View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

On the Relationship between Mobility,
Population Growth, and Capital
Spending in the United States
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

WP 2009-25

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth,
and Capital Spending in the United States∗
Marco Bassetto†and Leslie McGranahan‡
November 30, 2009

Abstract
In this paper, we assess the empirical relationship between population growth, mobility,
and state-level capital spending in the United States. To evaluate the magnitude of the
coefficients, we introduce an explicit, quantitative political-economy model of government
spending determination, where mobility and population growth generate departures from
Ricardian equivalence. Our estimates find strong responses in the level of capital provision
per capita to these demographic movements; in fact, the resulting coefficients are stronger
than the model delivers. Regression coefficients on population growth and mobility also
yield opposite implications for the direction to which spending is distorted by the politicaleconomy friction, posing a further challenge.

1

Introduction

The sharp recession recently experienced by the United States has highlighted once more the
plight of states whose finances are bound by constitutional restrictions on their indebtedness. The
∗

Very preliminary. We thank R. Andrew Butters for valuable research assistance. Marco Bassetto gratefully

acknowledges the National Science Foundation for support through grant # 0754551.
†
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and NBER
‡
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

1

magnitude of the shortfalls in many states’ revenue projections and their anticipated expenses
calls into serious question their ability to balance their books without substantial help from the
federal government, which is not bound by similar rules. Throughout the recession, the federal
government has been able to borrow large resources from the capital markets.
While almost all states are in principle prevented from borrowing to cover their ordinary budget, most of them routinely issue bonds to pay for capital improvements. This rule, commonly
known as “the golden rule,” has long been rationalized with the fact that capital improvements
benefit generations to come, who should be called to share the burden.1 Of course, such a rationale only holds in an economy that is far from Ricardian equivalence, for otherwise government
debt would have no effects on allocations and welfare (Barro [1]).
In this paper, we look at the evidence that state-level capital spending is driven by departures
from Ricardian equivalence stemming from mobility and population growth. We are certainly
not the first ones to study this question; indeed, one of our goals is to supplement Poterba [10]
by considering additional and more recent data. However, our main objective is to interpret
the magnitudes of the coefficients that we find through the lens of an explicit political-economy
model that has sharp quantitative predictions about magnitudes of departure from Ricardian
equivalence. This turns out to be important; while the model is rejected by the data, this
happens because the response of capital provision to population growth and mobility is too
strong compared to the limited deviations that the model would expect.
Our starting point is a simple environment where the population is spread across different states, and voters choose public spending year by year, taking into account the exogenous
prospects for mobility that they face and an exogenous path for the population growth in the
state they reside in.2 Voters discount future costs and benefits of their policy choices more heavily than efficiency would dictate: this occurs because they neglect costs and benefits that will
1
2

See e.g. Studensky [15].
By assuming that the evolution of population is exogenous, we abstract from the capitalization effects that

play a very important role in the literature on urban economics. A recent survey of this research is in Ross
and Yinger [12]. By looking at state-level data rather than local data, we expect capitalization to be much less
prevalent.

2

accrue to future residents of the state that are not yet present. This effect will be larger, the
faster a state’s population is growing or the more turnover among residents. In the absence of
any restriction on government indebtedness we would thus expect states to run large deficits.
However, as mentioned above, a version of the “golden rule” prevents voters from financing
non-capital expenses with debt. If strictly enforced, the golden rule fully restores incentives to
provide the correct amount of nondurable public goods: this is because both costs and benefits
accrue immediately, and no long-term consequences emerge. However, in the case of public capital, both benefits (of current investment) and costs (of current debt issuance) spill over into the
future. These costs and benefits could align if debt issuance were structured so that the debt
was paid off at the same time as the benefits accrued, but the two need not be aligned correctly.
In particular, whether costs or benefits will be shifted further into the future depends on many
parameters of the model, but especially on the duration of capital, the maturity of debt, and the
fraction of debt financing. The shorter the duration of capital, the longer the maturity of debt,
and the larger the fraction of debt financing, the more costs are shifted to the future relative to
benefits, to the point that voters might actually be induced to overspend.
The degree by which cost/benefit mismatches lead to inefficient spending depends on the
magnitude of departures from Ricardian equivalence. At one extreme, in a world of no mobility
and no population growth, the set of voters would be fixed and the distribution of costs and
benefits over time should be irrelevant. The model thus delivers quantitative predictions on how
mobility and population growth affect capital spending. It is these predictions that we take to
the data.
In our empirical exercise we document two main facts:
1. Capital spending by the states reacts to population growth much less than would be needed
to preserve a constant capital stock per capita. This implies that the capital stock per capita
declines with population growth.
2. For a given the population growth rate, capital spending is positively related to mobility,
i.e., it declines with the fraction of the population that remains in the state in any given
year.
3

We find that the magnitude of both effects is somewhat stronger than the model would be
able to predict, based on a plausible choice of parameters. Moreover, the two empirical facts
pose a greater challenge for the model when considered jointly. In the model, the inability of
public capital to keep up with population growth occurs when too little borrowing is allowed and
future benefits exceed future costs: when this is the case, higher population growth leads to more
severe underinvestment, rationalizing the weak response of investment to the capital needs of a
growing population. In contrast, a positive relationship between mobility and capital spending
is interpreted by the model as evidence of too much borrowing: when future costs exceed the
benefits, a more mobile population is more prone to overspending.
Section 2 presents the model through which we interpret the data. Section 3 provides further
intuition on the equilibrium relationship between government spending, population growth, and
mobility, and discusses ways in which this relationship can be informative about the parameters
of the model. Section 4 describes the data and provides a brief institutional overview. Our main
results are presented in section 5, while section 6 speculates on directions for future research.

2

Model

The model we adopt is based on Bassetto with Sargent [4]. However, we explicitly introduce here
the sources of variation across states and over time that will form the basis of our estimation
procedure. While highly stylized, the model we present provides an explicit account of the forces
that drive political decisions, and thus offers a transparent interpretation of the findings of our
empirical exercise.
We consider N states (jurisdictions), each populated by a continuum of households. Each
state n is characterized by the following random variables:
• nst , the population growth in state s at time t.
• θst , the probability that a household living in state s at t − 1 is alive and in the same
state at t. For simplicity, we adopt the Blanchard [5] assumption that the probability of
dying (and of moving) is independent of age; time variation in mobility will thus affect all
4

residents uniformly.3
• φst , a measure of the household preference for public goods in the state;
We assume that all residents of a state share the same mobility and the same preferences
for (state-level) public goods.4 By assuming that these random variables depend on the state,
rather than the household, we make our analysis tractable, but our results would be robust to
the extent that endogenous mobility across states is limited.5
Within period t, a household residing in state s has preferences given by
cit + φst

G1−σ
st
,
1−σ

(1)

where cit is consumption of a private good by household i (residing in state s) and Gst is the
per-capita level of a state-level public good.6
Households discount the future at a rate β θ̃, where θ̃ is the mortality rate (assumed constant
across states for simplicity). We assume that the probability that a household that moves from
one state to another will move back is negligible. Because of this, households discount future
benefits from the public goods and future taxes in the state in which they reside by βθs t+1 .
In each period, each person alive produces y units of output, which can be either consumed
as a private good7 or invested in the public good:
Gst =

1−δ
Gs t−1 + γst ,
1 + nst

(2)

where δ is the depreciation rate of the public good and γst is public spending per capita in period
t in state s. In our empirical specifications, we will consider several public goods, characterized
3

As shown in Bassetto and Lepetyuk [3] (e.g., figure 1), variation by age is not as important, except for the

old that are far from being pivotal.
4
Upon moving, each household thus inherits a new mobility and preference parameter, based on its new state
of residence.
5
For evidence of limited mobility across states, see Meyer[9] and Gelbach [7]. A model of policy determination
with endogenous mobility is developed in Bassetto [2].
6
We assume that public goods are subject to congestion externalities. Although this assumption does not
seem central to our results, we will study robustness in future versions.
7
The private good is nondurable. Private capital could be introduced with no effect on the results, if income
taxes are restricted to labor; see Bassetto with Sargent [4].

5

by different degrees of durability; in particular, we will constrast current expenditures (for which
we assume δ = 1) to capital expenditures. The analysis developed here immediately generalizes
to multiple public goods by assuming that each good enters additively in the utility function.8
In particular, our key equation (9) will hold for each good independently.
Each state has a government that is empowered to levy income taxes and produce public
goods.9 Taxes and spending are chosen by majority vote each period by the residents of the
state,10 subject to two borrowing restrictions. The first restriction limits to a value x the fraction
of public spending that can be financed with debt. The constitutions of most U.S. states prevent
borrowing, except to finance capital expenditures; this would correspond to x = 0 for current
(nondurable) expenses, and x = 1 for capital projects. We will both study the implications of
setting x to these values and make inference on x from the data. The second restriction limits
the duration of debt. In the model, this is represented by a parameter α, which represents
the minimal fraction of outstanding debt that must be bought back in any given period. This
parameter is a parsimonious representation of the limited duration of debt issued by U.S. states;
for some states, this limit is imposed by their constitution, while in other cases it might be
driven by other forces that are outside of the model, such as the lack of liquidity of maturities
longer than 30 years. The two borrowing restrictions give rise to the following constraints on
government behavior:
Bst = (1 + rt )

Bs t−1
+ Gst − Tst
1 + nst

(3)

α + rt
Bs t−1 ,
1 + nst

(4)

and
Tst ≥ (1 − x)Gst +

where Bst is government debt per capita, rt is the real interest rate, and Tst are tax revenues per
capita.
We assume that households can annuitize their wealth, so the equilibrium interest rate of the
economy is the constant rt = (1 − β)/β.
1−σ
PK
Gsjt j
The preferences over K public goods would thus be described by cit + j=1 φsjt 1−σ
.
j
9
Given that all residents of a state are identical and that location and income are exogenous, income taxes are

8

equivalent to fixed lump-sum payments.
10
Given our assumptions, all residents will share the same preferences, and the vote will be unanimous.

6

Details of the definition and characterization of an equilibrium are provided by Bassetto with
Sargent [4]. As in that paper, we focus on Markov equilibria, where the equilibrium provision
of public capital is independent of the past.11 In these equilibria, households believe that any
additional investment in public goods beyond the equilibrium level would only last for one period,
and would be undone by the voters next period. This is an equilibrium because next-period voters
will indeed choose to undo any past investment that exceeds the equilibrium level, if they expect
future voters to do the same.
To determine the equilibrium level of spending, we analyze the decision faced by voters in
period t. Given the nature of the equilibrium, an increase in the time-t provision of the public
good will be reversed in the subsequent period; such a policy change would thus have effects
on public good provision for only for one period, but its tax implications would stretch into the
future. On the cost side, equations (3) and (4) imply that an additional unit of Gst increases
time-t taxes in state s by 1 − x units. In period t + 1, the additional investment is undone by
reducing spending in the public good by (1 − δ)/(1 + ns t+1 ) units. Period-t + 1 taxes respond to
this investment reduction by 1 − x, and they are also affected by the additional debt issued in
period t. The combined effect is thus given by


x
(1 − x)(1 − δ)
1−β
+α −
.
1 + ns t+1
β
1 + ns t+1
An additional unit of spending in period t has no further effects on public spending beyond
period t + 1, but the consequences of debt linger, and taxes in period t + j vary by the following
amount:

j
Y



1
1−β
x
+ α [δ − α](1 − α)j−2 ,
1 + ns t+v
β
v=1

j > 1.

Whether taxes increase or decrease after period t + 1 depends on whether the public good
depreciates faster or slower than the rate at which government debt is paid back. When the
public good is not very durable and debt is paid back slowly, we have δ > α and taxes increase
in the long run.
11

Bassetto with Sargent does not include time variation in preferences and demographics. However, it is

straightforward to prove that, with quasilinear preferences, a Markov equilibrium of the same type exists even
when this time variation is introduced.

7

To a current resident of the state at time t, the expected present value of taxes per unit of
public investment is the discounted sum of all these present and future tax changes:

 


βθs t+1
1−β
Qst ≡Et 1 − x +
x
+ α − (1 − x)(1 − δ) +
1 + ns t+1
β



j
∞
Y
X
θs t+v
1−β
j
j−2
+ α (δ − α)
β (1 − α)
,
x
β
1 + ns t+v
v=1
j=2

(5)

where Et is the conditional expectation taken with respect to the statewide shocks.
In voting, a resident will equate the marginal utility of the additional public good provision in
period t with the expected present value of tax changes that will be triggered by this additional
provision:
φst G−σ
st = Qst =⇒ log Gst =

1
(log φst − log Qst )
σ

(6)

To simplify our expressions, we linearize log Qst around nst = 0 and θst = 1, and assume that
population growth and (one minus) the mobility rate follow AR(1) processes with autocorrelations ρn and ρθ and long-term means n̄ and θ̄. This yields the following expression:
β(1 − δ)
log Qst ≈ log(1 − β(1 − δ)) +
(1 + n̄ − θ̄ − ρθ (θst − θ̄) + ρn (nst − n̄))−
1 − β(1 − δ)


1 + n̄ − θ̄
ρn (nst − n̄)(1 − βρn (1 − δ))
ρθ (θst − θ̄)(1 − βρθ (1 − δ))
x
+
−
.
1 − β(1 − α) (1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρn (1 − α)) (1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρθ (1 − α))

(7)

To derive intuition, we consider four components of equation (7) in turn:
1. log(1 − β(1 − δ)). This is the only term that would apply if nst ≡ n̄ = 0 and θst ≡ θ̄ = 1.
With no population growth and no mobility ever, this is a standard representative-agent
economy where Ricardian equivalence holds. Consequently, neither the fraction of debt
financing x not debt maturity α have any effect on public good provision. Furthermore,
it is straightforward to verify that the representative agent votes for the efficient level of
Gst .12
2.

β(1−δ)
(1
1−β(1−δ)

+ n̄ − θ̄ − ρθ (θst − θ̄) + ρn (nst − n̄)). This piece is the only relevant addition

when borrowing is ruled out (x = 0). In this case, higher mobility and/or population
12

See Bassetto with Sargent [4] for the derivation of the efficient level.

8

growth between period t and period t + 1 implies a higher effective discount factor by the
voters, and an accordingly lower level of government investment (provided depreciation is
less than full, i.e., δ < 1). Future expected population growth is driven by the long-term
mean n̄ and, given the highly persistent process, by the past realization nt . The reasoning
for mobility is analogous, keeping in mind that mobility is represented by 1 − θs t+1 .
3.



1 + n̄ − θ̄
x
.
1 − β(1 − α)

(8)

This piece of the cost describes how debt financing changes the cost perceived by the voters
when population growth and mobility are constant over time. In this case, higher population growth (higher n̄) and/or higher mobility (lower θ̄) increase effective discounting, and
imply that the perceived cost of a public project is lower. Mobility and population growth
thus interact with debt financing to encourage government spending. For sufficiently high
values of x, this effect dominates the previous effect, and overspending can occur. This is
particularly likely if α is close to 0, i.e., when debt repayment occurs far into the future.
In practice, while population growth and mobility are not constant, they are very persistent.
It is straightforward to see that, as ρn → 1 and ρθ → 1, the entire effect of debt on the
perceived cost of funding the public good is captured by equation (8), where n̄ is replaced
by nst and θ̄ is replaced by θst . In this case, the intuition derived above for constant growth
and mobility still applies.
4. The remaining terms in equation (7) capture the way in which the speed of the repayment
schedule interacts with the demographic processes as nst and θst converge (in expectation)
back to their long-run steady states. Given the high level of persistence of these processes,
they are not quantitatively important in driving voters’ choices, except of course insofar as
they replace n̄ with nst and θ̄ with θst in equation (8).
Based on the intuition developed above, the model predicts that the stock of public capital
will be lower in states with more population growth and/or higher mobility if no borrowing is
allowed. When enough borrowing of sufficiently long maturity is allowed, this relation reverses,
9

and more population growth (mobility) is associated with higher capital. This is more likely to
happen for capital that depreciates faster.

0
−1
−2
−3
−4

1
1

0.98

0.8
0.6

0.96
0.4
0.94
Fraction of stayers θ

0.2
0

Fraction of debt financing x

Figure 1: Logarithm of public good provision with no pop. growth and constant mobility rate,
δ = 0.03.

To gain further insight, in figures 1 and 2 we plot the log of the stock of the public good as a
function of the fraction of households that stay within the state from one year to the next (“the
stayers”) and the degree to which debt financing is allowed.13 In both figures we set β = 0.96,
σ = 0.2, and α so that the half-life of debt is 15 years; we set population growth to 0 (to isolate
the effects of mobility), and we assume a constant mobility. Finally, we also normalize preferences
so that the efficient provision of the public good (in logs) is 0.
In figure 1 we set δ = 0.03, which may be appropriate for major infrastructure investment,
whereas figure 2 adopts δ = 0.06, in line with many estimates of the depreciation of private
capital. For each one of the figures, we set the preference shock φst so that 0 corresponds to the
efficient level.
Not surprisingly, figures 1 and 2 show that Ricardian equivalence holds if there is no mobility
13

The effects of population growth are analogous to those of mobility, so we do not plot them here.

10

0.5
0
−0.5
−1
−1.5
−2
−2.5
−3
1
1

0.98

0.8
0.6

0.96
0.4
0.94
Fraction of stayers θ

0.2
0

Fraction of debt financing x

Figure 2: Logarithm of public good provision with no pop. growth and constant mobility rate,
δ = 0.06.

(θ = 1), while spending departs more and more from the efficient level when the fraction of stayers
decreases. More interestingly, the sign of this departure depends on the circumstances. Under
a pure balanced budget (x = 0), we unambiguously obtain that public capital is underprovided.
However, under 100% debt financing, when capital is not very durable (δ = 0.06) costs are
shifted into the future to an extent that makes it worthwhile for voters to actually overprovide
public capital. In this case, increasing mobility (decreasing the fraction of stayers) increases
the provision of public capital. The main implication of the model is that, for high degrees of
debt financing, we should observe a positive relationship between the level of public capital and
mobility for capital goods subject to rapid depreciation, and a negative relationship for very
long-term projects.
In figure 3 we show that the basic intuition is unchanged when time-varying mobility and
population growth are introduced. This figure picks the same depreciation rate as figure 2
(δ = 0.06) and holds all parameters the same, except population growth is set at the longterm mean of the AR(1) process that we estimate from the data, and autocorrelations ρn and
11

1
0
−1
−2
−3
1
1

0.98

0.8
0.6

0.96
0.4
0.94
Fraction of stayers θst

0.2
0

Fraction of debt financing x

Figure 3: Logarithm of public good provision, δ = 0.06, with population growth and mean
reversion in the mobility rate.

ρθ are also set at their respective estimates. Because of positive population growth, Ricardian
equivalence no longer holds even when there is no mobility across states, but this effect is small.
The discussion above refers to the stock of public capital. In the data, we actually observe the
flows of public investment (and expenses in nondurable goods). In the model, this is captured
by the variable γst in equation (2). After appropriate substitutions, we obtain the following

12

expression:

1−δ
1
log γst ≈ log δ +
nst +
log φst − (1 − δ) log φs t−1 − δ log(1 − β(1 − δ))−
δ
δσ
βδ(1 − δ)
(1 + n̄ − θ̄ − ρθ (θst − θ̄) + ρn (nst − n̄))+
1 − β(1 − δ)


1 + n̄ − θ̄
ρn (nst − n̄)(1 − βρn (1 − δ))
ρθ (θst − θ̄)(1 − βρθ (1 − δ))
xδ
+
−
−
1 − β(1 − α) (1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρn (1 − α)) (1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρθ (1 − α))
β(1 − δ)2
(ρn (nst − ns t−1 ) − ρθ (θst − θs t−1 ))+
1 − β(1 − δ)


ρn (nst − ns t−1 )(1 − βρn (1 − δ)) ρθ (θst − θs t−1 )(1 − βρθ (1 − δ))
x(1 − δ)
−
.
(1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρn (1 − α))
(1 − β(1 − δ))(1 − βρθ (1 − α))
(9)
For high values of ρn and ρθ , public investment behaves very similarly to the stock of public
capital; in particular, the relationship between mobility and investment is very similar to that
between mobility and the stock of public capital. One important exception is the additional term
(1 − δ)nst /δ, which affects the relationship between investment and population growth. This
term captures the need to provide infrastructure for the additional population, and introduces
an additional reason why we should expect higher public investment in faster-growing states.14

3

Empirical Strategy and Identification

Equation (9) forms the basis of our empirical strategy. We will estimate the following regression:
log γst = a + b1 nst + b2 (nst − ns t−1 ) + b3 θst + b4 (θst − θs t−1 ) + st .

(10)

In practice, the high degree of persistence and the difficulty in matching the timing of political
choice and demographic movements imply that the estimates of b2 and b4 will be unreliable,
while estimates of b1 and b3 will be robust to slight mismatches in the timing of events. Because
of this, we will focus our discussion on estimates of b1 and b3 .
14

It is worth stressing that this result does not rely on our assumption about congestion. With no congestion

newcomers would not need any additional infrastructure, but the resulting increasing returns would make it
desirable to expand the stock of public capital per capita when population is higher.

13

Our identifying restriction is that the preference shock in (9) is uncorrelated with population
growth and mobility. In our preferred regression, we introduce several controls that are meant
to capture elements of the preference shock that may be correlated with demographics.
To assess the success and the shortcomings of the model in explaining the data, we proceed in
two steps. First, we completely parameterize the model imposing plausible values into equation
(9), and we study the dimensions in which the results diverge from the data. These parameter
values are summarized in table 1. Second, we give the model one degree of freedom and use
estimates of b1 and b3 to infer the amount of debt financing allowed at the margin (x), while
holding all other parameters at their calibrated values. This gives us an alternative measure of
the aspects of the data that the model is able to capture, and those that it misses.
Parameter
β
δ
α
ρn
ρθ
σ
x

Assigned Value Comment
0.96
0.06
1 − 2−1/15
Half-life of debt: 15 years
0.897
Estimate from data
0.973
Estimate from data (annualized)
0.2
Lower range of estimates surveyed by DelRossi and Inman [6]
1
100% debt financing allowed for capital projects
Table 1: Baseline calibration

To gain further intuition, consider what would happen if public investment were always at
its efficient level in all states. In this case, the model would deliver b3 = 0 and b1 = (1 − δ)/δ:
mobility should have no effect, while public investment should react positively to population
growth by an amount that matches exactly what is needed to keep the same stock of capital per
resident.
When b3 is different from zero, we can infer from its sign whether mobility is a force that
generates underprovision or overprovision of public capital in the model. Specifically, if b3 > 0,
more mobility (a lower θst ) lowers public investment. In this case, mobility is a force that leans
to underprovision. The opposite intuition applies when b3 < 0.
In the case of b1 , we can infer whether population growth is a force that leads to under– or
overprovision by looking at the sign of b1 − (1 − δ)/δ. When b1 < (>)(1 − δ)/δ, higher population
14

growth is not matched (more than matched) by adequate public investment, so population growth
is a force leading to underprovision (overprovision).
20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
Fraction of debt financing x

0.8

0.9

1

Figure 4: Coefficient b1 as a function of x, for four values of σ: 1/60,1/5,1,5 (flatter lines represent
higher σ).

Figures 4 and 5 adopt our baseline calibration and show how the coefficients b1 and b3 are
affected by x, for various values of σ. Within each graph, the four lines correspond to different
price elasticities of the demand for public goods: the higher is the elasticity (lower σ), the more
responsive are the coefficients to changes in x. In both graphs, there is a value of x that delivers
the neutral value ((1 − δ)/δ for b1 and 0 for b3 ), independently of σ. For values below this critical
threshold, borrowing is not sufficient to restore proper incentives, and underprovision ensues; we
then obtain b1 < (1 − δ)/δ and b3 > 0. Above the threshold, enough costs are shifted into the
future that more mobility (population growth) makes voters choose higher capital spending.
Using equation (9), simple algebra shows that the value of x such that b1 = 0 and that
which delivers b3 = (1 − δ)/δ will be different, unless ρn = ρθ . This can be seen in the pictures,
where the critical threshold is above 80% for population growth and below for mobility. In the

15

7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
−1
−2
−3
0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
Fraction of debt financing x

0.8

0.9

1

Figure 5: Coefficient b3 as a function of x, for four values of σ: 1/60,1/5,1,2 (flatter lines represent
higher σ).

range between the two critical thresholds, we cannot establish whether public capital is under–
or overprovided: greater population growth leads towards underprovision, but greater mobility
goes in the opposite direction. In practice, given the high autocorrelation of both processes, the
critical thresholds are very close to each other, and it is implausible for x to fall in this narrow
range.

4

Data and Institutional Features of the States

The assumptions in the model correspond to many of the basic features of state government
finance in the United States. Nearly all states operate under the strictures of balanced budget
requirements. These require that at some point in the budgeting process, current expenditures
are expected to be paid for out of current revenues. States differ in when in the budget process
balance must be obtained. As a result, these can differ in how binding they are in practice.
For example, the Illinois constitution states, “The Governor shall prepare and submit to the
16

General Assembly... a State budget for the ensuing fiscal year....Proposed expenditures shall not
exceed funds estimated to be available for the fiscal year as shown in the budget.” In Illinois, the
legislature is also required to pass a balanced budget. However, if circumstances change within
the fiscal year, the state can borrow to cover unexpected deficits.
Borrowing for capital expenditures lays outside these balanced budget requirements and separate provisions cover state ability to issue debt for capital projects. In Illinois, for example,
the state can issue debt provided that it is for a specific purpose and is approved by 3/5 of the
legislature or by a majority of voters in a referendum. Nearly all states also have capital budgets
that specifically detail how capital projects are to be financed.
For most municipal bonds, the state issues debt of a certain duration, gets the money up front,
spends the money within 2-5 years of issuance, pays interest over time (usually semi-annually)
and then pays the entire principal back when the bond matures. Most municipal bonds are
callable and most states allow bonds to be called and refunded provided that the duration is
not extended. Municipal bonds tend to be of fairly long duration. In October 2009, the average
maturity of municipal bonds was 16.9 years, while the average maturity of corporate bonds was
13.5 years.15 Also in contrast to corporate bonds, one municipal bonds issuance often contains
several maturities (these are called serial maturities). In addition, there are often sinking funds
associated with non-serial bonds where the issuer makes several payments into a sinking fund so
that the entire principal does not need to be funded at one point.
In order to estimate our model, our first need is to measure γst for current and capital spending. For this purpose, we use data from the Annual Survey of State Government Finances.
This data has been collected for all states by the Census Bureau since 1915 with the omission
of some years in the 20s and 30s. Since 1952, the survey has followed a fairly consistent format. The data are available in electronic format for (Fiscal Years) 1972 and from 1977-2007
and contain detailed information on government expenditures, revenues, and debt. These state
government finances data are extremely detailed and data are reported for over 400 categories for
each state. For example, expenditures are divided into 64 different government functions, such
15

See [13, 14].

17

as Air Transportation, Corrections, and Elementary and Secondary Education. For each function, expenditure data is available for numerous different purposes such as capital expenditures,
current expenditures and intergovernmental expenditure.
In this paper we are concerned with patterns of current and capital expenditures. According
to the survey’s classification manual, current expenditures include expenditures for employee
compensation, supplies and materials. By contrast, capital outlay includes “expenditure for the
purchase or construction, by contract or government employee, construction of buildings and
other improvements; for purchase of land, equipment, and existing structures; and for payments
on capital leases.16 ” In the data, capital outlay is further divided into construction, purchase of
land and existing structures, and purchase of equipment.
We supplement this with data on state population growth and state mobility. State population data is available annually from the Census Bureau. It is straightforward to calculate
population growth rates, nst and annual changes in these population growth rates, nst − ns t−1
from this data. The measure of mobility delineated in the theory is the probability that a household living in state s at t is alive and in the same state at t + 1. As mentioned earlier, we
extrapolate away from the death by assuming a constant hazard of death. Data on state migration flows are available in the Decennial Census. In the Census individuals are asked whether
they changed residences in the past five years and if so where they lived five years prior. We
define a state’s mobility as the number of people who lived in the state five years ago who live
in a different state in the Census year, divided by the number of people from the state five years
prior who still live in the US. We linearly interpolate between Census Years and use regression
analysis to predict migration flows since the last decennial Census.17 Because these are five-year
migration flows and we are interested in annual migration, we divide the resulting rates by five.
The percent of the population living in the same state is then one minus the percent of the
population who had moved. We label these individuals “stayers”.
16
17

See [16], chapter 5.
For extrapolation only, state migration rates are predicted based on state dummies, state specific time trends,

state population, median income, state poverty rates, percent over 65, percent under 25, percent urban, homeownership rate, percent with a high-school diploma, and percent with a bachelor’s degree.

18

We can only consistently estimate b1 , b2 , b3 , and b4 if the preference shock captured in st
is orthogonal to population growth and immobility. As a result, we include in the regression
features of states that we believe are correlated with spending and are also correlated with
either mobility or population growth. In particular we are concerned with proxying for state
resident preferences for fiscal variables that may also be related to population growth or mobility.
We choose several population attributes – average personal income, median household income,
percent of the population with a high-school diploma, percent urban, population density, percent
over 65, percent under 25, home ownership rate, population liberalism, and resident taste for
mobility. Most of these variables are available annually or by decade from the Census Bureau.
We interpolate between Census years for data that is available less frequently. Two measures
merit further discussion – population liberalism and resident taste for mobility. For population
liberalism, we use factor analysis; specifically, we take the first factor from five state political
variables – the percent of the popular vote for the Democratic Presidential candidate in the
previous election, the percent of the state’s Senate delegation that belongs to the Democratic
Party, the percent of the state’s House delegation that belongs to the Democratic party, the
average Americans for Democratic Action (ADA; a liberal political organization) score for the
state’s Senate delegation, and the average ADA score for the state’s House delegation. The
resident taste for mobility is measured as the number of people that moved to a new house in
state in the five years leading up to the Census divided by the number of people that stayed in
state. We add this proxy for preferences for mobility because we believe that many unobsevable
attributes of populations that would influence interstate mobility would influence within-state
mobility in a similar manner.
Variable means for these variables are presented in Table 2 for the 48 contiguous United
States. Alaska and Hawaii are omitted from the analysis.18 We can see from this table that
states vary substantially in per capita fiscal variables. We also note that state current spending
is about 8 times the level of state capital spending on average. Most capital spending is for
construction while smaller amounts are dedicated to land and equipment expenditure.
18

The inclusion of Alaska would alter the means and results due to unusual capital spending patterns in the

state.

19

Variable

Obs

Mean

Std. Dev.

Per Capita Capital Spending (2007 $)
Per Capita Spending on Land and Existing Structures (2007 $)
Per Capita Spending on Equipment (2007 $)
Per Capita Construction Spending (2007 $)
Per Capita Current Spending (2007 $)
Stayers (Fraction of Residents Remaining in State, 1-year horizon)
Fraction of Stayers Changing House within State (5-year horizon)
State Personal Income Per Capita (000 of 2007 $)
Median Household Income (000 of 2007 $)
Fraction with a High School Degree
Fraction Urban
Population Density
Fraction Over 65
Fraction Under 25
Democratic Leanings of State
Homeownership Rate

1440 314.107
1440
16.548
1440
42.619
1440 254.941
1440 2443.777
1440
0.979
1440
0.380
1440
28.274
1440
43.762
1440
0.782
1440
0.695
1440
0.148
1440
0.124
1440
0.373
1440 -0.00833
1440
0.680

128.570
16.211
19.971
115.580
686.4024
0.00609
0.0406
6.596
7.615
0.0904
0.147
0.189
0.0181
0.0358
0.943
0.0507

Table 2: Sample Moments

5

Results

In Table 3, we present regressions predicting the natural log of per capita fiscal variables based
on population growth, mobility, their first differences, and the preference parameters.19 We also
include year dummies to capture nationwide trends in spending. We cluster the standard errors
by state. We are particularly concerned with predictions of capital spending (in column 1) and
current expenditures (in column 5). Following the variable labels, we note those variables that
directly map into variables in our equations. In addition to capital and current spending we
estimate the determinants of subcategories of capital spending.
In the regression on capital spending, we note that states with more permanent resident
populations (more stayers), have significantly lower capital expenditures. A one standard deviation increase in the fraction of stayers (.006) decreases log per capita capital expenditure by
19

In the case of purchases of land and existing structures we lose two state-year observations due to zeros.

20

VARIABLES

Pop. growth (nt )
Pop. growth
change (nt − nt−1 )
Fraction of
stayers (θt )
Change in frac.
stayers (θt − θt−1 )
Internal
migration
Average pers.
income
Median
income
Frac HS
diploma
Frac urban
Pop. dens.
Fraction
over 65
Fraction
under 25
Liberal
index
Fraction
homeowners
Constant
Year dummies
Obs.
R-sq.

(1)
Total Capital
Spending

(3)
Equipment

(4)
Construction
Expenditures

(5)
Current

3.412
(2.287)
-3.634**
(1.409)
-33.49***
(5.172)
-10.44
(25.42)
-1.606
(1.188)
0.0283***
(0.00858)
-0.0139**
(0.00631)
-0.217
(0.622)
-0.435
(0.327)
0.316
(0.200)
0.288
(1.985)
3.588**
(1.453)
0.0218
(0.0307)
0.265
(0.722)
37.30***
(5.117)
yes

(2)
Land and
Purchases
of Existing
Structures
18.25***
(6.625)
-15.53**
(5.924)
21.76*
(12.89)
-16.93
(62.46)
2.748
(2.975)
0.00457
(0.0311)
-0.0146
(0.0190)
1.409
(1.689)
-0.619
(0.809)
1.892***
(0.685)
-0.0529
(5.583)
0.554
(3.638)
-0.125
(0.0779)
0.962
(1.653)
-21.21
(13.20)
yes

6.120**
(2.730)
-3.792*
(2.145)
-17.77***
(4.732)
9.982
(37.14)
-2.379
(1.831)
0.0314*
(0.0165)
-0.00800
(0.0104)
0.103
(0.665)
-0.638
(0.390)
0.0327
(0.303)
1.390
(2.073)
6.455***
(1.708)
0.00982
(0.0355)
0.272
(1.044)
18.22***
(4.208)
yes

1.250
(2.603)
-2.530
(1.550)
-38.88***
(5.652)
-15.95
(24.72)
-1.450
(1.095)
0.0283***
(0.00838)
-0.0142**
(0.00665)
-0.370
(0.708)
-0.406
(0.332)
0.316
(0.202)
-0.0803
(2.271)
3.355**
(1.587)
0.0298
(0.0329)
0.246
(0.686)
42.59***
(5.733)
yes

0.285
(1.635)
-0.251
(1.110)
-7.007**
(3.245)
4.967
(17.21)
-2.757***
(0.725)
-0.00157
(0.00831)
-0.00153
(0.00340)
0.986***
(0.342)
-0.413*
(0.234)
0.253
(0.204)
2.843**
(1.340)
-0.0248
(0.930)
0.0628***
(0.0143)
-0.464
(0.462)
15.96***
(3.265)
yes

1440
0.575

1438
0.119

1440
0.472

1440
0.549

1440
0.740

Table 3: Regression results. Each column corresponds to a different dependent variable. All
dependent variables are in logs of their per capita value. Robust standard errors in parentheses.
*** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
21

Figure 6:

-0.2, or about half a standard deviation. In figure 6, we display the relationship between per
capita capital spending and stayers for 1985. Even with no controls, a clear negative pattern
emerges, which is robust to excluding outliers such as Wyoming. As shown in table 3, column 2,
this relation reverses in the case of purchases of land and existing structures, arguably the most
durable component of spending.
The relationship between spending and population growth is far weaker; it is always positive, but not statistically significant for overall capital spending and for the large category of
construction.20 Figure 7 shows the 1985 snapshot with no controls: unlike the case of movers,
20

In Poterba [10], the relationship is negative. However, both in our paper and his, these coefficients are mostly

not significantly away from zero, so a different sign is not indicative of a large discrepancy. In future versions, we
plan to study in more details the differences between our results and Poterba’s. Three main differences stand out
in our methodology: first, our analysis considers a long range of years, while he looks at a single year; second, we
include highway spending, which is heavily affected by federal transfers and might thus behave differently; and

22

no clear pattern emerges, except for the outlier Wyoming, whose population contracted in that
year.

Figure 7:

Most of the variables measuring preference shocks are statistically insignificant in the capital
spending regression. There are two exceptions – the income variables and the percent of the
population under 25. For the income variables, the positive personal income effect dominates
the median income effect and we find that states with richer populations spend more on capital
goods. We also find that states with younger populations spend more on capital projects. This
may be explained by the large role of states in the purchase and construction of school buildings.
In column 5 we look at the determinants of current spending. Here we also find that having
a more stable population decreases expenditures. However, the magnitude of the effect is much
smaller. Here a one standard deviation increase in stayers (.006) decreases log current per
third, we regress logs of spending per capita rather than levels, to be consistent with our model.

23

capita expenditure by -0.04, or about one seventh of a standard deviation. Our model could be
consistent with this relationship if all the benefits of current spending occur in the current period,
while some of it is financed by debt. On the other hand, this relationship may be an indication
that we have not adequately captured some attributes of state population that both decrease
mobility and tastes for current expenditures. A number of other population attributes also
have statistically significant effects on current per capita expenditure. States with high internal
mobility also have lower current spending. This may be because individuals who move within the
state may be less tied into government services. We also find that states with a high proportion
of individuals with a high-school diploma have higher current expenditures. In addition we find
states with a higher percent urban have lower levels of current expenditure. This may be due
to the role of municipalities in the provision of public services in urban areas. This conjecture
is supported by the fact that this relationship goes away if we look at the determinants of state
and local spending combined. We also find that more liberal states have higher levels of current
expenditures.
To see how the results in table 3 square with the model, table 4 compares the coefficients
of interest to those predicted by the model. For general capital, we use the baseline calibration
of table 1; for its subcategories, we use different values of δ: δ = 0.02 for puchases of land and
existing structures, δ = 0.12 for equipment, and δ = 0.03 for construction. In the case of current
expenses, we set δ = 1 (full depreciation), and x = 0 (no borrowing allowed).
Consider first the case of total capital expenditures (column 1). At first glance, it may seem
surprising that both the model and the data point to a negative relationship between these
expenditures and the fraction of stayers. However, as we noted in section 3, this result emerges
when capital is financed mostly through long-term borrowing. As is noted in Inman [8] and
Poterba [10], states with high mobility can use debt issuance to transfer the funding of capital
projects to future residents and therefore may demand more spending. While current residents
get some of the benefits of the capital spending now, future residents pay. We also previously
established that a negative relationship between stayers and spending is less likely for capital
expenses that are very long-lasting. This can be viewed in the other columns. Our calibrated

24

VARIABLES

(1)
Total Capital
Spending

(2)
Land and
Purchases
of Existing
Structures

Coefficient on the fraction of stayers:
Regression (data)
-33.49***
21.76*
(5.172)
(12.89)
Calibration (model)
-13.44
18.64
Coefficient on population growth:
Regression (data)
3.412
18.25***
(2.287)
(6.625)
Calibration (model)
23.44
44.27
Needed to keep
15.67
49
per-capita level

(3)
Equipment

(4)
Construction
Expenditures

(5)
Current

-17.77***
(4.732)
-31.80

-38.88***
(5.652)
7.26

-7.007**
(3.245)
0

6.120**
(2.730)
22.27
7.33

1.250
(2.603)
32.04
32.33

0.285
(1.635)
0
0

Table 4: Comparison of coefficients of interest in the regression with their predicted values
according to the calibrated model.
model predicts an even stronger negative relationship between investment and stayers in the case
of equipment, while it predicts a strong positive relationship with land and a very weak one in
the case of construction. Qualitatively, the data fit with the model, with the important exception
of construction, where the model and the data are completely at odds. However, quantitatively
large discrepancies emerge. In particular, for the case of total capital expenditures, the data
suggest a much stronger response to the fraction of stayers compared to the one that the model
can justify. We could get a somewhat better fit by increasing the price elasticity of the demand
for public goods, but by choosing σ = 0.2 (a value at the low end of the spectrum of estimates)
we already gave the model some leeway in this dimension.
Table 4 shows even bigger discrepancies between the calibrated model and the data in the
case of population growth. For all categories of investment, the regression coefficients are below
what would be needed to maintain a constant per-capita provision of capital; in most cases, the
regression coefficients are far below this level. In contrast, the model would predict values even
higher than the replacement value for total capital: since 100% debt financing is associated with
overinvestment in the model, higher population growth induces bigger departures from Ricardian

25

equivalence and thus bigger overspending. Even for the categories in which underspending is
predicted, the model would expect coefficients close to those needed to keep a constant percapita profile. Our regression suggests one of three possible explanations:
1. States have been unable to keep up capital provision for a growing population in the last
30 years;
2. Congestion is much more limited than we assume, so there is less need for additional capital
for the growing population; furthermore, states do not exploit these increasing returns to
increase the per-capita provision as we would expect from Samuelson’s rule;
3. Population growth and preferences for capital spending are correlated; specifically, the
population of fast-growing states tends to have preferences skewed for small government.21
However, no evidence of this small-government bias appears for current expenses, for which
we obtain the predicted coefficient of 0.
The previous analysis imposed extremely tight constraints on the ability of the model to fit
the data, since no parameter was allowed to vary based on our empirical findings. We next
give the model one degree of freedom by inferring values of x from our regression results, while
keeping all other parameters fixed. Specifically, we look for the values of x that can match the
regression coefficients to those implied by the model. We do so independently for the coefficients
on population growth and the fraction of stayers. In order to identify x, we need measures of ρn
and ρθ . For population growth, our estimate from the data yields:
nst = 0.000961 +
(0.00017)

0.897

ns t−1 +error term

(0.0111)

For mobility, we rely on data from the decennial census, which asks respondents to report their
state of residence 5 years prior. We estimate the 10-year persistence in the fraction of 5-year
21

In the case of counties, Rappaport [11] argues that there is evidence that movers tend to favor smaller-

government areas, leading to growth in those areas.

26

stayers. This yields:
5(1 − θst ) =

0.0206
(0.0043)

+

0.760

5(1 − θs t−10 ) +error term

(0.0356)

The implied 1-year autocorrelation ρθ is 0.973.
Table 5 presents the values of x that reconcile the regression coefficients with the model,
along with the standard deviation computed using the delta method.22
(1)
Total Capital

x needed to
1.337
(0.0982)
x needed to
0.593
(0.0468)

(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Land and Equipment Construction
Current
Spending
Purchases
Expenditures
of Existing
Structures
match coefficient on the fraction of stayers:
0.949
0.762
1.766
0.121
(0.226)
(0.108)
(0.11)
(0.0605)
match coefficient on population growth:
0.609
0.590
0.49
0.011
(0.221)
(0.192)
(0.16)
(0.0663)

Table 5: Indirect estimates of the fraction of debt financing.
If we look at the inferred values for x needed to match each coefficient in isolation, it would
seem that the model could be reconciled with the data with just some slight stretches (except
for construction, where implied values of x are far from the reasonable range). In the case
of population growth, all of the implied values for x are well below 1: as we already know,
the regression coefficients on population growth would suggest underprovision of public capital,
which in the model only occurs if debt financing is markedly lower than 100%. In the case of
mobility, the regression coefficients imply overprovision of the public good, which the model can
reconcile if x takes a much higher value, even above 1 in some cases.
The main challenge arising from table 5 is that it is impossible to reconcile the regression
coefficients on population growth and mobility at the same time. The model implies a very tight
22

In computing the standard deviation, we take into account the uncertainty about the autocorrelation param-

eters. We assume independence of the errors across regression equations.

27

connection between the effects of population growth and the fraction of stayers on the provision
of the public good, and this connection is clearly rejected by the data. The fit of the model
might be improved if with some more freedom of moving other parameters, but this would be
unlikely to address the main difficulty: that the regression coefficients on population growth and
the fraction of stayers have opposite implications within the context of the model.23
Table 5 also contains estimates for the degree of debt financing of current expenses. These
estimates show that our results for current expenses are consistent with the ability by states
to borrow for a small fraction of these expenses. This is in line with the informal evidence
that states have a little room for “creative accounting” before the restrictions of the balancedbudget requirement kick in. Although we reject the hypothesis that the implied values of x from
population growth and mobility are the same (the P-value is about 4.5%), column (5) is much
closer to the theoretical results than the others.

6

Conclusion

In this preliminary draft, we have studied the relationship between population growth, mobility,
and capital and current spending at the state level in the United States. To interpret our
empirical results, we considered a full-fledged political-economy model, where the provision of
public goods is endogenously derived from the underlying demographic primitives.
When interpreted by the model, our regression coefficients behave schizophrenically: the
effect of population growth points to the range of underprovision of public capital, whereas the
response to increased mobility points to the opposite range of overprovision.
A maintained assumption in our analysis is that preferences for public goods are not systematically related to mobility and population growth at the state level, except through the variables
23

If we let σ vary as well as x, it would be possible to reconcile the coefficients b1 and b3 in the regression

with the model, by picking values of x in the narrow range in which population growth and mobility work in
opposite directions and blowing up the magnitude of the effect through a very low estimate of σ. However, this
would require values of the price elasticity of the demand for public goods that are much higher than anything
reasonable.

28

for which we directly controlled. A first step in reconciling data and theory is to look further
into the determinants of mobility and population growth.

References
[1] Robert J. Barro. Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?

Journal of Political Economy,

82:1095–1117, 1974.
[2] Marco Bassetto. Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments.
Working Paper 21, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 2008.
[3] Marco Bassetto and Vadym Lepetyuk. Government Investment and the European Stability
and Growth Pact. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives, 31(3):33–43,
2007.
[4] Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent. Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and
Ordinary Government Budgets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4):1167–1210, 2006.
[5] Olivier J. Blanchard. Debt, Deficits and Finite Horizons. Journal of Political Economy,
93(2):223–247, 1985.
[6] Alison F. DelRossi and Robert P. Inman. Changing the Price of Pork: the Impact of Local
Cost Sharing on Legislators’ Demands for Distributive Public Goods. Journal of Public
Economics, 71(2):247–273, 1999.
[7] Jonah B. Gelbach. Migration, the Life Cycle, and State Benefits: How Low Is the Bottom?
Journal of Political Economy, 112(5):1091–1130, 2004.
[8] Robert P. Inman. Public Employee Pensions and the Local Labor Budget. Journal of Public
Economics, 19(1):49–71, 1982.
[9] Bruce D. Meyer. Do the Poor Move to Receive Higher Welfare Benefits? Working Paper 58,
Joint Center for Poverty Research, 2000. Northwestern University/ University of Chicago.
29

[10] James M. Poterba. Capital Budgets, Borrowing Rules, and State Capital Spending. Journal
of Public Economics, 56(2):165–187, 1995.
[11] Jordan Rappaport. Local Growth Empirics. Working Paper 23, CID Harvard University,
1999.
[12] Stephen Ross and John Yinger. Sorting and Voting: A Review of the Literature on Urban
Public Finance. In Paul Cheshire and Edwin S. Mills, editors, Handbook of Regional and
Urban Economics. Volume 3, chapter 47, pages 2001–2060. Elsevier Science, North Holland,
1999.
[13] Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (SIFMA). US Corporate Bond Average Maturity. www.sifma.org, available under Research – Statistical tables.
[14] Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (SIFMA). US Municipal Average
Maturity. www.sifma.org, available under Research – Statistical tables.
[15] Paul Studensky. Public Borrowing. National Municipal League, 1930.
[16] U.S. Census Bureau.
ual,

2006.

Government Finance and Employment Classification Man-

Available at http://www.census.gov/govs/www/06classificationmanual/

06 gfe classmanual toc.html.

30

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan
Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-18

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment
Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

WP-09-08

Pay for Percentile
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-09-09

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot
François R. Velde

WP-09-10

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation
Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

WP-09-11

The Case of the Undying Debt
François R. Velde

WP-09-12

Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship
Program for Low-income Adults
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock
Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-09-13

WP-09-14

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:
Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-09-15

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,
Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-09-16

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-09-17

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-09-18

Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances?
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-19

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-09-20

Monetary Policy and Uncertainty in an Empirical Small Open Economy Model
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-21

Firm boundaries and buyer-supplier match in market transaction:
IT system procurement of U.S. credit unions
Yukako Ono and Junichi Suzuki
Health and the Savings of Insured Versus Uninsured, Working-Age Households in the U.S.
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Jonathan Hartley

WP-09-22

WP-09-23

The Economics of “Radiator Springs:” Industry Dynamics, Sunk Costs, and
Spatial Demand Shifts
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Thomas N. Hubbard

WP-09-24

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth, and
Capital Spending in the United States
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

WP-09-25

7