View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Labor Supply Response To
(Mismeasured but) Predictable Wage Changes


Eric French

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

efrench@frbchi.org
August 13, 2003

Abstract
Most panel data studies of intertemporal labor supply assume classical measurement
error. Recent validation studies refute this assumption. In this study I address nonclassical measurement error explicitly. I use data on males from the Panel Study of
Income Dynamics Validation Study to purge measurement error from the Panel Study
of Income Dynamics. I nd a large amount of predictable wage variation in the data,
even after accounting for measurement error. However, there is almost no labor supply
response to these predictable wage changes. Therefore, failure to control for non-classical
measurement error cannot explain the low estimated labor supply elasticities in other
papers.
JEL Codes: C51, J22

I

thank John Kennan, Rody Manuelli, Jonathan Parker, and Jim Walker for detailed comments and
encouragement. I also thank Joe Altonji, Peter Arcidiacono, Meredith Crowley, Nelson Gra , Dan Sullivan,
Jim Ziliak, the referees, and seminar participants at the Chicago Fed, SUNY-Stony Brook, and the Econometric
Society. Greg Duncan answered many data questions. Financial support provided by the National Institute on
Mental Health. The views of the author do not necessarily re ect those of the Federal Reserve System. Recent
versions of the paper can be obtained at http://www.chicagofed.org/economists/EricFrench.cfm/.

1

1

Introduction

This paper estimates the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, accounting explicitly for
measurement error. Several in uential studies, using person-speci c year-to-year variation
in hours and wages estimate a small (usually between 0 and .5)1 intertemporal elasticity of
substitution (MaCurdy (1981), Altonji (1986), Abowd and Card (1989), Holtz-Eakin et al.
(1988), Ziliak and Kniesner (1999)). All of the studies use data from the Panel Study of
Income Dynamics (PSID). However, Heckman (1993) argues that \the low estimated value
of the intertemporal-substitution elasticity found in panel data studies appears to be a consequence of non-standard measurement-error problems".2
Previous PSID studies assume the measurement error structure their estimation strategy
can accommodate, without asking what error structure they should want to accommodate.
They assume either that measurement error in hours and wages is white noise (Holtz-Eakin
et al. (1988), Ziliak and Kniesner (1999)) or white noise with a xed e ect (Altonji (1986),
Abowd and Card (1987,1989)). These assumptions imply that wages or wage changes two
years in the past are valid instruments for current wage changes. However, the literature
on measurement error indicates that measurement error in hours and wages is not white
noise (see the references in Bound et al. (2001)). Instead, measurement error in wages is
autocorrelated and is correlated with true hours and wages. This means that using twice
lagged wages and wage changes will not overcome the \division bias" problem which biases
labor supply elasticities downwards.3
In this study I develop a modi ed instrumental variables estimator to estimate the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. The estimator accounts for the measurement error
problems described above. The analysis proceeds as follows.
These estimates are signi cantly below the assumed elasticities in most Real Business Cycle models.
Therefore,
the PSID studies cast doubt on the microfoundations of the Real Business Cycle literature.
2
Another potential statistical problem with the PSID studies is small sample bias. Lee (2001) nds that
the estimated intertemporal elasticity of substitution is .5 when using standard instruments in the PSID and
accounting
for small sample bias.
3
These problems in the PSID studies motivate several new labor supply studies using natural experiments
(Oettinger (1999), Mulligan (1995, 1999), Camerer et al. (1997), Carrington (1996)). While these new studies
raise important criticisms, they produce no new consensus. For example, Camerer et al. (1997) estimate the
intertemporal elasticity of substitution to be -.7, whereas Mulligan's estimate is 2. One problem with these
studies is that they focus on small groups (Camerer et. al. on taxi cab drivers, Oettinger (1999) on stadium
vendors) or isolated instances (Carrington (1996) measures the intertemporal elasticity of substitution using
evidence from the Alaska oil pipeline boom). These speci c cases may not generalize to the population as a
whole.
1

2

First, I set up the standard intertemporal labor supply model. The object of interest
in this model is the labor supply response to anticipated wage changes. I use last year's
wage change to predict this year's wage change. Last year's wage change should have good
predictive power is there is a transitory component to wages. A transitory wage change
represents an event such as high wages being paid for a short period of time, as in the Alaskan
Oil Pipeline boom of the 1970s (Carrington, 1996). If workers anticipate that transitory wage
changes disappear, then transitory wage changes can identify the labor supply response to
anticipated wage changes.
While using last year's wage change has great power in predicting the current wage change,
it introduces potential measurement error biases. The estimator developed in this paper
accounts for the covariance of measurement error with true variables and the autocovariances
of measurement error.
Finally, I estimate the labor supply response to predictable wage changes, controlling
explicitly for measurement error in hours and wages. I estimate the properties of measurement
error using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics Validation Study (PSIDVS). I then use this
information about measurement error to purge measurement error from the PSID. I nd a
large transitory component of wages, even after controlling for measurement error.
I nd that failure to properly control for measurement error when estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution can lead to misleading inferences about the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. However, I also nd that controlling explicitly for measurement error
does not overturn the conclusions of previous PSID studies of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution. The estimated intertemporal elasticity of substitution is close to zero with a
standard error of .25.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the labor supply model and how I
control for measurement error when estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.
Section 3 describes the PSID data. It also describes the PSIDVS data that I use to estimate
the properties of measurement error. Section 4 presents estimates of the model of wage
dynamics and estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Section 5 concludes.

3

2

Estimating the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution

In this section I present a standard life-cycle labor supply model. I also present a wage
prediction equation. The central implication of the life-cycle labor supply model is that hours
changes are positively correlated with predictable wage changes. Lastly, I consider how to
address issues of measurement error in estimating the labor supply response to predictable
wage changes.
2.1

The Intertemporal Labor Supply Model

I begin with the standard intertemporal labor supply model. The speci cation is similar
to MaCurdy (1985). Preferences take the form:
U

= E0

T
X
t=1

t



v(cit )

exp(

hit1+  
it = ) 
1+ 1
1



(1)

where U is the expected discounted present value of lifetime utility, cit is consumption, v(:)
is some increasing concave function, and hit is hours worked. The parameter  is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, which is the object of interest in this study. Lastly, it
is the preference for work. De ne Ait as assets, rt the interest rate, and Wit the true wage.
Individuals choose labor supply4 and consumption paths to maximize equation (1) subject
to the dynamic budget constraint
Ait+1 = (1 + rt )(Ait + Wit hit cit )

(2)

which results in the labor supply function:
log hit =  log Wit +  log it +

(3)

it

which in rst di erences is
log hit = log Wit + log it + 

it ;

(4)

4
Most labor supply models assume that individuals choose their work hours given the wage. This rules out
the complications created by contracting models (see Rosen (1985) and Abowd and Card (1987), for example).

4

where  is the rst di erence operator (e.g., log hit = log hit log hit 1 ) and it is the
marginal utility of wealth.
The Euler equation implies that individuals equate expected marginal utility across time
according to
it 1 =

(1 + rt 1 )Et

(5)

1 it

where rational expectations5 implies that innovations to the marginal utility of wealth, denoted "it ; should be uncorrelated with lagged values of the marginal utility of wealth:
it = Et 1 it + "it

(6)

Equations (5) and (6) can be rewritten as
!

(1 + rt 1)it = 1 + (1 + rt 1 )"it
it 1
it 1

(7)
(1+rt 1 )"it ) yields

Taking logarithms of both sides of (7) and approximating log(1 +
log it log it

it

1

!

(1 + rt 1 )"it  (1 + rt 1 )"it (8)
1 + log (1 + rt 1 ) = log 1 +
it 1
it 1

Throughout I will assume that the approximation in (8) holds with equality. As innovations
in the marginal utility of wealth become arbitrarily small, equation (8) becomes an arbitrarily
close approximation.
Combining (8) and (4) results in
log hit = log Wit

 log

(1 + rt 1 ) +  (1 + rt 1 )"it + 
it

1

(9)

it :

The object of interest in this study is ; which is a measure of the substitution e ect associated
with a wage change.
If workers have rational expectations then at time t they know their state variables  log Wit ; rt;
Markov process that determines the evolution of the state variables, and optimize accordingly.
5

5

it ;

the

2.2

Using Lagged Wage Changes to Predict Current Wage Changes

Equation (9) shows that there are three determinants of hours changes that are potentially
correlated with wage changes: the interest rate, preference changes, and expectation errors.
I must control for all three objects in order to obtain a consistent estimate of : I remove the
correlation between wage changes and both the interest rate and preference changes by using
residuals from regressions of wage and hours changes on a full set of year dummy variables,
health status, age and education in the analysis.6 Throughout the rest of the paper, log Wit
is rede ned as the true wage residual and log hit is rede ned as the true hours residual.7
Time t wage changes log Wit are correlated with the time t expectation errors "it if
wage changes are unanticipated. However, if individuals have rational expectations then
expectation errors are uncorrelated with information known to the individual at time t 1:
Therefore, the wage can be instrumented using time t 1 information. A natural instrument
is last year's wage change, log Wit 1 : Consider the following model of wage growth:
log Wit = Æ + log Wit 1 + it :

\

(10)

Predicted wage growth, log Wit is then

\

log Wit = Æ + log Wit

1:

(11)

Individuals may use more information than what is used in equation (11), but must use at
least the information used in equation (11) when forecasting wage changes.
Inserting equation (11) into equation (9) (and netting out year e ects and preference
shifters) shows that the instrumental variables estimate of  is
=

\\

Cov(log hit ; log Wit )
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit )

Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 )
= Cov
(log Wit; log Wit 1 )

(12)

where the above objects are population moments. The labor supply response to these preSection 3 describes the procedure more fully. By construction, the hours residuals are uncorrelated with
the year e ects (and thus the interest rate) and with observable preference shifters such as health. Using
these hours residuals, the only determinants of hours changes will be wage changes and unobserved preference
changes.
7
The relationship between measured hours, the measured hours residual, and the true hours residual is
described in equations (14) and (25).
6

6

dictable wage changes identi es the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. For example, if
wages have a transitory component, wage changes will be negatively correlated across time,
i.e. Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1) < 0: Testing whether  is positive will then be equivalent to
testing whether Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) is negative.
2.3

The Problem of Measurement Error

Given that measurement error is pervasive in wage and hours data, measurement error
must be purged from equation (12). In most studies, measurement error is assumed to
be white noise (Altonji (1986), Holtz-Eakin et al. (1988), Ziliak and Kniesner (1999)) or
white noise with a xed e ect (Abowd and Card (1987, 1989)). However, validation studies
(Bound et al. (2000)) have refuted these assumptions. The validation studies have shown that
measurement error in wages and hours is negatively correlated with true wages and hours.
Bound et al. (1994) refer to this as \mean reverting measurement error". One potential
explanation for mean reverting measurement error is that workers underreport transitory
changes in wages and hours.8
The validation studies also suggest that the serial correlation properties of measurement
error may be more complicated than a simple xed e ect. While Bound et al. (1994) nd
only a .09 correlation in measurement error in earnings four years apart in the Panel Study
of Income Dynamics Validation Study, Bound and Krueger (1991) nd a .38 correlation in
measurement error in earnings two years apart when comparing matched CPS data to Social
Security Earnings Records. Note that if measurement error in earnings were white noise with
a xed e ect, the correlation of measurement error two years apart should be the same as
the correlation of measurement error four years apart.9
Although many models of measurement error are consistent with the evidence, a MA(1)
process with a xed e ect is a parsimonious model that is consistent with the evidence.
This is potential evidence that workers tend to forget short-term changes in hours and wages. If so, it
seems
unlikely that workers think seriously about adjusting their work hours to transitory wage uctuations.
9
The Bound et al. (1994) study and the Bound and Krueger (1991) study each use di erent datasets and
each has its own idiosyncratic problems. For example, one problem with the CPS study is that that some
people interviewed during this time period potentially had more than one Social Security number. Therefore,
the validation procedure is awed when using Social Security records as a validation source. The correlation of
measurement error could be the result of two successive mismatches between the CPS and the Social Security
records. Moreover, the PSID is a higher quality dataset. Problems of autocorrelation of measurement error
that exist in the CPS may not exist in the PSID. The data section describes some of the problems with the
PSIDVS. Nevertheless, the two studies give evidence that measurement error may be more complicated than
white noise with a xed e ect.
8

7

Therefore, consider the following model of measured hours and wages:10
log W~it = log Wit + uwit;

(13)

log h~it = log hit + uhit:

(14)

Measurement error in wages and hours follows:
uwit = uwi + wit + w wit 1 ;

(15)

uhit = uhi + hit + h hit 1 ;

(16)

where innovations to the transitory component of measurement error are correlated with the
transitory component of wages but not with any autocorrelated component of wages, i.e.
Cov(wit ; log Wit ) 6= 0; Cov(wit ; hit ) 6= 0; but Cov(wit ; log Wit k ) = 0; Cov(wit ; wit k ) =
0 for all k 6= 0: Moreover, assume that all the covariances of measurement error are stationary,
i.e. Cov(log Wit 1 ; wit 1) = Cov(log Wit ; wit ) and Cov(wit 1; hit 1 ) = Cov(wit; hit ): In
Appendix B I show that rst-di erencing equations (13)-(16) then inserting these equations
Cov( log hit ;log Wit )
into equation (12) results in a speci cation for  = Cov
( log Wit ;log Wit ) , where
1
1

Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 )

=

~ it 1 ) + (1
Cov(log h~ it ; log W

=

~ it; log W~ it 1 ) + (2
Cov(log W
+(1 2w + 2 )V ar(wit):

2h + hw )Cov(hit ; wit )
+Cov(wit; log hit ) + (1 2h)Cov(hit ; log Wit )
(17)

and
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 )

w

2w )Cov(log Wit ; wit) +
(18)

Wages are usually imputed using earnings divided by hours.11 Therefore, an overreport
Recall these are measured hours and wage residuals.
Some authors use alternative wage measures (Altonji (1986), Ziliak and Kniesner (1999)) which potentially
overcome the problems mentioned herein. However, Altonji (1986) measures the intertemporal elasticity for
10
11

8

of hours leads to an underreport of wages, making measurement error in hours negatively
correlated with measurement error in wages, i.e. Cov(hit ; wit ) < 0: Failure to include this
term will bias the estimate of Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1) upwards.12
Note that V ar(wit) is positive. Thus, failure to control for this term will bias the estimate
of Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1) downwards. Given that failure to control for measurement error biases Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) upwards and Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 ) downwards,
the intertemporal elasticity of substitution will most likely be biased downwards. This problem, known as \division bias", is well recognized in the labor supply literature.
What is less well recognized, however, is how \mean reverting measurement" error should
a ect the estimate of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Equations (17) and (18)
show that the covariance between measurement error and true hours and wages can also
create bias.
2.4

Sources of Bias when Twice Lagged Wage Changes Instrument for
Current Wage Changes

As stated previously, many researchers use twice lagged wages or twice lagged wage
changes to instrument for current wage changes. After controlling for preference shifters
and the interest rate, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution when using twice lagged
wage changes (used by Abowd and Card (1987, 1989), for example) as an instrument is


=
=

Cov(log hit ; log Wit 2 )
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 2 )
~ it 2 ) + h[Cov(hit ; log Wit ) + Cov(hit ; wit)]
Cov(log ~hit ; log W
~ it ; log W~ it 2) + w[Cov(wit; log Wit ) + V ar(wit )] :
Cov(log W

(19)

When using twice lagged wage levels as an instrument for the wage change (used by HoltzEakin et al. (1989), Ziliak and Kniesner (1999)), the intertemporal elasticity of substitution
a subset of the population. Moreover, his measure of the wage does not include bonuses and overtime, a
potentially important source of variability in wages. Ziliak and Kniesner (1999) use earnings divided by a
constant. If hours are autocorrelated but have a correlation coeÆcient of less than one, their procedure will
produce
upward biased estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.
12
This is true only when (1 2h + h w ) > 0; or when h and w are not \too big". Unfortunately, we have
little evidence on these two parameters. Assuming that the measurement error properties of earnings in the
CPS are the same as those for hours and wages in the PSID, results from Bound and Krueger (1991) indicate
that this inequality holds.

9

is


=
=

Cov(log hit ; log Wit 2 )
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 2 )
~ it 2) Cov(log hit ; uwi) + h[Cov(hit ; log Wit) + Cov(hit; wit )]
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
~ it; log W~ it 2 ) Cov(log Wit ; uwi) + w[Cov(wit ; log Wit ) + V ar(wit)] :
Cov(log W

(20)

Equations (19) and (20) show that using twice lagged wage levels and changes are only valid
instruments if measurement error has no MA(1) component, i.e. h = w = 0: If h > 0 and
Cov(hit ; wit ) < 0; the numerator in equations (19) and (20) is biased upwards. Likewise,
the denominator in equations (19) and (20) are biased downwards. This likely leads to
a downward biased estimate of : In other words, using twice lagged wage changes only
overcomes the division bias problem when there is no MA(1) measurement error component.
2.5

Estimating Equations

The restrictions necessary to identify the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (the ratio
of equations (17) to (18)) are described in Table 1. The rst ve restrictions in Table 1 follow
from equations (15) and (16) and the orthogonality and stationarity assumptions described
immediately below equation (16). However, given the data in the next section, both w and
h are still unknown without making further assumptions. In order to identify the MA(1)
measurement error coeÆcients h and w using data, we need information on the correlation
of measurement error across two adjacent years. Unfortunately, this does not exist in the
available data. Therefore, I consider two alternative sets of assumptions about the values
of w and h: Each set of assumptions enables me to identify the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution.
Under assumption (A1) I assume w = 0 and h = 0: Assumption (A1) and the assumptions in Section 2.3 result in the nal two identifying restrictions listed in Table 1. Using
these identifying assumptions, equations (17) and (18) can be rewritten as
~ it 1) + Cov(log hit ; uwit) Cov(log hit ; uwit
Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) = Cov(log h~ it ; log W


+ Cov(uhit ; log Wit)



Cov(uhit k ; log Wit )

+ Cov(uhit; uwit )

10

Cov(uhit ; uwit

k

); (21)

k

)

~ it ; log W~ it 1 )
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 ) = Cov(log W
+ 2Cov(log Wit ; uwit)

Cov(log Wit ; uwit

k

) + V ar(uwit)

Cov(uwit ; uwit

k

) (22)

for jkj > 1:
~ it ;log W~ it )
Cov( log W
In assumption (A2) I assume that w = (Cov
(log Wit ;wit )+V ar(wit )) and h =
~ it )
Cov( log ~hit ; log W
(Cov(log Wit ;hit )+Cov(wit ;hit )) : Assumption (A2) is equivalent to assuming Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 2 ) =
0 and Cov(log hit ; log Wit 2) = 0; i.e., all autocorrelation between measured wage changes
and their second lag arises from the autocorrelation of measurement error. Assumption (A2)
is satis ed if log wages are a random walk with white noise superimposed. Given these
assumptions, equations (17) and (18) can be rewritten as:
2

2

~ it 1) + Cov(log hit ; uwit) Cov(log hit ; uwit
Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) = Cov(log h~ it ; log W


+ Cov(uhit ; log Wit) Cov(uhit k ; log Wit) + Cov(uhit ; uwit)
+ 2Cov(log h~ it ; log W~ it 2 );
~ it ; log W~ it 1 )
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 ) = Cov(log W

Cov(uhit ; uwit

+ 2(Cov(log Wit; uwit ) Cov(log Wit ; uwit k ) + (V ar(uwit)
+ 2Cov(log W~ it; log W~ it 2 )

k

)

Cov(uwit ; uwit

(23)

k

)

(24)

for jkj > 1: The two estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution that I present in
this paper are the ratio of (21) to (22) and the ratio of (23) to (24).
3

Data

Given the scheme for estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution presented
above, I need information on the properties of measured wages and hours (namely the variances and covariances of wage and hours residuals) as well as the properties of measurement
error (namely the variances and covariances of measurement error). I use the PSID for
measuring the properties of measured wages and hours and the PSIDVS for measuring the
properties of measurement error.
Table 2 describes some basic characteristics of the PSID and PSIDVS samples. Because
11

k

)

the PSIDVS sample only has hourly workers, I show results for both all male workers in
the PSID as well as for male hourly workers in the PSID. The PSIDVS sample is older,
less educated and has higher wages than both the full and hourly PSID samples. Most
importantly, there is a \true" wage and hours measure which will be described below.
3.1

PSID Data

The data source used to estimate the properties of measured wages is a male subsample
of the PSID for the years 1981-1987, collected by researchers at the University of Michigan. I
restrict the PSID sample to the years 1981-1987 to maximize how comparable the PSID is to
the PSIDVS, which has data on hours and wages and measurement error in hours and wages
for 1982 and 1986. I exclude the Survey of Economic Opportunity (SEO) subsample, which
oversamples the poor and minorities. Survey respondents are asked about their earnings,
labor supply patterns, and other decisions during the previous calendar year. Therefore,
responses are for the years 1980-1986. Wages are imputed using annual earnings divided by
annual hours. Appendix A describes the sample selection criteria.
As described in section 2.2, I posit the following model of measured log hours changes,
log hit , and wage changes log Wit :
log hit = Xit G + log h~ it ;

(25)

log Wit = Xit B + log W~ it;

(26)

where Xit is a vector of personal characteristics and year dummy variables, and log h~ it and
log h~ it are the hours and wage residuals. Included in Xit are year dummies, a third order
age polynomial, education, and health. Note that log W~ it is orthogonal to the interest rate
by construction, as it is orthogonal to the year e ects. It is also orthogonal to observable
preference shifters such as health. Table 3 presents estimates for hours and wages 1980-1987.
The most striking aspect of the regressions in Table 3 is how little of the variation in wages
and hours these variables can explain. Note that these variables, less health, are the usual
instruments for wages when estimating labor supply functions. The R2 is .0111 for hours and
.0055 for wages. In other words, variation in the business cycle, age, education and health
12

explains only .55% of the variation in wage movements and 1.11% of the variation in hours
movements. The focus of this paper will be on the labor supply response to (the predictable
component of) the remaining 99.45% of wage variation.
Table 4 reports the covariance of time t measured hours and wage changes with time
t 1 and t 2 wage changes. There is a negative covariance between current and lagged
wage changes, indicating that if wages rose last year they will fall this year. There is a
positive covariance between current hours changes and lagged wage changes, indicating that
if measured wages rose last year, measured hours will on average rise this year. If hours and
wages were free of measurement error, Table 4 would indicate that hours rise in response to
a predictable decline in the wage. This would suggest a negative intertemporal elasticity of
substitution. Given the presence of measurement error, no such inference should be made.
The next section describes the measurement error corrections that will be made.
3.2

Using the PSIDVS to Determine the Properties of Measurement Error
in PSID Data

In order to identify the properties of measurement error, I use PSIDVS described in Bound
et al. (1994). A discussion of the survey design and results follows. The PSIDVS was designed
to test the properties of measurement error in the PSID. Researchers from the University of
Michigan surveyed employees at a single large Detroit-area manufacturing company in both
1983 and 1987.13 The employees who were interviewed in 1983 and were still employed by
the rm in 1987 were re-interviewed, as were an additional sample of workers who were not
interviewed in 1983. This creates a small panel of workers, as well as a somewhat larger cross
section of workers. The design of this survey and the questions in the survey are similar to
those in the PSID, although the PSIDVS asks fewer questions than the PSID.
The company records in the PSIDVS serve as a virtually error free dataset to compare
with worker reports. I will therefore regard company measures of hours and wages as true
hours and wages, log hit and log Wit :14 The company has information on annual earnings
Therefore, hours and earnings responses are for 1982 and 1986.
Formally true hours are Xit G +log hit and true wages are Xit B +log Wit : So long as measurement error is
uncorrelated with Xit it is not necessary to subtract Xit G from hours or Xit B from wages. There was a small
negative correlation between the variance of measurement error and education. Because the PSIDVS sample
has lower education than the PSID sample, this will lead to the variance of measurement error in the PSID
being overestimated. However, the correlation was small and would not signi cantly a ect the estimates.
13
14

13

and hours worked by all hourly employees.15 The company keeps records of earnings for
tax purposes. The number of hours worked by hourly employees is measured by punch-clock.
Therefore, the company has precise measures of both earnings and hours. Di erences between
company records and survey responses are attributed to measurement error on the part of
the employee. Since the survey design of the PSIDVS is similar to the survey design of the
PSID, a worker's propensity to misreport earnings and hours should be similar in the two
datasets.
Table 5 presents covariances between hours, wages, and measurement error in hours and
wages for male hourly workers. Three important aspects of the data are worth noting. First,
there is a negative covariance between measurement error in hours and wages. This is the
\division bias" problem. Second, it displays a positive covariance between wages and measurement error in hours, as well as the positive covariance between hours and measurement
error in wages.16 Inspection of equations (21) and (22) shows that mean reverting measurement error tends to o set division bias. Lastly, there is evidence of serial correlation in
measurement error. Failure to account for serial correlation of measurement error will lead
to an overstatement of the variance of transitory measurement error. This is important because the model is identi ed using transitory wage variation. Therefore, if we overstate the
amount of transitory wage variation attributable to measurement error, we will overstate the
importance of division bias. Although the covariances between measurement error and true
variables as well as the autocovariance of measurement error are statistically insigni cant,
they are fairly large in magnitude.
There are four major reasons why measurement error in the PSIDVS may not be comparable to measurement error in the PSID. The rst reason is that I assume that the company
records are perfect, and that the company records have been perfectly transcribed. Although
the PSIDVS is of high quality, it is not perfect.17 This should cause the variance of meaHourly workers were paid overtime.
These covariances are a result of mean reverting measurement error. Previous studies have found a negative
covariance between true hours and measurement error in hours. Given that wages are imputed by dividing
measured earnings by measured hours, it is unsurprising that there is a positive covariance between true hours
and measurement error in wages and a positive covariance between true wages and measurement error in
hours.
17
For example, one observation in the panel was deleted because the 1987 company report of an individual's
earnings in 1982 was di erent from its 1983 report of the same individual's earnings in 1982. Although the
discrepancy was small, it is potential evidence that there were transcription errors in 1983. Although I was
able to delete this observation, there are potentially other observations that are erroneous company reports or
other transcription errors.
15

16

14

surement error to be overestimated since measurement error on the part of the rm is being
attributed to measurement error on the part of the individual.
The second reason why measurement error in the PSIDVS may not be comparable to
measurement error in the PSID is that the PSIDVS samples a homogenous group of workers.
The PSIDVS respondents were all hourly workers18 who worked for a single rm, and most
were worked full time. Table 2 shows that the standard deviation of reported wages and
reported hours is much smaller in the PSIDVS sample than in the PSID sample. This may
bias results for the following reason. Recall that measurement error is potentially mean
reverting, i.e. Cov(log Wit ; uwit) < 0: Also note that in a sample with no variability in wages
it must be the case that Cov(log Wit ; uwit) = 0: Therefore, since there is less variability in
wages in the PSIDVS than in the PSID, the importance of mean reverting measurement
error is likely smaller in the PSIDVS than in the PSID. Inspection of equations (21) and (22)
shows that mean reverting measurement error tends to o set the variances and covariances
of measurement error. Given that the PSIDVS likely understates the importance of mean
reverting measurement error, it likely overstates the importance the division bias problem.
Third, most of the workers in the PSIDVS are older than those in the PSID and all of the
workers have remained with the same employer for several years. Therefore, it may be that
the workers in the PSIDVS are familiar with their earnings and hours of work and are able
to report the number of hours that they work more accurately than the population surveyed
by the PSID. This would tend to indicate that the variance of measurement error might be
underestimated in the PSIDVS.
Fourth, transitory wage shocks could be more or less important in this rm than for other
rms. Potentially, both the variance of measurement error and the covariance of measurement
error with true variables may be a ected by the size of the transitory wage shocks.19 The
extent of possible bias created by measurement problems in the PSIDVS is unclear. The next
Both salaried and hourly workers were interviewed, but the company has records for hours worked only
for hourly workers. Although the PSIDVS has no information about measurement error in hours for salaried
workers, it does have information about measurement error in earnings (which is used to impute wages)
for salaried workers. The variance of measurement error in earnings for salaried workers is .0232 and the
variance of measurement error in earnings for hourly workers is .0221, so the estimates for the two groups
are not statistically di erent from each other. Likewise, the covariance of measurement error in earnings with
reported
hours and reported earnings are also not statistically di erent for the two groups.
19
Bound et al. (1994) show that both earnings and hours were signi cantly lower in 1982 than in 1986,
potentially because of the 1982 recession. Table 5 shows that many of the variances and covariances of
measurement error are larger in 1982 than in 1986.
18

15

section reports results assuming that any possible bias is small.
4

Results

4.1

Estimates Using Measurement Error Corrections

Table 6 shows four estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, as well as rst
stage statistics. The necessary covariances for estimation are in tables 4 and 5. The sample
selection criteria are described in appendix A. Appendices C and D describe computation of
standard errors and the rst stage F and R2 statistics.
The estimates in column (1) make no corrections for measurement error. The estimated
intertemporal elasticity of substitution is negative. When assuming measurement error is
white noise, as in column (2), the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is positive.20 The
reason for the change in sign is that the estimates in column (2) account for the division bias
problem. As mentioned previously, failure to account for measurement error results in downward biased estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. However, the estimates
in column (2) do not account for the correlation between true variables and measurement
error. Column (3) accounts for the correlation of measurement error with true variables.
It shows that accounting for \mean reverting measurement error" reduces the estimated intertemporal elasticity of substitution. The estimates in column (3) assume that there is no
MA(1) component to measurement error, however. Column (4) assumes that all covariation
in hours and wage changes with twice lagged wage changes arises from measurement error.
Making this assumption reduces the estimate of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution
again. Although there is insuÆcient data to distinguish which assumption about the MA(1)
component of measurement error is better, both columns (3) and (4) indicate an intertemporal elasticity of substitution that is close to zero. Moreover, they are not statistically di erent
from each other, regardless of whether or not the PSID sample is restricted to hourly workers.
However, all estimates in columns (3) and (4) are statistically di erent from .7 and -.5 when
using all workers and are statistically di erent from .9 and -.7 when using hourly workers,
meaning that the estimates can reject a very large estimate of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution.
Note, however, that standard errors are large. The large standard errors are the result of the small sample
size of the PSIDVS. It would useful to re-estimate the model using new validation data if it becomes available.
20

16

4.2

Estimates Using Alternative Instruments for Wage Changes

Table 7 presents estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution using di erent
instruments for the time t wage change. The hours and wage change measures are again
residuals from regressions on an age cubic, education, year dummies and changes in health
status.21 Of the seven sets of estimates, columns (1)-(3) use instrument sets similar to other
authors.22 Column (1) uses an instrument set (log W~ it 2 ) similar to Abowd and Card
(1987, 1989). Column (2) uses an instrument set (log W~ it 2 ) used by Holtz-Eakin et al.
(1988). Column (3) uses an instrument set similar to Altonji (1986), who uses both the level
and rst di erence of the rst lag of the reported current hourly wage of hourly workers,
denoted log W_ it 1 and log W_ it 1 ; to instrument for log W~ it 2 : Because the two measures
are constructed di erently, measurement error in log W_ it 1 and in log W_ it 1 should be
uncorrelated with measurement error in log W~ it:23 This overcomes the division bias problem.
Unfortunately, it is likely that most of the transitory wage variation comes from overtime and
bonuses. Moreover, W_ it refers to a given point in time, whereas the relevant wage measure is
the wage over the calendar year. Therefore, most of the year-to-year variation in the hourly
wage is likely missing when using W_ it : This will reduce the predictive power of the rst stage
R2 and will also make measurement error in this wage measure negatively correlated with
the true wage. If measurement error in W_ it is negatively correlated with the true wage, the
measure becomes an invalid instrument.
Columns (1)-(3) show that the estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution
are higher when using log W_ it than when using log W~ it as an instrument. One possible reason
for this discrepancy is that serially correlated measurement error in log W~ it is biasing the
estimated intertemporal elasticity of substitution downwards. In section 2.4 I showed that
serially correlated measurement error most likely biases the intertemporal elasticity of substi21
I also tried a more standard approach. That is, include the age cubic, education, year dummies and
changes in health status as right hand side regressors in the second stage. The di erent approach did not lead
to 22substantially di erent estimates.
Data from 1969 to 1996 were used in the analysis, although the same coding decisions (outlined in Appendix
A) were used as in the previous subsection.
23
Altonji (1986) notes that the current hourly wage measure W_ it refers to the wage at the time of the
interview whereas the earnings divided by hours measure W~ it refers to hours and earnings over the previous
calendar year. In order to make the two wage measures refer to the same time period, I use the hours and
earnings measures reported at time t + 1 to generate W~ it:

17

tution downwards when using either log W~ it or log W~ it as an instrument. In columns (4) and
(5) the sample is restricted to hourly workers who have data on log W_ it 2 and log W~ it 2 :
In columns (6) and (7)The sample is restricted to hourly workers who have data on both
log W_ it 2 and log W~ it 2 : Since the same people are being used to estimate the intertemporal
elasticity of substitution, we should think that both log W_ it 2 and log W~ it 2 should yield
the same results and both log W_ it 2 and log W~ it 2 should yield the same results in the
absence of serially correlated measurement error. If serially correlated measurement error is
a ecting estimates when using the log W~ it measure of wages, then we should see higher estimates of Cov(log h~ it ; instrument) and lower estimates of Cov(log W~ it; instrument) when
using log W~ it 2 instead of log W_ it 2 as the instrument. It appears that there is evidence
for this claim, although di erences are statistically insigni cant. Therefore, there is some
evidence that serially correlated measurement error leads to downward biased estimates of
the intertemporal elasticity of substitution when using twice lagged wages.24 However, the
most important thing to note is that all estimates are close to zero. These results, combined
with the results in the previous subsection, show that person-speci c year to year variation
in hours is uncorrelated with person-speci c year to year variation in wages.
5

Conclusions

In this paper I estimate the labor supply response to predictable wage changes. Using
data from the PSID and the PSIDVS, I nd a large transitory component to wages, even after
correcting for measurement error. Since, by de nition, the transitory component of wages
vanishes over time, workers should anticipate that transitory wage shocks should vanish. This
means that workers can predict some wage changes, and thus the labor supply response to
these predicable wage changes identi es the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.
Using data from the PSIDVS, I nd that that measurement error in hours and wages is
correlated with true hours and wages. I also nd that measurement error is serially correlated.
This violates the assumptions of many previous PSID studies of intertemporal labor supply
and will most likely lead to downward biased estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution.
24

Ziliak and Kniesner (1999) also nd evidence that the W~ it measure leads to downward biased estimates.

18

However, properly controlling for measurement error does not overturn the qualitative
ndings of the previous PSID studies. Depending on the assumed autocorrelation structure
for measurement error, point estimates are -.03 to .10 with a standard error of .25. A
conservative range for the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is -.5 to .6. Although the
range is wide, an estimate of .6 is still well below the elasticities used in the Real Business
Cycle literature.

19

References

[1]

, \Intertemporal Labor Supply and Long Term Contracts,"
American Economic Review , March 1987, 50-68.
[2]
, \On the Covariance Structure of Earnings and Hours
Changes," Econometrica , March 1989, 57(2), 411-445.
[3]
, \Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Supply: Evidence from Microdata,"
Journal of Political Economy , 1986, 94, S176-S215.
[4]
, \Small Sample Bias in GMM Estimation of Covariance
Structures," Journal of Business and Economic Statistics , 1994, 14(3), 353-366.
Abowd, J., and D. Card

Abowd, J., and D. Card

Altonji, J.

Altonji, J., and L. Segal

[5]

, \The E ect of Age at School Entry on Educational
Attainment: An Application of Instrumental Variables With Moments From Two Samples," Journal of the American Statistical Association , vol. 87, no. 418, 1992, 328-336.
[6]
, \Growth-Rate Heterogeneity and the Covariance Structure of Life-Cycle
Earnings," Journal of Labor Economics , vol. 15, no. 2, 1997, 338-375.
Angrist, J. and A. Krueger

Baker, M.

[7]

Borjas, G.

, \The Relationship between Wages and Weekly Hours of Work: The Role
of Division Bias," Journal of Human Resources , Summer 1980, 409-423.

[8]

Bound, J., C. Brown, G. Duncan, and W. Rogers

, \Evidence on the Validity of
Cross-Sectional and Longitudinal Labor Market Data," Journal of Labor Economics,
1994, vol. 12, 345-368.
[9]
, \Measurement Error in Survey Data,"
in J. Heckman and E. Leamer, eds., Handbook of Econometrics Vol. 5, , 2001.
Bound, J., C. Brown and N. Mathiowetz

[10]

, \Problems With Instrumental Variables Estimation When the Correlation Between the Instruments and the Endogenous Explanatory
Variable Is Weak," Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 90, no. 430,
1992, 443-450.
[11]
, \The Extent of Measurement Error in Longitudinal
Earnings Data: Do Two Wrongs Make a Right?" Journal of Labor Economics, 1991, vol.
9, 1-24.
Bound, J., D. Jaeger, and R. Baker

Bound, J., and A. Krueger

20

[12]

Browning, M., A. Deaton and M. Irish

[13]

Camerer, C., L. Babcock, G. Lowenstein, and R. Thaler

[14]

Card, D.

[15]

Carrington., W.

[16]

Chamberlain, G

[17]

Duncan, G., and D. Hill

[18]

Farber, H. and R. Gibbons

[19]

Ghez, G, and G. Becker

[20]
[21]
[22]
[23]

, \A Pro table Approach to Labor Supply
and Commodity Demands Over the Life-Cycle," Econometrica, 1985, 53(3), 503-543.

, \One Day At a Time:
An Empirical Analysis of Cab Drivers," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1997.
, \ Intertemporal Labor Supply: An Assessment," in C. Sims(ed.), Advances
in Econometrics: Sixth World Congress , Volume 2, 1994.
, \The Alaskan Labor Market During the Pipeline Era," Journal of
Political Economy, 1996, 104(1), 186-218.
, \Panel Data," in Griliches and Intrilligator (eds.), Handbook of
Econometrics , 1984, 1247-1318.
, \An Investigation of the Extent and Consequences of
Measurement Error in Labor-economic Survey Data," Journal of Labor Economics ,
1984, 3(4), 508-531.
Economics , 1996, 1007-1047.

NBER, 1975.

, \Learning and Wage Dynamics," Quarterly Journal of

, The Allocation of Time and Goods Over the Life Cycle ,

, \Testing Intertemporal Substitution, Implicit Contracts, and
Hours Restrictions Models of the Labor Market Using Micro Data", manuscript, 2001.
Ham, J., and K. Reilly

, \What Has Been Learned About Labor Supply in the Past Twenty
Years?" American Economic Review, 1993, 83(2), S116-121.

Heckman, J.

, \Estimating Vector Autoregressions
with Panel Data," Econometrica, November 1988, 56(6), 1371-1395.
Holtz-Eakin, D., W. Newey, and H. Rosen

, \Finite Sample Bias in IV Estimation of Intertemporal Labor Supply Models:
Is the Intertemporal Substitution Elasticity Really Small?" Review of Economics and
Statistics , 2001, 638-646.

Lee, C.

21

[24]

MaCurdy, T.,

\An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life-Cycle Setting," Journal
of Political Economy 1981, 89(6), 1059-1085.

[25]

MaCurdy, T.

, \The Use of Time Series Methods to Model the Error Structure of
Earnings in a Longitudinal Analysis," Journal of Econometrics , 1982, 83-114.

[26]

, \Interpreting Empirical Models of Labor Supply in an Intertemporal
Framework with Uncertainty," in J. Heckman and B. Singer (eds.), Longitudinal Analysis
of Labor Market Data , Cambridge University Press, 1985.

[27]

, \The Intertemporal Substitution of Work - What Does the Evidence
Say?" Manuscript, University of Chicago, 1995.

MaCurdy, T.

Mulligan, C.

[28]

Mulligan, C.

, \Substitution Over Time: Another Look At Life Cycle Labor Supply,"
NBER Macro Annual 1998 , 1999, 75-134.

[29]

Nelson, C., and R. Startz

[30]

Oettinger, G.

[31]

Pischke, J-S

[32]

Rosen, S.

[33]

Staiger, D. and James Stock

[34]

Ziliak, J. and Kniesner

, \Some Further Results on the Exact Small Sample Properties of the Instrumental Variables Estimator," Econometrica, 1990, 58 (4), 967-976.
, \An Empirical Analysis of the Daily Labor Supply of Stadium Vendors,"
Journal of Political Economy , 1999, 360-392.
, \Measurement Error and Earnings Dynamics: Some Estimates From
the PSID Validation Study," Journal of Business & Economics Statistics, 1995, 13(3),
305-314.
, \Implicit Contracts: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature, 1985, vol.
23, 1144-1175.
Econometrica , 1997, 557-586.

, \Instrumental Variables with Weak Instruments,"

, \Estimating Life Cycle Labor Supply Tax E ects," Journal
of Political Economy, 1999, 326-359.

Below is the sample selection criteria used
for analysis. Table 8 describes the sample selection criteria that were used. The left hand
side column refers to the selection criteria, the next four columns refer to observations deleted
Appendix A: Sample Selection Criteria

22

from the PSIDVS where R refers to respondent observations and V refers to the validation
(i.e. rm) observation of the individual. The right hand column refers to observations from
the PSID. The initial subsample consisted of all males in the relevant years with hours greater
than zero.
A \-" implies that the sample selection criteria was not used to delete observations. The
only selection criteria used for the validation reports is that they are not missing and that
the rm reports be internally consistent (i.e. that a rm's 1987 report of a worker's 1982
earnings be the same as the 1983 report of the same worker's earnings). I use no other criteria
for the validation reports in the PSIDVS since I have no information on the true measures
of hours and wages in the PSID. For 1983 I delete respondent reports of multiple job holders
because the hours question refers to hours on all jobs, whereas the validation report refers
only to hours worked on the main job. For 1987 the hours question refers to the main job.
Two respondents reported the rm was not their main job.
I also deleted observations where there were earnings and hours assignments (i.e. the
reports were inaccurate). Unfortunately, earnings in 1983 were missing the assignment variable.
Appendix B: Derivation of Estimating Equations

This appendix gives the algebra behind equations (17) and (18). The numerator for the

23

equation for ; equation (17), is25
=
=
=
=
=

=

Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 )
Cov(log h~ it

uhit; log W~ it 1 wit 1)
~ it 1 ) Cov(uhit ; Wit 1 + uwit 1 )
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
Cov(log hit + uhit ; uwit 1 ) + Cov(uhit ; uwit 1 )
~ it 1 ) Cov(uhit ; Wit 1 + uwit 1 )
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
+Cov(log hit + uhit; uwit 1 ) + Cov(uhit; uwit 1 )
~ it 1 ) Cov(uhit ; log Wit 1 )
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
Cov(log hit ; uwit 1 ) Cov(uhit ; uwit 1 )
~ it 1 )
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
Cov(hit (1 h)hit 1 h hit 2 ; log Wit 1 log Wit 2 )
Cov(log hit log hit 1 ; wit 1 (1 w )wit 2 w wit 3 )
Cov(hit (1 h)hit 1 h hit 2 ; wit 1 (1 w )wit 2
~ it 1 ) + (1 2h + hw )Cov(hit ; wit )
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
+Cov(wit ; log hit ) + (1 2h)Cov(hit ; log Wit)

w wit 3 )

(27)

and the denominator of  is
25

Recall that since log hit is a variable with zero mean and log Wit 1 is a variable, Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) =
1 ):

E (log hit log Wit

24

=
=
=
=
=

=

Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 )

~ it
Cov(log W

uwit; log W~ it 1 uwit 1)
~ it ; log W~ it 1 ) Cov(log Wit + uwit; uwit 1 )
Cov(log W
Cov(uwit ; log Wit 1 + uwit 1 ) + Cov(uwit ; uwit 1 )
~ it ; log W~ it 1 ) Cov(log Wit; uwit 1 )
Cov(log W
Cov(uwit ; log Wit 1 ) Cov(uwit ; uwit 1 )
~ it ; log W~ it 1 ) Cov(log Wit; uwit 1 )
Cov(log W
Cov(uwit ; log Wit 1 ) Cov(uwit ; uwit 1 )
~ it ; log W~ it 1 )
Cov(log W
Cov(log Wit log Wit 1 ; wit 1 (1 w )wit 2 w wit 3 )
Cov(wit (1 w )wit 1 w wit 2 ; log Wit 1 log Wit 2 )
Cov(wit (1 w )wit 1 w wit 2 ; wit 1 (1 w )wit 2
~ it ; log W~ it 1 ) + (2 2w )Cov(log Wit; wit ) +
Cov(log W
+(1 2w + w2 )V ar(wit):

w wit 3 )

(28)

Appendix C: Obtaining Standard Errors

This appendix describes the procedure to obtain standard errors for both the rst stage
wage regression and the second stage estimate of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Estimation of both is similar so I focus on estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution for concreteness.
There are several econometric problems in estimating the standard error. First, estimates
of Cov(log h~ it ; log W~ it 1 ) and Cov(log W~ it ; log W~ it 1) come from the PSID whereas
the other objects come from the PSIDVS. Second, the estimate of Cov(log h~ it ; log W~ it 1);
for example, uses several years of data on the same individual, meaning that not all observations are independent of one another. Third, the same individuals are not observed in all
years, making the data unbalanced. The procedure below addresses all three problems.

25

Consider a highly simpli ed version of the problem where


^ =



PNA
PNB
1
i=1 Ai + i=1 Bi
NA +NB
P

PNV
NU
1
U
+
V
i=1 i
i=1 i
NU +NV


= TS

(29)

where Ai and Bi are individual contributions to a covariance, e.g. Ai = log h~ i85 log W~ i84
~ it] and Bi = log h~ i86 log W~ i85 E [log h~ it log W~ it]; and NA; NB ; NC ;
E [log h~ it log W
and ND are the number of observations in covariance A; B; C; and D: Assuming that the
wage and hours
generating process
is stationary,26 I alsoenforce the restriction
that A =
P


P
PNC
P
NA
B = NA +1 NB
Ai + NB Bi and C = D = NC +1 ND
Ci + ND Di as they are
both means of the same object. Embodied in this problem are all three previously mentioned
problems.
Denote NB = NB (NA ); NC = NC (NA); ND = ND (NA ) to indicate that NB ; NC ; ND
are to be viewed as functions of NA: Assume limNA !1 NB (NA) = kB ; limNA!1 NC (NA ) =
kC ; limNA !1 ND (NA ) = kD ; where kB ; kC ; kD are constants. In other words, the number
of observations in each moment condition (A; B; C; D)are all converging toin nity at the
PNA
PNB
same rate. Moreover,
assume
that
plimNA !1 NA +1 NB
i=1 Ai +
i=1 Bi = E (A) and
P

P
N
N
U
V
plimNA !1 NU +1 NV
i=1 Ui + i=1 Vi = E (U ):
Performing a Taylor's series expansion of ^ in equation (29) around  and squaring results
in the delta method. Written in matrix format, the delta method is:
!

@ 0 @
( ^ ) a N 0; ( @m
) W ( @m )

(30)

where m is a covariance, e.g. E (A); and W is the fourth moment matrix of the covariances
@ and W are replaced by their sample
needed to estimate equation (29). In practice, @m
The stationarity assumption is not necessary for estimation of ; but it simpli es the computation of the
standard errors.
26

26

analogs:
0

@ ^
@m


0
B
B
B
^W = B
B
B
B
@

=

B
B
B
B
B
B
@



1
T
1
T
S
T2
S
T2

2 P
NA (A A)2
1
i
 NA +NB 2 Pi=1
NA \NB (A A)(B B )
1
i
i
 NA +NB  i=1  P
NA \NU (A A)(U U )
1
1
i
i
 NA +NB  NU +NV  Pi=1
N
\
N
A V
1
1
i=1 (Ai A)(Vi V )
NA +NB NU +NV

1
C
C
C
C;
C
C
A

(31)



2 P
NA\NB (A A)(B B )
1
i
i
i=1
 NA +NB 2 PN
B (B
1
i B )2
 NA +NB  i=1  P
NB \NU (B B )(U U )
1
1
i
i
 NA +NB  NU +NV  PiN=1\N
B V
1
1
i=1 (Bi B )(Vi V )
NA +NB NU +NV

(32)

^
W

is a symmetric matrix. NA \ NB refers to the number of persons that contributed to both
the Ai covariance and the Bi covariance. Note that if Ai and Ui are from di erent datasets,
NA \ NV = 0. Therefore, if A and B were from one dataset and C and D were from another
dataset, W^ would be a block diagonal matrix. In practice, estimation of ^ and its distribution
is more tedious but no more complicated than what is described in this section. For example,
in the absence of measurement error, equation ^ will have ve objects in the numerator and
ve in the denominator (one for each year of PSID data), meaning that @@m^ is a 10  1 vector
and W^ is a 10  10 matrix.
Appendix D: Derivation of the First Stage Regression

This appendix shows the procedure to control for measurement error in the rst stage
regression (10) as well as the procedure to obtain the relevant rst stage F statistic and
R2 statistic. The procedure to control for measurement error is fundamentally similar to the
procedure used to control for measurement error when estimating  directly. Consider the
case where h=w = 0; but measurement error is correlated with true variables, as in column

27

1

: : C

C
C:
: : C
C
A

: : C
C
: :

3 of Table 6. The regression coeÆcient in the rst stage is
~ it wit; W~ it 1 wit 1)
Wit ; log Wit 1 ) Cov(log W
=
= Cov(log
~ it 1 wit 1)
V ar(log Wit 1 )
V ar(log W
~ it; log W~ it 1 ) + 2Cov(log Wit; wit ) + V ar(wit)
W
= Cov(log
(33)
~ ) 4Cov(log W ;  ) 2V ar( ) :
V ar(log W
it

1

it

wit

wit

Standard errors for are computed using the method described in Appendix C. The t
statistic is divided by its standard error. The F statistic is the square of the t statistic:
The R2 is the explained sum of squares divided by the total sum of squares. An appendix
available from the author describes the potential small sample bias in this problem. If the
series log Wit is stationary, then the R2 is
PN
(^log Wit)2
2
R = PNi=1
2
i=1 (log Wit+1 )

28

 ^2:

(34)

Object of Interest
Cov(log hit ; wit )
(1 + hw )Cov(hit ; wit)
Cov(log Wit ; hit )
Cov(log Wit ; wit )
(1 + w2 )V ar(wit)
w (Cov(log Wit ; wit ) + V ar(wit ))

Data Used to Estimate Object of Interest
Cov(log hit ; uwit ) Cov(log hit ; uwit+k ); jkj > 1
Cov(uhit ; uwit ) Cov(uhit ; uwit+k ); jkj > 1
Cov(log Wit ; uhit ) Cov(log Wit ; uhit+k ); jkj > 1
Cov(log Wit ; uwit ) Cov(log Wit ; uwit+k ); jkj > 1
V ar(uwit ) Cov(uwit ; uwit+k ); jkj > 1
(A1) 0
(A2) Cov(log W~it ; log Wit~ 2 )
h(Cov(log Wit ; hit ) + Cov(wit ; hit )) (A1) 0
(A2) Cov(log h~it ; log Wit~ 2 )
The rst ve identi cation restrictions are derived using the assumptions in Section 2.3
(A1) and (A2) are only necessary for identifying the last two objects of interest
(A1) is the set of assumptions that lead to estimating equations (21) and (22)
(A2) is the set of assumptions that lead to estimating equations (23) and (24)
Table 1: Properties of Transitory Measurement Error

29

Means and Standard Deviations of Variables, PSID and PSIDVS
Variable
PSID, all PSID, hourly PSIDVS
Age
38.9 (10.6) 37.9 (10.9) 45.9 (16.0)
At Least High School Grad? .84 (.37)
.73 (.44)
.65 (.35)
College Grad?
.30 (.44)
.07 (.26)
.12 (.33)
Tenure
9.5 (8.9)
8.9 (8.7)
15.1 (11.8)
log Reported Wage
2.50 (.55) 2.40 (.46)
2.90 (.19)
log Reported Hours
7.66 (.29) 7.60 (.27)
7.59 (.19)
log True Wage
2.92 (.11)
log True Hours
7.57 (.21)
N = 14; 920 N = 5; 521
N = 544
Table 2: Descriptive Statistics, PSID (1980-1986) and PSIDVS (1982, 1986)

30

Dependent Variable: log hit
log Wit
Estimate (S.E.) Estimate (S.E.)
Intercept
.064 (.18)
.018 (.22)
Age
-.050 (.013)
.0028 (.0165)
Age Squared
.0013 (.0003)
-.00014 (.00039)
Age Cubed
:000011(:000002) :0000014(:0000030)
College Grad
.045 (.006)
.025 (.0007)
High School
.040 (.007)
-.0005 (.0087)
Health Change
-.017 (.009)
-.052 (.012)
Year Dummies also included
R2
.0111
.0055
F Statistic
11.1
5.31
N
11,869
11,539
Table 3: OLS regressions for wage and hours changes, PSID, 1980-1987

31

All Workers
~
~
~ it; log W~ it 1 ) -.0366 (.0028)
Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 ) .0090 (.0015) Cov(log W
~ it 2 ) .0013 (.0014) Cov(log W~ it; log W~ it 2 ) -.0009(.0014)
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
Hourly Workers
~ it 1 ) .0082 (.0026) Cov(log W~ it; log W~ it 1 ) -.0324 (.0043)
Cov(log h~ it ; log W
~ it 2 ) .0021 (.0026) Cov(log W~ it; log W~ it 2 ) -.0005(.0024)
Cov(log ~hit ; log W
Table 4: Covariance of Hours and Wage Changes with Lagged Wage Changes, PSID, 19801986

32

Covariances of Measurement Error
Estimate (S.E.)
Cov(log Wi82 ; uhi82 ) .0049 (.0016)
Cov(log Wi86 ; uhi86 ) -.0009 (.0006)
Cov(log Wi82 ; uhi86 ) -.0044 (.0014)
Cov(log Wi86 ; uhi82 ) .0018 (.0013)
Cov(log hi82 ; uwi82 ) .0022 (.0051)
Cov(log hi86 ; uwi86 ) .0003 (.0021)
Cov(log hi82 ; uwi86 ) .0027 (.0027)
Cov(log hi86 ; uwi82 ) .0018 (.0021)
Cov(uhi82 ; uwi82 )
-.0202 (.0059)
Cov(uhi86 ; uwi86 )
-.0097 (.0025)
Cov(uhi82 ; uwi86 )
-.0018 (.0016)
Cov(uhi86 ; uwi82 )
.0001 (.0018)
Cov(log Wi82 ; uwi82 ) -.0051 (.0021)
Cov(log Wi86 ; uwi86 ) .0005 (.0007)
Cov(log Wi82 ; uwi86 ) .0028 (.0013)
Cov(log Wi86 ; uwi82 ) -.0032 (.0020)
V ar(uwi82 )
.0323 (.0075)
V ar(uwi86 )
.0172 (.0026)
Cov(uwi82 ; uwi86 )
.0023 (.0022)
Table 5: Covariances, PSIDVS

33

N

128
292
118
89
121
277
112
85
121
277
81
83
121
277
112
85
121
277
79

Measurement Error Specification (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Any measurement error?
no
yes
yes
yes
Correlated with true variables?
no
no
yes
yes
Includes MA(1) component?
no
no
no
yes
All Workers
First Stage Estimates
-.36 (.02) -.26 (.06) -.29 (.05) -.31 (.05)
F stat
522
18.6
39.1
47.9
R2
.128
.067
.085
.096
Second Stage Estimates
Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 )
.0090
-.0025
-.0021
.0005
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 )
-.0366
-.0156
-.0203
-.0221
 intertemporal
elasticity of substitution
-.25 (.04) .16 (.27) .10 (.26) -.02 (.23)
Hourly Workers
First Stage Estimates
-.38 (.03) -.26 (.08) -.30 (.07) -.32 (.07)
F stat
152
9.8
21.9
22.1
R2
.144
.069
.093
.101
Second Stage Estimates
Cov(log hit ; log Wit 1 )
.0082
-.0033
-.0029
.0013
Cov(log Wit ; log Wit 1 )
-.0324
-.0114
-.0162
-.0172
 intertemporal
elasticity of substitution
-.25 (.08) .29 (.40) .18 (.33) -.08 (.32)
Standard errors in parentheses
~ it 1 )
Cov( log h~ it ;log W
Column (1):  = Cov
( log W~ it ;log W~ it 1 )
~ it 1 )+Cov(uhit ;uwit )
W
Column (2):  = CovCov((loglogh~ itW~;log
~ it 1 )+V ar(uwit )
;
log
W
it
Column (3): ratio of equation (21) to equation (22)
Column (4): ratio of equation (23) to equation (24)
Table 6: Estimates of the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution Under Di erent Measurement Error Assumptions, 1981-1987 PSID, 1982, 1986 PSIDVS

34

35

(2)
All
log W~ it

2

-.0004
.0002
-2.0 (3.9)

.0003
-.0013
-.23 (.48)

-.03 (.15)

.0002
-.0064

34.16
.0026
13193

.06 (.25)

-.0002
-.0035

13.2
.0010
13193

.25
.0000
9874

2

(7)
Hourly
log W_ it

3.2
.0009
9874

2

(6)
Hourly
log W~ it

.010 (.019) -.033 (.005) -.023 (.006)

2

(5)
Hourly
 log W_ it

-.20 (.011)

(4)
Hourly
 log W~ it

Table 7: Estimates of the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution Under Di erent Instrument Sets, PSID 1969-1996

Second Stage Estimates, Dependent Variable is

First Stage Estimates, Dependent Variable is

(1)
All
 log W~ it

(3)
Hourly
 log W_ it 1 ;
2
2
log W_ it 1
 log W~ it
-.023 (.006) -.037 (.003) .014(.017),
-.036 (.007)
F stat
15.4
127.7
12.8
R2
.0005
.0035
.0022
N
31620
36331
11706
 log h~ it
Cov ( log ~hit ; instrument)
.00019
.0010
~ it ; instrument) -.00222
Cov ( log W
-.0104
intertemporal elasticity of substitution

-.18(.18)
-.10(.06)
.18(.19)
~
First stage regression: Wit = Æ + instrument + it
Standard errors in parentheses

Group
Instrument

Criterion for Deletion
Initial observations
Hours < 500 or Hours > 4500
Age < 25 or age > 65
Hours were assigned
Multiple job holders
Firm is not main job
Remaining observations
Earnings missing
Wages < $3 or > $100 (1987 dollars)
Earnings accuracy
1987 Validation data di erent
from 1983 Validation data
Missing education or health
Remaining observations
Hours

Wages

1983 (R)
339
3
4
50
23
259
7
0
245

1983 (V)
173
0
173
0
1
172

Table 8: Sample Selection

36

1987 (R)
449
1
10
9
2
427
0
0
28
399

1987 (V)
296
3
293
0
293

PSID
19160
793
2130
476
15761
0
569
258
14
14920