View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Liquidity Constraints of the
Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

REVISED
June 2016
WP 2009-20

Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class∗
Jeffrey R. Campbell† and Zvi Hercowitz‡
June 2016

Abstract
Existing evidence from the U.S. middle class shows that the MPC out of tax rebates
is either invariant to household liquid assets or a U-shaped function thereof. In contrast,
precautionary savings models predict a monotone decreasing relationship. We bridge
this gap with term saving: households’ savings for large foreseen expenditures, which
we find empirically widespread. Once incorporated into a calibrated precautionary
savings model, term saving generates empirically realistic MPCs. This is because the
approaching expenditure simultaneously motivates asset accumulation and raises MPCs
by shortening the effective planning horizon. We conclude that liquidity constraints of
the middle class are quantitatively important.

∗

We thank R. Andrew Butters, Ross Doppelt, and Ryan Peters for their excellent research assistance
and Sumit Agarwal, Gadi Barlevy, Mariacristina DeNardi, Simon Gilchrist, and Monika Piazzesi for their
thoughtful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors. They do not necessarily reflect
the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Federal Reserve System, or its Board of Governors.
†
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, USA and CentER, Tilburg University, The Netherlands
‡
Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya, Israel and Tel Aviv University, Israel
JEL Code: E21
Keywords: Fiscal Policy, Tax Rebates, Marginal Propensity to Consume, Term Saving, Precautionary Saving

1

Introduction

Liquidity constraints of middle-class households are of key importance for a host of macroeconomic questions, such as the size of the fiscal multiplier from tax cuts and the nature of
monetary policy propagation. However, it may seem implausible that middle class households face liquidity constraints because they typically hold liquid assets. By definition, these
can be converted immediately into consumption. Nevertheless, evidence from consumption
responses to tax changes in the U.S. casts doubt on this view. For example, Shapiro and
Slemrod (2003) found that households that own publicly-traded stocks spent no less and probably more out of one-time tax rebates arising from the Bush tax cuts than did poorer and
more plausibly liquidity-constrained households. That is, there is evidence that middle-class
households with liquid wealth can act like they face substantial liquidity constraints.
Carroll and Kimball (1996) proved that the consumption function from a precautionary
savings model is concave in cash on hand (the sum of current earnings and past savings).
Therefore, that model’s consumption responses to tax rebates decline with household wealth.
To bridge this gap between theory and data, we consider the possibility that a household’s
assets are accumulated to pay for a foreseen extraordinary expense. In that case, high assets
signal a shortage of liquidity relative to the approaching expense rather than an abundance
of liquidity arising from past good luck. For a household expecting such an expense, the
time remaining until it arrives is a key state variable. Hence, we call the accumulated assets
term savings. We provide household-level evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances
(SCF) that term savings motivations (particularly the purchase of a house or the payment
of a child’s college tuition) are at least as prevalent among the middle class as are standard
precautionary savings motivations like earnings risks.
Term saving does not overturn the basic notion that high MPCs reflect liquidity constraints. However, it does bring into question the common view that only individuals with
little liquid wealth can be liquidity constrained. With term saving, an expectation that liquid
wealth will be low in the future can induce households with currently substantial liquid assets
to behave as liquidity constrained and to have high MPCs today. Such expectations arise
naturally when households foresee an approaching large expenditure.
For our empirical analysis, we assign households to the middle class if they are not in the
top five percentiles of the wealth distribution, had after-tax labor income above the poverty
line, and did not receive Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (food stamps) in the previous year. This definition allows for the possibility that middle-class households occasionally
spend all available financial assets. Our matching theoretical definition of a middle-class
1

household combines impatience (relative to the market rate of interest), a borrowing constraint, and a recurring major expenditure. Impatience prevents middle class households
from accumulating wealth and joining the rich, while the borrowing constraint keeps them
from permanent immiseration in debt. With these two features alone, middle class households would become hand-to-mouth consumers like the “spenders” in Mankiw (2000). The
foreseen expenditure provides a motivation to save.
Our term savings model embodies this theoretical definition within the standard infinitelylived household. We begin by developing intuition in a deterministic environment. The
household has utility from ordinary consumption and from a special good. Ordinary consumption always increases utility, but the household has a taste for the special good only at
equally-spaced points in time. The taste for the special good induces term savings. For it
to induce substantially different behavior than does earnings risk in a precautionary savings
model, the hazard rate for its arrival should increase with the time since its last occurrence.
The predetermined times for the special good’s consumption starkly capture this requirement.
In this deterministic model, the household eventually settles into a cycle. At its beginning, a long time remains until the special good’s consumption. Although impatience might
initially dominate the household’s decisions and drive wealth to zero, consumption smoothing
eventually motivates the household to save. When the taste for the special good arrives, the
household spends all cash on hand and the borrowing constraint binds. This cycle exemplifies Zeldes’s (1984) distinction between a currently-binding liquidity constraint and one that
could possibly bind in the future. As he noted, expectations of future liquidity constraints
effectively shorten the horizon over which a currently unconstrained household optimizes and
thereby generate a large marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of transitory income.
Here, assets accumulate as the foreseen expenditure approaches, and so the current model
predicts that the observed MPC rises with wealth for households that are currently saving.
The quantitative assessment of term savings requires us to add earnings risk to the analysis, because precautionary saving works against term saving in shaping the empirical relationship between household wealth and the MPC. We calibrate income risk to match observations
of earnings from the PSID in Meghir and Pistaferri (2004) and we choose the household’s
discount factor and the special good’s expenditure share to match percentiles of wealth relative to labor income from middle-class households in recent waves of the SCF. With this
calibration, the average MPC from a from a one-time transfer is a relatively flat function
of wealth. For two households at either extreme of the wealth distribution, with no wealth
and wealth exceeding current annual earnings, the MPCs equal 53 percent and 72 percent.
If we remove the special good from the model and recalibrate the discount factor, the MPC
2

strongly decreases with wealth. That of households with no wealth is virtually unchanged
while that for households with wealth exceeding current annual earnings falls to 15 percent.
The pervasiveness of liquidity constraints has received a great deal of attention in the
consumption literature. Using the 1983 SCF, Jappelli (1990) found that about 20 percent
of U.S. households were either rejected for credit or rationally anticipated being rejected if
they applied. Other work has focused on documenting liquidity constraints as violations of
Hall’s (1978) random walk hypothesis for the marginal utility of consumption. Using food
consumption data from the PSID, Hall and Mishkin (1982) found that about 20 percent of
consumption is a simple function of current income, as if those households are consuming
“hand-to-mouth.” Estimating a similar model with aggregate data, Campbell and Mankiw
(1989) concluded that “Half of households follow the ‘rule-of-thumb’ of consuming their current income.” Also using the PSID, Zeldes (1989) observed that consumption growth of
households with low wealth responds negatively to lagged disposable income. Because the
analogous estimated responses for households with high wealth are weaker and sometimes
statistically insignificant, Zeldes interpreted his results as evidence in favor of liquidity constraints. With this interpretation, different definitions of “low wealth” imply that between 30
to 66 percent of households are liquidity constrained. Jappelli and Pistaferri (2010) reviewed
the considerable literature that has refined this approach and applied it to other countries
and data sets. In this paper, however, we concentrate on evidence from the U.S. only.
Hayashi (1987) noted that these studies have only limited implications for the average
MPC from temporary income in part because “the horizon of those who satisfy the Euler
equation is unknown ...”.1 The importance of term saving we document with the SCF leads
us to conclude that Hayashi’s “horizon” is typically much less than a decade, so that most
of the middle class acts as if they are liquidity constrained. Our model’s recurring large
expenditure tractably embodies this conclusion and allows us to measure its influence on
middle-class households’ MPCs.
Kaplan and Violante (2014) provided an explanation for large MPCs of middle-class
households that complements ours. In their model of “wealthy hand-to-mouth” consumers,
households save for retirement in a high-return asset with large fixed transaction costs, which
they interpreted as housing or retirement accounts, and a low-return liquid asset. They
emphasized that if the difference between the two assets’ returns is large enough, then those
who have converted all of their liquid assets into illiquid assets will have high MPCs in spite of
having substantial illiquid wealth. Our model of term saving shows that households currently
1

See that article’s penultimate sentence for the full context of this quote.

3

saving for a foreseen expenditure will also have high MPCs even though they have substantial
liquid wealth.
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we review existing
evidence about the marginal propensity to consume out of tax rebates in the U.S. and document the prevalence of precautionary and term saving with the SCF. Section 3 develops the
deterministic term savings model, and Section 4 adds earnings uncertainty and considers the
quantitative implications of a calibrated version of the model for the evidence reviewed in
Section 2. Section 5 offers concluding remarks.

2

Evidence

This section reviews the evidence on consumption and savings that motivates our exploration
of middle-class liquidity constraints. We begin with a review of previous empirical analysis
of households’ MPCs from tax-induced changes to disposable income. We then document
the pervasiveness of precautionary and term saving with data from recent waves of the SCF.

2.1

MPC Estimates

Changes in tax law provide rich opportunities for the empirical investigation of consumption
choices in the context of economically significant, policy relevant, and plausibly exogenous
changes to household income. The Reagan tax cuts, which were implemented in three stages,
are particularly useful for this because the last two stages were known to the public well before
their implementation. Whereas the permanent-income model predicts that the associated
anticipated changes in take-home pay should have zero impact on consumption, Souleles
(2002) estimated responses of nondurable consumption to the tax cuts of between 80 and 90
cents per dollar using Consumer Expenditure Survey data.2 When he split the sample by
liquid wealth relative to earnings, the consumption responses of households in the bottom
quartile were within 15 cents of their counterparts in the top three quartiles. Furthermore,
these differences were statistically insignificant.3 It seems that the majority of households
acted as if they were hand-to-mouth “spenders,” even those who had wealth when the tax cuts
were implemented. Souleles labelled these consumption responses “the marginal propensity
to consume (MPC) out of predictable income.”4
2

See the row labelled “d(withholding)t+1 ” in his Table 2.
See the first two rows of his Table 4.
4
See the third paragraph of his page 100.
3

4

Shapiro and Slemrod (2003, 2009), and Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2010) provided
more recent evidence on households’ MPCs from survey data. The Economic Growth and
Tax Relief Act of 2001 lowered tax rates retrospectively to the start of 2001, and the Treasury
mailed tax rebates to most taxpayers from July to October. Shapiro and Slemrod attached
questions to the University of Michigan’s monthly Survey of Consumer Attitudes and Behavior that solicited respondents’ anticipated uses of these rebated funds as well as their
expectations about future government spending and taxes. They found that 22 percent of
respondents anticipated spending most of the rebate, while the rest planned either to reduce
their debts or increase their savings. Using plausible distributions of the marginal propensities to consume across those who would “mostly spend” and “mostly save”, Shapiro and
Slemrod calculated an average marginal propensity to consume of about one third.
Famously, political disagreement made the persistence of the Bush tax cuts uncertain at
the time of their passage. The original legislation sunset in 2011, but Congress could have
either made them permanent or revoked them entirely before then. In theory, the persistence
of a tax cut determines the resulting the consumption response, but Shapiro and Slemrod
found no connection between a respondent’s views on future taxes and her propensity to
mostly spend the rebate.5 One might also expect that tax cuts represent real wealth to a
household only if accompanied by a reduction in government spending. Again, the data reveal
no such Ricardian link between expectations of government spending and the propensity to
spend.6
A theoretical justification for large MPCs out of tax rebates is that households cannot
borrow against higher expected future income to smooth consumption. Such traditional
liquidity constraints should be most prevalent among households with low income and low
wealth. Shapiro and Slemrod found no difference in the propensity to mostly spend the tax
rebates by income.7 They also tabulated the propensities to mostly spend across different
households based on their ownership of stocks, either in retirement accounts, mutual funds,
or brokerage accounts. They did find statistically significant differences across households,
but these are not consistent with the model of traditional liquidity constraints: the spending
fraction increases with stock ownership, with exceptions for the highest bracket and that
5

See the lines below “Size of future tax cuts” in their Table 5.
See the lines below “Impact of tax cut on government spending” in their Table 5.
7
See the rows under “Income ($)” in their Table 2.
6

5

with zero-assets.8,9
Shapiro and Slemrod (2009) used the same survey instrument and methodology to measure households’ propensities to spend the obviously temporary Economic Stimulus Payments
(ESP’s) of 2008. Surprisingly, the fraction of respondents who mostly spend their ESP’s is
nearly identical to that from the 2001 rebate checks, 20 percent. Just as with the earlier tax
rebates, Shapiro and Slemrod found “there is no discernible difference in spending propensity by income.”10 Finally, Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2010) found a dependence of the
Mostly-Spend rate on the household’s wealth in stocks similar to that from the 2001 tax rebates.11 Table 1 presents the Mostly-Spend percentages by stock ownership level from both
Shapiro and Slemrod (2003) and Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2010). It clearly shows that
the survey evidence does not support the traditional liquidity constraint model for either the
2001 tax rebates or the 2008 ESP’s.12
A pair of complementary articles, Johnson, Parker, and Souleles (2006) and Parker, Souleles, Johnson, and McClelland (2013), estimated the consumption responses from these two
tax experiments using questions appended to the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) that
measured when the household received the disbursed funds. The Treasury randomized this
8

See the lines under “Stock” in their Table 2. Shapiro and Slemrod report in their article’s original
working paper that this pattern also arises in regressions with dummy variables for the different stock ownership brackets, while age and other control variables are included. However, the relationship is statistically
indistinguishable from a flat line. See Tables 10 through 13 of NBER Working Paper 8672.
9
One might be legitimately concerned that the failure to find that the propensity to mostly spend the tax
rebate declines with stock wealth arises from the presence of illiquid retirement savings in that wealth. We
address this possibility in Appendix A.
10
See their Table 3. This quote is from the discussion below it.
11
Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod also examined the dependence of the Mostly-Spend rate on income and
wealth in a multivariate setting. They found “Given the substantial positive correlation of income and
wealth, it is hard to statistically identify separate effects of these two factors.” (Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod,
2010, page 86).
12
Shapiro and Slemrod (2003, page 385) offered the following explanation for the positive effect of stock
ownership on the Mostly-Spend rate: “Those stockholders with low wealth are trying to build wealth and
therefore have a powerful saving motive; those with higher wealth may already have adequate assets and
therefore are spenders on the margin.” Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2010, page 84) apply the same explanation to their findings. However, the most natural extant model of such “target savings”, the buffer stock
model of Deaton (1991), does not deliver this result. That model does have a stationary long-run distribution
of wealth, and households with initial wealth above its mean tend to dissave while those below it tend to
save. Nevertheless, the MPC out of wealth declines with wealth. This is evident in Deaton’s (1991) Figure
1, which shows consumption as a function of wealth to be concave. As noted in the introduction, Carroll and
Kimball (1996) formally prove this concavity.

6

Stock Ownership Class
None
$1 − $15, 000
$15, 001 − $50, 000
$50, 001 − $100, 000
$100, 001 − $250, 000
More than $250, 000
Refused/Don’t Know

2001 Tax Rebates
Percentage Percentage Spending
of Sample
Most of Rebate
42.8
19.5
9.1
13.1
9.9
18.1
6.8
26.7
6.2
33.6
5.1
22.9
20.1
25.3

2008 Economic Stimulus Payments
Percentage Percentage Spending
of Sample
Most of Rebate
33
20
13
19
14
19
10
14
11
25
9
39
11
25

Table 1: Rebate Spending Percentages

Source: Table 2 of Shapiro and Slemrod (2003) and Table 8 of Sahm et al. (2010)

timing based on the second-to-last digit in the recipient’s Social Security number, so the
effect of receiving the funds on current consumption can be estimated without substantial
endogeneity concerns. Johnson, Parker, and Souleles estimated a one-quarter effect on nondurable consumption of 0.462 with a standard error of 0.173.13 Kaplan and Violante (2014)
labeled such estimates rebate coefficients. The MPC equals the rebate coefficient summed
with any consumption response since the announcement of the tax cut.
Johnson, Parker, and Souleles sorted their sample into three groups by income. Households in their low-income group spent much more than those in the middle-income group, but
those with the highest income also spent more than those in the middle. The same pattern
arose when they split the sample by liquid assets.14 These point estimates provide partial
support for a “U” shape relationship between rebate coefficients and liquid assets, but the
difference between the coefficients on the high liquid assets group and the middle group is
statistically insignificant. In any event, these results provide no support for the standard view
that the MPC should monotonically decline with liquid assets. For the 2008 ESPs, Parker,
Souleles, Johnson, and McClelland measured rebate coefficients for nondurable goods and
all consumption of 0.128 and 0.523. Only the latter is statistically significant.15 When they
sorted their sample by income and liquid assets, the resulting rebate coefficients were statis13

See the first row and final column of their Table 3.
See their Table 5.
15
See the third row of their Table 2.
14

7

tically indistinguishable from each other.16 We conclude that the CEX-based estimates are
consistent with the irrelevance of a household’s assets for its rebate coefficients.
In a complementary analysis, Broda and Parker (2014) estimated rebate coefficients for
the 2008 ESPs using weekly household expenditure data from the Nielsen Consumer Panel
(formerly Homescan) augmented with survey data on the timing of the ESP’s receipt and
available household liquidity. Specifically, the survey asked households
In case of an unexpected decline in income or increase in expenses, do you have at
least two months of income available in cash, bank accounts, or easily accessible
funds?
Since this question partitions households into only two groups, the resulting data cannot
detect non-monotone effects of wealth on the rebate coefficient. Nevertheless, their point
estimates indicate that the rebate coefficient for the data’s covered expenditures (barcoded
items) over the three months following receipt was two to three times higher for households
lacking two months’ of earnings to cover an unexpected expense than for those with such a
financial cushion. Although this is an economically large difference, the associated 90 percent
confidence interval for the difference between the two rebate coefficients includes zero.17
In summary, the existing evidence on the MPC from tax-induced income changes indicates
that many households act as if they are liquidity constrained even though they have available
liquid assets. Furthermore, estimated rebate coefficients do not contradict this conclusion.
One potential explanation for high MPCs among households with liquid wealth is that
they base their consumption and saving decisions on “rules of thumb.” In support of this
perspective, Hsieh (2003) used data from Alaskan households to estimate rebate coefficients
for foreseen tax refunds and for much larger annual dividend payments from the Alaska
Permanent Fund (received in the fourth quarter of the year). He found that the rebate
coefficient from the tax refunds is positive and comparable to that estimated for the whole
United States by Souleles (1999), but the “rebate coefficient” from the Permanent Fund
payment was close to zero. He concluded that
This evidence suggests that households will take anticipated income changes into
16

See their Table 6. See also Misra and Surico (2014), who refined these estimates using quantile regressions.
See their Table 8. Using only variation in timing within each method of receipt (paper check or electronic
direct deposit), the two groups’ estimated rebate coefficients are 17.24 and 8.88, with standard errors of
6.72 and 4.84. Since the estimates come from independent samples, the t-statistic for their difference is
√
(17.24 − 8.88)/ 6.722 + 4.842 = 1.01. The results from using all variation in timing (in Table 8’s Panel A)
are similar.
17

8

account in their consumption decisions when the income changes are large, regular, and easy to predict, but will not do so when they are small and irregular.
(Hsieh, 2003, page 397)
The small estimated rebate coefficient for Permanent Fund payments indeed suggests that
large income fluctuations grab and hold households’ attention. However, a zero rebate coefficient can coexist with a large MPC (consistent with Kaplan and Violante (2014)), so Hsieh’s
results imply nothing for the MPCs out of those Permanent Fund payments.
Shapiro and Slemrod’s (2003) investigation of rules of thumb based on savings and consumption targets is of more direct relevance for MPCs. They sorted their respondents by
whether or not they have a budget and if they do, whether it targets spending, saving, or
debt repayment. (Multiple responses to this last question were allowed.) They reported
These findings are different than what one might have expected from an economic model of targeting, in which a household that spends a routine amount
would save residual income and vice versa. The survey evidence is the opposite:
target spenders tend to spend on the margin and target debt payers tend to save
on the margin. There is no substantial difference in spending rates for target
savers. (Shapiro and Slemrod, 2003, page 387)
Hsieh’s (2003) evidence suggests that rules of thumb or other predictions of behavioral economics can illuminate households’ responses to fiscal policy shocks. Nevertheless, Shapiro
and Slemrod’s (2003) results do not support the simplest such behavioral model. In any case,
we believe that an explanation based on rational expectations and fully-optimizing behavior
can be at least equally enlightening.

2.2

Term Saving and Precautionary Saving

We put forward an explanation for high MPCs among middle-class households that relies
on saving to finance foreseen large expenditures. Before proceeding with its theoretical
development, we present here evidence on the importance of such expenditures for the savings
decisions of middle-class households. The principle expenses we have in mind are purchases
of new homes and the college education of children.
2.2.1

The Sample

For our sample, we draw on five cross-sectional waves of the SCF; 1995, 1998, 2001, 2004,
and 2007. Unfortunately, the more recent 2010 and 2013 SCF waves omit a key variable, the
9

household’s Adjusted Gross Income, that we use to measure its federal income tax paid.
The SCF sample weights give the number of U.S. households that each household in the
sample represents. The first row of Table 2 uses these weights to list the number of households
represented in each of the five waves. This ranges from 99 million in 1995 to 116.1 million in
2007. We wish to focus the analysis on working-age middle class households. To be included
in our sample, a household must have answered all of the questions regarding savings motives
that we use below. Table 2’s second line gives the number of represented households after
dropping those that fail this screen. The total number of households lost varies between 2
and 3 million. Next, the household head must be between 25 and 64 years old at the survey
date. This requirement removes approximately 25 percent of the households.
The next two criteria remove the poor from our sample. The first requires the household
to have not received Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (formerly known as Food
Stamps) in the previous year, and the second requires the household’s after-tax labor income
to exceed the official poverty line for a household of that demographic composition. Table
2’s fourth and fifth rows list the number of households that these two poverty criteria retain.
Together, they remove between 20 and 25 percent of the remaining represented households
from our sample.
We compute after-tax labor income as pre-tax labor income less income and social insurance taxes as well as IRA contributions.18 We elaborate on our treatment of IRA contributions below in Footnote 22.
To exclude the wealthy from our sample, we first measure each household’s financial
assets: stocks, bonds, and balances in checking, saving, money market, and mutual fund
accounts. For consistency with our treatment of tax-advantaged retirement saving in the
measurement of after-tax labor income, we exclude balances in IRA accounts from financial
assets. We then define the wealthy to be those households in the top five percent of all
households represented in that wave of the SCF. Our final sample-selection criterion removes
households in which either the household head or spouse reports being self-employed. This
ensures that savings for business purposes do not substantially influence our results, and it
removes between 10 and 15 percent of the remaining households. Our final sample represents
18

More specifically, to compute the household’s after-tax labor income we calculated an average tax rate
using the household’s Adjusted Gross Income, the household’s federal tax filing status, and the federal income
tax and social-insurance (FICA and Medicare) tax tables. The resulting tax is subtracted from pre-tax labor
income of the household’s head and his or her spouse. The SCF includes no information on state of residence,
so we make no attempt to estimate state income taxes. However, we do assume that each worker with an
IRA account that is eligible to contribute to it makes the maximum possible contribution.

10

43.1 million households in 1995 and 53.1 million households in 2007.
To present the financial wealth distribution in our sample, Table 3 reports summary
statistics of financial wealth scaled by after-tax labor income for each SCF cross section. The
second column gives the income-weighted average of this ratio, and the remaining columns
give this income-weighted average for each decile of the ratio itself. We used all financial assets
in the numerator. In 1995, the overall average equals 30.8 percent. This climbs quickly to
47.6 percent in 1998 and 50.4 percent in 2001. For 2004 and 2007, the overall averages are
substantially lower, 43.7 percent and 46.1 percent.19 Even though the sample focuses on
middle-class households, the distribution of the ratio is quite skewed. The average ratio for
households in the fifth decile is between 9.2 and 13.1 percent. The analogous averages for
households in the tenth decile range from 171.6 percent to 263.8 percent.
2.2.2

Reasons for Saving

We begin exploring the quantitative importance of term saving by examining households’
answers to the following question:
Question 1 Now I’d like to ask you a few questions about your family’s savings. People
have different reasons for saving, even though they may not be saving all the time. What are
your family’s most important reasons for saving?
Each respondent could give up to six answers (five in 1995) from a detailed list, which we
broke into three categories, Retirement and Estate, Precaution, and Anticipated Expenditure.
Both Retirement and Estate had distinct entries on the list of answers, although the Estate
answer included intervivos transfers. Following Kennickell and Lusardi (2005), we assigned
an answer to Precaution if it was
• Reserves in case of unemployment,
• In case of illness; medical/dental expenses,
• Emergencies; “rainy days”; other unexpected needs; For “security” and independence,
or
• Liquidity; to have cash available/on hand.
19

Since the rise and fall of this ratio coincides with the growth and decline of the internet stock boom, we
calculated the same ratios excluding directly-held stocks and stock-based mutual funds from financial wealth.
The results (unreported here) confirm that excluding equities smooths this ratio’s evolution.

11

12

Survey
2001
106.5
103.5
76.3
71.7
61.5
57.0
48.8

Year
2004 2007
112.1 116.1
109.9 114.5
80.4 84.9
74.3 76.5
62.5 64.3
57.9 60.2
49.1 53.1

Table 2: Number of Households (in millions) Represented in the Surveys of Consumer Finances

1995
Households Represented in Original Sample,
99.0
& without imputed Age or Saving Survey responses,
97.0
& with heads between 25 and 64 years old,
71.3
& that received no TANF,
63.9
& that had labor income above the poverty line,
54.2
& are among least wealthy 95% of remaining households 49.9
& are not self-employed.
43.1

SCF
1998
102.5
100.3
74.4
68.8
59.2
54.3
46.9

Year

Full
Sample

1

2

3

4

5

Deciles
6
7

8

9

10

Including All Financial Assets
1995
1998
2001
2004
2007

30.8
47.6
50.4
43.7
46.1

0.1
0.3
0.4
0.1
0.3

1.5
2.1
2.3
1.5
1.7

3.6
4.6
4.9
3.6
3.7

6.2
8.0
8.1
6.2
6.5

9.2
13.1
13.0
10.3
10.3

13.4
20.4
21.0
16.0
16.4

22.4
32.3
32.2
25.4
26.0

37.1 71.1 171.6
54.7 100.5 247.7
54.3 100.6 263.8
42.4 85.5 214.9
44.2 84.2 220.8

Table 3: Ratios of Financial Assets to Annual After-Tax Labor Income (×100)
Note: Each cell reports a weighted average of nonretirement financial assets to labor income
net of federal income taxes, Social Security taxes, and contributions to tax-advantaged
retirement accounts. The weights are proportional to this after-tax income measure. The
second column uses the entire sample, while the remaining columns use observations grouped
by deciles of this ratio. Financial wealth definitionally equals the sum of checking accounts,
savings accounts, money-market deposit accounts, money-market mutual fund accounts,
certificates of deposit, non-money-market mutual fund accounts, savings bonds, brokerage
call accounts, directly-held bonds, and directly-held stocks.

The answers we used to infer an Anticipated Expenditure motive were:
• Children’s education; education of grandchildren,
• Own education; spouse’s education; education – NA for whom,
• Wedding, Bar Mitzvah, and other ceremonies,
• Buying own house,
• Purchase of cottage or second home for own use,
• Buy a car, boat or other vehicle,
• To travel; take vacations; take other time off, or
13

1995
Retirement & Estate
44.6
Precaution
45.1
Anticipated Expenditure 43.6

1998
60.1
30.9
43.7

2001
55.4
31.9
41.9

2004
57.9
31.3
42.6

2007
64.2
33.8
39.2

Table 4: Percentage Frequencies of Stated Reasons for Saving from the SCF

• Burial/funeral expenses.
Table 4 reports the frequencies for each of these three classes. Because a given household
can give multiple answers, these frequencies sum to more than 100 percent. In every year but
1995, Retirement and Estate is the most common of these three motivations with frequencies
of about 60 percent. Again with the exception of 1995, between 30.9 and 33.8 percent of
households reported Precautionary motives, while between 39.2 and 43.7 percent of them
reported motivation from an Anticipated Expenditure. In 1995, the Precautionary motive is
much more frequent and the Retirement and Estate motive is much less frequent. Overall,
the data indicate that saving for an anticipated expenditure is widespread and at least as
salient for middle-class households as precautionary saving.
2.2.3

A Closer Look at Term Saving

The SCF has an additional question on savings motives particularly relevant for term saving:
Question 2 In the next five to ten years, are there any foreseeable major expenses that you
and your family expect to have to pay for yourselves, such as educational expenses, purchase
of a new home, health care costs, support for other family members, or anything else?
Note that this question explicitly references health care costs, which we counted above as
a motive for precautionary savings. However, we can separate term saving for health care
from other term saving using a follow-up question. If the respondent answered Question 2
affirmatively, then the interviewer asked
Question 3 What kinds of obligations are these?
The interviewer then showed the respondent a list of possible expenditures. Another followup question asked whether or not the household was currently saving for the expense. A
14

1995
Foresees Expense 63.1
Saving Now
38.1
Saving Complete
.

1998
58.8
37.1
.

2001
60.5
36.8
.

2004
59.0
35.8
.

2007
57.5
33.9
1.6

Table 5: Percentage Frequencies of Saving for Anticipated Expenditure

household that is not currently saving might either have not begun saving or have already
completed saving. In 2007, the SCF questionnaire addressed this ambiguity by asking respondents if their saving was completed.
Table 5 reports the frequencies with which respondents reported a foreseen expense,
saving now for that expense, and (for 2007) whether or not the saving was complete. In
all of the waves, about 60 percent of households report an anticipated expense, and about
35 percent report that they are saving now for it. This is not far below the approximately
40 percent of households that claim an Anticipated Expenditure as one of possibly several
savings motivations when answering Question 1.20 Only a very small fraction of households
report that their saving for anticipated expenditures is complete. We have also tabulated the
answers to these two savings questions by the wealth deciles used in Table 3. The fraction
of households reporting a foreseen expense is nearly constant across wealth deciles, while the
fraction reporting that they are currently saving for the expense rises with wealth. Therefore,
the data do not reject the possibility that term savings substantially influences the wealthiest
middle-class households.
As might be expected, the major expenses listed in Question 2 – education, purchase of a
new home, and health care costs – are concentrated at specific stages of the life cycle. Table 6
reports the frequencies with which households responded to Question 3 with that particular
category, both overall and by age of the household’s head. (The denominators for these
frequencies include all households, not just those that answered Question 2 affirmatively.)
Between 13.3 and 17.7 percent of households anticipate a home purchase in the next five
to ten years. As expected, these are concentrated among younger households. Anticipated
educational expenses are somewhat more frequent, and these are concentrated among the
20

One might wonder why many more households report anticipated expenditures when responding to
Question 2 than report such expenses as a motive for saving in their answers to Question 1. One reason
might be that Question 1 explicitly includes foreseen health costs. Another reason might be that the specific
reference to “the next five to ten years” induces respondents to consider savings goals over a longer horizon.

15

middle aged. The overall frequency of anticipated medical expenses never exceeds 10 percent.
In the 2001, 2004, and 2007 surveys this frequency is highest among those late in their working
life, but one can hardly say that a typical older household is saving for medical care. This
result validates our original decision to label saving in anticipation of medical expenses as
precautionary. Overall though, Table 6 indicates that households tie anticipated expenditures
to their life cycles.

3

The Model

Inspired by the above evidence, our quantitative model of middle-class consumption and savings decisions adds precautionary and term saving motivations to the impatient, borrowingconstrained household in Campbell and Hercowitz (2009). The precautionary motive arises
from earnings uncertainty, and the term-saving motive comes from a periodic expenditure
with predetermined timing but endogenous size. The household represents an infinitely-lived
dynasty that is impatient relative to the market rate of interest. In spite of impatience, the
household saves in anticipation of the periodic expenditure.

3.1

Primitives and Optimization

The model proceeds in discrete time, and we think of a point in time as a “year.” This label
reflects our choice to focus on the entire MPC out of tax rebates rather than just the rebate
coefficient identified with variation across households in the monthly timing of their receipt.
The household values two goods, standard consumption and the special good. We denote
the quantities of these consumed in year t with Ct and Mt . The utility function is
∞
X
t=0

β

t



σ M 1−σ 
Ct1−σ 
1/σ
t
+ (1 + µt ) − 1
,
1−σ
1−σ

(1)

with 0 < β < 1 and σ > 0. Here, µt = µ > 0 every τ years and µt = 0 at other times. This
specification generates a periodic expenditure with exogenous timing and endogenous size.21
The household is endowed with one unit of labor which it supplies inelastically at the
wage rate Wt . Denote lump-sum taxes with Tt and net financial assets at the end of the
21

In the present context, the main issue regarding Mt is the liquidity shortage generated at the time of the
expenditure. We interpret the utility from consuming Mt as the discounted expected future benefits from
this expenditure. In any event, given that in the model the next expenditure endogenously shortens the
effective planning horizon, the utility flows in the future are of secondary importance here.

16

17

1995
15.5
28.3
25.2
16.9
8.3
9.4
8.9
11.9
5.9

2007 1995
13.3 18.6
35.1 11.8
14.4 14.7
16.4 27.0
11.5 24.5
8.5 26.9
11.0 13.4
5.0
7.1
3.0
4.9

Education
1998 2001 2004
19.9 17.8 19.2
18.5 11.1 16.3
16.9 16.9 14.9
26.8 20.5 22.1
29.4 26.6 27.3
19.1 23.1 26.4
19.2 15.7 15.5
6.4
7.7 11.8
2.2
2.6
6.2
2007 1995
17.1 8.3
13.7 5.7
13.3 9.5
23.4 7.8
21.6 8.9
25.3 8.0
15.5 9.7
9.3
7.9
6.7
9.5

Medical Care
1998 2001 2004
5.8
5.4
5.9
5.3
2.5
5.6
7.1
6.5
2.6
7.9
4.7
5.6
6.5
6.0
3.3
5.8
3.4
5.7
3.8
7.0
6.0
2.0
6.4 11.3
6.0 10.1 14.3

2007
6.8
4.3
5.2
4.8
4.0
7.5
8.1
11.8
10.2

remaining rows report the frequencies for households in the indicated 5-year age bins.

Surveys of Consumer Finance in 1995, 1998, 2001, 2004, and 2007. The first row reports the frequencies for all households, and the

This table reports the frequency of the three major foreseen expenses listed among households with some foreseen major expense for the

Age Category
All
25-29
30-34
35-39
40-44
45-49
50-54
55-59
60-64

Home Purchase
1998 2001 2004
17.7 17.1 15.5
33.5 24.0 29.5
28.1 29.0 21.2
19.0 22.6 16.1
15.3 14.8 11.8
15.4 11.2 12.7
5.3 12.6 10.4
6.1
6.4 11.3
3.4
6.1
7.3

Table 6: Frequency of Saving for a Specific Major Foreseen Expenditure by Age Group

previous year with At . The household’s budget constraint is
Ct + Mt = Wt − Tt + RAt − At+1 ,

(2)

where R is the gross interest rate, assumed to be constant.22 We assume that βR < 1,
so the household is impatient. In Campbell and Hercowitz (2009), we provide a general
equilibrium environment in which such a low interest rate arises endogenously from trade with
a more patient household. The household’s choices of all goods must satisfy nonnegativity
constraints. Furthermore, the household faces the standard borrowing constraint
At+1 ≥ 0.

(3)

Given A0 , the household chooses sequences of Ct , Mt and At+1 to maximize its utility subject
to the sequences of budget and borrowing constraints.
Denote the Lagrange multipliers on the year t budget and borrowing constraints with Ψt
and Γt . The first-order conditions for optimization are
Ψt = Ct−σ ,

(4)

Γt = Ψt − βRΨt+1 ,

σ
1/σ
σ
Ψt Mt = (1 + µt ) − 1 .

(5)
(6)

Without borrowing constraints, Ψt equals the marginal utility of lifetime resources. Here,
it represents the marginal value of current resources. The multiplier Γt equals the marginal
value of relaxing the borrowing constraint, which is the deviation from the standard Euler
equation; Γt is zero when the borrowing constraint is slack. Because Ψt is always positive,
the periodic expenditure Mt is positive when µt > 0 and zero otherwise.23
22

Our model omits one of the most prevalently cited savings motivations, retirement and estate. In the
U.S., saving limited amounts towards retirement has tax advantages if the saver is willing to suffer penalties
for withdrawal before a statutory retirement age. It is relatively straightforward to build such tax-advantaged
retirement savings into the model if we abstract from earnings risk and assume that all households hit the
statutory upper-bounds on retirement savings. That version of the model suggests that we measure income
net of retirement savings contributions, as we did above. Including such savings vehicles in our model with
earnings risk is much more challenging and lies beyond the scope of this paper.
23
We can manipulate (4), (6), and the constraint that Ct + Mt equals total consumption expenditures in
−σ
year t to get Ψt = (1 + µt ) (Ct + Mt ) . That is, µt has the interpretation of an increment in marginal utility
for any given total consumption expenditure.

18

3.2

The Ergodic Distribution of Wealth and the MPC

Because of the periodic changes in preferences, the appropriate analogue of a steady state
in this model is a deterministic cycle: Wt and Tt are assumed to be constant, and all of
the household’s choices follow a pattern that repeats itself every τ years. If we assume that
households are uniformly distributed over the cycle at any point in time, then we can calculate
the cross sectional distribution of financial wealth and the MPC. The remainder of this section
characterizes this ergodic distribution of wealth and the MPC analytically. These results
verify the intuition given above that term saving makes wealth an indicator of anticipated
liquidity constraints, so MPCs increase with wealth amongst households with positive wealth.
They also serve as a foundation for understanding the next section’s quantitative model which
incorporates both term saving and precautionary saving.
Denote ordinary consumption and assets κ years after the most recent purchase of the
special good in a deterministic cycle with C κ and Aκ .24 From (4) and (5), the necessary
conditions which a deterministic cycle must satisfy are
C κ+1
≥ (βR)1/σ for κ = 1, 2, . . . , τ − 1, and
κ
C
C1
≥ (βR)1/σ .
Cτ

(7)
(8)

The corresponding budget constraints are
C κ + Aκ+1 = W − T + RAκ for κ = 1, 2, . . . , τ − 1,
(1 + µ)1/σ C τ + A1 = W − T + RAτ .
This final form of the budget constraint replaces the periodic expenditure with its optimal
level derived from (4) and (6), ((1 + µ)1/σ − 1)C τ . With these conditions defining a deterministic cycle, we can characterize them with the following
Proposition 1 There exists a unique deterministic cycle. In it
1. C 1 /C τ > (βR)1/σ , and
2. if C κ+1 /C κ > (βR)1/σ and κ ≥ 2, then C κ /C κ−1 > (βR)1/σ .
24

Our model has a deterministic asset cycle in common with the models of Baumol (1952) and Tobin
(1956). Those models differ in key respects from ours. There, the length of the cycle is the key endogenous
variable, while here it is exogenous. We focus on the link between the asset cycle and liquidity constraints,
while those models focused on the link between assets and money demand.

19

Appendix B contains this proposition’s short proof. Its first enumerated result says that the
borrowing constraint binds in the cycle’s final year, when the household consumes the special
good. This fact is the analogue of the familiar result that an impatient household faces a
binding borrowing constraint in a steady state. The second enumerated result says that if
the borrowing constraint binds in some period before the special good is consumed, then it
must bind in the previous period as well. Taken together, these results state that the periodic
cycle always ends with the borrowing constraint binding while the household consumes the
special good. Immediately afterwards, it might be binding for one or more years. If it ceases
to bind, then the household accumulates wealth until the next opportunity to consume the
special good.
Zeldes (1984) noted that a binding borrowing constraint in the future works like a terminal
condition which shortens the effective planning horizon. The household’s response to an
unanticipated one-time increase in Wt − Tt on the deterministic cycle illustrates this. If the
borrowing constraint binds in the year of the increase, then the MPC equals one as expected.
If instead the borrowing constraint is slack then, the household allocates the increase in
current income across consumption between the present year in the cycle, κ < τ , and the
next time the borrowing constraint binds. The resulting marginal propensity to consume
(which can be easily calculated from the corresponding finite-horizon utility-maximization
problem) is
!−1
1−σ τ −κ
σ
τ −κ
1
1 − (βR )
+ (βR1−σ ) σ (1 + µ) σ
.
M P Cκ =
1
1−σ
1 − (βR ) σ
Whether or not this MPC is “large” relative to that we expect from the permanent income
theory of consumption depends on the importance of the special good for consumption.
Intuitively, M P C κ can be quite small if µ is so large that the household effectively only
consumes the special good. To make this more precise, consider the marginal propensity
to consume from the infinite-horizon utility-maximization problem with neither the special
1
good nor borrowing constraints, 1 − (βR1−σ ) σ . This will be less than M P C κ if and only if
1

(1 + µ) σ <

1
1

1 − (βR1−σ ) σ

.

(9)

Reasonable calibrations of the model in which ordinary consumption accounts for the majority of expenditures satisfy (9) comfortably, so we hereafter assume that it holds good.
We began this paper highlighting the empirical failure of M P Cs to substantially decline
with observed household wealth. The next proposition shows that term saving can indeed
20

Share of Earnings

Ordinary Consumption

Special Good

1

1

0.5

0.5

0

2

4

6

8

0

10

1

0.5

0

4

6

8

10

Marginal Propensity to Consume
Percentage Response

Share of Earnings

Beginning−of−Year Wealth

2

2
4
6
8
10
Years Since Periodic Expenditure

100

50

0

2
4
6
8
10
Years Since Periodic Expenditure

Figure 1: The Calibrated Model’s Deterministic Cycle

account for this qualitatively. To see our model’s implications for these observations, we
differentiate M P C κ above with respect to κ. The upper bound for µ in (9) signs the derivative
positively. Therefore, we conclude:
Proposition 2 Set κ ∈ 1, . . . , τ − 2. If µ, β, R, and σ satisfy (9) and
1

C κ+1 /C κ = C κ+2 /C κ+1 = (βR) σ ,
then Aκ < Aκ+1 and M P C κ < M P C κ+1 .
Proposition 2 implies that if we sampled households from the deterministic cycle, we would
find that M P Ct covaries positively with At among households with assets. Overall, the MPC
is a U-shaped function of wealth, attaining its highest value of one when beginning-of-year
wealth is either zero or its maximum observed value (RAτ ).
21

Figure 1 illustrates the qualitative implications of Proposition 2 with plots of the model’s
deterministic cycle (that is, Wt is held constant) using the calibrated parameter values reported below in Section 4. In the year of the expenditure and for four years thereafter, the
household chooses zero wealth, so its marginal propensity to consume in those years equals
100 percent. In the fifth year after the expenditure, saving begins and the marginal propensity
to consume falls. The MPC increases as the expenditure approaches. Since wealth simultaneously increases, those saving households with the highest wealth also have the highest
MPCs; just as predicted by the proposition.
In this section and throughout this paper, we have focused on the marginal propensity
to consume out of temporary tax rebates. Before proceeding to our quantitative analysis,
we wish to consider the deterministic model’s implications for another line of evidence that
measures the elasticity of consumption with respect to a persistent wage increase. For example, Baker (2014) shows that the elasticity of consumption with respect to exogenous and
persistent changes to earnings declines with wealth.25 Our model reproduces this observation, even though the MPCs out of temporary tax rebates increase with wealth. To see this,
note that the elasticity of current consumption with respect to a permanent increase in total
resources available from the present until the next periodic expenditure equals one, because
our household’s preferences are homothetic. The elasticity of interest is the product of this
with the elasticity of total resources available from the present until the next periodic expenditure with respect to a permanent earnings increase. In year κ of the model’s deterministic
cycle then this is
(W − T )(1 + R(1 − R−(τ −κ) )/(1 − R−1 )
.
RAκ + (W − T )(1 + R(1 − R−(τ −κ) )/(1 − R−1 )
This elasticity clearly declines with wealth, RAκ ; just as documented by Baker.

4

Quantitative Analysis

In this section, we investigate the quantitative contribution of term savings to middle-class
households’ MPCs by enriching the model with ongoing wage risk, calibrating its parameters,
and calculating the MPCs to transitory income changes and balanced-budget tax experiments. Our addition of wage risk follows Meghir and Pistaferri (2004). Using annual PSID
observations, they estimated a stochastic process of household heads’ log earnings that sums
25

See the fifth column of his Table 4.

22

a random walk with a first-order moving average. The resulting process for Wt is
ln Wt = ln WtP + ln WtT ; with
∆ ln WtP ∼ N (0, 0.1772 ),
ln WtT = εt + 0.2566εt−1 , and
εt ∼ N (0, 0.1732 ).
Although they estimated several processes with heteroskedasticity, we focus on this homoskedastic process for the sake of simplicity. We assume that the household faces a four
percent real rate of interest, so R = 1.04. Motivated by the phrasing of Question 2, we set
τ to 10. Our calibration uses logarithmic preferences (σ = 1).26 The remaining parameters
to be determined are β and µ, which jointly govern the household’s desired intertemporal
allocation of consumption. We set these so that the median and 75th percentile of the distribution of wealth to current labor income in the model’s ergodic distribution equal 0.14 and
0.46. These are the averages (across years) of the analogous medians and 75th percentiles
calculated from the 1995, 1998, 2001, 2004, and 2007 cross-sectional waves of the SCF. Given
the model’s other parameters, this procedure selects β = 0.8967 and µ = 1.5859.27
To solve the model, we first create its stationary representation by dividing Ct , Mt , and At
by WtP . Our solution of this stationary model uses standard discrete state space dynamic programming techniques. We constrain At+1 to {0, 0.0001, 0.0002, . . . , 1.3, 1.3001, 1.3002, . . . , 4}.
We approximate ln WtT with a nine-point Markov chain constructed from a three-point GaussHermite approximation to a standard normal random variable. We use the same three-point
approximation to model ∆ ln WtP .
Table 7 reports results obtained from this calibrated model. To calculate these, we begin with the model’s ergodic distribution for wealth and earnings (both scaled by earnings’
permanent component). For each point in its discrete state space, we compute the household’s responses to four changes in lump-sum transfers. In the first, each household receives
a one-time transfer. This is not a balanced-budget experiment, but the next experiment
balances the budget with a lump-sum tax in all subsequent years equal to the interest cost
of perpetually servicing the government debt used to fund the initial transfer. The next
26

We have also calibrated the model given σ = 1/2, σ = 3/2, and σ = 2. The MPCs we report below
are all within one percentage point of the analogous MPCs from these alternative calibrations. That is, the
assumed value for σ has no impact on our results worth reporting.
27
In the calibrated model, the special good accounts for about 61 percent of total consumption expenditures
in one of every ten years.

23

12At /Wt
0
(0,1]
(1,2]
(2,3]
(3,4]
(4,5]
(5,6]
(6,7]
(7,8]
(8,9]
(9,10]
(10,11]
(11,12]
13 or more
All Households

Frequency
30
15
8
8
6
5
4
4
3
3
3
2
2
6
100

Marginal Propensities to Consume out of a
One Year
One Year
Three Year
Five Year
Transfer
Tax Cut
Tax Cut
Tax Cut
53
51
82
93
35
32
64
86
26
24
59
81
25
22
59
79
24
22
59
78
26
24
61
75
31
29
64
75
37
36
67
75
46
44
71
77
51
50
74
79
58
57
78
81
63
62
80
83
66
65
82
84
72
71
88
91
42
40
71
85

Table 7: Average MPCs from the Calibrated Model with Term Saving

two experiments extend the initial tax cut to three and five years and increase the following permanent tax increase accordingly. Each row reports the MPCs in each experiment’s
first year for the group of households with income to wealth ratios in 14 ranges. The first
contains all households with exactly zero wealth (30 percent of the households), the second
contains households with positive wealth that is less than one month of its current earnings,
the third contains households with wealth greater than or equal to one month’s earnings but
less than two month’s earnings, etc. The table’s column labeled “Frequency” shows that the
distribution of the wealth to income ratio has a thick tail. The calibration ensures that its
median value is 0.14, but its mean equals 0.28.
For the first experiment of a one-time transfer, the MPC of households with zero wealth
equals 53 percent. Consistent with the intuition from a precautionary savings model, 43
percent of these households are actually accumulating wealth and so have MPCs below 100
percent. The MPC declines to 35 percent for households with between zero and one month
24

of income in wealth, and then to 26 percent for households with wealth between one and
two months’ income. Thereafter, the MPC flattens out until it begins to rise for households
with wealth between 5 and 6 months’ earnings. For the 6 percent of households with wealth
exceeding a full year of earnings, the MPC equals 72 percent.
The deterministic version of the model suggested that the long-run tax increase to balance
the current tax cut should have a small effect on the present consumption response – given
the effective shortening of the planning horizon. The present, more quantitatively relevant,
framework mimics this prediction: Permanently raising taxes to pay for the one-year tax cut
reduces the MPCs very little. For those with no wealth, the MPC drops from 53 percent
to 51 percent, and for those with wealth exceeding annual earnings it drops from 72 to 71
percent. Furthermore, the U-shaped relationship between the MPCs and household wealth
remains unchanged. Extending the tax cuts to three and five years raises the MPCs and
flattens them. For a five-year tax cut, the average MPC of households without wealth equals
93 percent. For those with wealth exceeding annual earnings, it equals 91 percent. Overall,
these results suggest that the persistence of a tax-induced increase in current income matters
much more than how it is financed.
In our model, households face both precautionary saving motives and term saving motives. To illustrate the quantitative contributions of term saving to its results, we have also
calibrated our model without term saving. For this, we set µ to zero and choose β so that
the ergodic distribution’s median ratio of financial wealth to current income equals 0.14. The
resulting value for β is 0.9303. The model’s other parameters remain unchanged. Table 8
reports the ergodic distribution and MPCs from this alternative calibration. Unsurprisingly,
removing term saving motives makes the wealth distribution’s right tail much thinner. Also
as expected, the marginal propensities to consume decline with wealth. For the experiment
with a one-year transfer the MPC of households with no wealth is 52 percent, while the
analogous MPC for household’s with wealth exceeding current annual earnings equals only
15 percent. The other experiments display a similarly dramatic decline of the MPC with
wealth. Apparently, the model cannot come close to reproducing the empirical relationship
between the MPC and household wealth without term saving.

5

Concluding Remarks

In standard precautionary saving models, liquidity constraints disproportionately influence
the consumption and savings decisions of households with low wealth. However, evidence

25

12At /Wt
0
(0,1]
(1,2]
(2,3]
(3,4]
(4,5]
(5,6]
(6,7]
(7,8]
(8,9]
(9,10]
(10,11]
(11,12]
13 or more
All Households

Frequency
16
23
15
12
10
7
5
3
2
2
1
1
1
1
100

Marginal Propensities to Consume out of a
One Year
One Year
Three Year
Five Year
Transfer
Tax Cut
Tax Cut
Tax Cut
52
49
85
93
40
37
72
87
38
35
67
84
28
24
58
78
24
20
53
74
23
19
51
72
22
18
48
69
21
17
45
67
19
16
43
64
18
15
41
62
18
14
39
60
17
13
37
58
17
13
36
56
15
12
33
52
34
31
63
80

Table 8: Average MPCs from the Calibrated Model without Term Saving

from the responses to tax rebates in the U.S. indicates that marginal propensities to consume are high (relative to the permanent-income-hypothesis benchmark) and fail to decline
with wealth. To bridge this gap between theory and evidence, we have incorporated saving towards a large foreseen expense – term saving – into a standard precautionary savings
model. In a deterministic version of the model with term saving only, high wealth reflects
an anticipated demand for liquidity rather than a liquidity surplus arising from past luck (as
with precautionary saving). In our quantitative model with earnings risk, the resulting high
MPCs for high-wealth households flatten what would otherwise be a declining relationship
between wealth and the MPC, thereby bringing the model into better alignment with the
evidence.
The principal lesson we take away from these results regards the pervasiveness of liquidityconstrained behavior across the middle class. Identifying “liquidity constraints” with violations of the standard Euler equation leads one to conclude that only a minority of households
26

are liquidity constrained. The standard precautionary savings model reinforces this view, because it predicts that the MPC should sharply decline with wealth. However, the anticipation
that liquidity constraints will bind in the future also compresses current consumption by propagating through term saving. The empirical pervasiveness of term saving motives, the failure
of measured MPCs to decline with liquid assets, and the success of the term saving model
at replicating the wealth-MPC relationship lead us to believe that liquidity constraints are
salient for most middle class households’ consumption and savings choices.

27

A

Regressions with Shapiro and Slemrod’s Data

In this appendix, we estimate regressions using the data from the August 2001, September 2001, and October 2001 Surveys of Consumer Attitudes and Behavior (ICPSR Studies
35286, 35287, and 35288) originally employed by Shapiro and Slemrod (2003). The dependent
variable equals the indicator for whether or not the household reports spending most of its
rebate, while the independent variables measure the survey respondent’s age group, educational attainment, household income quartile, region of residence, and indicators for whether
the household’s reported stock wealth is between $1 and $15,000 or exceeds $15,000. (Hence,
the omitted group consists of households with no stock wealth.) A household’s stock wealth
might include investments in retirement accounts, which could be illiquid. Fortunately, these
data contain a variable indicating whether anyone in the household has stocks invested within
an IRA, Keogh, or 401K retirement account. About 1/4 of stockholders have no stocks in
retirement accounts. Using this variable, we removed households with such investments from
the sample. Thus, any results we obtain from this tighter sample cannot reflect the presence
of illiquid retirement wealth. The estimated regression uses 625 observations and has an R2
of 0.04. The estimated linear-in-probabilities regression equation is
spendi = −0.057 I{Si ∈ [1, 15000]}+ 0.033 I{Si ∈ (15000, ∞)}+Other regressors+ui .
(0.058)
(0.046)
where spendi is the indicator of intending to spend most of the rebate for household i,
Si is household i’s stock wealth, and ui is the regression error. The parentheses below
each estimated coefficient contain heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors. The two
coefficients on the stock-ownership dummies are jointly insignificant, as is the difference
between them. The analogous regression that includes all households, regardless of whether
or not they hold stocks in retirement accounts, has 1216 observations and an R2 of 0.03. The
equation is
spendi = −0.046 I{Si ∈ [1, 15000]}+ 0.040 I{Si ∈ (15000, ∞)}+Other regressors+ui
(0.041)
(0.027)
The test of joint significance on the two coefficients has a p-value of 0.08. The linear combination of the high stock-ownership dummy less the low stock-ownership dummy has a t-statistic
of 2.09. These results indicate that Shapiro and Slemrod’s (2003) failure to find a negative
relationship between stock wealth and the propensity to spend most of the 2001 tax rebate
did not arise purely from a failure to separate stocks held in retirement accounts from total
28

stock wealth. They also reinforce the impression that these data have power to detect an
impact of stock ownership on the propensity to mostly spend the 2001 Bush tax rebate.

B

Proofs for Section 3.2

Lemma 3 The borrowing constraint must bind at least once in any deterministic cycle.
Proof. Suppose otherwise. then from (7) and (8), we can conclude that
τ
C2 C3
Cτ C1
·
·
·
= (βR) σ .
1
2
τ
−1
τ
C C
C
C

But this is impossible, because the left-hand side equals one while the right hand side is
strictly less than one.
Lemma 4 Suppose that the borrowing constraint is slack in one year of a deterministic cycle.
Then either the borrowing constraint is slack in the cycle’s next year or the cycle’s next year
is τ .
Proof. Let κ denote a year in which the borrowing constraint is currently slack but which
is followed by a year in which it binds. By construction, κ caps a spell of years over which
the borrowing constraint has been slack. Denote the number of years in this spell with j.
By definition, beginning-of-period wealth at the beginning of such a spell is zero. Therefore,
consumption in that year cannot exceed W − T . Since the borrowing constraint is slack
throughout the entire spell, this in turn bounds ordinary consumption in the year after κ
j
from above with (W − T )(βR) σ < (W − T ). However, total consumption expenditures in
that year must weakly exceed W − T , because the borrowing constraint binds in that year
(by assumption) and so consumption expenditures must equal total earnings summed with
any accumulated wealth. If κ 6= τ − 1, then this is impossible because total consumption
expenditures equals ordinary consumption expenditures. Therefore, κ = τ − 1.
Proof of Proposition 1. Lemmas 3 and 4 together imply that the borrowing constraint
binds in the final year (τ ) of a deterministic cycle. Therefore, a deterministic cycle corresponds to a solution of the finite-horizon utility maximization problem that starts in period
1 with zero assets and ends in period τ with the household consuming all available resources.
Since this problem maximizes a strictly concave objective over a convex constraint set, it
has a unique solution. This guarantees existence and uniqueness of a deterministic cycle.
29

With this established, applying Lemmas 3 and 4 again yield the proposition’s first numbered
conclusion, and the second numbered conclusion is a consequence of Lemma 4 alone.
Proof of Proposition 2.
Establishing that Aκ ≤ Aκ+1 proceeds inductively. First,
suppose that Aκ = 0. That is, κ is the cycle’s first year in which the borrowing constraint
is slack. The borrowing constraint alone then gives us that Aκ+1 ≥ 0 = Aκ . Next, suppose
that Aκ > 0 and that Aκ ≥ Aκ−1 . Since the borrowing constraint is slack in year κ − 1, we
1
know that C κ = (βR) σ C κ−1 < C κ−1 . Therefore, we have that
Aκ+1 − Aκ = R(Aκ − Aκ−1 ) − (C κ − C κ−1 ) > 0.
To prove that M P C κ < M P C κ+1 , differentiate the expression for M P C κ in the text with
respect to κ.
!
1
1
1
∂M P C κ
= (M P C κ )2 ln(βR1−σ )
(1 + µ) σ −
1
∂κ
σ
1 − (βR1−σ ) σ
This is positive if and only if (9) holds good. In this case, integrating from κ to κ + 1 gives
us the result that M P C κ < M P C κ+1 .

30

References
Baker, S. R. (2014, November). Debt and the Consumption Response to Household Income
Shocks. Technical report.
Baumol, W. J. (1952). The Transactions Demand for Cash: An Inventory Theoretic Approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 66 (4), 545–556.
Broda, C. and J. A. Parker (2014, December). The Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008 and
the aggregate demand for consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 68 (Supplement),
S20–S36.
Campbell, J. R. and Z. Hercowitz (2009). Welfare Implications of the Transition to High
Household Debt. Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (1), 1–16.
Campbell, J. Y. and N. G. Mankiw (1989). Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates:
Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 185–216.
Carroll, C. D. and M. S. Kimball (1996). On the Concavity of the Consumption Function.
Econometrica 64 (4), 981–992.
Deaton, A. S. (1991, September). Saving and Liquidity Constraints. Econometrica 59 (5),
1221–1248.
Hall, R. E. (1978, December). Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income
Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Political Economy 86 (6), 971–987.
Hall, R. E. and F. S. Mishkin (1982, March). The sensitivity of consumption to transitory
income: Estimates from panel data on households. Econometrica 50 (2), 461–481.
Hayashi, F. (1987). Tests for liquidity constraints: a critical survey and some new observations. In T. F. Bewley (Ed.), Advances in Econometrics: Fifth World Congress, pp.
91–120. Cambridge University Press.
Hsieh, C.-T. (2003, March). Do Consumers React to Anticipated Income Changes? Evidence
from the Alaska Permanent Fund. American Economic Review 93 (1), 397–405.
Jappelli, T. (1990, February). Who is Credit Constrained in the U.S. Economy? Quarterly
Journal of Economics 105 (1), 219–234.

31

Jappelli, T. and L. Pistaferri (2010, September). The Consumption Response to Income
Changes. Annual Review of Economics 2 (1), 479–506.
Johnson, D. S., J. A. Parker, and N. S. Souleles (2006, December). Household Expenditure
and the Income Tax Rebates of 2001. American Economic Review 96 (5), 1589–1610.
Kaplan, G. and G. L. Violante (2014). A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal
Stimulus Payments. Econometrica 82 (4), 1199–1239.
Kennickell, A. B. and A. Lusardi (2005, December). Disentangling the Importance of the
Precautionary Saving Motive. Technical report.
Mankiw, N. G. (2000, June). The Savers–Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy. American
Economic Review 90 (2), 120–125.
Meghir, C. and L. Pistaferri (2004, January). Income Variance Dynamics and Heterogeneity.
Econometrica 72 (1), 1–32.
Misra, K. and P. Surico (2014, October). Consumption, Income Changes, and Heterogeneity:
Evidence from Two Fiscal Stimulus Programs. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6 (4), 84–106.
Parker, J., N. S. Souleles, D. S. Johnson, and R. McClelland (2013, October). Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008. American Economic Review 103 (6), 2530–2553.
Sahm, C. R., M. D. Shapiro, and J. Slemrod (2010). Household Response to the 2008 Tax
Rebate: Survey Evidence and Aggregate Implications. Tax Policy and the Economy 24,
69–110.
Shapiro, M. D. and J. Slemrod (2003, March). Consumer Response to Tax Rebates. American
Economic Review 93 (1), 381–396.
Shapiro, M. D. and J. Slemrod (2009, May). Did the 2008 Tax Rebates Stimulate Spending?
American Economic Review 99 (2), 374–379.
Souleles, N. S. (1999, September). The Response of Household Consumption to Income Tax
Refunds. American Economic Review 89 (4), 947–958.

32

Souleles, N. S. (2002, July). Consumer response to the Reagan tax cuts. Journal of Public
Economics 85 (1), 99–120.
Tobin, J. (1956). The Interest-Elasticity of Transactions Demand for Cash. Review of Economics and Statistics 38 (3), 241–247.
Zeldes, S. P. (1984, July). Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from
Certainty Equivalence. Ph. D. thesis, MIT.
Zeldes, S. P. (1989, April). Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Political Economy 97 (2), 205–346.

33

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan
Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-18

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment
Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

WP-09-08

Pay for Percentile
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-09-09

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot
François R. Velde

WP-09-10

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation
Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

WP-09-11

The Case of the Undying Debt
François R. Velde

WP-09-12

Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship
Program for Low-income Adults
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock
Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-09-13

WP-09-14

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:
Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-09-15

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,
Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-09-16

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-09-17

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-09-18

Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances?
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-19

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-09-20

7