View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race
and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP 2005-02

Comments Welcome

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?

Lisa Barrow
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Cecilia Elena Rouse
Princeton University and NBER

February 2005

We thank Orley Ashenfelter, Kristin Butcher, Alan Krueger, Bridget Terry Long, and Jesse
Rothstein for useful conversations, and Nina Badgaiyan, Cindy Cassaza, and Sara Christopher for
expert research assistance. We are also grateful to Karima Nagi for the special tabulation of the
NLSY79 data. Funding was generously provided by the Education Research Section and the
Industrial Relations Section. All errors in fact or interpretation are ours. The opinions in this paper
do not reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.

Abstract
Using data from the U.S. Decennial Census and the National Longitudinal Surveys, we find little
evidence of differences in the return to schooling across racial and ethnic groups, even with attempts
to control for ability and measurement error biases. While our point estimates are relatively similar
across racial and ethnic groups, our conclusion is driven in part by relatively large standard errors.
That said, we find no evidence that returns to schooling are lower for African Americans or
Hispanics than for non-minorities. As a result, policies that increase education among the lowskilled have a good possibility of increasing economic well-being and reducing inequality. More
generally, our analysis suggests further research is needed to better understand the nature of
measurement error and ability bias across subgroups in order to fully understand potential
heterogeneity in the return to schooling across the population.

1
I.

Introduction
Inequality in the U.S. has been increasing over the past 25 years. In 1979 workers in the

bottom 10th percentile of the wage distribution earned $6.88 per hour (in 2003 dollars) while those
at the 50th and 90th percentiles earned $14.58 and $30.19 per hour, respectively. By 2000 real wages
at the 10th percentile had grown by roughly 5.4 percent to $7.25. At the same time real wages at the
median and 90th percentile grew to $15.71 and $35.65 per hour, a growth of 7.8 percent at the
median and 18.1 percent at the 90th percentile. Because differences in human capital (education and
experience) account for approximately one-third of the variation in wages and because the mean
economic return to schooling is estimated at 10 percent, many researchers and policy makers have
appealed to education and training policies to bolster the wages of the lowest skilled workers
(Heckman and Carneiro 2004, Krueger 2004).
Much less is known about how the estimated returns to schooling vary across the population.
For example, Carneiro, Heckman and Vytlacil (2003) and Taber (2001) find that the return to
education is higher for more able individuals. In contrast, neither Altonji and Dunn (1996) nor
Ashenfelter and Rouse (2000) find consistent evidence that the returns to schooling are higher for
individuals that come from more advantaged families. Further, Ashenfelter and Rouse (1998)
provide some evidence that the return may be higher for more disadvantaged individuals, and this
pattern would explain some of the empirical estimates of the economic benefit of schooling using
instrumental variables techniques (Card 2001). And yet, much social policy hinges on what we
believe to be the value of education for individuals. For example, policies aimed at improving the
incomes of the lowest skilled members of society will not either improve their economic well-being
or decrease inequality if their returns to schooling are low.

2
In this paper we provide further evidence on the variation in returns to schooling by
examining whether the benefits vary by race and ethnicity of the individual. We do so by estimating
the return to schooling using the U.S. Decennial Census as well as the National Longitudinal
Surveys of Young Men and Young Women, and the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, 1979.
We find that the return to schooling is relatively constant across racial and ethnic groups, even
controlling for ability and measurement error biases. The rest of the paper is organized as follows.
In the next section we lay out the empirical framework, in Section III we describe the data, in
Section IV we present the results, and we conclude in Section V.

II.

Empirical Framework

A.

Basic Specification
Following Mincer (1974) we estimate the relationship between schooling and income by

regressing the (natural) logarithm of the hourly wage (ln wij) of individual i of race or ethnicity j on
years of completed schooling (Sij) controlling for explanatory variables such as potential experience
or age1, sex, race, and geographic region of the country (Xij). As such we estimate:
(1)
(where gij is an error term). The coefficient on the schooling variable ($j) is interpreted as the
percentage increase in the hourly wage associated with one additional year of schooling and is
referred to as the “return to schooling.” Note that while we will refer to it as the “return to
schooling,” it is actually just the average percentage difference in mean earnings for each additional

1

In the analyses using the National Longitudinal Surveys we control for age rather than potential
work experience (age - education - 6) because of possible measurement error in education.

3
year of schooling. As Mincer (1974) shows, if foregone earnings are the only cost of school
attendance this is the private rate of return to the investment in a year of schooling. A more detailed
calculation of the “return” would incorporate the other costs of schooling, including tuition, as well.
Related to many of the econometric issues raised below is the question of why we may or
may not expect to find differences in the estimated return to schooling by race or ethnicity; that is,
why $j may vary by j. If we begin by assuming that equation (1) represents the true relationship
between wages and schooling and that differences in educational attainment occur randomly, then
a constant $j ($j = $) implies that we should estimate the same return to schooling for any subgroup
of the population. However, even if $j is constant we may observe different estimates of the return
to schooling for different subgroups if years of schooling is a poor proxy for human capital due to
differences in school quality and if average school quality varies systematically by race.
Alternatively, $j may not be constant. For example, the return to schooling may depend on
the level of education. In this case, estimating returns to schooling for subgroups of the population
with different levels of education (on average) will generate different estimates of the return to
schooling. Further, it is important to keep in mind that differences in educational attainment do not
occur randomly in the population but instead arise from individuals’ decisions. A simple model of
optimal schooling investment as in Becker (1967) and Card (2001) predicts that differences in
optimal schooling choice arise from differences in the benefits and/or costs of obtaining additional
schooling. As a result, individual differences in costs or expected benefits that vary systematically
by subgroup may generate differing returns-to-schooling estimates for different subgroups. For
example, assuming that education does not affect mortality rates, differences in mortality rates by
race mean that for any given level of education, African Americans have fewer expected years than

4
whites over which to receive the benefits of an additional year of schooling. If the costs of an
additional year of education are the same for all individuals, then an African American who decides
to invest in an additional year of education must expect to receive a larger increase in annual income
than an otherwise similar white individual making the same decision. For these reasons, it is an
empirical question whether the return to schooling is constant across the population.

B.

Econometric Issues
More generally, much of the literature estimating returns to schooling is concerned with

whether the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of $j in equation (1) reflect the causal effect of
education on wages. Specifically, does more schooling cause higher earnings or are more able
people more likely both to get more schooling and to earn higher wages, even in the absence of
additional schooling? In the latter case, the OLS estimates of $j will likely be upward biased due to
selection on ability.
Further, this ability bias may not be constant across the population. For example, if African
Americans and Hispanics tend to attend schools of poorer quality, then those students who manage
to get more schooling (particularly, perhaps, by going to college) may have unusually high ability.
This would generate greater selection bias among African Americans and Hispanics suggesting that
the cross-sectional estimate of the return to schooling is more severely upward biased for these
populations.
In this paper we address the potential for selection bias by including controls for ability

5
directly using test scores and using family relationships by studying siblings.2 When considering
family relationships, we characterize the wage equation as:
(2)
where ln wijk represents the log wage of individual i from racial/ethnic group j and family k, :jk
represents the “family” ability, and the other variables are defined as before. Family ability may
represent a number of things such as genetic endowment with respect to earnings capability or
access to resources that facilitate both educational attainment and labor market earnings. If log
wages are linear and separable in this ability, then one can address selection bias by relating the
difference in wages between family members (or siblings) to the difference in their education. If
there are no further unobserved differences between family members that are correlated with both
schooling differences and differences in earnings, then this “within-sibling” estimator will provide
an unbiased estimate of the return to schooling. In our analysis we can also directly control for an
observable measure of “ability” by also including individual test scores in equation (2).
There have been many previous estimates of the return to schooling using this estimator to
study the mean return to schooling (see, e.g., Gorseline (1932), Chamberlain and Griliches (1975,
1977)). More recently, Altonji and Dunn (1996) and Ashenfelter and Rouse (1998) use this
estimator to study how the returns to schooling differ by family background. We are unaware of
previous applications of this estimator to studying the return to schooling by race and ethnicity.

2

Other researchers, such as Angrist and Krueger (1991), Kane and Rouse (1993), and Card
(1995), address selection bias using instrumental variables estimators. In this strategy one must
identify an “exogenous” event (the instrumental variable) that affects an individual’s years of
completed schooling but that is uncorrelated with the error term in the wage equation.
Unfortunately, it is very difficult to identify valid instrumental variables and one usually requires
large samples in order to get precise estimates.

6
Measurement error in reported schooling poses another econometric challenge. The
attenuation caused by (classical) measurement error is exacerbated in within-sibling estimators, as
identified by Griliches (1977) because sibling education levels are so highly correlated. As such
the within-sibling estimator will generate a downward biased estimate of the return to schooling.
If the measurement error is classical in nature (i.e., uncorrelated with the error term in the wage
equation and with the true level of schooling), then an instrumental variables (IV) estimator using
an independent report of the respondent’s schooling as the instrumental variable will generate
consistent estimates of $j.3
Further, it is not clear why the measurement error need be constant across the population.
The reliability (or “signal-to-noise”) ratio is the proportion of the observed variance in schooling
due to the variance in “true” schooling. If one has two independent estimates of an individual’s
schooling level, the correlation between the two measures provides an estimate of the reliability
ratio.4 Using NLSY79 data we estimate reliability ratios for self-reported schooling, both in levels
(i.e., for each individual) and for the deviation from sibling-means. These estimates are reported in
Table 1. Overall we estimate that 11 percent of the observed variance in schooling levels is due to
measurement error. In addition, there is some variation by race/ethnicity. Nearly 20 percent of the
observed variance in schooling for African Americans is due to error compared to 14 percent for
Hispanics and 8 percent for whites. In contrast, there is not a lot of difference in the estimated

3

In this paper we assume classical measurement error in schooling. Kane, Rouse, and Staiger
(1999) provide evidence that measurement error in schooling may not be classical. Unfortunately
the sample sizes provided in our data are too small to implement their suggested estimator by
race/ethnicity.
4

See Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) for an excellent discussion of measurement error models.

7
reliability ratios by sex. The results in column 2 of Table 1 indicate that sibling differences in
educational attainment include more “noise” than individual measures of educational attainment.
Overall, 26 percent of the variance in sibling-differences in education is due to measurement error,
although the proportion due to error is one-third for African Americans. Based on these estimates,
we expect the estimated returns to schooling for African Americans and to some extent Hispanics
to be more downward biased than that for whites (non-African Americans/non-Hispanics).

III.

Data

A.

U.S. Decennial Census
We begin by using data from the 5 percent samples of the 1980, 1990, and 2000 Decennial

Censuses. The samples included individuals aged 25-65 who were U.S. citizens and born in the
U.S., who worked at least 1 week in the previous year, and who earned at least one-half of the
minimum wage.5

All wages and income are adjusted to 2003 dollars using the Personal

Consumption Expenditures chain-type price index from the Bureau of Economic Analysis. The
regression analysis is based on annual earnings.6
Because the schooling variable changed in 1990, we calculate the number of completed years

5

We constructed an hourly wage rate by adjusting annual wage and salary income by the number
of weeks worked in the previous year and the usual number of hours worked each week. We used
the minimum wage in effect in the year before the Census in question because the Census income
and wages refer to the previous year.
6

We get greater variation when we estimate the returns to schooling using hourly wages rather
than annual earnings. This is because the relationship between greater schooling and more stable
jobs is stronger for African Americans and Hispanics than for non-minorities. Whether this
correlation is explained by access to more stable jobs or changes in labor supply decisions is an
empirical question (Ashenfelter and Ham, 1979).

8
of schooling for 1990 and 2000 according to the recoding suggested by Park (1994). In addition,
in 1980 and 1990 we identify 5 racial groups–White, Black, Native American, Asian, and Other–as
well as people who identified themselves as Hispanic, regardless of their race. (Thus, the 6 racial
and ethnic groups are not mutually exclusive.) While in the 1980 and 1990 Censuses individuals
had to choose one race category, in the 2000 Census, individuals could choose multiple races. To
make the 2000 data as consistent as possible with the previous data, we grouped those who selfidentified as belonging to multiple racial groups into the “other” category.7 Finally, all estimates
using the U.S. Census are weighted by the individual weight assigned by the Census.

B.

National Longitudinal Surveys: Young Men and Young Women Cohorts
Young Men and Young Women are two of the original cohorts of the National Longitudinal

Surveys (NLS). Each cohort was chosen to be representative of Americans aged 14 to 24 in the
initial survey year, 1966 for Young Men and 1968 for Young Women. Both include an over-sample
of African Americans. We combine the Young Men and Young Women cohorts from the 1978
surveys to create a single data set of 7440 individuals. We restrict our estimation sample to those
with hourly pay greater than one-half of the minimum wage in 2003 dollars and those who are not
self-employed, not enrolled in school, and not in the military. Once we exclude those in 1978 with
no hourly pay data and those with no information on highest grade completed, we are left with an
estimation sample of 4802. The weighted means and standard deviations of this full sample are

7

To judge the sensitivity of our results to how we categorized the 1.37 percent of individuals who
selected multiple races, we tried alternative codings. Specifically, we tried running our regressions
for whites counting anyone who selected white only and any other combination including white as
“white” (and similarly for blacks and Asians). These alternative categorizations did not
substantively change our results.

9
provided in Appendix Table 1a.
The NLS also provides information identifying respondent siblings who are also respondents
in the Young Men or Young Women cohorts. Based on this information, we were able to identify
567 families with multiple respondents (1263 respondents) in our estimation sample. If we further
restrict the sibling sample to have IQ scores we are left with 298 families (642 respondents). As
shown in Appendix Table 1b, on average the sibling sample is somewhat younger than the full
estimation sample. Otherwise, the mean characteristics are quite similar.
The last three columns in Appendix Tables 1a and 1b list descriptive statistics for the full and
sibling samples conditional on the respondents having a non-missing IQ score. The underlying test
scores used to construct the IQ score were only collected for individuals who had completed nine
years of schooling as of the initial survey year resulting in a non-random sample of respondents for
whom we have an IQ score. In particular, respondents with non-missing IQ scores are less likely to
be African American or live in the South and have higher average wages and more years of
schooling. Within the sibling sample, respondents with IQ scores are also more likely to be male.

C.

National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 (NLSY79)
The National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 (NLSY79) is a survey of youth aged 14 to

21 as of December 31, 1978 including a nationally representative sample of the civilian
noninstitutionalized youths, an over-sample of civilian Hispanic, black, and economically
disadvantaged non-black/non-Hispanic youth, and a small military sample of youths aged 17 to 21

10
years.8 We use the 1993 survey of the NLSY79 in the analysis below and limit our sample to those
with hourly pay greater than one-half of the minimum wage in 1993 and less than $300 per hour,
as well as those who are not self-employed, enrolled in school or currently in the military.
An advantage of the NLSY79 is that in 1980 most survey participants were administered
the ASVAB (Armed Services Vocational Aptitude Battery), a basic skills test, from which it is
possible to construct an Armed Forces Qualification Test (AFQT) score. While researchers disagree
about whether AFQT scores mostly reflect “innate intelligence” or also reflect skills acquired in
school, most would agree that they reflect some information about the skills that individuals possess
at the time of the test.9 We use the AFQT as a measure of “observed” ability.10
As in the case of the NLS Young Men and Young Women surveys, many of the NLSY79
respondents have siblings who are also included in the survey. In 1979, 5914 of the civilian
respondents lived in a household with at least one other sibling (NLS Handbook, Table 3.2, p. 35).
And, in 1993 respondents were asked about their educational attainment as well as the educational
attainment of up to 13 of their siblings – whether or not these other siblings were respondents in the

8

Much of the military sample is dropped after 1984, and the supplemental sample of
economically disadvantaged youths is dropped after 1990.
9

For example, Herrnstein and Murray (1994) argue that the AFQT has many of the properties
of an IQ test – the scores do not just reflect specific knowledge that has been learned in school,
rather they reflect more general factors of “intelligence.” In contrast, Neal and Johnson (1996)
argue that AFQT scores increase with years of schooling and therefore are not a good measure of
IQ. Others, such as Rodgers and Spriggs (1996), argue that the AFQT is a racially biased test.
10

In the estimates presented here, we simply control for AFQT and do not address the fact that
individuals took the AFQT at different ages and had therefore completed differing years of
schooling. We have also estimated our models controlling for the individual’s education as of 1979
with qualitatively similar results.

11
original NLSY79.11 As a result, we can obtain own-reported and sibling-reported measures of a
respondent’s education level for those with siblings in the original NLSY79 sample who also
participated in the 1993 wave.
Once we additionally exclude those with no wage information and no information on
education, our “full sample” includes 6119 men and women between the ages of 28 and 36. Our
sibling sample contains information on 2419 individuals from 1062 households (for an average of
2.3 observations per household). Means and standard deviations for these samples are provided in
Appendix Table 2.

IV.

Results

A.

Results Using the Decennial Census
Using data from the Decennial Censuses allows us to get very precise estimates of the

relationship between education and wages by race and ethnicity. In addition, we look at how the
relationships have changed between 1979 and 1999 when there have been large increases in both
inequality and the returns to schooling. The primary drawback with the Census data is that we
cannot examine the potential for ability bias or measurement error problems.
We present estimates of the returns to schooling for men and women by six race/ethnicity
categories in Figure 1a.12 In 1979, an additional year is associated with a 7.3 percent increase in

11

12

Respondents were also asked a few other questions about their siblings (e.g., age, sex).

These returns to schooling were estimated from OLS regressions of the logarithm of annual
earnings on years of schooling, indicators for 9 regions, a quadratic in potential experience, and in
Figure 1a, an indicator for whether the individual was female. The regressions were weighted by
the Census weight.

12
annual income for African Americans and a 8.5 percent increase in annual income for whites.
Between 1979 and 1989 the estimated return to schooling increased dramatically for all races –
especially African Americans – but remained in a relatively tight range from 10.7 percent for the
“other” category to 12.3 percent for Asians and Pacific Islanders. Between 1989 and 1999 there was
a much smaller increase in the estimated returns to education on average, but an increase in the
range of estimates (10.2 percent for “other to 13.6 percent for Asians and Pacific Islanders). As
shown in the contrast between Figures 1b (for women) and 1c (for men), this increase in the
variation in the returns to schooling by race/ethnicity is particularly true for men.13
Based on estimates of the returns to schooling using Census data, we would conclude that
the estimated return to schooling for African Americans is roughly the same as that for whites and
that the return for Hispanics is somewhat lower. While previous selection- and measurement errorcorrected estimates suggest OLS generates an estimate of the return to schooling that is roughly
“right” overall (because the selection and measurement error biases balance one another) (e.g.,
Ashenfelter and Rouse (1998)), we do not know if this “rule of thumb” holds by race and ethnicity.

B.

Results Using the NLS Young Men and Young Women
Using the NLS Young Men and Young Women cohorts we can similarly estimate returns

to education overall and separately for whites and African Americans. While we cannot generate
estimates for any other racial or ethnic group, we can use the NLS measure of ability and

13

For an analysis of the change in returns to schooling by race and ethnicity between 1979 and
2000 using the Current Population Survey see Bradbury (2002).

13
information on siblings to get some idea about the role of ability bias.14 Later, when we turn to the
NLSY79 cohort we will additionally be able to address measurement error issues.
Table 2a provides various estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) overall and separately
for African Americans and whites using the NLS Young Men and Young Women cohorts. Each cell
represents estimates from a separate regression and each column represents estimates from a
different specification. All estimates are based on a regression of the natural logarithm of hourly
pay on years of completed education, a third-order polynomial in age, an indicator for whether the
individual is female, an indicator for whether the individual lives in the South, and a constant. We
weight observations using the 1978 sampling weights. Estimates for the overall sample (shown in
row 1) include indicators for whether the individual’s race is African American or other.15
Using the entire sample we estimate that an extra year of education increases hourly pay by
almost 6 percent. The separate estimates by race are quite similar. Although the estimate for
African Americans is somewhat higher than for whites, the difference is not statistically significant.
The estimates shown in column (1) of Table 2a do not control for the potential selection on ability
problem discussed above. Because IQ scores are missing for a nonrandom subset of the sample, the
estimates in column (2) are based on the sample of individuals who have an NLS measure of IQ but
do not include IQ score in the regression. In column (3) we control for ability by including the IQ
score in the regression. The column (2) estimates of the returns to education are somewhat smaller

14

In addition, because the sample sizes are so small we cannot estimate the returns to schooling
for men and women separately.
15

These specifications and those using the NLSY79 do not account for possible correlations
across individuals within the same household. As a result the standard errors are conservative,
although in the cross-sectional specifications allowing for such intra-household correlations makes
little difference.

14
at 5 percent, but once again we find no strong evidence that the returns to education differ between
African Americans and whites. Controlling for IQ score in column (3), we see some evidence that
indeed those who get more education are more able as the estimated returns to education decline by
almost one percentage point relative to the column (2) estimates.16 Note, however, there is a slightly
larger decline in the estimates between columns (2) and (3) for whites. This larger decrease may
be indicative of more selection on ability for whites or the IQ score may be a noisier measure of
ability for African Americans such that the column (3) estimates do not fully account for ability bias
for this subgroup.
In Table 2b we turn to the NLS Young Men and Young Women sibling sample in order to
allow for sibling fixed effects as well. The results in column (1) are based on the sample of siblings
and are quite similar to the estimates based on the entire sample. The returns to education estimated
from the sibling sample is about 5.5 percent overall; the estimate for African Americans is higher
at roughly 7 percent although once again the difference is not statistically significant. When we
allow for a sibling fixed effect in the column (2) estimates, the estimates decline by 10 percent for
African Americans and 25 percent for whites. In column (3) we further restrict the sibling sample
to those with non-missing IQ scores but do not directly control for IQ score in the regression. Again
we see that the subsample with non-missing IQ scores is not a random subset of our estimation
sample. Returns to schooling estimates for African Americans and whites are again slightly lower
than for the full sibling sample. Finally, in column (4) we re-estimate returns to schooling while
controlling for ability with IQ score and allowing for a sibling fixed effect. The estimated return to

16

Estimates that include IQ score but include an indicator for IQ score is missing are quite similar
to the estimates shown in column (2). The coefficient (standard error) estimates are 5.06 (0.25)
overall, 5.93 (0.44) for African Americans, and 4.86 (0.30) for whites.

15
schooling for African Americans is little changed by including IQ score once we have already
allowed for a sibling fixed effect. The estimate of the return to schooling for whites declines by 16
percent when controlling for a direct measure of ability.
In general we conclude from these surveys that the returns to schooling for African
Americans and whites are roughly equal, even after controlling for ability bias. However, using
these surveys we cannot correct for classical measurement error bias.

C.

Results Using the NLSY79
Estimates of the return to schooling using the NLSY79 are presented in Table 3 overall and

in Tables 4a and 4b for women and men separately. Each table has the following layout. Each cell
represents the return to schooling (× 100) from a separate regression. The basic specification is an
OLS regression of the natural logarithm of hourly pay on years of completed education, a third-order
polynomial in age, an indicator for whether the individual is female, indicators for four geographic
regions, and a constant. These regressions are unweighted, although results are similar if we weight.
Further, as with the analysis using the older NLS surveys, we do not cluster the standard errors on
the household such that the standard errors, especially those within sibling, are understated.17
Each column represents a different specification. The specifications in columns (1) and (2)
use the full sample; those in columns (3) - (8) are restricted to the sibling sample. The estimates in
the odd-numbered columns do not include the AFQT score while those in the even-numbered
columns do. The estimates in columns (5) - (8) control for a sibling fixed effect, and those in

17

In the cross-sectional specifications, the standard errors using “cluster” are very similar to those
that do not use allow for such intra-household correlations; the standard errors for the within-sibling
specifications presented in columns (5) and (6) in Table 3 are understated by about 50%.

16
columns (7) and (8) use the average of the sibling-reports of the respondent’s education as an
instrumental variable in an IV analysis. Thus, the estimates in columns (1) and (3) represent the
cross-sectional estimates and those in columns (2) and (4) address for selection bias by controlling
for the AFQT score. The estimates in column (5) control for selection by including a sibling fixed
effect; those in column (6) control for both a sibling fixed effect and the AFQT score; and the
estimates in columns (7) and (8) are similar to those in columns (5) and (6) but also correct for
measurement error.
In Table 3 we estimate an overall cross-sectional return to schooling of about 9 percent. The
estimate is highest among African Americans (10.4 percent) and lowest among Hispanics (7.6
percent). Only the estimated return for Hispanics is statistically different from that for the other two
groups. In general, controlling for selection by including an AFQT score decreases the crosssectional estimate of the return to schooling by about 3 percentage points (i.e., by comparing
columns (2) and (1) or columns (4) and (3)). However, while controlling for the AFQT makes the
biggest difference for the estimated returns to schooling (i.e., decreases the coefficient by the most)
for African Americans and Hispanics in the full sample (columns (1) and (2)), it makes the biggest
difference for non-minorities in the sibling sample (columns (3) and (4)). Overall, based on the
cross-sectional estimates, we find little difference in the return to schooling by race/ethnicity.
Estimates that account for a sibling fixed effect are presented in columns (5) - (8). As also
found with the older NLS surveys, a comparison of the estimates in columns (3) and (5) (or columns
(4) and (6)) suggest that controlling for a sibling fixed effect makes a bigger difference for nonminorities than for minorities, especially African Americans. In fact, the within-sibling estimate of
the return to schooling for African Americans is at most 1percentage point lower than the cross-

17
sectional estimate. The fact that controlling for siblings makes a smaller difference for minorities
than non-minorities may reflect less selection bias in the cross-sectional returns to schooling. Or,
it may suggest that controlling for a sibling fixed effect is less effective for some populations than
others. Why might this occur? While we limit our sample to “siblings” (excluding other household
relationships, such as spouses, parents, foster siblings, step-siblings, and adopted siblings), we
cannot distinguish between “full siblings” and “half-siblings.” If African Americans and Hispanics
are more likely to live with half-siblings than are non-minorities, then the family fixed effect may
not be a good proxy for unobserved family “ability.”18
Finally, the overall measurement error corrected (IV) estimate of the within-sibling return
to schooling increases to 9.16 percent in column (7) relative to an estimate of 7.6 percent in column
(5) suggesting an attenuation bias of about 20 percent. Further, we find that correcting for
measurement error has the greatest effect on the estimated returns to schooling for African
Americans, as expected based on the reliability ratios in Table 1. Generally, while we continue to
estimate a larger point estimate for African Americans than for Hispanics and non-minorities, the
differences across race/ethnicity are not statistically significant.19
While we find that returns to schooling, overall, do not appear to vary much by race or
ethnicity, in Tables 4a and 4b we examine whether this pattern also holds separately for men and

18

As evidence consistent with this explanation, the within-sibling coefficients in column (6) (that
control for AFQT) decrease the most relative to column (5) (that do not control for AFQT) for
African Americans. This pattern of results would be expected if the AFQT controls for other aspects
of “ability” that are not captured by the sibling fixed effect.
19

In results not presented here, we have also estimated these specifications using annual earnings
rather than hourly wages. While the estimated returns to schooling are alittle higher, there are no
differences by race or ethnicity.

18
women. The results for women are reported in Table 4a and those for men in Table 4b. These tables
have a similar structure to Table 3. We continue to estimate no significant differences in the returns
to schooling across African Americans, Hispanics, and non-minorities for both men and women.
While this result may partially obtain because of smaller sample sizes (resulting in less precise
estimates), the point estimates are also quite similar.

V.

Conclusion
Alarmed by the increasing wage and income inequality in the U.S., many researchers and

policymakers who are concerned that low-income individuals are losing ground have turned to
policies aimed at increasing educational attainment. And because African Americans and Hispanics
are disproportionately among the low-income, they are also disproportionately the focus of such
policies. Yet, we know little about the magnitude of the economic benefit from the increased
education for these subgroups of the population. Using data from the Census and the National
Longitudinal Surveys, we find little evidence of differences in the return to schooling across racial
and ethnic groups, even with attempts to control for ability and measurement error biases. While
we find point estimates that are relatively similar across racial and ethnic groups, we also partly
conclude this because of relatively large standard errors in some specifications due to small sample
sizes. That said, we find no evidence that returns to schooling are lower for African Americans or
Hispanics than for non-minorities. As a result, policies that increase education among the lowskilled have a good possibility of increasing economic well-being and reducing inequality.
We find some evidence that measurement error and selection bias may differ by race and
ethnicity. For example, self-reported levels of schooling are “noisier” for African Americans than

19
for other groups. And, we find less evidence of ability bias among African Americans and Hispanics
than among non-minorities. The finding of less ability bias among minorities may arise because
there is indeed less selection among these groups. Or, estimators that attempt to address selfselection may be less effective for some subgroups. More generally, our analysis suggests further
research is needed to better understand the nature of measurement error and ability bias across
subgroups in order to fully understand potential heterogeneity in the return to schooling across the
population.

20
References
Altonji, Joseph and Thomas Dunn. “The Effects of Family Characteristics on the Return to
Education.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 78 (1996), 692-704.
Angrist, Joshua D. and Alan B. Krueger. “Does Compulsory Schooling Affect Schooling and
Earnings?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 106 (November 1991): 979-1014.
Ashenfelter, Orley and John Ham. “Education, Unemployment, and Earnings.” Journal of Political
Economy 87 (October 1979), no. 5 part 2: S99-S116.
Ashenfelter, Orley and Alan Krueger. “Estimating the Returns to Schooling Using a New Sample
of Twins.” American Economic Review 84 (December 1994): 1157-1173.
Ashenfelter, Orley and Cecilia Rouse. “Schooling, Intelligence, and Income in America” in
Kenneth Arrow, Samuel Bowles, and Steven Durlauf, eds. Meritocracy and Economic
Inequality, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000, 89-117.
Ashenfelter, Orley and Cecilia Rouse. “Income, Schooling, and Ability: Evidence from a New
Sample of Twins.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 no. 1 (February 1998), pp. 253-284.
Becker, Gary S. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Refernce to
Education. New York: Columbia University Press, 1967.
Bradbury, Katharine L. “Education and Wages in the 1980s and 1990s: Are All Groups Moving Up
Together?” New England Economic Review, First quarter 2002, pp. 19-46.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. NLS Handbook, 2003. Retrieved January 13,
2005, from http://www.bls.gov/nls/handbook/nlshpdf.htm.
Card, David. “Earnings, Schooling, and Ability Revisited” in Solomon Polachek, ed., Research in
Labor Economics, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press (1995), 23-48.
Card, David, “Estimating the Return to Schooling: Progress on Some Persistent Econometric
Problems,” Econometrica 69, no. 5 (September 2001): 1127-1160.
Carneiro, Pedro and James J. Heckman. “Human Capital Policy” in Inequality in America: What
Role for Human Capital Policies? Benjamin M. Friedman (ed.) (Cambridge, MA: The MIT
Press, 2003), pp. 77-239.
Carneiro, Pedro, James J. Heckman, and Edward Vytlacil. “Understanding What Instrumental
Variables Estimate: Estimating Marginal and Average Returns to Education.” University
of Chicago working paper, 2003.

21
Chamberlain, Gary and Zvi Griliches. “Unobservables with a Variance-Components Structure:
Ability, Schooling and the Economic Success of Brothers.” International Economic Review
16 (June 1975): 422-449.
Chamberlain, Gary and Zvi Griliches. “More on Brothers.” In Kinometrics: The Determinants of
Socio-economic Success within and between Families, edited by Paul Taubman.
(Amsterdam: North-Holland), 1977.
Gorseline, D.W. The Effect of Schooling Upon Income. (Bloomington: Indiana University Press),
1932.
Griliches, Zvi. “Estimating the Returns to Schooling:
Econometrica 45, no. 1 (January 1977): 1-22.

Some Econometric Problems.”

Herrnstein, Richard J. and Charles Murray. The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in
American Life (New York: The Free Press), 1994.
Kane, Thomas, Cecilia Rouse, and Douglas Staiger. “Estimating the Returns to Schooling When
Schooling is Misreported” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7235,
July 1999.
Krueger, Alan. “Inequality, Too Much of a Good Thing” in Inequality in America: What Role for
Human Capital Policies? Benjamin M. Friedman (ed.) (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press,
2003), pp. 1-75.
Mincer, Jacob. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings (New York: Columbia University
Press), 1974.
Neal, Derek A., and William A. Johnson. “The Role of Pre-Market Factors in Black-White Wage
Differences.” Journal of Political Economy 104 (October 1996), pp. 869-895.
Park, Jin Huem. “Estimation of Sheepskin Effects and Returns to Schooling Using the Old and the
New CPS Measures of Educational Attainment.” Industrial Relations Section Working Paper
#338 (August 1994).
Rodgers, William and William Spriggs. “What Does AFQT Really Measure: Race, Wages,
Schooling and the AFQT Score.” The Review of Black Political Economy, 24 (1996), pp.
13-46.
Taber, Christopher. “The Rising College Premium in the Eighties: Return to College or Return to
Unobserved Ability?” Review of Economic Studies 68, no. 3 (July 2001), pp. 665-691.

22

Notes: Estimates use U.S. Decennial Census Data from 1980, 1990, and 2000 and are based on a
regression of the logarithm of annual earnings on years of schooling, indicators for 9 regions, a
quadratic in potential experience, and an indicator for whether the individual was female.
Observations are weighted using Census individual weights.

23

Notes: Estimates use U.S. Decennial Census Data from 1980, 1990, and 2000 and are based on a
regression of the logarithm of annual earnings on years of schooling, indicators for 9 regions, and
a quadratic in potential experience. Observations are weighted using Census individual weights.

24

Notes: See notes for Figure 1b.

25

Table 1
Estimated Reliability Ratios for Schooling Levels and Within-Siblings,
by Race, Ethnicity, and Sex of Individual
Levels

Within-sibling
All

All

0.89

0.74

African American

0.81

0.67

Hispanic

0.86

0.77

Not African American/Not Hispanic

0.92

0.78
Women

All

0.88

0.76

African American

0.83

0.68

Hispanic

0.82

0.76

Not African American/Not Hispanic

0.91

0.81
Men

All

0.89

0.73

African American

0.79

0.65

Hispanic

0.88

0.77

Not African American/Not Hispanic

0.92

0.76

Note: Estimates are based on sibling data from the NLSY79. The within-sibling education is the
deviation of the individual’s schooling level from the mean education of his or her siblings.

26
Table 2a
Estimates of the Returns to Schooling Using the NLS Young Men and Young Women Cohorts
(1)

(2)

(3)

Overall

5.69
(0.23)

5.11
(0.30)

4.18
(0.35)

African American

6.24
(0.41)

6.03
(0.78)

5.32
(0.85)

White

5.51
(0.27)

5.02
(0.33)

4.11
(0.38)

Drop observations
missing IQ score

N

Y

Y

Include IQ score

N

N

Y

Notes: Estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) based on regressions of the natural logarithm
of hourly pay on years of completed schooling, an indicator for sex equals female, a third-order
polynomial in age, an indicator for living in the South, an indicator for region is missing, and a
constant. Observations are weighted using the NLS provided sampling weights for 1978. The
“overall” estimates reported in row 1 also include indicators for race is African American and race
is other. Estimates in column (3) include the NLS measure of IQ.

27

Table 2b
Estimates of the Returns to Schooling Using Siblings from the NLS Young Men
and Young Women Cohorts
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Overall

5.49
(0.47)

4.63
(0.85)

3.65
(1.32)

3.14
(1.38)

African American

7.05
(0.73)

6.28
(1.23)

5.73
(3.34)

5.54
(3.43)

White

5.09
(0.59)

3.80
(1.09)

3.27
(1.46)

2.76
(1.54)

Drop observations
missing IQ score

N

N

Y

Y

Include IQ score

N

N

N

Y

Sibling fixed effect

N

Y

Y

Y

Notes: Estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) based on regressions of the natural logarithm
of hourly pay on years of completed schooling, an indicator for sex equals female, a third-order
polynomial in age, an indicator for living in the South, an indicator for region is missing, and a
constant. Observations are weighted using the NLS provided sampling weights for 1978. The
“overall” estimates reported in row 1 also include indicators for race is African American and race
is other. Estimates in columns (2), (3), and (4) include a family fixed effect. Estimates in column (4)
include the NLS measure of IQ.

28
Table 3
OLS and IV Estimates of the Returns to Schooling Using the NLSY 1979 Cohort
Full Sample

Sibling Sample
Cross-section

Within Siblings

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

IV

IV

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Overall

9.29
(0.24)

6.29
(0.30)

9.36
(0.40)

6.15
(0.48)

7.60
(0.69)

5.21
(0.76)

9.16
(0.88)

6.74
(1.02)

African American

10.43
(0.49)

7.15
(0.58)

9.97
(0.73)

7.14
(0.89)

9.84
(1.23)

6.60
(1.38)

12.66
(1.71)

9.87
(2.12)

Hispanic

7.63
(0.55)

4.22
(0.67)

9.18
(1.05)

5.92
(1.21)

7.21
(1.60)

5.32
(1.76)

8.52
(1.91)

6.45
(2.20)

Not African American/Not
Hispanic

9.43
(0.33)

6.69
(0.40)

9.17
(0.54)

5.64
(0.66)

6.30
(1.00)

4.44
(1.07)

7.54
(1.24)

5.65
(1.38)

Include AFQT score

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

Sibling Fixed Effect

N

N

N

N

Y

Y

Y

Y

Notes: Estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) based on regressions of the natural logarithm of hourly pay in 1993 on years of
completed schooling, an indicator for sex equals female, a third-order polynomial in age, indicator for regions, an indicator for region
is missing, and a constant. The “overall” estimates reported in row 1 also include indicators for race is African American and ethnicity
is Hispanic. Estimates in columns (2), (4), (6), and (8) include the AFQT score. The average of the sibling-reports of the
respondent’s education is used as the instrumental variable in columns (7) and (8). All estimates are unweighted.

29
Table 4a
OLS and IV Estimates of the Returns to Schooling Using the NLSY 1979 Cohort, Women
Full Sample

Sibling Sample
Cross-section

Within Siblings

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

IV

IV

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Overall

10.45
(0.35)

7.37
(0.42)

9.79
(0.80)

6.01
(0.92)

9.87
(1.31)

6.62
(1.44)

10.83
(1.59)

7.37
(1.83)

African American

11.45
(0.67)

7.54
(0.78)

12.08
(1.35)

7.37
(1.56)

10.63
(2.42)

5.39
(2.59)

13.93
(3.38)

8.26
(4.06)

Hispanic

9.48
(0.74)

5.52
(0.91)

11.88
(2.04)

7.17
(2.38)

9.04
(6.04)

7.36
(3.65)

9.71
(3.54)

8.27
(4.51)

Not African American/Not
Hispanic

10.37
(0.50)

7.90
(0.59)

8.10
(1.14)

5.35
(1.31)

9.13
(1.95)

6.61
(2.13)

9.54
(2.23)

6.75
(2.52)

Include AFQT score

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

Sibling Fixed Effect

N

N

N

N

Y

Y

Y

Y

Notes: Estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) based on regressions of the natural logarithm of hourly pay in 1993 on years of
completed schooling, a third-order polynomial in age, indicator for regions, an indicator for region is missing, and a constant. The
“overall” estimates reported in row 1 also include indicators for race is African American and ethnicity is Hispanic. Estimates in
columns (2), (4), (6), and (8) include the AFQT score. The average of the sibling-reports of the respondent’s education are used as the
instrumental variable in columns (7) and (8). All estimates are unweighted.

30
Table 4b
OLS and IV Estimates of the Returns to Schooling Using the NLSY 1979 Cohort, Men
Full Sample

Sibling Sample
Cross-section

Within Siblings

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

IV

IV

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Overall

8.23
(0.34)

5.28
(0.42)

8.01
(0.70)

5.15
(0.85)

5.69
(1.26)

3.32
(1.39)

8.16
(1.66)

5.91
(1.98)

African American

9.43
(0.72)

6.66
(0.87)

8.66
(1.31)

7.60
(1.61)

8.05
(2.10)

4.88
(2.47)

8.20
(2.99)

4.89
(3.92)

Hispanic

6.05
(0.79)

2.90
(0.96)

6.31
(1.94)

3.73
(2.20)

2.92
(3.55)

0.52
(3.96)

8.61
(4.27)

6.97
(5.04)

Not African American/Not
Hispanic

8.66
(0.44)

5.67
(0.55)

8.22
(0.93)

4.35
(1.13)

5.06
(1.71)

3.30
(1.85)

7.79
(2.24)

6.23
(2.56)

Include AFQT score

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

N

Y

Sibling Fixed Effect

N

N

N

N

Y

Y

Y

Y

Notes: Estimates of the return to schooling (× 100) based on regressions of the natural logarithm of hourly pay in 1993 on years of
completed schooling, a third-order polynomial in age, indicator for regions, an indicator for region is missing, and a constant. The
“overall” estimates reported in row 1 also include indicators for race is African American and ethnicity is Hispanic. Estimates in
columns (2), (4), (6), and (8) include the AFQT score. The average of the sibling-reports of the respondent’s education are used as the
instrumental variable in columns (7) and (8). All estimates are unweighted.

31

Appendix Table 1a
Mean Characteristics for the 1978 National Longitudinal Surveys
Young Men and Young Women Cohorts
Full Sample

Sub-sample with IQ Scores

Overall

African
American

White

Overall

African
American

White

15.39
[10.13]

11.84
[5.82]

15.88
[10.50]

16.17
[10.12]

12.79
[5.78]

16.42
[10.33]

Years of completed
schooling

13.30
[2.53]

12.20
[2.50]

13.44
[2.48]

13.73
[2.29]

13.00
[2.00]

13.78
[2.30]

Female

0.45
[0.50]

0.49
[0.50]

0.44
[0.50]

0.43
[0.50]

0.51
[0.50]

0.43
[0.49]

Age

29.66
[3.30]

29.42
[3.28]

29.70
[3.30]

30.01
[3.06]

29.66
[2.94]

30.04
[3.07]

Southern region

0.34
[0.48]

0.65
[0.48]

0.30
[0.46]

0.30
[0.46]

0.56
[0.50]

0.28
[0.45]

Number of observations

4802

1263

3486

3240

558

2646

Hourly pay

Notes: Standard deviations are in brackets. All means and standard deviations are calculated using the 1978 survey weights. Hourly pay
is in real 2003 dollars. Men’s age equals age in the initial survey year plus 12; women’s age equals age in the initial survey year plus 10.
The overall sample is 12 percent African American, 0.8 percent other, and 87 percent white. Conditional on having an IQ score, the overall
sample is 7.4 percent African American, 0.7 percent other, and 92 percent white.

32
Appendix Table 1b
Mean Characteristics for Siblings from the 1978 National Longitudinal Surveys
Young Men and Young Women Cohorts
Full Sample

Sub-sample with IQ scores

Overall

African
American

White

Overall

African
American

White

Hourly pay

15.11
[12.60]

11.59
[5.43]

15.71
[13.42]

16.37
[10.66]

13.98
[6.51]

16.46
[10.82]

Highest grade completed

13.48
[2.48]

12.16
[2.67]

13.72
[2.43]

14.09
[2.36]

13.02
[1.90]

14.16
[2.36]

Female

0.44
[0.50]

0.49
[0.50]

0.43
[0.50]

0.39
[0.49]

0.43
[0.50]

0.39
[0.49]

Age

28.41
[2.73]

28.39
[2.85]

28.39
[2.68]

28.96
[2.56]

28.91
[2.49]

28.91
[2.50]

Southern region

0.35
[0.48]

0.70
[0.46]

0.29
[0.45]

0.30
[0.46]

0.62
[0.49]

0.27
[0.44]

Number of observations

1263

434

819

642

124

512

Notes: See notes for Appendix Table 1a. The overall sample is 16.3 percent African American, 0.6 percent other, and 83 percent white.
Conditional on having an IQ score, the overall sample is 8.4 percent African American, 0.9 percent other, and 91 percent white.

33
Appendix Table 2
Mean Characteristics for the 1993 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, 1979
Full Sample

Sibling Sample

Overall

African
American

Hispanic

White

Overall

African
American

Hispanic

White

Hourly pay

13.67
[9.97]

11.52
[7.66]

13.22
[10.30]

15.06
[10.76]

13.94
[11.43]

11.41
[8.37]

13.79
[14.08]

15.67
[11.76]

Years of completed
schooling

13.11
[2.35]

12.89
[2.01]

12.43
[2.48]

13.48
[2.42]

13.21
[2.30]

12.87
[2.00]

12.57
[2.11]

13.68
[2.46]

Female

0.48
[0.50]

0.48
[0.50]

0.47
[0.50]

0.47
[0.50]

0.46
[0.50]

0.45
[0.50]

0.43
[0.49]

0.47
[0.50]

Age

31.51
[2.25]

31.55
[2.23]

31.39
[2.25]

31.54
[2.26]

31.17
[2.05]

31.23
[2.04]

31.00
[2.04]

31.19
[2.07]

Northeast region

0.17
[0.37]

0.14
[0.35]

0.14
[0.35]

0.19
[0.39]

0.17
[0.37]

0.12
[0.32]

0.13
[0.33]

0.21
[0.41]

North Central region

0.23
[0.42]

0.17
[0.37]

0.07
[0.26]

0.33
[0.47]

0.25
[0.43]

0.14
[0.34]

0.10
[0.29]

0.38
[0.49]

Southern region

0.41
[0.49]

0.62
[0.48]

0.31
[0.46]

0.32
[0.46]

0.41
[0.49]

0.71
[0.45]

0.31
[0.46]

0.25
[0.44]

64.97
[21.71]

51.62
[18.73]

57.83
[19.82]

75.25
[18.52]

63.97
[21.63]

50.03
[17.96]

58.42
[18.56]

75.29
[18.51]

6119

1819

1142

3158

2419

786

446

1187

AFQT score
Number of
observations

34
Notes: Standard deviations are in brackets. All means and standard deviations are calculated using the 1993 survey weights. Hourly
pay is in real 2003 dollars. Age equals age in the initial survey year plus 14.

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg

WP-02-06

Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-07

Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Firm’s First Year
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

Estimating Models of On-the-Job Search using Record Statistics
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-18

Banking Market Conditions and Deposit Interest Rates
Richard J. Rosen

WP-03-19

Creating a National State Rainy Day Fund: A Modest Proposal to Improve Future
State Fiscal Performance
Richard Mattoon

WP-03-20

Managerial Incentive and Financial Contagion
Sujit Chakravorti, Anna Llyina and Subir Lall

WP-03-21

Women and the Phillips Curve: Do Women’s and Men’s Labor Market Outcomes
Differentially Affect Real Wage Growth and Inflation?
Katharine Anderson, Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-03-22

Evaluating the Calvo Model of Sticky Prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-03-23

The Growing Importance of Family and Community: An Analysis of Changes in the
Sibling Correlation in Earnings
Bhashkar Mazumder and David I. Levine

WP-03-24

Should We Teach Old Dogs New Tricks? The Impact of Community College Retraining
on Older Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan

WP-03-25

Trade Deflection and Trade Depression
Chad P. Brown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-03-26

China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani and John W. Schindler

WP-03-27

International Business Cycles Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-03-28

Firing Costs and Business Cycle Fluctuations
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-03-29

Spatial Organization of Firms
Yukako Ono

WP-03-30

Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France
François R. Velde

WP-03-31

Deregulation and the Relationship Between Bank CEO
Compensation and Risk-Taking
Elijah Brewer III, William Curt Hunter and William E. Jackson III

WP-03-32

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Compatibility and Pricing with Indirect Network Effects: Evidence from ATMs
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-03-33

Self-Employment as an Alternative to Unemployment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-03-34

Where the Headquarters are – Evidence from Large Public Companies 1990-2000
Tyler Diacon and Thomas H. Klier

WP-03-35

Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Institutional Quality and Financial Market Development:
Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

7