View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

79-5
c
a;

E
E

o

u
"O

c

ra

s
V
’>
a;

c*
c

a>

library

F £ 0 t K , U R E S E R V E SANK
Of CHICAGO

E

03

CL

a;

a

ra
a>
a;

o'
a>
A Series of Occasional Papers in Draft Form Prepared by Members"o

MODELING THE MARKET FOR
BANK DEBT CAPITAL
Chayim Herzig-Marx
m

o

m
73
>

i
—
73

m

LT)

m

73

<

m
03

>
Z
t:

O

-n

n
x
n
>

a
o

Modeling the Market for Bank Debt Capital

by

Chayim Herzig-Marx

Department of Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The views expressed herein are solely those of the author and
do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. The material
contained is of a preliminary nature, is circulated to stimulate
discussion, and is not to be quoted without permission.




Modeling the Market for Bank Debt Capital

I.

Introduction
Considerable literature has appeared in recent years concerning

the response by financial markets to measurable differences in bank
riskiness.

Most extensively studied has been the market for long­

term bank debt (capital notes or debentures, subordinated to deposits).
Despite using similar models and samples, several of the studies came
to somewhat divergent conclusions, especially as regards the effect of
leverage on bank borrowing rates.

The purpose of this paper is to

explore possible explanations for such divergences and also to present
new empirical results on factors influencing the cost of bank debt.
To this end, a data set encompassing most fixed-rate issues by
banks and bank holding companies from 1971 to 1978 was assembled and
analyzed statistically.

This sample, 278 observations in total, is

considerably larger than those previously available to researchers
and thus allows more detailed analyses.

A new feature of our data

set is that bank debt placed privately is included in the sample,
which has the particular effect of extending our observations well
down into the range of small banks and holding companies.

Our sample

thus encompasses a much broader spectrum of bank sizes than previous
studies.




The factors we examine in an attempt to account for the diver­
gences noted above are (1) whether the debt is the obligation of a
bank or of a bank holding company, (2) whether the debt is the obli­
gation of a "large" or a "small" banking organization, and (3) whether
the debt was issued before or after the failure of Franklin National
Bank, an event that by most accounts had a substantial impact on the
banking and investing community.

In addition, we examine our sample

to see if privately placed issues obey the same risk premium model
as publicly issued debt.

In general, the results of our empirical

tests support the finding that leverage is not significant in explain­
ing risk premium, with the possible exception of the period before
the failure of Franklin.

We find significant effects for the bank/

holding company and small/large distinctions, as well as the public/
private distinction.

The effect of the failure of Franklin has pre­

viously received attention, and results in this paper corroborate
existing findings.

Finally, we note a disturbing implication of our

study for the regulatory function.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.

Section

II reviews several recent studies of bank debt, noting both similar­
ities among their results and differences.

Section III outlines the

theoretical model used in the present paper, and section IV presents
empirical estimates.
conclusions.




Section V summarizes the results and presents

- 3 -

II.

Previous Literature
The first examination of risk premiums on bank debt is by Pettway

(1976), who uses a model quite similar to that of Fisher (1959) in the
seminal study of the valuation of long-term debt.

Pettway's sample is

composed of primary market observations (new issues) on bank and
holding company debt issued from 1971 to 1974.

All issues in his sample

are non-convertible, fixed-rate, fixed-maturity, and publicly placed.
Pettway's basic findings are that bank risk variables do not signi­
ficantly contribute to explaining risk premiums, although financial
variables such as size of the issue, term to maturity, and period of
time since banks began issuing long-term debt are important.

In

particular, neither of two leverage variables is significant, the
ratio of borrowed funds to total capital or the ratio of debt capital
to equity capital.

Also, the distinction between bank and holding

company issues is not significant (tested with an intercept dummy
variable), nor is the size of the issuing firm, measured by total
assets.
Beighley (1977) focuses his attention on whether leverage should
be measured at the issuing firm level or at the consolidated holding
company level and also considers in greater detail whether leveraged
funds consist of all debt or just debt capital.

He uses secondary

market observations for 1972 to 1974, examining each year separately.
His sample consists only of holding company debt, all non-convertible,
fixed-rate, and publicly issued.
dict Pettway's.




Beighley's results largely contra­

He finds both size of the issuer and leverage to be

- 4 -

significant determinants of risk premium.

In addition, the ratio

of net loan losses to total loans, used as a proxy of the riskiness
of bank assets, becomes increasingly significant from 1972 to 1974.
Beighley does not report results for marketability of the debt issue
or term to maturity.
Martin’s (1977) paper is quite similar to those of Pettway and
Beighley.

He examines a single cross-section of debt securities

issued publicly between 1971 and 1974, using secondary market obser­
vations on debt yields from early 1975.

He includes two earnings

variables in his model, growth in earnings per share of common stock
and an interest coverage ratio, along with capitalization variables,
term to maturity, size of the issue, and an intercept dummy for hold­
ing companies.

While he finds term to maturity and marketability to

be significant, the same result obtained by Pettway, leverage is
insignificant in explaining risk premium.

Growth in earnings per

share and interest coverage are only significant if the size of the
issue and the size of the issuing firm are excluded from the regres­
sion model, implying considerable collinearity among the variables.
Holding company status in insignificant.

Thus, Martin corroborates

Pettway’s finding that leverage is insignificant as a determinant of
risk premium.
Herzig-Marx (1979b) also employs secondary market quotations in
his study, using early 1976 as the date of observation.

Both bank

and holding company issuers are represented in his sample, which




- 5 -

includes some convertible issues as well as straight debt.

Inclusion

of these convertibles is justified on the grounds that all such issues
trade far below par, at prices which approximate their value as
straight debt; a statistical examination supports this contention.
Herzig-Marx also includes several indenture provisions in his model,
such as provisions for early retirement of the debt and restrictions
on dividend payments by the issuing firm.

He also includes an earnings

variable, the gross rate of return on income-producing assets, and the
ratio of provision for loan losses to total loans as a proxy for the
riskiness of bank assets.

The results of this study indicate that

asset risk is a significant determinant of risk premiums, which is
what Beighley found, and that the rate of return on assets is also
significant, similar to Martin’s result.
the issuer is significant, as is leverage.

In addition, the size of
Term to maturity and mar­

ketability of the debt issue are not significant.
In sum, these four studies, although displaying considerable
uniformity of approach, empirical methodology, and sample construc­
tion, nonetheless reach different conclusions regarding the variables
that determine risk premiums on bank debt.

Particularly vexing is

the lack of agreement concerning the effect of leverage.

Among the

important sample differences are whether the observations represent
primary or secondary market quotations, the time period under obser­
vation, and whether banks or bank holding companies are included in
the samples.

This paper will address each of these differences in

an effort to ascertain their effects.




- 6-

III.

The Model
For this study, bank debt issues are observed in the primary

market, that is, at the time of issuance.
from the period 1971 to 1978.

Observations are drawn

Consequently, one can distinguish

among three types of variables that influence risk premiums.

First,

conditions in money and capital markets, especially as they pertain
to the economy’s position in the business cycle, must be considered.
Second, investor perceptions of the relative riskiness of issuing
banks and bank holding companies are included; especially prominent
in this category is investor attitudes toward the degree of leverage
employed.

Third, investor attitudes toward factors other than bank

riskiness are examined.

In this last category are the size of the

debt issue, indicating its marketability, and the term to maturity
of the debt.

Marketability has frequently been found to be a signi­

ficant determinant of risk premium, as noted in section II, and can
be viewed as an index of market risk should the investor be forced
to liquidate his holdings prior to maturity.

Term to maturity of the

debt is important since investors’ risk perceptions vary with the expected holding period.

In particular, the probability of default by

a risky issuer will be an increasing function of the investment horizon,
while the probability of default on risk-free debt is by definition
invariant to the investment horizon.

We thus expect premium to increase

with longer terms to maturity and to decrease with larger, i.e., more
marketable, issues.




7

Conditions in capital markets are of evident importance in
determining primary borrowing rates for banks.

Examining the rate

spread between Moody’s Aaa- and Baa-rated bonds, Jaffee (1975)
found that cyclical variations in risk premiums could be satisfac­
torily explained by six variables relating to the economy’s position
in the business cycle:

consumer sentiment, the unemployment rate,

the growth rate of corporate retained earnings, the growth rate of
fixed capital investment, the growth rate of output prices, and the
level of interest rates.

Based on the strength of Jaffee’s results,

we use the Baa-Aaa rate spread to index the economy’s position in the
business cycle, in effect turning his model around in the interests
of an economical empirical specification.

We also include the yield

on Treasury securities in our model to index the level of interest
rates in the market.

While Jaffee used the Baa bond rate for this

purpose, bond ratings are slow to reflect changes in corporate
riskiness, especially small changes.

In addition, recent theoretical

work by Merton (1974) derives the result that risk premiums are inverse­
ly related to the risk-free rate of interest.

Capital market conditions

are thus indexed by two variables, the Baa-Aaa rate spread and the level
of Treasury rates.
Two variables are used to measure riskiness of issuing banks
and bank holding companies.

The first is the gross rate of return

on income-producing assets (total assets less cash and due from banks
and plant and equipment).

In accordance with firmly established

finance theory, riskier assets should yield higher gross rates of




return.

The second variable is leverage, measured by the ratio of

total interest-bearing debt to total assets.

Interest-bearing debt

excludes demand deposits, most of which are held under compensating
balances to assure lines of credit and thus are not as risk-sensitive
as interest-bearing liabilities.
Besides these six variables, we wish to examine four other factors
that might influence debt costs:

private vs. public placements, bank

vs. holding company issuer, small vs. large issuer, and before vs.
after the failure of Franklin National Bank.

To do this, we subdivide

the sample according to those four categories and perform an analysis
of covariance to determine if the subsamples fit the same regression
model.

Since we are concerned with slope differences between groups,

and not primarily with intercept differences, we include four intercept
dummy variables in our basic regression model.

The variables appearing

in the model are as follows:




PREMIUM

=

arithmetic difference between the yield to
maturity on bank debt and yield to maturity
on Treasury debt of the same maturity;

ISSUE

=

size of the debt issue in millions of dollars;

TERM

=

term to maturity in years;

TYLD

=

risk-free rate of return for the same maturity
as the debt issue under observation;

SPREAD

=

the Baa-Aaa rate spread;

RGROSS

=

gross rate of return on income-producing
assets;

LEVERAGE

=

the ratio of interest-bearing liabilities
to total assets;

PRIVATE

0 if publicly placed, 1 if privately;

- 9 -

HC

=

0 if bank debt, X if holding company debt;

LARGE

=

0 if issuer under $5 billion in total assets,
1 if issuer over $5 billion in total assets;

FRANKLIN

*

0 if debt issued before 1974 Q4, 1 if issued
after 1974 Q3.

Expected signs are positive for TERM, SPREAD, RGROSS, and LEVERAGE,
and negative for ISSUE and TYLD.

The expected signs for the dummy vari­

ables are positive for PRIVATE and FRANKLIN, negative for LARGE, and
indeterminate for HC.

The reason the sign of PRIVATE is expected to be

positive is that smaller banks may tend to favor the private placement
market as well as banks whose financial soundness is such that public
disclosure might cause loss of deposits or higher borrowing costs.
Previous research has found that bank borrowing costs rose after the
failure of Franklin National Bank, and several studies have found
larger banks able to borrow on better terms than smaller banks.

The

reason we include a size variable as an intercept term is that collinearity between issuer size and issue size is thus mitigated, as well
as allowing us to perform a careful analysis of covariance.
effects are present in the HC dummy variable.

Two

First, holding companies

can have more diversified sources of income, which should reduce their
probabilities of failing and hence result in lower risk premiums.
Nonetheless, one should remember that most activities allowed to holding
companies are also permissible for national banks.

Second, investors

in holding company debt have a legal claim only on the parent company,
while bank subsidiaries are the primary sources of earnings.




Because

10 -

creditors of the holding company are farther removed from the actual
revenue stream, this implies a positive relationship with risk pre­
mium.

The empirical results will indicate which of these two effects

dominates.

IV.

Empirical Results
Table 1 gives some general characteristics of the sample used

for this study.

In total, the sample consists of 278 newly-issued

capital notes or debentures, all non-convertible.
issuer size is from $31 million to $74 billion.

The range of
Thus, in terms of

both number of observations and sizes of firms, the present sample
is much more inclusive than previous studies.
Table 2 presents regression results for the risk premium model
described in section III.
for the entire sample.

The column labeled "All" estimates the model

Only one sign, that for LEVERAGE, is counter to

expectation, although the coefficient is not significant by usual sta­
tistical criteria.
not significant.

The other bank riskiness variable, RGROSS, is also
These two results tend to confirm Pettway’s original

findings and those of Martin.
the 5% level or better.

All other variables are significant at

Overall, the model performs satisfactorily,

considering the long time period covered and the extensive range of
bank sizes.
Examining the quantitative effect of individual variables, one
can see that marketability, while significant, does not exert much
of an effect on risk premium. Each additional million dollars of debt




- 11 -

issued reduces risk premium by only 0.2 basis points, clearly quite
a small effect.

This may indicate that investors in bank debt are

generally not expecting to sell their holding prior to maturity, so
that potential trading volume is of no great concern.

Alternatively,

it may reflect the fact that private issues are included in the sample.
For these observations, ISSUE probably measures negotiating costs on a
per dollar of debt basis, indicating that there are no great economies
of scale in private debt placements.
Term to maturity has a more substantial impact.
year adds just over 2 basis points to required yield.

Each additional
The yield dif­

ferential between a 10- and a 30-year bond would thus be 42 basis
points, which is not inconsiderable.
The variables denoting conditions in capital markets and the
economy’s position in the business cycle are both highly significant
and quantitatively important.

TYLD, which references the overall

level of interest rates, is expected to be higher during expansionary
phases and lower during recessionary phases, ceteris paribus.

Thus,

as economic conditions turn more favorable, risk premiums on debt
fall.

This is the result predicted by Merton’s (1974) model.

Simi­

larly, the Baa-Aaa rate spread tends to widen as the economy moves
into a cyclical trough.

Thus, as economic conditions deteriorate

risk premiums on bank debt rise.
Private placements, as expected, tend to require yields approxi­
mately 27 basis points higher than public issues, ceteris paribus.




12 -

Large issuers are able to borrow on cheaper terms, and issues placed
after the failure of Franklin tend to carry much higher costs (but
more about this below).

Results for the holding company dummy vari­

able indicate that the diversification effect, if any, is swamped by
the fact that holding company obligations are farther removed from
the main source of income, namely the bank subsidiaries.
While most of these results make good intuitive sense, they are
all subject to qualification based upon the analyses of covariance
to be discussed next.

The purpose of these further analyses is to

determine whether the regression results are sensitive to sample
characteristics.

The statistical theory underlying analysis of cov­

ariance is as follows.

A measure of the extent to which an empirical

model fails to accord with the data used to test it is the sum of
squared residuals.

The residual sum of squares can always be reduced

by adding another variable to the regression model, provided that
additional variable is not perfectly collinear with variables pre­
viously included.

As a special case of adding more variables, con­

sider adding a complete replication of the original variables, except _
that each replication is used to estimate the model for one of two
(or more) mutually exclusive and exhaustive subsets of the original
sample.

Clearly, the combined residual sums of squares for the two

subsamples will be smaller than the single residual sum of squares
for the original sample, because in effect we are using twice as many
parameters to estimate the same relationship.

Whether a significant

improvement in explanatory power has been obtained by thus subdividing




13 -

the sample can be tested by the amount of reduction in the residual
sums of squares.

It turns out than an F-test is appropriate for

answering this question.^

The line labeled "F-ANCOVA" in Table 2

presents the value for the F-test obtained for each of the four ana­
lyses of covariance reported.

The test statistic reported, however,

excludes the effect of allowing the intercepts to vary; in other
words, the effect of the classifying dummy variable is taken into
account.
Results for the analysis of public vs. private placements indi­
cates that, by usual statistical criteria (5% level of Type I error),
there is no difference between public and private placement markets.
Indeed, a finding strongly to the contrary would be most surprising,
since private and public placements are close substitutes and both
markets are reasonably efficient; consequently, one would expect both
markets to evaluate a debt issue in about the same way.

One might

note, however, that the coefficient of SPREAD appears to be substan­
tially different, being negative and insignificant for public place­
ments and positive and highly significant for private.

This probably .

reflects the fact that private placements became a larger proportion
of all debt issued in the later years of the sample (1976 to 1978;
see Table 1).

Thus, this may be mirroring the effect, to be noted

below, concerning issues placed before and after Franklin failed.
The distinction between issuers that are banks and those that
are bank holding companies is depicted in the next two columns of




- 14 -

Table 2.

The F-test for slope differences indicates that the two

subsamples fit the same regression model.

In the case of this ana­

lysis, no important coefficient differences are apparent.

Thus, one

can conclude that financial markets evaluate specific risk and econo­
mic factors similarly for banks as for bank holding companies.

All

other things equal, though, holding companies face slightly higher
borrowing costs, probably due to the fact that bond investors have
a claim on the earnings of the holding company while most holding
company earnings flow from the bank subsidiaries.
We next consider the possibility that small and large banking
organizations are evaluated differently by financial markets.

The

F-test again indicates no significant subsample differences, although
here two coefficient estimates appear to differ substantially between
the two subsamples.

The coefficient of SPREAD is positive and sig­

nificant for small organizations while negative and insignificant for
large.

To what this difference might be due is not clear, although

as reported below sample differences for SPREAD can be shown to exist
The intercept dummy variable for holding companies is similarly posi­
tive and significant for small organizations while negative and in­
significant for large.

This probably reflects the fact that very few

large organizations are not holding companies (49 out of 57 issues by
large organizations were obligations of holding companies).

That

slope differences are not significant, while the intercept for large
organizations is negative and highly significant, suggests an inter­
esting interpretation.




As far as risk characteristics and economic

- 15

out arrives 5 to 7 days after the due date; if more time lapses and the
print-out has not arrived, inquiries should be made with Continental,
able to borrow at lower costs than smaller organizations.

This suggests

that there is some factor, unrelated to measurable differences in riski­
ness, related only to the size of the organization, that influences
investors1 perceptions of the probability of default.

The factor that

occurs immediately to mind is the bank regulatory apparatus.

Many

students of the banking industry have suggested that large banks are
less likely to fail because regulators are less likely to allow them
to fail.

Our empirical estimates suggest that regulatory protection

translates into approximately an 18 basis point advantage in the cost
of long-term funds.
Finally, we consider sample differences based upon issues placed
before and after the failure of Franklin National Bank.

The F-test

for this subdivision of the sample indicates significant slope dif­
ferences for the two time periods.

Previous literature, however,

has established that investor perceptions of bank risk probably did
undergo change due to Franklin’s demise (Fraser and McCormack 1978).
The change itself has been identified as investors’ views of the riski­
ness of the banking industry relative to the business cycle and concern
only the SPREAD variable (Herzig-Marx 1979a).

Netting out this latter

effect, the value of the F-test falls to 1.633, which is not significant even at the 10% level.

Thus, once we take account of the differ­

ing effect of SPREAD, there are overall no slope differences before
and after the failure of Franklin National Bank.




The coefficient

- 16 -

of LEVERAGE seems to change substantially, though, going from positive
and significant in the before period to negative and marginally sig­
nificant in the after period.

This could be interpreted as evidence

that highly leveraged banks no longer came to the debt market after
Franklin; sample values belie this interpretation, however, since
mean values (standard deviations) of LEVERAGE are 49.0% (10.7%) be­
fore Franklin and 57.0% (10.8%) after.

One might further note that

the only regression in which leverage is statistically significant is
in the before period.

This implies that previous studies which drew

most of their observations before Franklin failed might have found
leverage to be a statistically significant determinant of risk premium,
while those whose sample was predominately from the after Franklin
period would not have discerned any effect of leverage.

V.

Summary and Conclusions
This paper has presented further evidence on the pricing of bank

debt capital in the primary market.

Using a large data set covering

straight debt issues from 1971 to 1978, we have presented empirical
estimates for a valuation model encompassing business cycle factors,
bank risk variables, and investor attitudes toward marketability and
the investment horizon.

We have furthermore stratified the sample

in four ways to examine the sensitivity of the model to data char­
acteristics.

In general, the results were satisfactory and quite

consistent across different subsamples.




~ 17 -

Summarizing first the results bearing on divergences evident in
previous studies, we find that, on the whole, leverage is not signi­
ficant in explaining variations in risk premiums.

We draw the infer­

ence that such divergences as are found in the literature may well be
due to the period sampled, since observations before Franklin failed
tend to show a significant coefficient for LEVERAGE while those after
do not.

We find, however, that an intercept dummy variable denoting

issues that are obligations of bank holding companies is positive and
highly significant, counter to previous results by Pettway and Martin.
We believe the significance for HC probably stems from our use of a
longer period of observation, since its coefficient is only significant
in the after Franklin period.

We also find strong support for the

investor variables ISSUE and TERM, measuring marketability and the
investment horizon, respectively.

Studies that omitted these variables,

such as Beighley, are probably guilty of misspecification.
Variables denoting the economy’s position in the business cycle,
TYLD and SPREAD, are consistently significant in our regression model.
The empirical results in this paper indicate that investors believe
the banking industry’s level of risk to be countercyclical, as one
would expect:

risk falls during expansionary periods and rises during

contractions.

This has only been the case following the failure of

Franklin National Bank, however, corroborating previous empirical work.
Finally, we have presented new evidence concerning the private
placement market and the effect of issuer size.




The private placement

- 18 -

market appears to operate in much the same manner as the public issue
market, with the possible exception that riskier and/or smaller banks
tend to favor private placements.

Apart from an intercept difference,

privately placed debt is evaluated the same as publicly issued debt.
These findings lend support to the position that financial markets
be allowed a greater role in monitoring bank risk-taking.

Reservations

concerning the efficacy of financial market regulation are to a great
extent concerned over the smaller banking organizations and also
those that are much riskier than the norm.

Since many of these banks

are forced into the private market, for example when regulatory authori­
ties demand an increase in bank capitalization, finding that private
placement markets efficiently price risky debt makes reliance on fin­
ancial markets more attractive from a regulatory viewpoint.
Concerning the effect of issuer size, our results indicate that,
apart from an intercept difference, small and large banking organiza­
tions are evaluated alike.

This strongly implies that measurable

differences in bank riskiness influence debt prices the same regardless
of issuer size, but that size per se imparts a downward effect to bor^
rowing costs for large organizations.

These finding are consistent

with the view, frequently voiced, that bank regulation itself prompts
investors to believe that large banking organizations are less likely
to fail simply because they are large.

If so, bank regulation would

seem to have a particularly perverse effect on the riskiness of the
industry.




REFERENCES
Beighley, H. Prescott. "The Risk Perceptions of Bank Holding Company
Debtholders." Journal of Bank Research, Summer 1977.
Fisher, Lawrence. "Determinants of Risk Premiums on Corporate Bonds."
Journal of Political Economy, June 1959.
Fraser, Donald R. and McCormack, J. Patrick. "Large Bank Failures and
Investor Risk Perceptions: Evidence from the Debt Market."
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, September 1978.
Herzig-Marx, Chayim. "Large Bank Failures and Investor Perceptions of
the Riskiness of Banking." Staff Memoranda 79-3, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, 1979a.
Herzig-Marx, Chayim. "Comparing Market and Regulatory Assessments of
Bank Soundness." Staff Memoranda 79-4, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, 1979b.
Irving Trust Company. Report of Debt Securities Issued by Commercial
Banks and Holding Companies. Corporate Financial Counseling
Department, bimonthly with annual summary.
Jaffee, Dwight M. "Cyclical Variations in the Risk Structure of
Interest Rates." Journal of Monetary Economics, July 1975.
Johnston, J. Econometric Methods, second edition.
Hill Book Company, 1972.

New York:

Martin, Michael J. "Risk Premiums and Bank Bond Investors."
Economic Journal, July 1977.

McGraw-

Atlantic

Merton, Robert C. "On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Struc­
ture of Interest Rates." Journal of Finance, May 1974.
Pettway, Richard H. "Market Tests of Capital Adequacy of Large Com­
mercial Banks." Journal of Finance, June 1976.
Weaver, Anne S. and Herzig-Marx, Chayim. "A Comparative Study of the
Effect of Leverage on Risk Premiums for Debt Issues of Banks and
Bank Holding Companies." Staff Memoranda 78-1, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, 1978.




FOOTNOTES

^Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, The views expressed are
those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. The
author wishes to express his appreciation to Anne S. Weaver for her
assistance in this project and to Richard H. Pettway for his inval­
uable counsel and friendship.
■^For the derivation of a variety of tests relating to analysis of
covariance, see Johnston (1972, pages 192-297).
2 To take account of the known change in the coefficient of SPREAD
before and after Franklin failed, the basic regression model was
estimated with SPREAD and an interactive term between SPREAD and
FRANKLIN both included in the equation. The residual sum of squares
from this augmented equation was compared with the sum of the two
residual sums of squares from partitioning the sample. Using the
appropriate number of degrees of freedom, this F-test had the value
1.633.




Table 1
Sample Characteristics

Year

Number of
Observations

1971

13

1.40

0.52

5.97-

0.41

13

0

13

0

1972

56

1.32

0.54

6.09

0.24

24

32

41

15

1973

27

1.10

0.39

6.94

0.22

11

16

14

13

1974

17

1.25

0.77

7.25

0.47

4

13

13

4

1975

24

1.71

0.57

7.42

0.36

7

17

19

5

1976

40

1.57

0.62

7.67

0.29

7

33

17

23

1977

54

1.24

0.44

7.53

0.26

24

30

12

42

1978

47

0.80

0.32

8.28

0.28

27

20

13

34




Risk Premium
mean st. dev.

Risk-free Rate
mean st. dev.

# Issues
banks bhcs

Primary Market
public private

Table 2
Regression Results for Risk Premium Model

All
INTERCEPT

Public

vs.__ Private

4.122

5.347

4.978

0.002
(1.019)

-0.003
(1.070)

4.463
- 0 .002 **

Bank

vs.

HC
4.161
0.002
(1.503)

(2.059)

-0.003***
(2.860)

TERM

0.021***
(5.191)

0.023***
(5.704)

0.019**
(2.109)

0.026***
(4.236)

0 . 020 * * *
(3.420)

TYLD

-0.592***
(9.923)

-0.511***
(7.543)

-0.708***
(6.759)

-0.625***
(7.929)

-0.565***
(6.132)

SPREAD

0.656**
(2.383)

-0.003

1.484***
(2.958)

0.373
( 1 . 100)

0.922**
(2.042)

ISSUE

RGROSS

LEVERAGE

0.000

-

( 0 . 010)

0.001

0.000

-

( 0 . 012)

(0.041)

(0.009)

-0.048
(1.609)

0.025
(0.844)

-0.003
(1.224)

0.001
(0.157)

-0.007
(1.550)

-0.003
(0.891)

-0.003
(0.633)

0.271***
(2.985)

0.230**
(2.443)

-

-

PRIVATE

0.265***
(4.059)

HC

0.180***
(2.842)

0.119
(1.339)

0.106
(1.096)

LARGE

-0.283***
(2.628)

-0.219**
(2.045)

-0.313
(1.326)

0.007
(0.029)

-0.364***
(2.776)

FRANKLIN

0.581***
(4.256)

0.724***
(4.809)

0.428*
(1.784)

0.863***
(4.141)

0.445**
(2.33.5)

0.354

0.434

-2
R

0.415

0.445

F

20.619***

13.540***

RSS

50.616

17.279

267

132

d.f.
F-ANCOVA

1.761*

9.208***

0.402

10.864***

12.931***

30.408

15.093

34.247

126

107

151
0.741

Notes: Absolute values of t-statistics are in parentheses; asterisks
indicate significance levels (2-tailed tests) as follows: *, 10%;
**, 5%; ***, 1%; RSS is residual sum of squares; d.f. is degrees of
freedom; F-ANCOVA is F-test for slope differences.




Table 2 (con't)
Regression Results; for Risk Premium Model

After

Large

Before

4.728

2.750

3.860

4.674

ISSUE

-0.005
(1.549)

-0.001
(1.180)

-0.003**
(2.111)

-0.001
(1.158)

TERM

0.025***
(4.740)

0.013**
(2.026)

0.031***
(8.479)

0.015
(1.992)

TYLD

-0.636***
(9.499)

-0.293**
(2.239)

-0.513***
(9.024)

-0.598***
(6.138)

SPREAD

0.759**
(2.399)

-0.228
(0.411)

-0.632**
(2.409)

1.652***
(3.795)

RGROSS

-0.012
(0.517)

0.048
(1.398)

0.041
(1.620)

-0.013
(0.496)

LEVERAGE

-0.003
(1.074)

-0.003
(0.542)

0.008**
(2.335)

-0.006*
(1.724)

PRIVATE

0.230***
(2.787)

0.270*
(1.994)

0.238***
(3.079)

0.281***
(3.022)

HC

0.225***
(3.112)

-0.231
(1.355)

-0.138
(1.367)

0.166***
(1.995)

-0.093
(0.703)

-0.344**
(2.250)

Small
INTERCEPT

vs.

LARGE

FRANKLIN
-2
R

0.664***
(4.058)
0.374

0.369
(1.473)
0.227

F

15.604***

2.829***

RSS

43.209

5.319

d.f.
F-ANCOVA




211

47
1.233

vs.

0.656

0.395

23.901***
8.130

13.202***
36.475

99

159
3.863***