View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A S eries of O c c a sio n a l Papers in D raft Form P re p ared by M e m b e rs 'o

TH E PRO BLEM S OF M O N ETA R Y C O N TR O L
U N D ER Q UA SI — C O N TEM PO RA N EO U S RESERVES
Robert D. Laurent

SM-84-5
March 1985

The Problems of Monetary Control Under Quasi - Contemporaneous Reserves

by

Robert 0. Laurent
Department of Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The views expressed herein are solely those of the author and do not
necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the
Federal Reserve System. The material contained 1s of a preliminary nature, 1s
circulated to stimulate discussion, and not to be quoted without permission.







2

In recent years the reserve accounting system used by the Federal Reserve
has received a great deal of attention.

In particular, after the Fed

announced the adoption of a reserve targeting procedure of monetary control 1n
October 1979, there was strong and mounting criticism of lagged reserve
accounting.

In response, the Fed adopted a "contemporaneous" reserve system

1n February, 1984.

This new reserve accounting system appears to have pleased

many critics of lagged reserve accounting who apparently see the new system as
a solution to the problems posed by lagged reserves for a reserve targeting
procedure.

This paper examines the motivation behind, and the effects of the

move to the new reserve accounting system.
The monetary policy history of the last two decades has been replete with
changes 1n reserve accounting or operating procedures which have failed to
produce the effects Intended.

The adoption of lagged reserves Itself 1n 1968

produced exactly the opposite effects from the expected results that motivated
the adoption of the system.1

The adoption of reserve targeting 1n 1979

produced an Increase 1n short-run deposit volatility rather than the Intended
decrease.

2

Other changes such as operating through RPO's (reserves against

private deposits) proved simply Impossible to Implement.

This history

suggests that changes 1n reserve accounting or operating procedure have often
been advocated and/or adopted without a true understanding of either the
nature or consequences of the changes.

In the vernacular, changes 1n reserve

*The author has benefited from the comments of Herb Baer, Anne Marie
Gonczy, George Kanatas, Paul Kasrlel, Randy Merrls, Ed Nash, Larry Mote, Mary
Rosenbaum, Steve Strongln, and Vefa Tarhan. Any remaining errors are entirely
the responsibility of the author.
^See the paper by (Burger) and the article by (Coates).
^Laurent (1982)




3

accounting or operating procedure have often been a "pig 1n a poke."

The

analysis 1n this paper suggests that the new reserve accounting system 1s but
the newest "pig 1n a poke".
This paper argues that the reserve accounting system adopted 1n February,
1984 differs 1n Its monetary control properties 1n a substantive way from the
contemporaneous reserve system that those who advocated the change suppose 1t
to be.

The major reason for this difference 1s the existence of a two day lag

1n the new system, making 1t , 1n fact, a quasl-contemporaneous reserve
system.

The paper argues that the two day lag 1n the quasl-contemporaneous

system significantly changes the role of the monetary authority under a
reserve targeting procedure and raises both the costs of reserve management
for banks and the level and volatility of excess reserves 1n the banking
system above that of a true contemporaneous reserve system.

The analysis 1n

the paper shows quasl-contemporaneous reserves, while Inferior to
contemporaneous reserves, to be a potential Improvement over the previous
lagged reserve system.

However, the potential Improvement 1s likely to be

minor and obtained at both Increased adjustment costs to the banks and a
Increased complexity, which could easily lead observers to the erroneous
conclusion that reserve accounting changes have little potential for Improving
monetary control.
Perhaps as Interesting as the analysis of the effects of a switch to
quasl-contemporaneous reserves 1s the paper's analysis of the reason why so
many critics of lagged reserves failed to understand that the new reserve
accounting system 1s not a true contemporaneous system,
difference 1s Important.

and why the

The paper argues that this failure stems from a

widely held, but Inappropriate model of money stock determination that
utilizes a mechanistic multiplier approach where changes 1n reserves lead
directly to changes 1n money.




The paper argues for a model 1n which the

4

impact of reserves on deposits works through its influence on interest rates.
This latter approach reveals a potentially substantive difference in monetary
control between quasi-contemporaneous and contemporaneous reserves.
The first section of the paper discusses the connection between reserve
accounting and monetary control and presents two contrasting views of the
money stock determination mechanism.

The second section contrasts the

monetary control problems of lagged reserves as perceived through these two
differing views of money stock determination.

Section three describes the

difficulties of operating a reserve targeting procedure under the
quasi-contemporaneous reserve system and how it differs from the usual
conception of a reserve targeting monetary control system.

The fourth section

contrasts the monetary control properties of quasi-contemporaneous and
contemporaneous reserves under a reserve targeting procedure.

Conclusions are

presented in section five.
I
Though present discussions of reserve accounting are inextricably
intertwined with monetary control, reserve requirements were originally
imposed in 1864 for the purposes of increasing bank liquidity.

At that time

monetary control was not even considered a goal of monetary policy.
not become an accepted goal of monetary policy until the 1970s.

It did

Even after

the monetary authority adopted a money stock goal for monetary policy, a
controversy remained over whether superior monetary control was obtained by
targeting interest rates or by targeting reserves.

Through most of the 1970s

the monetary authority attempted to control money through an interest rate
targeting procedure.

As long as monetary control was attempted through

interest rate targeting, little attention was paid to the reserve accounting
system.




It was only with the announcement by the Fed of a reserve targeting

5

procedure of monetary control that the Impact of reserve accounting on
monetary control attained Importance.

To understand the development of the

association between reserve accounting and monetary control it 1s helpful to
understand both the common perception and the actual mechanism of money stock
determination through reserves.
Banks change the money stock by exchanging earning assets with the
public.

If banks buy earning assets (1.e make loans or buy securities) they

Increase the money stock while 1f they sell earning assets (1.e reduce their
loans outstanding or sell securities) they reduce the money stock.

The

analysis of money stock determination then, 1s essentially an analysis of what
Induces banks to exchange earning assets with the public.

The standard

description of the process of deposit expansion or contraction 1n the
elementary money and banking textbooks 1s that the level of excess reserves
determines money expansion or contraction.

In the usual textbook scenario a

bank eliminates Its excess reserves or reserve deficiency by purchasing or
selling a quantity of earning assets equal to its excess or deficiency 1n
reserves.

This first bank's adjustment then disturbs another bank's deposits

(and excess reserves) by a somewhat smaller amount.

This process continues

until the banking system comes to an equilibrium 1n which, according to the
textbook scenario, required reserves have been equated to the level of
reserves.

The banking system thus comes to equilibrium through a series of

successively smaller adjustments by Individual banks.
One widely held view, characterized here as the "mechanistic multiplier"
view, of the relationship between reserves and money stock determination seems
to approach the Issue much 1n the spirit of the standard textbook approach.
In this "mechanistic multiplier" approach, changes 1n the level of reserves
are believed to Induce a proportional change 1n deposits through the operation




6

of a money "multiplier" which magnifies and transmits the effect of changes 1n
reserves onto money.

The typical adherent of the "mechanistic multiplier"

view of money stock determination may acknowledge that 1n the very short run
the multiplier might be erratic, but the multiplier 1s viewed as sufficiently
stable, over the longer periods of time considered Important for monetary
policy (e.g. a quarter) to guarantee reasonably accurate monetary control.
The typical "mechanistic multiplier" adherent can cite extensive empirical
evidence of the stability of the money multiplier over longer periods of
time.

The Implication 1s that such multipliers can be used to forecast the

monetary control properties of a reserve targeting policy.

However, the

operation of the mechanism that underlies the multiplier 1s seldom detailed,
but presumably Involves something akin to the mechanism 1n the standard
textbook description of the deposit expansion or contraction process - where
banks react to excess reserves and reserve deficiencies.

It 1s probably true

that the great majority of those who have criticized lagged reserves and
advocated the adoption of contemporaneous reserves since the adoption of
reserve targeting could properly be classified as adherents of the
"mechanistic multiplier" approach to money stock determination.
However useful the textbook scenario may be as a pedagogical device for
demonstrating the ability of banks to produce a multiple expansion or
contraction 1n the money stock from a given change 1n reserves, 1t 1s clearly
not an accurate description of the reaction of banks that alters the level of
deposits and the money stock.

In practice, banks have available a federal

funds market where they may buy or sell reserves at the current federal funds
rate.

Banks, therefore, do not feel obligated to move their earning assets to

conform to the level of deposits they have attracted.

Rather, the price of

reserve credit relative to the return available on bank earning assets
determines whether a bank Increases or decreases Its earning assets purchased



7

from the public and therefore Increases or decreases the money stock.

For

example, even a bank currently deficient 1n reserves will extend additional
loans or purchase securities, and thereby Increase the money stock, 1f the
rate on current and expected future federal funds 1s low enough.

The bank

acts as an Intermediary and simply purchases enough federal funds to cover the
reserve loss from the purchase of new assets as well as cover Its original
deficiency.

Conversely, a high federal funds rate will Induce banks to reduce

their holdings of securities and loans (thereby reducing deposits) and channel
the funds obtained Into the federal funds market.
This view of bank behavior 1s consistent with the fact that many large
banks continuously purchase, and many small banks continuously sell funds 1n
the federal funds market.

This pattern reflects a profit maximizing

adjustment by banks to a situation where, 1n the absence of federal funds
transactions, the rate on the marginal earning asset 1s above the federal
funds rate at large banks and below the federal funds rate at small banks.

In

many cases, large banks consistently purchase more reserves 1n federal funds
than their level of required reserves, so that without these funds the banks
would not only be deficient, they would actually have negative levels of
reserves.

If banks mechanistically responded to tne level of reserves

associated with their deposits, these banks would long since have reduced
their earning asset holdings to cover the potential reserve deficiency.
In this "Interest rate" view of money stock determination the Impact of
the federal funds rate on bank behavior and the money stock 1s clear.

The

higher 1s the federal funds rate, the higher will banks expect future federal
funds rates to be, and the fewer earning assets purchased from the public a
bank will hold and the lower the level of deposits created by the bank.

Banks

compare the return expected on an earning asset that could be purchased from
the public over some period of time with the return expected on federal funds



8

rolled over dally during the same period.

At higher expected federal funds

rates lending 1n the federal funds market will appear more attractive and
lending to the public less attractive.

Thus, a higher federal funds rate

leads to a lower money stock and a lower federal funds rate leads to a higher
money stock.

The Important point to emphasize 1s that 1t 1s the federal funds

rate and not the level of reserves that 1s the proximate determinant of
changes 1n the level of deposits and money.

Most Importantly, for the

analysis that follows, 1t 1s critical to understand that 1f perchance the
reserve accounting system allowed a discrepancy 1n the signals sent to the
banking system by reserves and Interest rates, 1t 1s Interest rates, and not
reserves, that will determine the actual money stock changes.
As noted earlier, there has long been a controversy between advocates of
reserve targeting and the previous Fed policy of Interest rate targeting with
regard to the better method of monetary control.

If as 1n the "Interest rate"

view of money stock determination, Interest rates determine changes 1n the
money stock, can 1t make any sense to advocate a reserve targeting procedure?
It will be argued here that 1t 1s perfectly defensible to argue for a reserve
targeting procedure of monetary control even 1n the "Interest rate" view of
money stock determination, but 1t must be understood that such an argument 1s
actually a call for a specific automatic mechanism for setting the price of
reserve credit (i.e. the federal funds rate).

Conceptually, the mechanism 1s

designed to automatically move the federal funds rate to facilitate monetary
control.

Under such a mechanism, the monetary authority first sets the level

of reserves that 1t believes corresponds to the desired level of the aggregate
that 1t wishes to control.

In this respect the "Interest rate" view 1s no

different than the "mechanistic multiplier" view of a reserve targeting
procedure.

The difference lies 1n the delineation of the mechanism that

underlies the money control mechanism.



9

In the "mechanistic multiplier" view, the setting of reserves seems almost
automatically to lead to deposits (and required reserves) moving Into
equilibrium with the level of reserves.

In the "Interest rate" view the level

of reserves tethers an automatic mechanism that moves the federal funds rate
to a level that produces a money stock consistent with the level of reserves
provided.

If the actual level of deposits 1s such that required reserves

(which should, with properly set reserve requirements, correspond to the level
of the target aggregate) are too low for the level of reserves provided, then
the federal funds rate should fall.

As 1t falls, it Induces banks to increase

their holdings of earning assets purchased from the public and thereby
Increase the target aggregate.

This process continues until the target

aggregate changes enough to move required reserves Into equilibrium with
reserves.

The monetary authority simply sets the level of reserves.

After

that the market 1s left to determine the federal funds rate on the basis of
the difference between reserves and required reserves.

Reserve targeting, as

Interpreted by the "Interest rate" view of money stock determination does not
deny the Importance of Interest rates, but argues for a system 1n which
Interest rates are guided automatically by the market.

Having set a

predetermined level of reserves, reserve targeting relies on there being no
Interference placed on the movements 1n the federal funds

rate by the

monetary authority.
II
Even after the monetary authority adopted a monetary target goal 1n the
1970s, 1t continued to operate by setting a federal funds rate.

It proved

extremely difficult, however, to know what rate was appropriate for the
desired level of the money stock.

It was frustration with this approach that

led to the announcement of a shift to a reserve targeting procedure 1n
October, 1979.



The shift was Initially greeted with enthusiasm by adherents

10

of money stock control through reserve targeting.

Increasingly though,

advocates of money stock control through reserve targeting began to complain
about the effects of lagged reserves on the Implementation of a reserve
targeting procedure.
As long as the monetary authority had Implemented policy by setting a
federal funds rate, little attention was paid to the reserve accounting
system.

To one who holds a "mechanistic multiplier" view of money stock

determination, an Interest rate targeting procedure means that the monetary
authority will essentially move reserves to parallel changes in the level of
required reserves.

It rules out a policy of hitting some pre-determ1ned

target level of total reserves.

From the "interest rate" view of money stock

determination, the problem of an interest rate targeting procedure 1s that
Interest rates are being determined by the monetary authority rather than the
automatic mechanism that underlies a reserve targeting procedure.

In either

view, Interest rate targeting by the monetary authority makes the reserve
accounting system irrelevant for monetary control.
The Fed announcement 1n October, 1979 that 1t was shifting from an
Interest rate targeting procedure to a reserve targeting procedure, brought
Increased scrutiny to the lagged reserve accounting system.

The problem most

often Identified with lagged reserves under a reserve targeting procedure 1s
the fact that the monetary authority must supply a level of reserves at least
equal to the level of required reserves set by the banking system two weeks
earlier.

Thus, the monetary authority is constrained from supplying a level

of reserves below the level of required reserves set by the banking system two
weeks earlier.

This constraint 1s effective when the monetary target 1s far

enough below the actual level of deposits two weeks earlier to cause required
reserves 1n the current week to be above the level of reserves the monetary
authority would like to provide.



The problem this poses 1n the "mechanistic

n

multiplier" view of money stock determination, where reserves lead directly to
money, 1s that the monetary authority 1s precluded from producing the decline
3
1n reserves necessary to reduce an excessive level of deposits.
Indeed, an analysis of a contractionary reserve targeting policy under
lagged reserves 1s very Informative 1n contrasting the validity of the
"mechanistic multiplier" and "Interest rate" views of the relationship between
reserves and money.

If required reserves are above the monetary authority's

target level of reserves then 1t 1s clear that more reserves must be provided
than the monetary authority would wish.

When confronted with this constraint,

the typical adherent of a "mechanistic multiplier" view might concede that 1t
may be necessary to provide more reserves than desired 1n the current
settlement period, but that sticking to a slower rate of reserve growth over
the longer run would produce slower deposit growth.

This observation 1s

correct, but 1t begs the Important operational question.

That question, under

lagged reserves, 1s what the monetary authority can do 1n the current
settlement period to reduce deposits 1n the current settlement period so that
the level of reserves provided two periods later can be reduced.
1s clear.

The answer

The monetary authority must provide sufficient reserves to cover

the level of required reserves, but 1t can change the price at which 1t
provides the reserves.

By supplying less of the requisite quantity of

reserves through open market operations, the monetary authority forces banks
to borrow more reserves at the discount window and thereby pushes up the
federal funds rate.

The fewer reserves provided through open market

operations, the higher will be the level of borrowings and the federal funds
rate, and the lower will be deposits 1n the current week.

The lesson 1s clear

- Interest rates, not reserves, move deposits and the money stock.
^See the articles by Rosenbaum (1984) and Goodfrlend (1984).



12

The problems presented by lagged reserves for short run monetary control
are much more pervasive 1n the "interest rate" view than in the "mechanistic
multiplier" view of money stock determination.

Recall that in the "interest

rate" view of money stock determination, a reserve targeting procedure
involves having the monetary authority set the target level of reserves, and
then the reserve market is supposed to automatically move the federal funds
rate, on the basis of the difference between reserves and required reserves,
so as to guide required reserves and deposits into equilibrium with the level
of reserves.

One way of viewing

a reserve targeting procedure is that the

monetary authority dictates where it wants the banking system to go by setting
a level of reserves and the market then automatically adjusts the federal
funds rate to move the system on the basis of the difference between where the
monetary authority wants the system to go and where the system presently is.
Thus, there are two problems with lagged reserves.

One is the aforementioned

problem, also recognized by the "mechanistic multiplier" view, that on
occasion, the monetary authority is constrained from accurately setting
reserves as low as they would desire on the basis of where they want the
system to go.

The second problem, which occurs all the time, is that the

mechanism by which the present position of the system feeds back into the
determination of the federal funds rate, so as to guide the system to the
desired position is faulty.

Under a lagged reserve system, the current level

of deposits, and therefore any changes in the current level of deposits, have
no influence or feedback onto the federal funds rate so as to guide deposits
and required reserves into equilibrium with the level of reserves supplied.
Indeed, it 1s this second continual problem which explains the fact that not
only did interest rates become more volatile, as was expected with the adoption




13

of a reserve targeting procedure under lagged reserves, but short run deposit
4
changes also became more volatile - which was not expected.
Ill
Monetary control through total reserve targeting under contemporaneous
reserves has a somewhat mythical quality.

This arrangement underlies the

policy procedures recommended by virtually every advocate of steady monetary
growth.

It 1s also the system Implicit 1n every money and banking textbook

description of the banking system's role 1n deposit expansion and
contraction.

It's somewhat surprising therefore, to observe that total

reserve targeting and a contemporaneous reserve system has never characterized
monetary policy 1n the U.S.

Only 1n October 1979, under a lagged reserve

system, did the monetary authority announce for the first time a reserve
targeting procedure.

Even then, the policy was an unborrowed reserve policy

and there 1s a very serious question as to whether the monetary authority
5
actually could have pursued a total reserve operating procedure.
The
reserve accounting system 1n place before the 1968 switch to lagged reserves,
was not a contemporaneous system, but actually a one day lagged reserve
accounting system.6

An analysis of monetary control under a combination of

contemporaneous reserves (or quasl-contemporaneous reserves) and a total
reserve targeting procedure must therefore rely heavily on theoretical
analysis since empirical evidence 1s not available.
^See Robert 0. Laurent "A Critique of the Fed's New Operating Procedure"
"Staff memoranda 81-3. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1981.
6Ib1d.
6A bank's required reserves were calculated on the basis of Its deposits
at the beginning of the day, so that 1t was effectively based on deposits at
the end of the preceding day.




14

The reserve accounting system adopted in February, 1984 differs 1n a
number of significant ways from the combination of a total reserve operating
procedure and a contemporaneous reserves system Implicit 1n the textbooks.
First, the Fed cannot set the level of unborrowed reserves accurately.

In

practice, such factors as float and Treasury deposits cause random
disturbances to the level of unborrowed reserves.

Second, banks are able to

borrow at the discount window at the sum of the explicit cost of the
administratively set discount rate and the Implicit cost of Fed surveillance
entailed 1n the discount window.

Third, and most significant 1s the fact that

the new system retains a two day lag.

That 1s, the period from which deposits

are taken to compute required reserves runs from the end of business on the
Tuesday of the first week to the end of business of the Monday two weeks
later.

This 1s referred to as the reserve computation period.

Banks satisfy

reserve requirements with reserves 1n the period from the end of business on
Thursday two days after the first Tuesday, to the end of business on the
Wednesday two days after the second Monday.
reserve maintenance period.

This period 1s referred to as the

Figure 1 Illustrates the two day lag 1n the

quasi-contemporaneous reserve system.7

Figure 1
Reserve Computation and Reserve Maintainence Periods
, Tu

t

W , Th

,

F

,

Sa , Su ,

M

Reserve

L Th

F

Sa

t

Su

, Tu

,

W

, Th

,

F

, Sa ,

Su ,

■ Th

t

F

M

(

, Sa a Su

Computation

M

! Tu

t

Reserve

W

Maintainence

7For a more complete description of the reserve accounting changes
adopted 1n February, 1984 see (Gilbert & Treblng).




15

IV
Reserve requirements are designed to help control money under an operating
procedure 1n which the monetary authority hits a target level of total
reserves.

Therefore, a total reserve operating procedure 1s the appropriate

background against which to compare the present quasl-contemporaneous reserve
g

system with the contemporaneous system 1t 1s often thought to be.

There

are, however, a number of problems Impeding the monetary authority's conduct
of a total reserve operating procedure under either contemporaneous or
quasl-contemporaneous reserves.

Two of the problems, existing under either

reserve accounting system - the Inability of the monetary authority to
precisely set unborrowed reserves and the availability of the discount window
for banks to acquire reserves - are of relatively minor Importance.

The major

problem presented for the monetary authority in trying to control money
through a total reserve operating procedure, occurs under quaslcontemporaneous reserves and arises precisely from the two day lag which
differentiates the present quasl-contemporaneous reserve system from the
contemporaneous reserve system with which 1t 1s often m1d1dent1fled. This two
day lag, together with the fact that a bank may satisfy Its reserve
requirements with any pattern of reserves over the settlement period,

g

produces critical differences for monetary control between quaslcontemporaneous and contemporaneous reserves.
^Essentially, a contemporaneous reserve system 1s one 1n which the
Reserve Computation and Reserve Ma1nta1nence period are coterminus, so that
1t 's possible for the banking system to change required reserves after the
target level of total reserves has been set.
^Except that a bank cannot have a reserve account which 1s overdrafted
(1.e. have negative reserve balances) at the end of any day.




16

One may quickly grasp why the two day lag 1s so Important, by considering
an extreme example.

Suppose that, under the present reserve accounting

system, the monetary authority acted so as to convince the banking system that
the federal funds rate would be, say 8 percent on the final two day, lagged
portion of the settlement period.

Then 1t 1s clear that the federal funds

rate will not deviate far from 8 percent on the first twelve days of the
settlement period.

No bank will sell federal funds at less than 8 percent, or

pay more than 8 percent 1f 1t knows that the federal funds rate will be 8
percent sometime later 1n the settlement week.

In this extreme situation the

monetary authority could literally move reserves anywhere they wanted on the
first twelve days of the settlement period and not affect the level of
deposits.

The major point of such a hypothetical consideration 1s that

(because banks can satisfy reserve requirements with any pattern of reserves
over the settlement period) the behavior of the vital federal funds rate 1n
the twelve day, non-lagged portion of the settlement period depends critically
on the expected actions of the monetary authority 1n the two day lagged
portion at the end of the settlement period.
In presenting the "Interest rate" view of money stock determination
earlier, 1t was argued that the degree to which one follows a reserve
targeting procedure depends upon the extent to which the monetary authority
allows the federal funds rate to be determined by the Interaction of the
target level of total reserves and required reserves based on the existing
level of deposits.

Since the current federal funds rate 1s Influenced by

future expected federal funds rates 1n the same settlement period, a true
reserve targeting procedure requires that the monetary authority set the
target level of reserves and then avoid constraining or further affecting
expected federal funds rates 1n the remainder of the settlement period.

It

will be argued here that the two day lag 1n the quasl-contemporaneous reserve



17

accounting system significantly inhibits the ability of the monetary authority
to do this, and thus the possibility of controlling money through a total
reserve targeting procedure.
A reserve targeting procedure of monetary control requires that the
monetary authority set the target level of total reserves.

In practice, one

minor problem is that the monetary authority is not able to set the level of
unborrowed reserves accurately.

Fluctuations in Fed float and treasury

deposits at the Fed cause the level of unborrowed reserves to fluctuate
unpredictably.

It is not possible, at present, to predict and offset these

fluctuations before they occur, but it is possible to almost completely
neutralize disturbances after they occur.

For example, the monetary authority

could offset daily the disturbances to unborrowed reserves on each preceding
day.

This means that the level of unborrowed reserves over the settlement

period would be off target only by the unexpected disturbance on the final day
of the settlement period.

This would be a close approximation to a total

reserve targeting procedure.
A second, somewhat more major, problem afflicting a reserve targeting
procedure under quasi-contemporaneous reserves is the existence of the
discount window.

At the discount window, banks can choose to borrow and move

the level of reserves above the target level.

Banks would only choose to do

this if the cost of reserves at the discount window was attractive relative to
the cost of reserves in the federal funds market.

The cost of reserves at the

discount window has two components - the explicit cost embodied in the
discount rate and the implicit cost embodied in the surveillance imposed on
borrowers by the Fed.

In the "mechanistic multiplier" view, the discount

window causes a problem for monetary control through reserve targeting by
allowing reserves to deviate, at the initiative of the banks, from the
monetary authority's target level.



In the "interest rate" view of money stock

18

determination the problem of the discount window 1s that 1t acts to constrain
and Influence Interest rates, thereby preventing the automatic operation of
the money stock determination model underlying reserve targeting.

The

discount window Influences the federal funds rate once that rate surpasses the
discount rate.

As the level of unborrowed reserves falls below the level of

required reserves, the federal funds rate rises.

As the federal funds rate

rises above the discount rate, banks have an Increased Incentive to borrow
from the discount window, Increasing the level of reserves and dampening the
rise 1n the federal funds rate.^
Perhaps the simplest solution to the discount window problem 1s to
Increase the discount rate to a very high level where there would be no
Incentive for banks to borrow at the discount window.

This proposal, which

has often been linked with the adoption of a contemporaneous reserve
accounting system, 1s designed to eliminate borrowed reserves and cause total
reserves to be Identical to unborrowed reserves.

This high discount rate

along with the correction of disturbances to unborrowed reserves, would seem
to produce a system closely approximating a reserve targeting procedure of
monetary control.^

It will be argued here that whether this 1s so depends

critically on whether the reserve accounting system retains a lag - and that
the existence of the two day lag 1n the quasl-contemporaneous reserve
accounting system 1s the major problem Impeding monetary control through
reserve targeting.12
T^See the paper by Kasrlel and Merrls.
11 See Pakko p. 66.
12For a more mathematical treatment of quasl-contemporaneous reserve
accounting under a very rigid set of assumptions see Kopecky.




19

To demonstrate the Importance of the two day lag consider first an
approximate total reserve targeting procedure (1.e. offsetting the previous
day's disturbance to unborrowed reserves and setting a high, penalty discount
rate) under a true contemporaneous reserve system where 1t 1s possible for the
banking system to affect required reserves after the final level of unborrowed
reserves has been set.

13

How does such a system come to equilibrium 1f the

level of reserves 1s Initially set below the level of required reserves
determined by the current level of deposits?
causes the federal funds rate to rise.

The deficiency of reserves

As the federal funds rate rises, banks

find the sale of earning assets to be attractive and thereby reduce the level
of deposits.

As the level of deposits falls, required reserves also fall

until they are 1n equilibrium with reserves and the rise 1n the federal funds
rate stops.

One can easily Imagine a discount rate set so high that the

discount window 1s never used and the federal funds rate always equilibrates
at a level under the discount rate.

So with a high enough discount rate,

under true contemporaneous reserves, the monetary authority can, for all
practical purposes, run a total reserve targeting procedure.
However, the same arrangement does not produce a total reserve targeting
procedure under quasl-contemporaneous reserves.

The two day lag means that

when the target level of total reserves (adjusted for the error on the last
day) 1s below the level of required reserves established by the twelfth day of
the settlement period, then no matter how high the federal funds rate rises
and how much banks reduce the level of deposits, the level of required reserves
cannot be reduced below the level of reserves provided by the monetary
authority.

In this case, the federal funds rate Increases until 1t 1s above

130ne way to view this system 1s that the monetary authority has
completed Its open market operations by the morning of the last day and the
banking system has until the close of business of the last day to set deposits
and required reserves.



20

the discount rate, however high, and banks borrow sufficient reserves to move
total reserves above the level of required reserves.

Thus, 1n this case, the

administratively set discount rate serves to Influence and constrain the
federal funds rate and therefore determine the level of deposits.

This

scenario of federal funds rate and money stock determination 1s contrary to
the description of the mechanism underlying a total reserve targeting
procedure of monetary control.
It may seem that a total reserve targeting procedure could be closely
approximated under the two day lag by setting the discount rate so high that
the banking system would never enter the last two days with higher required
reserves than the level of reserves provided by the monetary authority.

That

1s, by setting the discount rate high enough, 1t might seem that one could
eliminate all borrowings.

If this were possible, 1t would allow the monetary

authority to approximate a true total reserve targeting procedure even with a
two day lagged quasl-contemporaneous system.
To see why this 1s not always possible, consider the behavior of an
Individual bank under such a system.

A bank, knowing that the monetary

authority sets a target level of unborrowed reserves, might Initially look at
the high discount rate and decide to avoid any possibility of needing reserves
later in the week.

All banks would try to build up excess reserves as

Insurance earlier 1n the week.

If all banks try to do this, then either there

are already excess reserves 1n the system or the federal funds rate would have
a tendency to rise early in the week and Induce banks to reduce their earning
assets (and deposits 1n the system) so that the banking system would enter the
last two days of the settlement week with required reserves well below the
level of reserves provided, eliminating the possibility of banks being forced
to borrow reserves at the discount window.

However, 1f banks always act this

way then the federal funds rate would always fall on the last two days of the



21

settlement week and the high discount rate would never influence the federal
funds rate.

14

Essentially, the situation would be one in which banks always

hold insurance (i.e. excess reserves) for an accident that never occurs.

This

is clearly impossible as a long run solution.
If the banking system continuously acts so as to cause the federal funds
rate to fall on the last two days of the settlement period, then the
individual bank would eventually realize that it has no incentive to try to
build up its excess reserve holdings early in the period.

On the contrary,

the incentive would be for the individual bank to run a deficiency early in
the settlement period and then cover the deficiency on the last two days of
the settlement period.

As long as other banks act so as to cause the federal

funds rate to fall on the last two days, banks that run deficiencies on the
first twelve days will do well, and this will increase the incentive for more
banks to run larger deficiences earlier in the period.

Finally, a period must

occur when the banking system as a whole enters the final two days with
required reserves above the fixed level of reserves provided by the monetary
authority.

This is a period when the federal funds rate rises until it

surpasses the discount rate by an amount sufficient to induce banks to borrow
the requisite quantity of reserves to make up the shortfall between required
reserves and the target level of reserves.

Thus, periods must occur when some

banks will be forced to borrow from the discount window under reserve
targeting and quasi-contemporaneous reserves.
It is important to understand how this occasional occurence affects
monetary control under a total reserve operating procedure and
quasi-contemporaneous reserves.

The monetary authority can come closer to

l^This is because the demand for excess reserves becomes very low and
very interest inelastic late in the settlement period at any rate high enough
to cover transactions costs in the federal funds market.



22

Implementing a total reserve targeting procedure by raising the discount
rate.

A higher discount rate causes the role of the monetary authority 1n

constraining the federal funds rate to diminish 1n the sense that the fedeal
funds rate will be less frequently constrained by the administratively set
discount rate.
procedure.

This 1s what 1t means to move toward a reserve targeting

However, it 1s also clear that the quasi-contemporaneous system 1s

different than a true contemporaneous system in that it 1s possible under a
true contemporaneous reserve system (where the banks can affect required
reserves after the level of reserves 1s set) for the administratively set
discount rate to be set so high that 1t never serves to constrain the federal
funds rate.

Under a quasi-contemporaneous system, there must be some times

when the administratively set discount rate, even under an approximation to a
total reserve targeting procedure, importantly Influences the federal funds
rate.
The problem a low discount rate poses for the conduct of a reserve
targeting procedure is that it can hamper the monetary authority's attempts to
slow down money growth.

In the "mechanistic multiplier" view this problem

appears as an inability to constrain the level of reserves while 1t appears in
the "Interest rate" view as a constraint on the ability of the federal funds
rate to rise and force the banking system to contract deposits Into
equilibrium with the level of reserves that the monetary authority would have
preferred to set.

Raising the discount rate to a very high level can solve

these problems under a contemporaneous reserve system (where 1t 1s possible
for banks to alter required reserves once reserves are set).

The discount

rate can be set so high that banks would never borrow, thereby avoiding the
problem of having the discount window alter the level of reserves in the
"mechanistic multiplier" view or influence the federal funds rate 1n the
"interest rate" view.



23

However, under a reserve accounting system that retains a lag there must
be occasions when banks will find 1t necessary to borrow at the discount
window, thereby Increasing reserves above the target level the monetary
authority would like to provide, and causing the federal funds rate to be
Influenced by the administratively set discount rate.

Raising the discount

rate benefits a monetary policy designed to operate through total reserves by
reducing the frequency with which banks make use of the discount window.

It

might appear then, that monetary procedure under a total reserve targeting
procedure and a quasl-contemporaneous reserve system can be made to
asymptotically approach the same policy under contemporaneous reserves by
raising the discount rate.

However, while this Improves monetary policy by

reducing the occasions when the banking system borrows at the window and the
discount rate constrains the federal funds rate, 1t also raises the level and
volatility of excess reserves and the cost of reserve management to the
Individual bank.

Thus, while a higher discount rate has the monetary

authority play a role closer to the role 1t 1s meant to play under a reserve
targeting procedure (1.e. the monetary authority becomes more Important 1n
determlng the level of total reserves), 1t has an additional effect which
weakens monetary control by making the relationship between reserves and
required reserves less stable.

Thus, there is a tradeoff between the monetary

authority's ability to Implement a reserve targeting procedure and constrain
monetary growth by raising the discount rate and the level and volatility of
excess reserves.

Figure 2 Illustrates the nature of this tradeoff.

Increasing the discount rate Initially Improves, but eventually worsens
monetary control.

This occurs because the lower the discount rate, the higher

will be the average level of borrowed reserves, and the greater will be the
average amount by which reserves exceed the target level of total reserves and
deposits exceed the target level of deposits.



At low discount rates, deposit

Figure 2
The Length of the Lag, the Discount Rate, and the
Pattern of Errors in Monetary Control

Contemporaneous

1 Day Lag

3 Day Lag

Discount
Rate

0%




Errors in Monetary Control

10 Day Lag

24

expansion 1s basically constrained only by the Impact of discount window
surveillance costs on the federal funds rate.

The response of the federal

funds rate to borrowing tends to be sluggish and gradual, working as 1t does
solely through the reaction of the discount

officers to extended periods and

Increased levels of Individual bank borrowing.

As the discount rate 1s

raised, the response of the federal funds rate to borrowings at the discount
window 1s heightened and accelerated.
more quickly.

This reins 1n excessive monetary growth

However, under a quasl-contemporaneous system where there

remains some lag, 1t was shown earlier 1n this paper that there will always be
some occasions when banks must borrow at the discount rate, no matter how
high.

As the discount rate 1s raised, the costs of this borrowing Increase.

In response banks will Increase their holdings of excess reserves as
protection against a possible high federal funds rate late 1n the settlement
period.

Since banks do not have prior knowledge of the periods 1n which rates

will rise, the Increase 1n the level and volatility of excess reserves will
have the effect of weakening monetary control.

As the discount rate 1s

raised, the detrimental effects of an Increasing volatility in excess reserves
finally outweighs the beneficial effects of an Increased ability to constrain
reserves, monetary control deteriorates and the curves bend back.
One way to represent this relationship 1s to express money as the product
of reserves and a multiplier, each of which has an error term,
e

m

respectively.
K

M

=(R +
•
'

J

e n )(r n

R,v

eD,

K

and

Then
f

e

)
nr

as the discount rate is raised the level and volatility of
the level and volatility of em rises.

falls but

Thus the optimal arrangement for

the discount window under a quasi contemporaneous reserve system 1s more
complicated than simply setting a high, penalty discount rate as 1s often

implied.



25

The curves 1n Figure 2 also show that the trade-off between monetary
control worsens as the length of the lag 1s extended.

The reason for this 1s

that when the banking system borrows (1.e., the federal funds rate 1s above
the discount rate) then the cost to the banking system 1s proportional to both
the federal funds rate and the number of days that one has to borrow.

Thus

when the banking system 1s forced to borrow, costs are higher, the longer 1s
the lag.

In response, banks will hold higher and more volatile levels of

excess reserves and monetary control will worsen as the length of the lag
Increases.

The figure also shows that for a contemporaneous reserve system

the curve does not bend back.

Because banks can bring required reserves Into

line with reserves under contemporaneous reserves, any Increase 1n the
discount rate above the level needed to Induce the largest adjustment 1n
required reserves necessary, does not Increase the cost to banks or the
holding of excess reserves.

Therefore 1t does not weaken monetary control.

The operation of a reserve targeting system of monetary control requires
that the federal funds rate respond to the difference between the level of
reserves and the level of required reserves based on the current level of
deposits.

Conducive to the operation of this system 1s the transmittal by

banks of the pressures from their excess reserve position Into the federal
funds market.

The more volatile the federal funds rate, the more effectively

will banks transmit their reserve position Into the federal funds market.

It

1s Informative to consider the adjustment 1n the behavior of the Individual
bank as the discount rate 1s raised under an approximate reserve targeting
procedure.

As the discount rate 1s raised, the bank comes to expect more

volatility 1n future federal funds rates over the remainder of the settlement
week.

This means that the bank will monitor Its reserve position more closely

earlier 1n the settlement period.




26

Perhaps, the best way to see why this happens 1s to consider the opposite
situation - where a bank knows that the federal funds rate will be a constant
fixed rate over the remainder of the settlement week.

Under a situation of

absolutely constant expected rates, 1t makes no sense for a bank to monitor
Its reserve position earlier 1n the week.

A bank that monitored Its reserve

position earlier 1n the week and offset any unexpected disturbances, would
simply be Increasing Its costs.

That 1s, 1t might offset an unexpected Inflow

by selling federal funds at one time and then have to offset an unexpected
outflow by buying federal funds at another time.

It could reduce both

monitoring and transactions costs by waiting until the end of the settlement
period and then offset net unexpected disturbances with one transaction.

This

1s a preferable means of operating since the bank knows that the federal funds
rate will be the same later 1n the week.
The more the federal funds rate 1s expected to fluctuate 1n the rest of
the settlement period, the more sense 1t makes for an Individual bank to
monitor Its reserve position earlier 1n the week.

In this way the bank can

reduce the risk of having to sell reserves at a low rate or buy reserves at a
high rate later 1n the settlement period.

If many banks monitor their reserve

position early In the settlement week, then the basic position of the banking
system (1.e. reserve surplus or deficiency) will Influence the federal funds
rate and cause the rate to move 1n the appropriate direction early 1n the
week.

This causes banks to adjust their earning assets (and deposits In the

banking system) early 1n the week which results 1n better monetary control and
a reduced probability of having the banking system enter the last two days
with required reserves above the level of reserves.
One way of viewing the problem of the lag 1n a quasi-contemporaneous
system 1s as an Inefficient pricing mechanism.

The federal funds rate 1s

supposed to reflect the relative magnitudes of reserves and required reserves



27

(based on the current level of deposits) and thus guide the banks to move
deposits and required reserves Into equilibrium with reserves.
the lag 1s that 1t throws this pricing system out of whack.

The problem of

Banks continue to

respond to the rate as 1f 1t accurately reflected the discrepancy between
reserves and required reserves.

In fact, however, the rate 1s responding to

the current level of reserves and the level of required reserves 1n the system
at the beginning of the lagged portion of the settlement period.

Thus, the

banking system loses the benefits of Its ability to respond to the pricing
system.

It causes the monetary authority to Intervene 1n a more obtrusive way

than 1t should 1n the federal funds market.

This means that the monetary

authority can, through movements 1n the discount rate, trade off Its ability
to constrain reserve expansion for Increased levels and volatility 1n excess
reserves.

This trade-off stems from a pricing Impediment 1n the federal funds

market produced by the lag.
This same analysis of the federal funds market also shows why monetary
control under a reserve targeting procedure with quasl-contemporaneous
reserves will be easier and more accurate than would be the case under the
same procedure with the previous lagged reserve system.

The improvement 1n

the new reserve accounting system stems from the fact that 1f the monetary
authority convinces the banking system that 1t will hold to the target level
of reserves whenever possible and that 1t will allow large changes 1n the
federal funds rate when 1t 1s not possible to hold to the target level of
reserves, then banks can reduce the pressures Imposed on the banking system
through appropriate responses 1n the first twelve days of the settlement week
under the quasl-contemporaneous system.

If the banking system learns that the

monetary authority will allow large changes 1n the federal funds rate at the
end of the settlement period, then banks will more closely monitor their
reserve position early in the settlement period and produce larger changes 1n



28

the federal funds rate early 1n the settlement period.

These large movements

in the federal funds rate early 1n the settlement week will cause banks to
respond through their holdings of earning assets and produce changes 1n
deposits under either lagged reserves or quasl-contemporaneous reserves.

The

advantage of quasl-contemporaneous reserves over the old lagged system 1s
that, to the extent that banks respond and change the level of deposits 1n the
proper direction 1n the first twelve days of the settlement period, a
quasl-contemporaneous system reduces the pressure on the banking system and
the cost of reserve management to the Individual bank while simultaneously
giving a more accurate and less volatile money stock because the level and
volatility of excess reserves are reduced.
But finally, 1t 1s extremely Important to note a less desirable effect of
quasl-contemporaneous reserves on the over-all progress toward accurate short
run monetary control.

The costs of adopting the new reserve accounting system

have been substantial.

It has been argued here that the system adopted

retains the same problems, though to a lesser degree, that troubled the
previous lagged reserve system.

Imposing such substantial costs to adopt a

change that falls to remove the pervasive fundamental problem of lagged
reserves may well reinforce the feeling of some observers that reserve
accounting changes have little potential to Improve monetary control.

Nothing

could be further from the truth; changes 1n reserves accounting could provide
the monetary authority with accurate short run monetary control even while
vastly simplifying reserve management for banks.15

However, after the

experience with quasl-contemporaneous reserves, 1t 1s not likely that the
reserve accounting system will soon again be changed with the goal of
Improving monetary control.
15See Laurent (1983)



Those advocates of short run monetary control who

29

applauded the move to quasl-contemporaneous reserves have unwittingly hampered
the longer run move toward accurate monetary control by basing their view of
money stock determination on a "mechanistic multiplier" model of money stock
determination and thereby confusing a quasl-contemporaneous reserves with true
contemporaneous reserves.
V

The analysis of quasl-contemporaneous reserve accounting Indicates that
while 1t 1s a potential Improvement, quasl-contemporaneous reserves retains
the same fundamental problem that plagued the previous lagged reserve system.
This analysis, must of necessity be based on theory, since a total reserve
operating procedure under a contemporaneous reserve system has never been the
monetary control process used by the Federal Reserve.

Quasl-contemporaneous

reserves has the advantage over lagged reserves that 1f the federal funds rate
moves in the first twelve days of the settlement period, the resulting changes
1n deposits produced by these Interest rate changes will affect required
reserves and relieve the Interest rate pressure on banks and the banking
system.

That 1s, the federal funds rate functions as 1t should under a

reserve targeting procedure 1n the first twelve days of the settlement period
- as a reflection of the discrepancy between reserves and required reserves
and a guide to banks on the actions necessary to eliminate the discrepancy.
However, to obtain this advantage, the monetary authority must, at least
occasionally, determine the federal funds rate through the discount rate on
the last two days of the settlement week, Irrespective of the changes produced
1n deposits on those days by the banking system.

That 1s, Interest rates do

not function as they should under a reserve targeting procedure on the last
two days of the settlement period and quasl-contemporaneous reserves presents
the same problems, 1n microcosm, as lagged reserves presented for monetary
control.




Even when the potential Improvement 1n quasi- contemporaneous

30

reserves over lagged reserves 1s realized by having the monetary authority
Impose a high discount rate, quasl-contemporaneous reserves remain Inferior to
contemporaneous reserves by Imposing a higher level and volatility of excess
reserves and Imposing higher reserve management costs on banks and the banking
system.
Perhaps most Important, the paper Investigates the basis of the analysis
which led many critics of lagged reserves to accept quasl-contemporaneous
reserves.

The paper argues that 1t stems from a widely held but seriously

deficient view of the linkage between reserves and money, labeled 1n the paper
the "mechanistic multiplier" view of money stock determination.

This view

perceives changes 1n reserves to lead directly to changes 1n deposits without
any description of the mechanism which causes the level of reserves to
Influence the level of deposits.

As a result, the Importance of the federal

funds rate, expected future federal funds rates and the consequences of the
fungible nature of reserves within the settlement week are lost 1n the
"mechanistic multiplier" view of money stock determination.

The paper

presents an alternative "Interest rate" view of the linkage between reserves
and deposits which gives a decidedly less sanguine view of the adoption of
quasl-contemporaneous reserves.

This latter view argues that the new reserve

accounting system cannot be made to function under a reserve targeting
procedure like the contemporaneous reserve system it is widely believed to be.
The Implementation of reserve targeting under quasl-contemporaneous
reserves can be made to more closely approach the same policy under
contemporaneous reserves by targeting unborrowed reserves and raising the
discount rate.

However, unlike the role the discount rate might play under a

true contemporaneous reserve system, the administratively set discount rate
under quasl-contemporaneous reserves must, at least occasionally, serve to
Influence the price of reserves to the banking system.



Not only does this

31

characteristic of the discount rate under quasi-contemporaneous reserves mean
that the monetary authority plays a more significant role 1n determining the
federal funds rate than 1t should 1n a reserve targeting procedure, 1t also
presents the monetary authority with a true dilemma 1n that an Increase 1n the
discount rate, while allowing the monetary authority to more closely Implement
a total reserves policy, also has the effect of Increasing the level and
volatility of excess reserves.

Thus, 1t 1s not always true, under a

quasi-contemporaneous system, that the higher the discount rate, the better
the monetary control.

Setting the discount rate presents a difficult

optimization problem.
Finally, the paper suggests that the shift to quasi-contemporaneous
reserves, even though an Improvement over lagged reserves, may actually work
to the detriment of the longer run quest of achieving accurate monetary
control.

By advertising the shift to quasi-contemporaneous reserves as a

major Improvement 1n monetary control, advocates of the shift may eventually
contribute to the erroneous Idea that reserve accounting 1s not Important for
monetary control.

Many advocates of short run monetary control, who have been

critical of lagged reserves have unwittingly contributed to this outcome by
falling to adequately understand the mechanism underlying a reserve targeting
procedure of monetary control and accepting quasl-contemporaneous reserves as
a true contemporaneous reserve system.




32

LITERATURE
Burger, Albert E. "Lagged Reserve Requirements: Their Effects on Reserve
Operations, Money Market Stability, Member Banks and the Money Supply
Process." Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, (1971).
Coats, Warren L., Jr., "The September 19168, Changes 1n 'Regulation D' and
Their Implications for Money Supply Control." Ph.O. thesis University of
Chicago, (1972).
Goodfrlend, Marvin. "The Promises and Pitfalls of Contemporaneous Reserve
Requirements for the Implementation of Montary Policy." Economic Review.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. (May/June 1984). Vol. 70/3.
Gilbert, R. Alton and Michael E. Treblng. "The New System of Contemporaneous
Reserve Requirements." Review. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. December
1982. Vol. 64, No. 10.
Kasrlel, Paul and Randall C. Merrls. "Reserve Targeting and Discount Policy,
Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Fall 1982.
Kopecky, Kenneth J. "Interest Rates and the Money Stock Under 'Almost'
Contemporaneous Reserve Accounting". Unpublished paper, Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System. (April, 1983).
Laurent, Robert D. "Lagged Reserve Accounting and the Fed's New Operating
Procedure". Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Midyear
1982.
__________________ . "Comparing Alternative Replacements for Lagged Reserves:
Why Settle for a Poor Third Best?" Staff Memoranda 83-2. Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. (1983).
Pakko, Michael R. "Lagged and Contemporaneous Reserve Accounting, Money
Market Stability and Monetary Control: A Topical History of Recent U.S.
Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. (May 27, 1983).
Tarhan, Vefa. "Bank Reserve Admustment Process and the Use of Reserve
Carryover Provision adn the Implications of the Proposed Accounting Regime."
Staff Memoranda 83-6. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. (1983)