View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The Role of Housing in Labor
Reallocation
Morris Davis, Jonas Fisher, and
Marcelo Veracierto

November 29, 2010
WP 2010-18

The Role of Housing in Labor Reallocation∗
Morris Davis
University of Wisconsin

Jonas Fisher
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Marcelo Veracierto
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
November 29, 2010

Abstract: This paper builds a dynamic general equilibrium model of cities and
uses it to analyze the role of local housing markets and moving costs in determining
the character and extent of labor reallocation in the US economy. Labor reallocation in
the model is driven by idiosyncratic city-specific productivity shocks, which we measure
using a dataset that we compile using more than 350 U.S. cities for the years 1984 to
2008. Based on this measurement, we find that our model is broadly consistent with the
city-level evidence on net and gross population flows, employment, wages and residential
investment. We also find that the location-specific nature of housing is more important
than moving costs in determining labor reallocation. Absent this quasi-fixity of housing,
and under various assumptions governing population flows, population and employment
would be much more volatile than observed.
Keywords: Migration, Cities, Housing markets, Labor markets.
JEL classification: J61, R23, R31
VERY PRELIMINARY

∗
We have benefited from the comments of seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, UCLA and Universidad Torcuato Di Tella. The views express here do not necessarily reflect
the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.

“The bigger issue is mismatch. Firms have jobs, but can’t find appropriate workers. The workers want to work, but can’t find appropriate jobs. There are many possible
sources of mismatch–geography, skills, demography–and they probably interact in nontrivial ways. For example, there may be jobs available in eastern Montana and western
North Dakota because of the oil boom. But a household in Nevada that is underwater
on its mortgage may find it difficult to move to those locations.”
(Narayana Kochelakota, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Sept. 8, 2010)

1

Introduction

The purpose of this paper is to analyze the role of housing in labor reallocation. Understanding this
role has become increasingly important in recent times. After a long period of low vacancies and high
unemployment in the aftermath of the recent financial crisis, vacancies have increased substantially
while unemployment has remained high. This has raised questions about why unemployed workers
are not being matched to the additional job openings. A possible answer is the one suggested by
the Minneapolis Fed President in the above quote: because of being underwater on their mortgages,
moving costs of some homeowners have risen, inducing them to stay in their current homes instead
of moving to cities with better job opportunities. Our ultimate goal is to evaluate this possibility.
In the current draft we pursue a more modest goal: To construct a framework in which such an
analysis can be performed. The basic question that we will address is if the model can reproduce
salient features of U.S. data on net and gross population flows, employment, wages, house prices,
and residential investment at the city level. We then use our model to assess the relative importance
of local housing markets versus moving costs in determining the magnitude of the population flows
observed in the U.S. economy.
In order to provide a guide for selecting the model economy and assessing its empirical plausibility we construct an annual panel data set for more than 350 Metropolitan Statistical Areas
(MSAs) over the 1984-2008 period. We find that these data have the following properties: 1)
wages and employment fluctuate significantly relative to their cross-sectional means, 2) employment fluctuations are double those of population, 3) gross population flows are about ten times
larger than net population flows, 4) house prices fluctuate about five times more than population,
and 5) residential construction is extremely volatile, fluctuating much more than population. The
substantial fluctuations in wages and employment suggest that cities must be subject to significant

1

idiosyncratic shocks. In turn, the large gross population flows indicate that moving costs must be
relatively small. Since net population flows are small this means that cities must have some type of
quasi-fixed factor pinning down their sizes. Housing is a natural candidate, since houses cannot be
moved across cities and since house prices fluctuate so much. The large volatility in construction
seems to contradict the view that housing is in quasi-fixed supply. However, it is consistent with
a binding irreversibility constraint on residential investment, which in turn may contribute to the
large fluctuations in house prices. Another factor that may contribute to the quasi-fixity of housing
and to the large fluctuations in house prices is that housing services are produced not only with
construction materials, but also with land, which by nature is in fixed supply. These considerations
underly the specification of our model economy.
Our model is a version of the Lucas and Prescott (6) islands economy in which islands are
interpreted as cities. Local housing services are produced using structures and local land. Housing
structures can be accumulated over time, but are subject to an irreversibility constraint. The local
stock of land is in fixed supply. Firms produce city-specific goods using capital and local labor as
inputs with a technology that is subject to city-specific idiosyncratic productivity shocks. Capital
is freely movable across cities, but labor is not. At the beginning of every period agents must
decide whether to stay in their current city or move. Agents must also move when they receive an
exogenous reallocation shock. Moving to a different city requires the payment of a fixed cost. Once
the moving cost is paid, agents can move to any city of their choice within the period. Once an
agent has settled in a city she must decide whether to become employed or not and the amount of
local housing services to consume. We assume perfect risk sharing across all agents in the economy.
We calibrate the model to several statistics derived from U.S. data. Some of these are closely
related to the neoclassical growth model, such as the interest rate, the labor share, the business
capital to output ratio and the business investment to output ratio. Additional observations that
we bring to bare on the model are the residential capital to output ratio, the residential investment
to output ratio and the share of land in house prices. In our benchmark case we use an elasticity
of substitution between goods that is commonly used in the trade literature. However, we consider
higher elasticities as well. We estimate the idiosyncratic productivity shock process using the
first order conditions determining efficient input use by firms, the technology parameters already
calibrated, and our panel data on employment and wages. The utility of leisure and the fixed
moving cost are treated as free parameters to match the standard deviations of employment and
population.
We find that the model is broadly consistent with the volatility and contemporaneous co-

2

movement of key model variables. However, the model fails to reproduce the volatility of house
prices and the serial correlation in employment, population and house prices observed in U.S. data.
This indicates that the model lacks a mechanism at the city level for propagating idiosyncratic
productivity shocks. With these caveats in mind we turn to analyze the importance of moving
costs versus local housing in determining the size of the net population flows observed in the
U.S. economy. We do this by considering two experiments. In the first experiment we set the
moving costs to zero. In the second experiment we allow housing to freely reallocate across cities.
Abstracting from exogenous population attrition, we find that moving costs are more important
than the fixity of housing in determining population volatility. This result is reversed when we
introduce exogenous population attrition. A robust finding, though, is that the fixity of housing
always play an important role in net population reallocation: In the most conservative case it
reduces the standard deviation of population growth rates by 37%.
Our paper is closely related to Van Nieuwerburgh and Weil (7), which also uses a Lucas-Prescott
islands economy to study cities and local housing markets. The papers differ in the models used
and in the issues analyzed. Van Nieuwerburgh and Weil abstract from labor supply decisions and
moving costs, but introduce permanent differences in the ability of agents. Their goal is to study
the effect of an increase in wage dispersion across US cities on the corresponding dispersion of house
prices. In contrast, we explicitly model labor supply decisions and moving costs (abstracting from
any differences in ability levels) in order to understand the role of housing in labor reallocation.
The paper is also related to Alvarez and Shimer (1) in that both papers use a Lucas-Prescott
islands economy and allow agents to enjoy leisure in the islands where they are located. However,
they interpret their islands as industries and use their model to analyze the behavior of wages and
unemployment. Finally, the paper is related to Kennan and Walker (4) since both papers analyze
migration decisions in the face of wage shocks and moving costs. However, they abstract from local
housing markets, assume undirected search, and do not consider any equilibrium interactions. The
structural estimation of their model suggest moving costs that are much larger than those obtained
in this paper.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data that we use in our
analysis. Section 3 describes the model economy. Section 4 describes a steady state equilibrium.
Section 5 characterizes a steady state equilibrium. Section 6 calibrates the model to U.S. data.
Finally, Section 7 presents the results.

3

2

Data

2.1

Sources

To provide an empirical underpinning to our analysis we construct an annual panel data set of
population, employment, population inflows and outflows, residential investment, house prices, and
average wage per job of a set of Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) over the 1984-2008 period.
The mappings of counties to MSAs we use (except when noted) are consistent with the definitions
given by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget (OMB) as of December, 2009.1 OMB currently
defines 366 MSAs in the United States and over our sample period, these MSAs account for about
83 percent of the aggregate population.
Our data on population, employment, and average wage per job are taken from the “Regional
Economic Accounts: Local Area Personal Income and Employment” tables as produced by the
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA).2 These annual data are available for all 366 MSAs from
1969 through 2008. The population data are from table CA1-3 and are mid-year estimates from
the Census Bureau. For employment, we use “Wage and Salary Employment,” line 20 of Table
CA25N). These are counts of full- and part- time jobs of salaried employees.3 We construct nominal
average wage per job as the sum of total wage and salary disbursements (line 50, Table CA05) and
supplements to wages and salaries (line 60, Table CA05) divided by wage and salary employment.4
We convert the nominal estimate to a real measure consistent with our model by deflating using
the CPI “All items less shelter.”5
For house prices, we use the repeat-sales house price indexes produced by the Federal Home
1

See http://www.census.gov/population/www/metroareas/lists/2009/List4.txt for these definitions.

2

These data are available at http://www.bea.gov/regional/reis/.

3

The BEA also publishes an estimate of “Total Employment,” which is the sum of wage and salary employment

and proprietors employment. The level and change of the two employment series are highly correlated. We use
wage and salary employment to be consistent with our measure of wages, described next; we do not want to include
proprietor’s income as part of wages because some of proprietor’s income represents payments to capital.
4

We construct our own measure because the BEA excludes wage and salary supplements when reporting “average

wage per job” in its Table CA34.
5

The specific CPI series we use is CUSR0000SA0L2.

http://www.bls.gov/cpi/.

4

This series is available for download at

Finance Agency (FHFA).6 These data are quarterly; for each MSA, we construct an annual estimate
as the average of all non-missing quarterly observations. All 366 MSAs have price-index data from
2001 through 2009, but prior to 2001, the time span of coverage varies by MSA. Summarizing:
Only 14 MSAs have house price indexes starting in 1976; 130 MSAs starting in 1980; 202 MSAs
starting in 1985; 326 MSAs starting in 1990, and so forth. As with average wage per job, we use the
CPI excluding shelter to convert these nominal indexes to real. For 11 MSAs, the FHFA does not
report an MSA-level index but rather a set of indexes corresponding to divisions within the MSA.7
For these MSAs, we set the level of the index for the MSA equal to the average of the reported
indexes for the underlying divisions.
Data on residential investment at the MSA-level are not available. To proxy for residential
investment, we use new housing unit building permits as collected by the Census Bureau. These
data have been organized by MSA as part of the “State of the Cities Data System” (SOCDS) that
resides on the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) Web Site.8 SOCDS reports
both monthly and annual data. We use the annual permits data, which begin in 1980 and end in
2009 — the monthly data begin in 2001. Note that the MSA-definitions in the SOCDS data are out
of date such that the experiences of only 362 MSAs (363 with one missing) rather than 366 MSAs
are available.9
We construct data on gross MSA-level population inflows and outflows using county-county
migration data based on tax records that is constructed by the Internal Revenue Service. These
data are available from 1978 through 1992 at the Inter-University Consortium for Political and
Social Research (ICPSR) web site; are available for purchase from the IRS for the 1992 - 2004
period; and are available for free on the IRS web site from 2004 through 2007. The data are annual
and cover the “filing year” period, not calendar year. For example, the data for 2007 approximately
refer to migration over the period April, 2007 to April, 2008.
For each of the years, the IRS reports the migration data using two files, one for county outflows
6

These data are available at http://www.fhfa.gov/Default.aspx?Page=87.

7

The MSAs are Boston, Chicago, Dallas, Detroit, Los Angeles, Miami, New York City, Philadelphia, San Francisco,

Seattle, and Washington, DC. Taking Boston as an example, the FHFA reports price indexes for each of the the 4
Metropolitan Divisions of the Boston MSA rather than the Boston MSA itself.
8

The data are available at http://socds.huduser.org/permits/.

9

We are in the process of constructing the appropriate MSA-level data using county-level information, also on the

SOCDS web site, but this process is not yet complete.

5

and one for county inflows, for each county in the United States. Both the inflow and the outflow
files report migrants in units of “returns” and in units of “personal exemptions.” According to
information from the IRS web site, the returns data approximates the number of households and
the personal exemptions data approximates the population.10 In the data work below, we study
the exemptions data.
In the inflow files, for every county the IRS reports the number of people that did not migrate
into that county, i.e. lived in that county for two consecutive years. It also reports, for people that
migrated into that county, each of the counties sending the migrants and the number of migrants,
although not every county sending migrants is reported: All counties sending a relatively small
number of migrants are lumped together into an “other county” category. Analogously, in the
outflow files, for every county the IRS reports the population that lived in that county for two
consecutive years (i.e., the non-migrants), and, for the people that migrated out of that county,
each of the counties receiving the migrants and their number. Like the inflows file, counties receiving
only a small number of migrants are lumped together into an “other county” category.
We define gross inflows into an MSA as the sum of all migrants into any county in that MSA, as
long as the inflows did not originate from a county within the MSA. Analogously, we define gross
outflows from an MSA as the sum of all migrants leaving any county in that MSA, as long as the
migrants did not ultimately move to another county in the MSA. In the case of gross inflows, the
originating counties are not restricted to be part of one of the 366 MSAs; and, in the case of gross
outflows, the counties receiving the migrants are not restricted to be included in one of the 366
MSAs.
Table 1 reports means, standard deviations, sample sizes and ranges for the data we use in this
study.

2.2
2.2.1

Statistics
Net Expansion and Contraction Rates

We use the BEA population data to measure net expansion  and net contraction rates   in the
U.S. Define the aggregate population in the middle of year  as  and the population in MSA  as
10

See http://www.irs.gov/taxstats/indtaxstats/article/0„id=96816,00.html for details.

6

of the end of year  as  .11 Given this, we set:
X

  =

: −1

X

   =

: −1

( − −1 )

(1)

(−1 −  )

(2)

Averaging over the 1985-2007 period, our overall sample period, we estimate the average value of
 to be 1.24 percent and the average value of   to be 004 percent. The gap between these two
values is average population growth, 120 percent over this period.
Our model does not have population growth. Define the realized aggregate population (gross)
growth rate in year  as  . To compute net expansion and net contraction rates after abstracting
from population growth, ̃ and ̃  , we assume MSAs receive new population at the aggregate rate,
and in proportion to their existing size. We compute
µ
¶
X

− −1
 ̃ =


:

 ̃  =



−1

X


:  −1

¶
µ


−1 −


(3)

(4)

We estimate the average value of ̃ and ̃  to each equal 043 percent.
2.2.2

Gross Expansion and Contraction Rates

We use the IRS data to understand gross population flows in general, and more specifically across
MSAs. Table 2 provides some detail on these data. Column (1) reports the total number of people
migrating into an MSA and column (2) reports the total number of people migrating out of an
MSA, both in millions. These data include all within-MSA migrants, including people moving to
a different county in the same MSA. Columns (1) and (2) are not exactly equal because not all
people move to and from counties included in on of the 366 defined MSAs.
Columns (3) and (4) strip out all within-MSA migration and only report across-MSA migration:
New inflows to an MSA (column 3) and outflows from an MSA (column 4), again both in millions
of people. Column (5) reports the total sample population corresponding to the IRS data for the
11

The BEA reports a middle-of-year estimate for the population. We use this estimate directly in computing  .

We compute the end-of-year population estimate  as the average value of the middle-of-year population in years
 and  + 1

7

366 MSAs.12 The population reported in column (5) is approximately equal to 65 percent of the
entire U.S. population.
Column (6) shows an estimate of the total migration rate (inclusive of both within and across
MSA moves), computed as the ratio of the average of columns (1) and (2) to column (5). Summarizing: About 6.2 percent of taxpayers move to a different county in any given year. Columns (7)
and (8) report across-MSA migration rates. Columns (7) and (8) strip out all within-MSA moves.
Column (7) is our “gross expansions rate” , the ratio of new-MSA inflows to population, defined
as the ratio of column (3) to column (5). Column (8) reports the gross contractions rate , the ratio
of MSA outflows to population, and defined as the ratio of column (4) to column (5). Columns (7)
and (8) show that about 4.3 percent of the population migrate to a different MSA in any given year.
Summarizing columns (6)-(8), about 1/3 of all moves are within-MSA moves, and 2/3 of all moves
are across-MSA moves. Finally, the last row of the table shows these migration percentages are
relatively stable over time: The yearly standard deviations are only about 0.2 percentage points.
Table 3 explores the relationship between net and gross migration a bit further. For each MSA
in each year, a net migration (gross inflows less gross outflows) percentage is computed. We then bin
these net migration percentages into deciles. The mean net migration rate of each decile is reported
in column (1) of Table 3; column (2) reports the mean gross expansion rate for each decile; and
column (3) reports the mean gross contraction rate. The table shows that at gross expansion and
contraction rates are an order of magnitude higher than net migration rates at all levels of net
migration rates. The data also shows that variations in net migration rates are mainly obtained
through variations in the gross expansion rates: the gross contration rates are fairly constant.
2.2.3

Standard Deviations and Correlations of Detrended Variables

We detrend the logarithm of any variable  as follows. First, we compute a “hatted” variable, ̂ ,
defined as  less the yearly sample mean. That is, assuming  = 1      MSAs in our sample in
each year , we compute
̂ =  −

µ

1


¶X


 

=1

The hatted variable is mean zero in every year. Next, we compute the change in the hatted
variable, ∆̂ . In the final step, we subtract the average value of ∆̂ for each MSA, that is
12

For each MSA, we construct estimates of beginning-of-year population (non-movers plus gross outflows) and

end-of-year population (non-movers plus gross inflows). The population of taxpayers is set to the average of these
beginning- and end- of year estimates.

8

assuming  = 1      observations for each MSA we compute
 = ∆̂ −

µ

1
 −1

¶X


∆̂ 

=2

We report statistics and correlations of the  variable in the above equation.
We have in mind that the growth rates of any variable in our sample can be characterized as
adhering to the following process:
∆ =   +  +  

(5)

with  a shock common to all MSAs,   an MSA-specific (fixed) component and  a mean-zero
stationary variable that is uncorrelated across MSAs. The “hatting” of variables has the effect of
removing the aggregate shock  , and the subtraction of the sample average growth rate for each
MSA removes an estimate of   , leaving as a residual a consistent estimate of  .
Table 4 shows standard deviations and contemporaneous correlations of the detrended variables.
The first two columns of the table report the standard deviations of ∆̂ and  . The standard
deviations of ∆̂ to  for most variables are similar except in the case of population, where  has
a considerably smaller standard deviation. Focusing on the standard deviations for  : Population
has the smallest standard deviation; the standard deviations of employment and wage per job are
roughly double that of population; the standard deviations of house prices, entries and exits are five
and seven times that of population; and, the standard deviation of housing permits are 31 times
that of population.
While most of the variables we report have a direct mapping to model variables, housing permits, which are available at the MSA-level, are intended to proxy for MSA-level real residential
investment, which is not available. The available evidence suggests that permits and residential
investment are highly correlated, but that permits are more volatile than residential investment.
Over the 1985-2008 period, the correlation of the log differences of aggregate permits and aggregate
real residential investment is 0.90. The standard deviation of the log difference of aggregate permits
is about 30 percent greater than real residential investment, 13.1% compared to 9.9%. Certainly,
a good deal of the volatility of the  we report for housing permits arises from volatility housing
permit data in the smaller MSAs. If we restrict attention to the top-100 largest MSAs in 1984, accounting for 78 percent of the population in our 366 MSA sample, the estimated standard deviation
of  falls from 27.6% to 20.1%.
The rightmost five columns of the table report contemporaneous correlations of all of the the 
variables. Almost all variables are positively correlated, except for lagged exits which is negatively

9

correlated with all variables except house prices. The correlation of average wage per job with most
variables is low, potentially signaling to measurement error in wages, a point to which we return
later.
Table 5 shows sample autocorrelations of the detrended annual data, the  variables, at lags
1-4. Summarizing: Lagged entries, housing permits, and average wage per job are not highly serial
correlation; population and employment have a more pronounced first-order serial correlation;
and house prices are highly serial correlation. Table 6 shows correlations of the  variable for
employment at time  with four lags and leads of the  for the other variables in our sample. The
reported correlations suggest that employment leads population, house prices, and exits (in the sense
that the correlation at the first lead of these variables is at least as large as the contemporaneous
correlation); and, employment lags housing permits and average wage per job.

3

The model economy

The economy is populated by a representative household that has a continuum of members with
names in the unit interval. The preferences of each household member is given by the following
utility function:
=

∞
X

  [ln  + ( ) +  ln (  )] 

=0

where  is consumption,  is leisure,  is housing services, 0    1 is the discount factor,
 ≥ 0 and  ≥ 0. Since household members are endowed with one unit of time and there is an
© ª
institutionally determined workweek of length 1 − ¯, leisure  must belong to the set 1 ¯ . The

household’s preferences are given by

Z

1

()

0

where () is the utility of household member . That is, the household puts equal weights to all
of its members.
The consumption good is produced using a continuum of intermediate goods. The production
function is given by
 =

∙Z

1



 () 

0

¸ 1

where  is output of the consumption good,  () is the amount of intermediate good , and  ≤ 1.
Observe that −1 (1 − ) is the elasticity of substitution of the intermediate goods.
Each intermediate good is produced by a single city using the following production function:
 =   

10

where  is the output of the city-specific intermediate good,   0 is a city specific productivity
shock,  is labor,  is capital,   0,   0 and  +  ≤ 1. The idiosyncratic productivity shock
 follows a finite Markov process with transition matrix .
Capital is freely movable across cities but labor isn’t. At the beginning of every period household
members are distributed in some way across all the cities of the economy. The household must
decide which household members to leave in the cities where they are initially located and which
household members to move. However, a fraction  of all household members are forced to move for
exogenous reasons. Whenever a household member moves to a different city the household incurs
a moving cost equal to  units of the consumption good. The household must also decide which
household members to put to work and which ones to leave non-employed. Household members
can only obtain employment and housing services from the cities where they are currently located.
Each city produces local housing services according to the following production function:
  =  1−

where   is the output of local housing services,  is local housing structures,  is local land, and
0 ≤  ≤ 1. While housing structures can be accumulated, cities have a fixed endowment of land ̂.
The technology for accumulating local housing structures is given by
+1 = (1 −   )  +  ≥ (1 −   )  

(6)

where 0     1 is the depreciation rate of housing structures and  ≥ 0 is gross residential
investment. Observe that local residential investment is subject to an irreversibility constraint.
Aggregate capital is accumulated according to a standard technology given by
+1 = (1 −   )  +  
where 0     1 is the depreciation rate of capital and  is gross investment.

4

Steady state equilibrium

In this section we describe a steady state competitive equilibrium. The state of a city  will be given
by its idiosyncratic productivity level , the number of people present at the city at the beginning
of the period , and the stock of local housing structures . A time invariant distribution  will
describe the number of cities across the different individual states  = (  ).
The representative household purchases the consumption good, invests in physical capital, invests in housing structures in each city, rents housing services in each city, and pays moving costs.

11

It earns income from the labor services supplied by its household members, from renting the household structures that it owns in each city, from renting the land that it owns in each city, from
renting the stock of capital and from the profits produced by the intermediate goods producers.
The state of the representative household is given by the stock of physical capital that it owns ,
a function  describing the number of household members that the household has at each type
of city  at the beginning of the period, and a function  describing the stock of local housing
structures that the household owns at each type of city . The household’s problem is described
by the following Bellman equation:
¶
¾
½
µ
Z
Z
 ()
0 0 0
 ()  +  (     )
 (  ) = max ln  +   ()  +  ln
 ()
subject to
Z
Z
Z
 +   +  () +  ()  ()  +  max { () − (1 − )  ()  0} 
Z
Z
Z
≤
 ()  ()  +  ()  ()  +  ()  +   + 
Z

 ()  = 1

 () +  () =  () 
 () ≥ 0
 0 = (1 −   )  +   
0 and  0 satisfy that for every 0 and every Borel set X 0 ×H0
Z
Z
¡ 0 0 0¢ ¡ 0
¢
0
0
0
          ×  =
 (  ) ( 0 ) ( ×  × ) 
X 0 ×H0

and
Z

X 0 ×H0

¡
¢ ¡
¢
 0  0  0  0  0 × 0 =
0

B

Z h
i
(1 −   )  (  ) +  (  ) ( 0 ) ( ×  × ) 
B

respectively, where

n
o
B = (  ) :  (  ) ∈ X 0 and (1 −   )  +  (  ) ∈ H0 
and where  () is total population in a city of type ,  () is total residential investment in a city
of type ,  () is the price of housing services in a city of type ,  () is the wage rate in city of
type ,  () is the rental price of housing structures in a city of type ,  () is the rental price of
land in a city of type ,  is the economy-wide rental price of capital,  () is the post-reallocation

12

total number of household members in a city of type ,  () is the number of housing members that
work in a city of type ,  () is the number of housing members that are non-employed in a city
of type , and  are profits. Observe that the household provides full consumption insurance to
all of its members. It also provides equal amount of housing services to all the household members
residing in a same city.
Intermediate good producers in a city of type  solve the following static maximization problem
o
n
max  ()   −  ()  −   

where () is the price of the intermediate good in a city of type , housing services producers in
a city of type  solve the following problem:
n
o
max  ()  1− −  ()  −  ()  

In turn, (economy-wide) producers of the consumption good solve the following problem:
(∙Z
)
¸1 Z


max
 ()  −  ()  ()  

¢
¡
A steady state equilibrium is an allocation ̄ ̄  ̄  ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ ¯  ̄  ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ , profits
ª
©
̄ and prices ̄  ̄ ̄  ̄  ̄  ̄ such that:
¢
¡
¡
¢
1) The household chooses ̄ ¯  ̄  ̄ ̄ ̄ ̄ when its individual state is given by ̄ ̄ ̄
¢ ©
ª
¡
and when it takes ̄ ̄ ̄ , ̄  ̄ ̄  ̄  ̄ and ̄ as given,
2) ̄and ̄ satisfy that:

̄ (  ) = 
̄ (  ) = 
for every  = (  ),
¡
¢
3) The intermediate good producers in a city of type  choose ̄ ()  ̄ () when they take
¢
¡
̄ ()  ̄ ()  ̄ as given,
³
´
¢
¡
4) The housing services producers in a city of type  choose ̄ ()  ̂ when they take ̄  ̄  ̄
as given,

5) The consumption good producers choose ̄ when they take ̄ as given,
6) The markets for intermediate goods clear, i.e.
̄ () = ̄ () ̄ () 
7) The markets for local housing services clear, i.e.
̄ () = ̄ () ̂1−

13

8) The market for the consumption good clears, i.e.
¯

̄ + 

+

Z



̄ ()̄ + 

Z

max {̄ () − (1 − )  0}  =

∙Z

¸1

 ()  


9) The market for business capital clears, i.e.
Z
̄ = ̄ () ̄
10) The stock of capital is stationary, i.e.
¯ =   ̄
11) The invariant distribution ̄ satisfies that for every  and every Borel sets X × H:
Z
¢
¡ 0
( 0 )̄ ( ×  × ) 
̄   X × H =
B

where

o
n
B = (  ) : ̄ (  ) ∈ X and (1 −   )  + ̄ (  ) ∈ H 

12) The total population and total residential investment rule of cities are generated by the
individual decisions of the representative household, i.e.
̄ (  ) = ̄ (  ) 
̄ (  ) = ̄ (  )

5

Characterization

Since the above is a convex economy with no distortions the welfare theorems apply. As a consequence, the equilibrium allocation can be obtained by solving the problem of a social planner that
maximizes the utility of the representative household subject to resource feasibility constraints.
However, it will be more useful to characterize the equilibrium allocation as the solution to a series
of city social planner’s problems, one for each city, with some side conditions.
The state of a city social planner is given by the city’s state (  ). His problem is described
by the following Bellman equation:
½
1 1− h   i
 

+  +  − ( + )  − 
 (  ) = max

"
)
#
X
 ̂1−

0 0 0
0
+ ln
 −  +   (     )(  )

0


14

subject to
 =  +  − 
 ≥ 0
 ≥ 
 +  ≤ 
 ≥ 0
0 = 
0 = (1 −   )  +  
where  is the number of people that leave the city,  is the number of people that arrive to the
city,  is the shadow value of a person that moves to a new city (exclusive of the moving cost ),
 is the shadow value of capital services,  is aggregate output of the consumption good, and  is
aggregate consumption. The city social planner takes (   ) as given. Observe that the number
of people that the city social planner allows to leave the city is bounded below by the fraction  of
initial residents  that receive an exogenous moving shock.
The optimal population decision rule (  ) is characterized by a lower population threshold
 ( ) and an upper population rule ̄ ( ) as follows:
©
ª
(  ) = max  ( )  min [(1 − )  ̄ ( )] 

(7)

That is, if beginning population net of exogenous attritions (1 − )  is less than the lower population threshold  ( ), the city social planner brings people into the city until population equals the
lower threshold. If (1 − )  is larger than the upper population threshold ̄ ( ), the city social
planner takes people out of the city until population equals the upper threshold. Otherwise, the
city social planner lets population decline at the exogenous attrition rate .
Given the optimal population decision rule, entries to the city  (  ) and exits from the city
 (  ) are given by
(  ) = max {(  ) − (1 − )  0} 

(8)

(  ) = max { − (  ) } 

(9)

respectively.
The optimal employment decision rule is characterized by the population decision rule and an
employment threshold ̄ () that solely depends on the idiosyncratic productivity of the city:
(  ) = min {̄ ()  (  )} 
15

(10)

That is, if the optimal population level is (  ) is below the employment threshold ̄ (), everybody in the city works. Otherwise, employment is equal to the employment threshold. Nonemployment is then given by
(  ) = (  ) − (  )

(11)

The optimal residential investment decision rule  (  ) is also of the (S,s) type. It is characterized by the optimal population rule and a threshold ̂ [ 0 ] as follows:
n
o
 (  ) = max ̂ [ (  )] − (1 −   )  0 

(12)

That is, if residential structures net of depreciation (1 −   )  is below the threshold corresponding
to the optimal population size (  ), residential structures are increased to that threshold level.
Otherwise, residential investment is equal to zero.
Conditional on a given employment level , the shadow value of an employed person is given
by:

h
 ( ) = ̂

1
−1


i

1
1−



 1− −

1−−
1−



h i


1−





an expression that takes into account the optimal choice of capital  conditional on the employment
level . The employment threshold ̄ () then satisfies that
 =  [ ̄ ()] 

(13)

i.e. ̄ () is the employment level at which the city social planner would be indifferent between
allocating an additional resident to employment or non-employment.
The shadow value of a city resident  (  ) solves the following functional equation:
⎧
⎪

⎪
⎪
⎪
⎡
⎤
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎨
 + 
⎢
⎥
³  1− ´
 (  ) = max
⎢
⎥
 
⎪
⎢
⎥
−
+

ln
+
max
{
[
(1
−
)
]

}
+

min
⎪
(1−)
⎪
⎢
⎥
⎪
⎪
¡
¢
⎣
⎦
P
⎪
0

0
⎪
+ (1 − )     (1 − )  (1 −   )  +  (  ) (  )
⎩
0

⎫
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎬
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎭

(14)

This equation states that the shadow value of a resident cannot become less than the shadow value
of a mover , otherwise the city planner would take people out of the city until the shadow value
of a resident is equal to the shadow value of moving. On the other hand, the shadow value of a
resident cannot exceed the shadow value of a mover  plus the cost of moving , otherwise the city
planner would bring people into the city until the shadow value of resident is equal to the shadow
value of a mover plus the moving cost. If the shadow value of a resident is between  and  +  the

16

social planner lets the population contract at the exogenous attrition rate , so population equals
(1 − ) . In this case, the shadow value of a resident is equal to a current return plus an expected
discounted value. The current return has three terms. The first term is the negative impact that
an additional resident has in lowering per-capita housing services. The second term is the gain
obtained by the additional resident from the existing per-capital housing services. The third term
is the marginal value of an employed person, if the additional resident is to become one. Otherwise
it is equal to the value of leisure. The expected discounted value has two terms. The first term
is the shadow value of a mover  times the probability that the additional resident becomes one
at the beginning of the following period. The second term is the expected continuation shadow
value of a city resident, given that the idiosyncratic productivity shock of the city will transit next
period according to the transition matrix  and that the optimal residential investment decision is
described by equation (12).
The lower population threshold  (  ) in equation (7) then satisfies the following equation:
µ  1− ¶
© £
¤
ª

+ max    (  )  
 +  = − +  ln
(15)
 (  )
n ¡
o´
X ³
¢
+ + (1 − )   0   ( )  max ̂   ( )  (1 −   )  ( 0 )
0

and the upper population threshold ̄ (  ) satisfies:
µ  1− ¶

+ max { [ ̄ (  )]  }
(16)
 = − +  ln
̄ (  )
n
o´
X ³
+ + (1 − )   0  ̄ (  )  max ̂ ( ̄ (  ))  (1 −   )  ( 0 )
0

That is, at the lower population threshold  (  ) the city planner is indifferent between bringing
an additional resident to the city or not and at the upper population threshold ̄ (  ) the city
planner is indifferent between taking an additional resident out of the city or not.
The expected discounted shadow value of an additional unit of next period housing structures
 ( 0  ), conditional
⎧
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎨
¢
¡

0
     = min
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎪
⎩

on next period population 0 , satisfies the following functional equation:
⎫
⎪
⎪
1
⎪
⎡
⎤ ⎪
⎪
⎬
P (0 0 (1− ))
0

(

)
(1−  )
⎢
⎥  (17)
0
⎢
⎥ ⎪
P  0
⎪
⎣
⎦ ⎪
⎪
0
0
0
⎪
+ (1 −   )   (  (    (1 −   ) ) (1 −   ) ) (  )
⎭
0

This equation states that the expected discounted shadow value of an additional unit of next period
housing structures cannot exceed 1, otherwise the city planner would invest until that shadow
value is brought down to the marginal cost of residential investment (which equals one unit of the

17

consumption good). If the expected discounted shadow value of an additional unit of next period
housing structures is less than one, the city planner lets housing structures depreciate at the rate   .
In this case, the expected discounted value of an additional unit of next period housing structures
equals its expected contribution to increasing next period housing services, plus the continuation
expected discounted value of the fraction of the additional unit of housing structures that does
not depreciate. Both terms take into account the fact that the idiosyncratic productivity shock of
the city transits according to the transition matrix  and that the optimal population decision is
described by equation (7).
The housing structures threshold ̂ ( 0 ) in equation (12) satisfies the following equation:
X ³
X [0  0  ̂ ( 0 )]
¡
¢ ¡
¢´
( 0 ) + (1 −   )   0  [0  0  ̂  0 ] ̂  0 ( 0 )
1 = 
̂ ( 0 )
0
0
That is, at the housing structures threshold ̂ ( 0 ) the city planner is indifferent between investing
an addition unit or not.
There are six side conditions that must be satisfied for a solution to the city social planner’s
problem to represent a steady state competitive equilibrium. First, given the decision rules (  )
and  (  ), the invariant distribution  must satisfy that for every  and every Borel sets X ×H:
Z
¢
¡ 0
( 0 ) ( ×  × ) 
(18)
  X × H =
B

where

o
n
B = (  ) : (  ) ∈ X and (1 −   )  +  (  ) ∈ H 

(19)

Second, that the market for the consumption good clears, i.e.

 +   + 

Z

 (  )  ( ×  × ) +

Z

 (  ) ( ×  × ) = 

Third, that aggregate population is equal to one, i.e.
Z
[ (  ) +  (  )]  ( ×  × ) = 1

(20)

Fourth, that the rental rate of capital satisfies the standard steady state relationship
=

1
− 1 +  


Fifth, that the rental market for capital clears, i.e.
Z
 (  )  ( ×  × ) = 
18

(21)

(22)

Sixth, that the aggregate output  that the city planner takes as given be generated by the optimal
decisions:

6

¾1
½Z h
i



 ( ×  × )

 =
 (  )  (  )

Calibration

In this section we calibrate the steady state competitive equilibrium described above to U.S. data
using a model time period equal to one year.
In order to calibrate the model we must first map it to the National Income and Product
Accounts (NIPA) appropriately. We identify the model stock of capital  with private nonresidential fixed assets, i.e. with plants, equipment and software. As a consequence, we identify   
R
with private nonresidential fixed investment. In turn, we associate   with private residential
investment.

Since personal consumption expenditures includes housing expenditures, we associate them with
Z
 +   +  
i.e. with model consumption, plus moving expenses, plus rental of housing services. However,
since model aggregate output  does not include the production of housing services, we define the
empirical counterpart of  as follows:
Z
Z

 = ( +   +  ) +    +  −  

= Total PCE + non-residential investment + residential investment - housing PCE expenditures.

Observe that we are not incorporating government expenditures and net exports to our definition
of  since our model abstracts from them.
Considering annual nominal data between 1985 and 2008, we calculate an average capitaloutput ratio  equal to 1.50 and an investment-output ratio (  )  equal to 0.156 . As a
consequence, we set the depreciation rate of capital to   = 0104. For the discount factor  we
choose it to generate an annual interest rate 1 = 004, which is a standard value in the literature.
From the first order conditions to the problem of the producers of the consumption good we
have that for every intermediate good :
 () =  1−  ()−1 

19

(23)

In turn, the first order conditions to the problem of the intermediate good producers are the
following:
 ()  ()
= 
 ()  ()

(24)

  ()
= 
 ()  ()

(25)

From equations (23), (24) and (25) it then follows that
R
 ()  () 
=

and

= 

That is, the share of labor is equal to  and the share of capital is equal to , independently of
the elasticity of substitution parameter . We then select  = 064, which is the share of labor
commonly used in the literature. In turn we choose  = 0217 which is consistent with the above
values for ,   and  and the fact that the rental rate of capital satisfies equation (21).
From the household’s first order conditions we have that
 = 


 1−



From this equation and the first order conditions for the housing services producers we then have
that:

 =  


 =  (1 − ) 

The price of one unit of housing structures   (  ), which equals the expected discounted value
of  net of depreciation, is then given by:
  (  ) = 

i
X h
(  )
+ (1 −   ) 
  0  (  )  (  ) ( 0 )

0

(26)



and the price of one unit of land   (  ), which equals the expected discounted value of  , is
given by
  (  ) = (1 − ) 

(  )
̂

+

X
0

h
i
  0  (  )  (  ) ( 0 )

The share of land in the total value of housing is then given by
  (  ) ̂
  (  )  +   (  ) ̂

20



We choose  to reproduce the average of this share in the U.S. economy, which according to (??) is
equal to 0.35.
We associate the aggregate value of housing structures,
Z
  (  ) 
with total private residential fixed assets in the NIPA accounts, since this measure represents the
cost of reproducing the stock of houses. We then choose the value of housing services in the utility
function  to generate

R

  (  ) 
= 151


which is the corresponding average ratio in the U.S. economy.
In turn, we select the depreciation rate of housing structures   so that
R 
 (  ) 
= 0062

the average ratio of private residential investment to our measure of output in the U.S. economy.
There is a lot of uncertainty about what value to choose for , the parameter determining the
elasticity of substitution between city specific goods. In our benchmark case we choose  = 0667 to
generate an elasticity of substitution equal to 3, which is the median value estimated by Broda and
Weinstein (2) using international trade data.13 However, since this is an elasticity of substitution
between goods and there must be some considerable amount of overlap in the production structure
of the different cities, we will consider higher elasticities of substitution as well.
The exogenous population attrition rate  is a crucial determinant of how large gross population
flows are in excess of net population flows. To explore the importance of gross flows in the model’s
ability to match U.S. data, we will consider two different scenarios. The first scenario has  = 0
so that it generates no population reallocation in excess of population net flows. In the second
scenario, we choose  so that the aggregate gross population expansion rate is about ten times
larger than the aggregate net population expansion rate, a feature of U.S. data discussed in Section
2.
In the absence of hard data about moving expenses we will treat the moving cost  as a free
parameter and choose it to reproduce the volatility of population reported in Section 2. Similarly,
we will treat the utility of leisure  as a free parameter and choose it to reproduce the volatility of
employment reported in Section 2. Instead of calibrating  to some employment/population ratio
13

This is also the elasticity of substitution between goods in Alvarez and Shimer (1).

21

we choose to treat it as a free parameter because it is not clear what measure of population the
model should correspond to. Observe that in the model economy a city’s population level increases
only after all its residents have become employed, a feature that would never be obtained using
some broad population measure (such as total population 16 years or older).
We now turn to a more delicate issue: the selection of the idiosyncratic productivity process.

6.1

Estimation of the idiosyncratic technology process

Contrary to the specification of the model, our data are generated from a growing economy subject
to aggregate disturbances and with permanent differences in growth rates among cities. It is
therefore necessary to place additional structure on the underlying process driving technology in
order to extract a model-consistent measure of the idiosyncratic technology process from the data.
A final consideration is that a preliminary analysis of the data suggests the idiosyncratic technology
process is very persistent with a root close to unity.14 Consequently, our empirical specification of
technology is
∆ ln  =   +  +  

(27)

where ∆ =  − −1  Here   captures idiosyncratic differences in growth across cities and  is
the growth rate of the aggregate technology. Since   is idiosyncratic,   = 0. We also assume
that  is normally distributed with mean zero and variance  2 .
We use profit maximization of the representative firm in city  and the fact that productive
capital is homogenous and allocated costlessly across cities to identify the idiosyncratic technology
process. Combining the first order conditions for labor and capital input in any two cities in any
date  yields:

=


µ




¶


1−

µ

Using the definition
̂ = ln  −




Z

¶− 1−(+)
1−



ln  

the first order conditions can be written as follows:
∆̂ =

1 − 

∆̂ +
∆̂

1 − ( + )

We measure the variable ∆̂ using this equation with data on wages and employment by city,
using pre-determined values for   and .
14

Need to add detail here.

22

Using (27), we have that ∆̂ satisfies
∆̂ =   +  
In practice we find evidence of positive first order serial correlation in ∆̂ . Therefore we augment
our empirical specification with the assumption that idiosyncratic wage growth, ∆̂ , is subject
to first-order moving average classical measurement error. It follows that the variance of the
idiosyncratic term is given by
 2

∙


=  [∆̂ −   ] − 2
1 − 
2

¸2

 [∆̂ −   ] [∆̂−1 −   ] 

We implement this procedure by identifying   with the time series average of measured ∆̂ .
It turns out that under our calibrated values of  = 064 and  = 0217, our estimate of   is
equal to 001091 when  = 1 and equal to 001764 when  = 0667. Given the measurement errors
in both cases, we estimate the standard deviation of wages to be 00129 in the first case and 00078
in the second. Observe that these standard deviations compare to a standard deviation of 00158
of measured wages.
Since our theory requires a stationary process for the idiosyncratic productivity levels, we will
approximate our estimated random walk process with the following AR(1) process:
ln +1 = 095 ln  + +1 

(28)

where  is i.i.d., normally distributed, with zero mean and variance  2 , where the variance  2 is set
to our empirical estimate. In addition, we will approximate by quadrature methods the stationary
process described by equation (28) using a finite state Markov process in which the idiosyncratic
productivity level is allowed to take 9 values.

7

Results

In this section we evaluate how well the model does in reproducing the data described in Section 2.
We also use the model to assess the importance of local housing markets vis-a-vis moving costs in
shaping population flows in the U.S. economy. As was already mentioned in the previous section we
will consider the case of  = 0667 (i.e. and elasticity of substitution equal to 3) as our benchmark
and we will treat the utility of leisure  and the moving cost  as free parameters. We first
consider the case of no exogenous attrition, i.e. the case in which  = 0̇. Positive excess population
reallocation will be introduced later on. For each of the parameter combinations (  ) that we
consider we recalibrate the model to the same observations described in the previous section.

23

7.1

Case  = 0

Table 7 reports standard deviations for the log differences of different variables, both for the U.S.
economy and a number of different versions of the model. The variables reported are employment
, population , wages , housing prices

  +  ̂
,


housing rentals  , housing structures , and

residential investment  . The last two columns, instead of reporting standard deviations, report
the average employment/population ratio  and the moving cost parameter  as a fraction of
average wages, respectively. Observe that we define housing prices as the total value of the housing
structures and land of a city divided by the total housing services produced by the city, and that
we define housing rentals as the price of one unit of housing services produced by the city.
To learn about the role of  and  in our calibration we start by setting the moving cost  to zero
and choosing  to generate an aggregate employment-population ratio equal to 062, which corresponds to the ratio of employment to population 16 years and over in the U.S. economy. The second
row of Table 7 (“ = 062,  = 0”) reports the results. We see that in this case employment is
significantly more volatile than in the data (2.74% instead of 1.83%). However all other variables
have zero volatility. What happens in this case is that, since the employment/population rate is
only 62%, the city planner can generate relatively small employment fluctuations in response to the
idiosyncratic productivity shock by shifting residents between employment and non-employment,
without having to resort to migrations in and out of the city. As a consequence, the population is
always equal to one and the stock of housing structures is constant. In fact, since housing structures
are constant the irreversibility constraint never binds and the housing structures/population ratio
 satisfies the frictionless version of equation (26) given by

1
− 1 +   =  



(29)

Observe that the frictionless version of equation (16), which becomes
!
Ã
 ̂1−
+ max { [ ]  } + 
 = − +  ln

can be satisfied for  = 1 and the solution  to equation (29) because the wage rate is always
equal to  (since employment is always less than ).
We now retain the assumption of zero moving costs  but set  equal to zero, such that
everybody in a city becomes employed. The third row of Table 7 (“ = 1,  = 0,”) reports the
results for this case. We see that employment fluctuates much less than in the previous case (1.92%
instead than 2.74%), bringing it closer to the data. The reason for this is that wages never hit

24

the value of leisure  and thus display enough volatility to dampen the employment fluctuations
quite significantly. However, by construction, population growth also has a standard deviation of
1.92%, which is more than twice as large as what is observed in the data.
To learn about the magnitude of the moving cost  needed to bring down the standard deviation
of population growth to what is seen in the data, we still set  equal to zero but now choose 
to reproduce that standard deviation. The fourth row of Table 7 (“ = 1,   0”) shows
that a moving cost  equal to 24% of annual wages is required to hit that target. However, now
employment, which by construction equals population, now fluctuates too little.
In the fifth column of Table 7 (“free  and ”) we choose the disutility of leisure  and the
moving cost  to reproduce the standard deviations of employment and population growth rates.
Observe that the average employment/population ratio  needed to make employment more
volatile than population by the factor observed in the data is 0986. In this case, the moving cost
 needed to generate the population fluctuations observed in the data is equal to 8.3% of annual
wages. Observe that wages fluctuate as much as in the data, indicating that the model generates a
reasonable correlation between employment and the idiosyncratic productivity shocks. Where the
model fails is in terms of housing prices and housing rentals. There are huge discrepancies in terms
of housing prices: Housing prices fluctuate only 0.32% in the model while they fluctuate 4.25% in
the data. The discrepancies are not as large in terms of housing rentals, but they are still significant:
housing rentals fluctuate 0.96% in the model while they 1.97% in the data. While the growth rate
of housing permits is very volatile in the data (its standard deviation is 27.6%) and it must be
closely related to the growth rate of residential investment, the standard deviation of the growth
rate in residential investment in the model economy is infinity because of the binding irreversibility
constraint. Observe from equation (17) that the price of housing structures (excluding current
rental income) is equal to one whenever residential investment is positive, and that it drops below
one only when residential investment is zero. Despite of this, the irreversibility constraint does not
contribute to generating large fluctuations in the price of housing structures because it binds for
only 0.14% of the cities.
In order to generate larger fluctuations in housing prices we introduce quadratic adjustment
costs to residential investment. Observe that up to this point the cost of producing the gross
increase in housing structures  described by equation (6) was  units of the consumption good.
Under quadratic adjustment costs, we assume that the same gross increase in housing structures

25

 costs
 +

Ω ³  ´2

2 

units of the consumption good.15 The sixth row of Table 7 (“free  and , Ω  0”) shows results
for this case. The selected value for Ω is admittedly arbitrary, but represents a compromise between
the goal of generating larger fluctuations in house prices and keeping residential investment enough
volatile to be broadly consistent with the evidence on housing permits. We see that in this case
employment and population fluctuate as much as in the U.S. economy since the value of leisure
 and the moving cost  have been selected to this end. Wages also fluctuate as much as in the
data, indicating that the model still generates a reasonable correlation between employment and
productivity shocks. Observe that housing prices have become significantly more volatile than
in the absence of quadratic adjustment costs (0.52% instead of 0.32%) but they are still far less
volatile than the data.(4.25%). Housing rentals are not much affected, while residential investment
display more reasonable fluctuations given that the investment irreversibility constraint no longer
binds. Under this parametrization the employment/population ratio is still equal to 98.5% while
the moving cost is lowered to only 4.2% of annual wages. In what follows we will treat this last
version of the model as our benchmark case when  = 0.
Table 8 displays contemporaneous correlations between the growth rates of the different variables in this economy. Compared with the empirical correlations displayed in Table 4 we see that
the comovements of employment with population (0.64), wages (0.36), residential investment (0.49),
and housing prices (0.76) are somewhat stronger, but still broadly in line with the data (0.40, 0.15,
0.25, and 0.38, respectively).16 The comovements of population with the other variables are also
broadly consistent with the data except for the correlation with residential investment, which is 0.43
in the model, while population and housing permits are empirically uncorrelated.17 The correlation
between wages and residential investment (0.34) is slightly higher than the empirical correlation
between wages and housing permits (0.10), but the correlation between wages and housing prices
is significantly stronger than in the data: 0.82 instead of 0.23. Also, the correlation between housing prices and residential investment is stronger than the corresponding empirical correlation with
housing permits: 0.51 instead of 0.22. All considered we conclude that comovements in the model
15

We select this specification for the quadratic adjustment costs because it is consistent with balanced growth.

16

Observe that given the lack of better measures, we associate residential investment with housing permits.

17

The correlation of population growth with housing prices is also somewhat too strong compared with the data:

0.79 instead of 0.33.

26

are roughly consistent with those observed in the data: except for the zero correlation between
population and housing permits, all other correlations have the correct sign.
The model does not perform as well in terms of autocorrelations, though. Table 5 showed that in
the U.S. employment, population and housing prices display sizable positive autocorrelations at the
one year horizon. However, Table 9 shows that in the model these autocorrelations are essentially
zero (only population exhibits some positive autocorrelation but it is rather small), inheriting the
same behavior of the idiosyncratic productivity shocks. On the other hand, wages and residential
investment are roughly consistent with the data.
There are also discrepancies in the leads/lags structure. Table 10 reports the correlations of
employment growth with the growth rates of different variables at different leads and lags. From
Table 6 we know that in the U.S. wages, and to some extent housing permits, lead employment
by one year. However, there are no comparable leads in the model economy. The lag structure is
also problematic. While Table 6 shows that U.S. employment is positively correlated with lagged
population and housing prices, in the model the correlation of employment with lagged population
is rather weak and nonexistent with housing prices.
Although the model fails to generate some positive autocorrelations in growth rates and misses
the lead/lag structure of employment with some other variables, we have set the model to very high
standards. These failures show that the model does not display an internal propagation mechanism
at the city level for the idiosyncratic productivity shocks. However the model still captures some
salient features of the data, such as volatilities and contemporaneous comovements. Perhaps the
most serious deficiency of the model is that it fails to generate the large volatility of housing prices
observed in U.S. data. However, this problem is not particular to our model: the difficulties of
general equilibrium models in generating large asset price fluctuations have become quite familiar
to the literature. In the specific case of housing prices, a similar problem has been encountered by
Davis and Heathcote (3) in the context of business cycle analysis.
7.1.1

Population flows and local housing markets

With these caveats in mind we now use the model to evaluate the importance of local housing
markets vis-a-vis direct moving costs in determining the magnitude of the population flows observed
in the U.S. economy. We first evaluate the effects of setting the moving cost parameter  to zero.
The second row of Table 11 reports the results of this experiment while the first row reproduces
statistics for our benchmark economy. We see that removing the moving costs have a relatively
small impact on employment volatility: Its standard deviation increases by 16% (from 1.86 to 2.16).

27

However, the impact on population volatility is quite significant: Its standard deviation increases by
60% (from 0.93 to 1.49). The decrease in employment volatility is enough to lower wage volatility
by 50% (from 0.72 to 0.36) while the increase in population volatility increases housing prices
volatility by 22% (from 0.52 to 0.63) and housing rentals volatility by 63% (from 0.92 to 1.50).
Observe that the volatility of housing structures and residential investment also increase slightly
to accommodate to the higher population volatility.
We now turn to evaluate the role of local housing markets in determining population flows. In
order to do this we consider a version of the model economy in which both housing structures and
land are freely mobile. That is, when people move to a different city they can now take their houses
with them. Admittedly this is an artificial experiment but it will be extremely useful for assessing
the importance of the immobility of houses in determining population flows.
In the economy with freely mobile housing the city planner’s problem becomes the following:
½
1 1− h   i

+  +  − ( + )  − 
 
 ( ) = max

)
∙  1− ¸
X

 −   −   +   (0  0 )( 0 )
+ ln

0


subject to
 =  +  − 
 ≥ 0
 ≥ 
 +  ≤ 
0 = 
where  is the economy-wide shadow value of housing structures and  is the economy-wide
shadow value of land. Observe that at these shadow prices the city planner is free to rent any
amount of housing structures  and land .
The third row of Table 11 reports the effects of converting the benchmark economy into one
with perfectly mobile housing (parameter values are exactly the same as those in the benchmark
economy, except for the adjustment cost parameter Ω, which is set to zero). We see that the effects
on housing structures are large: Its standard deviation increases by a factor of five (from 0.28 to
1.38). However, the effects on employment fluctuations are quite small: its standard deviation
increases only by 4% (from 1.86 to 1.93). As a consequence, the effects on wages are also relatively

28

small. Observe that, similarly to the previous experiment, the effects on population fluctuations
are significant: the standard deviation of population growth increases by 48% (from 0.93 to 1.38).
The reason why employment volatility increases less than population volatility in both experiments is that in the benchmark case employment has the cushion of unemployment to accommodate
to the idiosyncratic shocks, a margin that involves no adjustment costs. On the contrary, population is subject to adjustment costs given by the direct moving cost and the fixity of housing. As
a consequence, when one of these adjustment costs is removed the largest effects must fall on population volatility. Employment volatility also increases, however, because the pool of employable
people has become more volatile.
Observe from Table 11 that population fluctuates more in the second row than in the third.
That is, in the benchmark economy the direct moving costs are a more important factor than the
fixity of housing in determining population volatility.

7.2

Case   0

This section introduces explicit excess population reallocation by making the exogenous attrition
rate parameter  positive. Before doing so, we would like to point out that the version of the model
with  = 0 considered in the previous section can actually be reinterpreted as one with implicit
excess population reallocation. To see this, consider a version of the model in which population
mobility takes place in two stages. In the first stage, a person is forced to move “for family reasons”
with probability . When this happens the person is randomly assigned to a second person in the
economy and must move to the city where the second person is initially located, after payment
of a moving cost   . Observe that because of this random assignment, a city that has  initial
residents will lose  residents for family reasons and will gain  residents for family reasons,
leaving its size unchanged at the end of the first stage. In the second stage, after observing the
idiosyncratic productivity shock of the cities where they are subsequently located, people decide
whether to stay or reallocate after paying the moving cost , in exactly the same way that has
been described in previous sections. Observe that if the moving cost for family reasons   is equal
to zero, the equilibrium of the economy with exogenous family moves will be exactly the same as
the one in the previous section, except that gross population flows will be positive. If the moving
cost for family reasons   is positive, aggregate consumption will be affected. However, in this
case the equilibrium of the economy with family moves will coincide with the equilibrium of the
previous section after the utility of leisure parameter  and the utility of housing parameter  are

29

appropriately redefined. We conclude that the results of Tables 1-4 also correspond to economies
with exogenous family moves and, therefore, that they are consistent with positive gross population
flows of (arbitrary) size . The general equilibrium effects in Table 11 will generally depend on the
size of the moving cost for family reasons   , because it may affect the size of the wealth effects.
However, if   equals  the differences with Table 11 are likely to be small because  was only
equal to 4% of annual wages.
We now go back to our previous interpretation of the model, which abstracts from family moves,
and introduce a positive exogenous attrition rate . Observe that these exogenous attritions differ
from the family moves in that the people making these moves can freely choose where to reallocate
depending on local economic conditions (i.e. wages and housing). For the quantitative analysis
that follows it will be important to determine what size to introduce for the exogenous attrition
rate .
Recall from Section 2 that the gross population expansions rate is ten times larger than the
net population expansions rate in IRS data (4.3% vs. 0.43%). However, net population flows in
IRS data are larger than those obtained in BEA data. In particular, the standard deviation of
population growth is equal to 1.72% in IRS data while it is equal to 0.89% in BEA data. Since
BEA data is based on good quality census data, this suggests introducing lower gross population
flows than those obtained from IRS data. To determine an actual magnitude for the exogenous
attrition rate  we thus decide to do the following: We calculate the net expansions rate in the
benchmark economy “free  and , Ω  0” of Table 7, which has the same standard deviation
for population growth rates as BEA data, and pick an exogenous attrition rate that is ten times
larger. This delivers a  equal to 002.
The first row of Table 12 reports standard deviations for the benchmark economy “free  and
, Ω  0” when the exogenous attrition rate  is set to  = 002 while all other parameters are left
unchanged. Observe that relative to the first row of Table 11 population becomes significantly more
volatile: Its standard deviation increases by 42% (from 0.93 to 1.32) This allows employment to
fluctuate slightly more (its standard deviation increases by 11%) and this dampens wage volatility.
The higher population fluctuations also increase the volatility of housing structures, residential
investment and housing prices, but the effects are rather small. The reason why population becomes
more volatile when we introduce an exogenous attrition rate is that it creates a large pool of people
(more precisely, 2% of the population) that, independently of the size of the moving cost  and
the state of the cities where they are initially located, are forced to move. Since this pool of people
reallocates to cities that receive good idiosyncratic productivity shocks, population becomes more

30

responsive to the shocks and therefore becomes more volatile. For similar reasons as before, the
higher population volatility leads to more employment volatility.
The second row of Table 12 reproduces the second row of Table 11. That is, it reports the
equilibrium effects of setting the moving cost to zero. Compared to the first row of Table 12 we
see that the effects are much smaller when  = 002: The standard deviation of population growth
increases by only 13% (from 1.32 to 1.49 ). The reason is that the pool of people that is forced to
move is sufficiently large that the amount of people reallocating to new cities is similar to when
the moving cost is equal to zero. Essentially the main factor restricting net population flows in
the first row of Table 12 is the fixity of local housing. Indeed, we see in the third row of Table 12
that when housing becomes fully mobile that the effects on population flows are much larger: The
standard deviation of population now increases by 37% (from 1.32 to 1.81).
We conclude that when  = 002 the fixity of housing is more important than the moving costs
in determining population volatility. This is contrary to the case of  = 0. What is robust to both
cases is that the fixity of housing always plays a significant role in net population reallocation: Even
in the most conservative estimate it accounts for a reduction of 37% in the the standard deviation
of population growth.
Finally, to make clear that the effects of the moving costs critically depend on  the fourth row
of Table 12 reports the effects of doubling the moving cost parameter  so that it equals 8.4% of
annual wages. We see that the effects over the benchmark economy with  = 002 (first row of Table
12) are minuscule. The reason for this is that when  was 4.2% of annual wages, the economy was
already responding to the idiosyncratic productivity shocks by exclusively using people that had to
reallocate for exogenous reasons. When the moving cost doubles there are even more reasons for
doing this. On the contrary, we see in the fourth row of Table 11 that when the moving costs double
in the benchmark economy with  = 0 (first row of Table 11) that the effects are quite significant.
In particular, the standard deviation of population growth now decreases by 17% (from 0.93 to
0.77). Since we have interpreted the economy with  = 0 as one with exogenous reallocations for
“family reasons”, we conclude that determining the exact nature of the gross population flows will
be critical for evaluating the effects of moving costs.

References
[1] Alvarez, F. and R. Shimer. Search and Rest Unemployment. 2010. Econometrica, forthcoming.
[2] Broda, C. and D. Weinstein. 2006. Globalization and the Gains from Variety. Quarterly Journal

31

of Economics, 121 (2), 541-585.
[3] Davis M. and J. Heathcote. 2007. The price and quantity of residential land in the United
States. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2595-2620.
[4] Kennan, J. and J. R. Walker. The Effect of Expected Income on Individual Migration Decisions.
Econometrica, forthcoming.
[5] Kocherlakota, N. 2010. Back Inside the FOMC. Speech at Missoula, Montana (September).
[6] Lucas, R. and E. C. Prescott. 1974. Equilibrium Search and Unemployment. Journal of Economic Theory, 7, 188-209.
[7] Van Nieuwerburgh, S. and P. O. Weil. 2010. Why Has House Price Dispersion Gone Up? Review
of Economic Studies, 77, 1567-1606.

32

Table 1
Means and Standard Deviations, 1984-2008 (Except Where Noted)
All Variables Except the Real House Price Index in 000s

Std.

Avg.

Variable

Mean

Dev.

# MSAs

Population

607.8

1,423.3

366

Wage Employment

294.1

687.2

366

Pop. Inflows−1 *

20.1

30.5

366

Pop. Outflows−1 *

20.0

35.2

366

Housing Permits

3.7

7.8

362

Real House Price Index

127.3

27.0

334

Real Wage per Job **

35.5

5.8

366

* 1986-2008. ** Base Year 2000.

33

Table 2
MSA Mobility Rates, Aggregated Across MSAs, from IRS Data

Across-

Across-

Across-

Across-

Total

MSA

MSA

Mig.

Inflow

Outflow

Total

Total

MSA

MSA

Inflow

Outflow

Inflow

Outflow

Population

Rate (%)

Rate (%)

Rate (%)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

1985

9.92

9.74

7.15

6.97

155.05

6.34

4.61

4.49

1986

10.21

10.12

7.25

7.15

157.17

6.47

4.61

4.55

1987

9.99

9.93

7.12

7.05

157.82

6.31

4.51

4.47

1988

10.26

10.22

7.30

7.26

158.15

6.47

4.61

4.59

1989

10.61

10.58

7.60

7.58

162.45

6.52

4.68

4.67

1990

10.13

10.14

7.16

7.17

160.40

6.32

4.46

4.47

1991

10.19

10.11

7.11

7.03

162.41

6.25

4.38

4.33

1992

10.39

10.38

7.17

7.15

162.94

6.37

4.40

4.39

1993

10.31

10.37

7.06

7.13

163.21

6.34

4.33

4.37

1994

10.39

10.45

7.16

7.22

163.16

6.39

4.39

4.43

1995

10.07

10.11

7.00

7.04

165.28

6.10

4.23

4.26

1996

10.37

10.34

7.16

7.13

167.56

6.18

4.28

4.25

1997

10.52

10.44

7.24

7.16

169.53

6.18

4.27

4.22

1998

10.84

10.71

7.39

7.26

172.81

6.24

4.28

4.20

1999

11.00

10.87

7.47

7.34

176.64

6.19

4.23

4.15

2000

11.06

10.87

7.57

7.38

179.20

6.12

4.22

4.12

2001

11.19

11.12

7.48

7.41

183.07

6.09

4.08

4.05

2002

11.04

11.00

7.31

7.27

185.24

5.95

3.95

3.93

2003

11.21

11.16

7.40

7.36

186.59

5.99

3.97

3.94

2004

11.49

11.46

7.68

7.65

188.07

6.10

4.08

4.07

2005

11.98

11.97

8.12

8.11

188.44

6.36

4.31

4.30

2006

11.49

11.42

7.84

7.77

190.50

6.01

4.12

4.08

2007

11.58

11.48

7.87

7.76

197.48

5.84

3.99

3.93

Average

6.22

4.30

4.27

Std. Dev.

0.18

0.21

0.22

34

Table 3
IRS Data: Binned Net Migration and Gross Expansion and Contraction Rates
(366 MSAs, 1985-2007)

Net Mig

Mean

Mean

Mean

Decile

Net Mig Pct

Gross Exp Pct

Gross Contr Pct

(IRS)

(IRS)

(IRS)

(IRS)

(1)

(2)

(3)

0 - 10

-1.39

2.86

4.25

10 - 20

-0.69

3.01

3.70

20 - 30

-0.40

3.57

3.97

30 - 40

-0.17

3.79

3.96

40 - 50

0.03

4.21

4.18

50 - 60

0.23

4.32

4.10

60 - 70

0.47

4.80

4.33

70 - 80

0.78

5.40

4.62

80 - 90

1.28

6.16

4.88

90 - 100

2.54

7.69

5.15

35

Table 4
Sample Standard Deviations and Correlations
1985-2008

Std. Dev. of

Contemporaneous Correlations of 

∆̂

















Population 

1.39

0.89

1.00

0.40

0.43

-0.22

0.08

0.33

0.11

Employment 

2.10

1.83

1.00

0.40

-0.15

0.25

0.38

0.15

Lag Entries 

6.80

6.71

1.00

-0.24

0.20

0.22

0.12

Lag Exits 

6.76

6.63

1.00

-0.06

0.13

0.03

Permits 

27.78

27.61

1.00

0.22

0.10

House Prices 

4.37

4.25

1.00

0.23

Wage per Job 

1.64

1.58

1.00

36

Table 5
Sample Autocorrelations of 
1985-2008

Lag















0

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1

0.38

0.35

-0.08

-0.24

-0.12

0.67

0.09

2

0.22

0.03

-0.04

-0.01

0.01

0.22

-0.03

3

0.09

-0.06

-0.06

-0.02

-0.03

-0.10

-0.02

4

-0.03

-0.13

-0.14

-0.05

-0.07

-0.22

0.01

37

Table 6
Correlation of  for Employment at time t with leads and lags of the other  variables
1985-2008

Lag or Lead

−

−

−

−

−

−

−

=4

-0.16

-0.13

-0.08

-0.08

-0.03

-0.26

-0.11

=3

-0.16

-0.06

-0.01

-0.06

0.04

-0.22

-0.08

=2

-0.07

0.03

0.10

-0.09

0.14

-0.04

0.04

=1

0.06

0.35

0.18

-0.06

0.27

0.22

0.21

=0

0.40

1.00

0.40

-0.15

0.25

0.38

0.15

 = −1

0.42

0.35

0.18

0.10

0.10

0.38

0.10

 = −2

0.23

0.03

-0.08

0.25

-0.02

0.29

0.10

 = −3

0.11

-0.06

-0.11

0.16

-0.07

0.19

0.09

 = −4

0.02

-0.13

-0.13

0.09

-0.10

0.07

0.04

38

Table 7
Standard deviations: Case  = 0
 (ln  − ln −1 )







  +  ̂












1) U.S. economy

1.83

0.89

0.78

4.25

1.97

n.a.

27.6∗

n.a.

n.a.

2)  = 062,  = 0

2.74

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.62

0.0

3)  = 1,  = 0

1.92

1.92

0.56

0.61

2.23

2.33

∞

1.0

0.0

4)  = 1,   0

0.88

0.88

1.20

0.32

0.98

0.96

∞

1.0

0.24

5) free  and 

1.84

0.89

0.82

0.32

0.96

1.07

∞

0.986

0.083

6) free  and , Ω  0

1.86

0.93

0.72

0.52

0.92

0.28

5.46

0.985

0.042

∗:

standard deviation of housing permits growth rates

39

Table 8
Contemporaneous correlations: Case  = 0
 (ln  − ln −1  ln  − ln −1 )












  +  ̂








1.00

0.64

0.36

0.76

0.65

0.00

0.49

1.00

0.47

0.79

0.97

0.16

0.43

1.00

0.82

0.51

-0.16

0.34

1.00

0.85

-0.19

0.51

1.00

-0.08

0.52

1.00

-0.37



 + ̂






1.00

40

Table 9
Autocorrelations: Case  = 0
 (ln  − ln −1  ln − − ln −1− )

Lag







  +  ̂








=0

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

=1

0.00

0.16

-0.16

-0.01

0.06

0.66

-0.24

=2

0.00

0.09

-0.10

-0.03

0.02

0.48

-0.10

=3

-0.01

0.05

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0.37

-0.05

=4

-0.01

0.02

-0.04

-0.04

-0.03

0.29

-0.03

41

Table 10
Correlations with employment at different leads/lags: Case  = 0
 (ln  − ln −1  ln − − ln −1− )

Lead/Lag





  +  ̂








 = −4

-0.01

0.02

0.01

0.00

-0.05

0.0

 = −3

0.01

0.03

0.03

0.02

-0.05

0.01

 = −2

0.03

0.06

0.05

0.04

-0.04

0.02

 = −1

0.06

0.10

0.08

0.07

-0.02

0.03

s=0

0.64

0.36

0.76

0.65

0.0

0.49

=1

0.16

-0.07

-0.05

0.06

0.39

-0.06

=2

0.10

-0.06

-0.05

0.02

0.33

-0.06

=3

0.06

-0.04

-0.05

0.00

0.27

-0.05

=4

0.04

-0.03

-0.05

-0.02

0.22

-0.04

42

Table 11
Experiments: Case  = 0







  +  ̂












1) free  and , Ω  0

1.86

0.93

0.72

0.52

0.92

0.28

5.46

0.985

0.042

2)  = 0

2.16

1.49

0.36

0.63

1.50

0.31

5.73

0.988

0.000

3) mobile housing

1.93

1.38

0.65

n.a.

n.a.

1.38

n.a.

0.991

0.042

4) high 

1.81

0.77

0.83

0.45

0.76

0.27

5.26

0.984

0.084

43

Table 12
Experiments: Case  = 002







  +  ̂












1) free  and , Ω  0

2.07

1.32

0.48

0.62

1.33

0.31

5.73

0.988

0.042

2)  = 0

2.16

1.49

0.36

0.63

1.50

0.31

5.73

0.988

0.000

3) mobile housing

2.30

1.81

0.41

n.a.

n.a.

1.81

n.a.

0.994

0.042

4) high 

2.05

1.32

0.49

0.63

1.33

0.30

5.70

0.988

0.084

44

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Incomplete Information and the Timing to Adjust Labor: Evidence from the
Lead-Lag Relationship between Temporary Help Employment and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-08

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment
Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

WP-09-08

Pay for Percentile
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-09-09

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot
François R. Velde

WP-09-10

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation
Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

WP-09-11

The Case of the Undying Debt
François R. Velde

WP-09-12

Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship
Program for Low-income Adults
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock
Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-09-13

WP-09-14

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:
Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-09-15

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,
Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-09-16

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-09-17

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-09-18

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances?
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-19

Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-09-20

Monetary Policy and Uncertainty in an Empirical Small Open Economy Model
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-21

Firm boundaries and buyer-supplier match in market transaction:
IT system procurement of U.S. credit unions
Yukako Ono and Junichi Suzuki
Health and the Savings of Insured Versus Uninsured, Working-Age Households in the U.S.
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Jonathan Hartley

WP-09-22

WP-09-23

The Economics of “Radiator Springs:” Industry Dynamics, Sunk Costs, and
Spatial Demand Shifts
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Thomas N. Hubbard

WP-09-24

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth, and
Capital Spending in the United States
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

WP-09-25

The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-09-26

Comment on “Letting Different Views about Business Cycles Compete”
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-01

Macroeconomic Implications of Agglomeration
Morris A. Davis, Jonas D.M. Fisher and Toni M. Whited

WP-10-02

Accounting for non-annuitization
Svetlana Pashchenko

WP-10-03

Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy
Gadi Barlevy

WP-10-04

Benefits of Relationship Banking: Evidence from Consumer Credit Markets
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-10-05

The Effect of Sales Tax Holidays on Household Consumption Patterns
Nathan Marwell and Leslie McGranahan

WP-10-06

Gathering Insights on the Forest from the Trees: A New Metric for Financial Conditions
Scott Brave and R. Andrew Butters

WP-10-07

Identification of Models of the Labor Market
Eric French and Christopher Taber

WP-10-08

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Public Pensions and Labor Supply Over the Life Cycle
Eric French and John Jones

WP-10-09

Explaining Asset Pricing Puzzles Associated with the 1987 Market Crash
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-10-10

Does Prenatal Sex Selection Improve Girls’ Well‐Being? Evidence from India
Luojia Hu and Analía Schlosser

WP-10-11

Mortgage Choices and Housing Speculation
Gadi Barlevy and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-12

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard Reduce the Cost of Capital?
Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

WP-10-13

Introduction to the Macroeconomic Dynamics:
Special issues on money, credit, and liquidity
Ed Nosal, Christopher Waller, and Randall Wright

WP-10-14

Summer Workshop on Money, Banking, Payments and Finance: An Overview
Ed Nosal and Randall Wright

WP-10-15

Cognitive Abilities and Household Financial Decision Making
Sumit Agarwal and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-10-16

Complex Mortgages
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang, Clemens Sialm, and Edward Zhong

WP-10-17

The Role of Housing in Labor Reallocation
Morris Davis, Jonas Fisher, and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-10-18

6