per capita for industry (top panel), services (middle panel), and
agriculture (bottom panel). Beyond the well-known decline in agriculture in the
lower panel, two important features are discernible.
First, the share of manufacturing is hump shaped over development. Of
the 30 countries, 21 — including all high income countries — have experienced an
increase and then decline in industry, while the remaining lower income countries
1 3 These countries include Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, China, Colombia,
Denmark, Egypt, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, Norway, Pakistan/Bangladesh, South Africa, Spain, Sri Lanka, Sweden, Switzerland,
United Kingdom, United States, Taiwan and Thailand. Based on Maddison (2005), our data
covers: 68 percent of world population and 80 percent of world GDP in 2000; 70 percent and 74
percent, respectively, in 1950; and 40 percent and 60 percent, respectively in 1900. Although
the numbers are lower for 1900, since the longer time series include Western Europe and its
offshoots, we cover a much larger share of the population and economic activity undergoing
large structural change at the time.

8

1.00

Industry

0.80
0.60

Current Value Value-Added Share of Industry

0.40
0.20
0.00
6.00

7.00

8.00

9.00

10.00

11.00

9.00

10.00

11.00

10.00

11.00

1.00

Services

0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
6.00

7.00

8.00

1.00

Agriculture
0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
6.00

7.00

8.00

9.00

Log Real GDP/Capita

Figure 2: Sectoral Shares vs. Log Income per Capita for Country Panels

9

have only (yet) experienced the increase in industry. For these 21 countries,
the peak share averages 0.40 (std. dev: 0.05) and occurs at an average per
capita income of $7100 (st. dev.: $1800). Using this $7100 threshold to divide
the country-year observations in the sample, regressions of industry’s share of
country j on its log real income per capita (ln yj ) that include country-specific
fixed-effects (αj ) yields the following results (standard errors in parentheses):
< $7100 sample: Ind. Sharej = αj + 0.11 ln yj
(0.00)

≥ $7100 sample: Ind. Sharej = αj − 0.13 ln yj
(0.01)

Second, services constitute a substantial share of output even early on, but
exhibit a late acceleration with the decline of manufacturing. The 25 countries
for which we have data at levels of per capita income below $2000 have services
shares averaging 0.39 (std. dev: 0.07), which is comparable to the average share
of agriculture in that income level, 0.40. The analogous split sample regression
using service shares demonstrates the late acceleration:14
< $7100 sample: Serv. Sharej = αj + 0.07 ln yj
(0.01)

≥ $7100 sample: Serv. Sharej = αj + 0.20 ln yj
(0.01)

1.3

Rich Dynamics Home vs. Market Movements

The location of particular productive activities changes markedly over development, and many activities exhibit rich product cycles. Historically, and even
today in less developed economies, it has been difficult to construct truly meaningful national accounts, since they typically only encompass market activities.15
In these less developed economies, the advent and spread of industrialization
involves the marketization of many formerly home-produced activities, As documented by Reid (1935), these included “spinning, weaving, sewing, tailoring,
baking, butchering, soap-making, candle-making, brewing, preserving, laundering, dyeing, gardening, care of poultry,...,child care, education, and the care of
the sick” (p. 47).16
Two important industries that Reid omits are transportation and trade,
both of which became much less home produced over time. Canals, railroads,
and, later, mass transportation gradually replaced walking and horse-driven
1 4 The UN National Accounts Main Aggregates Database, which includes sector specific
numbers for a much larger cross-section of 161 countries but over a shorter time period (19702000), yields very similar results with low- and high-income sample coefficients of 0.07 and
-0.12 for industry, respectively, and 0.04 and 0.18 for services.
1 5 Owner-occupied housing services and self-consumed agricultural output, particularly important in poorer, agrarian economies, are often imputed into national accounts, but home
production of most other goods and services are not.
1 6 Reid’s observation was for the United States. Deane and Cole (1967) describe production
in pre-industrial Britain, where market transactions were more prevalent, but small-scale
production in the home still dominated. Even as industrialization increased market production
of textiles, many productive activities were still contracted or "put out" to households.

10

transportation. Similarly, sale of home-produced output at markets became
a smaller and smaller fraction of trade, as permanent retailers developed and
distribution chains expanded.
Eventually, many of these marketized activities, as well as other market services, have moved back in the home. Buera and Kaboski (2006) show how many
services declined in the twentieth century as important modern technologies and
goods diffused to households. Important product cycles include the decline of
transportation services, such as railroads, rail lines, and buses with the spread of
the private automobile. The automobile was also related to the decline in neighborhood retail services (food, apparel, ice, fuel, dairy, “five and dime stores”),
as was the spread of refrigerators and freezers.17 Similarly, the spread of washers, dryers, vacuums, microwaves, and other home appliances (see Greenwood et
al, 2005) was accompanied by declines in domestic servants, launders, and dry
cleaners. Francis and Ramey (2006) cite historical evidence that the spread of
many household appliances were associated with increases in household production labor because activities (e.g., bread baking, laundry) moved from market to
home production. Many newer activities that have started in the market have
also moved toward home production. Examples include the relative decline of
movie theaters (spread of televisions, VCRs, and DVD players), mail services
(computers, fax machines), and recently internet cafes (computers, cable internet connections).
These examples of demarketization are quantitatively important. Together,
Buera and Kaboski (2006) show that 75 percent of all declining service industries
between 1950 to 2000 are associated with identifiable movements toward home
production.

1.4

Summary

We have established 3 important facts:
Fact 1 The industrial revolution involves large scale technologies, but the scale
of manufacturing greatly exceeds that of services.
Fact 2 Both modern industry and services play an important role early in
development, but industry follows an extended hump-shape, while services
exhibits a late acceleration.
Fact 3 Economies experience rich product cycles between home and market
production, including marketization and later demarketization of many
services.
In the next section we present a model consistent with Fact 1, which in
turn yields Facts 2 and 3.
1 7 Lagakos (2006) examines the relationship between automobiles, retailing consolidation,
and productivity in the context of developing countries.

11

2

A Theory of Structural Change

We model the consumption decision over a continuum of discrete wants. Individuals also choose whether to home produce or to procure these wants from the
market. Production can be done using a traditional or a modern technology.
Production using the modern technology requires the use of fixed amount of
intermediate manufactured goods in combination with labor to produce up to
a maximum scale. To satiate each want requires the use of both manufactured
goods and services. In the model economy, as in the data, manufacturing differs
from services by requiring a larger fixed cost and operating at a larger scale.

2.1

Preferences

There is a continuum of consumption wants indexed by z. For each want z,
households make a discrete decision of whether to consume c(z) a service satisfying the want, and, if so, whether or not to home produce h(z) the service.
Preferences over these decisions are represented by the following utility function:
Z +∞
u (c, h) =
˜
[h (z) + γ (1 − h (z))] c (z) dz
(1)
0

where h (z) ≤ c (z) ∈ {0, 1}. As will be clear with the discussion of technologies,
z indexes the complexity associated with the production of a want.18
Since γ ∈ (0, 1), home production yields more utility, perhaps because it
avoids the disutility of public consumption (e.g., sitting next to others on the
bus instead of driving one’s own car), or because it allows an individual to
customize final consumption to his particular needs (e.g., driving one’s own car
allows to use the preferred scheduled and route).19

2.2

Technologies

Individual wants can be produced using a traditional or a modern (scale) technology. The traditional technology requires only labor as an input and experiences no productivity growth. The modern technology uses both labor and
a fixed input of intermediate manufactured inputs to produce up to a maximum scale. Overtime, the productivity associated with the modern technology
increases at a constant rate g.
1 8 These preferences over a continuum of satiable wants are related to Matsuyama (2000,
2002) and Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1989). On the preference side, our innovation is to
incorporate the home-production decision as in Kaboski and Buera (2007).
1 9 An alternative way to motivate home-production is to introduce transaction cost. See
Buera and Kaboski (2006) from a discussion of the implication of this alternative model.

12

2.2.1

Traditional Technology

Individual wants can be produced using a traditional technology that requires
only labor as an input and experiences no productivity growth:
y0 (z) = z −1 l
Labor productivity declines with the index of wants z, so that high z goods
and services are more complex, and therefore more difficult to produce. The traditional technology does not require manufactured inputs, and therefore exhibits
no scale economies. Therefore, all production using the traditional technology
is done at home.
2.2.2

Modern (Scale) Technology

We also consider a modern production technology that requires a fixed input and
is characterized by an efficient scale of production. In particular, production of
goods and services associated with a want z requires a specialized intermediate
manufactured input (k) of size q. Given the intermediate input, the technology
is linear in labor l up to a capacity of n:
½
© 0
ª if k < q
y (z, t) =
(2)
min n, egt z −λ l
if k = q

Furthermore, λ < 1, i.e., the modern technology is relatively more productive than the traditional technology for more complex goods. The modern
technology becomes relatively more attractive over time because technological
change increases productivity at a rate g, and consumption moves towards more
complex wants.
Here n represents both the capacity and the efficient scale. For example, if
a particular z were laundry, a service, then q might represent the cost of the
laundry machine, which enables one to wash n loads of laundry when used at
capacity.
At home, individuals will produce only one unit of output, and therefore
underutilize purchased intermediates, i.e., produce at a higher cost scale. For
this implication, it is important that the intermediates are indivisible (one cannot be half as productive with half a laundry machine) and specialized (a car
cannot substitute for a laundry machine in doing laundry).
2.2.3

Distinguishing Sectors

The first distinction we make between sectors is to assume that goods production
has a much larger efficient scale than services production. This is consistent with
the evidence presented in Section 2.
As we show in the following section, production requiring large intermediate
inputs q and/or done on a large scale n will tend to be performed on the market.
For simplicity we model the extreme limiting case as qM → ∞, so that manufactures are exclusively market produced. A further assumption of nM → ∞,
13

and qM /nM → 0 bounds the cost of goods. Thus, manufacturing production in
the market simplifies to a constant return to scale technology:20
yM (z, t) = egt z −λ lM
In what follows, to save on notation, we use q and n to refer to the intermediate input requirement and maximum scale associated with the production of
services.
Secondly, we also make the further simplification that goods are only intermediates and not valued directly in the utility function. Goods will nevertheless
be purchased as final consumption to be used in household production of services. Including goods as direct final consumption is feasible, but complicates
the analysis without yielding much insight. Thus, for every z there is an intermediate good and a final service.21
Finally, within the goods sector we distinguish agriculture as being the least
complex goods, those below an arbitrary level zA .
The assumption that goods production is large scale makes it market rather
than home produced.

2.3

Equilibrium

We can now state the household’s problem and the competitive equilibrium.
For each want z, the household makes three linked binary decisions: whether to
consume or not, c(z), if so whether to home produce or not, h(z), and again if
so, whether to use the modern technology in home production, m(z).
Normalizing labor as the numeraire, the household takes the wage and the
prices of each good pM (z) and service pS (z) as given, and solves the following
2 0 Alternatively, we can assume that qM → α, a constant that equals the intermediate goods’
nM
share in manufacturing. In this case, manufacturing production in the market simplifies to a
constant return to scale technology with fixed factor proportions:

ym (z, t) = eγt−λz min {(1 − α) lm , αkm } .
2 1 Furthermore, it can be argued that these two distinctions between goods and services
are intimately related, as final consumption tends to be more customized and therefore less
subject to large scale production (Locay, 1990).

14

static problem at each point in time:
Z +∞
max
[h (z) + γ (1 − h (z))] c (z) dz
m(z)≤h(z)≤c(z)

s.t.
Z ∞
0

1−

0

⎡

⎤

c(z) ⎣h(z)m(z)qpM (z) + [1 − h(z)] pS (z, t)⎦ dz =
{z
} |
{z
}
|
m anuf. cons.
service cons.
⎡
⎤

Z

0

∞

⎢
⎥
⎢
⎥
h(z) ⎢ e−gt m(z)z λ + [1 − m(z)] z ⎥ dz
{z
} |
{z
}⎦
⎣|
m odern hom e
production

(3)

trad. hom e
pro duction

The left-hand side of the budget constraint is total market expenditures,
while the right-hand side is income/labor supply.
The first-order condition of whether to home produce or market purchase a
particular service z yields the central intuition for the model. A particular want
is market produced iff:22
∙
µ
¶¸
1
μ pM q 1 −
>1−γ
(4)
n
The bracketed term represents the cost-savings of market production. Both
market and home production use labor (valued at the opportunity cost of time
w = 1), but the market service requires paying only a fraction (1/n) of the
intermediate goods cost, as opposed to the full goods cost from purchasing
the input. Households will use the market if the utility value of this costsavings (left-hand side) exceeds the lost utility from consuming market- rather
than home-produced output (right-hand side). Output that requires large or
expensive intermediates (high q or pM ), or has a large efficient scale n will
be home produced. Hence, our assumptions that manufacturing requires large
intermediates inputs q and is done on a large scale n justify the statement that
manufacturing is market produced.23
A competitive equilibrium is given by price functions pM (z, t), pS (z, t),
consumption, home production, and technology decisions c (z, t), h (z, t) and
2 2 The assumption that goods production is large scale makes it market rather than home
produced. This could be seen clearly from the the household’s first-order condition of whether
to home produce or market purchase a particular manufactured input, for the case qm and
nm are finite,
1
μ pM qM 1 −
> 1 − γ.
nM
As qm and nm go to infinity, the left-hand-side becomes arbitrarily large.
2 3 Strictly speaking, if manufactured goods are only intermediate goods there will not be a
utility advantage associated with home-production of manufactures. The following heuristic
argument should be understood within generalized model in which there is a utility gain associated with the home-production of manufactures, e.g., because of the possibility of custumizing
its design.

15

m(z, t)(associated with purchases of goods and services by households) such
that:
i. given prices pM (z, t) and pS (z, t), c (z, t), h (z, t) and m(z, t) solve (3);
ii. prices solve zero profits conditions, i.e.,
pM (z, t) = e−gt z λ
and

³
q´
pS (z, t) = 1 +
pM (z, t) ;
n

iii. markets (i.e., for labor, each z good, and each z service) clear.
Next, we characterize the evolution of the structure of production of the
economy. This process includes a shift from traditional technologies to modern
(scale) technologies, changes in the wants that are home vs. market produced,
and a transformation of the sectoral composition of output and employment.

3

Evolution of Structural Change

This section presents the results of the paper, which tie in closely with the
facts presented in Section 2, given our assumption of large scale modern technologies and the larger relative scale of manufacturing. Proposition 1 describes
the early transition from the pre-industrial to industrial scale economies and
the marketization of previously home production activities, while Proposition
2 describes the later phase of industrialization in which activities return to the
home as households begin mass consumption of modern technology intermediates. Thus, together the two propositions lead to rich product cycles, and a
growth in manufacturing relative to services. Finally, Proposition 3 shows how
the share of the service sector is increasing in its efficient scale of production.

3.1

Early Structural Transformation

For sufficiently low values of t, only the traditional technology is utilized. Since
production using the traditional technology requires no specialized inputs, all
production is done at home. Households consume the low z goods first, since all
z are valued symetrically, but the least complex output is cheapest to produce.
An upper bound z0 (t) defines the range of goods that are produced using the
traditional technology. Early on, z0 (t) also equals the most complex want that
is satiated z (t). This upper bound remains fixed until industrialization.24
¯
As productivity improves, the modern technology eventually becomes economically viable. The frontier z(= z0 ) is the first to be replaced by the modern
2 4 This meshes with the historical evidence of the pre-industrial economy: relatively stagnant, with a very high fraction of production done at a small scale and at home (Reid, 1935,
Deane and Cole, 1967, Mokyr, 1990, 2001).

16

technology, but over time the modern technology becomes more productive for
even the less complex output. During this period, the upper range of consumption z (t) increases, and the upper range of consumption produced using the old
technology z0 (t) declines. In particular, there exists a point in time at which the
modern technology overtakes the traditional technology for the most complex
want that is satiated, z = z0 :
½ µ
¾
q ¶
1+ n
1
(1 − λ)
t0 =
log
−
log 2
g
γ
2
The timing of the onset of industralization in the model depends positively
on the share of intermediate specialized inputs in the modern technologies, q/n,
and negatively on the rate of productivity growth in the modern technology and
the disutility associated with market consumption.25
The rise of scale technologies is associated with an increase in z (t) i.e., an
¯
expansion of the wants that are satiated, and a decrease in z0 (t) (a decline
of the range of wants satisfied through the traditional technology). Figure 3
illustrates this process. It describe the average cost per util as a function of the
complexity of wants for the traditional (dotted) and modern (solid) technologies.
Over time, the average cost per util for the modern technology declines.
Whether the new modern production that was previously traditional occurs
as market or home production depends on the efficient scale of services relative
to the utility advantage of home-production. If the scale of services is sufficiently
small relative to the utility advantage of home-production, 1 + q/n > γ (1 + q),
the advent of the modern technology is associated with a rise in the consumption
of intermediate manufactured goods by households to be used as input in the
home production of services. For these wants, services remain home produced,
and there is just a transition from a traditional to a modern technology that
utilizes intermediate inputs produced with a large scale technology. In the case
of wants for which the scale of service production is large relative to the utility
advantage of home-production, 1 + q/n < γ (1 + q), service production using
the modern technology occurs on the market. In section 5, we generalize the
model to allow for heterogeneity in the scale of services.
We summarize the previous discussion in the following proposition.
Proposition 1 (Industrialization): There exist two critical periods t0 and
t1 , t0 < t1 , such that:
i) for t < t0 , only the traditional technology is utilized, the set of wants that are
satiated remains fixed, and all production is done at home, i.e., z0 (t) = z (t) =
z (t) = 0;
¯
ii) for t0 ≤ t < t1 ,
(a) the most complex wants are produced using the modern technology, z0 (t) ≤
z ≤ z (t), the set of satiated wants expands, ∂ z (t) /∂t > 0, the set of wants pro¯
¯
duced using the traditional technology contracts, ∂z0 (t) /∂t < 0; and
2 5 In modelling the onset of the industrial revolution as the moment in which a modern
technology overcomes a traditional technology we follow Hansen and Prescott (2002). See
also Stokey (2001).

17

Industrialization with “Marketization” of Services

z
( 1 + q ) e − gt 0 z
1

γ

z

0

(t 0 ) =

z (t 0

(1 +

λ

q − gt 0 λ
)e
z
n

)

Rise of Mass Consumption

z

0

(t 1 ) =

z (t 1

)

z

(t 1 )

Figure 3: Average Cost per Util as a Function of Complexity (z): Traditional
Technology (red), Modern Market Technology (blue) and Modern Home Technology (pink)
(b) if 1+q/n < (>)γ, the most complex wants are satisfied in the market (at
1+q
home) using the modern technology, and the service and industrial sectors (only
the industrial sector) grow relative to agriculture.

3.2

The Rise of Mass-Consumption

Eventually the goods cost of producing any particular service z fall enough to
induce direct household purchase of the market good and the home production
of this service. Services begin returning to home production, but this time using
the modern technology. This leads to the mass consumption of manufactured
goods that are used in the production of services, and therefore is associated
with sectoral reallocations in output: the return of market production to the
home increases the demand for the given market good (by a factor of n), and
decreases the purchase of the related service. Thus, the manufacturing sector
experiences a boom relative to the service sector, and this contributes to the
rising section of the hump-shaped manufacturing trend found in the data.
Proposition 2 (Mass Consumption): Assume (1 + q/n)/(1 + q) <γ. Then,
there exist t1 > t 0 such that for t ≥ t 1 , the most complex home-produced wants
z
are produced using the modern technology, z0 (t) < z ≤ z (t) < ¯ (t), the set of
wants satiated expands, ∂ z (t) /∂t > 0, the set of home-produced wants using the
¯

18

modern technology expands, ∂z (t)/∂t > 0 and ∂z 0 (t)/∂t < 0 ; and the industrial sector grows relative to the service sector.
Proposition 2 links a surge in the share of manufacturing to a surge in the
share of manufactured goods in household consumption. We return to this
testable implication in Section 4.

3.3

Large Scale Services and the Decline of Manufacturing

The previous sections have developed the model’s ability to deliver a long extended rise of industry. This section focuses on the model’s implications for the
later decline in manufacturing, and corresponding rise in services.26
The model predicts that the larger the scale of services, the larger the relative size of the services sector. There are two intuitive reasons for this result.
First, the larger the scale, the less the goods cost per unit. That is, keeping
q constant, the share of intermediate goods is decreasing in scale. Second, the
larger the scale, the larger the cost savings of market production of services
(which produces at this efficient scale) relative to home production. The following proposition formalizes this.
Proposition 3: Both the share of market services (relative to market goods)
and the ratio of market labor to home labor are increasing in the the scale of
services, n.
In Section 4, we use the recent growth in the scale of services in the U.S. to
test this implication of the theory.

4

Testable Implications

This section examines evidence on two testable implications of the theory: (1)
evidence on the importance of the rise of mass consumption (Proposition 2), and
(2) evidence on the link between the scale of market services and their share
(Proposition 3).

4.1

Evidence on Mass Consumption

Proposition 2 predicts a link between the growth of household consumption of
manufactured goods and the growing importance of the industrial sector relative
to the service sector. It also links this consumption with the movement of
activities into home production. Figure 4 shows that patterns in the value-added
of industry and services are tied closely to household consumption of non-food
2 6 Buera and Kaboski (2006) focus on a related, and complementary explanation for the
growth in services: their increasing skill intensity.

19

0.6
Home Production
Time

Shares of Total

0.45

Non-Food Goods
Consumption

0.3

Industry
0.15

0
1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

2000

Year

Figure 4: U.S. Nominal Sectoral Share, 1870-2000
goods and services, respectively.27 Indeed, the peak of the share of the industrial
sector coincides with peaks in the share of consumption expenditures on nonfood goods. The peak in the fraction of non-leisure time spent in household
production also coincides with these other two peaks. More generally, a U-shape
in market labor supply over development is well-established and driven by the
market hours of women (Goldin, 1994, and Schultz, 1991), which presumably
reflects time reallocation between market and non-market production.
4.1.1

Scale and the Growth of Services

The model also has relevance for the decline of industry and corresponding
growth of services. Proposition 3 links the share of services to the optimal
scale of market service production n. Data from the County Business Patterns
show a steady increase of 70 percent in the average scale of services from 19471997, while the scale in the goods sector has actually declined.28 Moreover,
at a disaggregate level the growth in the service sector has been dominated
by services whose scale has grown, and who are now among the largest scale
2 7 The consumption data is from Lebergott (1996) and NIPA, while the fraction of nonleisure time spent on household production are from Ramey and Francis for the population
aged 18-65.
2 8 Scale is again defined as workers per establishment or workers per firm. In 1974, there
is a change from a "reporting unit" (firm) concept to establishment. The pre- and post-1974
changes are 59 and 17 percent, respectively.

20

services. Using scale and payroll information by 3-digit level from the 1959 and
1997 County Business Patterns, OLS regressions yield the following estimates
(with standard errors in parentheses):
∆sharei = 0.20 + 0.69 ∆ log scalei
(0.15)

(0.25)

(5)

where i represents 3-digit SIC industry (based on IPUMS 1950 coding, which
allows us to link it to IPUMS data on schooling levels of workers in each industry), ∆sharei is the absolute change in the percentage share of industry
in total payroll payments between 1959 and 1997. The positive coefficient on
∆ log scalei , the change in log employees per establishment, is significant at the
one percent level. That is, industries that have grown in share have been the
industries whose scale has increased.
This result is robust in two important ways. First, excluding the five largest
and five smallest changes in shares still yields an estimate that is positive and
still significant at a five percent level. Second, the relationship is not simply
capturing the relationship between growth and skill intensity observed in Buera
and Kaboski (2007). Controlling for skilli , the fraction of labor in an industry
that was college-educated in 194029 , yields the following estimates:
∆sharei = −0.31 + 0.71 ∆ log scalei + 5.01 skilli
(0.11)

(0.24)

(1.75)

(6)

The coefficient on ∆ log scalei is nearly identical and still significant at a one
percent level. Thus, growth in scale appears to be independently related to the
growth of disaggregate services.

4.2

Summary

We have presented theory and evidence of three phases of growth that include:
(1) an early introduction of scale technologies leading to industrialization and
a relative decline in the importance of agricultural output; (2) a somewhat
later expansion of industry associated with mass consumption, and (3) still
later expansion of services with the growth in their scale (which we develop in
Section 4). Figure 5 illustrates these three phases of structural change in the
model economy.

5
5.1

Extensions
Heterogeneity in the Scale of Services

So far, we have only considered two dimensions of heterogeneity: in the complexity of wants (z), and in the difference in fixed costs (q) and scale (n) of goods
vs. services. Presumably, there is ample heterogeneity in the scale technology
2 9 Using the fraction that was college-educated in 2000 yields similar results for the role of
scale, though the coefficient on skill is somewhat smaller given the higher education levels.

21

1
Agriculture
Services
Manufactured

0.9
0.8
0.7

Phase II

Share of Output

Phase I

Phase III

0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0

20

40

60

Time

80

100

120

Figure 5: Evolution of Structural Change in the Model Economy
even within services. On one side of the spectrum, we find clothing services that
requires relatively minor and divisible investments and, with the exception of
specialized clothing items like tuxedos, are seldom provided in the market. On
the other side are long distance travel services which require huge and lumpy
investments and, at least initially, tend to be provided in the market. In this
section we consider a simple extension of the basic model that incorporates this
diversity.
As before, we assume a continuum of wants indexed by their complexity
z ∈ [0, +∞), each want requiring the production of manufactured inputs to be
used with labor to produced the final service. In this extension, however, we
allow for multiple wants of a given complexity z with different technologies to
produce final services. To simplify the analysis, we consider two types of wants
differing in the size of required specialized manufacturing inputs , i.e., i = 1, 2,
¡
¢
¡
¢
1
1
with q1 < q2 , 1 + q1 < γ 1 + q1 and 1 + q2 < γ 1 + q2 .30
n
n
In this simple extension, the evolution of the economy is divided in four
stages characterized by three critical dates: t01 , t02 and t1 . In the first subperiod, all production is done using the traditional technology. This first stage,
t ∈ (−∞, t01 ), mimics the traditional economy in the model described in the
h λ−1
i
1
previous section with t01 = g log 2 2 (1 + q1 ) .
3 0 It is straightforward to generalize this model to the case of a continuum of wants of a
given complexity z, each of these wants indexed by the size of the fixed cost to provide the
final service q ∈ [0, ∞). In this model, there would be effectively two types of wants: i) those
(1/γ−1)
that are industrialized without the marketization of services, q ≤ 1−1/(γn) (> 0 provided
γn < 1); and ii) those that are (later) industrialized with the initial marketization of services,
(1/γ−1)
q > 1−1/(γn) .

22

The second stage, t ∈ [t01 , t02 ), starts when it becomes profitable to use the
modern technology for ¡
type 1 (small manufactured input requirement). In this
¢
1
stage, since 1 + q1 < γ 1 + q1 , households directly purchase the intermediate
n
manufactured inputs and home produce the final services themselves. Thus, this
stage is characterized by a rise of manufacturing production and consumption
relative to both agriculture/basic wants and services. The provision of clothing
services is an example of such a want.
The third stage, t ∈ [t02 , t1 ), is initiated when it becomes profitable to also
use the modern technology for type 2 wants. Given their large manufactured
¡
¢
1
input requirements, 1+q2 > γ 1 + q2 , type 2 services these are initially market
n
produced. In this stage, both manufacturing and (market) services production
and consumption rises relative to agriculture/basic wants. The provision of
long distance transportation services with steam-engine locomotives are a clear
example of these services.
The last stage is given by transition to home production of these type 2
services. This stage corresponds to the rise of mass consumption described in
the model studied in the previous section, and is also characterized by rise in
manufacturing production and consumption relative to both agriculture/basic
wants and modern services.
This extention highlights another force leading to a rise of manufacturing
production and consumption relative to both traditional sectors and modern
services: the early modernization of wants that are characterized by relatively
small scale technologies to provide the final service. As it was the case with the
rise of mass consumption that we discuss in the previous section, the difference
in the scale of production between home and market production of services, and
among different market services, is at the center of the process of structural
change.

5.2

Explicit Durability/Capital

In this section, we extend the basic model to allow for the durability of intermediate manufactured (capital) inputs. This is more in line with much of the
earlier motivation which involves home durables and market capital goods. It
also shows how the model maps into a more standard dynamic model that has
similarities to the standard neoclassical growth model, but also yields insight
into sectoral allocations.
In particular, we assume that each intermediate input faces one-hoss-shay
depreciation at a constant hazard rate δ. As before, there is a continuum of
wants indexed by z that are provided using labor and capital as inputs. For
simplicity, we only consider the limit case where the modern technology is used
in the production of all wants.
The preferences over the various wants within a period are still represented
by the utility function (1), while the intertemporal preferences are represented
the following time-separable utility function:

23

Z

∞

e−ρt U (C (t)) dt

(7)

0

R +∞
where C(t) = zA [h (z, t) + γ (1 − h (z, t))] c (z, t) dz and U (.) is a strictly increasing and concave function.
To simplify the exposition, we consider a decentralization in which households own the durable goods used in home production while the capital used
by the market sector is owned by a competitive holding company. Under this
assumption, the household’s problem simplifies to maximize (7) by choosing the
stock of durable goods used in home-production z (t), the purchases of durable
goods d (t), the most complex want that is purchase in the market z (t), and the
¯
stock of bonds B (t) subject to the time-t budget constraint
∂B (t)
+
∂t

Z

z (t)
¯

z(t)

ps (z, t) dz + d (t) = rB (t) + 1 −

Z

z(t)

−∞

dz
A (z, t)

where the left-hand side gives the purchases of new bonds, market services and
durable goods and the right-hand side the capital and labor income; and the
law of motion for the stock of durable goods
∂K d (t)
= δK d (t) + d (t)
∂t
R z(t)
where K d (t) = qs −∞ pm (z, t) dz, as all wants with complexity z < z (t) are
home-produced and therefore qs units of capital is required for production.
Standard optimal control arguments can be used to derive the dynamic system implied by the consumer’s problem. In what follows we describe a balanced
growth path of this system.
−σC
Provided U (C) = − e σ , a balanced growth path exists and is characterized
by the following two equations:
r =ρ+σ

g
λ

and
pm (z, t) qs (r + g + δ) +

1
ps (¯, t)
z
− ps (z, t) = (1 − γ)
A (z, t)
γ

The first condition, the Euler equation, equates the interest rate to the rate
g
of time preference plus a multiple of the growth rate, λ . The second condition
equates the marginal cost of expanding the set of home-produced goods to the
marginal return. The marginal cost (left-hand side) is given by the sum of the
1
rental cost, pm (z, t) qs (r + g + δ) and the labor costs, A(z,t) , net of the savings
associated with not having to satisfied this want in the market, ps (z, t). The
marginal return (right-hand side) is proportional to the utility gain of homeproduction relative to market consumption of a given want, 1 − γ. This last

24

condition determines the (constant) width of the set of services that are provided
by the market, z (t) − z (t).
¯
The model with durability allows us to study the effect of an increase in the
cost of capital on the structural composition of consumption of this economy.
Proposition: The share of services in consumption cs is a decreasing function
of the cost of capital r.
A larger cost of capital, due to a larger discount rate ρ or capital distortions,
leads to a bigger cost advantage of market services that use more “efficiently”
the capital input. Interestingly, this result is independent of whether services
are more or less capital intensive than manufactures.31

6

Conclusions

This paper has incorporated the efficient scale of productive units into theory of
structural change. In particular, the introduction of large scale technologies, and
the distinction between the scale of production in manufacturing, market services, and home produced services, help provide a unified explanation for broad
trends of structural transformation, including not only scale, but also sectoral
movements, and rich product cycles between home and market production.
We have also presented a potentially important explanatory factor in understanding the recent growth of the service economy: the increasing scale of
services, and the increasing importance of large scale services. To the extent,
that these large scale technologies may be improperly classified as services, these
trends have implications for revisiting sectoral definitions in national income accounts.
Our emphasis on the importance of scale is relevant to the definition of
the service sector in national accounting classification schemes. In particular,
the NAICS system, which was instituted in the 1990s, moved in principle to
a production method concept of industry. Still, it moved many large-scale information industries such as software publishing, printing, and motion pictures
were classified into the service sector, while smaller scale activities such as bakeries and customized goods production were moved into manufacturing. Such
classifications based on the content of what is produced rather than the production method lead to a less meaningful distinction between the sectors. Perhaps
such classifications need to be revisited.
3 1 In

this economy, the capital shares equals
αm =

qm
(r + δ + g) and αs =
nm
1+

qs
ns
qs
ns

(r + δ + g)

−

qm
nm

,

(r + δ + g)

for manufactures and for services. Thus, as long as r (t) = r, we get constant factor shares.
q
q
Furthermore, if ns = nm both sectors have the same capital intensity, αs = αm = α. Notice
s
m
that constant factor shares across sectors are consistent with manufactures operating at a
larger scale, i.e., both nm À ns and qm À qs .

25

A

Proof of the Results in the Paper

The various results in the paper follow from the characterization of the household’s problem. In this appendix we provide a characterization of this problem
and we relate this characterization to the propositions in the paper.
The household chooses the set of wants to home produce using the traditional
technology, z ∈ [0, z0 ], the set of wants to home produce using the modern
technology, z ∈ (z0 , z], and the set of want to market purchase, z ∈ (z, z ], where
¯
z0 ≤ z ≤ z . Thus, households choose thresholds z0 , z and z to maximize
¯
¯
max

0≤z0 ≤z≤¯
z

(1 − γ) z + γ z
¯

subject to the budget constraint
Z z
Z z
Z
¯
qpM (z, t) dz +
pS (z, t) dz = 1 −
z0

z

z0
0

−gt

zdz − e

Z

z

z λ dz

z0

¡
¢
q
where pM (z, t) = e−gt z λ and pS (z, t) = 1 + n pM (z, t). The first-order conditions are
γ + θ2 = μpS (¯, t)
z
(8)
£ −gt λ
¤
(1 − γ) + θ1 − θ2 = μ e z + qpM (z, t) − pS (z, t)
(9)
and

£
¤
λ
−θ1 = μ z0 − e−gt z0 − qpM (z0 , t)

(10)

where μ is the Lagrange multiplier of the budget constraint, while θ1 and θ2 are
the Lagrange multipliers of the inequality constraints, z0 ≤ z ≤ z .
¯
There are four cases to be considered. The analysis of Cases 1-3 provides a
proof of Proposition 2 (Industrialization), while Proposition 3 (Mass Consumption) is proven in the discussion of Case 4.
Case 1: z0 =z= ¯ (traditional economy) In this case, all production is
z
done at home using the traditional technology. The most complex want that is
satisfied using the traditional technology solves:
Z z0
zdz = 1
0

or

1

z0 = 2 2 .
This corresponds to the pre-industrial economy in which the set of wants
that are satisfied remains constant over time. This will be the optimal solution
as long as the following inequalities are satisfied
γ ≤ μpS (¯, t) ,
z
£ −gt λ
¤
(1 − γ) ≥ μ e z + qpM (z, t) − pS (z, t) ,
26

and
1

£
¤
λ
0 ≥ μ z0 − e−gt z0 − qpM (z0 , t)

λ
=
¯
for z0 ¢ z = z = 2 2 . Substituting in for pM (z0 , t) = e−gt z0 , pS (z0 , t) =
¡
1
q
1 + n pM (z0 , t), and z0 = z = z = 2 2 , and combining the three inequalities
¯
we obtain the following condition on t
¾
½
³
1
q ´ e−gt λ
−gt λ
2 2 ≤ min (1 + q) e 2 2 , 1 +
22 .
n
γ

That is, Case 1 holds for a sufficiently early date, i.e., t < t0 with
½
µ
¾¶
λ−1
1
1³
q´
2
t0 = log 2
min (1 + q) ,
1+
.
g
γ
n

z
Case 2: z0 =z< ¯ (industrialization with marketization of services)
In this instance, the first-order conditions simplify to
³
q ´ −gt λ
γ =μ 1+
¯
(11)
e z ,
n
h
³
q ´ −gt λ i
(1 − γ) = μ z0 − 1 +
(12)
e z0
n
and
Z z0
Z ¯
³
q ´ −gt z λ
1+
z dz = 1 −
zdz
(13)
e
n
0
z0

Combining (11) and (12) and integrating (13) yields two simple equations
in z and z0
¯
³
³
γ h
q ´ −gt λ i
q ´ −gt λ
¯
1+
(14)
e z =
z0 − 1 +
e z0
n
1−γ
n
and
2
1 ³
q ´ −gt λ+1 z0
1 ³
q ´ −gt λ+1
¯
+
(15)
1+
e z
−
1+
e z0 = 1
λ+1
n
2
λ+1
n
Equations (14) and (15) define an upward and a downward sloping curve in the
¯
(¯, z0 ) space, respectively. It is straightforward to see that ∂ z /∂t > 0 as both
z
curves move upward with productivity. The effect of technological progress on
the upper bound of the set of wants that are home produced using the traditional
technology z0 is given by
gt

∂z0
=−
∂t

e
−gγ (1+q/n)

h

λ+1
e−gt (1+q/n)

"

λ (1 − γ) −
|

³
1−

2
z0
2

´

λ+1
+ z0

i− 2λ+1 h ¡
¢ λ
λ+1
2
λ 1 − z0 /2 z0 +

1
e−gt (1+q/n)
λ+1
λ+1
2
e−gt (1+q/n) (1 − z0 /2) + z0
λ
z0 −

{z

+

<0 (second order conditions)

27

2
1−z0 /2 gt
(1+q/n) e

λ−1
z0

λ
z0 −

1
e−gt (1+q/n)

#
}

λ+2
+ z0

i

< 0.

Case 2 corresponds to the optimal solution if the following set of inequalities
are satisfied:
½
¾
³
q´ 1
λ
λ
z0 ≤ z0 e−gt (1 + q)and z0 > z0 e−gt min (1 + q) , 1 +
(16)
{z
}
|
n γ
{z
}
|
i.e., z0 =z
i.e., z0 <max{z,¯}
z

¡
¢
q 1
Together the conditions in (16) imply 1 + n γ < (1 + q), the expression in
Proposition 2.
Alternatively, these conditions can be expressed in terms of t, where t0 =
³ λ−1 ¡
¢´
q
1
1
log 2 2 γ 1 + n < t < t1 ,
g
t1 = −

1−λ
log {T } ,
2g

"

µ

and

T

= (1 + q/n) (1 + q)
> 0.

λ+1
1−λ

1
λ+1

γ
1−γ

¶ λ+1 µ
λ

#
¶ λ+1
λ
1 1+q
1+q
1
+
−1
−
1 + q/n
2 1 + q/n λ + 1

z
Case 3: z0 <z= ¯ (industralization without marketization of services) For this case, the first order conditions simplify to
£
¤
1 = μ e−gt z λ + qe−gt z λ ,
(17)
λ
λ
z0 − e−gt z0 − qe−gt z0 = 0

(18)

and

2
¤
1 £ −gt λ+1
z0
λ+1
− e−gt z0
=1
(19)
+ (1 + q)
e z
2
λ+1
Using (18) we obtain a simple log-linear solution for the upper bound of the set of
g
1
wants produced with the traditional technology log z0 = 1−λ log (1 + q) − 1−λ t.
Clearly the upper bound on the set of wants that are consumed (z) increases
overtime.
¡
¢
q 1
This will be the solution provided 1 + n γ > (1 + q) and t ≥ t0 .
This completes the proof of Proposition 2. The discussion of Case 4 provides
a proof of Proposition 3.

Case 4: z0 <z< ¯ (rise of mass consumption) This corresponds to
z
the situation after the rise of mass consumption. In this case, the first order
conditions simplify to
³
q ´ −gt λ
γ =μ 1+
¯
(20)
e z ,
n
³
i
h
´
q −gt λ
(21)
(1 − γ) = μ e−gt z λ + qe−gt z λ − 1 +
e z ,
n
28

λ
z0 − (1 + q) e−gt z0 = 0,

(22)

and
¢
¡
q
2
¤
¤
1 + n £ −gt λ+1
z0
(1 + q) £ −gt λ+1
−gt λ+1
− e z0
¯
− e−gt z λ+1 = 1.
+
+
e z
e z
2
λ+1
λ+1
(23)
This corresponds to the optimal solution if the following set of inequalities
are satisfied:
³
q´ 1
1+
< 1 + q and t > t1 .
n γ
Equation (22) can be solved for z0
log z0 =

1
g
log (1 + q) −
t
1−λ
1−λ

Using (20) and (21) we obtain a log-linear relationship between z and z
¯
!
Ã
¢
¡
q
(1 − γ) 1 + n
1
¡
¢
log z = log
+ log z
¯
1
λ
γq 1 − n

Finally, using (23) it is straightforward to see that z and z increase over time.
¯
Proof of Proposition 3: In the long run, the share of services in output (ys )
equal:

ys

=

=

Rz
¯

Rz q
¯
p (z, t) dz − z n pM (z, t) dz
z S
Rz
Rz
¯
qpM (z, t) dz + z pS (z, t) dz
0
Rz λ
¯
z dz
z
¡
¢Rz
Rz
¯ λ
λ dz + 1 + q
q 0 z
z dz
n
z

z λ+1 − z λ+1
¯
¡
¢
¡
¢
q
λ+1 − 1 + q − q z λ+1
1+ n z
¯
n
¶
µ
q
(1−γ)(1+ n )
+ (λ + 1) log z
¯
using that (λ + 1) log z = λ+1 log
1
λ
γq (1− n )
¶ λ+1
µ
q
λ
(1−γ)(1+ n )
1−
1
γq (1− n )
ys =
¶ λ+1
µ
q
¢ (1−γ)(1+ n ) λ
¡
¢ ¡
q
q
1+ n − 1+ n −q
1
γq (1− n )
=

Defining X =

µ

q
(1−γ)(1+ n )
1
γq (1− n )

¶ λ+1
λ

, we get

29

∂ys
∂X
q
q (1 − X)
= − £¡
+ £¡
¢
¤2
¢
¤2 > 0
q
q
∂n
∂n
1 + n (1 − X) + qX
1 + n (1 − X) + qX
since

A.1

∂X
∂n

=−

³

(1−γ)
γq

´ λ+1 µ
λ

q
(1+ n )
1
(1− n )

¶ λ+1 −1 ∙
λ

q
1
1
n2 1− n

+

q
1 (1+ n )
n2 (1− 1 )2
n

¸

< 0.

Explicit Durability

In the model with durable intermediate (capital) inputs, the household’s problem simplifies to
Z ∞
e−ρt U ((1 − γ) z (t) + γ z (t)) dt
¯
max
B(t), z(t), d(t), z (t)
¯

0

s.t.
∂B (t)
+
∂t

Z

z (t)
¯

z(t)

ps (z, t) dz + d (t) = rB (t) + 1 −

and

Z

z(t)

−∞

dz
A (z, t)

∂K d (t)
= δK d (t) + d (t)
∂t

R z(t)
where K d (t) = qs −∞ pm (z, t) dz.
The Hamiltonian of this problem is given by
∙
Z
¯
H (t) = u ((1 − γ) z + γ z ) + θ 1 + rB −

z

−∞

1
d
+μ
qs pm (z, t)

dz
− δqs
A (z, t)

Z

z

−∞

pm (z, t) dz −

The Principle of the Maximum implies
u0 (C) γ = θps (¯, t)
z

(24)

˙
−θ = (r − ρ) θ

(25)

−μ = −ρμ + u0 (C) (1 − γ)
˙
∙
¸
1
1
d
∂pm (z, t)
−θ
(26)
+ δqs pm (z, t) − ps (z, t) − μ
A (z, t)
qs pm (z, t)2
∂z
and
30

Z

z

z
¯

ps (z, t) dz − d

¸

θ (t) =

1 μ (t)
qs pm (z, t)

(27)

Performing standard manipulations we obtain the Euler equation
¸
∙
∂ z (t)
¯
1
∂ps (¯, t) ∂ z
¯
z
∂z (t)
+γ
=r−ρ−
+g
σ (1 − γ)
∂t
∂t
ps (¯, t)
z
∂z
∂t

(28)

and an equation for the equality of marginal cost of durables to the marginal
return of durables
qs pm (z, t) (r + g + δ) +

1
1−γ
z
− ps (z, t) =
ps (¯, t)
A (z, t)
γ

(29)

Holding Company’s Problem
We assume that there is a competitive holding company that owns the capital
stock used by the market sector. In particular, the holding company purchases
manufacturing goods and rents these for a rental price R (z, t) to maximize the
present value of profits
Z ∞Z ∞
e−rt [R (z, t) k (z, t) − I (z, t) pm (z, t)] dzdt
0

−∞

subject to the law of motion for each type of capital
˙
k (z, t) = I (z, t) − δk (z, t)
The firm’s problem solves the following Hamiltonian problem,
Z ∞
{[R (z, t) k (z, t) − I (z, t) pm (z, t)] + κ (z, t) [I (z, t) − δk (z, t)]} dz
H (t) =
−∞

Necessary conditions are:
κ (z, t) = pm (z, t)
−κ (z, t) = R (z, t) − rκ (z, t) − κ (z, t) δ
˙
implying
µ
R (z, t) = pm (z, t) r + δ −
Producer’s Problem

31

1
∂pm (z, t)
pm (z, t)
∂t

¶

(30)

Competitive firms produce market services and manufacturing goods. Zero
profits imply
pm (z, t) =

1
qm
R (z, t)
+
A (z, t) nm

ps (z, t) =

1
qs
+ R (z, t) .
A (z, t) ns

and

Using (30), we get
µ
¶
1
1
qm
∂pm (z, t)
pm (z, t) =
pm (z, t) r + δ −
+
.
A (z, t) nm
pm (z, t)
∂t
Guessing

∂pm (z,t)
1
pm (z,t)
∂t

= −g and using A (z, t) = egt−λz ,

pm (z, t) =
and
1+
ps (z, t) =

³

1−

qs
ns

1−

−

qm
nm

eλz−gt
(r + δ + g)

(31)

qm
nm

qm
nm

´

(r + δ + g)

(r + δ + g)

eλz−gt

(32)

q
where a bounded price of manufactured goods requires 1 − nm (r + δ + g) >
m
0. In this economy capital shares equal

αm =

qm
(r + δ + g)
nm

and
αs =
1+
qs
ns

³

qs
ns
qs
ns

(r + δ + g)
´
q
− nm (r + δ + g)
m

Thus, as long as r (t) = r we get constant factor shares. Furthermore, if
q
= nm , αs = αm = α.
m
Balanced Growth Path

g
For a balanced growth path we need to have z (t) = z (0) + λ t and z (t) =
¯
g
z (0) + λ t. Substituting these conditions into (28)
¯
h
g
gi
σ (1 − γ) + γ
=r−ρ−g+g
λ
λ
or

r =ρ+σ
32

g
λ

From (29)
qs pm (z, t) (r + g + δ) +
or
qs (r + g + δ) +

1
1−γ
z
− ps (z, t) =
ps (¯, t)
A (z, t)
γ

z
1
ps (z, t)
1 − γ ps (¯, t)
−
=
.
pm (z, t) A (z, t) pm (z, t)
γ pm (z, t)

Using (31) and (32),
µ
¶
1
qs 1 −
(r + g + δ)
ns
¶
¸
∙
µ
1−γ
qm
qs
z
=
−
(r + δ + g) eλ(¯(0)−z(0))
1+
γ
ns
nm

or

µ
¶
1
qs 1 −
ns
¶¸
∙
µ
1−γ
qm
1
qs
z
=
−
eλ(¯(0)−z(0))
+
γ
(r + g + δ)
ns
nm
The share of services in consumption equals
Rz
¯
p (z, t) dz
z s
cs =
Rz
Rz
¯
δqs −∞ pm (z, t) dz + qs ∂z pm (z, t) + z ps (z, t) dz
∂t

or

´
i¡
³
¢
q
q
z
1 + ns − nm (r + δ + g) eλ(¯(0)−z(0)) − 1
s
m
´
i¡
³
cs = ¡
¢
¢ h
g
q
q
z
qs δ + λ + 1 + ns − nm (r + δ + g) eλ(¯(0)−z(0)) − 1
s
m
h

(33)

Proof of Proposition: Differentiating (33) with respect to the cost of
capital we obtain
¡
¢
g
qs δ + λ
∂cs
∂A
=£ ¡
¢
¤2
g
∂r
qs δ + λ + A ∂r
h
³
´
i¡
¢
q
q
z
where A = 1 + ns − nm (r + δ + g) eλ(¯(0)−z(0)) − 1 , and
s
m
∂A
∂r

=

µ

+

qm
qs
−
ns
nm

1−γ
γ

¶

(r + g + δ)

1−γ
γ

³
´
1
¶
µ
qs 1 − ns
qm
qs
h
³
´
i−
−
q
q
ns nm
1 + ns − nm (r + g + δ)
s
m

³
´
1
qs 1 − ns
h
³
´
i
q
q
1 + ns − nm (r + g + δ)
s
m
33

qs
ns

qm
nm
³

> 0, then ∂A > 0 as the first two terms on the right-hand-side are
´ £ ∂r
¤
q
q
z
equal to ns − nm eλ(¯(0)−z(0)) − 1 and are therefore positive. In the case
s
m
qs
qm
ns − nm < 0, we know that the sum of the first and third terms are positive as
³
´
qs
qm
ns − nm (r + g + δ) + 1 > 0.
If

−

34

References
[1] Acemoglu, D. and V. Guerrieri. “Capital Deepening and Non-Balanced
Economic Growth.” mimeo, MIT (2005).
[2] Aguiar, M. and Hurst, E. “Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of
Time over Five Decades.” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper
No. 06-2
[3] Alessandria, G. and J. P. Kaboski. “Violating Purchasing Power Parity,”
mimeo Ohio State University (2006).
[4] Atack, J. and F. Bateman "Nineteenth Century American Industrial Development Through the Eyes of the Census of Manufactures: A New Resource
for Historical Research," Historical Methods, 32, 4: (Fall 1999), 177-188.
[5] Banerjee, A. and Duflo, E. “Growth Theory through the Lens of Economic
Development.” in Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 1a. Amserdam: Elsevier, 2005, pp. 473-552
[6] Banerjee, Abhijit and Andrew Newman. “Occupational Choice and the
Process of Development.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274298.
[7] Baumol, William J. “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The
Anatomy of the Urban Crisis,” The American Economic Review 57 (1967)
: 415-426.
[8] Becker, G. “A Theory of the Allocation of Time.” Economic Journal 75,
299 (September 1965): 493-517.
[9] Berg, M. "Factories, Workshops, and Industrial Organization" In Roderick
Floud and D.N. McCloskey, eds., The Economic History of Britain since
1700, 2nd ed., Vol. I, (1994) pp. 123-50.
[10] Broadberry, S., Market Services and the Productivity Race: British Performace in International Perspective, New York: Cambridge University Press,
2006.
[11] Buera, F. and Kaboski, J. “The Rise of the Service Economy” mimeo,
October, 2006.
[12] Buera, F. and Y. Shin “Financial Frictions and the Persistence of History:
A Quantitative Exploration,” mimeo Northwestern University and the University of Wisconsin-Madisson, 2006.
[13] Alfred Chandler, Scale and Scope, Cambridge: Harvard University Press,
1990.
[14] Chenery H. Structural Change and Development Policy. Washington, D.C.:
Oxford University Press, for the World Bank (1979).
35

[15] Chenery H. and M. Syrquin. Patterns of Development. Oxford University
Press (1975).
[16] Clark, C. The Conditions of Economic Progress. London: Macmillan
(1941).
[17] Phyllis Deane and W. A. Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959:
Trends and Structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, second edition, 1967.
[18] Echevarria, C. “Changes in Sectoral Composition Associated with Economic Growth,” International Economic Review 38 (1997): 431-452.
[19] Engel, E. "Die Productions- und Consumptionsverhaeltnisse des Koenigsreichs Sachsen," Zeitschrift des Statistischen Bureaus des Koniglich Sachsischen Ministeriums des Inneren, No. 8 und 9. Reprinted in the Appendix of
Engel (1895).
[20] Engel, E. “Die Lebenskosten Belgischer Arbeiter-Familien Frueher und
Jetzt,” International Statistical Institute Bulletin, 1895
[21] Fisher, A.G.B. “Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Production,” Economic
Record 15, June 1939, 24—38.
[22] Foellmi, R. and J. Zweimuller. “Structural Change, Engel’s Consumption
Cycles and Kaldor’s Facts of Economic Growth.” mimeo, University of
Zurich (2005).
[23] Fuchs, V. The Service Economy. New York: National Bureau of Economic
Research (1968).
[24] Gollin, D., Parente, S. and R. Rogerson “Homework, Farmwork, and International Differences in Productivity”, Review of Economic Dynamics 7
(2004), 827-850.
[25] Greenwood, J., A. Seshadri and M. Yorukoglu “Engines of Liberation.”
Review of Economic Studies, Jan 2005, v.72, n.1: 109-134.
[26] Haddad, C. (1974). Growth of Brazilian Real Output, 1900-1947. Doctoral
Dissertation, University of Chicago.
[27] Hall, R. and C. Jones. “The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending,”
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Forthcoming.
[28] Hansen, G. and E. C. Prescott. “Malthus to Solow,” American Economic
Review 92, September 2002, pages 1205-1217.
[29] Hoffmann, Walther G. Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der
Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts, Berlin: Springer, 1965.

36

[30] Hoffmann, Walther G. and J. Heinz Müller. Das deutsche Volkseinkommen
1851—1957. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr, 1959.
[31] Houthakker, H. S. “An International Comparison of Household Patterns,
Commemorating the Century of Engel’s Law,” Econometrica, 25, 532-551,
1957
[32] Hsieh, C.-T. and P. Klenow “Relative Prices and Relative Prosperity.”
American Economic Review, forthcoming
[33] Johnston, D. C. “In the New Economics: Fast-Food Factories?” The New
York Times, February 20, 2004, Friday.
[34] Katona, George, The Mass Consumption Society, New York: McGraw-Hill,
1964.
[35] Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie. “Beyond Balanced Growth,” Review
of Economic Studies 68 (2001): 869-882.
[36] Kravis, I.; A. Heston and R. Summers. “The Share of Services in Economic
Growth,” in Global Econometrics: Essays in Honor of Lawrence R. Klein,
eds. F. Gerard Adams and Bert G. Hickman, (1984).
[37] Kuznets, S. “Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: II.
Industrial Distribution of National Product and Labor Force.” Economic
Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 5, No. 4, Supplement (Jul., 1957),
pp. 1-111.
[38] Kuznets, S. “Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections.” The
American Economic Review, Vol. 63, No. 3 (Jun., 1973), pp. 247-258.
[39] Lagakos, D. “Explaining Cross-Country Productivity Differences in Retailing,” mimeo University of California at Los Angeles (2007).
[40] Lebergott, Stanley (1996). Consumer expenditures: New measures and old
motives. Princenton: Princeton University Press.
[41] Lee, D. and Wolpin, K. (2006a) “Intersectoral Labor Mobility and the
Growth of Service Sector,” Econometrica, 47,January, 2006, 1-46
[42] Lee, D. and Wolpin, K. (2006b) “Accounting for Wage and Employment
Changes in the U.S. from 1968-2000: A Dynamic Model of Labor Market
Equilibrium.” mimeo, January, 2006.
[43] Lloyd-Ellis, Huw and Dan Bernhardt. “Enterprise, Inequality and Economic Development.” Review of Economic Studies 67 (2000): 147-168.
[44] Locay, L. “Economic Development and the Division of Production between
Households and Markets.” Journal of Political Economy, 98 (1990): 965-82.

37

[45] Maddison, A. “Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist Economies:
Techniques of Quantitative Assessment,” Journal of Economic Literature
25 (1987): 649-698.
[46] Matsuyama, K. “A Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods under
Nonhomothetic Preferences: Demand Complementarities, Income Distribution, and North-South Trade, Journal of Political Economy 108 (2000):
1093-1120.
[47] Matsuyama, K. “The Rise of Mass Consumption Societies,” Journal of
Political Economy 110 (2002): 1035-1070.
[48] Mitchell, B. R. International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750-2000. New
York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003
[49] Mokyr, J. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic
Progress. New York and London: Oxford University Press, 1990.
[50] Mokyr, J. “The Rise and Fall of the Factory System: Technology, firms, and
households since the Industrial Revolution” Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, 55 (December 2001), pp.1-45.
[51] Murphy, K., Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny “Income Distribution, Market Size,
and Industrialization,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (August 1989):
537-64.
[52] National Resources Planning Board, Family Expenditures in the United
States: Statistical Tables and Appendixes, Washington: U.S. GPO, 1941,
209 pp.
[53] Ngai, R. and C. Pissarides “Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model of
Growth,” The American Economic Review, forthcoming.
[54] Ngai, R. anc C. Pissarides “Trends in Hours and Economic Growth”,
mimeo, October 2006
[55] Parente, S., Rogerson, R. and R. Wright “Homework In Development:
Household Production and the Wealth of Nations”, Journal of Political
Economy 108 (2000), 680-687.
[56] Ramey, V. and Francis, N. “A Century of Work and Leisure” NBER working paper series No. 12264, May 2006
[57] Reid, M. Economics of Household Production. New York: John Wiley and
Sons, Inc., 1934, pp. 408
[58] Rogerson, R “Structural Transformation and the Deterioration of European
Labor Markets,” mimeo, Arizona State University, September, 2005

38

[59] Rogerson, R., Rupert, P. and R. Wright “Homework in Labor Economics:
Household Production and Intertemporal Substitution”, Journal of Monetary Economics 46 (2000), 557-580.
[60] Scranton, P. Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industralization, 1865-1925. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press,
1997.
[61] Sokoloff, Kenneth L. "Was the Transition from the Artisanal Shop to the
Non-Mechanized Factory Associated with Gains in Efficiency?: Evidence
from the Manufacturing Censuses of 1820 and 1850." Explorations in Economic History, Vol. 21, No. 4, (October 1984): 351-382.
[62] Stigler, G. Trends in Employment in the Service Industries. National Bureau of Economic Analysis, 59, General Series.
[63] Stokey, N. “"A Quantitative Model of the British Industrial Revolution,
1780-1850," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 55
(2001), pp. 55-109.
[64] Vamplew, W. “Review: International Historical Statistics: The Americas
and Australasia. by B. R. Mitchell The Economic History Review, New
Series, Vol. 37, No. 3 (Aug., 1984), pp. 463-464.
[65] Vamplew, W. Australians: Historical Statistics, Fairfax, Syme & Weldon
Associates, Sydney, 1987.

39

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP-05-19

Constructing the Chicago Fed Income Based Economic Index – Consumer Price Index:
Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1983-2005
Leslie McGranahan and Anna Paulson

WP-05-20

Universal Access, Cost Recovery, and Payment Services
Sujit Chakravorti, Jeffery W. Gunther, and Robert R. Moore

WP-05-21

Supplier Switching and Outsourcing
Yukako Ono and Victor Stango

WP-05-22

Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrants’ Self-Employment Decision?
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-05-23

The Changing Pattern of Wage Growth for Low Skilled Workers
Eric French, Bhashkar Mazumder and Christopher Taber

WP-05-24

U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter
The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-21

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

The Effects of Maternal Fasting During Ramadan on Birth and Adult Outcomes
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Consumption Response to Minimum Wage Increases
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

6