View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Product Market Evidence on the
Employment Effects of the Minimum
Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

REVISED April 4, 2006
WP 2003-17

Product Market Evidence on the Employment
Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French∗
April 4, 2006

Abstract
We infer the employment response to a minimum wage change by calibrating a model
of employment for the restaurant industry. Whereas perfect competition implies employment falls and prices rise after a minimum wage increase, the monopsony model potentially implies the opposite. We show that estimated price responses are consistent with
the competitive model. We place fairly tight bounds on the employment response, with
the most plausible parameter values suggesting a 10 percent increase in the minimum
wage lowers low skill employment by 2 to 4 percent and total restaurant employment by
1 to 3 percent.

∗

Authors’ affiliation is Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. We thank Derek Neal for suggesting that we write
this paper; Gadi Barlevy, Jeff Campbell, John Kennan, Mike Kouparitsas, Lynn Riggs, Dan Sullivan, Ted To,
and Marcello Veracierto for useful comments; and Kate Godwin and Tina Lam for outstanding research
assistance. Author correspondence to Daniel Aaronson or Eric French, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 230
S. LaSalle St., Chicago, IL 60604 or email at daaronson@frbchi.org or efrench@frbchi.org.

1

1

Introduction

Until the early 1990s, the consensus was that an increase in the minimum wage causes a
small but statistically and economically significant loss in employment (e.g. Brown, Gilroy,
and Kohen (1982)). While it was known that this need not be the case if firms have wagesetting power (Stigler (1946)), the empirical results confirmed the qualitative predictions of
standard models of perfect competition, which most researchers suspected were relevant for
industries which primarily employed minimum wage workers.
However, Card and Krueger’s work in the early 1990s spawned a contentious debate over
the magnitude, and perhaps even the sign, of the employment response. In a series of papers, they find no or, in some cases, a small positive employment response to an increase in
the minimum wage.1 Moreover, they discuss a number of other facts that may be inconsistent with competitive markets but consistent with monopsony power, including a spike in
the distribution of wages at the minimum and the prevalence of posted vacancies. Recent
theoretical developments have been able to generate monopsony-like employment responses
after minimum wage increases by introducing labor market search with frictions (Burdett
and Mortensen (1998)), efficiency wages (Rebitzer and Taylor (1995), Manning (1995)), or
monopsonistic competition with free entry (Bhaskar and To (1999)).
This work has not gone unchallenged, as exemplified by the discussions in Card and
Krueger (2000) and Neumark and Wascher (2000). The latter authors, again in a series of
papers (e.g. Neumark and Wascher (1996) for a review), consistently find an effect more in
line with the Brown et al. (1982) literature review; a 10 percent increase in the minimum
wage leads to roughly a 2 percent decrease in teen employment.2 Others, including Deere,
Murphy, and Welch (1995), Kim and Taylor (1995), and Burkhauser, Couch, and Wittenburg
(2000), find even larger negative effects, on the order of 2 to 6 percent. This confusion is
particularly acute since the majority of these papers use the same sources of variation to
1
See Card and Krueger (1995) for a review. A sampling of other papers that corroborate these findings
include Wellington (1991), Machin and Manning (1996, 1997), and Dickens, Machin, and Manning (1999).
See Neumark and Wascher (2003) for a long list of international studies, many of which find no employment
response.
2
These results are consistent with views reported in a survey of leading labor economists (Fuchs, Krueger,
and Poterba 1998). However, a full quarter of respondents believe there is no teenage disemployment effect
from a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage, and another quarter judge the response to be 3 percent or
higher.

2

identify the employment elasticity (albeit often from different time periods or geographic
areas): either the cross-sectional or time series co-movement of teenage employment and the
minimum wage.
Many of these papers claim to be testing the market structure of low wage labor markets
without explicitly showing what the competitive and monopsonistic models imply. In this
paper, we do just that. Using data from the restaurant industry, we calibrate a model
of employment determination to infer employment and price responses to a change in the
minimum wage implied by the two market structures.
We initially calculate the responses assuming restaurants are price-takers in both the factor and product markets.3 Several pieces of information are supplied to the model, including
factor costs, the intensity of usage of low-wage workers, the elasticity of substitution between
factors, the elasticity of labor supply, and the elasticity of product demand. The model predicts that a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage reduces low skill restaurant industry
employment by roughly 2.5 to 4 percent and total restaurant employment by 1.5 to 3 percent
under perfect competition. A second implication of perfect competition is that higher labor
costs are pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices.
Next, we augment the model so employers potentially have monopsony power in the
labor market. Under monopsony, employment potentially rises in response to an increase in
the minimum wage. An implication is that when employment rises, output also rises, and
thus output prices fall. Therefore, the competitive and monopsonistic models have different
employment and output price predictions.
We use the models’ output price implications to test for the potential importance of
monopsony behavior in the labor market. This test relies on research (e.g. Aaronson 2001;
Aaronson, French, and MacDonald 2005) that shows that most of the higher labor costs
incurred by employers are pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices, a finding that
is in sharp contrast to the prediction of monopsony models. Consequently, we infer that
few restaurants will increase employment in response to a minimum wage increase. Using the
most plausible range of estimates of the model’s key parameters, we find that the employment
response to a 10 percent change in the minimum wage is likely between 2 and 4 percent for
low skill workers and 1 to 3 percent for total restaurant employment. We argue that the
3

We assume that the minimum wage affects wages and the price of the output good but does not affect the
price of other factor inputs.

3

estimates are well within the bounds set in the empirical literature. All of these predictions
are robust to allowing for monopolistic competition in the product market.
It is important to emphasize that our estimates are for the restaurant industry only.
Nevertheless, this industry is a major employer of low-wage labor and therefore a particularly relevant one to study.4 However, as a result of different intensity of use of minimum
wage labor, substitution possibilities, market structure, or demand for their products, other
industries might face different employment responses.
The next section describes the basic framework of our study. In this section, we introduce
the competitive and monopsony models and show how to use price pass-through to infer the
extent of monopsony power. Many of the results from this section are discussed further in
a longer version of this paper, Aaronson and French (2006). Section 3 and the appendix at
the end of this paper discuss the main parameters used to calibrate the model. Finally, in
sections 4 and 5, the results are described and some concluding comments are offered.

2

The Model
This section outlines the structure of the model and the assumptions used to identify the

employment response to a minimum wage change. We begin with the perfect competition case
and then introduce monopsony power, offering some intuition for the ambiguous impact it has
on employment. Finally, we provide a framework for bounding the importance of monopsony
power in the labor market, using primarily the output price response to minimum wage
changes.

2.1

Model Set Up

Throughout the paper, we assume that a large number,5 N, of firms with identical production technologies and identical products are perfectly competitive in the product market,
4

Prominent examples of studies that concentrate on the restaurant industry include Katz and Krueger
(1992), Card and Krueger (1995, 2000) and Neumark and Wascher (2000). According to the Current Population Survey’s Outgoing Rotation Groups, eating and drinking places (SIC 641) is the largest employer of
workers at or near the minimum, accounting for roughly a fifth of such employees in 1994 and 1995. The
next largest employer, retail grocery stores, employs less than 7 percent of minimum or near minimum wage
workers. Moreover, the intensity of use of minimum wage workers in the eating and drinking industry is
amongst the highest of the industrial sectors.
5
We do not allow for exit or entry, although we allow the size of businesses to change in response to wage
changes.

4

sell their products at a price p, and choose their inputs to maximize profits π :
π(K, L, H, M ) = pQ − rK − wL L − wH H − pM M

(1)

where Q = F (K, L, H, M ) is a constant elasticity of substitution aggregator of low skill labor
L, high skill labor H, capital K, and materials M, purchased at prices r, wL ,6 wH , and pM ,
respectively:
1

Q = (αK K ρ + αL Lρ + αH H ρ + (1 − αK − αL − αH )M ρ ) ρ
where σ ≡

1
1−ρ

(2)

is the partial elasticity of substitution between K, LL , LH and M in the

production of Q.7 The assumption of constant elasticities of substitution between all factors
is roughly consistent with the empirical literature described in Hamermesh (1993). The
market price is:

p = Z(

N


− η1

Qn )

(3)

n=1

where

N

n=1 Qn

is market output and η is the elasticity of demand for the output good.

Although the case we consider here is competition in the product market, augmenting the
model for monopolistic competition in the product market complicates the analysis but does
not change the results.8

2.2

Long Run Price and Employment Responses of Competitive Firms

Assume all low skilled workers are paid the minimum wage but high skilled workers are
paid above it (section 2.5 relaxes the assumption that all low skilled workers are paid the
minimum wage). Also assume that the minimum wage only affects the wage of low skilled
workers and that the supply of all factors of production to the firm are perfectly elastic.
6

We assume the minimum wage covers all employers in the labor market. However, employees in restaurants
with revenues of less than $500,000 per year are not covered by federal minimum wage law.
7
The constant returns production function assumption implies the size of each firm is indeterminate. However, assuming infinitesimally decreasing returns to scale and an infinitesimally small fixed cost of running the
firm preserves all the results yet implicitly defines a firm’s size. Therefore, we consider the firm size problem
unimportant.
8
So long as firms face constant elasticity of demand, all of the remaining equations in the paper are
unaffected. See appendix F in Aaronson and French (2006).

5

Assuming that all firms can adjust all factors, the price and employment responses to
a minimum wage hike, derived in appendix B of Aaronson and French (2006), have simple
analytical solutions. When firms are perfectly competitive (or monopolistically competitive
as in appendix F of Aaronson and French (2006)) and have a constant returns production
function, economic profits must be zero both before and after the wage change. Consequently,
all changes in labor costs are passed onto the consumer, i.e.
d ln p
= sL ,
d ln wmin
where sL ≡

wL L
wL L+wH H+rK+pM M

(4)

is low skill labor’s share of total costs.9

Because prices are higher after the minimum wage hike, the quantity produced declines
by sL η percent for every one percent increase in the minimum wage.
The elasticity of demand for low skill labor λ ≡

d ln L
d ln wmin ,

is:


 d ln p 
 d ln p 
σ−
η.
λ=− 1−
d ln wmin
d ln wmin


(5)

λ is rising (in absolute value) in the elasticity of substitution between labor and the other
factors of production (the “substitution effect”)10 and the elasticity of demand for the output
good (the “scale effect”). The substitution effect measures the change in factor ratios given
a wage change, holding output fixed. The scale effect measures the change in output given
a wage change, holding factor ratios fixed. Inserting equation (4) into equation (5) yields
equation (2.7a’) in Hamermesh (1993) and (11.6) in Card and Krueger (1995).
Nevertheless, there are several reasons why one might be wary of the long-run competitive
employment response shown in equation (5). It is to two of these concerns that we turn next.
In Section 2.3, we discuss the short-run employment response when firms cannot adjust their
capital stock in response to a minimum wage change. Section 2.4 introduces monopsony
9

LL
Under perfect competition, with no profits, sL is also equal to low skill labor’s share of revenue, sL = wpQ
.
Although the empirical evidence suggests that all elasticities of substitution between factors of production
are roughly similar in magnitude, one could argue that some substitution elasticities are close to zero whereas
others (such as the elasticity of substitution between high and low skill labor) are large. However, note that
both equations (4) and (5) can also be derived for the production function

10

1

Q = min{((1 − αL )H ρ + αL Lρ ) ρ , αK K, αM M }

(6)

wL L
where sL is redefined as sL ≡ wL L+w
. Therefore, by properly adjusting ρ and sL , it is possible to get some
HH
measure of the robustness of our results to different substitution elasticities between factors.

6

power in the labor market.

2.3

Short-Run Price and Employment Responses of Competitive Firms

In the short-run, firms might not be able to adjust their capital stock in response to a
minimum wage change, perhaps because of high adjustment costs or the irreversibility of
these investments.11 In order to capture the concept of fixed capital, we assume that firms
choose capital in order to maximize profits, keeping the wage of low skill labor constant. But
after the wage changes, the firm can adjust all factors except capital.12
In appendix C of Aaronson and French (2006), we show that if capital cannot adjust, the
price response to a change in the minimum wage is:
sL
d ln p
.
=
η
d ln wmin
sK ( σ ) + (1 − sK )

(7)

Inserting equation (7) into equation (5) gives the short run employment response.
An interesting special case arises when σ, the partial elasticity of substitution between
factor inputs, and η, the elasticity of demand for the output good, are equal. In this situation,
the price response is identical whether capital is fixed (equation (7)) or flexible (equation (4)).
Additional labor costs are always and fully pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices.
To see why, note that the elasticity of capital in response to changes in the minimum wage
when capital can adjust is:
d ln K
= sL (σ − η).
d ln wmin

(8)

Therefore, if σ = η, we should expect no capital response to changes in the minimum wage,
11
Empirical work on the disemployment effect of the minimum wage typically focus on annual changes to
employment, comparing levels pre- and post- the new minimum wage. This short-run response likely abstracts
from many adjustments to the capital-labor ratio that may arise over time in response to higher wage bills.
For example, in the fast food industry over the last decade or so, cash registers have been modified so that the
cashier need not know the price of a product, only its appearance. These machines also save time by directly
transferring orders from the cash register to the cooks. It is these long-run responses that are likely of greater
interest to policymakers. Baker, Benjamin, and Stanger (1999) illustrate the potentially distinct employment
effects that arise at different time horizons.
12
This approach can be justified by the following three period model. In period 1, firms choose K, and
believe they know period 2 prices with probability 1. In period 2, all prices are revealed, and the wage
potentially changes. The firm can then pick L and M. Although K is set for period 2, the firm can pick
period 3 values of K. In period 3, all prices were as anticipated. In this case, period 2 represents the short-run
equilibrium, and period 3 represents the long-run equilibrium.

7

even if capital can adjust. Thus the fixity of capital is irrelevant.
A second interesting case is when the production function is Leontief (i.e. σ = 0). So
long as the firm can cover its variable costs (i.e., pQ > wL L + wH H + pK K), firms cannot
increase profits by reducing output. Therefore, prices and employment are unaffected by
changes in the minimum wage. One notable application is putty-clay models (Johansen
(1959), Gilchrist and Williams (2000)). Although most empirical studies find evidence of
positive substitutability between factors of production (Hamermesh, 1993), putty-clay models
develop the idea that there may be substitutability between factors for firms being put into
place, but no substitutability for firms already in place. Therefore, substitutability between
factors only exist in the long run, as new firms enter the marketplace. In the short run,
putty-clay models also predict no employment or price response to minimum wage hikes.
Regardless, the key intuition, formalized in equation (5), is that price and employment
responses are linked.
Finally, part of the reduction in low skill labor is potentially offset by increases in high
skill labor. The employment response of high skill labor is
d ln p
d ln H
=(
)(σ − η).
d ln wmin
d ln wmin

(9)

The first term shows the change in product price (which is also equal to the change in marginal
cost). The second term has offsetting substitution and scale effects. After the minimum wage
increases, high skill labor becomes relatively cheaper than low skill labor, causing firms to
substitute to the former. However, the level of output falls, causing the firm to reduce all
factors. If σ = η, this offset is exact and we should expect no high skill labor response to
changes in the minimum wage.

2.4

The Short Run Employment and Price Responses of Monopsonistic
Firms

Next, we derive the employment and price effects of minimum wage changes when firms
are monopsonists in the labor market, or more specifically, monopsonistically competitive, as
in Dickens et al. (1999) or Manning (2003). The contribution of this model relative to others
is that we endogenize prices. The production function and product market are the same as
in the previous section. We show that employment may rise in response to a minimum wage
8

hike, but this implies prices will fall.
Many researchers have argued that fast food restaurants are highly competitive and therefore monopsony power is likely negligible.13 However, models such as Burdett and Mortensen
(1998) where employee search is costly often imply that employers have some degree of monopsony power. Furthermore, Card and Krueger (1995) document several empirical facts that
may be inconsistent with competitive models but are consistent with monopsony models. For
example, they argue that a well-documented spike in the wage distribution at the minimum
implies that, unless there is a similarly sized and placed spike in the distribution of ability,
some workers are not paid their marginal revenue product of labor. We show below that the
presence of a spike in the minimum wages is not necessarily evidence of monopsony power.
But other facts, such as the existence of posted vacancies, are not consistent with competition
if it is costly to post a vacancy. Competitive theory implies that an employer can obtain an
unlimited number of workers at the going wage rate, and that any vacancy is immediately
filled. Therefore, it seems plausible that restaurants have some amount of market power.
In this model, all low skill workers are identical in their productivity, but because of
differences in local labor market conditions, all firms in some markets pay above the minimum
wage and all firms in other markets pay the minimum wage.14 Each of the N firms within a
given local labor market face the labor supply curve15 for low skill labor:
γ1
γ2 −γ1
wL,−n
Ln = θ −γ1 wL,n

(10)

where wL,n is the wage offered by the nth firm and wL,−n is the average wage offered by all
other firms in the market. Therefore, all N firms compete in the same product and labor
market.16 We assume that γ1 ≥ γ2 , so that the quantity of labor supplied to the firm is
increasing in the wage offered by the firm, and is weakly falling in the wage offered by other
firms in the market. We also assume that γ2 ≥ 0; if all firms in the market increase their wage,
13

Although Stigler (1946) was the first to observe the potential importance of monopsony power when
analyzing minimum wage policy, he was clearly suspicious that this was a relevant scenario.
14
We assume that the wage ratio between high and low skilled workers is constant across labor markets.
See section 2.6 for more details.
15
Manning (2003) derives an identical specification
starting from a specification analogous to Dixit and Stiglitz (1977).
16
Thus we allow for differences in wages and the importance of monopsony power across labor markets,
although we assume that all employers of low skill labor are identical within a labor market. This is an
extreme assumption given that only 25 percent of all minimum wage workers are employed in the restaurant
industry, and thus restaurants compete with many types of firms in the labor market.

9

the total quantity of labor supplied in the market will increase. We assume that θ potentially
varies by labor market, although we do not give θ a subscript for notational convenience.
Therefore, within each local labor market, all firms face the same wage and output price but
the (low skill) wage and output price varies across labor markets.
Using equation (10), the inverse labor supply curve for low skill labor is:
1
γ

γ

1− γ2

w(Ln ) = θLn1 wL,−n1

(11)

wL = max{w(L), wmin }.

(12)

and their offered wage is

Note that in equilibrium all firms within a given market will purchase the same amount of
factor inputs and will have the same level of output. Therefore, we drop the n subscripts for
notational convenience.
Figure 1 shows the competitive and monopsony solutions to the firm’s problem. The
competitive solution (if the firm is a price taker in the labor market with an exogenous wage
w∗∗ ) is for the firm to hire L∗∗ workers at a wage w∗∗ . However, if the firm has monopsony
power, the firm will pay only w∗ and will hire L∗ workers.
Whether employment rises, falls or remains constant in response to an increase in the
minimum wage is determined by the level of the minimum wage. The simplest case occurs
when the minimum wage is not binding (wmin < w∗ ). In this case, a small change in the
minimum wage has no effect on employment. Equilibrium employment and wages are L∗ and
w∗ , respectively.
Now, suppose the minimum wage is set between w∗ and w∗∗ . In this case, employment in
a labor market with a minimum wage (e.g. Lmin in figure 2) is greater than employment in
the absence of the minimum wage (L∗ ).17 The intuition for this result is that although the
17

Note that a change in the minimum wage changes both the labor supply curve faced by the firm (because
wL,−n changes) and the MRP(L) curve faced by the firm (because the output price charged by other firms
changes). Thus the figures are not helpful for understanding the quantitative price and employment responses,
although they are helpful for understanding the qualitative responses. Furthermore, because the labor supply
curve and MRP(L) curve shift in response to the minimum wage, changing the minimum wage also changes the
boundary conditions w∗ and w∗∗ . Below, when we refer to w∗ , we mean the value of it for which w∗ = wmin ,
and w∗∗ the value for which w∗∗ = wmin . Therefore, figure 2 is not technically correct, although it helps
clarify the intuition of the model.

10

ln w

ln MC(L)

ln w(L)
ln w∗∗
ln w∗

ln MRP(L)
ln L∗

ln L∗∗

ln L

Figure 1: Illustration of monopsony equilibrium
minimum wage increases the average cost of labor for the firm, it reduces the marginal cost
of labor from (1 +

1
∗
γ1 )w

to wmin . Below Lmin , the marginal cost of labor is the minimum

wage. Whether the firm hires Lmin or Lmin − 1 workers, all workers are paid wmin . However,
for employment levels above Lmin , the marginal cost of labor is above the minimum wage; no
additional workers will work for wmin . The employer must increase the pay of all workers in
order to obtain an additional one. Consequently, employment is determined by the intersection of the minimum wage and the inverse labor supply function w(L). Therefore, increases
in the minimum wage lead to increases in employment for wmin ∈ [w∗ , w∗∗ ). Specifically, the
percent change in employment in the market (and thus the percent change in employment
for every firm in the market) is

d ln L 

d ln wmin 

= γ2 .

(13)

wL,n =wL,−n =wmin

The important insight is that although γ1 is the relevant parameter for understanding the

11

gap between the wage and the marginal revenue product of labor,18 it is γ2 that is important
for understanding the employment response to the minimum wage.
ln w

ln MC(L)

ln w(L)
ln wmin
ln w∗

ln MRP(L)
ln L∗

ln Lmin

ln L

Figure 2: Illustration of monopsony equilibrium with minimum wage (Bold line
denotes ln MC(L) curve)
We now solve out for the price response under monopsony when wmin ∈ [w∗ , w∗∗ ). Appendix D in Aaronson and French (2006) shows that, given equation (13) but allowing for
prices and other factors of production to adjust in the same way we did when allowing for a
competitive labor market, yields

d ln p 

d ln wmin 

for some


1
sL γ2 (1+ γ(θ)
)



 −
=
wL,n =wL,−n =wmin

1
γ(θ)

∈ [0, γ11 ], where



 −

1
γ(θ)

if capital can adjust

σ‘(1−sL )+sL η
1
sL γ2 (1+ γ(θ)
)
σ(1−sL −sK )+(sL +sK )η
∗∗

= (1 +

ln L −ln L
1 ( ln L∗∗ −ln L∗ )
γ1 )



(14)
if capital cannot adjust

− 1 measures the difference between

the wage and the marginal revenue product of labor, the vertical distance between ln w(L)
and ln MRP(L) in figure 1.
18

In the absence of a minimum wage, the marginal revenue product of labor is (1 +
for this reason γ11 is sometimes known as the rate of exploitation.

12

1
)
γ1

times the wage, and

Finally, if the minimum wage lies above the point of intersection of the inverse labor supply
function and the marginal revenue product of labor function MRP(L), i.e., wmin > w(L∗∗ ),
employment falls as the minimum wage rises. The marginal cost of labor function, MC(L), is
always equal to the minimum wage. The firm then sets employment by equating the MRP(L)
curve and the minimum wage, as in Sections 2.2 and 2.3. Because the MRP(L) curve slopes
down, increases in the minimum wage unambiguously lead to a reduction in employment.
The magnitude of the disemployment effect was discussed in section 2.2 for the case where
capital can adjust and 2.3 for the case where capital cannot adjust.
Note that the price response in equation (14) is unambiguously negative. Also recall that
equations (4) and (7) showed that, under competition (or if wmin > w∗∗ ), wage hikes unambiguously increase prices. Therefore, in response to a minimum wage hike, employment and
price changes are always negatively related.19 Employment falls and prices rise under perfect
competition, and employment can rise and price can fall under monopsony. Consequently,
price data offers an alternative means of inferring the importance of monopsony power in the
labor market.

2.5

Using Price Pass-Through to Infer the Extent of Monopsony Power

This section proposes a method to infer the extent to which monopsonistic behavior
p
is important using empirical estimates of price pass-through, E[ d lnd ln
wmin ]. Furthermore, we

show that once we infer the importance of monopsony behavior, we can infer the employment
response to increasing the minimum wage.
We allow for the fact that the minimum wage binds in some labor markets, but not in
others, because of variation in labor supply (i.e., θ). Given the results above, and assuming
that capital cannot adjust, the price response to a minimum wage change is:







sL
η
sK ( σ
)+(1−sK )
1
sL γ2 (1+ γ(θ)
)

d ln p

−
(θ) =
σ(1−sL −sK )+(sL +sK )η

d ln wmin



 0

if wmin ≥ w∗∗
if w∗ ≤ wmin < w∗∗

(15)

if wmin < w∗ .

Line 1 is derived in equation (7) and line 2 in equation (14). If the minimum wage does not
19

Again, the substitutability of high and low skill labor can result in an offsetting employment response of
high skill labor.

13

bind (line 3), output prices will not respond to a minimum wage increase.
The employment response is:



sL

if wmin ≥ w∗∗
−σ − (η − σ) sK ( η )+(1−s


)
K

σ
λ(θ) =

if w(L∗ ) ≤ wmin < w∗∗

γ2



 0

(16)

if wmin < w∗ .

Line 1 is derived using equation (5), plus the price response in line 1 of equation (15). Line
2 is derived in equation (13). If the minimum wage is not binding, as in line 3, there is no
employment response.
Define prob(wmin > w∗ ) as the share of firms that pay the minimum wage and V =
prob(wmin ≥ w∗∗ |wmin > w∗ ) as the share of firms facing a binding minimum wage such
that the minimum wage is equal to the M RP (L). If V = 1, then all firms affected by the
minimum wage behave competitively in the labor market. If V = 0, then all firms affected
behave as monopsonists. If we knew V , we could use equation (16) to compute the average
employment response. If all firms have the same elasticities and factor shares, then

∗

E[λ] =
θ

λ(θ)dF (θ) = −prob(wmin > w ) ×

sL
V σ + (η − σ)
η
sK ( σ ) + (1 − sK )




 
− 1 − V γ2 .


(17)
Fortunately, we can calculate V by using the extent of price pass-through. Analogous to
equation (17), the average price response is
E[

d ln p
]=
d ln wmin

θ

d ln p
(θ)dF (θ)
d ln wmin

=prob(wmin > w∗ )sL ×




 
1
(1 − V )γ2 (1 + γ(θ)
)
V
 .
− 
sK ( ση ) + (1 − sK )
σ(1 − sL − sK ) + (sL + sK )η
(18)

14

Rearranging equation (18), we can solve explicitly for V :
p
E[ d lnd ln
wmin ]

1

prob(wmin >w ∗ )

V =
sL
η
sK ( σ
)+(1−sK )

+

+

1
sL γ2 (1+ γ(θ)
)

σ(1−sL −sK )+(sL +sK )η

1
sL γ2 (1+ γ(θ)
)

σ(1−sL −sK )+(sL +sK )η




.

(19)

ln p
Values of E[ ddln
w ], sK , γ1 , γ2 , η, σ can be computed or taken from the existing literature. We

report the values that we use in table 1 of section 3 and the appendix. However, we do not
have direct estimates of prob(wmin > w∗ ) or sL . In section 2.6 we show how to infer these
objects using additional information.
In deriving equations (18) and (19), we assumed that sL and sK do not vary across labor
markets. However, the theory presented above indicates that the factor mix (and thus sL and
sK ) varies across labor markets. In the appendix, we provide empirical evidence, based on
the 1997 Economic Census for Accommodations and Food Services and the outgoing rotation
files of the CPS, that there is little geographic variation in labor’s share. Appendix E in
Aaronson and French (2006) also shows that, given the calibrated values described in this
papers appendix, geographic differences in low skill labor’s share are likely small, varying by
less than 15 percent (or 4 percentage points) across labor markets.20
We make two final observations about the model. First, all of the competitive and monopsony predictions described in this section are robust to allowing for monopolistic competition
in the product market, so long as there is a constant elasticity of demand. This result is
established in appendix F of Aaronson and French (2006).
Second, this model generates a spike in the distribution of wages at the minimum, even if
monopsony power is nonexistent.21 This is the case so long as σ and η are finite (i.e., labor
is not a perfect substitute for materials or capital and there is finite elasticity of demand for
the output good). Under these reasonable assumptions, low skill labor will still be used as a
factor of production, even when the price of labor rises, and increases in output prices will
20

Given the parameters listed in Section 3, allowing for labor’s share to vary across markets had only a
modest effect on our results.
21
Within our model, all low skill workers are paid the same wage, although there is wage dispersion across
labor markets. If two workers within the same labor market had different wages before the minimum wage
hike, they will have different wages after the minimum wage hike. There is some empirical evidence against this
implication of the model. Card and Krueger (1995) show that, within states, minimum wage hikes significantly
compress wages for those paid near the minimum wage. Unless labor markets are smaller than states (which
may be true for minimum wage workers), this is evidence against the model.

15

lead to a reduction but not cessation in output. In a geographically segmented labor market,
with heterogeneous, but not perfectly substitutable, labor, raising the minimum wage slightly
above the competitive wage will not shut down the industry. Even if labor were homogenous,
increasing the minimum wage will not shut down an industry. Therefore, higher labor costs
caused by an increase in the minimum wage can be (partially) pushed onto consumers.

2.6

Aggregation Issues

Ideally, we would like to use parameters to calibrate the model that correspond to restaurants that pay at or near the minimum wage. Unfortunately, we often must rely on estimates
in the literature that come from more aggregated sources, particularly the entire restaurant
industry. If all restaurants were identical, facing identical labor and product markets, using
aggregate data would not be a problem. But clearly this is not the case.
Perhaps the most serious concern is that we do not know either the fraction of restaurants
that pay the minimum wage (i.e., prob(wmin > w∗ )), or low wage labor’s share at restaurants
that pay the minimum wage, sL . However, we do have quite a bit of related information,
including the share of restaurant workers who are paid the minimum wage (prob(wmin = wi )),
labor’s share of total costs in the restaurant industry (sL + sH ), the fraction of workers who
are low skill (prob(L)) at any given restaurant (and are thus paid the minimum wage in low
wage markets), the average number of workers per restaurant by high wage (Z−min ) and low
wage (Zmin ) establishments, and minimum wage labor’s share of the aggregate wage bill.
In order to recover prob(wmin > w∗ )) and sL , we assume that there are only three types
of labor markets (i.e., θ can take on only three different values): those that pay the minimum
wage to workers and behave competitively (i.e., markets where the minimum wage intersects
the MRP(L) curve for every firm in the market), those that behave monopsonistically (i.e.,
markets where the minimum wage intersects the labor supply curve for every firm in the
market), and markets where the minimum wage does not bind. In markets where the minimum does not bind, all firms pay their low skill workers wagedif f × wmin . Furthermore,
high wage workers are paid a constant multiple of the wage of low skill workers within the
market. Thus, there is a four point wage distribution, with heterogeneity in two dimensions:
high and low skill workers, and high and low wage labor markets. We assume that prob(L)

16

is the same in high wage and low wage labor markets.22
In appendix G of Aaronson and French (2006), we show that

∗

prob(wmin ≥ w(L )) =

1−

prob(wmin =wi ) Z−min
Zmin
prob(L)
prob(wmin =wi )
prob(wmin =wi ) Z−min
+
Zmin
prob(L)
prob(L)

where the right hand side of equation (20) collapses to

prob(wmin =wi )
prob(L)

when

(20)

Z−min
Zmin

= 1. Using

household data, we can measure prob(wmin = wi ) fairly accurately.
Because we have information on sL + sH , but not sL alone, we must infer the relative
shares of each factor. In order to infer sL , we match minimum wage labor’s share of the
total wage bill (i.e., the share of total wages going to minimum wage labor) to the data. In
appendix G of Aaronson and French (2006), we show that low skill labor’s share is

 

sL = sL + sH × minimum wage labor’s share of the total wage bill ×
prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) + (1 − prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ))) ∗ wagedif f ∗
prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ))

Z−min
Zmin


.

(21)

The right hand side of equation (21) has three parts. The first part is labor’s share. The
product of the second and third parts are the share of labor costs going to low skill labor.

2.7

Total Employment Effects

Lastly, we are not only interested in low skill employment but total employment as well. To
calculate the impact on total restaurant industry employment, denoted E, we must compute
a weighted average of the low and high skill workers’ employment responses:
d ln E
=
d ln wmin


d ln L
d ln H
(prob(L)) +
(1 − prob(L)) × prob(lowwage)
d ln wmin
d ln wmin

(22)

prob(lowwage) is the share of workers who work for a minimum wage restaurant,
prob(lowwage) =

prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )
prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ) + (1 − prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) ZZ−min
min

(23)

22
Assuming that wages for high skill workers is a constant multiple of the wages of low skill workers and
that the fraction of low skill workers does not vary across labor markets, if fairly consistent with the data.
The coefficient of variation of restaurant worker wages within a city varies very little with the average wage
within a city, according to our calculations using CPS data. This is consistent with our joint hypothesis.

17

and is derived in equation (95) of Aaronson and French (2006).

3

Parameters and Estimation
Table 1 provides a summary of the parameters that we use to calibrate the model. The

right hand column gives the baseline values that we use, along with the range of values
considered in the robustness checks to follow. The appendix provides a full accounting of
how we chose these values.

4

Results

4.1

Employment and Price Responses

Table 2 reports our estimates of the employment response to a 1 percent minimum wage
hike under various scenarios for the key parameters. In the top panel, the employment
p
responses are based on a price response (E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] = 0.07) that is consistent with the

aggregate results in Aaronson (2001) and Aaronson et al (2005). The bottom panel is based
p
23
on a price response that is 1.5 standard errors below this estimate (E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] = 0.05).

Within each panel, the demand elasticity, η, varies between 0.5 and 1.0, and the elasticity of
substitution, σ, between 0.5 and 0.8. The remaining parameters are set to our best assessment
of their value, as described in table 1 and the appendix. All reported employment responses
are short-run.24
The first column displays the low skill employment response to a 1 percent minimum wage
increase under the assumption that all firms are price-takers in the labor market, λcomp ×
prob(wmin > w∗ ). Employment responses are described in equations (5) and (7) for firms
where the minimum wage binds. That is, labor markets are perfectly competitive, but some
firms pay above the minimum wage. First, consider the case where η = 0.5 and σ = 0.8.
Under these conditions, a 1 percent increase in the minimum wage cuts the low skill food
away from home workforce by 0.36 percent. If η = 1.0, the disemployment case is only
slightly larger, approximately 0.39 percent. The estimates are a bit more sensitive to σ.
23

These lower estimates are consistent with some specifications reported in Aaronson (2001).
Predicted short-run price responses depend on how much the ratio ση varies from 1. Given the range of
estimates for η and σ that we consider likely, the difference between the long-run and short-run response is
very small.
24

18

When σ = 0.5, λcomp × prob(wmin > w∗ ) falls to between 0.23 and 0.26. Reducing the
elasticity of substitution between factors eases the disemployment effect because firms have
less opportunity to substitute from labor to other factors. Accordingly, if σ is as high as 1,
the competitive employment response is over 0.5. While the variety of values are noteworthy,
given that the experiment covers what we consider to be the range of plausible values for η
and σ (and other parameters), it appears to us that the employment response is not especially
sensitive to reasonable parameter choices. Therefore, we can place reasonably tight bounds
on the low skill employment response under fairly strict assumptions about labor market
structure.
Next, we introduce monopsony power in the labor market. Recall that increases in the
minimum wage trace out the labor supply curve (with elasticity γ2 ) for monopsonists. Consequently, if all firms are monopsonists, minimum wage hikes significantly increase employment.25 Since firms are adding workers in response to a minimum wage change, output
increases and prices fall. The model predicts that the price elasticity under monopsony is
roughly -0.07. By comparison, the price elasticity under competition tends to be around 0.07.
Column 2 reports the value of V, which is, as described in equation (19), identified by the
degree of actual pass-through relative to the pure monopsony and perfect competition cases.
A number substantially below 1 would imply that monopsony power is important.26 For
p
example, if η = 0.5, σ = 0.5, and E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] = 0.07, then V = 1.04, suggesting that there is

little monopsony power in the industry. However, as factors become more substitutable, the
elasticity of demand becomes less elastic, or price responses are muted, the implied amount
p
of monopsony power increases. For example, if σ = 0.8, η = 0.5, and E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] = 0.05,

V = 0.82.
Column 3 reports our estimate of the low skill employment response to a 1 percent minimum wage change when the extent of monopsony power is accounted for explicitly. Calculations are based on equation (17). Like our estimates developed in the perfect competition
setting, these employment responses tend to cluster, in this case in the -0.2 to -0.4 range, with
the former appearing when σ is low, η is low, and/or price responses are high. To take one
p
fairly moderate reading of the parameters, say σ = 0.65, η = 0.75, and E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] = 0.06,
25

For example, when γ2 = 0.5, λmonop × prob(wmin > w∗ ) = 0.24.
V can exceed one if firms pass on more of a price increase than would be expected given perfect competition.
Empirically, overshifting of ad valorem taxes has been found by, among others, Besley and Rosen (1999) in
the retail apparel industry and Karp and Perloff (1989) in the Japanese television market.
26

19

we find V = 0.99, the low skill employment response is -0.3.27
H
Of course, these estimates ignore the impact on high skilled employment (E ∆∆lnlnwmin
) and
ln E
therefore potentially give a misleading picture of the total employment effect (E ∆∆
ln wmin ).

Column 4 shows that the employment response for high skilled workers is always negligible.
To estimate the impact on total restaurant industry employment, we must compute a
weighted average of the low and high skill workers’ employment responses, as in equation
(22). These results are presented in column 5. The total employment response to a 1 percent
increase in the minimum wage is roughly -0.2, with estimates ranging between -0.1 to -0.3
under reasonable parameter choices.28
Not only do we compare our predicted aggregate price increases to estimates in the literature, but we also
compare predictions of price increases in areas where the minimum wage does not bind
with areas where the minimum wage does bind. Consider the regression:



= γprob(wi = wmin ) + errori

(24)

i




where

∆ ln p
∆ ln wmin

∆ ln p
∆ ln wmin

is the average city level price response and prob(wi = wmin ) is the probi

ability that an individual in city i is paid the minimum wage before the minimum wage hike.
Assuming all labor markets are competitive implies that the regression coefficient γ should be
0.15 to 0.22, depending on the specification.29 Furthermore, allowing for the inferred amount
of monopsony from Table 2, the regression coefficient γ should be between 0.15 and 0.21.30
Using a panel of city level data, Aaronson et al. (2005) find that this regression has a
27

The only other parameters that have a substantive impact on these magnitudes are labor share (sL + sH )
and the share of workers that are low skill (prob(L)). To get an indication of the sensitivity of the results, we
ln p
] = 0.06. Altering sL + sH
start with the baseline described above (where σ = 0.65, η = 0.75, and E[ d lnd w
min
between 0.25 and 0.35 stretches the low skill employment response to be between -0.36 to -0.27. If, instead,
we allow prob(L) to be between 0.6 and 0.8, the low skill employment response falls in the range of -0.37 to
-0.26.
28
Furthermore, the other parameters, as discussed in the previous footnote, have a negligible impact (always
less than 0.03) on the total employment response.
29
Predicted values are obtained by setting V = 1 in equation (18), using the value of sL in equation (21),
and the formula for the relationship between prob(wmin = wi ) and prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) derived in equation
(20). The range of values for γ are obtained by varying the parameters in the same way as Table 2.
30
To make this calculation, we assume there are multiple labor markets within each city. The minimum
wage binds in some markets, but not in others. In all cities there is a probability V that firms in the market
have monopsony power, if the minimum wage binds in that market. We then use the inferred value of V from
the model, and use equations (18), (21), and (20).

20

coefficient of 0.36 with a standard error of 0.24. Therefore, estimated pass-through is greater
than, but is not statistically different from, the predicted competitive response or the implied
responses that allow for some monopsony power as in Table 2.

4.2

The Importance of Aggregation

How does accounting for heterogeneity affect our results? Table 3 shows estimates of
the competitive and monopsony price responses, V , and the competitive, monopsony, and
expected total employment responses to a 1 percent change in the minimum wage under three
scenarios. Model 1 allows for labor market heterogeneity but not worker type heterogeneity,
model 2 for worker heterogeneity but not labor market type heterogeneity, and model 3 for
heterogeneity in both labor market and worker types. Specifically, model 1 assumes that
some stores pay all of their workers the minimum wage and the remainder pay none of their
workers the minimum wage. There is only one type of labor, but variation in labor supply
(i.e., θ) causes the minimum wage to bind in some markets and not others. Model 2 assumes
that all restaurants within a market are identical and hire both high and low skill labor.
High skill labor is always paid above the minimum wage and low skill labor is always paid
the minimum wage. Therefore, each firm hires an identical share of the minimum wage labor
force and above minimum wage labor force. Note that wage dispersion arises across stores in
model 1 but within stores in model 2. Model 3 is our preferred model, where the amount of
heterogeneity within and across firms is calibrated using values in table 1. Model 3 was used
to generate the predicted price and employment responses in table 2.
Here, it is clear that competitive and monopsony price responses (but not employment
responses) are sensitive to assumptions about labor market and worker type heterogeneity.
The competitive price response varies from 0.051 in model 2 to 0.099 in model 1. Relative to
the empirical evidence of a price response of 0.07, model 1 predicts larger price responses than
the evidence and model 2 smaller price responses than the evidence. Consequently, model 1
predicts that some firms must have monopsony power in order to reconcile a large predicted
competitive response with a relatively small measured response, but model 2 predicts that
over 100% of all firms are competitive. Therefore, relative to a competitive employment
response of -0.17,31 model 1 predicts larger employment responses (in absolute magnitude)
31

The employment responses do not vary across models only when σ = η.

21

and model 2 predicts smaller employment responses.
When we allow for heterogeneity in both worker types and labor markets (model 3), we
find that the predicted price response is very close to the empirical estimates and thus we infer
that close to 100% of all firms are competitive.32 As a result, the predicted total employment
response is also close to the competitive response. As we argue in the conclusion, the estimates
derived from model 3 are within the bounds set by the empirical literature. However, ignoring
heterogeneity within or across establishments can badly bias price and employment responses.
To illustrate why aggregation affects the price response, and thus our predicted value of
V , consider the price response assuming all labor markets are competitive and σ = η (or
alternatively, that all factors can adjust). Recall that competition implies that all labor costs
are pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices. Inserting equation (4) into equation
(18) and assuming V = 1 yields
E[

d ln p
] = sL × prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )).
d ln wmin

(25)

Now consider what models 1 and 2 imply for sL , prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )), and thus the predicted
price responses. Setting

Z−min
Zmin

= 1, inserting equation (20) into (25) (and noting that there

is only one type of labor in model 1, so prob(L) = 1 and sL = sL + sH ) yields:
E[

d ln p
] = (sL + sH ) × prob(wmin = wi ).
d ln wmin

(26)

Assuming model 2, where all firms are identical, pay some of their workers the minimum
wage, and thus prob(L) = prob(wi = wmin ) and prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) = 1, equations (25) and
(21) can be rewritten as:
E[



d ln p
] = (sL + sH ) × minimum wage labor’s share of the total wage bill .
d ln wmin

(27)

Using equations (26) and (27) and the values in table 3, we can better understand the
predicted price responses from models 1 and 2. Since minimum wage workers are paid less
than other workers, prob(wmin = wi ) > (minimum wage labor’s share of the total wage bill)
and thus price pass-through is greater in the first model than the second. The difference arises
32

Table 2 shows that V ranges from just below 1 to just above 1 for reasonable perturbations of the
parameters.

22

from the relative weight of high and low wage workers in the total wage bill. For example, in
the empirically relevant case where restaurant size and labors share of the total wage bill are
constant across restaurant types, restaurants that hire minimum wage workers have a smaller
payroll and fewer sales. Consequently, for a fixed payroll, this implies more minimum wage
restaurants in a labor market and a larger aggregate price response to changes in minimum
wage laws.
We now quantify the price predictions of models 1 and 2. Recall that we estimate that
roughly 33 percent of restaurant workers are impacted by the level of the minimum wage
although their compensation consists of only 17 percent of the aggregate restaurant wage
bill. Consider model 1 first. If all restaurants either pay the minimum wage or above the
minimum wage, 33% of all workers are paid the minimum wage by the 33% of all restaurants
that pay the minimum wage. These 33 percent of all restaurants have pass through of 30
percent (because labor’s share is 30%) and the rest have pass through of 0 percent, for an
aggregate pass-though of 33% × 30% = 9.9%.
Next, consider model 2. If all restaurants have the same distributions of high wage and
minimum wage workers, then minimum wage labor is 17 percent of labor costs at every
restaurant. If total labor’s share is 30 percent, then we should expect pass-through to be
30% × 17% =5.1% at every restaurant. The large differences between these two calculations
makes it clear that properly handling the aggregation issue is critical. Our best assessment,
model 3, lies between these two extremes.

5

Conclusion
We use a model of labor demand to calibrate the employment response to a change in the

minimum wage for the food away from home industry. If all firms are price-takers in the labor
market, the model predicts roughly a 3.5 percent fall in low skill employment in response to
a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage. A second implication of the competitive model
is that
higher labor costs are pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices. This price
response stands in sharp contrast to the monopsony model, offering a way to identify the
extent of monopsony power in the labor market for the restaurant industry. Relying on
previous research that shows that most of the higher labor costs incurred by employers are
23

pushed onto consumers in the form of higher prices, we infer that few restaurants will have
positive employment responses in reaction to a minimum wage increase. Consequently, using
the most plausible range of estimates for the key parameters in the model, we find that the
low skill employment response to a 10 percent change in the minimum wage is likely around 3
percent. The total employment response, including high skilled (non-minimum wage) workers
is likely around 2 percent. These estimates are just slightly below the perfect competition
prediction.
Are our findings consistent with studies that directly estimate the employment response
to a minimum wage change? Again, we want to emphasize that the findings reported here
are for the restaurant industry only. As a result of different intensity of use of minimum wage
labor, substitution possibilities, market structure, and demand for products, other industries
should face distinct employment responses. Consequently, it is difficult to compare our results
to those that identify the employment effect off the co-movement of teenage employment and
the minimum wage, without knowing the full range of these parameters for the major industry
employers of teens.
However, if we were to compare our low skill results to the teen studies, we believe our estimates would be well within the range supported in the literature.33 Moreover, among those
studies that explicitly look at the restaurant industry, our results are quite consistent with
Neumark and Wascher (2000), who find the employment response to be around -0.2 but a bit
larger than those reported in Card and Krueger (2000).34 An employment response of zero,
while clearly theoretically plausible, does not seem consistent with the level of monopsony
power inferred from the price responses observed in the food away from home sector. Therefore, our results provide evidence against the hypothesis that monopsony power is important
for understanding the observed small employment responses in the literature.
33
To get comparable estimates, the teen studies need to be adjusted for coverage (e.g. table 2 in Brown
1999). Brown’s adjustments are based on wage distributions for 16-24 year olds, as calculated in Neumark
and Wascher (2002). He argues that the share of workers in this age group impacted by the minimum wage
is close to 20 percent, suggesting that the elasticity of demand for teenagers should be factored up 1/0.2=5.
However, since this calculation is based partly on 20-24 year olds, a more conservative guess for 16-19 year
olds would be 3.
34
Our results are not exactly comparable to theirs, because our results are for the entire restaurant industry,
whereas their results are just for the fast food industry, where a higher share of workers are paid the minimum
wage.

24

6

References
Aaronson, Daniel. 2001. “Price Pass-Through and the Minimum Wage.” Review of

Economics and Statistics 83, no. 1: 158-169.
Aaronson, Daniel, Eric French, and James MacDonald. 2005. “The Minimum Wage,
Restaurant Prices, and Labor Market Structure.” Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago.
Aaronson, Daniel and Eric French. 2006. “Product Market Evidence on the Employment
Effects of the Minimum Wage.” Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
available at http://www.chicagofed.org/.
Baker, Michael, Dwayne Benjamin, and Shuchita Stanger. 1999. “The Highs and Lows
of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time-Series Cross-Section Study of the Canadian Law.”
Journal of Labor Economics 17, no. 2: 318-350.
Besley, Timothy and Harvey Rosen. 1999. “Sales Taxes and Prices: An Empirical Analysis.” National Tax Journal 52, no. 2: 157-178.
Bhaskar, V. and Ted To. 1999. “Minimum Wages for Ronald McDonald Monopsonies: A
Theory of Monopsonistic Competition.” Economic Journal 109, no. 455: 190-203.
Brown, Charles. 1999. “Minimum Wages, Employment, and the Distribution of Income,
” In Handbook of Labor Economics, eds. Orley Ashenfelter and David Card. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Brown, Charles, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen. 1982. “The Effect of the Minimum
Wage on Employment and Unemployment.” Journal of Economic Literature 20, no. 2:
487-528.
Brown, Douglas. 1990. “The Restaurant and Fast Food Race: Who’s Winning?” Southern Economic Journal 56, no. 4: 984-995.
Burdett, Kenneth, and Dale Mortensen. 1998. “Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and
Unemployment.” International Economic Review 39, no. 2: 257-273.
Burkhauser, Richard, Kenneth Couch, and David Wittenburg. 2000. “A Reassessment of
the New Economics of the Minimum Wage Literature with Monthly Data from the Current
Population Survey.” Journal of Labor Economics 18, no. 4: 653-680.
Card, David and Alan Krueger. 1995. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of
the Minimum Wage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

25

Card, David and Alan Krueger. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study
of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: Reply.” American Economic
Review 90, no. 5: 1397-1420.
Deere, Donald, Kevin M. Murphy, and Finis Welch. 1995. “Employment and the 19901991 Minimum-Wage Hike.” American Economic Review 85, no. 2: 232-237.
Dickens, Richard, Stephen Machin, and Alan Manning. 1999. “The Effects of Minimum
Wages on Employment: Theory and Evidence from Britain.” Journal of Labor Economics
17, no. 1: 1-22.
Dixit, Avinash and Joseph Stiglitz. 1977. “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum
Product Diversity.” American Economic Review 67, no. 3: 297-308.
Fuchs, Victor, Alan Krueger, and James Poterba. 1998. “Economists’ Views about
Parameters, Values, and Policies: Survey Results in Labor and Public Economics.” Journal
of Economic Literature 36, no. 3: 1387-1425.
Gilchrist, Simon and John Williams. 2000. “Putty-Clay and Investment: A Business
Cycle Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 108, no. 5: 928-960.
Goodwin, Barry and Gary Brester. 1995. “Structural Change in Factor Demand Relationships in the U.S. Food and Kindred Products Industry.” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 77, no. 1: 69-79.
Grossman, Jean. 1983. “The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Other Wages.” Journal
of Human Resources 18, no. 3: 359-378.
Hamermesh, Daniel. 1993. Labor Demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hussain, Iftikhar. 2004. “Consumer Demand and the Role of Labor Supply and Durables.”
Unpublished manuscript, University College London.
Johansen, Leif. 1959. “Substitution Versus Fixed Production Coefficients in the Theory
of Economic Growth: A Synthesis.” Econometrica 27, no. 2: 157-176.
Karp, Larry and Jeffrey Perloff. 1989. “Estimating Market Structure and Tax Incidence:
The Japanese Television Market,” Journal of Industrial Economics 37, no. 3: 225-239.
Katz, Lawrence and Alan Krueger. 1992. “The Effect of the Minimum Wage on the
Fast-Food Industry.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, no. 1: 6-21.
Kim, Taeil and Lowell Taylor. 1995. “The Employment Effect in Retail Trade of California’s 1988 Minimum Wage Increase.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 13, no. 2:

26

175-182.
Machin, Stephen and Alan Manning. 1997. “Minimum Wages and Economic Outcomes
in Europe.” European Economic Review 41, no. 3-5: 733-742.
Machin, Stephen and Alan Manning. 1996. “Employment and the Introduction of a
Minimum Wage in Britain.” Economic Journal 106, no. 436: 667-676.
Manning, Alan. 1995. “How Do We Know That Real Wages Are Too High?” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 110, no. 4: 1111-1125.
Manning, Alan. 2003. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Neumark, David and William Wascher. 1996. “Reconciling the Evidence on Employment
Effects of Minimum Wages: A Review of Our Research Findings.” In The Effects of Minimum
Wages on Employment ed. Marvin Kosters. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.
Neumark, David and William Wascher. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A
Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: Comment.” American
Economic Review 90, no. 5: 1362-1396.
Neumark, David and William Wascher. 2002. “Do Minimum Wages Fight Poverty?”
Economic Inquiry 40, no. 3: 315-333.
Neumark, David and William Wascher. 2003. “Minimum Wages, Labor Market Institutions, and Youth Employment: A Cross-National Analysis.” Unpublished manuscript,
Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
Piggott, Nicholas. 2003. “The Nested PIGLOG Model: An Application to U.S. Food
Demand.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85, no. 1: 1-15.
Rebitzer, James and Lowell Taylor. 1995. “The Consequences of Minimum Wage Laws:
Some New Theoretical Ideas.” Journal of Public Economics 56, no. 2: 245-255.
Stigler, George. 1946. “The Economics of Minimum Wage Legislation.” American Economic Review 36, no. 3: 358-365.
Teulings, Coen. 2000. “Aggregation Bias in Elasticities of Substitution and the Minimum
Wage Paradox.” International Economic Review 41, no. 2: 359-398.
Wellington, Alison. 1991. “Effects of the Minimum Wage on the Employment Status of
Youths: An Update.” Journal of Human Resources 26, no. 1: 27-46.
Yang, Jiawen. 1997. “Exchange Rate Pass-Through in U.S. Manufacturing.” Review of

27

Economics and Statistics 79, no. 1: 95-104.

Appendix A: The Parameters of the Model
This appendix details the parameter values we use in the calibration exercise.
p
Price Pass-Through, E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] Aaronson et al (2005) use store-level data from the

food away from home component of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) during 1995 to 1997
to identify the extent of price pass-through.35 They find that, in the aggregate, a 10 percent
increase in the minimum wage increases prices by roughly 0.7 percent during a four month
period around the minimum wage enactment date. These results are comparable to Aaronson
(2001), who uses panels of U.S. city and Canadian province CPI data from 1978 to 1995. Card
and Krueger (1995) also use CPI indexes for Food Away from Home in 27 large metropolitan
areas, finding larger price increases in those cities with higher proportions of low-wage workers.
Although their estimates are consistent with full pass-through, their standard errors are
extremely large. They cannot reject zero price pass-through in many of their specifications.
Moreover, additional evidence from specific state increases in Texas and New Jersey suggests
close to no price response. As a result, they conclude that their estimates are “too imprecise
to reach a more confident assessment about the effects of the minimum wage on restaurant
prices.” However, Aaronson (2001) and Aaronson et al (2005) use substantially more data
and document large and significant increases in food away from home prices immediately
surrounding an increase in the minimum wage. These latter results are consistent with
studies of price pass-through resulting from other cost shocks, such as sales taxes levies (e.g.
Besley and Rosen 1999) and exchange rate movements (e.g. Yang 1997).
In the calibration exercise, which aggregates all markets and types of restaurants, we use
p
a value for E[ d lnd ln
wmin ] of 0.05 or 0.07.

Labor’s Share, sL + sH

There are a number of sources for labor share, all of which tend to

report similar numbers for the food away from home industry. First, 10-K company reports
35

While the time frame is somewhat short, this three-year period contains an unusual amount of minimum
wage activity. A bill signed on August 20, 1996 raised the federal minimum from $4.25 to $5.15 per hour,
with the increase phased in gradually. An initial increase to $4.75 (11.8 percent) occurred on October 1, and
the final installment (8.4 percent) took effect on September 1, 1997. Moreover, additional variation can be
exploited by taking advantage of cross-state differences in market wages, state-imposed minimum wages that
exceed federal levels, and differences in establishment type.

28

contain payroll to total expense ratios. Of the 17 restaurant companies that appear in a
search of 1995 reports using the SEC’s Edgar database, the unconditional
mean and median of this measure of labor share is 30 percent and it ranges from 21 to
41 percent.36 These numbers are in-line with a sampling of 1995 corporate income tax forms
from the Internal Revenue Service’s Statistics on Income Bulletin. Because operating costs
are broken down by category, it is possible to estimate labor’s share.37 According to these
tax filings, labor cost as a share of operating costs for eating place partnerships is roughly 33
percent. Consequently, we set sL + sH to 30 percent but test the robustness of the results to
values between 25 and 35 percent.
Finally, we are particularly interested in labor share in low wage firms. Depending on
the elasticity of substitution between factors, firms in high wage labor markets theoretically
could have either a higher or lower labor’s share. To gauge this heterogeneity, we use the
1997 Economic Census for Accommodations and Food Services, which reports payroll for
full service (FS) and limited service (LS) restaurants. LS includes fast-food stores and any
restaurant without sit-down service and where customers pay at the counter prior to receiving
their meals. Therefore, they tend to be the primary employer of minimum wage labor.
According to this 1997 census, labor share, as a fraction of sales, is slightly higher at FS
(31 percent) than LS (25 percent) stores.38 Therefore, there is little evidence of a significant
difference in labor share across establishment type.
Furthermore, there is no evidence of an association between labor share and average city
wages. Here, we correlate MSA-level labor share from the 1997 Economic Census for Accommodations and Food Services with MSA-level real wage rates computed from the 1990-1999
outgoing rotation files of the CPS. That correlation is small and statistically insignificant for
both limited service (-0.08) and full service (-0.06) establishments. The lack of a geographic
association between labor share and wages is particular evident when breaking the cities into
quartiles based on their average wage rate during the 1990s. For limited service establishments, labor share is (lowest to highest wage quartile) 0.258, 0.262, 0.260, and 0.256. Among
36

The search uses five keywords: restaurant, steak, seafood, hamburger, and chicken.
The IRS claims that labor cost is notoriously difficult to decompose for corporations and therefore we
restrict our analysis to partnerships, where there is less concern about reporting.
38
Several 10-K reports of individual restaurant companies show that wages account for 85 percent of compensation. Therefore, labor’s share based on compensation is roughly 36 and 29 percent at full and limited
service restaurants.
37

29

full-service establishments, labor share is 0.308, 0.312, 0.311, and 0.306. See appendix E of
Aaronson and French (2006) for a further discussion of this point.
Capital and Material’s Share, sK and sM

Based on the same sample of company

financial reports used to compute sL + sH , we assume that capital share is 30 percent and
materials share is 40 percent. When we allow sL + sH to vary, we also allow either capital or
material share to adjust accordingly. The results are not sensitive to modifications of these
shares between capital and materials.
The Share of Minimum Wage Workers, prob(wmin = wi ), and Minimum Wage
Labor’s Share of the Total Wage Bill

The minimum wage should affect prices and

employment only if it impacts wages. Therefore, we need the share of workers’ wages influenced by minimum wage policy. Since this is not available in company reports, we estimate
the share of employees that are paid at or very near the minimum wage from the outgoing
rotation files of the Current Population Survey (CPS) for the two years prior to the 1996
legislation.39 During this time period, 23 percent of restaurant industry workers were within
10 percent of the minimum wage, and therefore clearly impacted by a characteristically-sized
10 percent increase in the minimum wage.
However, this estimate is insufficient for understanding the fraction of workers affected
by the minimum wage change. Workers paid slightly above the minimum wage also tend
to receive pay increases in response to minimum wage increases.40 To approximate this
phenomena, we use the outgoing rotation file wage distribution and assume that one-third
of workers within 150 percent of the old minimum are impacted by the new minimum wage
change. No one beyond this threshold is assumed to be impacted. These assumptions imply
prob(wmin = wi ) = 0.33. That is, one-third of restaurant workers are influenced by minimum
wage legislation. We test the robustness of the results to values of prob(wmin = wi ) between
0.25 and 0.40.
Using the same CPS data and assumptions about spillovers, we also estimate that minimum wage labor constitutes 17% of the wage bill. Therefore, 33% of all restaurant workers
39

There are no federal changes and only two state changes during these two years. We exclude the two
states, Vermont and Washington, with such activity, as well as all data from June to August of 1995, for
which there are no geographic identifiers.
40
See Grossman (1983) and Card and Krueger (1995) for empirical evidence and Card and Kruger (1995)
Teulings (2000),and Manning (2003) for potential explanations.

30

are paid the minimum wage, but they are paid only 17% of the total value of wage payments
in the restaurant industry.
The Wage Distribution Parameters, prob(L), wagedif f

We allow for wage hetero-

geneity in two dimensions. We assume that there are two types of workers (high and low
skill) and two types of labor markets (high and low wage). We assume that low skill workers
in high wage markets are always paid above the minimum wage (as are all high skill workers).
However, all low skill workers in low wage labor markets are paid the minimum wage. Furthermore, we assume that all restaurants have the same skill distribution, so the probability
of being low skill, prob(L), does not vary by labor market. Given this assumption, prob(L) =
the probability that someone in a low wage labor market is paid the minimum wage. This
pins down the probability that a worker is low skill.
We define a local labor market as a city. Aaronson et al (2005) use the 1979-1995 CPS
Outgoing Rotation Groups to estimate the share of restaurant workers that are paid at or
near the minimum wage among cities covered in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) survey.41
They find that roughly 70 percent of restaurant workers are paid at or near the minimum
wage in the lowest wage cities. Therefore, we assume prob(L) = 0.70 but allow prob(L) to
vary between 0.60 and 0.80.
In order to allow for wage differences across labor markets, we set θ as a two point
distribution. The distribution for θ shifts wages for both high and low skill workers, which
in turn shifts wagedif f . We pick wagedif f = 1.5 to match the dispersion in wages across
cities. Although the ratio of average wages in high wage cities (i.e., the highest paying 50
percent of cities represented in the CPI) to average wages in low wage cities is roughly 1.15,
different measures of dispersion give larger differences in high versus low wage areas. For
example, the ratio of wages in the top 15% of all cities relative to the bottom 15% of all cities
is 1.5.
Using this information, we can infer the probability that an individual restaurant pays
the minimum wage to its low skill workers using equation (20). Furthermore, we can infer the
41

The 27 CPI cities are New York City, Philadelphia, Boston, Pittsburgh, Buffalo, Chicago, Detroit, St
Louis, Cleveland, Minneapolis-St. Paul, Milwaukee, Cincinnati, Kansas City, DC, Dallas, Baltimore, Houston,
Atlanta, Miami, Los Angeles, San Francisco, Seattle, San Diego, Portland, Honolulu, Anchorage, and Denver.
After 1986, prices for 12 of these cities – Buffalo, Minneapolis-St. Paul, Milwaukee, Cincinnati, Kansas City,
Atlanta, San Diego, and Seattle, Portland, Honolulu, Anchorage, and Denver – are reported semiannually.
Therefore, they only included pre-1986 observations for those cities.

31

share of all restaurant workers who work for restaurants that pay the minimum wage using
equation (23).
Average Restaurant Size in High Versus Low Wage Labor Markets,

Z−min
Zmin

We

compute the average number of employees per restaurant in high wage Z−min and low wage
Zmin markets using the 1997 Economic Census for Accommodations and Food Services. Our
definition of a labor market is an MSA. High and low wage cities are determined by the 19901999 average real wage computed from the Outgoing Rotation Files of the CPS. We combine
limited and full service establishments to compute restaurant size from all restaurants. The
results are similar if we look at all eating and drinking places.
We find that restaurants in high wage cities employ roughly 10 percent fewer workers
than in low wage cities. For example, the ratio of restaurant size in the 15 percent of cities
with the highest wages relative to 15 percent of cities with the lowest wages is 0.9.
Admittedly, there is a great deal of restaurant size heterogeneity within a city. Furthermore, much of this heterogeneity could be because local labor markets are smaller than cities.
In order to explore the importance of restaurant size within a city, we measure average restaurant size for full service (which rarely pay the minimum wage) and limited service (which
often pay the minimum wage) restaurants separately.
We find, on average, that limited service restaurants employ a little over 20 percent fewer
workers than full service restaurants across all cities, 10 percent fewer among low wage cities,
and 30 percent fewer among high wage cities. Therefore, using restaurant type,

Z−min
Zmin

is, on

average 1.2 but varies from 1.1 to 1.3.
Given that the range of estimates for

Z−min
Zmin ,

we set it at 1 as our benchmark, but allow

it to vary between 0.9 and 1.3.
The Elasticity of Demand for Food Away From Home, η

There is little compelling

evidence on η for the restaurant industry. Brown (1990) uses 1977 and 1982 cross-sectional
Census data to calculate an η of 0.2 and 1 for food away from home and fast food, respectively.
Piggott’s (2003) estimates, which use time series data and a generalized model of food demand
that nests the main demand systems currently in use, suggest more elastic demand, probably
above 1. Hussain (2004) uses repeated cross section data from the Consumer Expenditure
Survey and carefully controls for some of the endogeneity problems associated with demand

32

estimation. Hussain finds an estimate of 0.2 to 0.3 in the basic specification, although he
obtains estimates of over 1 when he addresses the endogeneity of labor supply and durables.
In our results, we provide estimates when η is between 0.5 and 1.0.
The Elasticity of Substitution Between Labor and Capital, σ

We could not find

estimates of σ for restaurants. On the one hand, this is unfortunate since there is little reason
to expect that factor substitution is equal across industries. In fact, Hamermesh’s (1993)
review of industry- and product-specific σs reveals a fairly broad range of estimates. However,
as Hamermesh stresses, micro-oriented estimates generally do not alter conclusions reached
from studies using aggregated data. Substitution between labor and capital is generally
between 0.5 and 1.0 for the vast majority of industries, with a mean estimate of 0.75 from
Hamermesh’s review of aggregate studies and 0.50 from his review of micro studies. Given
that the overwhelming majority of these studies are based on manufacturing sectors, the
closest parallel to the eating and drinking industry that we could find was Goodwin and
Brester (1995), who analyze the food manufacturing industry and find that σ is roughly 0.9
in the 1970s and 0.5 thereafter.42 Therefore, we allow σ to vary between 0.5 and 0.8.
The Marshallian labor supply elasticities, γ1 and γ2

We set the labor supply elas-

ticity, holding wages at other firms fixed, at γ1 = 5 but examined the robustness of the
results to values between 2 and 10. This range is based on Card and Krueger’s (1995, p.
376) interpretation of γ1 calibrated from estimates of wage elasticities of the hiring and quit
functions. They conclude that while γ1 could vary between 2 and 10, the upper range is more
theoretically and empirically plausible.
We set

1
γ(θ)

=

1
2γ1 ,

an approximation that is exact if θ has a uniform density. However,

we found that all values of

1
γ(θ)

∈ (0, γ11 ) to give very similar results.

Bhaskar and To (1999) and Manning (2003) point out that if the labor market is characterized by monopsonistic competition rather than pure monopsony, then setting γ1 = γ2
calibrated using hire and quit rates will lead to erroneous inference. Under monopsonistic
competition, increases in a firm’s wage reduce the quantity of labor supplied at all other
firms. Because an increase in a binding minimum wage increases the wage of all firms, it will
42
Likewise, Hamermesh’s review of the substitutability between labor and materials suggests similar sized
values. Again, this is consistent with the findings in Goodwin and Brester (1995).

33

have a smaller effect on a firm’s labor supply than just increasing that firm’s wage. Although
for most demographic groups, labor supply elasticities are close to 0, the empirical evidence
is that labor supply is somewhat elastic for low wage groups. Therefore, we set γ2 = 0.5 but
allow it to vary between 0 and 1.

34

Appendix B: Solution to the Model Under Perfect Competition
This appendix shows how to solve for the price and employment responses under perfect
competition. We discuss price and employment responses under constant returns production
(in our case, when K can adjust) below, diminishing returns (when K cannot adjust) in
appendix C, and the monopsony case in appendix D.
The first order conditions for maximization of the profit function in equation (1) shows
that the marginal products of capital, labor, and materials (obtained by differentiating equation (1) with respect to K, L, H and M ) are equal to their relative prices,
∂Q wH
∂L , p

=

∂Q pM
∂H , p

=

∂Q
∂M .

r
p

=

∂Q wL
∂K , p

=

Solving for the marginal products and taking logs of the first order

conditions yields:

σ(ln pM



σ(ln r − ln p) = σ ln αK + ln Q − ln K ,


σ(ln wL − ln p) = σ ln αL + ln Q − ln L ,


σ(ln wH − ln p) = σ ln αH + ln Q − ln H ,


− ln p) = σ ln(1 − αK − αL − αH ) + ln Q − ln M ,

(28)
(29)
(30)
(31)

respectively.
In this appendix, we make use of the following definitions:
d ln Q
d ln H
ν, d ln
wmin ≡ ξ, d ln wmin ≡ −τ . In addition, we define

d ln L
d ln wmin

d ln K
d ln wmin

d ln M
≡ µ, d ln
wmin ≡

≡ −λ (as opposed to

d ln L
d ln wmin

≡

λ in the text) for notational convenience. Note that43

d ln p
=
d ln wmin

d ln Q
d ln wmin
d ln Q
d ln p

=

−τ
.
−η

Differentiating equations (28)-(31) with respect to ln wmin , assuming
43

(32)

d ln r
d ln wmin

= 0,

d ln pM
d ln wmin

=

To derive equation (32), recognize that τ represents the equilibrium output response to a minimum wage
Q
is the ratio of the output response to the price response caused by an
change. Moreover, note that dd ln
ln p
increase in the minimum wage. Because the demand curve for Q does not change in response to the minimum
wage (but the supply curve for Q does), changes in prices and quantities are caused only by the supply curve
Q
= −η.
for Q moving along the demand curve, which has elasticity η. Therefore, ddln
ln p

35

0, and

d ln wH
d ln wmin

= 044 and using (32) yields
τ 
= τ + µ,
η

τ
λ=σ 1−
+ τ,
η
τ 
= τ + ξ,
σ
η
τ 
σ
= τ + ν,
η
σ

(33)
(34)
(35)
(36)

respectively. Inspection of equations (33), (35), and (36) shows that µ = ν = ξ.
In order to obtain the output response to a minimum wage change, differentiate output
with respect to the minimum wage:
∂Q dK
∂Q dL
∂Q dH
∂Q dM
dQ
=
+
+
+
.
dwmin
∂K dwmin
∂L dwmin ∂H dwmin ∂M dwmin
Multiplying both sides by

wmin
Q ,

(37)

inserting equations (33)-(36), and noting that µ = ν = ξ,

equation (37) can be rewritten as:
−τ = (1 − sL )µ + sL (−λ).

(38)

Combining equations (33), (34) and (38) and solving for the unknowns {µ, λ, τ } yields:
λ = (1 − sL )σ + sL η

(39)

which is equation (5) of the text, and
τ = sL η.

(40)

Using equation (32), equation (40) can be rewritten as
d ln p
= sL
d ln wmin

(41)

which is equation (4) of the text.
44

Since a small share of workers (and an even smaller share of the wage bill) is affected by the minimum
wage, the minimum wage likely has small effects on aggregate income and demand. Therefore, the price of
capital, materials, and high skill labor are unlikely to be impacted as well.

36

Appendix C: Labor Demand when Capital Cannot Adjust
When capital cannot adjust, equations (28) and (33) no longer hold. Instead, there is no
capital response: i.e., µ = 0. However, equations (34)-(37) still apply. Now, the analog of
equation (38) is
−τ = (1 − sL − sK )ν + sL (−λ).

(42)

Combing equations (34)-(36) with equation (42) yields
τ=

sL σ
.
sK + (1 − sK ) ση

(43)

Using equations (32) and (43) we get the price response:
sL
d ln p
.
=
η
d ln wmin
sK ( σ ) + (1 − sK )

(44)

Using equations (44), (43) and (34), we get the low skill employment response:
λ=η
where

d ln p
d ln wmin

d ln p
d ln p
+ σ(1 −
)
d ln wmin
d ln wmin

(45)

is defined in equation (44), and high skill employment response:
ξ = (σ − η)

d ln p
.
d ln wmin

(46)

Appendix D: Employment and Price Responses with Heterogeneous Labor
Markets
This appendix shows how to solve for the equilibrium price and employment responses
when firms have monopsony power. To solve the monopsony model, we note that equations
(33), (35), and (36) still hold. However, equation (29) must be replaced by equation (47)
where the marginal product of labor is:



wmin
if wmin ≥ w(L∗∗ )


∂Q
1
=
)wmin if w(L∗ ) ≤ wmin < w(L∗∗ )
(1 + γ(θ)
∂L 


 (1 + 1 )w(L)
if wmin < w(L∗ ).
γ1

37

(47)

1
γ(θ)

∗∗

= (1 +

ln L −ln L
1 ( ln L∗∗ −ln L∗ )
γ1 )

− 1 measures the difference between the wage and the marginal

revenue product of labor, the vertical distance between ln w(L) and ln M RP (L) in figure 1,
and always lies between 0 and

1
γ1

when L is between L∗ and L∗∗ . Note that equation (47)

has three segments; θ determines which of these segments is equal to the marginal product
of labor. As pointed out in the text, we assume that dispersion in θ causes dispersion in the
distribution of wages. Equation (11) shows that for low values of θ, firms need only pay a
low wage in order to obtain a given number of workers. Thus, for a sufficiently low value
of θ, the minimum wage will bind and employment is determined by the intersection of the
minimum wage and the MRPL curve. As θ increases, firms must pay higher market wages in
order to obtain a given number of workers. Therefore, for a sufficiently high value of θ, the
minimum wage will not bind.
When employment is determined by the intersection of the minimum wage and the MRPL
curve, employment is determined in the same way as when a firm is in a perfectly competitive
market. Therefore, the top line of (47) holds and the employment responses are the same
as those in Appendices B and C when capital can and cannot adjust, respectively. However,
when employment is determined by the intersection of the minimum wage and inverse labor
supply curve, equation (45) must be replaced by

λ = −γ2 .

(48)

We solve for when capital can adjust and cannot adjust, respectively. Consider the case where
capital can adjust first. Using equation (47) in place of (34) and assuming that profits are
close to zero, equation (37) can be rewritten as:

−τ = (1 − sL )µ + sL 1 +
for

1
γθ

1 
(−λ)
γ(θ)

(49)

∈ [0, γ11 ]. Combining equations (33), (48), and (49) gives us
τ = −

γ2 (1 +

1
γ(θ) )sL η

σ(1 − sL ) + ηsL

.

(50)

Equation (50) allows us to identify two key objects of interest. First, combining it with

38

equation (33) yields the capital response (which is also equal to the high skill labor response)

µ=

Second, using

d ln p
d ln wmin

γ2 (1 +

1
γ(θ) )sL η




−
σ(1 − sL ) + ηsL


σ
−1 .
η

(51)

= τη , the price response is
1
γ2 (1 + γ(θ)
)sL
d ln p
.
= −
d ln wmin
σ(1 − sL ) + ηsL

(52)

Next, consider the case where capital cannot adjust. Using equation (37), the output
response (i.e., the analog to equation (49)) is

−τ = (1 − sL − sK )ν + sL 1 +

1 
(−λ)
γ(θ)

(53)

Combining equations (35), (48), and (53) gives us
τ = −

γ2 (1 +

1
γ(θ) )sL η


σ(1 − sL − sK ) + η(sL + sK )

(54)

with price response
1
γ2 (1 + γ(θ)
)sL
d ln p
.
= −
d ln wmin
σ(1 − sL − sK ) + η(sL + sK )

(55)

Appendix E: The Relationship Between Labor’s Share and θ
In deriving equations (18) and (19), we assumed that sL and sK do not vary across labor
markets. However, the theory presented above indicates that the factor mix (and thus sL and
sK ) can vary across labor markets, for two reasons. First, even when comparing two labor
markets where the minimum wage binds (and the minimum wage is the same in both markets),
differences in θ can create differences in low skill labor’s share. Second, factor shares vary
across markets where θ is sufficiently low that the minimum wage binds versus labor markets
where θ is sufficiently high that the minimum wage does not bind. We presented evidence
on geographic variation in labor share in the papers appendix. This appendix further shows
that, given the parameter values discussed in Section 3, differences in factor shares across
markets are likely to be small, probably between 0 and 14 percent. Therefore, with both of

39

these pieces of evidence in hand, it seems reasonable to conclude that factor shares do not
vary by labor market.
The goal of this appendix is to show how wages, employment and labor’s share vary with
θ. If θ is low, the minimum wage will be equal to w∗∗ in Figure 2, and employment will
equal L∗∗ . As θ rises, employment falls as employment is determined by the intersection of
the minimum wage and inverse labor supply curves. But, for large values of γ1 (i.e., if the
quantity of labor supplied to the firm is elastic), small changes in θ affect neither wages nor
employment.45
Next, consider the case where the minimum wage is between w∗ and w∗∗ , as in Figure
2. Increasing θ along this range does not affect the wage, because the wage is equal to the
minimum. However, employment declines as θ increases because fewer workers are willing
to work at the minimum wage. If θ is sufficiently high that the minimum wage does not
bind, increases in θ increase wages and reduce employment. As we show below, (low skill)
labor’s share can either increase or decrease with θ, depending on whether the elasticity of
substitution between factors, σ, is less or greater than 1. Based on the evidence discussed in
section 3, we believe σ is less than 1, and therefore higher θ (and therefore a higher wage)
reduces the amount of labor used but increases labor’s share.
The fact that wages are increasing in θ is obvious upon inspection of equation (11). Our
primary interest is in understanding differences in employment caused by differences in wages
that are in turn caused by differences in θ. Our analysis of CPS data indicates that high wage
cities pay, at most, 50% more than relatively low wage cities.
The first order conditions (28), (30), and (31) still hold, although (29) becomes
σ(ln wL − ln p + ln(1 +
Redefine

d ln K
d ln θ



1
)) = σ ln αL + ln Q − ln L .
γ1

d ln Q
≡ µ, ddlnlnM
θ ≡ ν, d ln θ ≡ −τ in addition to

45

d ln H
d ln θ

(56)

L
≡ −ξ, dd ln
ln θ ≡ −λ. Then

To see this point, note that the vertical distance between the inverse log labor supply curve and the log
marginal cost curve is ln(1 + γ11 ) ≈ γ11 . As a result, even if the MRPL curve of the firm is infinitely elastic, the
minimum wage can only increase wages by at most a factor of γ11 and still increase employment. Therefore,
the most that labor supply could increase in a market by raising the minimum wage is ∆ ln L = γ2 ∆ ln w = γγ21 .
To the extent that MRPL curves slope down, employment gains of raising
the minimum wage will be smaller. Given the parameter values in section 3, the employment gains are only
about 10%.

40

equations (33), and (36) still hold. However, equation (34) becomes
λ=σ

 d ln w τ 
−
+ τ,
d ln θ
η

(57)

We assume that increases in θ increase wL and wH equally ( ddlnlnwθL =

d ln wH
d ln θ ).

Because of

this, λ = ξ and thus low and high skill labor have the same elasticities.
Equation (49) must be rewritten as
−τ = (1 − sL − sH )µ − (sH + sL (1 +

1
))λ.
γ(θ)

(58)

Solving for λ yields:
1
)) 
(1 − ση )(sH + sL (1 + γ(θ)
d ln wL
λ=σ
1+
.
sL
σ
σ
d ln θ
η − γ(θ) (1 − η )

Assuming that

sL
γ(θ) (1

− ση ) is small relative to

σ 46
η ,

(59)

equation (59) can be rewritten as


d ln wL
σ + s(η − σ) .
λ=
d ln θ

(60)

In order to calculate the elasticity of low skill labor’s share with respect to the wage, we
calculate:

d ln L d ln wL
d ln sL
=
+
−
d ln θ
d ln θ
d ln θ

d ln wL L + wH H + pM M + rK
d ln θ

.

(61)

Equation (61) can be rewritten as


d wL L + wH H + pM M + rK
d ln wL
θ
d ln sL
.

=(
− λ) −
d ln θ
d ln θ
dθ
wL L + wH H + pM M + rK
(62)
46

sL
Note that γ(θ)
is between 0 and
and η are similar in size. Therefore,
our assumption seems reasonable.

sL
. For reasonable values, this term is less than 0.02. Furthermore, σ
γ1
σ
s
is
likely close to 1, γ(θ)
(1 − ση ) is likely between -0.01 and 0.01, and
η

41

Taking the derivative, noting that µ = ν, λ = ξ and some algebra yields

 d ln wL
d ln sL
= (1 − sL − sH )
−λ−µ
d ln θ
d ln θ

(63)

which can be rewritten as
d ln wL
d ln sL
= (1 − sL − sH )(1 − σ)
.
d ln θ
d ln θ
Dividing both the left and right hand sides by

d ln wL
d ln θ

(64)

gives an elasticity of low skill labor’s

share with respect to wage changes (caused by changes in θ) equal to (1 − sL − sH )(1 − σ).
Given that most estimates of σ are between 0.5 and 1, sL + sH is approximately .3, and wage
differentials between high wage and low wage markets are equal to wagedif f = 1.5, the log
differential in low skill labor’s share is between 0 and (1 − .3)(1 − .5)(ln 1.5 − ln 1) = .14 log
points, or 14%.

Appendix F: Labor Demand Under Monopolistic Competition when Capital
Can Adjust
In this appendix we augment the model to allow for monopolistic competition in the
product market, although we note that the results in this section hold if firms are monopolists
in the product market as well. The critical assumption is that there is a constant elasticity
of demand. If this is the case, there is a constant mark-up over marginal cost. Consequently,
increases in labor cost are pushed onto the consumer, as is the case under perfect competition.
In this appendix, we show that equilibrium elasticities are the same as in Appendix B.
We assume that consumers have the utility function



U = U Q0 , Q̃

where Q0 is the numeraire good, Q̃ ≡



1−ηZ
N
n=1 Qn



(65)
1
ηZ −1

and Qn denotes output at the nth

restaurant. Furthermore, we assume that the aggregator U (., .) is such that
d ln Q̃
= −η
d ln p̃
where p̃ is the price index associated with Q̃ : p̃ ≡
42

(66)


ηZ −1

ηZ
N
n=1 pn



ηZ
ηZ −1

. Equation (66) is

satisfied if U (., .) is a CES aggregator and the share of income spent on Q̃ is close to 0. Dixit
and Stiglitz (1977) point out that two-stage budgeting techniques can be used to analyze this
consumer demand problem. In the second stage the consumer solves:
N


max

{Qn }N
n=1

Z
Q1−η
n



1
1−ηZ

(67)

n=1

subject to
N


pn Qn = X,

(68)

n=1

where X is total expenditure on Q̃. The consumer’s first order condition for utility maximization yields

pn = ζ −1

Qn
Q̃

−ηZ
(69)

where ζ is the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint. If N is sufficiently large, then
Qn is small relative to Q̃ and thus the firm does not take into account the effect of Qn on Q̃
when assessing the effect of Qn on pn .
Therefore, the nth firm’s problem is to maximize
Z
− rKn − wmin Ln − wH Hn − pM Mn
π(Kn , Ln ) = ΩQ1−η
n

(70)

where Ω = ζ −1 Q̃ηZ . The first order conditions for profit maximization are:
wmin = Ω(1 −

r = Ω(1 −

Z
ηZ )Q−η
αL
n

Z
αK
ηZ )Q−η
n

wH = Ω(1 −

Z
ηZ )Q−η
αH
n

43

Qn
Ln

Qn
Kn

1−ρ
(71)

1−ρ

Qn
Hn

,

(72)

1−ρ
,

(73)

pM = Ω(1 −

Z
ηZ )Q−η
(1
n

Qn
− αL − αH − αK )
Kn

1−ρ
,

(74)

Taking logs of both sides of equations (71)-(74) and differentiating with respect to ln wmin
yields
d ln Q̃
d ln Qn
1
d ln ζ
+ ηZ
− ηZ
+
1=−
d ln wmin
d ln wmin
d ln wmin σ

1
d ln Q̃
d ln Qn
d ln ζ
+ ηZ
− ηZ
+
0=−
d ln wmin
d ln wmin
d ln wmin σ

1
d ln Q̃
d ln Qn
d ln ζ
+ ηZ
− ηZ
+
0=−
d ln wmin
d ln wmin
d ln wmin σ

1
d ln Q̃
d ln Qn
d ln ζ
+ ηZ
− ηZ
+
0=−
d ln wmin
d ln wmin
d ln wmin σ
Observation of equations (76)-(78) shows that

d ln Kn
d ln wmin

=









d ln Qn
d ln Ln
−
d ln wmin d ln wmin




d ln Qn
d ln Kn
−
.
d ln wmin d ln wmin

d ln Qn
d ln Hn
−
.
d ln wmin d ln wmin

d ln Qn
d ln Mn
−
.
d ln wmin d ln wmin

d ln Hn
d ln wmin

=

(75)

(76)

(77)

(78)

d ln Mn
d ln wmin .

Note that in equilibrium all firms produce the same amount and thus prices pn are equal.
Using the definition of the aggregate quantity index Q̃ and price index p̃ we obtain
1

Q̃ = N 1−ηZ Qn

ηZ

(79)

p̃ = N ηZ −1 pn .

(80)

d ln Qn
d ln Q̃
=
.
d ln wmin
d ln wmin

(81)

Inspection of equation (79) shows that

44

Moreover, equations (69), (79), and (80) show that
d ln p̃
d ln ζ
=−
.
d ln wmin
d ln wmin

(82)

Inserting equations (81) and (82) into equations (75) and (76) gives equations (34) and (33).
In order to get the output response to a change in the minimum wage, differentiate output
with respect to the minimum wage, as in equation (37). Note, however, that the marginal
products of capital and labor, and materials are:
r
∂Qn
=
∂Kn
pn (1 −

1
ηZ )

(83)

∂Qn
wmin
.
=
∂Ln
pn (1 − η1Z )

(84)

wH
∂Qn
=
∂Hn
pn (1 − η1Z )

(85)

pM
∂Qn
=
∂Mn
pn (1 −

(86)

Using equation (37), multiplying both sides by

wmin
Q

1 .
ηZ )

and using equations (83) and (84) yields



wmin Ln d ln Ln
1
rKn d ln Kn
wH Hn d ln Hn
pM Mn d ln Mn
d ln Qn
=
+
+
+
.
d ln wmin
pn Qn d ln wmin
pn Qn d ln wmin
(1 − η1Z ) pn Qn d ln wmin pn Qn d ln wmin
(87)
Note that pn Qn (1 −

1
ηZ )

= wmin Ln + rKn + wH Hn + pM Mn . Inserting this into equation

(87) gives equation (38), where sL =
d ln Qn
d ln wmin

=

d ln Q
d ln wmin ,

wL
wmin L+rK+wH H+pM M .

Because all firms are identical,

where Q is aggregate output of all restaurants. Given that the equations

and unknowns are the same as in Appendix B, the resulting elasticities are the same as in
Appendix B.
Although all elasticities are the same as before, special care must be made in interpreting
labor’s share, sL . Labor’s share is labor’s share of the firm’s costs, not labor’s share of the
45

firm’s revenue. If the firm makes an economic profit, then the two will not be the same.
Lastly, we note that if firms are monopsonists in the labor market, the employment
response to minimum wage change is as in equation (48). Therefore, the output response is
determined by equations (28), (38) and (48), and thus the price response is the same as in
equation (52).

Appendix G: Aggregation
In this appendix, we discuss some of the aggregation issues that were described briefly in
Section 2.6. Specifically, we derive prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) and sL using other parameters.
First, we show how to infer prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )). We have information on the share of
restaurant workers who are paid the minimum wage, prob(wmin = wi ), the fraction of workers
who are low skill, prob(L) (recall that this fraction is identical for all restaurants), as well as
the average number of workers per restaurant that pay low skill workers at and above the
minimum wage, Zmin . To see how these objects can identify the probability that a restaurant
pays the minimum wage, note:
N × prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) × prob(L) × Zmin = I × prob(wmin = wi )

(88)

where N is the total number of restaurants and I is the total number of restaurant workers.
The left hand side of equation (88) is the number of minimum wage workers employed (the
employer side) and the right hand side is equal to the number of individuals who report
working in the restaurant industry and also report being paid the minimum wage (i.e., the
household side). Rearranging equation (88), we get:
prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) =
I
N

prob(wmin = wi )
I
× .
prob(L)Zmin
N

(89)

can be identified using information on the relationship between the total number of workers

employed by the restaurant industry, as measured from both the employer and household side:
N prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) × Zmin + N prob(wmin < w(L∗ )) × Z−min = I

(90)

where Z−min is the number of employees per restaurant that pay above the minimum wage.
Combining equations (89) and (90) yields the relationship between the object of interest

46

prob(wmin < w(L∗ )) and the object we obtain from known data sources:
∗

prob(wmin ≥ w(L )) =

1−

prob(wmin =wi ) Z−min
Zmin
prob(L)
prob(wmin =wi )
prob(wmin =wi ) Z−min
+
Zmin
prob(L)
prob(L)

(91)

which is equation (20) of the text.
Next, we infer sL . We do this by matching both the share of restaurant workers paid the
minimum wage and also their share of the total wage bill, which we define as:

E

1
I


i=1 wi 1{wi = wmin }


1 I
E I i=1 wi

I

(92)

where wi is the wage of individual i, and 1{wi = wmin } is a 0-1 indicator equal to 1 when
wi = wmin , and is equal to 0 otherwise. In order to proceed, we note that the numerator of
equation (92) is equal to (prob(wmin = wi ) × wmin ), where prob(wmin = wi ) is the probability
that an individual is both low skill and works for a low wage firm, i.e., prob(wmin = wi ) =
prob(L, lowwage). Because by assumption the share of all workers that are low skill does
not vary by labor market, firms in high wage and low wage markets employ high skill and
low skill workers in equal proportions, prob(wmin = wi ) = prob(L)prob(lowwage). Similar
reasoning can be used to obtain the probability that an individual is low skill and works in a
high wage market, that an individual is high skill and works for in a low wage market, and
that individual is high skill and works for in a high wage market. Wages for low skill-low
wage labor market, low skill-high wage labor market, high skill-low wage labor market, and
high skill-high wage labor market workers are: wmin , (wmin × wagedif f ), ( wwHL × wmin ), and
( wwHL × wagedif f × wmin ), respectively. Now, equation (92) can be rewritten as:
prob(L)prob(lowwage)wmin



A prob(lowwage) + A((1 − prob(lowwage)) × wagedif f ) wmin

(93)

where
A = (prob(L) + (1 − prob(L))

47

wH 
.
wL

(94)

Using equation (91) and prob(wmin = wi ) = prob(L) × prob(lowwage) it is straightforward
to show that:
prob(lowwage) =

prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ))
prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ) + (1 − prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) ZZ−min
.
min

(95)

Using equations (93) and (95),
minimum wage labor’s share of the total wage bill =
prob(L)prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ ))



A × prob(wmin ≥

w(L∗ ))

+ (1 − prob(wmin ≥

w(L∗ )))



∗ wagedif f ∗

Z−min 
Zmin

(96)

where wagedif f is the wage differential between high wage and low wage areas (caused by
differences in θ), and

wH
wL

is the ratio of wages of high skilled workers to low skilled workers.

If all restaurants paid the minimum wage (i.e., if prob(wmin ≥ w(L∗ )) = 1), then equation
(96) would be equal
Because

sL
sL +sH

=

sL
sL +sH .
prob(L)
w
prob(L)+(1−prob(L)) wH

, it is straightforward to use equation (96) to derive

L

equation (21).

48

Table 1: Parameters of the model
Parameters

Price pass-through,
d ln p
]
E[
d ln wmin

Baseline
(range of values considered
in robustness checks)
0.05 and 0.07

Labor’s share, s L + s H

0.30 (0.25 to 0.35)

Capital’s share, s k

0.30 (0.25 to 0.35)

Source

Aaronson (2001) and
Aaronson et al (2005)
1997 Economic Census
for Accommodations
and Food Services; IRS
Statistics on Income
Bulletin; 10-K reports
10-K reports

0.40 (0.35 to 0.45)
10-K reports
Material’s share, s M
Share of Minimum wage
0.33 (0.25 to 0.40)
Estimated from the CPS
workers, prob( wmin = wi )
Minimum wage labor’s share
0.17
Estimated from the CPS
of total wage bill
Fraction of workers that are
0.70 (0.60 to 0.80)
Aaronson et al (2005)
low skill, prob(L)
Ratio of wages in high wage
1.5
Estimated from the CPS
and low wage labor markets,
wagediff
1997 Economic Census
Ratio of the average restaurant 1 (0.9 to 1.3)
for Accommodations
employment in high and low
and Food Services
Z − min
]
wage markets,
Z min
Elasticity of demand for food
0.5 and 1.0
Piggott (2003); Hussain
(2004)
η
away from home,
Elasticity of substitution
0.5 and 0.8
Hamermesh (1993)
between labor and capital, σ
5 (2 to 10)
Card and Krueger
Marshallian labor supply
(1995)
elasticity, γ 1
0.5 (0 to 1)
Marshallian labor supply
elasticity, γ 2
1
1
1
(0 to
)
2γ 1
γ1
γ ( L)
Notes: See the appendix for a detailed description of how these parameter values were
determined.

Table 2: Estimates of λ Under Different Assumptions about Labor Market Structure,
Price Responses, the Elasticity of Demand for Food Away from Home (η ), and the
Elasticity of Substitution between Labor and Capital ( σ ).

Parameter
Assumptions

Competitive low skill
The extent
employment response
of monopsony
1
( λcomp * prob( wmin > w*) ) power
(V)

(1)

(2)

Employment response
when the extent of
monopsony power is
included
Low
High
Total
Skill
Skill
(3)
(4)
(5)

d ln p
] = 0.07
d ln wmin
η = 0.5,σ = 0.8
-0.36
0.98
-0.34
0.02
-0.23
η = 1.0, σ = 0.8
-0.39
1.10
-0.45
-0.01
-0.32
η = 0.5,σ = 0.5
-0.23
1.04
-0.25
0.00
-0.18
η = 1.0, σ = 0.5
-0.26
1.21
-0.36
-0.04
-0.26
d ln p
Price response E[
] = 0.05
d ln wmin
η = 0.5,σ = 0.8
-0.36
0.82
-0.25
0.02
-0.17
η = 1.0, σ = 0.8
-0.39
0.90
-0.33
-0.01
-0.23
η = 0.5,σ = 0.5
-0.23
0.89
-0.19
0.00
-0.13
η = 1.0, σ = 0.5
-0.26
1.00
-0.26
-0.03
-0.19
Notes: See text for details. See table 1 and the appendix for other parameter values used.
1
See equation 19. A number below 1 implies monopsony power.
Price response E[

Table 3: Estimates of Price and Low Skill Employment Responses Under Different
Assumptions About Aggregation
Estimates

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

0.099
d ln p
]) under Perfect Competition
d ln wmin
-0.109
d ln p
Price response ( E[
]) under Monopsony
d ln wmin
The extent of Monopsony power (V)
0.86
Price response ( E[

Total employment response:
Under Perfect Competition
Under Monopsony
Weighted by V
Heterogeneity in skill type
Heterogeneity in labor market type

-0.17
0.17
-0.12

0.051

0.064

-0.056

-0.071

1.18

1.04

-0.17
0.17
-0.22

-0.17
0.17
-0.18

No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
d ln p
Note: See text for detail. We use η = 0.5, σ = 0.5 , E[
] = 0.07 and the parameter
d ln wmin
values from table 2. Wagediff is set to 1.5 for models 2 and 3 and is set to match
minimum wage labor’s share of the total wage bill and prob(wmin=wi) in model 1.

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Dynamic Monetary Equilibrium in a Random-Matching Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-00-1

The Effects of Health, Wealth, and Wages on Labor Supply and Retirement Behavior
Eric French

WP-00-2

Market Discipline in the Governance of U.S. Bank Holding Companies:
Monitoring vs. Influencing
Robert R. Bliss and Mark J. Flannery

WP-00-3

Using Market Valuation to Assess the Importance and Efficiency
of Public School Spending
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse
Employment Flows, Capital Mobility, and Policy Analysis
Marcelo Veracierto
Does the Community Reinvestment Act Influence Lending? An Analysis
of Changes in Bank Low-Income Mortgage Activity
Drew Dahl, Douglas D. Evanoff and Michael F. Spivey

WP-00-4

WP-00-5

WP-00-6

Subordinated Debt and Bank Capital Reform
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-00-7

The Labor Supply Response To (Mismeasured But) Predictable Wage Changes
Eric French

WP-00-8

For How Long Are Newly Chartered Banks Financially Fragile?
Robert DeYoung

WP-00-9

Bank Capital Regulation With and Without State-Contingent Penalties
David A. Marshall and Edward S. Prescott

WP-00-10

Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care?
Susanto Basu and John Fernald

WP-00-11

Oligopoly Banking and Capital Accumulation
Nicola Cetorelli and Pietro F. Peretto

WP-00-12

Puzzles in the Chinese Stock Market
John Fernald and John H. Rogers

WP-00-13

The Effects of Geographic Expansion on Bank Efficiency
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-00-14

Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Employment Dynamics
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-00-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Post-Resolution Treatment of Depositors at Failed Banks: Implications for the Severity
of Banking Crises, Systemic Risk, and Too-Big-To-Fail
George G. Kaufman and Steven A. Seelig

WP-00-16

The Double Play: Simultaneous Speculative Attacks on Currency and Equity Markets
Sujit Chakravorti and Subir Lall

WP-00-17

Capital Requirements and Competition in the Banking Industry
Peter J.G. Vlaar

WP-00-18

Financial-Intermediation Regime and Efficiency in a Boyd-Prescott Economy
Yeong-Yuh Chiang and Edward J. Green

WP-00-19

How Do Retail Prices React to Minimum Wage Increases?
James M. MacDonald and Daniel Aaronson

WP-00-20

Financial Signal Processing: A Self Calibrating Model
Robert J. Elliott, William C. Hunter and Barbara M. Jamieson

WP-00-21

An Empirical Examination of the Price-Dividend Relation with Dividend Management
Lucy F. Ackert and William C. Hunter

WP-00-22

Savings of Young Parents
Annamaria Lusardi, Ricardo Cossa, and Erin L. Krupka

WP-00-23

The Pitfalls in Inferring Risk from Financial Market Data
Robert R. Bliss

WP-00-24

What Can Account for Fluctuations in the Terms of Trade?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-00-25

Data Revisions and the Identification of Monetary Policy Shocks
Dean Croushore and Charles L. Evans

WP-00-26

Recent Evidence on the Relationship Between Unemployment and Wage Growth
Daniel Aaronson and Daniel Sullivan

WP-00-27

Supplier Relationships and Small Business Use of Trade Credit
Daniel Aaronson, Raphael Bostic, Paul Huck and Robert Townsend

WP-00-28

What are the Short-Run Effects of Increasing Labor Market Flexibility?
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-00-29

Equilibrium Lending Mechanism and Aggregate Activity
Cheng Wang and Ruilin Zhou

WP-00-30

Impact of Independent Directors and the Regulatory Environment on Bank Merger Prices:
Evidence from Takeover Activity in the 1990s
Elijah Brewer III, William E. Jackson III, and Julapa A. Jagtiani
Does Bank Concentration Lead to Concentration in Industrial Sectors?
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-00-31

WP-01-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
On the Fiscal Implications of Twin Crises
Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo

WP-01-02

Sub-Debt Yield Spreads as Bank Risk Measures
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-01-03

Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald and Matthew D. Shapiro

WP-01-04

Do Regulators Search for the Quiet Life? The Relationship Between Regulators and
The Regulated in Banking
Richard J. Rosen
Learning-by-Doing, Scale Efficiencies, and Financial Performance at Internet-Only Banks
Robert DeYoung
The Role of Real Wages, Productivity, and Fiscal Policy in Germany’s
Great Depression 1928-37
Jonas D. M. Fisher and Andreas Hornstein

WP-01-05

WP-01-06

WP-01-07

Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Charles L. Evans

WP-01-08

Outsourcing Business Service and the Scope of Local Markets
Yukako Ono

WP-01-09

The Effect of Market Size Structure on Competition: The Case of Small Business Lending
Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Rosen and Gregory F. Udell

WP-01-10

Deregulation, the Internet, and the Competitive Viability of Large Banks
and Community Banks
Robert DeYoung and William C. Hunter

WP-01-11

Price Ceilings as Focal Points for Tacit Collusion: Evidence from Credit Cards
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-01-12

Gaps and Triangles
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-01-13

A Real Explanation for Heterogeneous Investment Dynamics
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-01-14

Recovering Risk Aversion from Options
Robert R. Bliss and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou

WP-01-15

Economic Determinants of the Nominal Treasury Yield Curve
Charles L. Evans and David Marshall

WP-01-16

Price Level Uniformity in a Random Matching Model with Perfectly Patient Traders
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-01-17

Earnings Mobility in the US: A New Look at Intergenerational Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-18

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Effects of Health Insurance and Self-Insurance on Retirement Behavior
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-01-19

The Effect of Part-Time Work on Wages: Evidence from the Social Security Rules
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-01-20

Antidumping Policy Under Imperfect Competition
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-01-21

Is the United States an Optimum Currency Area?
An Empirical Analysis of Regional Business Cycles
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-01-22

A Note on the Estimation of Linear Regression Models with Heteroskedastic
Measurement Errors
Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-01-23

The Mis-Measurement of Permanent Earnings: New Evidence from Social
Security Earnings Data
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-24

Pricing IPOs of Mutual Thrift Conversions: The Joint Effect of Regulation
and Market Discipline
Elijah Brewer III, Douglas D. Evanoff and Jacky So

WP-01-25

Opportunity Cost and Prudentiality: An Analysis of Collateral Decisions in
Bilateral and Multilateral Settings
Herbert L. Baer, Virginia G. France and James T. Moser

WP-01-26

Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg
Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-06

WP-02-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Structural Empirical Model of Firm Growth, Learning, and Survival
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

7