View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

REGIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES
Working Paper Series

Regional Growth and Development Theory:
Summary and Evaluation
Geoffrey J. D. Hewings

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO



WP- 1990-5

Regional Growth and Development Theory:
Summary and Evaluation
Geoffrey J.D. Hewings*
A bstract
Regional growth and development theory has undergone several periods of
intense introspection and re-evaluation. After four decades of work in this
area, there remains little consensus as to a generally accepted theory. In this
paper, a review of the approaches will be provided, beginning with the
neoclassical ideas and moving to the set of debates that appear to be of
importance at the present time. These focus on the role of linkages and
alternative forms of production space. Some new ideas are presented about
the role of change in structure and the important role played in innovation
diffusion and adoption.

’•‘Department o f Geography and Regional Science Program and Director, Regional Economics
Applications Laboratory, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




1

I. Introduction
Assume that an analyst was faced with the following problem. A nation was
divided into n distinct, mutually exclusive and exhaustive regions; data were
available for the major aggregates associated with macroeconomic accounting
at the national level but, at least initially, the analyst was not provided with
information at the regional levels. Drawing on received theory, what could
the analyst say about the expected patterns of growth and development at the
regional level? Essentially, one is asking the analyst a set of questions:
• how do regions grow?
• why do some grow more quickly than others while others decline?
• will regional growth and eventually measures of regional welfare all
converge on the national values or diverge?
While these are eminently reasonable questions, a review of the available
literature would suggest that there is little consensus on the process of change
and the expected outcomes and that the empirical evidence is often
inconclusive or just unavailable.
In the final analysis, the major question of concern revolves around the
expectation that levels of welfare among the region, no matter how measured,
will either converge on or diverge from the national average. Of course, more
recent work in dynamic theory suggests that the patterns themselves (whether
of divergence or convergence) may have some cyclical component; these
findings cast suspicion on the acceptability of any equilibrium criterion.
However, it should also be stated that many of the recent theoretical
contributions have yet to be subjected to extensive empirical validation.
One feature that is quite prominent throughout the regional growth and
development literature is the heavy intellectual debt owed to macroeconomic
growth and development theory, international trade theory and behavioral
relationships among macro and micro variables. A distinctive, quintessential
regional theory has yet to emerge although reliance on mainstream economics
appears to be weakening over time.
In the next section, the tour through the literature will begin with the
neoclassical approaches; thereafter, some of the more recent perspectives will
be reviewed. The roles of linkages and interaction and the problem of

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




2

causation will provide the focus for the next section. The question of space
will be addressed very briefly before some concluding comments are
provided.
n . N e o c la s s ic a l T h eory 1
The problems stated in the first section present an attractive challenge to the
analyst stepped in the neoclassical paradigm. However, as Isard (1956)
pointed out so eloquently, the "Anglo-Saxon bias" characterizing the
foundations of modem economic theory precluded any direct and easy
translation to a real world in which space had dimension and distance
represented a real obstacle to overcome. Furthermore, this bias reflected itself
in the lack of awareness of some of the important work being undertaken in
languages other than English by scholars such as Palender, Predohl, Weber,
Von Thunen. In the beginnings of regional theory, most closely associated
with the work of Olsen (1971), Borts and Stein (1964) and later with Siebert
(1969), real space was transformed into the physical complement of homo
economicus. It was rational (i.e., uniform), with no barriers to entry;
transportation costs were assumed to be either negligible or a simple function
of distance. Factors were able to move between parts of the space, i.e.,
between regions, freely and without incurring transaction costs. In
equilibrium, factor equality would be achieved across space with all factors
paid their marginal products.
The neoclassicists begin with a standard production function:
Yr = f T [K,L,t]
where Y is gross regional product in region r, and K and L are levels of labor
and capital respectively. The final argument is technical progress, an
amalgam of effects that combine to improve the efficiency of the stock of
resources within the region. Growth in the system is assumed to be fullcapacity growth; the interest rate serves as the mechanism to equate
investment and savings. Within the national system, regions can grow at
different rates (in terms of population and rates of progress). Adjustments
take place in the capital/output ratio. Although there is a global equilibrium in
the savings/investments relations, there is no restriction that this should occur
at the regional level. For example, the higher the region's growth rate, the
more likely it will be to import capital. Since capital and labor are assumed to
be perfectly mobile, and that each region produces homogeneous outputs, one

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




3




would expect that capital will flow from high to low wage regions and labor
will flow in the opposite direction until factor returns are equal. Hence, the
long run effect will be for low wage regions to grow faster; the influx of new
capital will raise wages but begin to decrease the marginal product of capital
that was initially higher than in the high wage regions. Eventually,
convergence will take place.
Criticism of the neo-classical model can be provided from any number of
perspectives; perhaps, though, the assumption of perfect mobility of factors
(and the implicit assumption of omniscience on the part of those factors-e.,
they have perfect information) creates the most difficulty. Notion of inertia,
lumpiness of capital, the interindustrial and interregional linkages that
characterize modem production systems all serve to dampen the transfer of
the theory to reality.
The Harrod-Domar model, on the other hand, would predict that with initial
differences in regional growth rates, divergence in levels of welfare between
regions will occur. The model examines rates of growth in output and capital;
the rate of growth for population (and hence, labor) is assumed to be constant.
Trade among regions is considered explicitly with the result that steady
growth in a single region would alter the interregional flows of labor and
capital elsewhere in the system. In this model, a steady-state path of growth
would be unlikely; regions with higher propensities to save and lower capitaloutput ratios will grow faster. Their growth rates will, in turn, attract
inmigration and further the growth processes, further enhancing the separation
in levels of welfare between regions.
In the context of the known real world, such theories are easy targets for
criticism (see for example, Clark et al. 1987); however, as a theory, it does
provide important insights into the potential functioning of markets in a world
in which physical distance is an important concern. However, the nature of
this distance impact-i.e., its embodied characteristics-precludes a simple
translation of space into a transport surface in which costs are purely a
function of length of travel. The costs of overcoming space involve time as
well as real monetary outlays; they are further tempered by the nature and
volume of the good being transported (including the possibility that the good
might be individuals), the direction travelled, the final distance, and so forth.
Other authors, such as Thirlwall (1974), have argued that regions should be
treated no differently than nations. With the exception of some functions
(such as the ability to issue currency), they behave very much the same way as
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5

4

nations. Accordingly, Thirlwall argues, many regional problems are really
balanceofpayments problems. Ifwe believethatregionsbehave ina similar
fashion to nations, then we might find Thirlwall's arguments persuasive.
Essentially, he argues that in line with national development problems, the
problems ofregional adjustment stem from an inabilitytohandle balance of
payments crises. With no ability to regulate exchange rates through
devaluation/revaluation, what options are open to regional governments? In
the US-modest taxation policy; industrial incentives (to lower costs of
production and thus provide an analogous response to devaluation at the
national level), exportpromotion plans, industrial targeting (usually focused
on import substitution). However, it is not clear whether initiatives
undertakenby thestateshavecreatedsignificantimpactsincomparison tothe
effects generated by the differential, spatial expenditures by the federal
government. In particular, the role of defense spending in the 1980s has
significantly altered the economic structure and nature of the growth
processesinmany states.

More Recent Perspectives
The neoclassical theoriesand thepolicyprescriptionsderived therefrom have
been subjecttoabarrageofcriticism. This "assault"mightbe summarizedas
coming from structuralist/Marxistperspectives, regional adjustment theorists
and, most recently, from those proposing notions of new production spaces.
The movement of production away from a system of individually-owned
plants producing single products for geographically limited markets to one
characterized by multiregional and multinational enterprises has further
dampened the enthusiasm for neoclassical vision of regional growth and
development. The structuralists (see Massey and Meegan (1982), Holland
1976a,b) focus attention on imbalances in accumulation between factors
(labor and capital) and over space (between one region and another or
between countries). Exploitation oflabor inevitably resultsin concentration
of wealth; itis not entirely clear whether this will always result in spatial
concentration, although the empirical evidence used in support of these
approaches usually documents the existence of a classic "north-south"
problem. Itshouldalsobe mentioned thatthestructuralistapproaches tendto
beascriticalofthoseanalystsusingmodels (suchaseconomic base orinputoutput)astheyareoftheneoclassicaltheorists.
Althoughcriticalofthisbody oftheory,Clarketal(1986)havesuggestedthat
firms (and hence regions) are in a state of continuous adjustment since the

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




5




environment in which they are operating is constantly, and not necessarily
uniformly,changing. The neteffectofthisistointroduceuncertaintyintothe
calculus of decision-making, thereby creating opportunities for investment
andmarketingdecisionsthatwillturnouttobesub-optimal. While theideais
intuitively appealing, the development of the theory and attendant empirical
evidencehaslaggedbehind.
Scott(1988) has recently provided what may be termed a mediated position
between the stricttenets of the neoclassical vision of change and the more
critical structuralist claims. His suggestion of "flexible production spaces"
provides an attractive vehicle forexamining the dynamics of change within
urbanandregionaleconomies. Essentially,hefocuseson thefactthatfirmsin
the latterpartofthe twentieth century have a much greaterflexibilityto (a)
choose production processes and (b)choose thelocationofsuppliers. Given
therapidlywithwhich many products move through aproductcycle,thereis
littleguarantee any longer thatnew products will be produced in the same
location and with thesame setofsuppliers. This summary sketch ofScoot's
ideasdoesnotprovideacompletepictureoftheapproach; however, from the
perspective ofthispaper, itdoes suggest a number ofimportant dimensions.
First,attention on the firm or industry isprobably more criticalthan before,
essentially because the dynamics of change within a regions may not be
evident from an examination ofgross, macro-level statistics. Secondly, the
nature of change in one region at one point in time may provide a very
imperfect guide to futureactivities; theflexibilityalluded toearliersuggests
thatfirmscan searchaglobalmarketforsitesand inputsthatwillyieldhigher
returns on investment. The ephemeral nature of the nonmetropolitan
expansion heralded in the 1970s suggests thatrapid movements through the
product cycle have the capability of disequilibriating growth patterns.
Thirdly, Scott'sevidence suggests thateven though growth may be occurring
in small firms,largefirms exact a very importantrole insettingdemand for
productsandprovidingmany importantinputs. Ifanything,inthelasttwenty
years,thenatureofinterdependenceintheeconomy hasincreasedratherthan
decreased. This has been accomplished through extensive vertical
disintegration; in some cases, the linked firms in the production chain have
been scattered throughout the globe. In other cases, strong agglomeration
economies, such as those associatedwith thejust-in-timeproduction system,
havecreatedindustrialcomplexeswithinregions.
Recent work by regionalanalysts,such asDendrinos and Mullaly (1981) and
Dendrinos and Haag (1984), especially in the application ofnonlinear urban
dynamics suggeststhatsome oftheprocessesidentifiedby Scott(1988)could
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5

6

be conceived withinadifferentparadigm. For example, drawing upon chaos
theory, one might consider regions as "strange attractors" in an economic
sense, around which and through which gyrate a complex of interdependent
flows within the social accounting production space. While the aggregate
effectofdifferentinputs intothesystem (defensecontracts,export demands,
new firms creation)may yieldsimilarchanges inthelevelsofkey variables,
the paths through which these changes move will be different, generating
differencesindistributionsacrossspaceandsectors.
What is not clear from these new perspectives is the issue of regional
convergence ordivergence; sincemost oftheanalyseshavebeen shortrun in
nature,itmay beprematuretoexpectcommitments tothelonger-termoutlook
forregions within a national economy. The changing nature of production
creates options foronce laggingregions togrow more rapidly; whether they
will or not still depends on many classical factors of location decision­
making. In the next section, some ofthesemore traditionalapproaches will
beexamined.

Linkages, Interaction, Causation
Regional analystshave long had an interestintheroleoflinkages: theearly
statement on location theory were very much concerned with the ability of
firmstoassembleinputs,produceandmarketgoods withinacost-minimizing
orprofit-maximizing environment. This interesthas manifested itselfin the
constructionofregionalmodels thatfocuson theessentialinterdependence of
activitieswithinregionaleconomies.
Perhaps the best known theory that focuses on linkages was proposed by
Perroux (1955); hisnotion of"poles de croissance" orgrowth polescaptured
the essential interdependence within economic systems. Economies were
assumed togrow asaresultofthepropulsive forcescreatedby key sectorssectorswith strongbackward andforwardlinkages. These linkagesgenerated
impulses throughout the economy, creating industrial demand and, through
payments of wages and salaries, consumption demand. A parallel concept,
thegrowth center,may be thoughtofas thespatialanalog tothegrowth pole
idea. Growth centers were regions/metropolitan areas in which there was
assumed to exista strong degree of interaction among sectors. Hence, the
multiplierand acceleratoreffectsofclassicalgrowthmodels were assumed to
be concentratedinspace. Closelyalliedwith theseideasarethecircularand
cumulative causation theories ofMyrdal (1957) and the work ofRasmussen

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




7

(1952) and Hirschman (1958). Myrdal envisioned growth as a selfperpetuating mechanism whereby additions tooutput generate attractions for
more investment and so forth. Pred translated this idea into a theory of
metropolitan growth; Thompson (1965) introduced the notion of a ratchet
effect,a level ofsizethatassuredcontinuedgrowth within aregion or urban
economy. Hirschman andRasmussen bothprovidedimportantideasaboutthe
roleofkey sectors within economies. However, the empirical evaluation of
theseconceptshasprovidedthesourceofagreatdealofdebate(seeHewings,
1982)much ofwhich hascenteredon theproblemsofconsistentidentification
ofkey sectorsand theassociatedissueofwhether such key sectorsidentified
from input-output models of the economy produced in the past provide
accurateguidancefordevelopmentpotential.
Taken asawhole,thesecontributionshavebeen importantessentiallybecause
they have focused on the structure of the economy. In terms of
convergence/divergence, there would appear to be suggestions that regions
would tend to diverge, the divergence emanating from the properties of the
cumulativecausationthatattractedgrowth inthefirstplace. Inthe 1960s and
1970s, there was a great deal of interestinpromotion regional development
based on the creation of growth centers; however, many policy-makers felt
that the process was akin to ordination-one simply anointed a regional
economy asagrowth centerand waitedforgrowth tooccur. Needless tosay,
most oftheresultswere disappointing! Thisisnottosuggestthatlinkagesare
unimportant,butratherthattheprocessofcreationoflinkagepatternsisvery
complex and notsubjecttothemere waving ofamagic wand.
Therehasbeen agreatdealofinterestintryingtounderstandthedynamics of
changewithinurbanandregionaleconomies intermsoftheevolutionofaset
oflinkagesamong thecomponents oftheeconomy. The variousmodels, such
aseconomic base, input-outputand econometric, thathave been developed at
theregionallevelplaceheavyemphasis on asystem thatisdemand drivenand
generates total impacts that are some multiple of the initial changes. The
specification of this multiplier effect has been the source of considerable
debate in the literature (see Hewings and Jensen, 1986; Richardson, 1985,
Bolton, 1985 forreviews). Only afew authorshave attemptedtoexamine the
natureofthisinteractioninterms ofthe stageofdevelopment characterizing
the regional economy. Figure 1 provides a schematic space-time
representationofthesetofeconomies withinanation. What canwe sayabout
the expected paths ofdevelopment through which these economies might be
expected to pass? How will this movement be associated with the changing
nature of interactions among industries, consumers, governments and other
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




8

institutions? Can we expect some logical progression in the nature of the
structure of the economy as we move from small,rural economies to those
describing large, complex metropolitan/industrial systems? How will the
natureoftheseeconomies,atdifferentstages,varyovertime?
Figure 1
Space-tim e representation of structure o f economies
Rural economy

Urban economy

National economy

TIME

The received literature in regional analysis provides very little help in
answering these questions; as shown on Figure 1, we are able to offer
comments to the effect that increasing complexity and increasing
connectedness are associated with movements across space and over time.
However, there is a dearth of empirical evidence and the accumulated
information isnotenough toofferany comments as tothenature ofchange.
Jensen etal.(1987) offera hypothesis thatthe evolution might be unilinear
and be characterizedby thepathshown inFigure2. However, recentwork in
urban dynamics and catastrophetheory suggeststhattheevolutionaryprocess
is likely to be nonlinear with substantial discontinuities created by sharp
changes in the external environment (i.e.,oil shocks) or the introduction of
radicalnew innovationsinproductandproductionprocess.
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




9

Figure2
Unilinear evolution, fundamental economic structures and economies
Phenotype
Ka)

Phenotype
H(a)

e • •

Phenotype
N(a)

Phenotype
1(b)

Phenotype
H(b)

• • •

Phenotype
N(b)

Phenotype
Kz)

Phenotype
H(z)

• • •

Phenotype
N(z)

Cross-section at time-period T

'
FES

Path of unilinear economic evoluation
Fundamental economic structure

Thompson (1965) offered a vision of regional growth and development that
stressed the changing nature of linkages within the regional system. As the
economy evolved, he suggested thatthethresholdlevelswhere localdemand
would be feasiblecreated discontinuities in development thatwould witness
the process of import substitution of inputs formally purchased outside the
region. Agglomeration economies and the ever-expanding local market
wouldprovideadditionalopportunitiesfornew firmstolocateintheregionor
forexistingfirms toexpand. Thompson also stressedthekey roleplayedby
inducedincome-the effectsofspendingfrom wages andsalariesgeneratedby
export sales-even to the extentof suggesting thatthe economy may be ina
position to begin exporting services originally located in the region toserve
thelocalmarket. Infact,asBeyers (1989) has shown, theexportofservices
from regionsinsome partsoftheUS isnow asimportantand asextensiveas
the exports of manufactured goods. Figure 3 provides a version of the
expected development path ofaregion interms ofstructuralcomplexity; the
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




10

Figure3
Nonunilinear evolution, fundamental economic structures and economies
Phenotype
1(a)

Phenotype
11(a)

•

•

•
•

•
•

Phenotype
l(z)

Phenotype
H(z)

Unifinear evoluation

Phenotype
llla(1)

Phenotype
llla(z)

Catastrophe

Nonunilinear
evoluation

Cross-section at time-period T

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




11

suggestion here isthat the process islogistic with long periods of low and
high levels of complexity and a relatively shorter period during which the
regionmoves from thelow tothehighlevel. Recentwork by Okazaki (1989)
inJapanhasintroducedthenotionof"hollowingout,"aprocessofdecreasing
complexity inthestructureofaregionaleconomy. The processes ofvertical
disintegration noted by Scott (1988) may be considered tobe a case inpoint
wherein theproduction spaces offirms/industriesexpandbeyond theconfines
of a single region’s economy. Do these processes enhance or retard the
convergenceofregionalwelfarelevels?
Itisclear that, apart from the abortive attempt to generate artificial growth
centers,theroleoflinkagesand linkagedevelopment continues toplayakey
roleingrowth and developmentprocessesattheregionallevel. However, the
major differencesbetween the 1980s and earlierdecades istheenhanced role
ofserviceactivityand institutions. The earliereconomic models ofregional
economies were very much dominated by the demand (= export) lead
economic development theories derived from international trade theory.
Exports were assumed tocomprise mainly goods produced by manufacturing
plants within the region; the service activity thatexisted was assumed to be
supporting thefunctioning ofthemanufacturing exports. Littleattentionwas
paid to monetary flows and "invisibles"; to be fair, some authors, such as
Blumenfeld (1955), suggested thatthe economic base theorists had got itall
wrong-it was the nonbasic sector thatprovided the attractionfor new firms
and thusthebasisforgrowthand development.
In attempting to assess the state of current thinking, several points emerge.
First,the simplisticcategorization ofeconomies as manufacturing, serviceor
resources based isprobably misleading. Regions should be characterized by
the nature and strengths of their internal and external interactions; as
economies evolve, itischanges in this part of the system that are likely to
create the major impacts. In a sense, one is arguing that the processes
describedby Scottarereallyprocesses oforganizationofproduction with the
linkage pattern potentially undergoing substantial spatial shifts as new
products and processes are introduced. Secondly, it is not clear whether
regions can influence the nature of these changes through policies; as
Glickman andWoodward (1989)haveargued,thereissome generalsuspicion
about thezero-sum natureofindustrial incentivesprograms, especially those
offeredtoforeignfirmsinterestedinlocatingintheUS. On theotherhand, it
isclear thatregions do function as systems ofinteracting firms and thatthe
more ofthisactivity thatcan be encouraged tolocate within theboundaries,

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




12

ceterisparibus,thebetterofftheregionaleconomy willbeintermsofincome,
employment,andothermeasuresofwelfare.
Figure 4
Innovation and the incom e-expenditure-industry system

However, there isone dimension of change thatappears prominently in the
regional science literature but rarely in the context of regional growth and
development theory. The theory of innovation diffusion and adoption has
provided substantial insights in the nature of change associated with the
introduction of new products and the manner in which those products have
been adopted by consumers or other firms. Rarely has this literature
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




13




examined the indirect and induced effects of innovation diffusion (see
Hewings et al. 1989). Figure 4 suggests a way in which the innovation
processmightbe capturedwithinthecontextofsome oftheformal models of
regionaleconomies (suchasan input-outputoreconometric model). Figure 5
provides some speculation on thenature ofchanges ofindividual parameters
and Figure 6 provides some possible ways in which change might be
manifested withinasetofinteractingindustries. The suggestionismade that
innovation spread and its impact on changes in structure provide a useful
explanatory mechanism for understanding the changing complexity of
economies.
Figure 5
Qualitative description of redistributional dynam ics
(diagram numbers refer to text classifications)

Ju n e 1990, W P -19 9 0-5




Figure 6
Types of diffusion of change in an input-output modelling fram ework
1

n

1

n

1

n

1

n

Does Space Matter?
Wamtz (1967) ina provocative address totheRegional Science Association
discussed the tyranny of space and itsrelationship to time. Many scholars
remainskepticalabouttheimportanceofspaceinconditioningthegrowthand
development paths of regional economies. Arguments are proposed to the
effect that new developments in air travel and telecommunications have
produced a "shrunken" world. Firms arenow freetolocateinawidervariety
of locations than was the case two or three decades ago; in essence, to use
Weber's (1929) distinctions,have more factorinputs become ubiquitous and
thereforceasedtoprovideconstraintsonlocation?As withanygeneralization,
therearewhole truthsandpartialtruths. Thereisno doubtthatfirmsdo have
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5

15

potentially greater locational flexibility than ever before; however, as the
ubiquityofsome resourcesincreasesand factorcoststendtoequalize,greater
attentionisthereforetransferredtothosefactorinputswhose pricesstillvary
substantially over space. The most important would appear tobe labor and
the cost of capital. Small differences in labor costs can translate into
substantial differences in unit costs and, with large production runs, into
importantdifferencesinprofitmargins.
Barnesand Sheppard (1984) haverecentlybegun toexploretheapplicationof
Sraffa's (1973) ideas of switching and reswitching in a spatial context. In
theirvision,product,processandlocationarelinkedinacomplex ofdecision­
making with little expectation that new product demands will necessarily
followthesameprocessofproductioninthesame geographicallocations.
The recent developments within the Chicago SMSA, especially firm
migration to the suburbs, have created new problems for firms wishing to
employ laboratthe lower end ofthe skillspectrum. The processes here are
suggestive ofthefindingsofAmos (1988); he updated some ofWilliamson's
(1965, 1977) work which lead to the hypothesis of an inverted ’u' shaped
processofdevelopmentby suggestingthatmacro-levelconvergences(suchas
that observed at the census region level in the United States) may be
accompanied by increasing intra-regional disparities. When viewed at the
metropolitan scale, this suggestion of divergence in access tojobs, income
levels and welfare generally, would appear to be characteristic of a large
number ofmetropolitancomplexes.

Concluding Comments
The majorwork inregionalgrowth anddevelopmenttheorywas articulatedin
aworld thatwas strictlyhierarchical. Decisionswereassumed totakeplaceat
the international level, then the national level and finally filterdown to the
regionaland sub-regionallevels. Accordingly, theview ofdevelopment was
essentiallytop-down. Inrecentyears,two majordevelopments appeartohave
created a need tochallenge some of these ideas. The firstfinds regions and
nations (other than the one in which the region is located) interacting and
developing trade relationships directly. The second, and potentially more
pervasive, isthe development of major groupings of nations into economic
communities such as the European Community, the US-Canada Free Trade
Agreement, ASEAN and soforth.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990 WP-1990-5

,




16

What are the implications for regional development? In the United States,
several stateshave begun todevelop what isde facto a foreign tradepolicy;
this has been manifested in the establishment of trading missions in several
countriesinEurope and Asiainan attempttolureinvestmentcapitalwith the
majorgoalofjobcreation. WhileGlickman andWoodward (1989)havebeen
verycriticalofsuch "foreignsmokestackchasing,"thepressuresforallstates
toentertheracehas been intense,especially intheMidwest. The incentives
packages offered tomany ofthe firms have raisedjustifiableconcerns about
the wisdom of such actions, measured in terms of traditional cost-benefit
appraisalcriteria.2
The second development, multination tradingalliances,isnotnew; however,
what characterizesthepresentdevelopments isthedegreetowhich individual
autonomy willbe surrenderedinsome criticalareas(likemonetarypolicy). In
the post 1992 European Community, the nature of regional development
policy willbe different;itisnotclearwhether similarcriteriawillbe applied
acrossallregionsorwhethertherewillbe some attempttodifferentiallyassist
areas whose development indices are way out of line with the country in
which they are located if not in terms of the EC as a whole. In North
America, themuch vauntedUS-Canada FTA hasbegun totake shape. Initial
estimates ofthe impacts suggest thatintheUS thebenefits from Free Trade
are likely to be small, even negligible. A more interesting question is the
degree to which the FTA will hurt or help specific sectors and regions,
especially in the Midwest and Northeast-the major US-Canada trading
partners.
Scholars outside US, have been puzzled by the absence of a coordinated
regionaldevelopmentpolicy. The roleoftheindividualstateshasbeen much
strongerthancomparablerolesforregionsinothercountries. The one arm of
the federal government that was specifically involved with regional
development, the Economic Development Administration, has been
ineffectivewithcontinualthreatsforitseliminationby successiveRepublican
administrations. Changes in the pace of development over the next two
decades are likely to reveal new spatial development configurations. The
major concern in the Midwest will be the degree to which the optimism
generated inthelasthalfdozen years willbe translated intoa foundation for
growth well intothe next century. More generally, few scholars seem tobe
preparedtooffersuggestionsastothelikelypathsofdevelopmentinthenext
fiftyyears in terms ofregional convergence or divergence. The changes of
thelasttwo decadeshavecreatedsome concernaboutventuringtoofarouton
alimbwithforecastsofsuchcomplex patternsofdevelopment.
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




17

Footnotes
^This section draws heavily on Richardson (1969, 1973); Borts and Stein (1964), Siebert (1969)
^In many cases, a cost-benefit analysis has not been undertaken but assertions have been made
about the stream o f benefits being positive. A great deal hinges on (1) number of indirect jobs
created (which often depends on exchange rates (2) length o f time firm stays in state and (3)
degree to which the fiim meets targets. The Volkswagen plant in New Scranton, Pennsylvania
failed on all three counts (see Van Meter, 1989)

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




18

References
Amos, O.M. (1988) "Unbalanced regional growth and regional income
inequality in thelatterstages ofdevelopment," RegionalScienceandUrban
Economics18:549-566.
Barnes, T. and Sheppard, E. (1984) "Technical choice and reswitching in
spaceeconomies,"RegionalScienceandUrbanEconomics14:345-362.
Beyers, W.B. (1989) TheProducerS
ervicesandEconomicDevelopmentin
theUnitedStates:TheLastDecade,Economic Development Administration,
Washington,D.C.
Blumenfeld, H. (1955) "The economic base of the metropolis," Journal
AmericanInstituteofPlanners21:114-132.
Bolton, R. (1985) "Regional econometric models," Journal ofRegional
Science,25:495-520.
Borts,G.H. and Stein,J.L.(1964) EconomicGrowthi
naFreeMarket(New
York: ColumbiaUP).
Clark, G.L., Gertler, M.S. and Whiteman J. (1986) RegionalDynamics:
StudiesinAdjustmentTheory(Boston:AllenandUnwin).
Dendrinos,D.and Haag,G. (1984) "Towardsastochasticdynamical theoryof
location:empiricalevidence,"GeographicalAnalysis16:287-300.
Dendrinos, D. and Mullaly, H. (1981) "Evolutionarypatternsofmetropolitan
populations,"GeographicalAnalysis13:328-44.
Glickman, N.J. and Woodward, D.P. (1989) TheNew Competitors:How
ForeignInvestorsareChangingtheU.S.Economy(New York: BasicBooks).
Hewings, G.J.D. (1982) "The empirical identification of key sectors in an
economy: aregionalperspective,"TheDevelopingEconomies20:173-195.
Hewings, G.J.D. and Jensen, R.C. (1986) "Regional, interregional and
multiregional input-output models," in P. Nijkamp and E.S. Mills (eds.)
HandbookofRegionalandUrbanEconomics,Vol 1: Regional Economics
(Amsterdam: NorthHolland)295-355.
Hewings, G.J.D., Jensen, R.C., West, G.R., Sonis, M., and Jackson, R.W.
(1989) "The spatialorganization ofproduction: an input-outputperspective,"
Socio-EconomicPlanningSciences23:67-86.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




19

Hirschman,A.O. (1958)TheS
trategyofEconomicDevelopment(New Haven:
YaleUP).
Holland,S.(1976a)CapitalVersust
heRegion(London: Macmillan).
Holland,S.(1976b)TheRegionalProblem(London: Macmillan).
Isard,W. (1956)Locationandt
heSpaceEconomy(Cambridge: MIT Press).
Jensen, R.C., Hewings, G.J.D., Sonis, M. and West, G.R. (1987) "On a
taxonomy ofeconomies,"A
ustralianJournalofRegionalStudies2:3-24.
Massey, D. and Meegan, R. (1982)AnatomyofJobLoss:TheHow,Whyand
WhereofEmploymentDecline,(London: Methuen).
Myrdal, G. (1957) EconomicTheoryandUnderdevelopedRegions(London:
Duckworth).
Okazaki, F. (1989) "Dynamic aspects of input-output scheme for analysing
the so-calledhollowing out phenomenon inan advanced national economy,"
paper presented at the Eleventh Pacific Regional Science Conference,
Singapore.
Perroux, F. (1955) "Note sur la notion de 'pole de croissance,'" Economie

Appliquee.

Pred, A. (1977) City-Systemsi
nAdvancedEconomies(New York: Halsted
Press).
Rasmussen, P. (1952) S
tudiesinIntersectoralRelations(Amsterdam: North
Holland).
Richardson, H.W. (1969) Elements of Regional Economics (London:
Penguin).
Richardson,H.W. (1973)RegionalGrowthTheory(London: Macmillan).
Richardson, H.W. (1985) "Input-output and economic base multipliers:
lookingbackwardandforward,"JournalofRegionalScience25:608-661.
Scott, A.J. (1988) Metropolis:Fromt
heDivisionofLabortoUrbanForm
(Berkeley:UniversityofCaliforniaPress).
Siebert,H. (1969) RegionalEconomicGrowth:TheoryandPolicy(Scranton:
InternationalTextbookCo.).
Sraffa, P. (1973) ProductionofCommoditiesbyMeans ofCommodities,
(Cambridge: UniversityPress).

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




20

Thirlwall, A.P. (1974) "Regional economic disparitiesand regional policy in
theCommon Market," UrbanS
tudies11:1-12.
Thompson, W. (1965)APrefacet
oUrbanEconomics(Baltimore:FreePress).
Van Meter, W. (1989)AnExPostAnalysisoft
heRegionalEconomicImpact
oftheVolkswagenAutoFacilityinWestmorelandCounty,Pennsylvania,
unpublishedM.A. thesis,DepartmentofGeography,UniversityofIllinois.
Wamtz, W., "Global science and the tyranny of space," Papers oft
he
RegionalScienceAssociation,19:7-19.
Weber, A. (1929) TheoryofLocationofIndustry(Chicago: University of
ChicagoPress).
Williamson, J.G. (1965) "Regional inequality and the process of national
development,"EconomicDevelopmentandC
ulturalChange13:3-45.
Williamson, J.G. (1977) "Unbalanced growth, inequality and regional
development: some lessons from US history," in V.L. Arnold (ed.)

AlternativestoConfrontation:ANationalPolicyTowardRegionalChange
(Lexington:Heath)3-61.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-5




21

Federal Reserve Bank ofChicago
RESEARCH STAFF MEMORANDA, WORKING PAPERS AND STAFF STUDIES
The following listspapers developed in recent years by the Bank’sresearch staff. Copies of those
materials that are currently available can be obtained by contacting the Public Information Center
(312) 322-5111.
Working Paper Series—A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Sev­
enth Federal Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Regional Economic Issues
*WP-82-l

Donna Craig Vandenbrink

“The Effects of Usury Ceilings:
the Economic Evidence,” 1982

:*WP-82-2

David R. Allardice

“Small Issue Industrial Revenue Bond
Financing in the Seventh Federal
Reserve District,” 1982

WP-83-1

William A. Testa

“Natural Gas Policy and the Midwest
Region,” 1983

WP-86-1

Diane F. Siegel
William A. Testa

“Taxation ofPublic Utilities Sales:
State Practices and the IllinoisExperience”

WP-87-1

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Measuring Regional High Tech
Activity with Occupational Data”

WP-87-2

Robert H. Schnorbus
Philip R. Israilevich

“Alternative Approaches to Analysis of
Total Factor Productivity at the
Plant Level”

WP-87-3

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Industrial R&D An Analysis ofthe
Chicago Area”

WP-89-1

William A. Testa

“Metro Area Growth from 1976 to 1985:
Theory and Evidence”

WP-89-2

William A. Testa
Natalie A. Davila

“Unemployment Insurance: A State
Economic Development Perspective”

WP-89-3

Alenka S. Giese

“A Window ofOpportunity Opens for
Regional Economic Analysis: BEA Release
Gross State Product Data”

WP-89-4

Philip R. Israilevich
William A. Testa

“Determining Manufacturing Output
for States and Regions”

WP-89-5

Alenka S.Geise

“The Opening ofMidwest Manufacturing
to Foreign Companies: The Influx of
Foreign Direct Investment”

WP-89-6

Alenka S. Giese
Robert H. Schnorbus

“A New Approach to Regional Capital Stock
Estimation: Measurement and
Performance”

*Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.




Working Paper Series (cant'd)

WP-89-7

William A. Testa

“Why has Illinois Manufacturing Fallen
Behind the Region?”

WP-89-8

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Regional Specialization and Technology
in Manufacturing”

WP-89-9

Christopher Erceg
Philip R. Israilevich
Robert H. Schnorbus

“Theory and Evidence ofTwo Competitive
Price Mechanisms for Steel”

WP-89-10

David R. Aliardice
William A. Testa

“Regional Energy Costs and Business
Siting Decisions: An IllinoisPerspective”

WP-89-21

William A. Testa

“Manufacturing’sChangeover to Services
in the Great Lakes Economy”

WP-90-1

P.R. Israilevich

“Construction ofInput-Output Coefficients
with Flexible Functional Forms”

WP-90-4

Douglas D. Evanoff
Philip R. Israilevich

“Regional Regulatory Effects on
Bank Efficiency”

WP-90-5

Geoffrey J.D. Hewings

“Regional Growth and Development Theory:
Summary and Evaluation”

WP-90-6

Michael Kendix

“Institutional Rigidities as Barriers to Regional
Growth: A Midwest Perspective”

Issues in Financial Regulation

WP-89-11

Douglas D. Evanoff
Philip R. Israilevich
Randall C. Merris

“Technical Change, Regulation, and Economies
of Scale for Large Commercial Banks:
An Application ofa Modified Version
of Shepard’sLemma”

WP-89-12

Douglas D. Evanoff

“Reserve Account Management Behavior:
Impact ofthe Reserve Accounting Scheme
and Carry Forward Provision”

WP-89-14

George G.. Kaufman

“Are Some Banks too Large to Fail?
Myth and Reality”

WP-89-16

Ramon P. De Gennaro
James T. Moser

“Variability and Stationarity ofTerm
Premia”

WP-89-17

Thomas Mondschean

“A Model of Borrowing and Lending
with Fixed and Variable Interest Rates”

WP-89-18

Charles W. Calomiris

“Do "Vulnerable'' Economies Need Deposit
Insurance?: Lessons from the U.S.
Agricultural Boom and Bust ofthe 1920s”

’•'Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



3

Working Paper Series (
cont'd)
WP-89-23

George G. Kaufman

“The Savings and Loan Rescue of 1989:
Causes and Perspective”

WP-89-24

Elijah Brewer III

“The Impact ofDeposit Insurance on S&L
Shareholders’Risk/Return Trade-offs”

Macro Economic Issues

WP-89-13

David A. Aschauer

“Back ofthe G-7 Pack: Public Investment and
Productivity Growth in the Group ofSeven”

WP-89-15

Kenneth N. Kuttner

“Monetary and Non-Monetary Sources
ofInflation: An Error Correction Analysis”

WP-89-19

Ellen R. Rissman

“Trade Policy and Union Wage Dynamics”

WP-89-20

Bruce C. Petersen
William A. Strauss

“Investment Cyclicality in Manufacturing
Industries”

WP-89-22

Prakash Loungani
Richard Rogerson
Yang-Hoon Sonn

“Labor Mobility, Unemployment and
Sectoral Shifts: Evidence from
Micro Data”

WP-90-2

Lawrence J.Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“Unit Roots in Real GNP: Do We Know,
and Do We Care?”

WP-90-3

Steven Strongin
Vefa Tarhan

“Money Supply Announcements and the Market’s
Perception ofFederal Reserve Policy”

WP-90-7

Prakash Loungani
Mark Rush

“Sectoral Shifts in Interwar Britain”

WP-90-8

Kenneth N. Kuttner

“Money, Output, and Inflation: Testing
The P-Star Restrictions”

WP-90-9

Lawrence J.Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“Current Real Business Cycle Theories
and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations”

WP-90-10

S. Rao Aiyagari
Lawrence J. Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“The Output, Employment, And Interest Rate
Effects ofGovernment Consumption”

*Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



Staff Memoranda—A series ofresearch papers in draft form prepared by members of the Research

Department and distributed to the academic community for review and comment. (Series discon­
tinued in December, 1988. Later works appear in working paper series).
**SM-81-2

George G. Kaufman

“Impact ofDeregulation on the Mortgage
Market,” 1981

**SM-81-3

Alan K. Reichert

“An Examination ofthe Conceptual Issues
Involved in Developing Credit Scoring Models
in the Consumer Lending Field,” 1981

Robert D. Laurent

“A Critique ofthe Federal Reserve’sNew
Operating Procedure,” 1981*

George G. Kaufman

“Banking as a Line ofCommerce: The Changing
Competitive Environment,” 1981

SM-82-1

Harvey Rosenblum

“Deposit Strategies ofMinimizing the Interest
Rate Risk Exposure of S&Ls,” 1982

♦SM-82-2

George Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“Implications ofDeregulation for Product
Lines and Geographical Markets of Financial
Instititions,” 1982

*SM-82-3

George G. Kaufman

“The Fed’sPost-October 1979 Technical
Operating Procedures: Reduced Ability
to Control Money,” 1982

SM-83-1

John J. Di Clemente

“The Meeting ofPassion and Intellect:
A History ofthe term ‘Bank’in the
Bank Holding Company Act,” 1983

SM-83-2

Robert D. Laurent

“Comparing Alternative Replacements for
Lagged Reserves: Why Settle fora Poor
Third Best?” 1983

**SM-83-3

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman

“A Proposal for Federal Deposit Insurance
with Risk Sensitive Premiums,” 1983

*SM-83-4

Henry N. Goldstein
Stephen E. Haynes

“A Critical Appraisal ofMcKinnon’s
World Money Supply Hypothesis,” 1983

SM-83-5

George Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“The Future ofCommercial Banks in the
Financial Services Industry,” 1983

SM-83-6

Vefa Tarhan

“Bank Reserve Adjustment Process and the
Use of Reserve Carryover Provision and
the Implications ofthe Proposed
Accounting Regime,” 1983

SM-83-7

John J. Di Clemente

“The Inclusion ofThrifts in Bank
Merger Analysis,” 1983

SM-84-1

Harvey Rosenblum
Christine Pavel

“Financial Services in Transition: The
Effects ofNonbank Competitors,” 1984

SM-81-4
**SM-81-5

*Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



Staff Memoranda (cont'd)

SM-84-2

George G. Kaufman

“The Securities Activities ofCommercial
Banks,” 1984

SM-84-3

George G. Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“Consequences of Deregulation for
Commercial Banking”

SM-84-4

George G. Kaufman

“The Role ofTraditional Mortgage Lenders
in Future Mortgage Lending: Problems
and Prospects”

SM-84-5

Robert D. Laurent

“The Problems ofMonetary Control Under
Quasi-Contemporaneous Reserves”

SM-85-1

Harvey Rosenblum
M. Kathleen O’Brien
John J. Di Clemente

“On Banks, Nonbanks, and Overlapping
Markets: A Reassessment ofCommercial
Banking as a Line ofCommerce”

SM-85-2

Thomas G. Fischer
William H. Gram
George G. Kaufman
Larry R. Mote

“The Securities Activities ofCommercial
Banks: A Legal and Economic Analysis”

SM-85-3

George G. Kaufman

“Implications of Large Bank Problems and
Insolvencies for the Banking System and
Economic Policy”

SM-85-4

Elijah Brewer, III

“The Impact ofDeregulation on The True
Cost of Savings Deposits: Evidence
From Illinoisand Wisconsin Savings &
Loan Association”

SM-85-5

Christine Pavel
Harvey Rosenblum

“Financial Darwinism: Nonbanks—
and Banks—Are Surviving”

SM-85-6

G. D. Koppenhaver

“Variable-Rate Loan Commitments,
Deposit Withdrawal Risk, and
Anticipatory Hedging”

SM-85-7

G. D. Koppenhaver

“A Note on Managing Deposit Flows
With Cash and Futures Market
Decisions”

SM-85-8

G. D. Koppenhaver

“Regulating Financial Intermediary
Use of Futures and Option Contracts:
Policies and Issues”

SM-85-9

Douglas D. Evanoff

“The Impact of Branch Banking
on Service Accessibility”

SM-86-1

George J. Benston
George G. Kaufman

“Risks and Failures in Banking:
Overview, History, and Evaluation”

SM-86-2

David Alan Aschauer

“The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal
Policy”

^Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.




Staff Memoranda (cont'd)

SM-86-3

George G. Kaufman

“Banking Risk in Historical Perspective”

SM-86-4

Elijah Brewer III
Cheng Few Lee

“The Impact ofMarket, Industry, and
Interest Rate Risks on Bank Stock Returns”

SM-87-1

Ellen R. Rissman

“Wage Growth and Sectoral Shifts:
New Evidence on the Stability of
the Phillips Curve”

SM-87-2

Randall C. Merris

“Testing Stock-Adjustment Specifications
and Other Restrictions on Money
Demand Equations”

SM-87-3

George G. Kaufman

“The Truth About Bank Runs”

SM-87-4

Gary D. Koppenhaver
Roger Stover

“On The Relationship Between Standby
Letters ofCredit and Bank Capital”

SM-87-5

Gary D. Koppenhaver
Cheng F. Lee

“Alternative Instruments for Hedging
Inflation Risk in the Banking Industry”

SM-87-6

Gary D. Koppenhaver

“The Effects of Regulation on Bank
Participation in the Market”

SM-87-7

Vefa Tarhan

“Bank Stock Valuation: Does
Maturity Gap Matter?”

SM-87-8

David Alan Aschauer

“Finite Horizons, Intertemporal
Substitution and Fiscal Policy”

SM-87-9

Douglas D. Evanoff
Diana L. Fortier

“Reevaluation ofthe Structure-ConductPerformance Paradigm in Banking”

SM-87-10

David Alan Aschauer

“Net Private Investment and Public Expenditure
in the United States 1953-1984”

SM-88-1

George G. Kaufman

“Risk and Solvency Regulation of
Depository Institutions: Past Policies
and Current Options”

SM-88-2

David Aschauer

“Public Spending and the Return to Capital”

SM-88-3

David Aschauer

“IsGovernment Spending Stimulative?”

SM-88-4

George G. Kaufman
Larry R. Mote

“Securities Activities ofCommercial Banks:
The Current Economic and Legal Environment

SM-88-5

Elijah Brewer, III

“A Note on the Relationship Between
Bank Holding Company Risks and Nonbank
Activity”

SM-88-6

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman
Cynthia M. Latta

“Duration Models: A Taxonomy”

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman

“Durations ofNondefault-Free Securities”

^Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



1
Staff Memoranda (cont'd)
SM-88-7

David Aschauer

Is Public Expenditure Productive?”

SM-88-8

Elijah Brewer, III
Thomas H. Mondschean

Commercial Bank Capacity to Pay
Interest on Demand Deposits:
Evidence from Large Weekly
Reporting Banks”

SM-88-9

Abhijit V. Banerjee
Kenneth N. Kuttner

Imperfect Information and the
Permanent Income Hypothesis”

SM-88-10

David Aschauer

Does Public Capital Crowd out
Private Capital?”

SM-88-11

Ellen Rissman

Imports, Trade Policy, and
Union Wage Dynamics”

Staff Studies—A series of research studies dealing with various economic policy issues on a national
level.
SS-83-1
**SS-83-2

Harvey Rosenblum
Diane Siegel

‘Competition in Financial Services:
the Impact of Nonbank Entry,” 1983

Gillian Garcia

‘Financial Deregulation: Historical
Perspective and Impact of the Garn-St
Germain Depository Institutions Act
of 1982,” 1983

*Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.