View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Prospective Deficits and the Asian
Currency Crisis
Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum and
Sergio Rebelo

Working Papers Series
Research Department
(WP-98-5)

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Prospective De…cits and the Asian Currency
Crisis
Craig Burnside¤ Martin Eichenbaumyand Sergio Rebeloz
,
November 5, 1998

Abstract
This paper argues that the recent Asian currency crisis was caused by
large prospective de…cits associated with implicit bailout guarantees to failing banking systems. We articulate this view using a simple dynamic general equilibrium model whose key feature is that a speculative attack is
inevitable once the present value of future government de…cits rises. This
is true regardless of the government’s foreign reserve position or the initial
level of its debt. While the government cannot prevent a speculative attack,
it can a¤ect its timing. The longer the delay, the higher in‡ation will be
under ‡exible exchange rates. We present empirical evidence in support
of the three key assumptions in our model: (i) foreign reserves did not
play a special role in the timing of the attack, (ii) large losses in the banking sector were associated with large increases in governments’ prospective
de…cits, and (iii) the public knew that banks were in trouble before the
currency crises.
J.E.L. Classi…cation: F31
Keywords: Currency crisis, banking crisis, speculative attacks, Asia.

¤

The World Bank
Northwestern University, NBER and Federal Reserve of Chicago.
z
Northwestern University and NBER.
y

1. Introduction
Recent events in Asia have renewed interest in the causes and consequences of
speculative attacks on …xed exchange rate regimes. The explanation preferred by
policy makers in Asia is that the currency crisis was a self ful…lling prophecy:
it happened because speculators thought it was going to happen.1 Not surprisingly, proponents of this view argue that the International Monetary Fund should
provide resources to fend o¤ such predatory attacks and help prey countries recover from them. Multiple equilibrium models of currency crises can be used to
rationalize this interpretation of recent events in Asia.2
The most natural alternative explanation of the Asian currency crisis is that
it re‡ected pro‡igate …scal policy: ongoing …scal de…cits led to sustained reserve
losses and to the eventual abandonment of …xed exchange rates. This is the
standard view of speculative attacks in ‘…rst generation’ models of currency crises.
To articulate this view, the speculative attacks literature focuses on two types of
policy experiments: (i) an increase in the …scal de…cit that must eventually be
monetized;3 and (ii) an exchange rate peg that is unsustainable because it reduces
the government’s seignorage revenues without compensating …scal adjustments.4
Both experiments imply that the collapse of a …xed exchange rate is preceded
by ongoing de…cits and rising debt levels. This has motivated a large body of
empirical work aimed at predicting currency crises on the basis of …scal de…cits
and other macroeconomic aggregates.5
The standard explanation for speculative attacks has an obvious shortcom1

Radelet and Sachs (1998) also take this perspective in addition to arguing that the actions
of the IMF exacerbated the crises.
2
See for example Obstfeld (1986a, 1996), and Sachs, Tornell and Velasco (1996).
3
See for example Krugman (1979), Flood and Garber (1984), Obstfeld (1986b), and Calvo
and Végh (1998).
4
See for example Calvo (1987) and Wijnbergen (1991).
5
For a recent example see Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1996).

2

ing when applied to Asia: governments of the crisis countries (Indonesia, Korea,
Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand) were running either surpluses or small
de…cits and had substantial foreign exchange reserves. Indeed, when they abandoned …xed exchange rates, all had more than enough reserves to buy back the
monetary base, and virtually all of M1 (see Section 6).
This evidence notwithstanding, we argue that the Asian currency crises were
caused by fundamentals: large prospective de…cits associated with implicit bailout
guarantees to failing banking systems. The expectation that these future de…cits
would (at least in part) be …nanced by seignorage revenues led to a collapse of
the …xed exchange rate regimes in Asia.6 Of course market participants could
have believed that governments would fund their obligations by raising taxes or
lower expenditures. But is this credible? In our view it is not. The state of the
world in which …nancial intermediaries would su¤er grievous losses is exactly the
state of the world in which current and prospective real output and tax revenues
would fall. While not modeled in this paper, raising distortionary taxes or lowering government purchases under those circumstances could well be politically
unacceptable or socially undesirable relative to the alternative: monetizing the
prospective de…cits and receiving aid from international agencies like the International Monetary Fund. But this alternative is incompatible with maintaining
…xed exchange rates. In this sense, our view of recent events in Asia is related
to ‘second generation’ speculative attack models which stress that governments
consider the costs and bene…ts of abandoning …xed exchange rate regimes.7
To articulate our view of the Asian currency crisis, sections 2 and 3 of the
paper study the dynamics of a speculative attack in a variant of the perfect fore6

Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998a) also discuss the possible role played by expectations
of future seignorage revenues in the Asian currency crises. They do so under the assumption
that the a¤ected countries faced a limit on the ratio of total private foreign debt to government
reserves.
7
See Obstfeld (1994) and references therein.

3

sight small open economy model considered by Calvo (1987). The key di¤erence
between our model and Calvo’s is the nature of the monetary experiment that we
analyze. To capture the e¤ect of a prospective de…cit on a …xed exchange rate
regime we assume that at time 0 agents receive information that future de…cits will
be larger than they originally believed. The government’s intertemporal budget
constraint implies that a speculative attack is inevitable. This is true regardless of
the government’s initial level of foreign reserves or its initial debt position. Once
the government learns that the present value of future de…cits has risen, the only
choices left to it are when and how to raise the seignorage revenues required to
meet its intertemporal budget constraint.
We analyze the date of a speculative attack, i.e. the date at which the economy
switches from a …xed to a ‡oating exchange rate regime, under two assumptions.
First, we assume that the government follows a threshold rule according to which
the …xed exchange rate regime is abandoned in the …rst period that net government
debt reaches some exogenous upper bound. Second, we consider the case in which
the only constraint faced by the government is its intertemporal budget constraint.
In both cases we depart from the speculative attack literature by distinguishing
between the time of the speculative attack and the time at which the government
implements the new monetary policy required to balance its intertemporal budget
constraint. Disentangling these two events considerably enriches the dynamic
implications of the model.
Using versions of the model calibrated to Korean and Thai data, we show in
Section 4 that the speculative attack occurs after the information about higher
future de…cits arrives but before the new monetary policy is implemented. An
econometrician looking at the data would see an exchange rate crisis - but he
would not see large de…cits, low levels of reserves, high growth rates of money or
high rates of in‡ation prior to the speculative attack. The econometrician could
4

well conclude that the attack was a multiple equilibrium phenomenon. In fact it
re‡ects fundamentals: high prospective de…cits.
While the government cannot prevent a speculative attack, it can a¤ect its
timing by borrowing. The cost of delaying is higher future in‡ation once the
speculative attack takes place. This raises the issue of what monetary policy
the government should pursue. Section 5 shows that in our simple model, the
optimal policy is to abandon …xed exchange rates as soon as information about
higher prospective de…cits arrives. Since this result re‡ects, in part, the absence
of nominal rigidities in our model, it serves primarily to highlight the costs of
delaying a speculative attack. In reality, these costs must be counterbalanced
against the bene…ts (if any) of delay.
Section 6 o¤ers empirical evidence in support of the three key assumptions
in our model: (i) foreign reserves do not play a special role in the timing of the
attack; (ii) large losses in the banking sector are associated with increases in governments’ prospective de…cits; and (iii) the public knows that banks are in trouble
before the exchange rate crisis occurs. To address (i), we examine the behavior of
foreign exchange reserves prior to the crises. To address (ii) we use information
on pre and post currency crisis loan default rates to generate rough estimates of
governments’ total implicit liabilities to the …nancial sector. To address (iii) we
construct and analyze stock market based measures of the value of …nancial and
non…nancial sectors in the crisis countries. We …nd strong evidence that in Korea,
Thailand, and to a lesser extent Malaysia and the Philippines, the value of the
…nancial sector had been declining, in both absolute and relative terms, well before their currency crises. Coupled with the institutional information summarized
by Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998), this constitutes strong evidence in favor
of assumption (iii). Finally, Section 7 presents concluding remarks and discusses
some shortcomings of our analysis.
5

2. A Benchmark Model
In this Section we describe a continuous time, perfect foresight endowment economy populated by an in…nitely lived representative agent and a government. All
agents, including the government, have access to international capital markets.
The government faces a standard present value budget constraint and …nances
expenditures through lump sum taxes, seignorage revenues and borrowing.
There is a single consumption good in the economy and no barriers to trade,
so that purchasing power parity holds:
Pt = St Pt¤ :

(2.1)

Here Pt and Pt¤ denote the domestic and foreign price level respectively, while
St denotes the exchange rate (de…ned as units of domestic currency per unit of
foreign currency). For convenience we assume that Pt¤ = 1.
2.1. The Representative Agent
The representative agent maximizes lifetime utility, de…ned as:
U=

Z

0

1

c1¡¾ ¡ 1 ¡½t
t
e dt.
1¡¾

(2.2)

Here ct denotes consumption, ½ is a strictly positive discount factor, and ¾ > 0
is the inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: The representative
agent can borrow and lend in international capital markets at a constant real
interest rate r. To eliminate trends in the current account we assume that r = ½:
The representative agent’s ‡ow budget constraint is given by:
¢bt + ¢dt = ¡¢mt
if t 2 I;
_
_
=
bt + dt = y + r(bt + dt) + v ¡ ct ¡ ¿ ¡ ¼t mt ¡ mt if t 2 I:
_
6

(2.3)

Here bt and dt denote real domestic government debt and net foreign assets held
by the representative agent, respectively, y denotes the constant exogenous endowment of output, v denotes the constant level of lump sum transfers from the
government, ¿ denotes the constant level of lump sum taxes, and ¼t is the in‡ation
rate. The variable mt represents real money balances, de…ned as mt = Mt =Pt ,
where Mt denotes nominal money holdings. Throughout the paper xt denotes
_

dx
.
dt

Constraint (2.3) takes into account the possibility of discrete changes in mt , dt ,
and bt at a …nite set of points in time, I. The ‡ow budget constraint, together with
the conditions lim e¡rt bt = lim e¡rtdt = 0; implies the following intertemporal
t!1

t!1

budget constraint for the household:

b0 + d0 =

Z

0

1

e¡rt [ct + ¿ ¡ y ¡ v + ¼t mt + mt ]dt +
_

X

e¡ri ¢mi :

(2.4)

i2I

According to (2.4), the present value of the representative agent’s expenditures,
inclusive of taxes and transfers, must equal the present value of endowment income
plus initial net assets.
Finally, the agent faces the following continuous time analogue to a cash in
advance constraint on consumption purchases:
ct · mt :

(2.5)

Since the nominal interest rate is positive in all the scenarios that we consider,
(2.5) holds with strict equality.
The problem of the representative household is to maximize (2.2) subject to
(2.3) and (2.5) by choice of time paths for ct ; mt ; bt and dt ; subject to a known
time path for Pt . In the Appendix we show that the …rst order conditions for this
problem imply:
c¡¾ = ¸(1 + r + ¼ t );
t
7

(2.6)

where ¸ is the current-valued Lagrange multiplier associated with (2.3). Equation
(2.6) will play a central role in our derivations.
2.2. The Government
The government purchases goods, g; makes transfer payments, v; levies lump sum
taxes, ¿ ; and may borrow at the real interest rate r. In addition, the government
can print money. The government’s ‡ow budget constraint is given by:
¢ft ¡ ¢bt = ¢mt
if t 2 I
_t ¡ bt = ¿ ¡ g ¡ v + r(ft ¡ bt ) + mt + ¼t mt if t 2 I:
_
=
f
_

(2.7)

In this equation ft represents the government’s real net foreign assets.8 The ‡ow
budget constraint together with the conditions lim e¡rtft = lim e¡rt bt = 0; imply
t!1

t!1

the following intertemporal budget constraint for the government:
b0 ¡ f0 =

Z

0

1

e¡rt(¿ ¡ g ¡ v + mt + ¼ tmt )dt +
_

X

e¡ri ¢mi :

(2.8)

i2I

According to this condition, the present value of future surpluses including the
value of seignorage revenues must equal the value of the government’s net initial
debt.
2.3. A Competitive Equilibrium
A competitive perfect foresight equilibrium for this economy is a set of allocations
ct ; mt; bt + dt ; a set of prices Pt and St; and a set of paths for the …scal variables,
¿ t ; gt and vt; such that the following conditions hold: (i) ct ; mt , bt + dt solve the
household’s problem given the paths for Pt; St , ¿ t and vt (ii) the government’s
8

r
nr
r
It is common in the literature to divide ft into two components: ft = ft + ft ;where ft
nr
and ft denote the government’s net foreign exchange reserves and the remaining net foreign
assets in the government portfolio, respectively. Note that if ft and bt yield the same rate of
return, they enter the government’s ‡ow budget constraint symmetrically. So given values for ¿
and g, and a path for mt the model can only determine the time path of the government’s total
debt: bt ¡ ft .

8

intertemporal budget constraint (2.8) holds; and (iii) St = Pt for all t: Note that
this de…nition applies to an economy operating under either a …xed or a ‡exible
exchange rate equilibrium.
2.4. A Sustainable Fixed Exchange Rate Regime
In a sustainable …xed exchange rate regime agents anticipate zero in‡ation and
(2.6) reduces to:
c¡¾ = ¸(1 + r);

(2.9)

implying that consumption is constant over time. The budget constraint (2.4)
implies that:
c = r(b0 + d0) + r

Z

1

0

e¡rt (y + v ¡ ¿ )dt:

(2.10)

In this equilibrium, the money supply is endogenous. Purchasing power parity
(2.1), and the cash in advance constraint (2.5) imply that the equilibrium level of
the money supply is:
M = Sc:

(2.11)

So in a sustainable …xed exchange rate regime, the money supply is constant and
the present value of current and future real surpluses equals the initial real net liabilities of the government: no seignorage revenues are available to the government.
In our model economy, seignorage revenues can be generated only if the country
abandons the …xed exchange rate regime.9 In a …xed exchange rate regime, the
government’s intertemporal budget constraint (2.8) simpli…es to:
b0 ¡ f0 =

Z

0

1

e¡rt (¿ ¡ g ¡ v)dt:

9

(2.12)

If there were growth in P ¤ or in consumption, the government would collect some seignorage
revenue under …xed exchange rates.

9

3. Exchange Rate Crises
Suppose that at time 0 agents learn that there has been an increase, Á, in the
present value of the de…cit due to a rise in future transfer payments. Speci…cally,
we assume that transfers increase permanently after date T 0 :
(

vt = v for 0 · t < T 0 ;
vt ¸ v for t ¸ T 0 :

To simplify we suppose that taxes and government purchases remain constant.
The increase in the government de…cit is then given by:
Á=

Z

1

T0

e¡rt (vt ¡ v)dt:

The government’s new budget constraint is:
b0 ¡ f0 =

Z

1

0

e¡rt (¿ ¡ g ¡ v)dt

¡Á +

Z

0

1

(3.1)

e¡rt (mt + ¼t mt )dt +
_

X

e¡ri ¢mi :

i2I

Using equation (2.12) this can be rewritten as:
Á=

Z

0

1

e¡rt (mt + ¼ t mt )dt +
_

X

e¡ri ¢mi :

(3.2)

i2I

Since the government must collect seignorage revenues it must, at some point,
abandon the …xed exchange regime.10
For simplicity we assume that the government will raise the seignorage revenues
to balance its intertemporal budget constraint by a combination of a one time
10

To see this suppose that the economy never reverted to a ‡exible exchange rate regime.
Expected in‡ation would then be zero and the demand for real balances would remain constant
over time. What happens if the government prints money to …nance the de…cit? Since there
is no demand for this money, agents will simply trade it for a di¤erent asset. Regardless of
whether this asset is domestic bonds, foreign bonds or foreign reserves, the nominal money
supply will revert to its initial value. This means that no seignorage revenue has been raised by
the government.

10

increase in the stock of money at time T equal to ¢MT and growth in the money
supply at rate ¹ from period T on. We denote the time period in which the
government abandons the …xed exchange rate regime by t¤ : To determine t¤ , we
must make assumptions regarding the government’s rule for abandoning the …xed
exchange rate regime.
3.1. A Threshold Rule For Total Debt
In this section we consider a rule that is motivated by standard assumptions in the
speculative attack literature. We assume that the government follows a threshold
rule: it abandons the …xed exchange rate regime in the …rst period t¤ when bt ¡ ft

reaches ª:

In the literature this threshold rule is typically specialized to apply only to
the foreign exchange reserves of the government.11 This requires the additional
assumption that the only component of the government’s portfolio that changes
over time is the central bank’s foreign reserves. Then the threshold rule on net
government debt is transformed into a threshold rule for reserves so that the
government abandons the …xed exchange rate regime when reserves reach a certain
lower bound.
3.2. Timing
To analyze how the economy reacts to the information about higher prospective
de…cits it is useful to distinguish between four intervals of time.
Time Interval 1: 0 < t < t¤: This is the time interval after information about the
higher future de…cits has arrived but before the collapse of the …xed exchange
11

See for example Krugman (1978) and Obstfeld and Rogo¤ (1998). Exceptions to this assumption include Drazen and Helpman (1987, 1988) and Wijnbergen (1993).

11

rate regime. We denote the value of consumption, real balances and nominal
¹
money supply in this interval of time by c, m, and M ; respectively.
¹ ¹
Time Interval 2: t¤ · t < T: This is the time interval between the collapse of
the …xed exchange rate regime and the new steady state ‡exible exchange

rate equilibrium. We denote all variables that are time varying during this
regime with a subscript t (e.g. ct is consumption). Variables which are
constant during this time interval are denoted with a superscript ¤.
Time Interval 3: T · t < T 0 : This is the interval of time after the new monetary

policy has been implemented but before the new level of transfers has been
adopted. We denote all variables that are constant during this time interval
with a lower bar.

Time Interval 4: t ¸ T 0 : This is the time interval after which the new transfer

policy is implemented. As with time interval 3, we represent all variables
that are constant during this interval with a lower bar.

3.3. Computing the Time of the Speculative Attack
In order to solve for the time of the speculative attack, we must compute the
model’s dynamic, perfect foresight equilibrium. In this section, we describe the
key equations that allow us to do this.
At time 0, when information about the new …scal de…cit arrives, the representative agent re-optimizes his consumption plan. The value of the Lagrange
~
multiplier associated with his intertemporal budget constraint jumps from ¸ to ¸.
The consumption optimization condition for time interval 1 is,
~
(¹)¡¾ = ¸(1 + r), for 0 < t < t¤ .
c

12

(3.3)

Since the government rebates the seignorage revenues in the form of lump sum
transfers, the present value of the resources available to the consumer does not
change with the arrival of new information at time zero. However, given that the
rate of in‡ation will no longer be constant, consumption at time 0 will, in general,
be di¤erent from c. The cash in advance constraint is binding, so the time 0 value
of real balances must also jump from m = c to m = c. Since Pt = S before t¤ the
¹
¹
change in real balances is accomplished by a change in the nominal money supply
¹
¹
from M to M , where M is given by:
¹
M = S¹:
c

(3.4)

The change in the money supply occurs as private agents adjust the amount
of domestic money, government debt and foreign reserves that they hold. For
¹
example if M > M; agents increase real balances by selling government bonds, bt ;
or foreign assets, dt for domestic money.
In the second time interval, the …rst order condition for consumption is:
_
Pt
~
c¡¾ = ¸(1 + r + ), for t¤ < t < T .
t
Pt

(3.5)

Since in‡ation jumps discretely at t¤ ; so does consumption. The path for St must
be continuous, so that Pt¤ = S: Otherwise, given our assumption of perfect foresight, there would be arbitrage opportunities associated with trading the currency
just before and after t¤ .
By assumption, net government debt at time t¤ rises to ª:
¹
¹
(M ¡ M ¤ )
M ¡ M rt¤ Z t¤
b ¡f = ª =
+ [b0 ¡ f0 +
]e +
(g + v ¡ ¿ )ert dt: (3.6)
S
S
0
t¤

t¤

The last two terms of this equation represent the accumulated government debt
¹
up to t¤. The term (M ¡ M )=S represents the jump in the value of the debt that
13

¹
takes place at time zero. The term (M ¡ M ¤ )=S represents the discrete, positive

increase in government debt that takes place at t¤ : This increase re‡ects the fact
that agents trade domestic money, at the exchange rate S; for either government
bonds or foreign assets.
Equations (3.3) and (3.5) together with the cash in advance constraint imply:
µ

¶

M ¤ ¡¾
c¡¾
¹
dPt 1
):
=
(1 + r +
Pt
1+r
dt Pt
This di¤erential equation in Pt can be written as:
dPt
= aPt1+¾ ¡ bPt;
dt
a = (M ¤)¡¾ (1 + r)¹¾ ;
c

(3.7)

(3.8)

b = (1 + r):
The solution to (3.8) is:

"

b
Pt =
a ¡ e(t¡°)¾b

#1=¾

(3.9)

:

Here ° is a constant of integration determined by the condition that Pt must be
continuous at t¤ . This requires that Pt¤ = S so (3.9) can be used to express ° as
a function of t¤ :

1
ln(a ¡ bS ¡¾ ):
(3.10)
¾b
Equation (3.9), the cash in advance constraint at time T , and the continuity of
° = t¤ ¡

the price level at T (required to prevent arbitrage opportunities) imply that:
PT = MT =c =

"

b
a ¡ e(T ¡°)¾b

#1=¾

:

(3.11)

The level of consumption in the third time interval, which we denote by c, is
determined by the condition:
~
c¡¾ = ¸(1 + r + ¹), for t ¸ T:
14

(3.12)

Solving equation (3.11) for ° and using equation (3.10) we …nd:
¡¾
1
a ¡ bPT
t =T ¡
ln
:
¾b a ¡ bS ¡¾
¤

(3.13)

The value of t¤ depends on the magnitude of the de…cit being …nanced (Á),
the monetary policy used to …nance it, and the debt threshold ª. Since the
government increases the money supply at time T , PT will, in general, be greater
than S: This suggests that t¤ < T; that is, the attack takes place before the
new monetary policy is implemented. In fact this is the case that arises in the
calibrated versions of our model economy. However, there are two other cases to
consider: t¤ = 0, and t¤ > T .12
The …rst case, t¤ = 0, arises when MT is large enough that the rate of in‡ation
at time zero is higher than ¹. The relatively high rate of in‡ation at time 0 induces
agents to lower their consumption thus creating a fall in money demand and a rise
in government debt. If the rise in debt is large enough to trigger the threshold rule
then a speculative attack occurs immediately. The exchange rate will, in general,
be discontinuous at time 0. See Subsection 4.3 for further discussion.
The second case, t¤ > T , occurs for large values of ª. The exchange rate
¹
is still …xed at T and the endogenous level of the money supply is equal to M.
With a constant money supply no seignorage revenues are collected at T: Even
though the government prints money and buys back government bonds, the money
supply remains una¤ected. This is because private agents reverse the e¤ects of
the open market operation by trading money for bonds. The money supply only
changes at t¤, at which point it drops to M ¤ = cS: Thereafter the growth rate
of the money supply and the rate of in‡ation are both equal to ¹: The time of
the speculative attack is determined by the requirement that the government’s
intertemporal budget constraint (2.8) holds.
12

Equation (3.13) is only valid when 0 < t¤ < T .

15

The …nal step in computing t¤ is to ensure that c is consistent with the house¹
hold’s budget constraint, (2.4) and that monetary policy raises su¢cient revenues
to balance the government’s budget constraint:13

b0 ¡ f0 =

¹
M ¡ M Z 1 ¡rt
+
e (¿ ¡ g ¡ vt )dt +
S
0
¹
M ¤ ¡ M ¡rt¤
e
+
ZS

+

1

T

(3.14)

e¡rt (¹c)dt + (c ¡ cT )e¡rT :

The term (c ¡ cT ) represents the adjustment in real balances that takes place at

time T in response to the discontinuous decline in in‡ation to its new level, ¹.

It is evident from (3.14) that there is a continuum of (MT ; ¹) combinations
that satisfy the government’s budget constraint. If we …x MT we can then solve
for the values of c and ¹ that simultaneously solve (2.4) and (3.2). Proceeding
¹
analogously we can …x ¹ and solve for c and MT . Since it is not possible to carry
¹
out these steps analytically we now turn to calibrated versions of the model.

4. Numerical Experiments
Here we study the determinants of speculative attacks in versions of our the model
that have been calibrated using Korean and Thai data.
4.1. Model Calibration
Table 1 summarizes the parameter values of our benchmark models. Throughout
we use 1996 as the baseline period for time series that are sampled at annual
RT
The seignorage collected between time t¤ and time T , t¤ e¡rt (mt + ¼t mt )dt was omitted
_
_
from this equation because it is equal to zero. This follows from the fact that Mt = 0 during
¤
this interval of time and from the cash in advance constraint, M = St ct .
13

16

frequencies. In addition we normalize both output and the time 0 exchange rate,
S; to be one.
Calibrating the Model Using Korea Data
We begin by discussing the debt and threshold rule parameters b0 ; f0 ; d0 ; Á;
and ª: The domestic and foreign debt levels of the public sector in our model were
calibrated using the consolidated debt levels of the Korean government and central
bank. The Korean Ministry of Finance (MOFE) reports that the level of total
government and public sector bonds outstanding at the end of December 1996
was equal to approximately 37:4 trillion won.14 According to the International
Financial Statistics (IFS) of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the Bank
of Korea held claims on the government equal to 2 trillion won as of the end of
December 1996. To avoid double counting, we subtracted this number from the
reported level of total government and public sector bonds. The IFS also reports
that the Bank of Korea had net domestic liabilities (excluding those vis-a-vis the
government, o¢cial entities and base money) of 4:7 trillion won. Based on this
evidence, we conclude that consolidated government domestic liabilities equaled
roughly 37:4¡2+4:7 = 40:1 trillion won, or 10:3 percent of 1996 GDP. Accordingly
we set b0 = 0:103.
The Korea Institute for International Economic Policy (KIEP) estimated that
the foreign debt of the public sector in June 1997 was equal to 2:0 trillion won.15
According to the IFS, the value of the central bank’s net foreign assets was approximately 28:0 trillion won. This suggests that the overall net foreign assets of
the consolidated public sector was equal to roughly 26:0 trillion won or 6:7 percent
of 1996 GDP. We set f0 = 0:067 and b0 ¡ f0 = 0:036. According to the Bank of
14
15

This data was obtained from MOFE’s World Wide Web site, http://www.mofe.go.kr/.
The data are published on the Web at http://kiep.go.kr.

17

Korea, the value of private sector net foreign debt at the end of 1996 was roughly
13:9 percent of GDP. Accordingly we set d0 = ¡0:139.

In Section 6 we argue that the value of non-performing loans relative to GDP

prior to the crisis was roughly 0.25. Taking this to be an estimate of the governments implicit liabilities to the …nancial sector we set Á = 0:25. Since there
is substantial uncertainty about this number we explore the sensitivity of our results to perturbations in Á. The benchmark value of ª was chosen to match the
increase in consolidated government liabilities that occurred in the period leading up to late October 1997 when the won …rst lost an unprecedented (by recent
standards) fraction of its value. Using data from KIEP and the IFS, we estimate
that net liabilities of the consolidated public sector rose to 5:3 percent of GDP as
of the end of September 1997. Accordingly we set ª = 0:053. Later we explore
the sensitivity of our results to perturbations in ª.
We now discuss how the benchmark value of ¿ was chosen. According to the
IMF World Economic Outlook, the ratio of government revenue to GDP in Korea
was roughly 22:0 percent in 1996. Since our model abstracts from investment and
from the trade balance, we subtract 27:8 percent from output to ensure that the
consumption to output ratio in the model matches the 1996 value in the data,
roughly 0:5.
We set the real interest rate, r, to the average ex-post real interest rate in Korea
for the period from January 1990 to April 1997, 7:45%. We chose the inverse of
the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, ¾; to be equal to 1:0. Finally, we
assume that the average world rate of in‡ation, ¼¤ ; is 4 percent. This corresponds
approximately to the average rate of in‡ation in the U.S. over the past 10 years. In
the theoretical model we assumed that ¼ ¤ = 0: Allowing for a positive value of ¼¤
means that the government will collect some revenue during the …xed exchange
rate regime. However, this does not change any of our conclusions since those
18

seignorage revenues have already been pledged to …nancing the old level of the
de…cit.
Calibrating the Model to Thai Data
According to the Bank of Thailand, total government domestic debt not held
by the central bank at the end of December 1996, was roughly 41.7 billion baht or
0.9 percent of GDP. We set b0 = 0:009.16 The Bank of Thailand estimated that
the foreign debt of the public sector in December 1996 was roughly equal to 430.2
billion baht. According to the IFS, net foreign assets of the Thai central bank
equaled 988.6 billion baht in December 1996. This suggests that the level of net
foreign assets of the consolidated public sector was equal to 558.4 billion baht or
12.1 percent of 1996 GDP. Thus, we set b0 ¡ f0 = ¡0:112. Using data from the

Bank of Thailand we estimate that net foreign debt of the private sector at the
end of 1996 was roughly 38:4 percent of GDP, so we set d0 = ¡0:384.17

In Section 6 we argue that a rough estimate of the …scal cost of the banking

bailout to be 30 percent of GDP, so we set Á = 0:3. The parameter ª was chosen
to match the decline in consolidated government assets that occurred in the period
leading up to the Thai crisis in July 1997. We estimate that during this period
(until the end of June 1997), net assets of the consolidated public sector fell to
7.5 percent of GDP. We set ª = ¡0:075.

According to the IMF World Economic Outlook, the ratio of government rev-

enue to GDP in Thailand was 18:9 percent in 1996. As in the Korean case, we
subtracted an additional 26:5 percent from output to ensure that the consump16

Bank of Thailand data was obtained from their World Wide Web site at
http://www.bot.or.th/.
17
This …gure was obtained by taking a standard measure of total gross external debt, subtracting public sector external debt, and then subtracting the foreign assets of the banking system.
As in the Korean case, these are the only private sector foreign assets for which information is
generally available.

19

tion to output ratio in the model equaled the 1996 value of that ratio in the data,
roughly 0:5:
We set the real interest rate, r, equal to the average ex-post real interest rate
in Thailand for the period from January 1990 to April 1997, 4:2%. The remaining
parameter values are the same as in the Korean calibration.
Table 1: Parameter
Parameter Korea
Y
1
S
1
b0
0.103
b0 ¡ f0
0.036
d0
-0.139
Á
.25
ª
.053
r=½
.0745
¿
.22

Values
Thailand
1
1
0.009
-.112
-0.384
.30
-.075
.0420
.19

¾

1

1

T
¼¤
¹
MT =M

3
.04
.08
1.10

3
.04
.065
1.10

Description
Real output
Time 0 exchange rate
Time 0 government domestic debt
Time 0 net government debt
Time 0 private net foreign assets
Present value of increase in de…cit
Upper limit on net government debt
Real interest rate
Lump sum taxes
Inverse elasticity of
intertemporal substitution
Time of monetary policy change
U.S. In‡ation Rate
Growth rate of Mt after T
Jump in Mt at T

4.2. Results
Since the two calibrated versions of the model display very similar dynamics, we
focus our discussion on the Korean case. Figure 1 depicts the dynamic equilibrium
paths of ct (which coincides with mt ), ¼t , Mt , bt ¡ ft and St (which coincides with
Pt) for the model calibrated to the Korean data. Two key features of Figure 1 are
worth noting. First, the speculative attack occurs at t¤ = 2:27, before the change
in monetary policy which occurs at T = 3: For the Thai case, t¤ = 2:42. Second,
in‡ation begins to increase at t¤ , well before the change in monetary policy. This
20

is reminiscent of classic results in Sargent and Wallace (1981) according to which
future monetary policy a¤ects current in‡ation.
We now turn to the behavior of consumption. In the benchmark model consumption increases discretely at time zero (not displayed in Figure 1) to a level
that is higher than both the old steady state (¹ > c) and the new steady state
c
reached after T (¹ > c). The fact that c > c results from two features of the
c
¹
equilibrium. First, since seignorage revenues are rebated to the household, the
present value of resources available to private agents is the same before and after
the increase in the government de…cit. Second, since in‡ation is at its lowest value
before t¤, the e¤ective price of consuming during time interval 1 is lower than in
all other periods. Figure 1 indicates that during time interval 2 consumption
declines. This re‡ects the rise in in‡ation relative to time interval 1. During time
intervals 3 and 4 consumption is constant because in‡ation is constant. Notice
that c > c because in‡ation is zero during time interval 1 but positive during time
¹
intervals 3 and 4.
Consider next the behavior of the money supply and government debt. In the
initial steady state, the level of the money supply is determined by the cash in
advance constraint c = M=S: At time 0; consumption jumps from c to c; while
¹
the exchange rate remains constant. It follows that the money supply must jump
¹
from M to M = S¹: Agents obtain the additional money needed for consumption
c
transactions by trading in foreign reserves or government bonds. Consequently,
government debt drops discontinuously at time 0 (not displayed in Figure 1). For
the remainder of time interval 1 all model variables remain constant except for
government debt which evolves according to:
#

"

Z t
¹
M ¡ M rt
bt ¡ ft = b0 ¡ f0 ¡
e + (g + v ¡ ¿ )ertdt:
S
0

(4.1)

At time t¤ there is a discontinuous decrease in consumption which re‡ects the
21

jump in in‡ation that occurs at the onset of the ‡oating exchange rate regime.
Since the exchange rate is still …xed at t¤ the cash in advance constraint implies
that the money supply falls discontinuously at the time of the attack. Agents
exchange domestic money for foreign reserves or government debt, raising total
government liabilities to ª. It is this decline in domestic money holdings that is
often described as a speculative attack.
At time T , the new monetary policy is implemented so that there is a policy
induced jump in MT after which the money supply grows at rate ¹. The government engineers the increase in MT by retiring government debt. Before the
new transfer policy is implemented at T 0 the government is actually running a
surplus, so that government debt is declining. After T 0 (not displayed) both the
government de…cit and the debt begin to increase.
4.3. Why Doesn’t the Attack Take Place At Time Zero?
A …xed exchange rate regime is a price …xing scheme. As long as the government
can borrow enough funds it can support a …xed price for its currency. So the key
determinants of t¤ are the government’s ability to borrow, which is determined by
its intertemporal budget constraint, its willingness to borrow, which is determined
by ª; and agent’s demand for domestic money. The latter demand is tied to
agents’ optimal consumption path. For a speculative attack to occur at time 0
there must be a large enough drop in c0 to trigger the threshold rule on debt.
Since the new monetary policy is only implemented at T; and in‡ation at time 0
is actually low relative to later periods, consumption does not typically drop at
t = 0. As noted above in the benchmark model it actually rises.
To provide further intuition about the relation between consumption and exchange rate dynamics, Figure 2 depicts the equilibrium of the model if the government maintains its choice of T , MT and ¹ but abandons …xed exchange rates
22

at time 0 while keeping the money supply at some value M0 until time T . Figure
2 corresponds to the case where M0 = M .18
The key feature to note is that here the exchange rate initially appreciates at
t = 0. This is because in‡ation is lower at time zero than in later time periods.
Since the e¤ective price of consumption is low relative to future periods, the initial
level of consumption rises relative to the old steady state. Since the money supply
is constant, the cash in advance constraint implies that S must fall, i.e. the
exchange rate appreciates. This illustrates the importance of the link between
consumption and money demand in determining exchange rate dynamics. An
attack will happen at time 0 only if consumption and real balances fall enough to
drive government debt to a value greater than or equal to ª.
4.4. Sensitivity Analysis
Table 2 describes the e¤ect of perturbations to the Korean benchmark parameter
values on the timing of a speculative attack and the present value of seignorage
revenues. Four key results emerge here. First, if the increase in the de…cit re‡ects
a rise in government purchases rather than an increase in transfers, then t¤ falls.
The reason for this is as follows. In the benchmark model, time 0 consumption
rises by 2 percent relative to its initial steady state level. Correspondingly, there
is an increase in the demand for money and a reduction in the government’s debt.
Other things equal, the reduction in b0 ¡f0 delays the time at which bt ¡ft reaches
its threshold level, ª: Because of the rise in future government purchases, the

household’s wealth declines relative to its initial steady state value. Consequently
time 0 consumption does not rise by as much as in the benchmark model. Now
c is roughly equal to the initial steady state level of consumption, c; and there
¹
¹
We also experimented with setting M0 = M , as well as chosing M0 so that the government’s
intertemporal budget constraint is satis…ed. These perturbations made very little di¤erence to
the results.
18

23

is no initial improvement in the government’s debt position. Other things equal,
this implies bt ¡ ft will reach ª more quickly than in the benchmark case. Note

that seignorage revenues also fall relative to the benchmark case. This occurs
primarily because the fall in the household’s wealth leads to a decline in c which

reduces the ‡ow of seignorage revenues (¹c) after T .
Table 2: Sensitivity Analysis
Present Value
t¤
Seignorage
Baseline
2:27 0:25
Constant transfers 1:60 0:24
¾=5
2:82 0:25
T = 10
9:44 0:16
ª = 0:10
2:64 0:25
MT =M = 2
1:10 0:40
¹ = 0:12
2:11 0:45
Second, a decrease in the elasticity of intertemporal substitution to 1/5 (¾ =
5) increases t¤ . This re‡ects a greater desire on the part of the household to
have a smooth consumption path. There is also a small decline in seignorage
revenues which results from a lower level of c: Third, a rise in T increases t¤ and
reduces the present value of seignorage revenues. The latter happens because
positive seignorage revenues are generated only when the new monetary policy is
implemented. Fourth, an increase in ª increases t¤ and reduces the present value
of seignorage revenues. The basic reason for the rise in t¤ is that it takes longer
for government debt to hit the threshold level associated with abandoning …xed
exchange rates. The impact on seignorage revenues is more subtle. Recall that no
seignorage revenues are collected between t¤ and T , i.e.

RT

t¤

e¡rt (mt + ¼t mt)dt = 0,
_

so that the increase in t¤ has no direct impact on the present value of seignorage
revenues. As it turns out, the decline in seignorage is caused by the fall in money
¹
demand, M ¡ M ¤; that occurs when the government debt jumps to its threshold
24

level ª at t¤ . The higher is ª; the larger is the decline in money demand and the
greater is the loss in seignorage revenue at t¤.19
A potential shortcoming of the experiments reported in Table 2 is that they
do not hold seignorage revenues constant. We now consider the results of experiments in which monetary policy is adjusted to ensure that the government’s
intertemporal budget constraint is satis…ed. Table 3 reports results when monetary policy is adjusted via changes in MT , while Table 4 corresponds to the case
in which ¹ is adjusted.
Consider …rst the results of perturbing the benchmark values of ¾ and T ,
as well as assuming that the rise in prospective de…cits re‡ects a rise in future
government purchases. Comparing Tables 2, 3 and 4 we see that very small
adjustments in monetary policy are necessary to compensate for the changes in
seignorage revenues associated with these perturbations of the benchmark model.
As a consequence the analogue values of t¤ in the three tables are very similar.
Next we consider how uncertainty about Á a¤ects the time of the speculative
attack. Table 3 presents results for Á = 0:1 and Á = 0:4. Note that the time of
the attack is relatively insensitive to Á; ranging from 2.08 to 2.39. In contrast ¹
ranges from 0.05821 to 0.1081. Table 4 presents results for Á = :23 and Á = 0:27.
We considered this narrow range of variation for Á because, in our model economy,
the government cannot raise more than 3 percent of GDP in seignorage through a
jump in the money supply at time T . Note that both t¤ and MT =M are relatively
sensitive to variations in Á: But it is still the case that the attack continues to
take place before T in all these experiments: t¤ ranges from a low of 2:06 to a
high of 2:58.
19

There are two o¤setting e¤ects associated with higher values of ª: (i) t¤ is increasing in ª
so that the loss of seignorage revenue at t¤ is discounted more heavily, and (ii) a higher value
of ª is associated with a larger jump in money demand at T: In our benchmark models, these
e¤ects are outweighed by the e¤ect discussed in the text.

25

Table 3: SensitivityAnalysis
(¹ adjusted to keep seignorage constant)
MT = 1:1; Seignorage = 0:25
t¤
¹
for all entries
Baseline
2:27 :0800
Transfers = 0
1:59 :0824
¾=5
2:82 :0801
T = 10
9:32 :1124
Á = :10
2:08 :0521
Á = :40
2:39 :1081

Table 4: SensitivityAnalysis
(MT adjusted to keep seignorage constant)
¹ = :08; Seignorage = :25
t¤
MT =M
for all entries
Baseline
2:27 1:10
Transfers = 0
1:43 1:14
¾=5
2:82 1:10
T = 10
8:33 2:13
Á = 0:23
2:58 1:04
Á = 0:27
2:06 1:16

We now study the sensitivity of our results to the threshold parameter ª.
Regardless of the particular threshold rule that the government adopts, its intertemporal budget constraint must hold. As discussed above, an increase in ª
reduces seignorage revenues. The government must compensate for the loss of
these revenues by either raising MT or ¹: Figure 3 depicts the time of the attack
and the adjustment in monetary policy as ª varies from 0:04 to 0:15. Panel A
pertains to the case where MT is …xed and the adjustment occurs via ¹. Panel
B refers to the case where ¹ is held …xed and the adjustment occurs via MT .
The key points to note are as follows. First, regardless of how monetary policy
is adjusted, t¤ is an increasing function of ª: Basically, this re‡ects the fact that
the government can delay the date of the speculative attack by borrowing more
resources. Second, both MT and ¹ are increasing functions of ª. It turns out
that as MT increases, the peak rate of in‡ation in time interval 2 also increases.
Consequently the cost of delaying the attack when monetary policy adjusts via
an increase in MT is higher in‡ation during the transition to the new steady state
of the economy. As ¹ increases, so too does the steady state rate of in‡ation.
We conclude that the price for delaying a speculative attack is a higher rate of
in‡ation in the future. This suggests that the key issue is not whether govern26

ments can borrow to fend o¤ speculative attacks, but whether they should. To
examine this issue we proceed in two steps. First, we brie‡y consider the equilibrium of our model when the only constraint faced by the government is (2.8), its
intertemporal budget constraint. In Section 5, we discuss the optimal policy for
the government to pursue.
4.5. The Present Value Rule
We now consider the equilibrium of the model when the government operates
under a present value rule, i.e. (2.8) is the only constraint that the government
faces. We proceed by asking the question: what is the maximal value of ª consistent with (2.8)? In one sense we have already answered this question. Given
the parameters of monetary policy (MT and ¹), there is a unique ª such that
(2.8) holds, so that the present value rule can always be described ex post as a
threshold rule on government debt.
Suppose that we …x one of the monetary policy parameters, say ¹: For every
value of MT there exists a value ª such that (2.8) holds. We can ask the question:
what is the value of MT that maximizes ª? For our benchmark case we obtain
roughly MT =M = 10.20 The associated values ª and t¤ are 0:48 and 2:91; respectively. Alternatively we could …x MT and seek the value of ¹ that maximizes ª.
We did not pursue this experiment because it yields extreme results in our model:
at the cost of hyperin‡ation the government could delay the attack for a very long
(but …nite) period of time. This is because the government can seize all private
wealth by generating su¢ciently high in‡ation. It’s ability to do so is an artifact
of two assumptions which we make in our model: the cash in advance constraint
applies only to consumption, and output is exogenous.
20

This is the value of ª that satis…es (2.8) when MT = 10M: Further increases in MT lead
to very small changes in ª.

27

We conclude by noting that Figure 3 and the results of this section convey a
common message: changes in the threshold rule, ª, do not a¤ect the inevitability
of the speculative attack, only its timing and how much monetary policy must
be adjusted to balance the government’s budget. A government can substantially
delay the collapse of a …xed exchange rate regime by borrowing but only at the
cost of higher future in‡ation. Because of this, it is not obvious that a government
should borrow to delay an attack, even if it can. We now address the question of
what monetary policy should the government pursue.

5. Optimal Monetary Policy
This section demonstrates that the optimal monetary policy in our economy is
to abandon the …xed exchange rate regime as soon as new information about the
de…cit arrives. The required seignorage revenues should be raised by an increase
in M0 and/or setting the growth rate of money to a constant, ¹. This monetary
policy succeeds in balancing the government’s intertemporal budget constraint
without inducing distortions into the economy.21 This result follows from three
features of our model: output is exogenous, the cash in advance constraint applies
only to consumption, and seignorage is rebated to the households.
To demonstrate the optimality of the proposed policy, suppose that the government could …nance the increase in the present value of the de…cit using lump
sum taxes. The equilibrium under this …nancing strategy cannot be improved
upon: the …xed exchange rate could be maintained and in‡ation would continue
to be zero. Note that since tax revenue are rebated lump sum to households,
consumption will remain at its initial steady state level, c.
We now prove the optimality of our candidate monetary policy by showing
that it supports the same allocation as that which obtains when the government
21

Rebelo and Xie (1998) prove an analogous result for a continuous time closed economy.

28

raises to lump sum taxes. Recall that the optimal behavior of consumption is
dictated by equation (2.6). It follows that if ¼t is constant, consumption will
also be constant. Since seignorage revenues are rebated to the household, the
intertemporal budget constraint is una¤ected and consumption will still equal c.
To …nance the increase in the present value of the de…cit it must be the case that:
Z 1
c
(M0 ¡ M) +
e¡rt(¼ t mt + mt )dt = Á:
_
M0
0

(5.1)

The …rst term represents seignorage collected from increasing the money supply
to M0 at time 0: The integral term re‡ects seignorage obtained from the future
growth rate of money. Relation (5.1) implies that M0 and ¹ must satisfy:
c
(M0 ¡ M ) + ¹c=r = Á:
M0
Since this is feasible, the proposed policy supports the optimal equilibrium allocation.
One important caveat to the preceding discussion is that it abstracts from
nominal rigidities in prices and wages as well as from non-indexed domestic debt
and unhedged loans denominated in foreign currency. These aspects can clearly
a¤ect optimal monetary policy and the optimal time to abandon …xed exchange
rates. The key point of the preceding discussion is to emphasize that there are
clear costs to delaying the adjustment of monetary policy. In our model, the
cost is the distortion of consumption decisions induced by the fact that lower
in‡ation now is purchased at the price of higher in‡ation in the future. The more
a government borrows to delay a speculative attack, i.e. the higher is ª; the
higher are these costs. In this sense, the ability to borrow from abroad to delay a
speculative attack actually reduces welfare.

29

6. Empirical Evidence
This section presents evidence to assess the empirical plausibility of our interpretation of the recent Asian currency crisis. Speci…cally, we o¤er evidence in
support of three key assumptions in our model: (i) foreign reserves do not play a
special role in the timing of the attack, (ii) large losses in the banking sector were
associated with increases in governments’ prospective de…cits, and (iii) the public
knew that banks were in trouble before the exchange rate crises.
Some Background Information
Figure 4 plots exchange rates of various Asian countries from July 1995 through
May 1998. To provide a frame of reference, vertical lines are drawn at what we
refer to as the crisis dates. These correspond to the …rst instance in which there
were historically large devaluations or depreciations of the currency in question.
Table 5 presents the cumulative depreciation rates of various Asian currencies
from the crisis dates to May 1998. It is evident that the experience of the crisis
countries was very di¤erent from that of the non-crisis countries (Hong Kong,
Singapore and Taiwan).

Table 5: Cumulative Depreciation Rates (May 1998)
Indonesia Malaysia Thailand Korea Philippines Hong Kong Singapore Taiwan
77%¤
35%¤
36%¤
34%¤¤ 32%¤
0%¤
12%¤¤¤
13%¤¤
¤
from July 97 ¤¤ from Oct. 97 ¤¤¤ from Aug 97
As further background, Table 6 presents the annual growth rate of real GDP,
the o¢cial CPI in‡ation rates and the …scal surpluses for the Asian countries,
Japan and the U.S, over the period 1995 - 1997. Note that there are no dramatic
di¤erences between the crisis and non-crisis countries. The crises certainly could
not have been predicted on the basis of large and/or growing pre crisis …scal de…cits
30

in the crisis countries. We refer the reader to Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998)
for a more comprehensive survey of the pre crisis situation in Asia.
Table 6

Real GDP Growth CPI In‡ation Rates Fiscal Surplus
% of GDP
1995 1996 1997 1995 1996 1997
1995 1996 1997
Indonesia
8.2
8.0
5.0
9.0
6.6
11.6
0.8
1.4
1.9
Korea
8.9
7.1
5.9
4.7
4.9
6.6
0.4
0.3
-0.5
Malaysia
9.5
8.6
7.3
3.2
3.3
2.9
3.8
4.2
2.8
Philippines 4.8
5.7
5.1
11.0 5.2
6.1
-1.4 -0.4 -1.0
Thailand
8.7
6.4
0.0
7.5
4.8
7.7
2.6
1.6
-1.1
Hong Kong 3.9
4.9
5.3
7.0
6.6
5.2
-0.3 2.2
3.8
Singapore
8.7
7.0
7.6
0.9
2.0
2.0
2.7
2.8
1.8
Taiwan
6.0
5.7
6.9
4.6
2.5
-0.5
0.4
0.2
0.2
Japan
1.5
3.9
0.9
-0.1 0.1
1.7
-3.6 -1.1 -0.2
USA
2.0
2.8
3.8
2.8
2.9
2.3
-1.9 -1.1 -0.2
Foreign Reserves
Recall that in our model, foreign reserves do not play a special role in the decision to abandon …xed exchange rates. Whether they are high or low is irrelevant
because they are already pledged to …nancing the old level of the de…cit. An attack is inevitable once prospective de…cits rise, regardless of the level of reserves.
Moreover, the timing of the attack does not depend on the level of reserves: it
depends on the government’s threshold rule for overall debt. To help assess how
reasonable these implications are, Figure 5 displays the ratio of foreign reserves
to the monetary base and M1 in the crisis countries over the period July 1995
- May 1998. Two key facts emerge here. First, all of these countries had more
than enough reserves to buy back the monetary base at the time their currencies
collapsed. In fact, in all cases, they could have bought back over 90 percent of
M1. Thailand’s reserves were actually twice as large as M1 at the time of the
collapse. Based on this evidence, we conclude that the level of foreign reserves
31

did not play a critical role in the Asian currency crisis.22
The Size of the Government’s Implicit Liabilities
We now discuss the impact of the banking crises on the governments’ potential
liabilities. We proceed in two steps. First, we provide evidence based on estimates
of loan default rates prior to the crises. Second, we discuss the size of government
outlays in Korea, Thailand, Indonesia and Malaysia associated with e¤orts to
reorganize their …nancial sectors.
Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998) provide estimates on loan default rates
in Asia prior to the crises. These are summarized in the …rst columns of Tables 7
and 8. Note the sharp di¤erence between default rates in the crisis and non-crisis
countries. In the former they range from a low of 14 percent in the Philippines
to a high of 19 percent in Thailand. In all of the non-crisis countries the ratio of
non-performing loans to total loans is roughly 4 percent. Using these default rates
and data on total credit to domestic enterprises and …nancial institutions, we can
generate a rough estimate of the government’s total implicit liabilities stemming
from guarantees to the …nancial sector.23
Columns 2, 3 and 4 of Table 7 report total non-performing bank loans as
a percentage of the monetary base, real output and central government revenue,
respectively. Table 8 reports the analogue percentages for the liabilities associated
with non-bank foreign borrowing. Note that regardless of which measure we use,
Korea and Thailand exhibit high levels of total implicit liabilities. For example, in
Korea, the ratio of total non-performing loans to real GDP (obtained by summing
22

The observation that many countries abandoned …xed exchange rates even though they had
enough reserves to cover the Monetary Base (Obstfeld and Rogo¤ (1998)) is also consistent with
multiple equilibrium theories of exchange rate collapses (see Obstfeld (1996)).
23
Our data on domestic lending are from the IMF International Financial Statistics. We have
attempted, as best as possible, to net out lending from one type of …nancial institution to another
(for example, lending by a deposit money bank to some other type of …nancial intermediary).

32

the entries in the …fth columns of Table 7 and Table 8) is roughly 25 percent. This
is the number we used to calibrate our model. In the case of Thailand, this ratio
equals 30 percent.
Table 7: Estimated Total Non-Performing Bank Loans
Estimate of Non-Performing
Credit
Credit to
NonDomestic
% of
% of
1997
Perform.
Enterprises
% of
1997
Central
Loans
and
MB
(% of
Financial
GDP**
Gov.
all loans)
Institutions*
Revenues**
(6/97)
Indonesia
17
343
129.6
9.4
63.0
Korea
16
589
454.1
22.1
103.7
Malaysia
16
403
88.8
23.3
98.3
Philippines 14
1365
84.5
7.8
41.1
Thailand
19
7912
289.6
30.2
176.7
Hong Kong 4
2223
91.6
6.6
33.6
Singapore
4
160
35.0
4.4
11.8
Taiwan
4
12157
26.8
6.0
50.0
*For Indonesia and Korea, expressed in trillions of local currency units.
For the others, in billions of local currency units
**Estimates.

33

Table 8: Estimated Liabilities from Non-bank Foreign Borrowing
Estimate of Non-Performing
Credit
Non-bank
NonPrivate
% of
Perform.
Sector
% of
1997
% of
Loans
Borrowing
1997
Central
MB
Gov.
(% of
from
GDP**
all loans)
Abroad*
Revenues**
(6/97)
Indonesia
17
92
34.6
2.5
16.8
Korea
16
23
18.0
0.9
4.1
Malaysia
16
19
4.1
1.1
4.5
Philippines 14
134
8.3
0.8
4.0
Thailand
19
343
12.6
1.3
7.7
Hong Kong 4
198
8.2
0.6
3.0
Singapore
4
12
2.6
0.3
0.9
Taiwan
4
88
0.2
0.0
0.4
*For Indonesia and Korea, expressed in trillions of local currency units.
For the others, in billions of local currency units.
**Estimates.

The previous two tables summarize information on default rates and implicit
liabilities prior to the currency crisis. J.P.Morgan (1998) has estimated nonperforming loans as a percentage of total loans and GDP in Indonesia, Korea,
Malaysia and Thailand, as of June 1998. In addition they provide estimates of
the amount of capital, as a percent of GDP, needed to restore bank capital to
the 8% Bank of International Settlement’s Capital Adequacy Requirement level.
Their estimates assume 60% recovery rates on non-performing loans and no losses
to depositors. This information is contained in Table 9.

34

Table 9: Post-crisis Estimates of Non-Performing
Loans and Recapitalization Requirements
Indonesia Korea Malaysia
Non-performing Loans
50
30
25
(Percent of Total Loans)
Non-performing Loans
37.5
49.5
41.25
(Percent of GDP)
Recapitalization Need¤
30
30
22
(Percent of GDP)

Thailand
30
30
30

Comparing Tables 7 and 8 with Table 9, we see a dramatic increase in the
magnitude of non-performing loans relative to the pre-crisis estimates. From the
perspective of our theory the post crisis estimates are at least as relevant as
the pre crisis estimates, since these are tied to the current liabilities of the crisis
governments. Notice also that, with the exception of Malaysia, the recapitalization
needs as a percentage of GDP all exceed our benchmark value of Á.
There are a variety of ways in which the crisis governments could …nance their
implicit liabilities to the banking sector. For example, they could, in principle, cut
government spending or raise taxes. It is important then to consider the actual
programs which governments are setting up to deal with their banking crises. To
date, these plans do not involve large …scal adjustments. Indeed as of July 1998,
J.P. Morgan (1998, page 12) conclude that the crisis governments have little room
left to cut spending or raise taxes.
With this in mind, we now discuss brie‡y aspects of the …nancial restructuring programs in a subset of the crisis countries. Our most detailed information
pertains to Korea. As of May 1998, Korea announced a program involving a total
…scal outlay of 49 trillion won to achieve three goals: (i) purchase 25 trillion won
in bad loans from troubled …nancial institutions, (ii) recapitalize …nancial companies by 15 trillion won; and (iii) bolster their deposit-insurance fund by about

35

9 trillion won.24 Combined with the 7.5 trillion won already spent by the Korea
Asset Management Corporation (KAMC) on bad loans and the 3 trillion won
already allocated for the recapitalization of Korea First Bank and Seoul Bank,
this represents a total …scal cost of 60.5 trillion won or about 13 percent of the
budget estimate of GDP in 1998. This is a …scal cost of more than two and a
half times the size of the monetary base.25 To raise funds for these programs
the Korea Asset Management Fund and the Deposit Insurance Fund will issue
government backed bonds, the interest on which will be paid by the government.
Interest costs through 1999 alone are estimated to total just over 20 trillion won.
Details are more sketchy regarding Thailand where the government has launched
a process of …nancial sector recapitalization under the auspices of two newly created agencies, the Radhanasin Bank and the Asset Management Corporation. The
cost of this program has been estimated by Standard and Poor’s to be roughly 1
trillion baht, or about 21 percent of estimated GDP in 1998.26
In Malaysia, the bank restructuring agency, the Pengurusan Danaharta Nasional Berhad, was initially capitalized with roughly 6 billion dollars, which equals
5 percent of 1997 real GDP.27 Finally, the Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency,
which is supervising the reorganization of the …nancial sector in Indonesia, has
already spent eleven billion dollars which represents over 6 percent of 1997 GDP.28
Based on this, we conclude that the crisis governments are actively involved in
restructuring their …nancial sectors in ways that involve substantial resource outlays. This is consistent with the conclusion reached by J.P. Morgan (1998, page
24

Wall Street Journal, May 21, 1998.
The bailout program is designed to force existing equityholders to bear a great deal of the
losses associated with bad loans, since these loans will be valued at 50 percent of their book
value, and not all of them will be purchased by the KAMC. This will force shareholders to write
down the value of their capital.
26
Reported in The Nation, 24 April 1998.
27
Wall Street Journal, 12 August, 1998.
28
Wall Street Journal, 12 August, 1998.
25

36

12), that “... the burden of absorbing banks’ bad loans will increasingly fall on
governments. To some extent, this has already happened in countries where the
central bank’s lender of last resort activities have e¤ectively put the government
in control of a large number of banks - notably in Indonesia, Korea and Thailand.”
We now present evidence on the role that central banks played in supporting
…nancial institutions after the currency crises. Figure 6 displays central bank
credit to deposit money banks, expressed as a ratio of the monetary base, from
1995 on. With the exception of the Philippines, this ratio increased dramatically
after the crises. For example, in Korea the ratio climbed from roughly one to 3
and half times the base, while in Thailand it increased from less than 10 percent to
roughly 50 percent of the base. We do not have detailed information on how these
loans were backed. But presumably, if the quality of the assets of these banks had
been high, there would have been no banking crisis to start with and no need for
central bank lending. This observation suggests that these loans represent, to a
large extent, subsidies to the …nancial sector.
Were the Banking Crises a Surprise?
We now consider whether private agents anticipated the state of the banking
system prior to the currency crises. Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998) discuss
the fragile state of the …nancial sectors in the crisis countries prior to the recent
speculative attacks. In addition they provide several example of bank failures and
reorganizations that occurred prior to the crises.
While their discussion is very informative, it leaves open the question of how
markets aggregated the information contained in the episodes that Corsetti, Pesenti and Roubini (1998) discuss. To investigate this issue we obtained daily
data on stock market indices of the value of the banking or …nancial sectors and
the industrial or commercial sectors in the crisis countries. We then constructed
37

monthly indices of the market value of the …nancial sectors in these countries as
well indices of non…nancial sectors.29 These are presented in Figure 7 and summarized in Table 10. Note that in Korea, Thailand and to a lesser extent the
Philippines and Malaysia, the value of the …nancial sectors had been declining
well before the currency crises.

Table 10: Changes in Banking Sector Stock Market Values
% Decline
Banking Index
Korea
Aug. 3, 1991 Oct. 29, 1997 67%
Thailand
Jan. 4, 1994 July 2, 1997
92%
Philippines Feb. 17, 1997 July 11, 1997 34%
Malaysia
Feb.25, 1997 July 11, 1997 26%
Peak

Crisis

% Decline

Banking Index
Manufacturing Index

64%
80%
14%
8%

For Korea the decline in the banking index from its peak (August 3, 1991) to
the date of the currency crisis (October 29, 1997) was 67 percent. The analogue
decline in the ratio of the banking index to the manufacturing index was 64
percent. In the case of Thailand the decline in the …nance index from its peak
(January 4, 1994) to the date of the crisis (July 2, 1997) was 92 percent. The
analogue decline in the ratio of the …nance index to the commerce index was 80
percent. In the Philippines, the peak in the …nance index took place on February
17, 1997. This series declined by 34 percent between this date and the date at
which their currency crisis began in earnest (July 11, 1997). The peak to trough
decline in the ratio of the …nance index to the commerce index was 14 percent.
Finally for Malaysia the peak in the …nance index took place on February 25,
29

We used the following Bloomberg series to construct our monthly banking/…nancial sector indices: Indonesia-JAKFIN, Korea-KOSPBANK, Malaysia-KLFIN, Philippines-PFINC,
Thailand-SETFIN, Hong Kong-AOF, Singapore-SESFIN, Taiwan Province-TWSEBKI. The
Bloomberg series used to construct monthly industrial or commercial sector indices were:
Indonesia-JAKMANU, Korea-KOSPMAN, Malaysia-KLPRO, Philippines-PCOM, ThailandSETCOM, Hong Kong-AON, Singapore-SESIND, Taiwan Province-TWSESTEE.

38

1997. This series declined 26 percent between this date and the date of the crisis
(July 11, 1997). The peak to trough decline in the ratio of the …nance index to
the industrial index was 8 percent.
Based on this evidence we conclude that private agents in these four countries
understood the potentially fragile nature of their banking systems. This also suggests that markets anticipated that the government would bail out only depositors
and creditors of the banks. Had they anticipated that the banks would be fully
insured by the government, the equity value of banks would not have changed,
other things being equal.
Finally we note that examining nominal interest rate movements prior to the
crises could be useful for assessing private agent’s expectations about the timing
of the speculative attack. Our model predicts that nominal yields on bonds of
maturity greater than t¤ ought to rise once agents receive information about the
increase in prospective de…cits. In future work, we intend to pursue this avenue
of research.30 In so doing, we face three serious problems: (i) as far as we can tell,
the available data pertain primarily to short term loans, typically of duration less
than one year, (ii) there was active government intervention in the crisis countries
aimed at a¤ecting short term interest rates, and (iii) there were capital controls
in some of these countries, e.g. Korea. Finally, it seems important to enrich
our model (see below) before formally investigating its detailed implications for
nominal interest rates.
30

Cline and Barnes (1997) analyze trends in spreads on U.S. dollar denominated Eurobonds.
They conclude that these spreads fell in emerging markets, including Southeast Asia, between
mid-1995 and mid-1997. While useful this information does not bear directly on the issues raised
in this paper. Since the bonds in question are dollar denominated, the spreads re‡ect default
risk rather than expected depreciation. Similar comments apply to Park and Rhee’s (1998)
analysis of the yield spread on Korean Development Bank global bonds.

39

7. Conclusions
This paper focused on the role played by large prospective de…cits in the Asian
currency crisis. Our basic argument is simple: absent the political will to raise
taxes or cut spending, governments have to resort to seignorage revenues to pay
for the bailout of the banking system. In a world of forward looking agents this
makes a currency crisis inevitable. In versions of our model calibrated to the
Korean and Thai economies, the collapse of the …xed exchange rate happens after
agents learn that future de…cits will rise but before the government implements
its new monetary policy. Under this scenario standard macroeconomic aggregates
such as past in‡ation and …scal de…cits are not useful in predicting currency crises.
In this limited sense our model rationalizes claims that the Asian crises were hard
to predict.
Our model suggests that we focus our empirical analysis on information useful
for forecasting prospective de…cits. This is why we studied the state of the Asian
banking system prior to the crisis. We found evidence consistent with the view
that agents knew that banks were in trouble before the crisis and that the size of
the …nancial sector bailout would be large. This evidence does not rule out the
possibility that the Asian currency crises were multiple equilibrium phenomena.
But it does suggest a simple explanation based on fundamentals.
We conclude by highlighting some important shortcomings of our analysis.
First, in our model the state of the banking system is costlessly revealed to agents
at a particular point in time. In reality, obtaining this information took time
and resources. Moreover, information about banking problems in one country
may have conveyed information about banking systems in other countries. We
suspect that understanding the precise timing and sequencing of currency attacks
will require an analysis of these information dynamics. Second, we modeled the

40

decision of when to abandon …xed exchange rates with a simple threshold rule on
government debt. In practice this decision is shaped by political considerations.
Modeling these political aspects is likely to lead to insights regarding the timing of
speculative attacks. Third, to isolate the role of prospective de…cits we abstracted
from nominal rigidities. These rigidities will almost surely have an impact on the
nature of optimal monetary policy. Finally, we did not address the issue of how
the collapse of …nancial intermediaries a¤ects future output and tax revenues. We
took as given that in the state of the world where banks collapsed, governments
would …nd it di¢cult to raise tax revenues. In future work we intend to study in
detail the role played by the …nancial sector in generating the persistent recessions
that are often associated with currency collapses.

41

References
[1] Calvo, Guillermo ‘Balance of Payments Crises in a Cash-in-Advance Economy,’ Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 19, 19-32, 1987.
[2] Calvo, Guillermo and Carlos Végh ‘In‡ation Stabilization and BOP Crises
in Developing Countries,’ forthcoming John Taylor and Michael Woodford
(eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics, North-Holland, 1998.
[3] Cline, William and Kevin Barnes ‘Spreads and Risk in Emerging Markets
Lending,’ Institute of International Finance Working Paper No. 97-1, 1997.
[4] Corsetti, Giancarlo, Paolo Pesenti and Nouriel Roubini ‘What Caused the
Asian Currency and Financial Crisis?,’ Working Paper, New York University,
1998.
[5] Corsetti, Giancarlo, Paolo Pesenti and Nouriel Roubini ‘Paper Tigers? A
Model of the Asian Currency Crisis?,’ Working Paper, New York University,
1998a.
[6] Drazen, Allan and Elhanan Helpman ‘Stabilization with Exchange Rate Management Under Uncertainty,’ in E. Helpman, A. Razin, and E. Sadka, Economic E¤ects of the Government Budget, MIT Press, 1988.
[7] Drazen, Allan and Elhanan Helpman ‘Stabilization with Exchange Rate Management,’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 835-855, 1987.
[8] Flood, Robert and Peter Garber ‘Collapsing Exchange Rate Regimes: Some
Linear Examples,” Journal of International Economics, 17, 1-13, 1984.
[9] J. P. Morgan ‘Asian Financial Markets, Third Quarter 1998,’ July 17, 1998.

42

[10] Kaminsky, Graciela, Saul Lizondo, and Carmen Reinhart ‘Leading Indicators of Currency Crises,’ Working Paper, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, 1996.
[11] Krugman, Paul ‘A Model of Balance of Payments Crises,’ Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 11, 311-25, 1979.
[12] Obstfeld, Maurice ‘Rational and Self-Ful…lling Balance-of-Payments Crises,’
American Economic Review, 76, 72-81, 1986a.
[13] Obstfeld, Maurice “The Logic of Currency Crises,” Banque de France–
Cahiers Économiques et Monétaires, 43, 189-213, 1994.
[14] Obstfeld, Maurice ‘Speculative Attack and the External Constraint in a Maximizing Model of the Balance of Payments,’ Canadian Journal of Economics,
29, 1-20, 1986b.
[15] Obstfeld, Maurice ‘Models of Currency Crises with Self-Ful…lling Features,’
European Economic Review, 40, 1037-48, 1996.
[16] Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogo¤ ‘The Mirage of Fixed Exchange
Rates,’ Journal of Economics Perspectives, 9, 73-96, 1995.
[17] Park, Daekeun and Changyong Rhee ‘Currency Crisis in Korea: Could It
Have Been Avoided?’ Working Paper, Seoul National University, 1998.
[18] Radelet, Steven and Je¤rey Sachs ‘The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crisis,’ Working Paper, Harvard Institute for International Development, 1998.
[19] Rebelo, Sergio and Danyang Xie ‘On the Optimality of Interest Rate Smoothing,’ forthcoming Journal of Monetary Economics, 1998.

43

[20] Sachs, Je¤rey, Aaron Tornell and Andres Velasco ‘Financial Crises in Emerging Markets: The Lessons from 1995,’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 147-215, 1996.
[21] Sargent, Thomas and Neil Wallace ‘Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic,’
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 5, 1-17, 1981.
[22] Wijnbergen, Sweder Van ‘Fiscal De…cits, Exchange Rate Crises and In‡ation,’ Review of Economic Studies, 58, 81-92, 1991.

44

8. Appendix
The problem of the representative household is to maximize (2.2) subject to (2.3)
- (2.5) by choice of time paths for ct ; mt ; bt and dt ; given a known time path for
¼ t. The current-valued Hamiltonian associated with this problem is:
H =

c1¡¾ ¡ 1
t
+ ¸t [y + r(bt + dt ) + v ¡ ct ¡ ¿ ¡ ¼t mt ¡ zt ] +
1¡¾
µt zt + ! t (mt ¡ ct)

where zt = mt .
_
The …rst order conditions to the problem are given by:

c¡¾ = ¸t + ! t ;
t
¸t = µ t ;
_
¸t = (½ ¡ r)¸t = 0;

_
µ t = µ t ½ + ¸t ¼ t ¡ ! t :

These equations imply (2.6) in the main text.

45

Figure 1: Response to News about an Increase in Prospective
Deficits

Consumption, Real Balances

Inflation
0.25
0.2

0.5
0.15
0.1
0.45

0.05
0
2

2.5

3
time

3.5

4

2

2.5

Net Government Debt, Money Supply

3
time

3.5

4

3.5

4

Exchange Rate

0.6

1.15

0.4
1.1
0.2
1.05
0

-0.2

1
2

2.5

3
time

3.5

4

2

2.5

3
time

Figure 2: Reverting To Floating Exchange Rates at Time 0

Consumption, Real Balances

Inflation

0.54

0.2

0.52

0.15

0.5
0.1
0.48
0.05

0.46
0.44

0
0

1

2
time

3

4

0

1

Money Supply

2
time

3

4

3

4

Exchange Rate

0.58

1.2
1.15

0.56

1.1
0.54
1.05
0.52

1

0.5

0.95
0

1

2
time

3

4

0

1

2
time

Figure 3a: Effects of Varying Threshold Rule Parameter Ψ on the
Time of the Attack
µ Adjusted to Satisfy the Government’s Present Value Constraint

Growth Rate of Money

Time of the Attack

0.042

2.8

0.0415

2.6

0.041
2.4
0.0405
2.2

0.04
0.0395
0

0.05

0.1
Ψ

0.15

0.2

2

0

0.05

0.1
Ψ

0.15

0.2

Figure 3b: Effects of Varying Threshold Rule Parameter Ψ on the
Time of the Attack

MT Adjusted to Satisfy the Government’s Present Value Constraint

MT/M

Time of the Attack
2.8

1.14
2.6

1.12

2.4

2.2
1.1
0

0.05

0.1
Ψ

0.15

0.2

2

0

0.05

0.1
Ψ

0.15

0.2

Figure 4
Nominal Exchange Rates Versus the U.S. Dollar
Indonesia

Korea

100
Jun 97=100

120

100
80
60

80
60

Malaysia

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

100
Jun 97=100

80
60

80
60

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

20
1996
JUL

20
1996
JAN

40

1995
JUL

40

1996
JAN

Hong Kong

Thailand
120

100

100
Jun 97=100

120

80
60

80
60

Singapore

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

JAN

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

20
1996
JAN

40

20
1995
JUL

40

Taiwan Province of China
120

100

100
Jun 97=100

120

80
60

80
60

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JAN

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

20

1996
JAN

40

20
1995
JUL

40

1996
JUL

Jun 97=100

120

100

Jun 97=100

1997
JAN

The Philippines

120

Jun 97=100

1996
JUL

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

20
1996
JUL

20
1996
JAN

40

1995
JUL

40

1996
JAN

Jun 97=100

120

Each point represents a value, at the end of a month, of 100×S6/97/St where St is the
number of local currency units per U.S. dollar at date t. Vertical lines represents crisis
dates determined by the first month in which a large depreciation occurred. Source: IFS.

Figure 5
Foreign Reserves Relative to Monetary Aggregates
Korea

Indonesia

Malaysia

Singapore

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1997
JAN

Hong Kong

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
1996
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

Taiwan Province of China

9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JAN

1995
JUL

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
1996
JUL

1995
JUL

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0

Thailand

1995
JUL

1997
JAN

The Philippines

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0

1995
JUL

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

1995
JUL

1995
JUL

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0

4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0

The solid line represents the ratio of foreign reserves to the monetary base. The dotted
line represents the ratio of foreign reserves to M1. Note the different vertical scale used
for Hong Kong and Singapore for better visibility. Source: IFS.

Figure 6
Central Bank Credit Extended to Banks Relative to Base Money
Indonesia

Korea

Malaysia

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

0.0
1996
JUL

0.0

1996
JAN

0.8
1995
JUL

1.6

0.2
1998
JAN

0.4

1997
JUL

2.4

1997
JAN

3.2

0.6

1996
JUL

0.8

1996
JAN

4.0

1995
JUL

1.0

The Philippines

Thailand

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

1996
JAN

1995
JUL

0.0

1998
JAN

0.2

0.0
1997
JUL

0.4

0.2
1997
JAN

0.6

0.4

1996
JUL

0.8

0.6

1996
JAN

1.0

0.8

1995
JUL

1.0

Taiwan Province of China

1998
JAN

1997
JUL

1997
JAN

1996
JUL

0.0
1996
JAN

0.0

1995
JUL

0.2
1998
JAN

0.4

0.2
1997
JUL

0.4

1997
JAN

0.6

1996
JUL

0.8

0.6

1996
JAN

1.0

0.8

1995
JUL

1.0

Each graph plots the value of credit extended by the central bank to commercial banks
relative to the monetary base. Source: IFS except for Malaysia, for which the source is
Bank Negara Malaysia.

Singapore

40

20

0
Jan-97

Jul-98

60

Jul-98

80
Jan-98

100

Dec-97

120
Jul-97

Taiwan Province of China

Jun-97

0

Dec-96

200

Jul-96

400

Jul-96

600

Jan-96

800

Dec-95

1200

Jul-95

Thailand

Jul-95

1400

Jan-95

Jul-98

Jan-98

Jul-97

Jan-97

Jul-96

Jan-96

Jul-95

Jan-95

0
Jul-98

Feb-98

Jul-97

Jan-97

Jul-96

Jan-96

Jul-95

Jan-95

Jul-94

Jul-93
Jan-94

Jan-93

Jul-92

Jan-92

Jul-91

Jan-91

Jul-98

Feb-98

Aug-97

Feb-97

Aug-96

Feb-96

Sep-95

Mar-95

Sep-94

Mar-94

June 97=100

Indonesia

Dec-94

40

Jul-94

60

Jan-94

Malaysia

Jul-94

120

100

Jan-94

140

120

Jul-93

140

100

June 97=100

80

Jan-93

Jul-98

Jan-98

Jul-97

Jan-97

Jul-96

Jan-96

Jul-95

Dec-94

50

0

Jun-94

0

Jul-94

40

Jul-93

20

0
Dec-93

20

Jul-93

60

Jul-93

20

Jul-93

Jan-93

June 97=100
80

Jan-93

1000

June 97=100

Jan-93

June 97=100

300

100

Dec-93

160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0

June 97=100

Jul-98

Jan-98

Jul-97

Jan-97

Jul-96

Jan-96

Jul-95

Jan-95

Jul-94

Jan-94

Jul-93

Jan-93

June 97=100
120

Jan-93

Jul-98

Jan-98

Jan-97

Jul-96

Jan-96

Jul-95

Dec-94

Jul-94

Dec-93

Jul-93

Jan-93

June 97=100

Figure 7
Stock Market Indices and Crisis Dates
Korea

250

200

150

100

Philippines

80

60

40

180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0

Hong Kong

The thin line represents the level of the stock market index for the finance sector (banking
for Korea). The thick line represents the level of this index relative to a stock market
index for the industrial (Hong Kong, Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore), manufacturing
(Korea), commerce (Philippines, Thailand) or steel (Taiwan) sector. The vertical lines
represent crisis dates for each country. Source: Bloomberg. Note the different horizontal
scale for Korea for illustrative purposes.