View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series
,11111Wifi iiilli™iIIII§«lf III! •
!!fl!!l!l||ll!illll
is



Does The Japanese Stock Market Price
Bank Risk? Evidence from Financial
Firm Failures

Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt
Hunter and George G. Kaufman

Working Papers Series
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
December 1999 (W P -99-31)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
O F CHICAGO

DOES THE JAPANESE STOCK MARKET PRICE BANK RISK?
EVIDENCE FROM FINANCIAL FIRM FAILURES

Elijah Brewer HI*
Hesna Genay*
William Curt Hunter*
George G. Kaufman**

December 1999

* Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
** Loyola University Chicago and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Corresponding author: Hesna Genay, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Research, 230
S. LaSalle Street, Chicago, IL 60604. hgenav@frbchi.org.
The research assistance of Scott Briggs, Kenneth Housinger, George Simler, and Alex Urbina is
greatly appreciated. The authors also would like to thank Anil Kashyap, participants at the The
Sixth Annual Global Finance Conference, The Thirty-Fifth Annual Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition, and 1999 FMA Meetings for valuable comments, and Rieko
McCarthy of Moody’s Investor Services for the information she so kindly provided. The views
expressed here are those of the authors and do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve
System.




ABSTRACT
The efficiency of Japanese stock market to appropriately price the riskiness of Japanese
firms has been frequently questioned, particularly with respect to Japanese banks which have
experienced severe financial distress in recent years. This paper examines the response in the
stock market returns of Japanese commercial banks to the failure of four commercial banks and
two securities firms between 1995 and 1998. The analysis finds that the stock market responded
to new information of the failures and did so rationally. Financially weaker banks were affected
more adversely by the failure of other banks and financial institutions than were healthier banks.
This suggests that the Japanese stock market is more efficient, even for banks, than often
perceived.




DOES THE JAPANESE STOCK MARKET PRICE BANK RISK?
EVIDENCE FROM FINANCIAL FIRM FAILURES

I.

Introduction
Efficient financial markets promote aggregate economic welfare by allocating financial

resources to their most potentially productive uses as signaled by market prices. Numerous
studies have explored the efficiency of financial markets in the U.S. and other countries. At least
for the U.S., the evidence suggests that markets have priced securities reasonably well on the
basis of their underlying risk characteristics, particularly where this information is publicly
available. A large number of studies have focused on the U.S. banking sector, which experienced
severe financial difficulties during the 1980s. In particular, these studies have examined whether
the U.S. stock market was able to differentiate among individual institutions with different
financial and risk profiles, incorporate new information in the prices of securities quickly and
fully, and adjust for the effects of regulatory influences, such as explicit or implicit federal
government provided guarantees on some or all of the liabilities of the institutions. On the whole,
the evidence suggests that the U.S. market performed all these tasks reasonably efficiently for
banks and other industries.1

1For example, see Aharony and Swary (1983), Binder (1985a, 1985b), Brewer and Jackson
(1998), Cornell and Shapiro (1986), Cornett and Tehranian (1989,1990), Karafiath and Glascock
(1989), Karafiath, Mynatt, and Smith (1991), Madura and Bartunek (1994), Millon-Comett and
Tehranian (1989, 1990), Peterson and Wall (1991), Schwert (1981), Swary (1986), and Wall and
Peterson (1990). See Flannery (1998) for a discussion of this literature.




At about the same time as the U. S. banking system started to recover during the early
1990s, the Japanese banking system started to deteriorate. By the late 1990s, many of the larger
Japanese banks appeared to be market value insolvent and most of the others barely solvent. In
1998, nonperforming loans at Japanese banks were estimated to be as high as $1 trillion or 20
percent of their on-balance sheet assets and considerably higher at some institutions. Only liberal
accounting treatment permitted most Japanese banks to satisfy the Basle capital standards and
only conjectural government guarantees permitted most major banks to continue to operate
without depositor runs. However, despite the favorable accounting treatment and government
guarantees, Japanese financial institutions continued to suffer severe liquidity problems in the
interbank markets and several had to be rescued or closed in recent years. At the same time and
in response to the problems, the stance of the Japanese regulators towards banking problems and
their resolution strategies underwent significant changes. In short, Japanese financial institutions
experienced fundamental shifts in their operating environment during the 1990s. In light of these
events and the ongoing attempt by the Japanese government to resolve the insolvencies and
restructure and recapitalize the banking system, it is of considerable interest to explore whether
the Japanese stock market was able to price the securities of Japanese banks efficiently and
provide market signals to bank management.
It is often argued that the Japanese capital markets are not as efficient as those in the
United States due to differences in regulatory, institutional, accounting, and disclosure practices.
For instance, until 1993, Japanese banks did not report the amount of nonperforming loans in
their portfolios and it was not until 1998 that they reported nonperforming loans by U.S.
standards. The lack of extensive information on bank asset quality is an obvious impediment to




2

investors’ ability to assess and compare the condition of banks. In addition, extensive stable
cross-shareholdings among firms, particularly between banks and commercial firms, is a wellknown feature of Japanese markets. Because these shareholders hold large blocks of shares and
have other ties with Japanese banks, their motivations, and hence their responses, may differ
from those of shareholders in the U.S. In addition, Japanese regulators have relied as much on
implicit administrative guidance as on explicit regulation of banks; have been reluctant to let
financial institutions fail; and have been closely associated with the banks they regulate both
during and after their tenure in office. As a result of these differences, actions taken by regulators
in response to changes in bank risk, and the investors’ responses to regulatory actions, may differ
in the two countries.
More recently, however, a number of studies have developed evidence suggesting that
Japanese financial markets do, on the whole, price shares efficiently.

Peek and Rosengren

(1999) found that the interest rates charged large Japanese banks in the international interbank
loan markets responded in the expected direction to a number of financial and regulatory events,
including the failures of Japanese financial institutions. Bremer and Pettway (1999) found that
the Japanese stock market anticipated the rating downgrades of Japanese banks, and Chiou
(1999) reported that Japanese affiliates of Daiwa Bank suffered negative excess returns following
the announcement of Daiwa’s trading scandal in 1995. Lastly, Yamori (1999) reported that the
failure of the Hyogo Bank in 1995 had a negative impact on the excess returns of the banking
industry and, in particular, of banks in weaker financial condition.
This study expands Yamori’s analysis to examine the impact of the failure of six Japanese
financial institutions — four banks and two securities firms - between 1995 and 1998 on the




3

market valuation of surviving Japanese banks. These failures were likely to signal additional
information to investors about the financial state of the Japanese banking industry and the
potential responses by the Japanese regulators. Our results indicate that shareholders interpreted
the events as significant adverse changes in the risk environment of the surviving banks and that
they were able to differentiate among banks when assessing the impact of the events on equity
values. These results add to the growing body of evidence which suggests that Japanese investors
incorporate news regarding changes in bank risk quickly and efficiently.
II.

The Failures/Nationalizations
The six financial failures examined in this paper are watershed events in the postwar

Japanese financial markets. The details of the events surrounding these failures are described
below.
A . H y o g o B ank (A u gu st 3 1 ,1 9 9 5 )

At the close of business on August 30, 1995, Hyogo Bank became the first commercial
bank in Japan to fail since the end of World War n. At the time of its resolution, Hyogo Bank, a
mid-sized regional bank with ¥3.75 trillion ($37 billion) in total assets, had ¥1.5 trillion ($14.75
billion) or 40 percent of its assets invested in mostly real-estate related problem loans (see
McGill, 1995).2’3 The resolution of Hyogo Bank represented the first, albeit small, departure from

2 On the same day the Hyogo Bank closure was announced, the Osaka government announced
that Kizu Credit Cooperative would suspend its operations. Although Kizu was Japan’s largest
credit union, it was much smaller than Hyogo Bank (Kizu Credit Cooperative had ¥9 billion in
total assets as of March 31, 1995 versus over ¥3.7 trillion in Hyogo Bank’s total assets). The
closure of Kizu followed several days of depositor runs on the institution and the assisted
mergers of several other credit unions in previous years. Therefore, the market impact from the
Hyogo announcement is likely to dominate the impact from the Kizu announcement and, at
minimum, reinforce it in the same direction.
3 All yen figures are converted to dollars at the time the yen figures were reported. Japanese




the traditional Japanese "convoy system." Under this system, regulators would encourage strong
banks to merge with the weak institutions in return for favorable regulatory treatment.
Depositors, other creditors, and in most instances shareholders, of the insolvent bank would
suffer no losses. In Hyogo Bank’s case, all deposits (including those above the

d e ju r e

¥10

million per depositor insurance limit in effect at the time) were protected and paid out. However,
the payments to the depositors depleted the existing reserves of the government operated Deposit
Insurance Corporation (DIC) and insurance premiums had to be raised subsequently. Importantly,
unlike previous failures, losses were imposed on shareholders and nondeposit creditors of the
bank. But, the largest creditors and shareholders of Hyogo Bank, who were primarily other
financial institutions —including all three large long-term credit banks, two large city banks, and
several trust banks —were encouraged by the government to provide the funds necessary to
capitalize a newly-formed bank that would eventually take over Hyogo's operations. Therefore,
the resolution of Hyogo Bank did not differ substantially from the traditional convoy system.
At the time of Hyogo's failure, the Ministry of Finance announced that it would not
permit any of the country's largest 20 banks to fail before the year 2000 (Reuters News Agency,
October 24, 1995). Nevertheless, two years later in 1997, three major institutions failed —Sanyo
Securities, Hokkaido Takushoku Bank, and Yamaichi Securities.

banks are generally divided into four broad categories —city, trust, long-term credit, and regional
—according to both size and type of business. Historically, the four types of banks have differed
in their size, composition of assets and loans, customer base, funding sources, and regulatory
requirements and treatment. Long-term credit and city banks were the larger banks and trust
banks the most specialized. Although, over time, deregulation and increased competition among
financial institutions have blurred the lines separating the business activities of Japanese banks,
in the periods under observation these banks still maintained their traditional characteristics.
Genay (1998) documents some of the differences in the operations of city, regional, long-term
credit, and trust banks.




5

B. S a n yo S e c u ritie s (N o vem b e r 4, 1 9 9 7 )

Sanyo Securities, a relatively small institution, filed for court protection from creditors on
November 4, 1997. This was the first failure of a securities firm in the postwar era and had a
significant impact on the financial markets. Despite its small size, Sanyo’s default on its
liabilities in the short-term money market appeared to signal that the problems in the financial
sector were greater than widely perceived, and caused a number of other financial institutions to
experience liquidity difficulties, including both Hokkaido Takushoku Bank and Yamaichi
Securities.
C. H o k k a id o Takushoku B an k (N o v e m b e r 17, 1 9 9 7 )

On November 17,1997, the Hokkaido Takushoku Bank Ltd. announced that, due to its
difficulties in raising funds, it would transfer its operations in the Hokkaido region in northern
Japan to the North Pacific Bank. Its operations outside of Hokkaido were eventually sold to
Chuo Trust and Banking Co. Hokkaido Takushoku Bank was the smallest city bank, but one of
the largest 20 commercial banks in Japan, with more than ¥9.5 trillion ($76.7 billion) in assets.
The bank’s bad loans were sold to the Deposit Insurance Corporation, and the Bank of Japan
extended emergency loans to the bank during the transition period. The problems of the bank
were well-known, and its closure followed an aborted government-sanctioned merger attempt
with the nearby Hokkaido Bank.4

4 News articles reported that depositors began to withdraw funds from the bank after it was
announced that the planned merger with Hokkaido Bank would not happen. News reports also
noted that many of the large stakeholders, e.g., the life insurance companies, refused to inject
additional funds into the bank’s capital base in the weeks leading up to its closure. The bank’s
share price, which was ¥222 at the beginning of 1997, had dropped to ¥65 the day before the
failure announcement on November 17, 1997. The day after the announcement, shareholders
could only receive ¥5 per share.




6

D. Y am aichi Securities (N ovem ber 24, 1997)

In the days following Hokkaido Takushoku’s failure, the Japanese financial markets
experienced significant turbulence. Despite the large amount of liquidity provided to the markets
by the Bank of Japan, domestic credit lines to weak companies were cut further and share prices
of financial institutions dropped significantly.

Yamaichi Securities, one of the four largest

security houses, was among the institutions that suffered the most. Its share price dropped
sharply, as indications mounted that it was facing a severe liquidity crisis. On November 20,
1997, the company announced that it had asked Fuji Bank, its main creditor and close affiliate, to
provide the necessary financial support to ease its liquidity needs and to recapitalize the
company. This announcement provided a temporary reprieve to the company. However, in the
days following, it became apparent that Fuji was unwilling to provide this support. Following
Moody’s downgrade of Yamaichi bonds to junk bond status, the Yamaichi board held an
emergency meeting over the weekend of November 22, 1997. On Monday, November 24, 1997,
the company announced that it would close.
At the time, the failures of Hokkaido Takushoku Bank Ltd. and Yamaichi Securities were
viewed by many market participants as the end of the traditional "convoy system" and the
beginning of a new era in Japanese financial history. The regulators had allowed two large
institutions to fail. The Bank of Japan and the Deposit Insurance Corporation provided funds to
ensure the liquidity of the markets and protect senior creditors and clients of the institutions, but
shareholders were not rescued. The two failures were taken as a signal that the regulatory
authorities — the Ministry of Finance (MoF) and the Bank of Japan — were taking stronger
actions to resolve insolvent institutions than they had up to that time in order to slow the rapidly




7

spiraling costs of the insolvencies to both other banks and the taxpayers.
E. L o n g -T erm C re d it B an k o f J a p a n Ltd. (O c to b e r 23, 1 9 9 8 )

Following the three failures in November 1997, the government began to inject public
funds into banks to assist in their recapitalization. By March 1998, the government had injected a
total of ¥1.8 trillion (approximately $13.5 billion) into major banks. Among the banks receiving
government funds were the Long-Term Credit Bank of Japan, Ltd. (LTCB) and the Nippon
Credit Bank (NCB) —two very large banks widely perceived to be in serious financial trouble.
The debt of Long-Term Credit Bank was downgraded several times and its share price dropped
sharply in the first half of 1998. The declines in LTCB's share price came to a halt on June 26,
1998, when it announced that it was in merger talks with Sumitomo Trust Bank, a trust bank in
stronger financial condition. However, the president of Sumitomo Trust Bank made it clear that
the merger would proceed only after an inspection of LTCB's assets. Sumitomo Trust would not
assume the bad loans at LTCB's non-bank affiliates, and expected government assistance to fund
the merger. Market participants interpreted the proposed merger as a return to the traditional
convoy system, where a weak bank was merging with a stronger bank with government
assistance. The merger announcement, however, was not sufficient to bring a turnaround at the
bank.
In the following months, LTCB experienced several further downgrades of its debt and
announced a major restructuring plan at the end of August.

At the same time, the newly-

established Financial Supervisory Agency (FSA) began the inspection of LTCB's assets5. In
addition, the use of public funds to support the merger of Sumitomo Trust and LTCB became a

5 The Financial Supervisory Agency, which assumed supervisory responsibilities for financial




8

major point of contention between the ruling Liberal Democratic Party and the opposition parties.

On October 19 1998, news reports indicated that the FSA had informed LTCB earlier in the day
that the bank was insolvent on a market-value basis as of the end of September, when it was last
inspected. The reports also indicated that LTCB was expected to be nationalized later in the
week, when recently adopted banking legislation would take effect.*6 Four days later on October
23, 1998, LTCB applied for nationalization. The government announced that it would guarantee
all obligations of LTCB, the DIC would purchase the bank's shares (last traded at ¥2), and the
Bank of Japan would provide financial aid to LTCB as necessary to maintain liquidity in
financial markets. According to the FSA report, at the end of September, the bank had ¥160
billion in book-value capital, total assets of ¥24 trillion, ¥500 billion in latent losses on its
securities portfolio, and problem assets totaling ¥4.62 trillion, or 19 percent. These losses were
greater than the bank’s reported capital.
F. N ip p o n C r e d it B an k L td. (D e c e m b e r 13, 1 9 9 8 )

The semi-annual public financial statements issued by Japanese banks on November 24,
1998 for the six months ending September 30 showed that another large long-term credit bank —
the Nippon Credit Bank (NCB), with assets of ¥7.7 trillion as of September 1998 — had
significant amounts of problem loans and that its earnings had deteriorated significantly since
March 1998. However, the bank stated that it was still solvent. On December 9, 1998, it was
announced that NCB and Chuo Trust and Banking Co. were abandoning their previously
institutions from the Ministry of Finance, was established on June 22, 1998.
6 The package of eight bills approved by the parliament on October 12, 1998 was aimed at
resolving the bad loans of Japanese banks and dealing with the failure of financial institutions.
The legislation allowed for recapitalization of banks with public funds and created the Financial
Reconstruction Commission (FRC), to, among other duties, administer nationalized insolvent




9

announced merger and would form a looser alliance instead. The abandoned merger plan was
perceived as a sign of further problems at NCB. Shortly thereafter, news reports indicated that
the FSA’s examination of the bank showed that as of March 31, 1998, contrary to what NCB had
reported, the bank had a capital deficit of ¥94.4 billion and was insolvent. On December 12, the
government urged Nippon Credit to apply for nationalization, which it did on the next business
day —December 14. The government provided assurances that the repayment of all of NCB's
obligations would be made in full and on time and that the Bank of Japan would provide loans to
ensure the liquidity of the markets.
III.

Implications of the Failures
These failures reflect significant shifts in Japanese regulation of financial institutions and

markets. First, the three sets of failures - the Hyogo Bank failure in 1995, the three failures in
November 1997, and the two nationalizations in 1998 —indicate a shift in Japanese insolvency
resolution policy. In the Hyogo failure, regulators let a commercial bank fail and allowed losses
to shareholders. The three failures in November 1997 showed the market participants that size
was no longer an insurance against failure or closure. The two nationalizations in 1998 followed
a year of frequent changes in the regulators' approach to nonperforming loans and a prolonged
debate on the use of government funds to clean up the banking problems. The newly created
FSA was given the mandate to resolve the banking sector problems. Hakuo Yanagisawa,
Chairman of the Financial Reconstruction Commission, stated that the nationalization of the two
long-tem credit banks "demonstrate that the bank regulatory environment in Japan has
dramatically changed, and that the government will begin imposing rigorous standards on banks

institutions.




10

to try to win the confidence of financial markets."

(The W ash ington P o st,

December 14, 1998)

In addition, each of the six failures revealed that the amount of bad loans and valuation
losses previously disclosed by the banks had been significantly understated and concealed the
extent of the banks’ problems. Two months prior to its collapse, Hyogo Bank had reported bad
loans amounting to 2.2% of its loan portfolio. The Ministry of Finance later revealed that the
bank’s losses had actually totaled 55.5% of total loans

(A m erican B an ker,

April 12, 1995, p. 38).

The bad loans at Hokkaido Takushoku Bank were actually three times the amount stated in its
last financial statement. At the time of its failure, Yamaichi Securities revealed that it had ¥264.8
billion off-balance sheet losses that were previously undisclosed. In September 1998, shortly
after a Bank of Japan inspection gave LTCB a clean bill of health and indicated that the bank was
solvent as of March 1998, the FSA revealed that the bank was insolvent when assets were valued
at market value. Three months later in December 1998, the FSA determined that NCB had also
been insolvent as of March 31,1998.
Table 1 compares the financial condition and performance of the three failed banks to the
surviving banks using data published in the banks' last full-year financial statements.7 It is
apparent that the failed banks had much lower reported earnings and asset quality than the
surviving banks. The reported capital ratios were not lower, however.

This reflected their

dramatic understating of loan losses and other losses. Similarly, although not shown, Sanyo
Securities had lower capital ratios and Yamaichi Securities had lower earnings than their
competitors.

In the twelve months leading up to their failure, the three banks also had lower

stock market returns than the surviving banks. Although table 1 highlights the weak condition of

Because the financial statements of Hyogo Bank were not available to us, we cannot compare




11

the failed institutions relative to the average surviving bank in the period before their failure, the
three failed institutions were not the worst ones. At the time of each failure, there were banks that
were in worse financial condition, even by the optimistic numbers reported by banks.
Lastly, the six failures revealed a significant change in the institutional and support
structure of Japanese financial institutions. Traditionally, weak or troubled institutions could rely
on implicit and explicit government support, capital injections and new loans from financially or
otherwise affiliated companies, or rescue mergers with a stronger firm. In five of the six failures,
there were attempts to rescue the failed institutions through traditional methods, i.e. financial
assistance from affiliated healthy firms.

For various reasons, these attempts failed and the

financial institutions were resolved soon after. The Hokkaido Takushoku Bank failed when its
planned merger with Hokkaido Bank, another, smaller institution in Hokkaido, was abandoned.
In October 1998, a month before the failure of Sanyo Securities, the government had trieu 10
persuade other companies to provide financial support. However, the requested support did not
come through.

Similarly, Fuji Bank refused to provide support to its affiliate Yamaichi

Securities before its failure.

As noted above, a regulator sanctioned and supported merger

between LTCB and Sumitomo Trust failed to materialize and NCB and Chuo Trust and Banking
Co. abandoned their planned merger a few days before NCB’s nationalization.
Both the six failures per se and the changes in regulatory practices that resulted in the
official recognition of insolvencies represented important new information for investors in
Japanese banks. If Japanese bank shares were priced efficiently, then this new information should
have been reflected in share prices quickly and completely. However, the actual price response

Hyogo’s financial condition to surviving banks.




12

of individual banks to these events could be ambiguous and difficult to predict. On the one hand,
the failures could have revealed previously undisclosed or understated problems in the banking
system and increaed operating and regulatory costs for the surviving banks.

If investors

perceived an increase in risk of the banking system, the cost of funds for surviving institutions
could increase significantly, eroding their profits and capital. Banks who were perceived to be
similarly insolvent could be seen as the next victims of the regulatory agencies’ resolution
process, or could face increased surveillance and various regulatory actions to restrict their
O

activities. Therefore, the failure announcements could have had a significant negative impact on
the share prices of surviving institutions

(th e n e g a tiv e reva lu a tio n h yp o th esis).

On the other hand, investors could perceive the failures as positive signals for the
industry. If uncertainty regarding the condition of the banking system or regulators’ failure to
resolve insolvencies imposed additional costs on financially strong banks, the resolution of the
uncertainty or a stronger regulatory posture could benefit surviving institutions. The exit by
failure of weak firms may improve the competitive conditions for surviving banks (Lang and
Stulz, 1992; and Kaufman, 1994). In such cases, we would expect a positive share price reaction
to the failure announcements (the p o s itiv e

reva lu a tio n h yp o th esis).

Moreover, if investors could differentiate between weak and strong banks, we would
expect their reaction to events to differ across banks. In particular, we would expect the share
prices of stronger banks to react less negatively to perceived adverse news and more positively to
perceived positive news than those of weaker banks. Such response was observed for U.S. banks
and thrifts during the crisis of the 1980s (Brewer, 1995; Lang and Stulz, 1992). However, the

8 See Grammatikos and Saunders (1990) for a discussion of this point.




13

ability of the market to differentiate among banks is affected by the quality and timeliness of the
information that is publicly disclosed about these institutions. The less accurate, precise, or
timely the information, the less likely are security prices to fully reflect the actual financial and
risk characteristics of the banks. Thus, even if the failures revealed new information and had a
significant impact on the banking sector, their impact on individual bank share prices may still
not be highly correlated with the reported condition of the banks

(th e p u r e o r n o n in fo rm a tio n a l

co n ta g io n h yp o th esis).

Alternatively, the failure announcements could have been anticipated by market
participants or viewed as having no impact on the operations of other banks. In such cases, we
would expect no significant effect on the share prices of surviving banks as a result of the
announcements (the

irrele va n ce h y p o th e sis).

In the remainder of the paper, we examine whether and how these events were viewed by
the shareholders of surviving banks and test the four hypothesis of market response stated above.
More specifically, we examine the stock market reaction to announcements regarding the
resolution of the six institutions.
IV.

Data and methodology
Our empirical methodology closely follows the methodology widely used in papers

examining the response of stock prices to announcements that may be expected to provide
additional information about the financial condition of the issuers of the securities and changes in
the regulatory environment (e.g. Binder, 1998; and MacKinlay, 1997). The stock returns of each
surviving bank were examined to identify any abnormal performance on or around the
announcement of the six events.




The impact of the events was estimated by employing a
14

multivariate regression model, similar to that used in Binder (1985a, 1985b, 1988), Karafiath
(1988), Karafiath and Glascock (1989), Karafiath, Mynatt, and Smith (1991), Malatesta (1986),
Millon-Comett and Tehranian (1989), and Schipper and Thompson (1983). For each event, the
baseline model takes the following form:
1+2
X

R it = ° i +

2
P i s R ms

s = t-2

where

Rit is

the stock return of bank i on day t;

market index for day s ( s 6 [t - 2, t + 2]);
D k is

fiis is

+ X

Y > kD k

+

(1)

£ u,

k --2

at

is the intercept coefficient for bank v,

R m is

the

the market risk coefficient for bank i on day s;

a binary variable that captures the impact of an event, and equals 1 if day t is equal to the

event day k ( k e [-2,2]), zero otherwise;

y ik is

the event coefficient for bank i; and

e it is

a

random error term which is assumed to be i.i.d. normal and independent of the market return and
the binary variables. Equation (1) was estimated separately for each bank. The estimated
parameters

Yik

capture daily intercept shifts in the interval from day -2 to day +2 returns

associated with a failure announcement on day 0 and is an estimate of the excess return.
The announcement dates of the failures were obtained through a search of th e
J o u rn a l,

W all S tr e e t

Reuters news wire, Newscast news service, and from the Knight Ridder business wire.

All wire services that were searched included news articles from Japanese and other international
news sources. If an announcement was made after the market was closed or over the weekend,
we used the next trading date as event date 0. Consequently, event days for each of the six
failures were defined as: August 31, 1995 for Hyogo Bank; November 4, 1997 for Sanyo
Securities; November 17, 1997 for Hokkaido Takushoku Bank; November 25, 1997 for




15

Yamaichi Securities; October 19, 1998 for the Long-Term Credit Bank; and December 14, 1998
for Nippon Credit Bank.9
Daily stock prices and returns were obtained for more than 100 banks from Bloomberg
and the University of Rhode Island’s Pacific Basin Capital Markets Research Center (PACAP)
1998 database. The P A C A P series on stock prices adjusts for dividends and stock splits, whereas
Bloomberg does not. At the time of this analysis, P A C A P data were not available for 1998,
when the LTCB and N C B were nationalized. However, we statistically analyzed the P A C A P and
Bloomberg daily series for the 1990-1997 period and for each of the four failures in 1995 and
1997, and found a high degree of correlation. Thus, we use the P A C A P daily stock returns for
the first four events, and daily returns computed from closing prices provided by Bloomberg for
each of the two events in 1998.
Market returns are measured by the TOPIX index, which includes seasoned shares of
major companies (First Section) traded on the Tokyo Stock Exchange and is weighted by the
number of shares listed. W e specify the market return at several leads and lags as an explanatory
variable to correct for the possibility of nonsynchronous trading, especially for some of the
smaller banks in the sample (Scholes and Williams, 1977).
A potential problem with event study analyses of stock returns is that the event itself
could cause a structural change in the parameters of the market model. Kane and Unal (1988)
note that changes in the parameters of the market model may significantly affect the results of
studies focusing on time series as well as the cross-sectional responses to a given event or a set of
chronologically close events. To minimize this problem, we used different estimation periods to

9 Although the LTCB was officially nationalized on October 23, 1998, the first official news of




16

determine the stock market reactions to each failure announcement. However, because the three
failures in 1997 and the two nationalizations in 1998 were clustered together, we grouped all
events in each of these two years together. The estimation periods for the three sets of events
are: a 225-trading-day period from November 8, 1994 through October 2, 1995 for the Hyogo
Bank announcement; a 225-trading-day period from January 30, 1997 through December 29,
1997 for the announcements of Sanyo Securities, Hokkaido Takushoku Bank Ltd., and Yamaichi
Securities; and a 285-trading-day period from November 19, 1998 through January 19, 1999 for
the nationalization of the Long Term Credit Bank of Japan Ltd. and Nippon Credit Bank Ltd. To
analyze the impact of 1997 and 1998 announcements, we modify equation (1) as follows:
t+2
Ru

=«,+£
e

where

e

X

2
P A sK s

+X

s=t-2

is the number of events in 1997

e

(e

X

Y ik,'D k,e

+ £*,

d ’)

k--2

=3) or 1998

(e

=2). P is an indicator variable that

identifies post-event periods within each estimation period and allows the market risk coeficient,
,to shift after each event. For instance, during the 1998 estimation period, P i is equal to 1 for
the period between the nationalizations of LTCB and NCB, zero otherwise; and P 2 is equal to 1
for the period following the nationalization of NCB, zero otherwise. The omitted period is preLTCB nationalization.

P

is defined analogously for the 1997 estimation period.

The analysis proceeds in two parts. In the first part, we examine the distribution of
individual banks’ excess returns for each event. If the failures have unanticipated implications
for the banking industry, we would expect the stock returns of the sector to adjust accordingly.
Under the positive revaluation hypothesis, we would expect the average excess return during the
event window to be positive and statistically significant. If, on the other hand, events reveal

its nationalization was reported on October 19, 1998 and this is used as the event date.




17

previously unanticipated adverse news for the banking industry (the negative revaluation
hypothesis), we would expect the average industry reaction to be statistically negative.
Alternatively, the events may reveal no new information or be considered irrelevant by the
shareholders of surviving banks. In that case, the average industry excess return would be
statistically indistinguishable from zero. To determine, which one of these cases holds, we test
the following hypothesis:

(2)

for each event e and event day k , where N is the number of surviving banks. W e also test
whether the cumulative excess returns, averaged across banks, over the [-1,1] and [-2,2]
windows are equal to zero; that is, we test

(3)

A failure to reject

H\

or

H i

for a given event, however, does not necessarily indicate

that the event had no impact on the stock returns of surviving banks. It is conceivable that while
the average impact on the stock returns of surviving banks might be statistically indistinguishable
from zero, the impact on some banks’ stocks is significant. To explore this possibility, we also
examined other characteristics of the distribution of excess returns (e.g. the median, the
minimum, and the maximum excess return) and report a number of test statistics.
In the second part of the analysis, we explored whether there was evidence of crosssectional variation in the responses of the Japanese banks to the failures. W e relate the individual
bank reactions (y,) on the event date (day 0) to measures of individual bank strength and




18

estimate the following equation:
y i0 = a + (/>CONDi

for each of the six events.

C O N D t is a

+ bxR E G I O N A L , + b 2T R U S T , + r\,

(4)

variable that describes the financial condition of bank i at

the time of the event; R E G I O N A L i is an indicator variable that equals one if bank i is a regional
bank, zero otherwise; and,

TRUSTi

is an indicator variable that equals one if bank

i

is a trust

bank. W e include the indicator variables TRUST and R E G I O N A L in our specification of
equation (4) to control for any systematic differences across various types of Japanese banks that
are not captured by our other variables.
The financial condition of banks at each event date is measured by four descriptive
variables: the ratio of loan loss reserves to total book value of equity capital (LLR), the ratio of
nonperforming loans to total book value of equity capital (NPL), the ratio of domestic loans to
firms in the construction industry, real estate sector, and finance and insurance industries to total
domestic loans (RISKY), and Moody’s Bank Financial Strength Rating (RATING), which is a
measure of a bank’s intrinsic safety and soundness.10 Banks with higher ratios of LLR, NPL, and
RISKY are assumed to be in weaker financial condition and have lower quality assets than other
banks. RATING is a cardinal measure of Moody’s Bank Financial Strength Rating and was
constructed such that banks with lower ratings have a higher value of the measure. The data

10 During our sample period, the regulatory definition of nonperforming loans was changed twice
to be more inclusive and to give a broader measure of bad loans. W e use the amount of
nonperforming loans as reported by the banks. Hence, the measure of nonperforming loans
changes over time. However, since the changes are in effect for all banks and we estimate
equation (4) separately for the different events, the change in definition should not affect our
results. As a robustness check, we also estimated equation (4) using the older, narrower
definition of nonperforming loans. The results were qualitatively similar to those reported.




19

were obtained from the December 1997, September 1998, and February 1999 disks of the Fitch
IBCA’s Bankscope database. W e estimated equation (4) separately for each measure of C O N D to
minimize multicollinearity problems among the four variables.
If shareholders differentiate between weak and strong banks as measured by
their assessment of the impact of events on bank value, then we would expect

COND

(f>

in

to be

statistically negative. If the events reveal adverse news, the excess returns of banks in weaker
(stronger) financial condition with higher values of

COND

would be relatively more negative

(positive). Similarly, ifthe events represent good news for the surviving banks and shareholders
differentiate across banks, the returns of stronger banks would respond more positively to the
events. Hence, a statistically significant and negative estimate for

<j>

would be consistent with

shareholders providing potential market discipline on the management of financially weak banks.
On the other hand, if an event reveals adverse news for the banking sector, but shareholders do
not differentiate among banks of different financial strength, there would be no statistical
relationship between

COND

and excess returns, consistent with the pure contagion hypothesis.

To explore these possibilities, we test the hypothesis
#o :0 = 0,

(5)

for each of the six events and the four alternative measures of C O N D .

V.

Empirical results
Table 2 reports the estimated average excess returns for the banking industry and the

distribution of excess returns for individual banks on and around each of the six events. The first
five rows of each panel describe the excess returns for each day in the five-day event window.




20

The last two rows report statistics on the cumulative returns over the [-1, 1] and [-2, 2] windows,
respectively. The cumulative returns are calculated as the sum of excess returns in each day in the
relevant event window.
The firstcolumn of table 2 reports the mean of individual banks’excess returns, weighted
equally, for an event day or window.11 The second column reports the p-values associated with
the t-tests for testing whether the excess returns differ from zero as given by hypotheses
H i

H [0

and

in equations (2) and (3). The t-ratios are calculated by dividing the average parameter

estimates for each excess return by the sample cross-sectional standard deviation, and assuming
that each parameter estimate is an independent drawing from the same (normal) distribution.
Columns 3 through 6 of table 2 provide additional information on the distribution of
individual banks’ excess returns. Column 3 reports the total number of banks that had negative
excess returns on each event day and over the three and five day event windows. Column 4
reports the median excess returns and the results of the Wilcoxon signed-rank z-statistic test for
evaluating whether the median values of excess returns equal zero (see Deshpande, Gore, and
Shanubhogue, 1995). Because the average excess returns associated with an event may be
statistically indistinguishable from zero, but most banks have a negative or positive excess
return, or the cross-sectional mean of excess returns is influenced by a few outliers, the statistics
in the last four columns provide additional useful information.
The results in table 2 indicate that the average and the median excess returns for surviving

11 These averages of more than 100 regression coefficients estimated for individual banks can be
interpreted as excess returns for an equally-weighted portfolio of the sampled banks. The model
was estimated for individual banks in order to obtain the distribution of bank-specific excess
returns.




21

banks on the event day (day 0) were mostly negative and statistically significant. Of the six
average returns on the event day, four are negative, but only three are significant at the 5 percent
level. Only the average return for the announcement of the nationalization of N C B is, on
average, positive and significant. Likewise, the median excess returns for the event dates were
negative and statistically significant for four of the six failures. Although the mean excess return
for the LTCB nationalization is statistically indistinguishable from zero, the median return is
negative and significant, suggesting that the mean is influenced by a few large positive returns.
In addition, 76 out of 106 of sample banks had negative excess returns on the announcement of
L T C B ’s nationalization.
An examination of excess returns both in the two days following the announcements and
cumulatively over the [-1, 1] and [-2, 2] windows indicates that the impact from the failure
announcements was relatively stronger in the two days following the failures. Of the six average
cumulative returns over the [-1, 1] window, five are significant and four are negative. Only the
average cumulative return associated with the Sanyo Securities event is insignificant. Again, the
impact of N C B ’s nationalization on surviving banks appears to be different from the previous
events. The average cumulative excess return over both the [-1, 1] and [-2, 2] windows are
positive and statistically significant. In addition, of the 18 average excess returns over the three
days 0 to 2, 13 are significantly different from zero and 11 of the 13 are negative. Except for the
nationalization of the NCB, this is consistent with the negative revaluation hypothesis.
These results suggest that shareholders of Japanese banks viewed most of the failures as
adverse news for the surviving banks and incorporated the new information into share prices
quickly and efficiently. These findings are consistent with the results in Peek and Rosengren




22

(1999), Bremer and Pettway (1999), Chiou (1999), and Yamori (1999).12 To determine whether
the response of shareholders was based on the financial characteristics of the individual banks,
we relate the individual banks’ excess returns on the event day to measures of the banks’
financial strength, as modeled in equation (4). The results are reported in table 3.
As can be seen in the table, financially weaker banks were, on the whole, affected more
adversely by the failure announcements. The higher a surviving bank's ratio of loan loss reserve
or nonperforming loans to its equity capital and the higher its ratio of loans to firms in the riskier
construction, real estate, and finance and insurance industries relative to its total loans, the more
negative were its excess returns. Likewise, the higher rated banks were affected less by the
failure announcements than were the lower rated banks. That is, the failures were perceived by
the market as relatively "good news" for the financially sounder banks and as “bad news” for the
more precarious banks.
The results are particularly strong for the three failures in 1997. Although most of the
coefficient have negative signs, for the Hyogo failure in 1995 and the two nationalizations in
1998, they are not statistically significant. Again the nationalization of the N C B produces results
that are inconsistent with those for the other failures, but are not, in general, statistically

12Although the overall results in Peek and Rosengren (1999) are similar to our results, there are
some differences in the impact of individual events. These differences in the results of the two
studies can be due to (1) differences in the response of different claimholders in question
(shareholders in this paper versus unsecured creditors in Peek and Rosengren); or (2) differences
in the samples (all banks that trade in the Tokyo Stock Exchange in our sample versus three to
eight banks that have interbank quotations in London in the Peek and Rosengren sample). W e reestimated equation (1) with the sample of banks in Peek and Rosengren. The response of the
shareholders of the smaller sample of banks was roughly similar to the response of these banks’
unsecured creditors. Hence, any differences with respect to individual events that exist between
the results in Peek and Rosengren and the results of this paper appear to be due to differences in
bank samples, rather than differences in the structure of the claims under study.




23

significant. Thus, the evidence provides little support for the pure contagion hypothesis. Rather,
investors responded to the failures rationally according to the financial condition of the surviving
bank. Weaker banks were more adversely affected than stronger banks. In future work, we will
examine the responses for longer event windows. W e will also adjust our methodology for
potential cross-sectional and time-series correlation in excess returns of individual banks.

VI.

Summary and Conclusions
This paper examined the ability of the Japanese stock market to price Japanese bank

shares according to their risk characteristics during the country’s banking crisis and to
incorporate new information into the share prices. The failure of four domestic commercial
banks of various sizes between 1995 and 1998, and of two security firms in 1997 were events
that signaled information that could affect the perceived risk environment of the surviving banks
and trigger responses in their share prices. The sample examined consists of more than one
hundred banks, whose shares traded on the Tokyo Stock Exchange during the 1990s.
Two sets of hypotheses were tested — the first concerns the average response of the
overall bank share prices to the failures and the second concerns the response of individual bank
share prices. The failures represented new information that affected equity returns. Returns in
the industry as a whole responded negatively to five of the six failures. The average abnormal
returns were negative on or around the failure of all but the Nippon Credit Bank. The negative
response is consistent with the negative revaluation hypothesis and implies that the failures were
perceived to be bad news for other banks as a whole, possibly signaling either or both increased
public recognition of the weak financial condition of the industry and/or feared stronger
responses to bank problems by the regulatory agencies.




24

The response of individual banks to these failures was for the most part related to the
financial condition of the bank. Abnormal returns tended to be more negative for banks in
weaker financial condition as reflected in higher ratios of loan loss reserves, nonperforming
loans, risky loans, and in lower Moody’s credit ratings, and less negative and even positive for
banks in better financial condition. This suggests that the market was able to differentiate among
banks in its response to the failures, so that any contagion from the failures was rational and
information-based.
The evidence presented in the paper suggests that the Japanese stock market priced the
relative risk characteristics of banks even in periods of severe banking crisis and incorporated
new information quickly and reasonably efficiently. Thus, there is little reason to suspect that
market monitoring and discipline cannot be used by bank regulators in Japan more extensively to
supplement regulatory discipline and to promote a safer and more efficient banking system.




25

References
Aharony, Joseph and Itzhak Swary, 1983, “Contagion Effects of Bank Failure: Evidence from
Capital Markets,” J o u r n a l o f B u s in e s s 56(3), 305-322.
Binder, John J., 1985a, “Measuring the Effects of Regulation with Stock Price Data,” R a n d
J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m ic s 16(2), 167-183.
Binder, John J., 1985b, “On the Use of the Multivariate Regression Model in Event Studies,”
23(1), 370-383.

J o u r n a l o f A c c o u n t in g R e s e a r c h

Binder, John J., 1988, “The Sherman Antitrust Act and the Railroad Cartels,” J o u r n a l
a n d E c o n o m ic s 31(2), 443-467.
Binder, John J., 1998, ‘The Event Study Methodology Since 1969,” R e v ie w
11(2), 111-37.

o f Law

o f Q u a n tita tiv e

F in a n c e a n d A c c o u n t in g

Bremer, Marc and Richard H. Pettway, 1999, “Does the Market Discipline Japanese Banks?”
University of Missouri manuscript.
Brewer in, Elijah, 1995,“The Impact of Deposit Insurance on S & L Shareholders' Risk/Retum
Trade-Offs,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l S e r v ic e s R e s e a r c h 9(1), 65-89.
Brewer HI, Elijah and William E. Jackson El, 1998, “Requiem for a Market Maker: The Case of
Drexel Burnham Lambert and Below-Investment-Grade Bonds,” unpublished manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, December.
Chiou, Ingyu, 1999, “Daiwa Bank’s Reputational Crisis: Valuation Effects on Bank-Firm
Relationships,” manuscript, New York University.
Cornell, Bradford and Alan Shapiro, 1986, “The Reaction of Bank Stock Prices to the
International Debt Crisis,” J o u r n a l o f B a n k in g a n d F in a n c e 10(1), 55-73.
Deshpande, J.V., A.P. Gore, and A. Shanubhogue, 1995, S t a t is t ic a l A n a ly s is
New Delhi, India: Wiley Eastern Limited.

o f N o n n o rm a l D a ta ,

Flannery, Mark J., 1998, “ Using Market Information in Prudential Bank Supervision: A Review
of the U.S. Empirical Evidence,” J o u r n a l o f M o n e y , C r e d it a n d B a n k in g 30, 273-305.
Genay, Hesna, 1998, “Assessing the condition of Japanese banks: How informative are
accounting earnings?” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago E c o n o m ic P e r s p e c tiv e s , Fourth Quarter,
12-34.
Grammatikos, Theoharry and Anthony Saunders, 1990, “Additions to Bank Loan-Loss Reserves:
Good News or Bad News?” J o u r n a l o f M o n e t a r y E c o n o m i c s 25(2), 289-304.




26

Kane, Edward J. and Haluk Unal, 1988, “Change in Market Assessments of Deposit Institution
Riskiness,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l S e r v ic e s R e s e a r c h 1(3), 207-29.
Karafiath, Imre, 1988, “Using D u m m y Variables in the Event Methodology Structure,” F in a n c ia l
23(3), 351-358.

R e v ie w

Karafiath, Imre and John Glascock, 1989, “Intra-Industry Effects of a Regulatory Shift: Capital
Market Evidence from Penn Square,” F in a n c ia l R e v ie w 24(1), 123-134.
Karafiath, Imre, Ross Mynatt, and Kenneth L. Smith, 1991, “The Brazilian Default
Announcement and the Contagion Effect Hypothesis,” J o u r n a l o f B a n k in g a n d F in a n c e 15(3),
699-716.
Kaufman, George G., 1994, “Bank Contagion: A Review of the Theory and Evidence,” J o u r n a l
o f F in a n c ia l S e r v ic e s R e s e a r c h 8(2), 123-150.
Lang, Larry H. and Rene M. Stulz, 1992, “Contagion and Competitive Intra-industry Effects of
Bankruptcy Announcements: An Empirical Analysis,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l E c o n o m ic s 32(1),
45-60.
MacKinlay, A. Craig, 1997, “Event Studies in Economics and Finance,” J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m ic
L it e r a t u r e 35(1), 13-39.
Madura, Jeff and Kenneth Bartunek, 1994, “Contagion Effects of the Bank of New England’s
Failure,” R e v ie w o f F in a n c ia l E c o n o m ic s 4(1), 25-37.
Malatesta, Paul, 1986, “Measuring Abnormal Performance: The Event Parameter Approach
Using Joint Generalized Least Squares,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l a n d Q u a n tita tiv e A n a ly s is 21(1),
27-38.
McGill, Peter, 1995, “Japan: Has the M O F Muffed it?”

E u ro m o n e y ,

97.

Millon-Comett, Marcia H. and Hassan Tehranian, 1989, “Stock Market Reactions to the
Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980,” J o u r n a l o f B a n k in g
a n d F in a n c e 13 (1), 81-100.
Millon-Comett, Marcia M. and Hassan Tehranian, 1990, “An Examination of the Impact of the
Gam-St Germain Depository Institutions Act of 1982 on Commercial Banks and Savings and
Loan,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c e 45(1), 95-111.
Peek, Joe and Eric S.Rosengren, 1999, “Determinants of the Japan Premium: Actions Speak
Louder than Words,” T h e J o u r n a l o f I n t e r n a t i o n a l E c o n o m i c s , forthcoming.




27

Peterson, Pamela P. and Wall, L. D., 1991, “Valuation Effects of New Capital Issues by Large
Bank Holding Companies,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l S e r v ic e s R e s e a r c h 5(1), 77-87.
Reuter’s News Service, 1995, “Moody’s Says Weak Japan Banks Will Need Help,” October 24,
1995.
Schipper, Katherine and Rex Thompson, 1983, ‘The Impact of Merger-Related Regulations on
the Shareholders of Acquiring Firms,” J o u r n a l o f A c c o u n t in g R e s e a rc h 21,184-221.
Scholes, Myron and Joseph Williams, 1977, “Estimating Betas from Nonsynchronous Data,”
J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l E c o n o m ic s 5(3), 309-327.
Schwert, G. William, 1981, “Using Financial Data to Measure the Effects of Regulation,”
24(1),121-158.

J o u r n a l o flx c w a n d E c o n o m ic s

Swary, Itzhak, 1986, “Stock Market Reaction to Regulatory Action in the Continental Illinois
Crisis,” J o u r n a l o f B u s in e s s 59(3), 451-473.
Wall, Larry D. and David R. Peterson, 1990, ‘The Effect of Continental Illinois'Failure on the
Financial Performance of Other Banks,” J o u r n a l o f M o n e t a r y E c o n o m ic s , 26(1), 77-99.
Yamori, Nobuyoshi, 1999, “Stock Market Reaction to the Bank Liquidation in Japan: A Case for
the Information Effect Hypothesis,” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l S e r v ic e s R e s e a r c h 15:1,57-68.




28

Table 1. A Comparison of Failed and Surviving Institutions
T his table presents a com parison o f the accounting and stock market perform ance o f the three banks that failed in
1997 and 1998 to the perform ance o f surviving banks. M arket-adjusted stock returns are calcu lated as the daily
stock return o f a bank m inus the return on the valu e-w eigh ted index for the T o k y o S to ck E xch an ge, and, for
surviving banks, are averaged across banks. T h e sam ple periods for stock returns are 185 trading d ays betw een
January 3 0 , 1997 and O ctober 2 9 , 1997 for the 199 7 failure; and the 221 trading days betw een N ovem b er 18, 1997
and O ctober 14, 1998 for the 1998 failures.

A.

Banks
1998 Failures

1997 Failures
H okkaido
Takushoku

Surviving
B anks
(N = 1 0 6 )

L ongTerm
Credit
B ank

N ip p on
Credit
Bank

S u rvivin g
B anks
(N = 1 0 4 )

A cco u n tin g earnings (three-year average, in percent)
R eturn on average equity

-6 .7 0

-2 .5 8

-1 3 .8 7

-5 4 .3 0

-6 .5 5

R eturn on average assets

-0 .2 0

-0 .0 5

-0 .4 6

-0 .9 4

-0 .1 9

A sse t Q uality (a s o f last financial statem ent b efore failure, in percent)
L oan lo ss reserves /
G ross loans

4 .9 0

1.74

4 .7 8

9 .0 6

2 .8 0

N onperform ing loan s /
G ross loan s

13.31

3 .2 9

6 .5 2

1 6 .0 4

3 .4 2

R isky loans / T otal
dom estic loans

3 4 .6 5

2 5 .7 6

4 6 .4 7

6 2 .0 1

2 6 .2 8

C apital and S iz e (as o f last financial statem ent before failure)
B IS ratio (% )

9 .3 5

9 .3 9

10.32

8.25

10.01

T otal assets (trillion yen)

9 .0 5

7 .5 6

2 5 .0 8

12.23

5 .5 6

0 .3 3 1

0 .0 7 1

M arket-adjusted S tock R eturns
M ean

-0 .3 5 1

-0 .0 4 3

-0 .9 2 6

B. Securities Firms
Sanyo
Securities
T otal assets (trillion ¥ )

Y am aichi
S ecu rities

A ll other
(N = 19)

T he “B ig T h ree*”

0 .2 6

1.93

0 .7 2

3.65

6 3 .0 8
-0 .8 3

2 2 5 .1 2
-8 .7 5

1 7 8 .4 2
-3 .4 8

2 7 1 .7 1
-4 .7 4

R O E (%)

-3 .9 6

-3 1 .5 2

4 9 .4 9

8 8 .0 8

-1 8 .8
7 1 .5 2

-1 4 .8 2

L iquid assets / Short-term funding (%)

E quity / A ssets (% )
R O A (%)

6 9 .1 4

* T he “B ig T hree”are N om ura Securities, N ik k o S ecurities, and D aiw a Securities.




29

Table 2 Excess Returns of Surviving Banks
T h is table describ es the distribution o f e x c e ss returns across su rvivin g banks in the fiv e-d a y w in d ow surrounding the
sev en events. E x c e ss returns are d efin ed as yik in the equation:
R i,

/+2
2
= «, + X P isR ms + X
s—t—2

VaPk

+ £it.

k=-2

w hich is estim ated for each bank in the sam ple. T h e colu m n lab eled “M ean ” reports the cro ss-sectio n a l averages o f
e x c e ss returns for each day in the ev en t w in d o w , as w ell as the cu m u lative e x c e ss returns over the [-1, 1] and [-2, 2]
w in d ow s. T he colu m n lab eled “P -value: m ean = 0 ” reports the p -valu es for the h yp oth esis test

Hl
0 :— ^y.k =

0•

T he colum n labeled “P ercent n egative” reports the percent o f total e x c e ss returns that are n egative, and the colum n
labeled “M edian ” reports the m edian value o f e x c e ss returns and its statistical sig n ifica n ce. T h e colu m n s labeled
“M inim um ” and “M axim u m ” report the m inim um and m axim um valu es o f the e x c e ss returns. ***’ and
indicate
statistical sig n ifica n ce at the 1% and 5% le v e ls, resp ectively.

H Y O G O FAILURE (August 31,1995; N=100)
M ean

P-value:
m ean = 0

Perce? it
negative

M edian

M inim um

M axim um

-2

-0 .4 2 2

0 .0 0 0 6

70

-0 .3 8 * *

-5 .5 0

4 .3 1

-1

0 .0 0 6

0 .9 6 5 8

48

0 .1 8

-7 .2 5

3 .0 4

0

-0 .7 9 3

0 .0 0 0 2

71

-0 .1 9 * *

-8 .0 3

3.41

1

-0 .9 2 6

0 .0 0 0 1

71

-0 .6 2 * *

-6 .1 9

5 .6 6

2

0 .1 5 4

0 .4 2 7 1

44

0 .2 4

-9 .5 0

6 .8 9

[ - 1 .1 ]
t - 2 ,2 ]

-1 .7 1 3

0 .0 0 0 1

74

-1 .1 0 * *

-1 5 .3 5

1 .4 6

-1 .9 8 2

0 .0 0 0 1

75

-0 .9 9 * *

-1 9 .4 7

3 .6 2

SAN Y O FAILURE (November 4,1997; N=102)
M ean

P -value:
m ean = 0

Percent
n egative

M ed ian

M inim um

M axim um

-2

0 .3 8 9

0 .0 5 5 4

46

0 .3 0

-7 .7 9

4 .4 5

-1
0

1.147
-0 .6 8 4

0 .0 0 0 1
0 .0 0 0 6

31
68

0 .8 4 * *

-5 .6 1
-7 .8 8

9 .0 4
3 .8 8

1
2

-0 .3 2 6

0 .1 4 8 0
0 .0 0 0 2

54

0 .0 0

-6 .7 1

-0 .9 6 5

68

-0 .4 3 * *

-1 4 .2 2

7 .2 6
3 .8 4

[ - l.i]
[ - 2 ,2 ]

0 .1 3 6

0 .6 9 9 6

50

0 .1 4

-1 0 .2 8

1 7.80

-0 .4 3 9

0 .4 2 5 9

48

0 .3 8

-2 8 .6 7

2 1 .5 2

-0 .6 6 * *

H O K K A I D O T A K U S H O K U FAILURE (November 17,1997; N=102)
M ean

P-value:
m ean = 0

Percent
negative

M edian

M inim um

M axim um

-2

-0 .3 6 0

0 .1 9 9 7

63

-0 .2 6 *

-1 1 .2 0

- -1

-1 .0 2 6

0 .0 0 1 3

66

-0 .4 3 * *

-1 8 .2 7

9.51

0

0 .2 3 2

0 .5 8 6 2

55

0 .0 0

-2 3 .4 8

14.05

7 .3 8

1

-1 .1 0 7

0 .0 0 6 0

66

-0 .5 0 * *

-1 9 .5 5

9 .8 9

2

-2 .1 7 5

0.0 0 0 1

68

-0 .7 9 * *

-3 0 .7 5

7 .7 0

[ - i , i]
[-2, 2]

-1.901

0 .0 0 3 5

68

-1 .1 8 * *

-2 6 .9 7

14.50

-4 .4 3 6

0 .0001

77

-2 .7 4 * *

-4 7 .5 0

16.68




30

Table2. Excess Returns ofSurvivingBanks, continued
YAMA1CHI FAILURE (November 25,1997; N=102)
M ean

P-value:
m ean = 0

Percent
negative

0 .2 6 4 5

57

M edian
-0 .0 2

M inim um

M axim um

-2 3 .3 8

15.82

-0 .3 4

-17.91

2 1 .3 0

-0 .8 9 *

-2 4 .8 0

5 .7 9

-2

-0 .5 4 8

-1
0
1

0 .2 3 9

0 .5 4 8 4

58

-2 .6 3 9

63

-4 .5 2 5

0.0001
0.0001

71

-1 .5 8 * *

-3 7 .5 5

7 .6 7

2

1 .8 1 0

0 .0 3 3 3

48

0 .0 8

-3 0 .3 9

3 5 .0 4

M . 1]
[ - 2 ,2 ]

-6 .9 2 5

0.0001
0.0001

82

-3 .2 0 * *

-6 3 .2 9

2 0 .4 0

73

-3 .3 1 * *

-7 0 .0 0

2 9 .3 4

-5 .6 6 3

The LTCB Nationalization (October 19,1998; N=106)
M ean

P-value:
m ean = 0

Percent
n egative

M edian

M inim um

M axim um

-2

-0 .3 9 8

0 .0 7 3 7

59

0 .0 0

-8 .6 9

5 .3 2

-1

-1 .0 3 2

0 .0 0 1 6

80

-0 .8 7 * *

7 .5 3
9 .0 6

0

-0 .3 4 5

0 .1 2 9 3

76

-0 .4 1 * *

-1 0 .0 7
-8 .8 4

1

-0 .5 4 1

0 .0 0 6 9

76

-0 .4 5 * *

-7 .4 4

5 .3 3

2

0 .4 9 5

0 .1 3 0 0

60

-0.01

-5 .5 4

13.62

[-1, 1]
[ - 2 ,2 ]

-1 .9 1 8

0 .0 0 0 2

74

-1 .0 2 * *

-1 8 .6 7

8 .5 6

-1 .8 2 1

0 .0 0 3 9

65

-0 .8 5 *

-1 9 .1 5

16.97

The NCB Nationalization (December 14,1998; N=106)
M ean

P-value:
m ean = 0

P ercent
n egative

M edian

M inim um

M axim u m

-2

0 .7 6 5

0 .0 0 0 1

43

0.25

-2 .3 7

6 .5 0

-1

0 .6 1 7

0 .0 0 1 3

44

0.27

-3 .6 5

7 .2 2

0

0 .6 4 3

0 .0 0 0 3

39

0 .3 5 *

-3 .7 7

6 .7 3

1

-0 .5 5 9

0 .0 0 7 8

59

0 .0 0

-1 4 .1 6

4 .0 4

2

-0 .3 4 9

0 .0 3 9 8

78

-0 .2 6 * *

-5 .3 6

6 .8 4

[ - 1 ,1 ]
[-2, 2]

0.7 0 1

0 .0 2 5 1

-8 .5 7

1 3 .3 0

0 .0 0 3 5

46
41

0 .2 0

1.117

0.8 0 *

-9 .5 2

19.23




31

Table3. Excessreturnsand FinancialStrength
T his table presents estim ates o f the correlation betw een selected m easures o f b anks’ financial con d ition and their
e x c e ss returns on the ev en t dates, estim ated b y the fo llo w in g m odel:
y i0 = a + 0 C O N D ;

+ bxR E G I O N A L , + b J R U S T , + 77,

T he dependent variable is the day 0 abnorm al return calculated from a market m od el as sp ecified in equation (1 ).
T he variable C O N D is, alternatively, the ratio o f loan lo ss reserves to total b o o k valu e o f equity (LLR); the ratio o f
nonperform ing loans to total b o o k value o f equity (N P L ); the ratio o f risky loan s (d efin ed as loans to real estate,
construction, and fin an ce sectors) to total d o m estic loans; or a cardinal m easure o f M o o d y ’s financial strength rating
(R A T IN G ), w here higher num bers correspond to low er ratings. R A T IN G is unavailable for the H y o g o failure
sam ple. T he sam ple statistics for the four m easures o f financial co n d itio n are reported in the last tw o row s o f each
panel. T he standard errors o f co effic ie n t estim ates are adjusted for heteroskedasticity. A ll equations include
unreported co efficien ts for bank type, R E G IO N A L and T R U S T .
and **’ indicate statistical sig n ifica n ce at the
1% and 5% le v e ls, resp ectively.

Hyogo Bank Failure
LLR

<t>

NPL

-1 .0 7 3

R ISK Y

-1 .3 1 6

-0 .0 3 2

St. error

1.847

1 .1 5 9

0 .0 6 1

Rz

-0 .0 1 6

-0 .0 0 8

-0 .0 5 5

F -statistic

0 .4 8 8

0 .7 5 4

0 .2 3 7

N

98

98

45

Sam p le m ean

0 .2 1 0

0 .2 4 6

2 6 .6 1 8

St. deviation

0 .1 6 1

0 .2 8 5

7 .0 7 4

Adj.

F inancial condition

Sanyo Securities Failure
L LR

N PL

R ISK Y

-0 .6 0 7 * *

-0 .2 0 8 * *

R A T IN G

<*

-1 .1 9 6 * *

St. error

0 .1 7 4

0 .0 8 2

0 .0 4 0

0 .2 3 0

Adj. R*
F-statistic

0 .1 9 6
9 .0 3 5

0 .2 1 6
1 0 .1 0 4

0 .4 2 6
11.622

0 .3 2 6

N

100

100

44

48

Sam ple m ean

0 .4 4 9

0.886

2 5 .5 7 7

4 .3 1 3

St. deviation

0.721

1 .4 9 0

7 .6 6 2

1.5 0 4

-0 .8 1 4 * *

8 .5 8 7

F inancial condition

Hokkaido Takushoku Bank Failure
N PL

LLR

R ISK Y

R A T IN G

p

-2 .1 1 4 * *

-1 .2 6 1 *

-0 .1 7 4 *

-0 .7 9 3 *

St. error

0.734
0.200

0 .5 3 0

0 .0 8 4

0 .3 4 3

A dj. R2

0 .2 6 1

0 .2 1 0

0 .1 7 3

F-statistic

9 .2 3 6

1 2 .6 4 2

4 .8 1 6

4 .2 7 3

N

100

100

44

48

0.449
0.721

0.886
1.490

25.577
7.662

4.313
1.504

F inancial condition
Sam ple mean
St. deviation




32

Table3. Excess returnsand FinancialStrength,continued
Yamaichi Securities Failure
R ISK Y

L LR

N PL

0

-2 .8 9 7 *

-1 .6 8 5 *

-0 .3 1 5 *

-2 .7 5 3 * *

St. error

1.401

0 .7 2 6

0 .1 2 4

0 .7 7 9

A d j.R * .
F-statistic

0 .0 9 4

0 .1 4 3

0.031

0 .2 0 7

4 .4 2 6

6 .5 0 2

1.457

5 .0 9 5

100

100

44

48

Sam ple m ean

0 .4 4 9

0 .8 8 6

2 5 .5 7 7

4 .3 1 3

St. deviation

0 .7 2 1

1.490

7 .6 6 2

1 .5 0 4

N

R A T IN G

Financial con d ition

LTCB Nationalization
0

L LR

NPL

-0 .6 1 9

-0 .4 2 4 *

R ISK Y
-0 .1 8 5

R A T IN G
-0 .1 1 9

St. error

0 .3 6 3

0 .1 8 7

0 .1 0 5

0 .2 4 9

A dj. R 2

0 .0 0 1

0 .0 0 8

-0 .0 0 7

-0 .0 6 6

F-statistic

1 .0 2 8

1 .2 6 9

0 .9 0 7

0 .0 9 0

N

104

104

43

45

Financial condition
Sam ple m ean

0 .6 8 9

1 .2 1 4

2 6 .2 8 5

4 .7 1 1

St. deviation

0 .6 5 0

1 .0 5 2

6.391

1.547

NCB Nationalization
L LR

0

-0 .0 4 9

NPL
0 .0 3 1

R ISK Y

R A T IN G

-0 .0 3 5

0 .3 7 7 *

St. error

0 .2 1 7

0 .1 3 8

0 .0 7 8

0 .1 4 3

A dj. R 2

-0 .0 2 1

-0 .0 2 2

-0 .0 4 0

0 .0 4 1

F-statistic

0 .2 8 9

0 .2 7 0

0 .4 5 7

1.625

N

104

104

43

45

Sam ple mean

0 .6 8 9

1 .2 1 4

2 6 .2 8 5

4 .7 1 1

St. deviation

0 .6 5 0

1.052

6.391

1.547

Financial condition