View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

orKmg rape
CO
(T>
FS’
c n




The Post-War U.S. Phillips Curve:
A Revisionist Econometric History
R e s p o n s e to E v a n s a n d

Robert G. King and Mark W. Watson

Working Papers Series
Macroeconomic Issues
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
September (W P-94-17)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

T h e P o s t - W a r U .S . P h i l l ip s
A

C u rv e :

R e v is io n is t E c o n o m e tric H is to ry

R e s p o n s e

to

E v a n s

a n d

M

c C a llu m

R ob ert G. K ing
U n iv ersity o f V irgin ia and
F ederal R eserve B an k of R ich m on d
M ark W . W atson
N orth w estern U n iversity and
F ederal R eserve B an k of C hicago
S ep tem b er 22, 1994

1

In tro d u c tio n

We thank Charles Evans and Bennett McCallum for their thoughtful comments on
our paper. To put their comments into perspective and to make our reply more
self-contained, we begin our response with a short summary of our main findings.
Our paper explores two notions of instability in the relationship between inflation
and unemployment. The first is the traditional one, and concerns instability in the
linkage between unemployment and inflation in the post-war U.S. data. We called this
the P h illip s c o r r e la tio n in our paper, and the paper presents a set of findings on these
correlations. Specifically, the paper documents that the unemployment/inflation pro­
cess was unstable over the post-war period, with a break occurring around 1970.
There are two notable aspects of this instability:
• More instability is evident in inflation than in unemployment.
• More instability is evident in the low frequency components of the macroeco­
nomic data than in other components.
We documented these instabilities in a variety of ways, including plots of components
of the data (filtered to uncover trend, business cycle and irregular components), formal
econometric tests for instability, and split-sample forecasting exercises. The analysis
also uncovered certain characteristics of the process that appeared relatively stable:




1

• Much more modest changes in the inflation and unemployment correlations are
evident over business cycle frequencies and at short-run forecasting horizons.
These results are documented in panel B of our Figure 2 and in our Figure 8, and
underlie our claim that the Phillips correlation is alive and well at the business cycle
frequencies.
The second notion of instability that we explore concerns the changing relative
response of unemployment and inflation to aggregate demand shocks - a notion that
we called the P h illip s c u r v e trade-off. We showed that the estimated value of this
trade-off depends both on sample period and on the definition of aggregate demand
shocks that serves to econometrically identify the model. It is in our presentation of
these results that we have some differences of opinion with Evans and McCallum.
2

R e sp o n se T o E vans:

Evans’s comments are focused on one important feature of the REM model, namely
the non-zero value of the estimated long-run Phillips trade-off. While our point
estimate of this trade-off is small in the REM model, it is statistically different from
zero, and is large enough to warrant Evan’s careful scrutiny.
As our paper shows, and Evans reminds the reader, the data clearly indicate a
negative long-run correlation between inflation and unemployment. The key struc­
tural question is whether this correlation arises from common long-run movements in
the variables associated with exogenous changes in money - potentially an exploitable
trade-off - or merely reflects accommodative changes in money in response to long-run
changes in unemployment associated with demographic or other real factors?
Evans carries out two exercises designed as specification checks for the REM
model. First, he compares the estimated shocks from the REM identified model
to two other series suggested as measures of exogenous changes in money or mone­
tary policy. The first series is the set of indicator variables developed by Romer and
Romer (1989); they suggested that these measure exogenous tightening of monetary
policy. The second series is developed in Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (1994).
It is constructed from VAR residuals in a six-variable model: specifically, the shock
to the Federal Funds Rate, after conditioning on the contemporaneous values of em­
ployment, the price level and commodity prices. As Evans realizes, the problem with
comparing these series is that it is like comparing Fruit A with Fruit B and Fruit C,
without knowing which of the fruits is the apple, the orange or the banana. That is,
all that can really be learned from the exercise is that the series are different; to learn
more requires knowing that one of the series accurately represents exogenous changes
in money. We are unwilling to concede that either of the other two series accurately
measure exogenous changes in the money supply.1
C r it i c is m s o f th e R o m er an d R o m er se r ie s in th is regard are offered b y P lo sse r (1 9 8 9 ) an d




2

Evans’s second exercise focuses on potential omitted variable bias in the REM
model. There is every reason to suspect that bias is present: the estimated REM
model is predicated on only two structural shocks, assumed to be a nonsingular
transformation of the one-step-ahead forecast errors in the bivariate VAR relating
unemployment and inflation. Hansen and Sargent (1991), Lippi and Reichlin (1993)
and others point to the potential pitfalls in such a specification (see Watson (1994)
for a survey). Evans checks for this type of misspecification by including lags of other
variables in the model, and comparing the estimated impulse response functions to
those from the bivariate model. Our paper included one check of this sort, based on
prior work by Gordon (1982,1990b): we concluded that little changed when the model
was augmented with a variable measuring the relative price of food and energy. Evans
considers four additional variables, and the results are summarized in his Figure 2. It
is clear from this figure that the estimated impulse responses do change as variables are
added to the model, and undoubtedly some of the changes are statistically significant.
Yet, we were impressed by the s ta b il ity of the impulse responses shown in the first
column of figures: there are essentially no changes on the inflation impulse responses,
and the only changes in the unemployment responses occur at longer horizons. Thus
our conclusion is that the estimated Phillips curve trade-off changes little as these
variables are included, at least over the one to two year horizon. Evan’s results do cast
doubt on the long-run point estimates obtained from the REM model. In this regard
it is useful to note that several alternative identifications yield estimates that are
essentially zero. One of these is the an alternative monetarist identification, explored
by Roberts (1993) and King and Watson (1992), that makes inflation respond only
to tdt in the long run, thus corresponding to notion that long-run inflationary is a
strictly monetary phenomenon.
3

R e s p o n s e to

M c C a llu m ;

As McCallum stresses in his final paragraph, his comments are focused on our provoca­
tive title (“A Revisionist Econometric History”) and not on the more “substantive”
aspects of our paper. McCallum’s contention is that, from the standpoint of history
of thought, the evolution in the consensus view of the Phillips trade-off was caused
by changes in the persistence of the inflation process, and not by changes in the as­
sumptions used to identify the short-run trade-off parameter. We found McCallum’s
comments both thoughtful and interesting, particularly because of the major role that
he played in the evolution of thought on the subject (for example, McCallum (1976)).
Yet, we respectfully disagree with his contention, and offer the following remarks in
defense of our title.
else w h e r e . T h e id e n tific a tio n a ssu m p tio n s e m p lo y e d b y C h r istia n o , E ic h e n b a u m a n d E v a n s (1 9 9 4 )
suffer fro m th e sa m e p o te n tia l d e fe c ts a s th o se in th e R E M m o d e l.




3

3 .1

H o w d id K e y n e s i a n s e s t i m a t e t h e P h i l l i p s C u r v e ?

There is no disagreement about how Keynesians estimated the structural Phillips
curve. They ran regressions of the general form
a * x ( L ) ir t

=

a „ u{ L ) u t

+ £»*•

(1)

This equation was sometimes augmented with additional explanatory variable, and
the lags of prices were often interpreted as capturing “expected inflation.” Typically,
these “price equations,” or more generally the equations in the “wage-price block,”
were estimated by ordinary least squares.
From our perspective, the high water mark of the pre-rational expectations anal­
ysis of the Phillips curve was the Econometrics of Price Determination Conference
held in October 1970. Papers from this important conference were published in a
1972 volume edited by Otto Eckstein. In his introduction to the volume, James To­
bin explains the rationale for estimating the Phillips trade-off using regressions of the
form given in equation (1) in terms of a specific exclusion restriction in Keynesian
models of the era:
“aggregate demand determines unemployment, which can be taken as the
semi-exogenous variable for the wage-price subsystem.”
That is, the econometric practice was based on an identification assumption, essen­
tially about the magnitude of effects of price shocks, e*, on unemployment.
3 .2

W a s t h e r e a m o n e ta r is t a lte r n a tiv e ?

In Milton Friedman’s (1971) “Monetary Framework,” he describes a two-stage deter­
mination of macroeconomic activity.2 In this framework, nominal income (K) is first
determined by money demand ( M d) and money supply ( M s), with the latter treated
as the main empirical determinant over short periods. Thus in Friedman’s model,
nominal income can be taken to be exogenous over short periods. Second, Friedman
indicates that a previously “missing equation” is needed to provide “a division of a
change in nominal income between prices and output” (Friedman, 1971, p. 49). For
this purpose, he suggests either of the following two equations:
A l o g ( P ,) = A l o g ( P ; ) + a|A fo,,(r,) - A W ) ] + 7 |l0g(!/,) - login,')]
A/o3(t/,) = Afonin;) + (1 - a)[Afon(K,) - Afoj(v;')] - 7 [log(n,) - login,')]
since the fact that Y = P y implies that A l o g Y = A l o g ( y ) + A l o g ( P ) . (In this
expression, the * denotes anticipated variables, each of which Friedman treated as
formed adaptively).
2F ried m a n (1 9 7 1 ) is re p r in te d , w ith d isc u ssio n , in G o rd o n (1 9 7 4 ).




4

In the terminology of section 3 of our paper, Friedman therefore argued that
one could equivalently specify either a price adjustment equation or a supply curve.
However, from an empirical point of view, the crucial point is that short-run is not
necessarily captured by “the simple Keynesian assumption that all of the change in
income is in output.” (Friedman, 1971, p. 50). Further, Friedman’s analysis suggested
the strategy of estimating one of these equations using the rate of change of nominal
national as an exogenous variable.
This strategy was implemented by Anderson and Carlson (1972), who estimated
a “price equation” of the form:
A lo g ( P t )

= d (L )[A lo g (Y t )

-

G A P t- \ )

+ A A lo g (P t)

where G A P t~i was defined as the discrepancy between the prior period’s real output
and the full employment level of output. Taken together with other aspects of the
St.Louis model, this empirical specification implemented Friedman’s theoretical view.
Nominal income was proximately exogenous in the price equation, reflecting the fact
that it was dominated by monetary factors. Importantly, the estimates of Ander­
son and Carlson (1972) implied that there was no long-run effect of an permanent
expansion of money growth on unemployment.
This monetarist specification of Anderson and Carlson was sufficiently novel that
it had substantial coverage in the Eckstein volume. The authors themselves drew
a schematic of the operation of their model, highlighting that its channels differed
from those of the traditional Keynesian model. They also produced a broad-based
econometric critique of conventional price equation estimates, with sections headed
“expectations,” “money,” and “simultaneity.” In the latter, they indicated that they
disagreed strongly with the traditional Keynesian practice of treating unemployment
as proximately exogenous. Further, the St. Louis alternative warranted extensive
commentary in Tobin’s introduction (p. 12):
“The wage-price block of the St.Louis Model diverges from the other mod­
els in taking price inflation and unemployment to be jointly dependent on
aggregate demand variables-money GNP and the Okun gap between po­
tential and real output.”
“The St. Louis procedure may be preferable to the usual procedure.”
Thus, Tobin clearly points to differences in the exogeneity assumption of the (Mone­
tarist) St. Louis Model and the (Keynesian) “other models” explored by other authors
in the Eckstein volume. Further, the exogeneity assumption that Tobin mentions as
standard (quoted in section 3.1 above), is precisely what we labelled “Traditional
Keynesian” in our paper.3
3Our qualifier “Traditional” is important. Analysis of the output-inflation tradeoff in Gordon
(1982), treats nominal rather than real output as exogenous. For more discussion of this, see Gordon
(1990a,b).




5

Importantly, in the rational expectations estimates of the Phillips curve by Sargent
[1976], the St. Louis method was taken to its logical conclusion: money was used as
an instrumental variable for estimating the short-run linkage between unemployment
and inflation. While it is possible to argue with the identifying assumption used by
Sargent, his estimation method is appropriate for the model that he constructed: it
leads to the short-run slope estimate that we use for our REM identification.
3 .3

W h y h a s t h e e s t i m a t e d L o n g - R u n T r a d e - o f f F a lle n ?

We titled our paper “A Revisionist History of the Phillips Curve” because it shows
that alternative assumptions about the short-run slope were important for the decline
in the estimate of the long-run slope. Certainly, the increase in the persistence of in­
flation (documented in our paper and in McCallum’s comments) played an important
role in the evolution of the consensus view about the long-run Phillips curve. But, it
is not simply the increase in persistence that is responsible for the current view that
there is a small long-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Instead, it is
also the movement to the view that inflation and unemployment are simultaneously
determined, being influenced by both supply and demand shocks, that is important
for this decline.
One way of seeing this is to look again at the estimates in our Table 1. In each
column, the estimated trade-off falls from the pre-1970 to the post-1970 sample. As
our paper shows, this is a reflection of the increase in the persistence of inflation.
But, suppose for a moment that mainstream macroeconomists had maintained the
1970 Gordon-Solow identifying assumption. From Table 1, their estimate of the longrun trade-off would have fallen from -1.3 to -0.6. That is, the traditional Keynesian
identification implies that a current policy of raising the permanent inflation rate by
5% would bring about a 3% lower long-run unemployment rate.
We think that few macroeconomists now view a long-run trade-off of this size
as reasonable. More “mainstream” results are given by the short-run identification
that we term “rational expectations monetarist.” In the preceding section, we traced
this identification to earlier monetarist roots, in the theoretical analysis of Friedman
(1971) and the empirical analysis of Anderson and Carlson (1972). Thus, we think
that there are two parts to the answer to the question, “what killed the long-run
Phillips Curve in the U.S.?” First, the persistence of inflation increased, bringing
into play the considerations developed by Lucas and Sargent. Second, mainstream
macroeconomists shifted away from a traditional Keynesian identifying assumption
that made unemployment (or real output) determined entirely by aggregate demand
in the short-run.




6

R e fe re n c e s
[1] Friedman, M.F. (1971). A Theoretical Framework for Monetary Analysis, NBER
Occasional Paper 112, New York: NBER, distributed by Columbia University
Press.
[2] Gordon, R.J. (1974). M ilto n F r ie d m a n ’s M o n e t a r y
C r i t i c s , Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

F r a m e w o r k : A D e b a te w ith H is

[3] Hansen, L.P. and Sargent, T.J. (1991). Two Problems in Interpreting Vector Autoregressions, R a t i o n a l E x p e c ta tio n s E c o n o m e tr ic s (ed.) L. Hansen and T.J. Sar­
gent, Boulder. Co.: Westview.
[4] Lippi, M and Reichlin, L. (1993). The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and
Supply Disturbances : Comment, A m e r i c a n E c o n o m ic R e v ie w , 83, 644-52.
[5] McCallum, B.T. (1976). Rational Expectations and the Natrual Rate Hypothesis:
Some Consistent Estimates, E c o n o m e tr ic a , 44, 43-52.
[6] Plosser, C.I. (1989). Money and Business Cycles: A Real Business Cycle Interpre­
tation, paper presented at the 14th Annual Economic Policy Conference, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
[7] Tobin, J. (1972). The Wage-Price Mechanism: Overview of the Conference, The
E c o n o m e t r i c s o f P r ic e D e t e r m i n a t i o n (ed.) 0 . Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.8
[8] Watson, M.W. (1994). Vector Autoregressions and Cointegration, H an dbook o f
E c o n o m e t r i c s Vol. 4, (e<L) R-F. Engle and D. McFadden, Amsterdam: North
Holland.




7

Working Paper Series
A series ofresearch studieson regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District,and on financial and economic topics.

REGIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES
Estimating Monthly Regional Value Added by Combining Regional Input
With National Production Data

WP-92-8

P h ilip R . Israilevich an d Kenneth N. K uttner

Local Impact ofForeign Trade Zone

WP-92-9

D a v id D . W eiss

Trends and Prospects forRural Manufacturing

WP-92-12

W illiam A . Testa

Stateand Local Government Spending-The Balance
Between Investment and Consumption

WP-92-14

R ich ard H. M attoon

Forecasting with Regional Input-Output Tables

WP-92-20

P.R. Israilevich, R. M ahidhara, and G J D . H ew ings
A Primer on Global Auto Markets
P au l D . B allew an d R obert H. Schnorbus

WP-93-1

Industry Approaches toEnvironmental Policy
in the Great Lakes Region

W P-93-8

D a v id R. A llardice, R ich ard H. M attoon and William A. Testa

The Midwest Stock Price Index-Leading Indicator
ofRegional Economic Activity

WP-93-9

W illiam A . Strauss

Lean Manufacturing and the Decision to Vertically Integrate
Some Empirical Evidence From theU.S. Automobile Industry

WP-94-1

Thomas H. K lie r

Domestic Consumption Patterns and the Midwest Economy

W P-94-4

R obert Schnorbus an d P aul B allew




1

W orking paper series continued

To Trade orNot toTrade: Who Participates inRECLAIM?

WP-94-11

Thomas H. K lier an d R ichard M attoon

Restructuring & Worker Displacement in theMidwest

WP-94-18

P aul D . B allew and R obert H. Schnorbus

ISSUES IN FINANCIAL REGULATION
Incentive Conflict in Deposit-Institution Regulation: Evidence from Australia

WP-92-5

E dw ard J. K ane and G eorge G. Kaufman

Capital Adequacy and the Growth ofU.S. Banks

WP-92-11

H erbert B aer and John M cE lravey

Bank Contagion: Theory and Evidence

WP-92-13

G eorge G. Kaufman

Trading Activity, Progarm Trading and the Volatility of Stock Returns

WP-92-16

Jam es T. M oser

Preferred Sources of Market Discipline: Depositors vs.
Subordinated Debt Holders

WP-92-21

D ou glas D . E vanoff

An Investigation ofReturns Conditional
on Trading Performance

WP-92-24

Jam es T. M oser an d Jacky C. So

The Effectof Capital on PortfolioRisk atLife Insurance Companies

WP-92-29

E lijah B rew er 111, Thomas H. M ondschean, and Philip E. Strahan

A Framework forEstimating the Value and
InterestRate Risk ofRetail Bank Deposits

WP-92-30

D a v id E. Hutchison, G eorge G. Pennacchi

Capital Shocks and Bank Growth-1973 to 1991

WP-92-31

H erbert L. B aer and John N . M cE lravey

The Impact of S&L Failures and Regulatory Changes
on the CD Market 1987-1991

WP-92-33

E lijah B rew er an d Thomas H. M ondschean




2

W orking p aper series continued

Junk Bond Holdings, Premium Tax Offsets, and Risk
Exposure atLife Insurance Companies

WP-93-3

Elijah B rew er 111 an d Thomas H. M ondschean

Stock Margins and the Conditional Probability ofPrice Reversals

WP-93-5

P au l Kofman an d Jam es T. M oser

IsThere Lif(f)e After DTB?
Competitive Aspects of Cross Listed Futures
Contracts on Synchronous Markets

WP-93-11

P au l Kofm an, Tony Bouwman and Jam es T. M oser

Opportunity Cost and Prudentiality: A RepresentativeAgent Model ofFutures Clearinghouse Behavior

WP-93-18

H erbert L. B a er, Virginia G. France an d Jam es T. M oser

The Ownership Structure ofJapanese Financial Institutions

WP-93-19

H esna G enay

Origins of the Modem Exchange Clearinghouse: A History ofEarly
Clearing and Settlement Methods atFutures Exchanges

WP-94-3

Jam es T. M oser

The Effect of Bank-Held Derivatives on Credit Accessibility

WP-94-5

E lijah B rew er III, B ernadette A . M inton an d Jam es T. M oser

Small Business Investment Companies:
Financial Characteristics and Investments

WP-94-10

E lijah B rew er III an d H esna Genay

MACROECONOMIC ISSUES
An Examination ofChange inEnergy Dependence and Efficiency
in the Six Largest Energy Using Countries-1970-1988

WP-92-2

J a c k L .H e rv e y

Does theFederal Reserve Affect Asset Prices?

WP-92-3

Vefa Tarhan

Investment and Market Imperfections in theU.S. Manufacturing Sector

WP-92-4

P aula R. Worthington




3

W orking p aper series continued

Business Cycle Durations and Postwar Stabilization of the U.S. Economy

W P-92-6

M ark W. Watson

A Procedure forPredicting Recessions with Leading Indicators: Econometric Issues
WP-92-7
and Recent Performance
Jam es H. Stock an d M ark W. Watson

Production and Inventory Control atthe General Motors Corporation
During the 1920s and 1930s

WP-92-10

A nil K . K ashyap and D a v id W. W ilcox

Liquidity Effects, Monetary Policy and the Business Cycle

WP-92-15

Law rence J . Christiano and M artin Eichenbaum

Monetary Policy and External Finance: Interpreting the
Behavior ofFinancial Flows and InterestRate Spreads

WP-92-17

Kenneth N. Kuttner

Testing Long Run Neutrality

WP-92-18

R obert G. K ing and M ark W. Watson

A Policymaker’sGuide to Indicators ofEconomic Activity

W P-92-19

C harles E vans , Steven Strongin, and F rancesca Eugeni

Barriers toTrade and Union Wage Dynamics

WP-92-22

Ellen R. Rissman

Wage Growth and Sectoral Shifts: Phillips Curve Redux

WP-92-23

Ellen R. Rissm an

Excess Volatility and The Smoothing of InterestRates:
An Application Using Money Announcements

WP-92-25

Steven Strongin

Market Structure, Technology and the Cyclicality ofOutput

WP-92-26

Bruce Petersen an d Steven Strongin

The Identification of Monetary Policy Disturbances:
Explaining the Liquidity Puzzle

WP-92-27

Steven Strongin




4

W orking pap er series continued

Earnings Losses and Displaced Workers

WP-92-28

Louis S. Jacobson, R obert J. LaLonde, and D an iel G. Sullivan

Some Empirical Evidence of the Effects on Monetary Policy
Shocks on Exchange Rates

WP-92-32

M artin Eichenbaum an d C harles Evans

An Unobserved-Components Model of
Constant-Inflation Potential Output

WP-93-2

Kenneth N. K uttner

Investment, Cash Flow, and Sunk Costs

W P-93-4

P au la R. Worthington

Lessons from theJapanese Main Bank System
forFinancial System Reform inPoland

WP-93-6

Takeo H oshi, A nil K ashyap, an d G aryL ovem an

Credit Conditions and the Cyclical Behavior of Inventories

WP-93-7

A nil K . K ashyap, Owen A. Lam ont and Jerem y C. Stein

Labor Productivity During the Great Depression

WP-93-10

M ichael D . B ordo an d C harles L. Evans

Monetary Policy Shocks and Productivity Measures
in the G-7 Countries

WP-93-12

C harles L. E vans and Fernando Santos

Consumer Confidence and Economic Fluctuations

WP-93-13

John G. M atsusaka a n d A rg ia M. Sbordone

Vector Autoregressions and Cointegration

WP-93-14

M ark W. W atson

Testing forCointegration When Some of the
Cointegrating Vectors Are Known

WP-93-15

M ichael T. K . H orvath an d M ark W. Watson

Technical Change, Diffusion, and Productivity

WP-93-16

Jeffrey R. C am pbell




5

W alking p aper series continued

Economic Activity and the Short-Term Credit Markets:
An Analysis of Prices and Quantities

WP-93-17

Benjamin M . Friedman an d Kenneth N. K uttner

Cyclical Productivity in a Model ofLabor Hoarding

WP-93-20

A rgia M. Sbordone

The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks: Evidence from the Flow ofFunds

WP-94-2

Law rence J. Christiano, M artin Eichenbaum an d Charles E vans

Algorithms for Solving Dynamic Models with Occasionally Binding Constraints

WP-94-6

Law rence J. Christiano and Jonas D .M . Fisher

Identification and the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks

WP-94-7

Law rence J. Christiano, M artin Eichenbaum and C harles L. Evans

Small Sample Bias in G M M Estimation ofCovariance Structures

WP-94-8

Joseph G. A ltonji an d L ew is M . Segal

Interpreting theProcyclical Productivity ofManufacturing Sectors:
External Effects ofLabor Hoarding?

WP-94-9

A rgia M . Sbordone

Evidence on Structural Instability in Macroeconomic Time Series Relations

WP-94-13

Jam es H. Stock and M ark W. Watson

The Post-War U.S. Phillips Curve: A Revisionist Econometric History

WP-94-14

R obert G. K ing an d M ark W. Watson

The Post-War U.S. Phillips Curve: A Comment

WP-94-15

C harles L. Evans

Identificationof Inflation-Unemployment

WP-94-16

B ennett T. M cCallum

The Post-War U.S. PhillipsCurve: A RevisionistEconometric History
Response toEvans and McCallum

WP-94-17

R obert G. King and M ark W. Watson




6